S.A.P.I.EN.S
Surveys and Perspectives Integrating Environment and
Society
4.2 | 2011
Vol.4 / n°2
Ten themes for eco-innovation policies in Europe
René Kemp
Gaëll Mainguy (éd.)
Édition électronique
URL : http://journals.openedition.org/sapiens/1169
ISSN : 1993-3819
Éditeur
Institut Veolia
Référence électronique
René Kemp, « Ten themes for eco-innovation policies in Europe », S.A.P.I.EN.S [En ligne], 4.2 | 2011, mis
en ligne le 04 octobre 2011, consulté le 23 octobre 2020. URL : http://journals.openedition.org/
sapiens/1169
Licence Creative Commons
Volume 4 issue 2
Ten themes for eco-innovation
policies in Europe
2011
S . A . P. I . E N . S
Surveys
René Kemp
Professorial fellow at UNU-MERIT in Maastricht and professor of Innovation and sustainable development
at ICIS, Maastricht University, the Netherlands
Abstract
Correspondence to: r.kemp@maastrichtuniversity.nl
’’
Most developed countries have innovation policies for green innovation. This paper examines the
rationale for such policies, offers a typology of eco-innovation and develops ten themes for ecoinnovation policy, which are: 1) the need for policy to be based on identified barriers, 2) preventing
windfall profits, 3) specific versus generic support policies, 4) balance between policy measures
and timing, 5) targeted spending in areas where innovation is needed, 6) missions, 7) strategic intelligence for innovation, 8) portfolios, 9) policy learning and 10) policy coordination and public-private
interactions. Relevant cases are discussed and empirical information is provided. It is proposed
that the ten themes serve as a framework for eco-innovation policy-making and policy evaluation.
Keywords: Innovation policy, Eco-innovation, Effective governance.
TablE of CoNTENTS
1 Introduction
2 Eco-innovation as a special type of innovation
3 The different rationales for eco-innovation policy
4 Eco-innovation policy in the EU
5 Themes for eco-innovation policy
5.1 Theme 1: Eco-innovation policies should be based on identified barriers
5.2 Theme 2: Preventing windfall profits
5.3 Theme 3: Specific versus general support
5.4 Theme 4: Balance of policy measures and timing
5.5 Theme 5: Targeted spending in areas where innovation is needed
5.6 Theme 6: Missions for system innovation
5.7 Theme 7: Strategic intelligence for innovation
5.8 Theme 8: Innovation portfolio
5.9 Theme 9: Policy learning
5.10 Theme 10: policy coordination and public-private interactions
6 Conclusions
Author’s note: The research for this paper was partly funded by the European Commission, through
the INNO GRIPS project “Analysis of Innovation Drivers and Barriers in Support of Better Policies”,
DG Enterprise (work package 2 Socio-economic trends for innovation policy). The results of this
work can be found in Arundel, A., Kanerva, M., Kemp, R. (2011) Integrated Innovation Policy for an
Integrated Problem: Addressing Climate Change, Resource Scarcity and Demographic Change to
2030. PRO INNO Europe: INNO-Grips II report, Brussels: European Commission, DG Enterprise
and Industry. I am grateful to the comments of two reviewers and those of Raimund Bleischwitz and
Melissa Cox, which helped me to sharpen arguments. The paper also benefitted from discussions
at the Innogrips workshop. I thank Serdar Türkeli for putting the ten themes in a comprehensive
scheme. To do so is an intellectual achievement in its own right.
Published: 5 October 2011.
Edited by: Gaëll Mainguy – This article has been reviewed by two anonymous referee.
© Author(s) 2011. This article is distributed under the Creative Commons Attribution 3.0 License.
http://sapiens.revues.org/1169
1
Kemp Ten themes for eco-innovation policies in Europe
User practices,
markets, institutions
Cradle to cradle (C2C)
Disrupt
existing
linkages
Sustain
existing
linkages
Social innovation
Transformative innovation
Organised carsharing
Smart-grid
Incremental innovation
Techno-fix
Improved
wind turbines
Electronic fuel
injection
Radical
Incremental
Carbon capturing
and sequestering
(CCS)
Technology
(knowledge,
competences,
skills)
Figure 1. Classification of eco-innovation based on technology and market/user practices
Source: Author based on Clark (1985) and Arundel et al. (2011). Note: The plotting of eco-innovations is indicative and not based on
metrics-based method. Over time the innovation may move upwards and to the right when it becomes more institutionally disruptive and
technologically radical.
1. INTRoDUCTIoN
Modern innovation policy has developed with experience
over the past 20 years. Around the turn of the century it was
heavily influenced by research by innovation scholars arguing that the focus of policy should be less on technical discovery and more on the national system in which innovation
occurs, whose features shape interactive learning processes
amongst innovation actors and the uptake of innovation in
society (Lundvall and Borras, 1998; Mytelka and Smith, 2002;
Edquist, 2004). This was followed by calls to build and organise technology innovation systems for green energy technologies (Jacobsson and Johnson, 2000; Hekkert et al., 2007;
Bergek et al., 2008) and creating strategic intelligence for
research and innovation through the use of foresight, technology assessment, benchmarking and demand articulation
(Smits and Kuhlmann, 2004). With the help of new innovation
paradigms (described in Remøe, 2008) and dedicated evaluations, innovation policy grew out of technology policy which
was primarily oriented towards military, civil engineering and
energy technologies. Eco-technologies are a beneficiary of
the greater attention to innovation for the manufacturing and
service sectors; all EU countries have a number of policies
for eco-innovation (Kletzan-Slamanig et al., 2009). Over the
course of 50 years, innovation policy has been characterised
by shifting paradigms which did not fully replace each other
but layered upon each other. The paradigms are: mission-led
support for military technologies and civil engineering technologies; policies to improve the “national system of innovation”; and a new mission-led approach with an orientation to
technologies viewed as crucial for coping with new societal
2
challenges such as demographic change (aging population),
growing health costs, environmental sustainability, or energy/
resource security (Gassler et al., 2008, p. 203). Borrás (2009,
p. 1) observes a widening and deepening of innovation policies,
in the sense that “governments are becoming more pro-active
in using deeper and new forms of policy intervention and in
expanding their areas of involvement in order to accomplish
large socio-economic goals”. Eco-innovation is a prime candidate for “new mission” policies, to deal with (interrelated)
societal challenges of climate change, resource efficiency and
energy/resource scarcity.
Between countries there are significant differences. Over half
of public R&D in the USA goes to defence, compared to 11%
in Germany, 30% in France and 40% in the UK. In Germany,
65% of public R&D is for measures which do not fall into the
categories of defence, space and key technologies (Gassler et
al., 2008, p. 213).
The focus of this paper is on the rationales for eco-innovation policy and their implications for instrument choices and
effective governance. The paper draws on the literature on
effective governance of innovation (Smits and Kuhlmann,
2004; Kaiser and Prange, 2005; Braun, 2008; Borrás, 2009)
and the more specialised literature on eco-innovation policy
(Faber et al., 2008; Kemp & Zundel, 2007; Kletzan-Slamanig
et al, 2009; OECD, 2011). The contribution is both empirical
and theoretical. The structure of the paper is as follows:
section 2 defines eco-innovation; section 3 investigates the
policy rationales for innovation and eco-innovation, where
we will see that there are two rationales (market failure and
Kemp | P2
system failure); section 4 describes EU policies and strategies for the support of eco-innovation and provides information about Member State policies for eco-innovation;
section 5 develops ten themes for eco-innovation policy; and
the final section draws conclusions.
2. ECo-INNoVaTIoN aS a SPECIal
TYPE of INNoVaTIoN
normal technology in a sector (for example, gas or coal burning stations in the case of electricity generation). It does not
have to be the best option available; innovations in coal burning technology would qualify as eco-innovation if they reduce
emissions. The second thing that follows from this is that the
term eco-innovation crucially depends on an overall assessment
of environmental effects and risks. Life cycle assessment
There are different definitions of eco-innovation and related
definitions such as environmental innovation. Past studies
of eco-innovation have focussed on environmentally motivated innovation, overlooking the environmental gains from
“normal” innovations.1
Whether or not an innovation is an eco-innovation depends
on whether the innovation on a life cycle basis is less environmentally harmful than the use of relevant alternatives. The
innovation can be less environmentally harmful by using
fewer resources, using less toxic material, being less polluting through the use of special or different process steps, and
by not relying on the use of fossil fuels. Besides the environmental gain, there should be an element of novelty, either
from the development point of view or an adoption point of
view. According to the Oslo Manual (OECD, 2005), innovation
is defined as the implementation of a new or significantly improved product (good or service), or process, a new marketing
method, or a new organizational method in business practice.
The OECD makes a distinction between innovations new to the
world and those new to the adopter.
Based on the above OECD definition of innovation, ecoinnovation may be defined in the following way (Kemp and
Pearson, 2008):
Eco-innovation is the production, assimilation or exploitation of a product, production process, service or management or business method that is novel to the organisation
(developing or adopting it) and which results, throughout
its life cycle, in a reduction of environmental risk, pollution and other negative impacts of resources use (including
energy use) compared to relevant alternatives.
In the Eco-Innovation Observatory2, the aspect of resource use
is made the central element of eco-innovation:
Eco-innovation is innovation that reduces the use of
natural resources and decreases the release of harmful
substances across the whole life-cycle.
From this, two important things follow. First, that all new processes that are more resource efficient are eco-innovations.
Anything is an eco-innovative solution as long as it is more environmentally benign than “relevant alternatives”. The relevant
alternative may be the technology in use in a company or the
S . A . P. I . E N . S
Kemp Ten themes for eco-innovation policies in Europe
Box A. MEI classification of eco-innovation
A. Environmental technologies
• Pollution control technologies including waste water
treatment technologies
• Cleaning (clean-up) technologies that treat pollution released into the environment
• Cleaner process technologies: new manufacturing
processes that are less polluting and/or more resource
efficient than relevant alternatives
• Waste management equipment
• Environmental monitoring and instrumentation
• Green energy technologies
• Water supply
• Noise and vibration control
B. Organizational innovation for the environment:
• Pollution prevention schemes
• Environmental management and auditing systems: formal systems of environmental management involving
measurement, reporting and responsibilities for dealing
with issues of material use, energy, water and waste.
