IANUS
Diritto e Finanza
Rivista di studi giuridici
ISSN: 1974-9805
https://www.rivistaianus.it
n. 26 - dicembre 2022
IN THE NAME OF GOD:
MANAGING RISK IN ISLAMIC FINANCE
Valentino Cattelan
http
IANUS n. 26-2022
ISSN 1974-9805
IN THE NAME OF GOD: MANAGING RISK IN ISLAMIC FINANCE1
Valentino Cattelan
Lecturer in Law,
Birmingham City University
In Against the gods: the remarkable story of risk (1996), Peter L. Bernstein illustra come il saper
dominare il rischio abbia guidato la moderna società occidentale nel convertire «il futuro da nemico in
opportunità», laddove il rischio vine quantificato, misurato, e gestito per mitigare i pericoli dell’inatteso, e
dove procedure di risk-taking, -transfer e pooling sono divenute esse stesse fonti di legittimo profitto.
Commentando il lavoro di Bernstein nel passaggio dal ‘rischio’ occidentale alla nozione araba di ﺭﺯﻕrizq,
‘il sostenimento (divino)’, questo articolo si riferisce all’azzardo umano, o fortuna, in arabo ﺯﻫﺭzahr, i
‘dadi’ delle future chances, attraverso una prospettiva comparativa ed interculturale. Più precisamente,
l’articolo intende mostrare come specifiche assunzioni antropologiche conducano ad una teoria ed una
pratica alternative della gestione del rischio in un mercato la cui peculiarità sta nell’operare non
‘contro’ ma ‘in Nome di Dio’: vale a dire, il mercato della finanza islamica.
In Against the gods: the remarkable story of risk (1996), Peter L. Bernstein illustrates how the
mastery of risk has driven modern Western society into converting «the future from an enemy into an
opportunity», where risk is quantified, measured, and managed to mitigate the perils of the unexpected,
and where risk-taking, -transfer and -pooling have become per se sources of legitimate profit.
Commenting on Bernstein’s work while moving from the Western ‘risk’ to the Arabic ﺭﺯﻕrizq, ‘(God’s)
sustenance’, this article looks at human hazard, ﺯﻫﺭzahr, the ‘dice’ of future chances, through a
comparative and inter-cultural perspective. More precisely, it aims to show how specific anthropological
assumptions result in an alternative theory and practice of risk management in a market whose
peculiarity is to operate not ‘against’ but ‘in the Name of God’: namely, the market of Islamic finance.
Summary:
1. Gods, men and the (un)expected: from Bernstein’s risk to the Arabic rizq ()ﺭﺯﻕ
2. Islamic finance, Muslim anthropology, and legitimate profit: al-kharaj bi-l-daman
3. Conceiving and managing risk in God’s creation: the logic of Islamic finance
4. Conclusions: another, remarkable, story of risk?
Saggio sottoposto a double-blind peer review.
This article remained for a long time in the preliminary format of working paper (CATTELAN, In the
Name of God: managing risk in Islamic finance, in Eabh Working Papers Series, 14-07, 2014; available
online at http://www.eabh.info/publications/eabh-papers). I thank the editorial committee of IANUS for
the opportunity to give it appropriate collocation as article in a peer-reviewed journal.
Transliteration note: please consider that in the transliteration from Arabic into English graphical forms
have been simplified (e.g. riba instead of ribā; Shari‘ah in the place of šarī‘ah; daman instead of ḍamān;
haqq in the place of ḥaqq; and so on).
Quotations of the Qur’an are taken from YUSUF ALI, An English interpretation of the Holy Qur’an
with full Arabic text, Lahore, 1975. The sura is specified in Roman numbers; the ayat in Arab numbers
(e.g. Q. IX:51, 51th ayat of the 9th sura).
1
149
VALENTINO CATTELAN
«The word “risk” derives from the early Italian risicare,
which means “to dare”. In this sense, risk is a choice
rather than a fate. The actions we dare to take, which
depend on how free we are to make choices, are what the
story of risk is all about. And that story helps define what
it means to be a human being»2.
1. Gods, men and the (un)expected: from Bernstein’s risk to the Arabic rizq ()ﺭﺯﻕ
Peter L. Bernstein’s extraordinary book Against the gods: the remarkable story
of risk3 has been able to popularize and make accessible to the general public the
intricacy of a concept, that, as he remarks, «touches on the most profound aspects
of psychology, mathematics, statistics, and history» (p. ix). The volume itself won
the Edwin G. Booz Price for the most insightful, innovative management book in
1996, as well as the Clarence Arthur Kelp/Elizur Wright Memorial Award in 1998;
not really unexpectedly, considering this success, Against the gods has sold over
500,000 copies worldwide.
Indeed, dealing with the (un)expected is what risk management is all about:
something that Bernstein defines as that ‘revolutionary idea’ shaping modernity,
where, far from being an antagonist, as the unpredictable whim of gods or the
mysterious fate, the future has become an opportunity. Moving away from the fear
of the unexpected, his volume tells us about «[…] the story of a group of thinkers
whose remarkable vision revealed how to put the future at the service of the
present… [converting] risk-taking into one of the prime catalysts that drives
modern Western society. Like Prometheus, they defied the gods and probed that
darkness in search of the light that converted the future from an enemy into an
opportunity. The transformation in attitudes towards risk management unleashed
by their achievements has channelled the human passion for games and wagering
into economic growth, improved quality of life, and technological progress» 4.
From Fibonacci’s Liber Abaci (1202), Cardano’s Liber de Ludo Aleae (1525)
and Galileo’s Sopra le scoperte dei dadi (1623), the astonishing story of risk
developed in Western society through the laws of probability framed by Pascal,
Fermat, and Chevalier de Méré 5, and the science of statistics of Graunt, Petty, and
Halley, fostering the development of insurance as a commercial concept in the
eighteenth century6. It was in that time, with Bernoulli’s paper on Specimen
Theoriae Novae de Mensura Sortis (1731), that risk-taking was related not only to
objective facts but also to a «subjective view about the desirability of what is to
2
BERNSTEIN, Against the gods: the remarkable story of risk, New York, 1996, 8.
See previous note.