Examples are EMAS and ISO 14001.
• Chain management: cooperation between companies so
as to close material loops and to avoid environmental
damage across the value chain (from cradle to grave)
C. Product and service innovation offering environmental
benefits:
• New or environmentally improved products (goods) including eco-houses and buildings
• Green financial products (such as eco-lease or climate
mortgages)
• Environmental services: solid and hazardous waste
management, water and waste water management, environmental consulting, testing and engineering, other
testing and analytical services
• Services that are less pollution and resource intensive
(car sharing is an example)
D. Green system innovations:
• Alternative systems of production and consumption that
are more environmentally benign than existing systems:
biological agriculture and a renewables-based energy
system are examples
Source: Kemp and Pearson (2008)
1 “Normal” innovations are developed for normal market reasons of saving costs or providing better services to users.
2 See http://www.eco-innovation.eu/
Kemp | P3
3
Kemp Ten themes for eco-innovation policies in Europe
Table 1. Types of market failure and system failure
Market failure
System failure
Public good nature of knowledge gives rise to problems of appropriation
the benefits from innovation (e.g. risk of imitation)
Inadequacies in the technology/knowledge infrastructure
Uncertainty and incomplete information about costs and benefits
of innovation
Old and rigid technological capabilities within companies causing
transition failures to new knowledge bases
Market power
Insufficient entrepreneurship
Entry barriers
Not enough risk capital and high capital costs
Network externalities causing a lock-out
Regulations acting as barriers to innovation
Price gap for environmental innovations at the beginning of the
learning curve
Unfamiliarity with and social resistance to certain innovations
Actors not being able to coordinate joint action
Source: Author based on Faber et al. (2008)
based on multi-attribute value theory can be used for such
an assessment. We should note here that this approach may
create a problem for survey analysis: the respondents’ assessment of whether an innovation is better than relevant
alternatives on a life cycle basis need not be true. In fact, the
knowledge may not be available or may crucially depend on
how and where the innovation is used. Life cycle assessment (LCA) analyses been completed only for a handful of
products and processes, in which restrictive assumptions
have to be made about for example the intensity of use and
re-use of materials.
In 2008, the European Commission funded a project called MEI
(Measuring Eco-Innovation) with the aim of developing a classification of eco-innovation. The resulting typology is summarised in Box A.
The MEI classification of eco-innovation includes but is not
limited to the important category environmental technologies.
It includes organizational innovations for the environment and
environmentally beneficial product and service innovations
including innovations for which the environmental benefit is
not a special aim. It also includes green system innovation,
comprehensive changes in the systems of power supply, mobility, and food and agriculture.
The term eco-innovation supersedes the concept of environmental technology. The OECD is using it as a central
concept within discussions on green growth, alongside
the term sustainable manufacturing (OECD, 2008). For the
European Commission, “eco-innovation is the natural junction of the pursuit towards sustainability, competitiveness
and job creation” (European Commission, 2010, p. 60).
3. THE DIffERENT RaTIoNalES
foR ECo-INNoVaTIoN PolICY
There are various rationales for the need for eco-innovation policy. These include market failure rationale and
system failure rationale, each of which is composed of different elements. The market failure argument comes from
neo- classical economics, which is concerned with efficient
allocation of resources.
The neoclassical arguments for support of innovation have to
do with:
1 public good nature of knowledge causing an “appropriability” problem (innovators are unable to appropriate
the full social and economic benefits from innovation);
2 uncertainty about the costs and benefits of innovation;
An alternative classification, highly relevant for policy, is
whether or not the innovation is technologically radical and
institutionally radical. For example, smart grids are technologically and institutionally radical, electronic fuel injection
systems are only technologically radical and organised car
sharing is only institutionally radical (see Figure 1). Innovations that do not fit with existing rules and practices require
changes in the institutional set up. Radical innovations usually
come from outsiders. Barriers may be economic and institutional, an issue which is examined in section 3.
4
3 market entry barriers and monopoly power working
against innovation from challengers.
The first argument is usually singled out as the market failure
argument for innovation policy. According to economic theory, companies will under-invest in research and innovation,
because of uncertainty and the public good nature of knowledge, making it difficult for innovators to appropriate the
economic benefits of an innovation in the market place. First
mover advantages and patents however can compensate for
Kemp | P4
S . A . P. I . E N . S
Kemp Ten themes for eco-innovation policies in Europe
Macroeconomic and
regulatory context
Communication
infrastructures
Education and
training system
Global
innovation networks
Product market
conditions
Firms’ capabilities
and networks
Other
research
bodies
Science
system
Clusters of
industries
Regional
innovation systems
Knowledge generation, diffusion and use
Supporting
institutions
National innovation system
Factor market
conditions
National innovation capacity
COUNTRY PERFORMANCE
Growth, job creation, competitiveness
Figure 2. A systemic view of innovation
Source: Managing National Innovation Systems (OECD, 1999)
this. When patent protection is very strong (as in the case of
pharmaceuticals) there may be overinvestment in R&D and
monopoly-based inefficiencies through patent races where
the first one to get a patent can dominate the market. Contrary
to wide belief, the neoclassical case for innovation support
is not clear-cut. Companies may do either too little R&D or
too much. There is also not a perfect solution to the problems. In the absence of perfect information about (marginal)
costs and benefits (which are likely to differ among potential
innovations), it is unclear what the optimal level of R&D is. As
Metcalfe and Georghiou (1998, p. 81) write:
Jaffe et al., 2005; Popp, 2006; Newell, 2010; Popp, 2010), one
having to do with the public good nature of knowledge and one
based on the non-internalisation of negative effects from economic activity. As to the problem of uncertainty, perhaps ecoinnovation may suffer more from information problems than
normal innovation. Consumers may distrust environmental
claims or be unaware of environmental aspects.
While market failure provides a general rationale for
policy intervention, it is inherently imprecise in its
detailed prescription: a firm may spend too much or too
little on innovation, it may innovate too quickly or too
slowly, it may undertake excessively risky projects or
be too conservative.
The market failure idea has been complemented by the
system failure idea (Smith, 2000), referring to problems of
technology infrastructure, technology capabilities acting as
technology rigidities, and institutional inadequacies (in capital markets, organizations and public policy, see Table 1).3
Within companies, conservative mindsets, lack of entrepreneurship and short-termism are believed to work against
(non-incremental) innovation but there may also be more
structural and broader factors acting against innovation
such as lack of venture capital.
Also eco-innovators may produce too much innovation but the
danger of that is far smaller because eco-innovator suffers from
perhaps an even more important market failure which is that
the external costs of environmentally unfriendly alternatives are
usually not internalised (reflected in the price), but transferred
to society and the environment. In the case of eco-innovation, it
is being said that we have two market failures (Rennings, 2000;
The idea of system failure is based on a system-evolutionary
view (Smith, 2000; Lipsey and Carlaw, 1998) of innovation
dynamics that sees innovation activities as embedded in a
system of knowledge generation, diffusion and use, with
national innovation capacity being shaped by education
and training systems, market conditions for factors and
products, the macroeconomic and regulatory context (for
3 In case of great rigidities, it is common to talk about lock-in. Unruh (2000) argues that fossil-fuel based energy systems have undergone processes of reinforcing
adaptations leading to the current dominance of high carbon technologies and the accumulated knowledge, capital outlays, infrastructure, available skills, production routines, social norms, regulations and life styles which support these, which he calls carbon lock-in.
Kemp | P5
5
Kemp Ten themes for eco-innovation policies in Europe
120
100
80
60
40
20
Increase and focusresearch,
demonstration and…
Establishing
technology platforms
Establishing European
Networks of technology testing…
Develop on EU catalogue of
existing directories and databases…
Ensure that new and revised
standards are performance-related
Develop and agree on
performance targets for key…
Mobilising financial
instruments to share the risks of…
Public/private partnerships
Promote new business niches
Financial instruments for
renewables and energy efficiency…
Measures in support of ecoindustries
Promote socially and
environmentally responsible…
Dissemination of good practices
among financial institutions
Identification of opportunities to
integrate environmental…
Review operational criteria of the
Structural Funds
Review state aid guidelines
Encourage systematic
internalisation of costs through…
Review environmentallyharmful
subsidies
Encourage procurement of
environmental technologies
Life cycle costing promotion
Investigation of technology
procurement
Raise business and consumer
awareness
Provision of targeted training
Promotion of environmental
technologies in Developing
Promoting responsible
investments in and use of…
Regular Review of
the Action Plan
European Panel on
Environmental Technologies
Open Method of Co-ordination
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
Getting from research
to markets
Improving Market Conditions
Acting
Globally
Moving Forward
Figure 3. Overview of eco-innovation measures in EU Member States
Source: Kletzan-Slamanig et al (2009, p. 49), based on answers from ETAP Member State contacts to WIFO questionnaire in 2009.
a discussion with examples, see Kaiser and Prange, 2005).
Within a structuralist evolutionary perspective, a country’s
economic and environmental performance depends on
capabilities, interaction effects and shaping conditions, as
depicted in Figure 2.
The dynamic aspects of interconnected processes of change
are taken up in the literature about sustainability transitions, technological regime shifts and functions approaches of technology innovation systems (Kemp, 1994; Rip and
Kemp, 1998; Jacobsson and Johnson, 2000; Geels, 2002,
2004; Elzen et al., 2004; Smith and Stirling, 2010; Grin et al.,
2010). Within this literature, technology is situated in the
contexts that enable it to work, which means that the focal
concern is not just with artefacts, but with the structures,
agents and processes that reproduce a ‘socio-technical
practice’ (Smith and Stirling, 2010). The literature finds
that “some socio-technical systems are embedded more
robustly than others, in the sense that they enjoy greater
institutional support, larger economic significance, more
supportive infrastructures, better integration with other
social practices, and broader political legitimacy” (Smith
and Stirling, 2010). These factors can help some systems to
survive—and even to expand—even when they impose a considerable cost upon society.
6
A good example of lock-in is car-based modes of mobility,
which cause carbon emissions, local air pollution, noise, congestion, traffic accidents and deaths, social exclusion, land
fragmentation, and problems of oil dependence and energy
security (Cohen, 2006). These problems are addressed in a
partial and piecemeal manner. Examples include the requirement for seat belts to reduce injuries from collisions, unleaded
petrol to prevent neural damage from lead poisoning, road
pricing to deal with congestion (a measure which has proved
difficult to implement), fuel injection systems to increase the
efficiency of engines and emission control systems in the
case of cars. A common feature of these examples is that
the solution is found within the system of automobility and
not in alternative systems of mobility. Technological alternatives must compete not only with components of an existing
technology, but also with the overall system in which it is
embedded (Smith, 2000, p. 96).
A special feature of environmental innovation is that the
market for environmental innovation is largely a market
commanded by environmental policy. In the case of environmental regulation in the form of emission limit values there
are hardly any incentives for reducing environmental impact
beyond what is legally required. Suppliers of environmental
goods and services may speculate that better eco-technology
Kemp | P6
will become mandatory, but this usually takes many years; it
is estimated that it takes more than six years before standards are adapted to new technology (Krozer, 2002). In the case
of a product ban or a ban of a dangerous substance, there is
a strong incentive for innovation, as happened in the case of
CFCs and PCBs, for which substitutes were developed in a
short period of time. But such bans are rare. In the case of
regulations that can be met by existing technology, positive
incentives do exist for cost-saving environmental innovation.
There is always an incentive for cost-reducing eco-innovation,
whatever policy is used.
4. ECo-INNoVaTIoN PolICY IN THE EU
Within the system failure perspective, it is knowledge barriers, institutional barriers and competition with old products that create problems for non-incremental innovation.
The task for policy is to build effective innovation systems 4
(Nelson, 2009). The focus is on knowledge, capabilities
for innovation and institutions governing learning activities. Applied to eco-innovation, the problem is believed to
lie with the innovation system, which is underdeveloped for
eco-innovation or favouring incremental change over radical change. An innovation system comprises many things:
the infrastructure of knowledge and access thereto, labs for
testing and research, the knowledge transfers taking place
in companies, universities and research institutes, and the
regulations and customs that may promote or inhibit environmental innovation. Other forms of system failure are
insufficient risk capital and high capital costs, insufficient
entrepreneurship, lack of knowledge, resistance from users, and absence of complementary assets including infrastructure. System failure refers to a dysfunctional system
of innovation. Environmental innovation suffers from both
market failure and system failure. The distinction between
these two types of failure is not always a sharp one. The
system failure idea offers an important complement to the
market failure idea, by drawing attention to more structural
factors with their own path dependencies.
Although innovation has always been seen as part of the
solution in environmental problems, prior to 2005 few programmes at the EU-level specifically addressed the stimulation of environmental innovations. There are two notable
exceptions: first, the fairly small ACE-Programme (Action
Communautaire pour l’Environnement), which ran from
1984-1991 with a total budget of 41 million euro; second, its
successor, the LIFE-Programme (L’Instrument Financiel
pour l’Environnement), which has been running since 1992,
with a cumulative budget of well over 1.3 billion EUR (Faber
et al., 2008, p. 191). The LIFE-Programme is a broad tool
for the implementation of the Union’s environmental policy.
It subsidizes the demonstration of new technologies with
positive effects on the environment, but it is not exclusively
focussed on technologies or innovations, since, for example,
nature conservation projects can apply for subsidy. Overall,
almost 2500 projects were supported until 2004 (Faber et al.,
2008, p. 191).
S . A . P. I . E N . S
Kemp Ten themes for eco-innovation policies in Europe
European innovation policy is primarily focused on the promotion of international cooperation in R&D. The Framework Programmes (FP) are the main instrument for this. Environment
and sustainable development are explicitly part of all FPs. In
the Sixth Framework Programme, 2.1 billion EUR is labelled
for the priority theme sustainable energy, environment and
transport (Faber et al., 2008, p. 190). The 7th framework programme is said to support environmental technologies up to a
sum of 10 billion EUR.5
Not every environmental innovation faces the same number of problems; particularly radical innovations with environmental benefits and green system innovations, which
require change and adaptation at the supply and demand
side and institutional framework, can be expected to face
many problems. Radical innovations have uncertain yields
and require a long period of development and long-term
investment; they usually require the involvement of many
actors for their development, creating problems of coordination of interdependent activities and problems of appropriating the benefits.
Over the past six years, eco-innovation has received growing
attention. An important EU initiative in the field of environmental innovations is ETAP: the Environmental Technologies Action Plan. This strategic programme was adopted in
January 2004. It is a joint initiative of DG Environment and DG
Research (European Commission, 2004). ETAP seeks to exploit the potential of environmental technologies to improve
both the environment as well as European competitiveness,
thus contributing to growth and job creation. The actions
in ETAP are mainly aimed at getting results from research
more readily into the market. Following ETAP, some programmes of FP6 have been redrafted, funds have been made
available by the European Investment Bank, and Technology
Platforms on environmental domains have been established
and stimulated. Furthermore, mutual learning between
Member States in the area of financial instruments for the
introduction of new environmental technologies into the
market has been promoted (European Commission, 2004).
Whereas there are good reasons for government involvement
into the creation and diffusion of innovation, such attempts do
not guarantee success in terms of positive outcomes. What
this means is that we should also consider the possibility of
“policy failure” (Malerba, 2009). The issue of policy failure is
taken up in section 5 about effective governance.
A new initiative is the Eco-Innovation Action Plan. The action
plan kept the priority areas of ETAP but sought to expand
focus from green technologies to all aspects of eco-innovation, bringing existing ETAP tools to “the next level”, to
leverage private funding through new financial instruments, to
increase SME focus by better linking with existing initiatives,
4 The literature on innovation systems is replete with definitions (Edquist, 2004). In a recent book on technology policy, Richard Nelson defines an innovation system
as “the complex and varied set of actors and arrangements that, through the action and interactions they engender and mold, influence the pace and pattern of
technological innovation in a field” (Nelson, 2009, p. 11). The field can be national, sectoral, regional or technology-specific.
5 Presentation From ETAP to Eco-Innovation Action Plan from Timo Mäkelä, Director DG ENV Directorate E International Affairs, LIFE and eco-innovation on 11 Feb.
2010 in Brussels).
Kemp | P7
7
Kemp Ten themes for eco-innovation policies in Europe
Table 2. Barriers to accelerated eco-innovation uptake and development in SMEs in EU-27
Very serious
Somewhat serious
Not at all serious
Not serious
Uncertain demand from the market
34
Uncertain return on investment or too long a payback
period for eco-innovation
32
Not applicable
33
30
Insufficient access to existing subsidies and fiscal incentives
Existing regulations and structures not providing
incentives to eco-innovate
14
27
17
30
25
11
29
6
8
14
5
12
8
19
13
7
19
15
8
21
15
6
26
26
Reducing energy use is not an innovation priority
11
17
32
31
Lack of external financing
14
32
36
Lack of funds within the enterprise
DK/NA
Technical and technological lock-ins
(e.g. old technical infrastructures)
22
29
20
Lack of qualified personnel and technological
capabilities within the enterprise
23
28
22
Market dominated by established enterprises
21
28
23
16
9
20
17
6
8
Reducing material use is not an innovation priority
17
27
25
18
9
Limited access to external information and knowledge,
including a lack of well-developed technology support services
16
27
26
19
9
Lack of suitable business partners
16
Lack of collaboration with research institutes and universities
13
25
21
26
24
22
19
9
20
Q7. I will list you some barriers that could represent an obstacle to accelerated eco-innovation uptake and
development for a company. Please tell me for each of them if you consider them a very serious,
somewhat serious, not serious or not at all serious barrier in case of your company?
Base: all companies, % EU27
Source: Flash Eurobarometer 315 Attitudes of European entrepreneurs towards eco-innovation (Gallup, 2011). Answers are based on stated
opinions of company managers.
to reinforce the global dimension and to improve cooperation
and coordination with global efforts.6
All Member States have policies for eco-innovation. An
overview of measures for all Member States is given in
Figure 3 showing that there is a mix of policies. The measures fall into four areas. Within the area Getting research to
the market, most of the support actions are in R&D support.
For Improving market conditions, Member States also use a
range of policies, the majority of which relate to regulation
and raising environmental awareness. The relatively even
distribution of policy instruments (measures) to improve
market conditions suggests that there are few gaps in the
policy portfolio, but a deeper analysis is required to really
determine whether this is true. For Acting globally and Moving forward, there are far fewer policies. Acting globally is
not a MS responsibility but an EU one. Moving forward is
about improving ETAP and the Open Method of Coordination
(for a discussion of internationalisation of research and the
OMC, see Kaiser and Prange, 2005). There is no document
discussing the theoretical basis for the policies, so we can
only speculate about the link with market failure and system
failure. R&D support fits with the view that the public good
nature of knowledge and uncertainty led companies to underinvest in R&D (market failure issue about inappropriate
incentives). Establishing innovation platforms is based on
innovation system thinking. The policies under improving
market conditions and acting globally aim to foster learning and encourage the uptake of innovations. They fit with
proposals of evolutionary economists that the uptake of
innovation is suboptimal, having to do with capabilities and
inappropriate institutions. Moving forward is about coordination and thus about correcting system failure.
5. THEMES foR ECo-INNoVaTIoN PolICY
In section 3, we examined the market failure and system
failure rationales for eco-innovation policy. Both rationales
have informed policy and have been used to legitimise
policy by innovation policy makers and academics. There
are different views as to what policy makers should do, and
how. Neo-classical economists tend to be sceptical about
the ability of government to overcome coordination failures
but they support education policies, the support of start-up
companies and experiments with new technologies, and the
use of special capital market schemes for risky innovations.