4 ID., 1.
5 ID., 57-72.
6 ID., 92.
3
150
IANUS n. 26-2022
ISSN 1974-9805
be gained, or lost, by the decision» 7. From this perspective, if «Cardano, Pascal,
and Fermat provided a method for figuring the risks in each throw of the dice, …
Bernoulli introduces us to the risk-taker - the player who chooses how much to
bet or whether to bet at all. While probability theory sets up the choices, Bernoulli
defines the motivations of the person who does the choosing. This is an entirely
new area of study and body of theory. Bernoulli laid the intellectual groun dwork
for much of what was to follow, not just in economics, but in theories about how
people make decisions and choices in every aspect of life» 8.
From that time onwards, through Gauss’s normal distribution9, Poincaré’s
study of information/decision-making and Bachelier’s analysis of speculation 10,
the theory of risk has further advanced through Arrow 11, Knight and Keynes’s
notion of risk as ‘measurable uncertainty’ 12. An uncertainty whose source can be
found in others’ intentions, as explained by Von Neumann, Morgenstern and
Nash’s game theory13; and whose measure has led financial theory to well-known
concepts such as portfolio selection, diversification, the capital asset pricing
model (by Markowitz and Sharpe), the Black and Scholes formula, and to prospect
theory in behavioural economics (by Kahneman and Tversky) 14.
Of course, this very concise introduction to Bernstein’s book does not even
distantly mirror the richness of its contents: the interested reader will find in
Against the gods, and its broad bibliography, much better satisfaction of his
intellectual enquiries. But, at least superficially, this summary highlights how
centuries of extraordinary intellectual elaboration in Western society transformed
the future from an antagonist into a product of a (human) present where risk is
quantified, measured, and managed to mitigate the perils of the unexpected.
Accordingly, within this cultural setting, activities of risk-taking, -transfer and pooling (i.e., banking, investment, insurance, or even gambling, businesses) have
become in the West a source per se of legitimate profit, where, in the
(extra)ordinary enterprise of risk management, as we know it today, the ‘gods’ are
left aside.
But from where does the idea of ‘risk’ come from? And how much does it
explain about human nature, given that its story, in the end, is all about «[t]he
actions we dare to take» and «how free we are to make choices»?
If the Latin resecare, resicum, risicum, riscus are the direct precedents for the
Italian risicare, meaning ‘to dare’, and risco (from which the current Italian
7 ID., 100. Daniel Bernoulli, in fact, introduced the revolutionary idea that «the value of an item must
not be based on its price, but rather on the utility that it yields», which varies from person to person
(BERNSTEIN, cit., 99; italics in the original text).
8 ID., 108 (italics in the original text).
9 ID., 136.
10 ID., 200.
11 ID., 204.
12 ID., 219.
13 ID., respectively at 232, 235, and 243.
14 ID., respectively at 260, 304 ff., 270.
151
VALENTINO CATTELAN
rischio, the French risque, the English risk, the Spanish riesgo and the German
Risiko, all derive), a more ancient etymology of the word ‘risk’, in contrast,
remains uncertain. The Latin forms may have derived from the Greek ριζα,
meaning ‘root’, ‘stone’, ‘cut of the firm land’, which was also used as a metaphor
for a ‘difficulty to avoid in the sea’.15 For the ancient Greeks the uncertainty of
survival in the Mediterranean was caused by the whims of gods like Zeus and
Poseidon, and the ‘stone’ of the firm land as well as the ‘root’ of a tree were
symbolic images of a lifeline, securing the sailors from the perils of the sea. Quite
interestingly, the classical Greek ριζα seems to find (at least phonetically) an
equivalent in the Arabic rizq ()ﺭﺯﻕ, from which the word ‘risk’ may derive, too:
the term may have been absorbed by ancient pre-Islam Arabic from Greek, via
Mediterranean contacts, or vice-versa. The rich legacy of such contacts is also
witnessed by the word ‘hazard’, that moved into English from the French hasard
and the Spanish azar, both (certainly) coming from the Arabic ﺯﻫﺮzahr, meaning
‘dice’, thus the chance of human luck. 16
But, apart from this digression on probable linguistic transmissions through the
Mediterranean, if rizq on the one side expresses the idea of ‘fortune’, ‘profit’,
‘gain’, ‘blessing’ (thus, safety from the perils of life, as in the etymology of ριζα
and later ‘risk’), on the other side, and quiet remarkably, this fortune is depicted
and conceived in Arabic language in the particular sense of «a sustenance that is
given by God for livelihood». 17 Accordingly, the verb razaqa is always used in
the sense of ‘God providing somebody with means of subsistence’; ﺍﻟﺮﺯﺍar-razzaq,
‘the Maintainer’, ‘the Provider’ is one of the ninety-nine attributes of God; and
ﻣﺮﺯﻭﻕmarzuq is the ‘person blessed by God’, thus ‘fortunate’, ‘prosperous’,
‘successful’. At a very preliminary glance, therefore, the secular nature embedded
in modern Western ‘risk’ stays far apart from the Arabic rizq, where the future
and its fortunes are given by God.
To the extent to which the phonetic connection between the Greek ριζα and the
Arabic rizq may been tentatively suggested and is certainly thought-provoking, it
seems to me that their distant meanings may also offer a clue (or at least an
intellectual temptation) to broaden Bernstein’s history of risk by adopting a
15 In this sense, for instance, SKJONG, Etymology of risk. Classical Greek origin - Nautical expression
- Metaphor for “difficulty to avoid the sea”, 2005, available online at the following address
http://research.dnv.com/skj/Papers/etimology-of-risk.pdf. Indeed, it is of interest that «these lexical
borrowings happened in the end of the middle-ages, when mentalities woke up and people dared to
discover the world. So that from the 16th century on, the term got a benefit meaning, for example in
middle-high-German Rysigo … a technical term for business, with the meaning “to dare, to undertake,
enterprise, hope for economic success”» (ID.).
16 BERNSTEIN, Against the gods: the remarkable story of risk, cit., 13. Both the Greek ριζα and the
Arabic rizq ( )ﺭﺯﻕmay even find a common Indo-European or Semitic root (a hypothesis of ancient
comparative linguistics which is, of course, far beyond my expertise and the aims of this writing).
Speaking of risk (and my personal risk-aversion), anyway, I would not put my money neither on ριζα
nor ﺭﺯﻕas the very first origin of the term and its related meaning(s).