In general, neoclassical economists favour the use of generic
subsidies policies for business R&D and other types of policies
(such as R&D tax-breaks) that reduce the costs of research
6 Ibid.
8
Kemp | P8
Table 3. Impact of WBSO researcher cost subsidy scheme on projects
No impact of the
WBSO on projects
taking place
The WBSO is decisive
factor for projects
taking place
> 200 employees
72%
4%
50-199 employees
38%
6%
10-49 employees
35%
19%
< 10 employees
22%
23%
Source: Brouwer et al. (2002), Figure 2-5 p. 40.
and of innovation. Although they are aware that for some project the subsidies may not be needed they still favour generic
schemes because they think there is no way of discriminating
between projects that need a subsidy in order to be undertaken
and those that do not. They are in favour of decentralized decision making and wary of planning and regulation.
Evolutionary-structuralists on the other hand see a need
for specific support programmes, for example programmes
for strategic technologies such as ICT and biotechnology, to
assist companies in the transition towards new knowledge
bases. They also believe that the government should improve
the technology infrastructure, through technology transfer
centres, education and training programmes, or by fostering
ties between companies and research institutes. Neoclassical economists are critical of the possibility of government
to formulate specific programmes and policies. They think
that companies themselves are perfectly able to engage in
cooperation with relevant knowledge holders and they are
against horizontal cooperation (collaboration between competitors) because they believe this will undermine competition.
The preference for focussed policies does not imply that evolutionary economists are against generic framework policies
such as R&D subsidies; they are in favour of such policies but
view these policies as rather blunt and insufficient. Acrossthe-board R&D subsidies will give rise to windfall gains.
According to them, incentive policies should be targeted to
areas and types of innovation for which the incentives are low.
They also appear more sceptical about privatisation and the
creation of markets for property rights because they fear that
this might undermine the technology infrastructure. They
attach great importance to public sector research institutes,
universities and standards setting bodies, which are viewed
as important elements of the technology infrastructure.
5.1 THEME 1: ECo-INNoVaTIoN PolICIES
SHoUlD bE baSED oN IDENTIfIED baRRIERS
S . A . P. I . E N . S
Kemp Ten themes for eco-innovation policies in Europe
We have seen that not all innovations need government support.
In general, incremental innovation does not need special support. In contrast, transformative innovations face a number
of barriers, having to do with costs, uncertainty, problems of
appropriation and the need for institutional change. To be effective and not wasteful, innovation policy should be based on
identified barriers to particular types of eco-innovation instead
of on abstract notions of market failure and system failure.
This requires mechanisms for learning about those barriers.
According to a recent Eurobarometer survey of 5,222 managers of small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) in the
EU-27 Member States, uncertain demand from the market and
uncertain return are the two biggest obstacles to eco-efficient
innovations7, followed by lack of funds and unhelpful regulations (see Table 2). Lack of qualified personnel and technological capabilities is found to be a much important barrier than
lack of cooperation with research institutes and universities.
It would have been interesting to learn about the barriers to
different types of eco-innovation but the survey did not examine this. It also did not make a distinction between process
changes and product changes. It would also be interesting to
compare the barriers for different types of eco-innovation with
those for normal innovation, to gain information about specific
problems faced by different types of eco-innovation.
There is a role for innovation researchers to study barriers.
Evaluation of the national system of innovation is well-established within OECD countries, where the performance of national systems of innovation is even benchmarked (Lundvall
and Tomlinson, 2002; Remoe, 2008). Within the Eco-Innovation
Observatory an attempt is being made to benchmark national
systems for eco-innovation in resource efficiency (work on this
is ongoing).8
According to a study by the Wuppertal Institute for the
European Parliament (Bleischwitz et al., 2009), the ecoinnovation support programmes of the European Commission programmes suffer from three funding gaps: between
R&D and the start-up phase; between the start-up and early
stage; and between the early stage and mass market commercialization. For a deeper analysis into barriers and gaps
for specific technology innovation systems (such as algaebased fuels and concentrated solar power) the innovation
functions model can be used (Jacobsson and Johnson, 2000;
Hekkert et al., 2007; Bergek et al., 2008).9
5.2 THEME 2: PREVENTING WINDfall PRofITS
This section tries to probe more deeply into some of the
issues, through a discussion of ten themes of effective policy
and effective governance. The focus is on eco-innovation,
but most arguments and considerations apply to innovation
support through government policies more generally.
Support for innovation may be unnecessary and ineffective. A drawback of financial support policies is that projects
receiving support would also be undertaken in the absence
of support. An evaluation in 2002 of the Dutch WBSO scheme
7 My term for the eco-innovations studied in the survey, being new or substantially improved solutions resulting in more efficient use of materials, energy and water.
8 See http://www.eco-innovation.eu/
9 According to the functions approach, the development of an emerging technology innovation system (such as solar PV) depends on the well-functioning of seven
functions: knowledge development, knowledge diffusion, resource mobilisation, research guidance, entrepreneurial activity, market development and legitimacy
(societal support) (Hekkert et al., 2007).
Kemp | P9
9
Kemp Ten themes for eco-innovation policies in Europe
Table 4. A taxonomy of innovation policy
Supply-side Measures
Demand-side Measures
Finance
Equity
support
Fiscal
measures
Public
venture
capital
funds
Mixed or
subsidised
private
venture
funds
Loss
underwriting
and
garantees
Tax
incentives
Corporation
tax
reductions
for volume
or increment
in R&D
Reductions
in employers
payroll tax
and social
contributions
Personal tax
incentives
for R&D
workers
Services
Support for
public sector
research
University
funding
Laboratory
funding
Collaborative
grants
Strategic
programmes
for industry
Support for
contract
research
Equipment
sharing
Support for
training &
mobility
Grants for
industrial
R&D
Information
& brokerage
support
Networking
measures
Systemic
policies
Regulation
Public
Procurement
Support of
private
demand
Tailored
courses for
firms
Entrepreneur
ship training
Subsidised
secondments
Industrial
research
studentships
Support for
recruitment
of scientists
Grants for
R&D
Collaborative
grants
Reimbursable
loans
Prizes to
spend on
R&D
Contact
databases
Brokerage
events
Advisory
services
International
technology
watch
Patent
databases
Benchmarking
Support
for clubs
Foresight
to build
common
visions
Co-location
in incubators,
Science
parks etc
Cluster
policies
Supply
chain
policies
Use of
regulations
& standards
to set
innovation
targets
Technology
platforms to
coordinate
development
R&D
procurement
Public
procurement
of innovative
goods
Demand
Subsidies and
Tax
incentives
Articulation
of private
demand
Awareness
and Training
Catalytic
Procurement
Source: Edler and Georghiou (2007, p. 953), based on authors’ inventory of policy measures.
consisting of a subsidy on researcher costs revealed that in
72% of the cases where companies with more than 200 employees use the WBSO, the scheme had no impact on the
carrying out of a project (see Table 3) (Brouwer et al., 2002).
For companies with more than 50 employees, only 5% of the
projects would not be carried out without the WBSO support.
For smaller projects the “additionality” of support is significantly higher but still rather low: the WBSO support was a
deciding factor in 19% of the projects. In about half of the
projects the WBSO had some impact (e.g. with regard to the
size and duration of a project).
Technology-blind fiscal support for R&D, which is widely
used, inevitably gives rise to windfall profits, by funding research that would have been done anyhow. Ways to reduce
the windfall gains include relying on expert judgement as to
whether innovation support is needed, or focussing on small
firms for whom the additionality of innovation support has
been shown to be higher, encouraging them to do an innovation project they would not have done otherwise or would have
done in a less elaborate manner.
5.3 THEME 3: SPECIfIC VERSUS GENERal SUPPoRT
Specific support for R&D has a bad name amongst economists, much more than the generic fiscal support policies,
for the reason that “government cannot pick winners”. Whilst
there is an element of truth in this, we have just seen that blind
innovation and research support can be wasteful. In the case
of specific support the additionality of support can be better
considered, as well as the nature of other barriers. The need
for support will differ over time and the challenge for policy
10
is to discontinue support in time, something that may prove
difficult because of uncertainty and pressure from special
interests. In sectors where private R&D is low such as energy
there is a need to support R&D. In areas of great inertia and
long development times there is a need to support the creation of technology innovation systems—to achieve learning
economies and foster learning and institutional change in the
selection environment. Specific technologies such as algaebased fuels and organic solar cells suffer from specific barriers that no general support scheme can successfully address.
Specific support for specific technologies is not about picking
winners but about dealing with specific barriers.
The requirement for co-funding by industry is one way of
making sure that the technologies to be developed will not
turn out to be “white elephants”. A possible model here is
the public-private partnership model that is used in the
German Clean Energy Partnership (CEP) for hydrogen and fuel
cell vehicles, which was instrumental in the creation of the
German National Innovation Programme Hydrogen and Fuel
Cell Technology (NIP). For transport applications, 700 million EUR is available to pay for hydrogen fuel cell vehicles
(HFCV) research and innovation projects for the 2007-2016
period, with half of this sum coming from industry. A National
Development Plan specifies the agenda for technology development. To coordinate policy goals and implement projects
on a more executive basis a special organization has been set
up: National Organization for Hydrogen and Fuel Cell Technology
(NOW), a quasi-governmental organization. NOW participates
in all steering committee meetings and ensures that political imperatives are respected. NOW also makes sure CEP
is aligned with related R&D and demonstration activities in
Kemp | P10
Germany. Alignment of German activities with those abroad is
achieved through international contacts with related organizations such as the EU Fuel Cells and Hydrogen—Joint Undertaking (based on Ehret and Dignum, 2010).
In Germany, the government and the automobile industry are
making a technological bet on HFCV, but the bet is a calculated bet based on the belief that future cars have to meet strict
carbon emissions goals that internal combustion engines are
unable to meet, thus necessitating electric drive systems or
the use of biofuels. Of the different electric drive systems,
hydrogen fuel cells are believed to be the most attractive
option for users, as they comply with established preferences
for range and comfort. It is entirely possible, of course, that
the market for FCV will be small and that HFCV will be a white
elephant, which is why we need multiple technology innovation
mission programmes, a point further developed below.
5.4 THEME 4: balaNCE of PolICY MEaSURES aND TIMING
While R&D policy can help facilitate the creation of new environmentally friendly technologies, it provides little incentive
to adopt these technologies (Newell, 2010, p. 263). Adoption,
so important for post-innovation improvements, calls for
demand-side measures but the incentives for innovation from
market pull policies may be too weak or may favour particular
types of technologies. Technologically non-challenging regulations merely stimulate cost-reducing innovation, and incentive-based environmental policies are found to stimulate the
diffusion of existing technologies and marginally innovative
change (Kemp, 2000; Kemp and Pontoglio, in press). For ecoinnovation, there should be a balance between supply-side
measures and demand-side measures (see Table 4). Innovation policy should work in tandem with environmental policy
(Popp, 2006; Newell, 2010; OECD, 2011).
The need for a balance between supply and demand measures is illustrated by the experiences with the EU emissions
trading system (ETS) for carbon emissions. The ETS is the
cornerstone of European climate policy, covering 10,800
industrial installations across Europe in four energy-intensive sectors. The total value of carbon trade amounted to
100.5 billion USD in 2008 and 118.5 billion USD in 2009. It
was introduced in part because it was believed to stimulate
innovation in low-carbon technologies. It largely failed to
have this effect. It stimulated fuel switching and efficiency improvements but its effects on innovations new to the
world were small according to two evaluations (one for the
paper and pulp industry in Italy and one for the power sector
in Europe). Rather than invest in new process technologies,
paper mills in shortage of allowances preferred to postpone
abatement decisions to later years, borrowing allowances
from subsequent periods (Pontoglio, 2010). In the power
sector in Germany and Europe, the ETS stimulated RD&D10
in carbon capture technologies and corporate procedural
change, but its impact on RD&D for wind and other renewables and on gas efficiency RD&D was negligible (Rogge
et al., 2010). The auctioning of (lower amounts) of carbon
rights can be expected to achieve more, but the authors of
the evaluation believe that promoting emerging renewables
regimes requires other policies than the ETS (Rogge et al.,
2010). Environmental policies are thus not a substitute for
innovation policy, just as innovation policy is not a substitute
for environmental policy. Apart from balance, timing is a
crucial issue (Sartorius and Zundel, 2005; OECD, 2011):
S . A . P. I . E N . S
Kemp Ten themes for eco-innovation policies in Europe
“Political impulses at the wrong time either barely
bring about a worthwhile effect or else they cost too
much money and time to bring about a real change
in economic behaviour. At the right time, even weak
political incentives can stimulate external environmentally friendly innovations.” (Zundel et al., 2005, p. 10)
5.5 THEME 5: TaRGETED SPENDING IN aREaS
WHERE INNoVaTIoN IS NEEDED
There is a clear need for innovation policy to provide targeted
support in areas where innovation is needed. One such area
for eco-innovation is low-carbon technologies and systems.
To reduce carbon emissions by the 80% that is needed
according to the IPCC by 2050 will require cost-reducing
innovation in carbon reduction technologies. According to
the Energy Technology Perspectives report from the IEA (being the most authoritative study on the research, technology
and innovation implications of climate change to date), there
is a significant gap between the current level of investment
in low-carbon technology RD&D and the investment needed to bring forward the technologies necessary for halving
global energy-related CO2 emissions by 2050 (compared to
2005 levels) (IEA, 2010). Addressing this gap is said to require annual public-sector spending two to five times the
current levels. The ETP 2010 study estimates the annual gap
as between USD 40 and 90 USD billion, of which they say that
half should come from public sources (IEA, 2010, p. 480).
The most important target for RTD spending is advanced
vehicles (battery electric vehicles, (plug-in) hybrid electric
vehicles, hydrogen fuel cell vehicles and energy efficient internal combustion vehicles) where the ETP 2010 proposed
additional annual spending between 26 and 43 billion USD.
Current levels of annual public spending for low-carbon
RD&D are estimated at 10 billion USD. This is just to show
the magnitude of the RD&D efforts that are needed according to energy (innovation) experts.
The Secretariat of the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC) estimates that an additional 200 billion USD in global investment and financial
flows will be required annually by 2030 just to return GHG
emissions to current levels (UNFCCC, 2007, quoted in
Newell, 2010, p. 254).
10 RD&D stands for Research, Development and Demonstration.
Kemp | P11
11
Kemp Ten themes for eco-innovation policies in Europe
Table 5. Characteristics of Old and New “Mission-Oriented” Projects
Old: Defence, Nuclear and Aerospace
New: Environmental Technologies
The mission is defined in terms of the number of technical achievements
with little regard to their economic feasibility.
The mission is defined in terms of economically feasible technical
solutions to particular environmental problems.
The goals and the direction of technological development are defined in
advance by a small group of experts.
The direction of technical change is influenced by a wide range of actors
including the government, private firms and consumer groups.
Centralised control within a government administration.
Decentralised control with a large number of involved agents.
Diffusion of results outside the core of participants is of minor importance Diffusion of the results is a central goal and is actively encouraged.
or actively discouraged.
Limited to a small group of firms that can participate owing to the
emphasis on a small number of radical technologies.
An emphasis on the development of both radical and incremental
innovations in order to permit a large number of firms to participate.
Self-contained projects with little need for complementary policies and
scant attention paid to coherence.
Complementary policies vital for success and close attention paid to
coherence with other goals.
Source: Soete and Arundel (1993, p. 51)
5.6 THEME 6: MISSIoNS foR SYSTEM INNoVaTIoN
Among innovation experts there is a discussion of whether
persistent problems such as global warming warrant missionoriented programmes. According to Keith Smith (2008, p. 2) the
answer is yes: “We now require new large-scale “mission-oriented” technology programs for low- or zero emissions energy
carriers and technologies, resting on public sector coordination
and taking a system-wide perspective.” Others are sceptical
of the usefulness of missions. According to innovation experts
Mowery, Nelson and Martin (2010), global warming cannot be
effectively dealt with through technology missions, because
the challenge is not to develop technologies but to get innovations adopted, which is very much a matter of economics rather
than technology. They do, however, believe that “strong, wellresourced government technology policy is part of the solution”.
Superficially, the attention to missions seems like a return to
the emphasis in the 1950s and 1960s on public goals to guide
science and technology development. There is, however, a
big difference between the old missions for environmentally
sustainable development and the new: the older projects
developed radically new technologies through government
procurement projects that were largely isolated from the
economy (Soete and Arundel, 1993, p. 51). Mission-oriented
projects for sustainable development require the adoption of
new technologies and practices across a wide range of sectors
as well as changes in consumer demand and behaviour. This
brings many actors into the process and will require a range
of policies and customised solutions to deal with the many
barriers. Economic feasibility is a key condition, together with
social acceptability. An overview of the difference between old
and new mission policies is given in Table 5.
Innovation missions oriented towards the whole of society
require policy coordination across sectors and levels of
government. The focus for achieving CO2 reductions in trans-
12
port is on electric vehicles powered by batteries and fuel cells.
CO2 reductions can also be achieved through policies to reduce
car-based mobility, through improved public transport, organised car sharing and integrated transport. Intermodal travel
is a niche phenomenon both in terms of use and in terms of
a lack of a developed knowledge infrastructure. There are
few spokesmen for it and a limited amount of technical and
professional cohesion is evident from best practice publications. A study about intermodal travel in the Netherlands and
UK reported that policy interest is unstable and often implicit
(Parkhurst et al., in press).
The experiences in the Netherlands and the UK (described in
Parkhurst et al., in press) suggest that transport intermodality will rarely emerge as a significant phenomenon without
national government support and active involvement of various actors (public transport companies, parking companies,
real estate companies and local authorities). Even in the
Netherlands, where transport coordination is more possible,
major organizational barriers exist, such as the fragmented
systems of mobility providers and public transport concessions.
To overcome these barriers and promote sustainable mobility,
the authors believe a long-term coordinated approach is necessary involving several of the following elements: implementation of convenient car-public transport interchanges; bicycles
for short-term rental that are integrated with public transport; integrated ticketing across different transport modes;
dynamic information and booking services, and individualized
demand-responsive forms of public transport that provide links
to scheduled public transport (from Parkhurst et al., in press).
5.7 THEME 7: STRaTEGIC INTEllIGENCE foR INNoVaTIoN
The development of enabling technologies such as smart
grids and innovations such as eco-friendly driving, modular
vehicles and intermodal travel requires strategic intelligence.
The report Towards a 50% more efficient road transport sys-
Kemp | P12
S . A . P. I . E N . S
Kemp Ten themes for eco-innovation policies in Europe
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
2017
2018
2019
2020
Meshed HVDC network validated
Specification of secure offshore HVDC
Tools for pan-European grid monitoring and control
Smart
grid
Feasibility of RES for grid stability
50% L&M V networks
up-graded
Tools for architecture and long term grid scenario and planning
35% RES
In the grid
Proposal for market designs
CCS plants with > 40 % efficiency
Power plants with > 50 % efficiency
CCS
Demonstration of CCS chains
using existing technologies
Up to 12 CCS demonstration plants
Atlas of storage sites
CCS plants
cost
competitive
Reference plants for most mature technologies
Bioenergy
Pilots for less mature technologies
14% of EU
energy
Demonstrators for less mature technologies
Reference plants for less mature technologies
Smart
cities
100 new residential,
100 new non-residential
zero energy buildings
5-10 development & deployment
programmes on smart grids
Existing buildings refurbishment:
• 5-10 ambitious cities: >50% (public buildings)
• 5-10 pioneer cities: >50% (all buildings)
All new building net zero energy
10-20 testing programmes
on sustainable mobility
Testing programmes in 10-20 cities
of alternative fuel vehicles
5-10 programme strategies with 50% of H&C demand
from RES, 5-10 programme strategies with 50% of
H&C demand from RES in low energy buildings
40% of CO 2
Reduction
through
Sustainable
energy
Figure 4. Technology roadmaps for smart cities and the industrial initiatives on Smartgrids, CCS and Bioenergy
From: http://ec.europa.eu/research/energy/eu/policy/set-plan/index_en.htm
tem by 2030 the European Road Transport Research Advisory
Council (ERTRAC, 2010), analyses how the transport sector
can be made more energy-efficient, cut carbon emissions,
become more safe, reliable and efficient from a logistical
point of view. The vision is based on the following concepts:
eco-friendly driving; safe and smart driving; basic, affordable
vehicles; passenger comfort; modularity; terminal efficiency;
driver and transport efficiency; logistics efficiency; cost-effective vehicles; and vehicle efficiency.