17 WEHR, A dictionary of modern written Arabic, ed. by J M. Cowan, IV ed., Wiesbaden, 1994.
152
IANUS n. 26-2022
ISSN 1974-9805
comparative perspective, moving from the Western to the Arab side of the
Mediterranean by looking at the hazard, ﺯﻫﺮzahr, the ‘dice’ of future chances,
through an inter-cultural approach. In other terms, does a different anthropology
of risk characterize Islam in comparison to the West? Should we tell, in this regard,
a story of risk different from Bernstein’s? And, if this diverse story is still to be
told, how much may it help us to ‘define what it means to be a human being’ in a
Muslim context?
Indeed, today the investigation on ριζα/rizq is far from being purely speculative
and confined to comparative linguistics or the domain of intellectual conjectures.
On the contrary, it can be directly related to the development of a niche of the
financial system whose outstanding peculiarity, to Bernstein’s surprise, is to operate
not ‘against’ but ‘in the Name of God’: namely, the market of Islamic finance.
In this direction, challenging the perils of the Mediterranean in the search for
another root of safety from the unexpected (the ancient Greek ριζα), this article
dares to look at human fortune in the light of the Arabic rizq, and investigating
how a diverse anthropology of risk in Islam may actually result in alternative
practices of risk management, as manifested today by Shari‘ah-compliant
financial institutions.
Thus, the Islamic financial market and its peculiar principles (prohibitions of
riba, interest; uncertainty and speculation, gharar; gambling, maysir) will be
depicted within an anthropology of time where not only the future, but also the
present, are a divine (rather than human) creation, and where, accordingly, risk
itself is deeply re-framed both as a concept and as a source of legitimate profit.
Indeed, to the extent to which, as we will see, in a reality created directly by God
the future remains an economic opportunity (Q. II:275: «Allah has permitted
trade»), any legitimate profit follows from man’s responsibility (al-kharaj bi-ldaman) in performing Shari‘ah by participating in the divine creation of the ‘real’
and as an ‘agent’ of the only ‘Actor’. It is this dual canon of ‘participation’ and
‘agency’ that coherently implies a conceptualization of risk in Islam, which is
focused on the primacy of the real economy; exchange equilibrium (with any
unlawful increase due to riba, gharar or maysir being prohibited); and profit-loss
sharing (section 2 of this article).
As a result, alternative rationales rule risk management in Islamic finance. In
fact, while risk continues to hold an economic value, this value is linked to real
assets and business activities through the assumption of liability (‘profit follows
responsibility’, al- kharaj bi-l-daman), leading to fundamental peculiarities in the
practice of Islamic banking, insurance (takaful) and securities (sukuk) trade that
can hardly be compared to conventional ones, as well as rejecting financial
products, such as derivatives that are deemed lacking in any commercial value
since nothing ‘real’ is actually traded (section 3). To conclude (section 4), the
article will remark how this alternative story of risk would require further
consideration in financial theory and regulation, for the benefit of a level playing
field where conventional and Islamic finance would be able to co-exist and prosper
under the same (God’s?) sky.
153
VALENTINO CATTELAN
2. Islamic finance, Muslim anthropology, and legitimate profit: al-kharaj bi-l-daman
Islamic finance has recently experienced increasing visibility as an ethical
alternative to conventional business,18 as well as exceptional growth in GCC and
South- Asian countries (above all, Malaysia), with an average growth rate between 10
and 20 per cent in the last decade.19 At any rate, while forming a promising niche in
the Middle East and Asia, at present its market share is only around two to three per
cent of total transactions at a global level; moreover, as far as Europe and the West
are concerned, the United Kingdom, as the largest national market (after Turkey), still
attracts only a marginal percentage of Shari‘ah-compliant assets, despite the
favourable regulation fostered by the local government.20
From a historical standpoint, modern Islamic finance finds no precedent in the
Muslim society of the past, which did not experience institutionalised credit
institutions such as the European banks of the Middle Ages. As shown by Udovitch,21
financial support in classical Islam was mainly supplied by informal capital providers
or by credit- labour partnerships for commercial activities. In contrast, the birth of
contemporary Islamic finance relates to a flourishing academic literature on Islamic
economics, from the ‘70s onwards,22 and to the first experiments of Islamic banking
in Egypt, under the liberalization programme by President Sadat, the Infitah (‘opendoor’) policy.23 While these preliminary examples of Islamic finance were
primarily driven by purposes of social cohesion through enlarging the access to
credit for the poor, it was during the ‘80s that a more advanced industry developed
under the criteria of Shari‘ah-compliance, moving from a restricted domain into larger
18
TRIPP, Islam and the moral economy. The challenge of capitalism, Cambridge, 2006.
As noted in THE BANKER (2013), Top Islamic financial institutions, Special Report, London, 2013.
20 For one of the first overviews on the matter, see ERCANBRACK, Regulating Islamic finance in the
United Kingdom, in CATTELAN (ed.), Islamic finance in Europe: towards a plural financial system,
Studies in Islamic Finance, Accounting and Governance, Cheltenham, UK - Northampton, MA, USA,
2013, 157-178. In this light, the original enthusiasm shown by Western scholarship towards Islamic
finance as a «key dimension of the relationship between Arab banks and their European counterparties»
(WILSON, Islamic finance in Europe, in RSCAS Policy Papers, Musmine – Muslim Minorities in Europe,
European University Institute, Florence, 2007, 8) remains still today quite premature.
21 UDOVITCH, Partnership and profit in medieval Islam, Princeton, 1970.
22 See, for instance, CHAPRA, Islamic welfare State and its role in the economy, Leicester, 1979;
SIDDIQI, Banking without interest, Leicester, 1976; SIDDIQI, Issues in Islamic banking: selected papers,
Leicester, 1983.
23 In order to uphold social mobility by facilitating the access of the poor to credit, the government
licensed Nasser Social Bank (1971) and Faysal Islamic Bank (1977), that had their precursor in the Mit
Ghamr Savings Bank (licensed by Nasser in 1963 and closed in 1968), deemed to be the first historical
experiment of modern Islamic banking. While observing Islamic precepts in their operations (mainly the
prohibition of interest, riba), these banks were primarily concerned with realising social aims by
providing credit to segments of Egyptian society that, otherwise, would not qualify for loans (see MAYER,
Islamic banking and credit policies in the Sadat era: the social origins of Islamic banking in Egypt,
in Arab Law Quarterly, 1985, 49).