Technology assessment, foresight, evaluation and benchmarking are tools or sources of strategic intelligence (Smits
and Kuhlmann, 2004). Such exercises can be linked to innovation and can also be used for policy coordination so important for radical eco-innovations. It is important that the whole
range of innovative solutions is considered, including social
innovations (e.g. in the domain of transport, an example of a
social innovation is organised car-sharing, where people do
not own a car and, because of this, do not use a car for most
of their trips). There is also a need for assessing sustainability benefits of green (system) innovations and sustainability
claims of different actors.
5.8 THEME 8: INNoVaTIoN PoRTfolIo
For sustainable development and green growth it is advisable that government support be given to a broad portfolio of
options, to widen the search process, which often is unduly
narrow, focussing on the most economic options, which tend to
be in the prevailing technological paradigm. There should also
be a good mix between low-risk and high-risk projects. It is
especially important that also radical, disruptive technologies
are being supported and not just options which help to make
present systems greener (it is equally important that one does
not rely too strongly on long-term solutions as they may remain
a long-term solution, nuclear fusion being an example of this).
By relying on adaptive portfolios, two possible mistakes of sustainable energy policy may be prevented: 1) the promotion of
short-term options resulting from the use of technology-blind
generic support policies such as carbon taxes or cap and
trade systems (which despite being “technology-blind” are
not technology neutral at all because they favour low-hanging
fruit and regime-preserving change (Jacobsson et al., 2009)),
and 2) picking losers (technologies and system configurations
which are suboptimal) through technology-specific policies.
In this connection we want to mention the Communication
from the European Commission “Investing in the Development
of Low Carbon Technologies” (European Commission, 2009)
which sets out a portfolio approach, called the European
Strategic Energy Technology Plan (SET-Plan). SET-Plan is the
technology pillar of the EU’s energy and climate change policy.
SET-plan proposes an increase in private and public investments in low-carbon technologies from 3 billion EUR to 8 billion EUR in the next year, or an additional 50 billion EUR over
the ten years from 2010 to 2020.
Kemp | P13
13
Kemp Ten themes for eco-innovation policies in Europe
Innovation policy
Environmental policy
Energy policy
Advisory Group
Other policies
Steering committee
Federal level
Action Plan
European Union
Supply driven policies
Demand driven policies
Working Group 1
public procurement
WG 2: regulations
favoring innovation
WG 3: new financial
instruments
Existing Innovation
Support schemes:
R&D companies
SME-programme
Strategic Basic
Research Technical
Highschools
Clustersupport… +
Ecoscan
User
Group 1
Pole of Excellence VITO (+
universities, technical highschools)
User
Group 2
Bringing existing
technology to a
commercial stage
User
Group x
New
knowledge
development
Knowledge diffusion, Prodem,
BBT/EMIS
Figure 5. Innovation Platform for Environmental Technologies (MIP) in Flanders
Source: Dries et al. (2006, p. 259)
SET-plan proposes appropriate spending for a number of
European industrial initiatives, based on estimates of what is
needed for achieving the EU climate and energy targets for
2020. SET-plan involves six European Industrial Initiatives (on
Solar Energy, Bioenergy, Wind Energy, CCS, Smartgrids, and
Sustainable Nuclear Fission) and the Smart Cities initiative.
Each initiative has set itself a target for 2020 and has established a Technology Roadmap and Implementation Plan with
milestones. Milestones for the smart grid, CCS, bio-energy
and smart cities are given in Figure 4.
The 50 billion EUR in extra spending over the next 10 years
should come from business and member states. SET-Plan
is based on proposals from technology companies and from
well-organised research actors. An impact assessment of
SET-Plan offers insights into the considerations (European
Commission, 2007).11 The discussion of the need for policy
action is rather general and does not refer to specific studies
into market barriers for different technologies.12
5.9 THEME 9: PolICY lEaRNING
Uncertainty prevails with respect to innovation as well as
to what innovation policy can or will achieve (Nauwelaers
and Wintjes, 2008, p. 226). Uncertainty as to the effects
of policy instruments call for policy learning. Experience
with innovation policy making in European Member States
shows that policies are usually a follow-up on existing
policies (Nauwelaers and Wintjes, 2008). Official researchbased evaluations play a limited role in innovation policy,
as policy instruments are seldom evaluated for their effectiveness and efficiency (Nauwelaers and Wintjes, 2008).
There is a need for lessons learned by executive agencies
and evaluators of effective governance to be disseminated
internationally (Kaiser and Prange, 2005; Borrás, 2009).
The European Action Plan for Eco-innovation, the successor of ETAP (the European Action Plan on Environmental Technologies), could be used for this purpose. Within
the ETAP roadmap exercise, governments were asked to
indicate which policies were successful and what lessons
had been learned. Better exchange of experiences can help
the national road maps to become an agent for change. At
the moment, the roadmap process is more a formal requirement than a vehicle for change. Only in Germany has
the roadmap for ETAP been externally assessed by innovation policy experts. The roadmap is currently being updated in two countries (Romania and Sweden) and updates
are planned in six countries (Cyprus, Denmark, Hungary,
Ireland, Poland and Portugal) and possibly France (based
on Kletzan-Slamanig et al., 2009).
Since the effects of policies depend on the characteristics of
the policies and the context in which they are applied (Kemp
and Pontoglio, in press; OECD, 2011), contextual features
and design features should be incorporated in the evaluation
of eco-innovation policies (OECD, 2011). Evaluations should
11 http://ec.europa.eu/energy/technology/set_plan/doc/2009_comm_investing_development_low_carbon_technologies_impact_assessement.pdf
12 The impact assessment is mindful about the weak and possibly biased knowledge base for decision-making when it writes: “Understanding the evolving characteristics, economics and performances, and barriers for market penetration of such a broad portfolio is a problem that needs to be addressed in developing an
energy technology policy. The information is dispersed and multifaceted. In many occasions it is either inaccurate or the source has a vested interest.” (European
Commission, 2007, p.13)
14
Kemp | P14
S . A . P. I . E N . S
Kemp Ten themes for eco-innovation policies in Europe
Market Failure Approach
Generic Subsidies and Policies
Generic Barriers
System Approach
Specific Support Programmes
Specific Barriers
Complements
Theme 2
Preventing Windfall
Profits
Identified Barriers
Shapes
Supports
Theme 1
Eco-innovation
policy based on
Identified Barriers
Requires
Requires
Theme 3
Considering Specific
versus Generic
Support Schemes
Includes
Analysis of
areas and
evidence on
Innovation
Funding
Gaps acc. to
Targets
Supports
Economic
Feasibility
and Social
Acceptability
of Adoption
of New
Technologies
Formation of
Adaptive
(high and
low risk)
Portfolios
and Options
Theme 9
Policy
Learning
Requires
Assessment of
Sustainability
Benefits and Claims
of Different
Innovations and
Actors
Includes
Supports
Theme 7
Strategic
Intelligence
Includes
Theme 8
Portfolios
Includes
Supports
Requires
Includes
Theme 6
Missions for
System
Innovation
Includes
Supports
Requires
Extends
Theme 5
Targeted
Spending
Learning About
Different Types
of Barriers for
Different Types
of Innovations
Theme 4
Balance of
Policy
Measures
Includes
Analysing Additionality
effects of Generic and
Specific supports to
overcome Identified
Barriers
Includes
Balance of
Regulations and
Incentives for
creation and
adoption of
new/existing ecoinnovations
Supports
Includes
Supports
Includes
Horizontal Policy
Coordination
(environment policy
and innovation policy)
Includes
Vertical coordination at
Regional, National, EU
and International levels
Evaluation of Policy
Instruments/Mixes
and Co-Funding
through PublicPrivate Partnerships
Considering Social and
Technological
innovation solutions at
multi-level settings and
International
dissemination of
lessons learned
Supports
Requires
Theme 10
Policy Coordination
and Public-Private
Interactions
Supports
Supports
Figure 6. The links between the ten themes for eco-innovation policy
also consider policy interaction effects (Kivimaa, 2008;
Ringeling, 2005).
5.10 THEME 10: PolICY CooRDINaTIoN
aND PUblIC-PRIVaTE INTERaCTIoNS
Policy coordination is a difficult issue for which there are
no simple solutions (Braun, 2008). In the case of eco-innovation, there is a strong need for horizontal policy coordination, i.e. to align environmental policy with innovation
policy, and a need for vertical policy coordination (across
layers of government), each of which comes with problems
(Schrama and Sedlacek, 2003). Up until now innovation
policy is very much a national responsibility, despite the
growing importance of regional and supra-national innovation policy (Kaiser and Prange, 2005). European innovation
policy is primarily focused on the promotion of international
cooperation in R&D. The European Research Area and SETplan for low-carbon energy technologies are attempts at
internationalisation of research and innovation. The EU has
formulated programmes for eco-innovation and for various
kinds of eco-innovation, technology platforms have been
created at the EU level. The platforms serve a useful role
in agenda-setting and coordination of research work at the
European level, but their privileged position vis-à-vis EU
policy makers can be a problem from a public interest point
of view. To deal with the problem of special interests, Borrás
(2009) suggests that the roles and risks between public and
private actors in complex public-private interactions should
be defined. Risks and public concerns are also to be considered in innovation policy, to enhance public legitimacy and
secure good results.
In Flanders in Belgium a vehicle for policy coordination is the
eco-innovation platform (Milieu-innovatie platform, MIP),
described in Dries et al. (2006) and illustrated in Figure 5.
Created in 2004, the mission of the platform is to “activate
innovation synergies between relevant private and public
actors”. Policy instruments of three ministerial domains will
be “pooled” on a common goal, using a “non-hierarchical”
way of networking of ministries and administrations.