19
154
IANUS n. 26-2022
ISSN 1974-9805
commercial practice.24 At present, Islamic financial institutions offer to the generality
of customers (Muslim or not) an immense variety of products, from investmentdeposits (so-called PSIAs, profit sharing investment accounts) to takaful, lit.
‘guaranteeing each other’, the Islamic risk-shared insurance model aimed at avoiding
‘uncertainty’ (gharar); as well as equity fund management and Islamic securities
(sukuk).
In compliance with Shari‘ah, fundamental peculiarities characterize Islamic
financial transactions, whose validity requires, apart from the avoidance of prohibited
investments (such as alcohol, pork, pornography), the elimination of any profit
deriving from an ‘unlawful increase’, that is to say, interest (prohibition of riba),
unreasonable uncertainty (ban of gharar) and gambling (maysir).25
These rules necessarily result in a favour towards asset- and equity-based financial
instruments and a corresponding dismissal of both debt-based products (likely to
produce riba) and hazard-affected securities (gharar, maysir). More precisely, since
conventional loans are essentially gratuitous in Islamic law (due to the prohibition of
riba), ordinary interest-bearing credit transactions are replaced in Islamic finance by
asset-backed contracts, such as murabaha (mark-up or cost-plus sale), salam (advance
purchase), istisna‘ (commission to manufacture) and hire-and-sale (ijara); or by
equity-based instruments such as mudaraba (silent partnership) and musharaka (full
partnership). In both cases (asset-backed or equity instruments), legitimate profit has
to derive from the necessary assumption of a liability correlated to a reference entity,
according to the fundamental principle al-kharaj bi-l-daman, that is to say, profit (i.e.
the chance of gain, in the sense of what is someone’s due, what someone deserves;
see Wehr: « ﻫﺬﺍ ﺧﺮﺟﻚthat’s what you need, what you deserve»26) relates to liability,
i.e. the risk of potential loss for which the person is responsible (from the root نمض
damina, ‘to be or become responsible or liable, give security or guaranty’).
Thus, another notion of ‘fortune’, different from, while complementary to, ﻕﺯﺭ
rizq, ‘(God’s) sustenance’, appears here: that is to say, the basic postulate in Islamic
finance that any legitimate profit (kharaj) has to derive from a liability, a
24
The literature dealing with Islamic economics and finance is enormous. Valuable references
remain ARCHER - KARIM (eds.), Islamic finance: the regulatory challenge, New York, 2007; AYUB,
Understanding Islamic finance, New York, 2007; CHAPRA, Islamic welfare State and its role in the
economy, cit.; CHAPRA, Islam and economic development, Islamabad, 1993; EL-GAMAL, Islamic finance.
Law, economics, and practice, Cambridge, 2006; HASSAN - LEWIS (eds.), Handbook of Islamic banking,
Cheltenham, UK, 2007; IQBAL - LLEWELLYN (eds.), Islamic banking and finance: new perspectives on
profit-sharing and risk, Cheltenham, UK, 2002; Khan - Porzio (eds.), Islamic banking and finance in the
European Union. A challenge, Cheltenham, UK, 2010; SIDDIQI, Banking without interest, cit.; SIDDIQI,
Issues in Islamic banking: selected papers, cit.; USMANI, Introduction to Islamic finance, Karachi, 2000;
VOGEL - HAYES, Islamic law and finance: religion, risk and return, Arab and Islamic Law Series, The
Hague, 1998; WARDE, Islamic finance in the global economy, Edinburgh, 2000.
25 SALEH, Unlawful gain and legitimate profit in Islamic law: riba, gharar and Islamic banking, II
ed., London, 1992; CATTELAN, From the concept of haqq to the prohibitions of riba, gharar and maysir
in Islamic finance, in International Journal of Monetary Economics and Finance, 2009, 2 (3/4), 384397.
26 WEHR, A dictionary of modern written Arabic, cit.
155
VALENTINO CATTELAN
responsibility, or an accountability (daman) of the economic actor for assuming a risk,
through which he deserves God’s blessing (rizq) by following the right Path, Shari‘ah.
At this point, before interpreting how the principle al-kharaj bi-l-daman affects
risk management in Islamic finance, a more in-depth investigation is needed with
regard to Muslim anthropology. In my opinion, in fact, instead of looking at Islamic
finance in the light of (conventional?) ethical investments, a more appropriate
understanding of its logic can be derived from locating its rationales within the
Qur’anic Creator paradigm that shapes the life of every Muslim. 27 Accordingly, the
conceptualization of risk in Islamic finance may find better interpretation in
connecting rizq, as ‘God’s sustenance’, to what is deserved by the human being
through becoming responsible for his action (daman as source of legitimate
profit). In other terms, how God provides for human existence and how man, by
becoming responsible for his actions, deserves God’s favour in Islam?28
As is well-known, Islam means ‘submission to God’: a submission of the believer
(muslim), which is complementary to God’s absolute omnipotence. The great
theologian and legal scholar al-Ghazali (d. 505/1111), in his doctrinal work al-Iqtisad
fi’l-I‘tiqad summarizes the nature of God’s creativeness in the sentence: «What He
wills, is and what He does not will, is not»: 29 «This extends to the least, seemingly
insignificant, occurrence: “… not even the casual glance of a spectator nor the stray
thought in the mind come to be outside the sphere of His will”. Will is also expressed
by the term mashi’ah, “volition”, and so it is that the word shay’, “thing”, deriving
from the same root, is sometimes glossed as “what has been willed [by God] to exist”
».30
God’s perpetual creative power models all the reality («To Him is due the primal
origin of the heavens and earth. When He decreeth a matter, He saith only “Be,” and
it is’»: Q. II:117),31 as an element of His unquestionable perfection.32 Indeed, «There
are eight names for God, among the canonical ninety-nine, which direct our attention
to Allah as the source of all that is: al-Badi’ (Absolute Cause), al-Bari’ (Producer),
al-Khaliq (Creator), al-Mubdi’ (Beginner), al-Muqtadir (All-Determiner), al-
27 On the matter, please refer to NETTON, Allah transcendent: studies in the structure and
semiotics of Islamic philosophy, theology and cosmology, London, 1989. See also CATTELAN, Islamic
finance and ethical investments. Some points of reconsideration, in KHAN - PORZIO (eds.), Islamic
banking and finance in the European Union. A Challenge, cit., 76-87; CATTELAN, Shari‘ah economics as
autonomous paradigm: theoretical approach and operative outcomes, in Journal of Islamic Perspective
on Science, Technology and Society, 1 (1), 2013, 3-11.
28 GIMARET, Théories de l’acte humain en théologie musulmane, Paris and Leuven, 1980.
29 ORMSBY, Theodicy in Islamic thought. The dispute over al-Ghazali’s “Best of all possible
worlds”, Princeton, 1984, 192.
30 ID.
31 See also HOOVER, Perpetual creativity in the perfection of God: Ibn Taymiyya’s hadith commentary
on God’s creation of this world, in Journal of Islamic Studies, 15 (3), 2004, 287-329.
32 Corresponding texts in Q. III:47,59; VI:73; XVI:40; XXXVI:82; XL:68.
156
IANUS n. 26-2022
ISSN 1974-9805
Musawwir (Fashioner), al- Qadir (All-Powerful) and al-Qahhar (Dominator), each
with various connotations of creating».33
God being the only Creator, the Muslim lives ‘in surrender’ to God’s omnipotence,
as an agent of the only Actor, participating in the creation by performing God’s Will,
within a conception of time where the divine immediate creation is inserted within the
flow of contingent human agencies, and «the world comes to be at the time when the
eternal will stands in nexus with its coming-to-be».34
The complementary truths of God’s omnipotence and human responsibility, with
the corollary linkage between divine eternity and human history in the flow of time
(conceived as an atomistic succession of instants, each created by God),35 find their
pivotal reconciliation through the Revelation of Shari‘ah (literally, ‘the road leading
to water’, the Way, the Path) (Q. XLV:18).36 In fact, in order to make human beings
responsible for their actions and able to deserve His blessings, God has given the
Qur’an,37 lit. ‘what is read’, the ‘recitation’, and sent the Prophet as reminder of the
Message («Say: “Nothing will happen to us except what Allah has decreed for us: He
is our Protector”: and on Allah let the Believers put their trust»: Q. IX:51).38
There are no obstacles for the believer to seek the right Way, the true Guidance:
«for the Muslim the whole religion itself is in a very real sense a synonym of God’s
guidance: Islam is “being rightly guided”».39 The Revelation is clear, and the clarity
of Truth doesn’t require any imposition: «Let there be no compulsion in religion:
Truth stands out clear from Error: whoever rejects Evil and believes in Allah hath
grasped the most trustworthy hand-hold, that never breaks. And Allah heareth and
knoweth all things» (Q. II:256).40 Anyway, the clarity of the Truth does not mean that
33
BURRELL, Creation, in WINTER (ed.), The Cambridge companion to classical Islamic theology,
Cambridge, 2008, 141.
34 Ghazali, as quoted in ORMSBY, Theodicy in Islamic thought. The dispute over al-Ghazali’s
“Best of all possible worlds”, cit., 193; for the alternative conceptualization of freedom in Islam, see
WATT, Islamic alternatives to the concept of free will, in La notion de liberté au Moyen Age. Islam,
Byzance, Occident, Paris, 1985, 15-24.
35 In this regard, see the illuminating BÖWERING, The concept of time in Islam, in Proceedings of the
American Philosophical Society, 141 (1), 1997, 55-66.
36 CALDER, Shari‘ah, in Encyclopaedia of Islam, II ed., 1978.
37 «The Qur’an as a whole… maintains human responsibility at the same time as it asserts divine
omnipotence… In the end, then, the Qur’an simply holds fast to the complementary truths of God’s
omnipotence and man’s responsibility» (BELL, Introduction to the Qur’an, Edinburgh, 1970, 150-152).
38 This is in Islam the Way, the Guidance that expresses the decision by God intervening under the
form of a communication concerning human actions; in this sense, according to Stelzer, «divine law is a
manifestation of the divine Word» (STELZER, Ethics, in WINTER (ed.), The Cambridge companion to
classical Islamic theology, Cambridge, 2008, 169). See also GOLDZIHER, Introduction to Islamic theology
and law, New Jersey, 1981.
39 NETTON, Allah transcendent: studies in the structure and semiotics of Islamic philosophy,
theology and cosmology, cit., 24-25.
40 «The truth is clear, settled, and definitely convincing… The truth stands here, facing us; it is
presented to us. The truth in its completeness is submitted to us as clarity-for-us… The truth, established
and secured by its certainty, makes no distinction between “momentary” and “eternal”. The truth is valid
not because it has ascended above the nonlasting; the truth is valid because it stands firmly established
157
VALENTINO CATTELAN
it is manifest, and ilm al-fiqh (literally ‘science of comprehension’, ‘understanding’)
is the discipline specifically aimed at making manifest God’s Will as clearly revealed
in the Qur’an and exemplified by the Prophet (sunna).
To summarize the anthropology of Islam, as depicted by Netton in the Qur’anic
Creator Paradigm, Muslim conception of life «embraces a God who (1) creates ex
nihilo; (2) acts definitely in historical time; (3) guides His people in such time [through
Shari‘ah]; and (4) can in some way be known indirectly by His creation [in the light
of the understanding of the Revelation through fiqh]».41
Indeed, in the total sovereignty by God to create everything that comes-to-exist,
the ‘real’ itself (haqq, which is one of the name of God: al-Haqq) holds a meaning of
‘Truth’ as being ‘right’: in other terms, it fosters a conception of the reality as being
essentially ethical, a product of God’s Will in the unity (tawhid) of the creation as the
only (real, true, just) ‘Actor’, of which the believers are ‘agents’.
«A vision of the reality as being in its essence imperative, a structure not of objects
but of wills. The moral and the ontological change places, at least from our point of
view. […] The “real” here is deeply moralized, active, demanding real, not a neutral,
metaphysical “being”, merely sitting there awaiting observation and reflection; a real
of prophets not of philosophers».42
Thus, the ‘right’ ontologically acquires a ‘tangible’, ‘real’ nature (not by chance
‘reality’ is one of the various meaning of haqq (pl. huquq), next to ‘truth’ and
‘right’),43 as a ‘concrete’ entity whose allocation is provided by God (through the
benevolence of His blessing, )ﺭﺯﻕ, in the light of Shari‘ah: and, coherently, it is the
performance of Shari‘ah that makes the human being responsible (damin) for his
actions, thus deserving what is due (kharaj).