Demand-driven policies are coordinated with supply-driven
policies through a steering committee and various working
groups (Dries et al., 2006, p. 258).
According to the evaluation of Dries et al. (2006), the aspect
of interactive policy making and transparency should be
strengthened, together with processes for creating strategic
intelligence. Furthermore, the policy mix should be broadened
and the policy focus on system innovation should be widened.
Further research is needed on the need for policy coordination in areas of water, waste and carbon reduction and
energy efficiency. An area for which policy frameworks
are weakly developed is sustainable resource management, being a new topic for policy. Details of sustainable
Kemp | P15
15
Kemp Ten themes for eco-innovation policies in Europe
resource management are currently being worked out by
UNEP’s International Resource Panel in terms of a multilevel framework to dematerialize society. Dematerialization
helps to reduce negative environmental impacts, reduce
vulnerability to price volatility of scarce materials, avoid
resource-based conflicts and make a transition to a lowcarbon economy (renewable energy technologies depend
on scarce materials) (Bleischwitz et al., 2010). Practical
policies for international sustainable resource management
need to be worked out, with real policies and frameworks to
be tested out and adapted with experience.
6. CoNClUSIoNS
In this paper, we offer a discussion of the rationales for ecoinnovation policy and discuss issues of instrument choice and
coordination. One important conclusion is that the case for
eco-innovation policy is stronger than for normal innovation
because the benefits of eco-innovation are undervalued in
the market place and because of problems of lock-in to welldeveloped and well-embedded technologies in power supply
and transport. Markets are a poor selection mechanism for
eco-innovation because prices do not reflect environmental costs and cannot be easily made to do so. Especially for
green energy, the low costs of fossil fuels, long lead times,
as well as issues of connection, disadvantage innovations that
do not fit in the current paradigm, calling for specific support
policies for green innovations outside existing technological
paradigms. Eco-innovation may be fostered through generic
policies for improving the national (and regional) system for
(eco)-innovation and through technology-focussed policies for
specific technology innovation systems.
Different types of eco-innovation require different policies. In
general, incremental improvements of commercial products
do not require special support. Companies are perfectly capable of producing and funding these. Radical innovations
and system innovation are much more in need of support, but
the barriers to them and the level of support needed will differ. Radical innovations that are transformative require more
support than technical fixes for problems of well-established
regimes. Support for transformative innovation should go
beyond the financial as it requires institutional change in the
economic and social world.
For dealing with the grand challenges of climate change and
energy/resource security, EU policy makers have expressed
an interest in “mission” policies (without using the word
mission). In the author’s view, there is a role for innovation
missions, but the key challenge is not to develop technologies
but to get innovations adopted, which is very much a matter of
economics, institutional change and appropriate designs rather than an issue of technology development. To avoid lock-in,
the missions should be based on a portfolio of technologies
with the innovations subjected to ongoing evaluation, to circumvent policy capture by special interests, an issue which is
16
given little attention in current discussions on eco-innovation
policy. In general, eco-innovation policy is very much oriented
towards high-technology options, as a result of demand from
actors (companies and researchers) interested in those options. There is a danger that the portfolio of eco-innovation
options is too narrow and unbalanced (see Nill and Kemp,
2009; OECD, 2011).
Whilst market failure and system failure provide reasons for
public intervention, actual interventions may be a “failure”
too. Innovation policy does not lend itself easily to rational
choice, because of uncertainty and information asymmetries
between policy makers and actors in industry and research.
Policy should evolve with experience and involve critical evaluation of the system of innovation governance in which policy
choices are made. It is important that policy should not be
viewed purely in instrumental terms but as a trajectory in
itself (see Voss, 2007). To successfully carry out a transition
towards more environment-benign energy resources and to
better utilize material resources through energy saving technologies and recycling will require a forward-looking process
of adaptive policy making. The need for information in the
policy process puts a premium on feedback and flexibility in
the design of strategies and policies for eco-innovation—to
avoid “policy failure”.
To make effective policies it is necessary that government
officials have a correct understanding of eco-innovation barriers and of innovation dynamics in general. Blind technology
support, favoured by economists, is found to generate windfall
profits to recipients and to be unsuccessful in stimulating radical change. The case for fiscal policies appears to be weaker
than the case for specific (focussed) innovation policies. In the
author’s opinion, more support should be given to transformative innovation, something that requires long-term policy and
a good deal of policy coordination.
The overall conclusion is that eco-innovation policy should
be more concerned with its own functioning. The ten themes
may help to do this by bringing into focus relevant issues for
policy. As shown by Figure 6, the themes are not just separate
themes but are inter-linked. Effective policy depends on effective governance, both of which depend on policy learning and
the creation of strategic intelligence.
Editor’s note
This article is a revised version of a paper presented at the Third
International Wuppertal Colloquium on Sustainable Growth
and Resource Productivity that took place on September 4-6,
2010, in Brussels and has been jointly organized by Raimund
Bleischwitz (Wuppertal Institute, Germany), Paul Welfens
(European Institute for International Economic Relations at
the University of Wuppertal) and ZhongXiang Zhang (EastWest Centre Hawai); see also: http://www.wupperinst.org/en/
projects/proj/index.html?projekt_id=313&bid=138
Kemp | P16
REFERENCES
Arundel, A., M. Kanerva & R. Kemp (2011). Integrated Innovation Policy for an Integrated Problem: Addressing Climate
Change, Resource Scarcity and Demographic Change to 2030.
PRO INNO Europe: INNO-Grips II report. Brussels: European
Commission, DG Enterprise and Industry.
Bergek, A. et al. (2008). Analyzing the functional dynamics
of technological innovation systems: a scheme of analysis.
Research Policy 37(3): 407-429.
Bleischwitz, R. et al. (2009). Eco-innovation – putting the EU on
the path to a resource and energy efficient economy. (Wuppertal
Spezial 38.) Wuppertal: Wuppertal Institute.
Bleischwitz, R., P.J.J. Welfens & Z.X. Zhang (2010). Introduction of special issue “The international economics of resources
and resource policy”. International Economics and Economic
Policy 7: 147–151.
Borrás, S. (2009). The Widening and Deepening of Innovation
Policy: What Conditions Provide for Effective Governance. CIRCLE
Electronic Working Paper Series Paper no. 2009/02.
Braun, D. (2008). Organising the political coordination of
knowledge and innovation policies. Science and Public Policy
35: 227-239.
Brouwer, E. et al. (2002). WBSO nader beschouwd, onderzoek naar
de effectiviteit van de WBSO. PWC/ Dialogic/ TU Delft, Utrecht.
Clark, K. (1985). The interaction of design hierarchies and
market concepts in technological evolution. Research Policy
14: 235-251.
Cohen, M. (2006). A social problems framework for the critical
appraisal of automobility and sustainable systems innovation.
Mobilities 1: 23–38.
Dries, I., J. Larosse & P. Van Humbeeck (2006). Linking
innovation policy and sustainable development in Flanders.
In: Governance of Innovation Systems: Case Studies in CrossSectoral Policy, pp. 245-270. Paris: OECD.
Edquist, C. (2004). Systems of innovation, perspectives and
challenges. In: J. Fagerberg, D. C. Mowery, R.R. Nelson (Eds.)
The Oxford Handbook of Innovation, pp. 181-208. Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
Ehret, O. & M. Dignum (2010). Introducing hydrogen and fuel
cell vehicles in Germany. In: F. Geels, R. Kemp, G. Dudley and
G. Lyons (Eds.) Automobility in Transition? A Sociotechnical
Analysis of Sustainable Transport. London: Routledge.
Elzen, B., F.W. Geels & K. Green (Eds.) (2004) System Innovation and the Transition to Sustainability: Theory, Evidence and
Policy, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
S . A . P. I . E N . S
Kemp Ten themes for eco-innovation policies in Europe
Edler, J. & L. Georghiou (2007). Public procurement and
innovation—resurrecting the demand side. Research Policy
36: 949–963.
ERTRAC (2010). Towards a 50% more efficient road transport
system by 2030, ERTRAC Strategic Research Agenda 2010. European Road Transport Research Advisory Council. http://www.
eurosfaire.prd.fr/7pc/doc/1297329503_ertrac_sra_2010.pdf
European Commission (2004). Stimulating technologies for sustainable development: an environmental technologies action plan
for the European Union. Communication from the Commission,
COM(2004) 38 final. Brussels.
European Commission (2007). A European Strategic Energy
Technology Plan (SET-Plan): Full impact assessment. Commission Staff Working Paper. SEC(2007) 1508, COM(2007)
723 final. Brussels, 22.11.2007.
European Commission (2009). Investing in the development of
low carbon technologies (SET-Plan). Communication from the
Commission to the European Parliament, the Council, the
European Economic and Social Committee and the Committee of the Regions. COM(2009) 519 final. Brussels, 7.10.2009.
European Commission (2010). Rationale for Action, Commission Staff Working Paper, accompanying document Europe
2020 Flagship Initiative Innovation Union, SEC(2010) 1161,
Brussels, 6.10.2010, COM(2010) 546 final.
Faber, A., R. Kemp & G. van der Veen (2008). Innovation policy for
the environment in the Netherlands and EU. In: C. Nauwelaers,
R. Wintjes (Eds.). Innovation Policy in Europe. Measurement and
Strategy, pp. 171-202. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Gallup (2011). Flash Eurobarometer 315 Attitudes of European
entrepreneurs towards eco-innovation, Survey conducted by
The Gallup Organization, Hungary upon the request of Directorate-General Environment of the European Commission.
Gassler, H., W. Polt & C. Rammer (2008). Priority setting in
technology policy. Historical developments and recent trends.
In: C. Nauwelaers, R. Wintjes (Eds.), Innovation Policy in
Europe. Measurement and Strategy, pp. 203-224. Cheltenham:
Edward Elgar.
Geels, F.W. (2002). Technological transitions as evolutionary
reconfiguration processes: a multi-level perspective and a
case-study, Research Policy 31(8-9): 1257-1274.