Coming back now to our topic of discussion, to which extent does this ontological
nature of the ‘right’ affect the idea of risk and the practice of risk management?
Indeed, in a reality where everything is an immediate divine creation and the ‘right’
(haqq) subsists within the performance of Shari‘ah, if the future remains an
(economic) opportunity, it is not anymore a ‘human product’ but the result of the
human participation in the divine creation of the ‘real’ as an agent of the only ‘Actor’.
It is this dual canon of ‘participation’ and ‘agency’ that logically implies in Islamic
finance a conceptualization of risk that tends towards the primacy of the real economy
over finance, exchange equilibrium, as well as risk-sharing strategies in financial
dealings.
In a nutshell, paraphrasing Bernstein, the actions we dare to take, which depend on
how responsible we are in performing Shari‘ah in the reality created by God, are what
the story of risk in Islamic finance is all about.
amid the flow of things nonlasting» (SMIRNOV, Understanding justice in an Islamic context: some points
of contrast with Western theories, in Philosophy East and West, 46 (3), 1996, 338).
41 NETTON, Allah transcendent: studies in the structure and semiotics of Islamic philosophy,
theology and cosmology, cit., 22.
42 GEERTZ, Local knowledge. Further essays in interpretive anthropology, New York, 1983, 177-178.
43 LANE, Arabic-English lexicon, 8 Vols., 1865. Available online at http://www.laneslexicon.co.uk.
158
IANUS n. 26-2022
ISSN 1974-9805
3. Conceiving and managing risk in God’s creation: the logic of Islamic finance
As just remarked, in Islamic finance, according to the principle al-kharaj bi-ldaman, risk management is conceptualized as a distribution of gains and liabilities
where the deserved profit (kharaj) follows the assumption of responsibility (daman)
in the light of man’s participation in the marketplace as an agent in the ‘real’/‘right’
(haqq) created by God.
Here, the ‘right’ (haqq) necessarily relates to something ‘real’ (haqq, again); thus,
any advantage or disadvantage cannot be separated from the actual possession or
ownership of an underlying asset. Coherently, in Islamic finance risk management is
shaped in the light of the primacy of the real economy, and asset-backed transactions
substitute the nominal exchanges of conventional finance. In a nutshell, risk becomes
in Islamic finance an asset-related ‘entity’, and not a commercial ‘entity’ per se, to
the extent to which ‘pure’ financial products, such as derivatives, deemed lacking in
any commercial value (since nothing ‘real’ is actually traded) are rejected.
This alternative conceptualization of risk may find further explanation within
Islam’s atomistic conception of time,44 where God’s creativeness shapes any instant
in the unity (tawhid) of the ‘real’/‘right’ (haqq as result of the only Truth, Haqq). At
the micro level of human existence, this cosmology45 is mirrored by a haqq that is not
conceived anymore as the ‘right’ of a person in opposition to the ‘right’ of another
person, but as a logical structure comprising both the ‘right’ and its corresponding
‘obligation’,46 which makes sense «only within the unity of the two “elements” […]
the huquq are not the “rights” and “obligations” that serve to connect autonomous
elements»,47 but ‘sides’ of a justice existing through a balanced unity (tawhid), where
economic resources are ‘shares’ of the unique justice (‘adl) given by God (from
which, possibly, the concept of ‘sustenance’, )ﺭﺯﻕ. Then, if time is composed of single
instants created by God, each of them must hold a balanced distribution of ‘rights’
(huquq), ruled by a transactional equilibrium, which is guaranteed by quantitative
balance (prohibition of riba) and qualitative disclosure (gharar and maysir).48 Debtstructures and hazard-affected transactions (as in the case of financial derivatives),
therefore, become unlawful in the light of Islamic risk management.
44 Thus, «atomism was not only most congenial to a vision of God acting instantaneously in the world
as the sole true cause, it also proved akin to Arabic grammar, which lacks genuine verbs for “to be” and
“to become”. Neither does Arabic employ the tenses of past, present, and future. Instead, it uses verbal
aspects of complete and incomplete, marking the degree to which an action has been realized or is yet to
be realized without distinguishing precisely between present and future» (BÖWERING, The concept of
time in Islam, cit., p. 60).
45 NETTON, Allah transcendent: studies in the structure and semiotics of Islamic philosophy,
theology and cosmology, cit.
46 KAMALI, Fundamental rights of the individual: an analysis of haqq (right) in Islamic law, in The
American Journal of Islamic Social Sciences, 10 (3), 1993, 340-366.
47 SMIRNOV, Understanding justice in an Islamic context: some points of contrast with Western
theories, cit., 345.
48 CATTELAN, From the concept of haqq to the prohibitions of riba, gharar and maysir in Islamic
finance, cit.
159
VALENTINO CATTELAN
Last, as seen, this asset-backed financial model, fostered by the need of exchange
equilibrium, upholds human agency and participation in the ‘real’/‘right’ (haqq)
through criteria of profit-loss sharing implemented by Islamic financial institutions in
their business activity.49
Considering all this, some conclusions can be advanced on the conceptualization
of risk (as rizq ﺭﺯﻕand, then, daman )ﺿمﻦin Islamic finance.
A fundamental principle has been preliminarily mentioned in our investigation: alkharaj bi-l-daman, ‘profit follows responsibility’, ubi emolumentum ibi onus. The
principle is incorporated in a famous hadith, according to which the risk for loss of an
asset falls upon the person who is receiving benefit from the asset itself.50 As seen, in
Islamic finance any advantage or disadvantage cannot be separated from a contextual
ownership or possession (gain accompanies liability for loss).
Thus, in case of commercial activities, where participants provide capital and/or
labour, the contracting parties necessarily share the risk of the undertaking, and,
consequently, its profits (mudaraba and musharaka). In asset-based transactions, risk
follows the ownership or possession of the res, and a fixed return (e.g., the mark-up
of murabaha) becomes admissible, not in terms of the illicit riba, but as related to the
risk that has been borne by the vendor (again, al-kharaj bi-l-daman). In other terms,
here, the risk is not a commercial ‘entity’ per se, but «is generally a function of either
legal ownership or possession of the res».51
The proposed interpretation of al-kharaj bi-l-daman as the principle governing the
legitimacy of profit in Islamic risk management finds confirmation in the centrality of
the object in the theory of contracts in Islamic law (where «it is the thing… that takes
primacy. […] the thing must have a material, concrete existence. It does not exist trace
of what has been called: res incorporales»).52 This principle provides hermeneutical
help in the understanding of the fatawa issued by Shari‘ah scholars in Islamic finance,
as well as the recommendations by the Accounting and Auditing Organization for
Islamic Financial Institutions (AAOIFI).53
49 Although much is still to be done in the direction of equity-products, such as mudaraba and
musharaka, as major share of their portfolio. Accordingly, Islamic scholarship has always called for an
increase of equity-based products in the balance sheets of Islamic financial institutions. See, for instance,
the resolution by the AAOIFI Shari‘ah Board (13- 14 Feb 2008, Bahrain): «the Shari’ah Board advises
Islamic Financial Institutions to decrease their involvement in debt- related operations and to increase
true partnership based on profit and loss sharing in order to achieve the objectives of the Shari‘ah».
50 Abu Dawud, Tirmidhi, Nisa’I, ibn Maja, Ahmad ibn Hanbal. The principle was also incorporated
in Art. 85 of the Majalla (see also Art. 87, al-ghurm bil-ghunum, which has the same meaning).
51 FADEL, The regulation of risk in Islamic law, the common law, and federal regulatory law, in
Proceedings of the Fourth Harvard University Forum on Islamic Finance, Harvard University,
Cambridge, Massachusetts, 2002, 83.
52 CHEHATA, Études de droit musulman. 2 / La notion de responsabilité contractuelle. Le concept de
propriété, Paris, 1973, 122. See also VOGEL, Contract law of Islam and the Arab Middle East, in
International Encyclopedia of Comparative Law, Vol. VII, Contracts in general, Chapter 7, Tübingen,
Dordrecht, Boston, Lancaster, 2006, 1-77.
53 The Accounting and Auditing Organization for Islamic Financial Institutions (AAOIFI) is a nonfor-profit organization established on 26th Feb 1990, aimed at proposing accounting, auditing,
160
IANUS n. 26-2022
ISSN 1974-9805
For instance, the principle al-kharaj bi-l-daman as ‘risk linked to the res’ finds a
direct application in the definition of sukuk, Shari‘ah-compliant investment
certificates,54 according to Art. 2 AAOIFI Shari‘ah Standards. Here investment sukuk
are defined as «certificates of equal value representing undivided shares in ownership
of tangible assets, usufruct and services or (in the ownership of) the assets of particular
projects or special investment activity» [italics not in the original text] and, according
to Art. 5/1/2, «it is permissible to issue certificates for (to securitize) assets that are
tangible assets, usufruct and services by dividing them into equal shares and issuing
certificates for their value. As for the debts owed as a liability, it is not permissible to
securitize them for the purpose of trading».
The reference to the ownership of tangible assets, usufruct, and services as ‘source’
of legitimate profit for the sukuk holder is clearly related to the interpretation
previously given of the principle al-kharaj bi-l-daman; the reference to ‘undivided
shares’ finds justification in the undivided character of the reference pooling; the
criteria of primacy of real economy, transactional equilibrium and profit-loss sharing
clearly emerge as well.
The same principle has been confirmed in a resolution by the AAOIFI Shari‘ah
Board (13-14 Feb 2008, Bahrain) on the issuance and trade of sukuk, which has
brought about massive consequences on the market of Islamic securities, specifying
that «sukuk, to be tradable, must be owned by sukuk holders, with all rights and
obligations of ownership, in real assets, whether tangible, usufructs or services,
capable of being owned and sold legally» [italics not in the original text].
The meaning of the ruling, with its reference to the ownership of the underlying
assets, reflects a logic where commercial dealings are part of a ‘reality’ (haqq) created
by God: accordingly, the ‘incorporation’ of the risk in real assets, through their
ownership or possession, guarantees the balanced distribution of gains according to
the responsibilities assumed by the parties (al-kharaj bi-l-daman).
At this point, one may say that risk does not exist in Islamic finance as ‘unbundled
commodity’ the way it does in conventional finance: on the contrary, since «risk of
loss is deemed to be a characteristic either of legal ownership or possession, [… it is]
not deemed property that can be exchanged for other property».55
Thus, in Islamic finance, the risk is shared when capitals or workforce are put
together (commercial enterprises), since it belongs to the capitals and workforce
(mudaraba and musharaka); it is transferred in a sale (or in any other transaction, such
as lease) since it belongs to the transferred property (murabaha, salam or ijarah).
With specific reference to the ban of ‘unreasonable uncertainty’, and in accordance
with the reasoning followed in this article, El-Gamal interprets the prohibition of bay’
governance, ethics and Shari‘ah standards for Islamic financial institutions and the industry
(www.aaoifi.com): see, for instance, previous note 49.
54 In the global financial market investment sukuk are usually based on the contracts of mudaraba or
musharaka; in the case of the sale or rent of the assets, other structures are applied (i.e. sukuk al-murabaha
or sukuk al-ijara).
55 FADEL, The regulation of risk in Islamic law, the common law, and federal regulatory law, cit., 83.
161
VALENTINO CATTELAN
al- gharar in the sense of the ban of the ‘trading of risk (of loss)’, as property per se.56
Consequently, a conventional insurance contract, where the risk of negative events
is transferred from the beneficiary to the insurer with the contextual payment of a
premium, is deemed invalid in Islamic finance, since the amounts exchanged by the
insured and the insurer are unequal and depend upon uncertain future events. For these
reasons, the insurance contract is replaced in Islamic finance by the takaful company,
where, on the contrary, the risk is shared among the participants in a mutual guarantee
linked to an investments fund, which may be structured as mudaraba or musharaka
or according to a wakala (agency) contract related to the administration of the fund.
Once again, the criteria of primacy of real economy, exchange equilibrium and profitloss sharing dominate Islamic risk management.
In this context, an example of this alternative conceptualization is given below,
with regard to the invalidity of a conventional insurance contract: «Take an insurance
contract. At T1, A, the insured, pays a premium to B, the insurer, in exchange for B’s
promise to protect A against certain losses should a predetermined contingency occur.
A pays a thaman in the form of premiums but does not receive a muthamman, at least
not immediately, in return. Likewise, B receives a muthamman but does not
immediately deliver a thaman to A. After the parties enter into the insurance contract,
one of the two scenarios is possible.