Kemp | P17
17
Kemp Ten themes for eco-innovation policies in Europe
Geels, F.W. (2004), From sectoral systems of innovation to
socio-technical systems: Insights about dynamics and change
from sociology and institutional theory, Research Policy 33(6-7):
897-920.
Geels, F.W. & R.P.J.M. Raven (2007). Socio-cognitive evolution
and co-evolution in competing technical trajectories: Biogas
development in Denmark (1970-2002). International Journal of
Sustainable Development & World Ecology 14(1), 63-77.
Grin, J. et al. (2010). Transitions To Sustainable Development.
New Directions in the Study of Long Term Transformative Change,
New York: Routledge.
Guy, K. & C. Nauwelaers (2003). Benchmarking STI policies in
Europe: in search of good practice. In: The IPTS Report, No. 71.
Sevilla: IPTS.
Hekkert, M.P. et al. (2007). Functions of innovation systems:
a new approach for analyzing technological change. Technological Forecasting and Social Change 74(4): 413-432.
Henderson, R. & R.G. Newell (2010). Accelerating Innovation
In Energy: Insights from Multiple Sectors (Harvard Business
School working paper 10-067).
IBO (2002). Samenwerken en stroomlijnen: opties voor een
effectief innovatiebeleid. Eindrapportage Interdepartementaal
Beleidsonderzoek (EZ-02-311), Den Haag.
IEA (2010). Energy technology perspectives 2010. Paris: OECD
and IEA.
Jacobsson, S. & A. Johnson (2000). The diffusion of renewable
energy technology: an analytical framework and key issues for
research. Energy Policy 28: 625-640.
Jacobsson, S. et al. (2009). EU renewable energy support
policy: faith or facts? Energy Policy 37: 2143-2146.
Jaffe, A.B., R.G. Newell & R.N. Stavins (2005). A tale of two
market failures: Technology and environmental policy. Ecological Economics 54(2-3): 164-174.
Kaiser, R. & H. Prange (2005). Missing the Lisbon target?
Multi-level innovation systems and the challenge for EU policy
coordination. Journal of Public Policy 25(2): 241-263.
Kemp, R. (1994). Technology and the transition to environmental sustainability. the problem of technological regime shifts.
Futures 26(10): 1023-46.
Kemp, R. (2000). Technology and environmental policy—
innovation effects of past policies and suggestions for improvement. In: OECD proceedings Innovation and the Environment,
pp. 35-61. Paris: OECD.
18
Kemp, R. & P. Pearson (2008). Measuring eco-innovation (Final
Report MEI project). Maastricht: UNU-MERIT.
Kemp, R. & S. Pontoglio (in press). The innovation effects of
environmental policy instruments—A typical case of the blind
men and the elephant?, submitted to Ecological Economics.
Kemp, R. & S. Zundel (2007). Environmental innovation policy: Is
steering innovation processes possible? In: M. Lehmann-Waffenschmidt (Ed.), Innovations Towards Sustainability. Conditions and
Consequences, pp. 25-46. Heidelberg, New York: Physica Verlag.
Kivimaa, P. (2008). The innovation effects of environmental
policies: linking policies, companies and innovations in the
Nordic pulp and paper industry. Acta Universitatis Oeconomicae Helsingiensis A-329, Helsinki School of Economics.
Kletzan-Slamanig, D et al. (2009). Assessment of ETAP roadmaps
with regard to their eco-innovation potential. Technical Report 2:
Country fiches for the ETAP roadmaps. Vienna: Austrian Institute
of Economic Research (WIFO).
Krozer, Y. (2002). Milieu & Innovatie. PhD Thesis. Rijksuniversiteit Groningen, Groningen.
Lipsey, R. & K. Carlaw (1998). Technology policies in neoclassical and structuralist-evolutionary models. STI Review
22: 31-73.
Lundvall, B. & S. Borrás (1998). The Globalising Learning
Economy: Implications for Innovation Policy. Luxembourg: Office
for Official Publications of the European Communities.
Lundvall, B.-A. & M. Tomlinson (2002). International benchmarking as a policy learning tool. In: M.J. Rodrigues (Ed.) The
New Knowledge Economy in Europe, pp. 203-231. Cheltenham:
Edward Elgar.
Malerba, F. (2009). Increase learning, break knowledge lockins and foster dynamic complementarities: evolutionary and
system perspectives on technology policy in industrial dynamics. In: D. Foray (Ed.) The New Economics of Technology Policy,
pp. 33-45. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Metcalfe, J.S. & L. Georghiou (1998). Equilibrium and evolutionary foundations of technology policy. STI Review 22: 75-100.
Mowery, D.C., R.R. Nelson & B.R. Martin (2010). Technology
policy and global warming: why new policy models are needed
(or why putting new wine in old models won’t work). Research
Policy 39(8): 1011–1023.
Mytelka, L.K. & K. Smith (2002). Policy learning and innovation
theory: an interactive and co-evolving process. Research Policy
31(8-9): 1467-1479.
Kemp | P18
Nauwelaers, C. & R. Wintjes (2008). Innovation policy, innovation in policy: policy learning within and across systems
and clusters. In: C. Nauwelaers & R. Wintjes (Eds.), Innovation Policy in Europe. Measurement and Strategy, pp. 225-268.
Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Nelson, R.R. (2009). Building effective ‘innovation systems’
versus dealing with market failures as ways of thinking about
technology policy. In: D. Foray (Ed.) The New Economics of
Technology Policy, pp. 7-16. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Newell, R.G. (2010). The role of markets and policies in delivering innovation for climate change mitigation. Oxford Review
of Economic Policy 26(2): 253–269.
Nill, J. & R. Kemp (2009). Evolutionary approaches for sustainable innovation policies: from niche to paradigm? Research
Policy 38(4): 668-680.
Rennings, K. (2000). Redefining innovation: eco-innovation
research and the contribution from ecological economics.
Ecological Economics 32: 319-332.
Ringeling, A.B. (2005). Instruments in four: the elements of policy design. In: P. Eliadis, M.M. Hills, M. Howlett (Eds), Designing
Government: From Instruments to Governance, pp. 185-202.
Kingston, Ontario: McGill-Queens University Press.
Rip, A. & R. Kemp (1998). Technological change. In: S. Rayner
and L. Malone (Eds.), Human Choice and Climate Change,
pp. 327-399. Washington D.C.: Batelle Press.
Rogge, K., M. Schneider & V.H. Hoffmann (2010). The innovation impact of EU emission trading – findings of company case
studies in the German Power Sector. Fraunhofer ISI Working
Paper Sustainability and Innovation No. S 2/2010.
OECD (1999). Managing National Systems of Innovation. Paris:
OECD.
Sartorius C. & S. Zundel (Eds.) (2005), Time Strategies, Innovation and Environmental Policy. Advances in Ecological
Economics. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
OECD (2005) Oslo Manual. The measurement of scientific and
technological activities. Proposed guidelines for collecting and
interpreting technological innovation data. Paris: OECD.
Schrama, G.J.I. & S. Sedlacek (2003). Environmental and
Technology Policy in Europe. Technological Innovations and Policy Integration. Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers.
OECD (2008) Sustainable manufacturing and eco-innovation.
First steps in building a common framework. DSTI/IND(2008)16/
REV1. Paris: OECD.
Smith, K. (2000). Innovation as a systemic phenomenon: rethinking the role of policy. Enterprise & Innovation Management
Studies 1(1), 73-102.
OECD (2011). Better Policies to Support Eco-innovation. OECD
studies on Environmental Innovation. Paris: OECD.
Smith, K. (2008). Climate change and radical energy innovation:
the policy issues. Report to Garnaut Commission on climate
Change, Australia.
Parkhurst, G. et al. (in press). Intermodal personal mobility: A
niche caught between two regimes. In: Geels, F.W., R. Kemp,
G. Dudley, G. Lyons (Eds.) Automobility in Transition? A sociotechnical analysis of sustainable transport. London: Routledge.
Pontoglio, S. (2010). An early assessment of the influence on
eco-innovation of the EU emissions trading scheme: evidence
from the Italian paper industry. In: Mazzanti M., Montini
A (Eds.) Environmental Efficiency, Innovation and Economic
Performances, pp. 81-91. London: Routledge.
Popp, D. (2006). R&D subsidies and climate policy: is there a
‘free lunch’? Climatic Change 77 (3-4): 311-41.
Popp, D. (2010). Innovation and Climate Policy, NBER Working
Paper No. 15673.
Remøe, S.O. (2008). Innovation governance in dynamic economies. Lessons from the OECD MONIT project. In: C. Nauwelaers
& R. Wintjes (Eds.), Innovation Policy in Europe. Measurement and
Strategy, pp. 139-170. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
S . A . P. I . E N . S
Kemp Ten themes for eco-innovation policies in Europe
Smith, A. & A. Stirling (2010). The politics of social-ecological
resilience and sustainable socio-technical transitions. Ecology
and Society 15(1): 11.
Smits, R. & S. Kuhlmann (2004). The rise of systemic instruments in innovation policy. International Journal of Foresight
and Innovation Policy 1(1/2): 4-32.
Soete, L. & A. Arundel (1993). An integrated approach to
European innovation and technology diffusion policy: a Maastricht memorandum. Publication EUR 15090. Brussels: EU.
Steward, F. (2008). Breaking the boundaries. Transformative innovation for the global good, NESTA provocation 07, April 2008.
UNEP (2011), Decoupling natural resource use and environmental impacts from economic growth: A Report of the Working Group
on Decoupling to the International Resource Panel, M. FischerKowalski et al. (Authors). Nairobi, Kenya: UNEP.
Unruh, G.C. (2000). Understanding carbon lock-in. Energy
Policy 28: 817-830.
Kemp | P19
19
Kemp Ten themes for eco-innovation policies in Europe
Voss, J.-P. (2007). Designs on Governance. Development of
Policy Instruments and Dynamics in Governance. PhD Thesis,
University of Twente.
Zundel, S. et al. (2005), Conceptual Framework, In: C. Sartorius
& S. Zundel (Eds.) Time Strategies, Innovation and Environmental Policy. Advances in Ecological Economics, pp. 10-51.
Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
20
Kemp | P20