In the first scenario, the specified contingency occurs and B compensates A for the
loss. From the perspective of the jurists, the money delivered from B to A is A’s
muthamman that he receives in exchange for the premiums that he had already paid.
Similarly, the money B pays A in this scenario is the thaman that B paid in order to
receive A’s muthamman (premiums). Accordingly, they conclude that this exchange
is invalid: first, because it involves riba (the deferred exchange of money); and
second, because of uncertainty in the thaman and the muthamman. Recall that the
promise to indemnify against a loss cannot serve as the muthamman that would
complete the exchange because it is not property that can be delivered to the insured.
In the second scenario, the term of the insurance contract is completed without the
occurrence of the specified contingency. In this case, according to the jurists, there
simply has been no exchange: although the insured has delivered property to the
insurer in the form of premiums, the insured has never delivered any property
(muthamman) to the insured in return. Likewise, the insurer has received property
(muthamman) without paying a price (thaman) in exchange. Accordingly, the trade
fails because it entails “consuming the property of another unjustly” (akl amwal alnas bi-al-batil)”. In the view of the jurists, it is unjust for the insurer to keep the
property of the insured without ever giving him property in return».57
56
EL-GAMAL, An economic explication of the prohibition of gharar in classical Islamic
jurisprudence, Paper presented at the 4th International Conference on Islamic Economics, Leicester, UK,
2000.
57 FADEL, The regulation of risk in Islamic law, the common law, and federal regulatory law, cit., 83.
162
IANUS n. 26-2022
ISSN 1974-9805
4. Conclusions: another, remarkable, story of risk?
Sailing (metaphorically) the Mediterranean from its Western to the Arab side, in
search for firm land (the Greek ριζα) to avoid the perils of the sea, this article has
moved from the Western risk to the Arabic rizq ﺭﺯﻕ, in the attempt to provide an
interpretation of risk management within the distinctive anthropology of Islamic
finance.
In this direction, it has been suggested that in order to look at the hazard of the
future, ﺯﻫﺮzahr, the ‘dice’ of human chances, through an inter-cultural approach,
Bernstein’s Remarkable story of risk should be read not ‘against’, but ‘in the Name of
God’. Indeed, in an anthropology of time where not only the future, but also the
present, is a divine (rather than human) creation, the conception of risk is re-framed
at its very roots, leading to criteria of risk management that cannot leave aside the
‘real’/‘right’ (haqq) of God’s (Haqq) creation. Thus, primacy of real economy,
exchange equilibrium and the pursuit of profit-loss sharing become the cornerstone of
any legitimate human profit (kharaj) as a result of an assumption of liability (daman);
and the paradigm of banking, insurance and investment activities, necessarily framed
in the light of asset- backed and commercial enterprises, becomes hardly comparable
to the conventional one.
Of course, the voyage from the Western risk to the Arabic rizq ﺭﺯﻕ, and then
daman ﺿمﻦas human responsibility for performing Shari‘ah as source of legitimate
profit ( ﺧﺮﺝkharaj), has been roughly ‘mapped’ in these pages, and rapidly sketched:
much further investigation is needed for a comparative history of risk, according
to an inter-cultural perspective. But, to the extent to which this article may represent
a little contribution to the matter, two final considerations are advanced, both with
regard to the Western and Islamic theories of risk management, and to their current
co-existence in the international financial market.
First, looking at both sides of the Mediterranean, another protagonist, next to risk,
should be considered for a comprehensive, comparative financial theory: the idea of
‘credit’, and credit management. In this regard, if in Bernstein’s Against the gods the
role of Christian thought in the history of risk is marginalized, the great cultural
historian Jacques Le Goff, in contrast, has highlighted how religion must not be
forgotten when writing the history of money and credit in Western society:58 in this
way, in the ‘fight’ between gods and men for ruling the (un)expected, the former get
their own back. On the Arab side, if Brunschvig underlines how in classical Islamic
thought «like any good and useful good, gold (dhahab) and silver (fidda, wariq) have
been created and given generously by God to the disposition of the human being» 59
(and here, indirectly, rizq ﺭﺯﻕreappears again), much has still to be investigated on
the conception of money and credit relations (dayn) in Islamic finance. Metaphorically
58
LE GOFF, La bourse et la vie. Economie et religion au Moyen Age, Paris, 1986; LE GOFF, Le Moyen
Age et l’argent. Essai d’anthropologie historique, Paris, 2010.
59 BRUNSCHVIG, Conceptions monétaires chez les juristes musulmans (VIII-XIII siècles), in
BRUNSCHVIG (ed.), Études d’islamologie, Vol. II, Paris, 1976, 273.
163
VALENTINO CATTELAN
speaking, another voyage through the Mediterranean is certainly needed.
Second, if an alternative conceptualization of risk characterizes Islamic finance, as
this article has tried to highlight, it seems to me that further consideration should be
given to this diverse, while still remarkable, story of risk in financial regulation, too.
In fact, while a plural financial system, where different conceptions of economic
justice(s) co- exist and influence each other,60 may still be distant, it cannot be denied
that a level playing field, where conventional and Islamic finance will be able to coexist and prosper in the same marketplace, will necessarily have to consider how
parameters of capital adequacy and governance for Islamic financial institutions
should be adapted in the light of their peculiar model of risk management, requiring
amendments ad hoc to international standards (e.g., Basel criteria). These adaptations,
far from certifying ‘god’s victory’ over the human story of risk, will foster a fair
competition in a marketplace where Islamic and conventional finance will properly
integrate one aside the other, under the same (God’s) sky.
In the end, if on the one side the remarkable story of risk leads our rationality as
well as imagination to deal with the (un)expected, between gods’ and men’s power,
and in this way «helps define what it means to be a human being» and «how free we
are to make choices»,61 on the other side a comparative study of risk in financial theory
may lead “to alternative perspectives on economic development and social
integration, nourishing […] an open society through the centrality of individual
freedom”.62
And this freedom to choose among alternative financial models may be what the
future story of risk will be about.
60 CATTELAN (ed.), Islamic finance in Europe: towards a plural financial system, Studies in Islamic
Finance, Accounting and Governance, Cheltenham, UK - Northampton, MA, USA, 2013.
61 BERNSTEIN, Against the gods: the remarkable story of risk, cit., 8.
62 CATTELAN, Towards a plural financial system, in CATTELAN (ed.), Islamic finance in Europe:
towards a plural financial system, cit., 232.
164