The Journal of Modem African Studies, ij, 3 (1979), pp. 359-380
The Revolution Betrayed:
Ethiopia, 1974-9
by M I C H A E L C H E G E *
I T is now close to five years since a revolution spearheaded by the
Ethiopian working class, students, and an assortment of petty-bourgeois
elements, overthrew the monarchy of Emperor Haile Selassie I, Elect
of God, King of Kings, and the Conquering Lion of the Tribe of Judah.
With the Emperor has gone the archaic feudal land system which
dominated nearly all aspects of the entire Ethiopian society. Gone too
is the feudal aristocracy and the nascent national bourgeoisie which
clung tenaciously to the imperial coat-tails with unusual political
myopia to the very end.
In has come a self-styled Marxist-Leninist military regime which has
carried out extensive land redistribution to the peasantry, and thereby
delivered the final death-blow to feudalism and the feudal aristocracy
which thrived on it. In 1975 the regime also nationalised major indus-
tries and commercial farms. Although, as we shall see shortly, the
social classes which were in the vanguard of the revolution have been
the pre-eminent victims of military tyranny, this does not in any way
detract from the progressive impact of these measures on Ethiopian
society as a whole.
Ethiopia, of course, differs fundamentally from most African states.
The long history of the core Amhara-Tigre civilisation, with its succes-
sive kingdoms rooted in the feudal mode of production, partly explains
this. The subjugation of nationalities in the periphery of Ethiopia's
central highlands by the Shoan-Amhara nobility is also part of the
explanation. So too is Ethiopia's extremely brief period of colonisation
in the form of the Italian occupation from 1935 to 1941. In the process,
the country experienced an extremely limited level of capitalist achieve-
ment. By nearly every index of social and economic development,
Ethiopia ranks no higher than fifth from the bottom among African
states, yet it is here that the first socialist revolution in the continent has
occurred. The issue becomes essentially one of understanding the social
basis ofrevolution in overwhelmingly agrarian, underdeveloped societies.
* Senior Lecturer in Government and Director of the Diplomacy Training Programme,
University of Nairobi.
0022-278X/79/2828-4160 $02.00© 1979 Cambridge University Press
25-2
360 MICHAEL GHEGE
The outbreak of both the Bolshevik and Chinese revolutions in
largely agrarian and economically backward societies posed questions
of cardinal importance to socialist revolutionary theory and practice.
They forced into the forefront of political debate various issues relating
to the revolutionary potential of the peasantry, the dictatorship of the
proletariat in nations with minimal working classes, the revolutionary
role of progressive intellectuals, the mode of the development of
productive forces under socialism, and so on. For better or for worse,
all this has gone a long way in extending our knowledge of the modalities
of class struggles under revolutionary conditions.
Likewise, Ethiopia's experience provides valuable insights into some
of the most basic issues of contemporary African politics: the revolu-
tionary predisposition of the peasantry; the political inclinations of the
so-called 'labour aristocracy', the national bourgeoisie, the petite bour-
geoisie, and the lumpenproletariat. On top of that, it offers some useful
object-lessons for anyone involved in revolutionary praxis in the Third
World. One needs to understand the full interaction of social forces
which has made this once-popular revolution veer towards a dictator-
ship of the military, turning its most avid adherents into its primary
victims. Ethiopia provides an object lesson on how easily the most noble
revolutionary goals can be betrayed.
Yet, in spite of the unfolding drama of the Ethiopian revolution, and
the very real prospects that something useful could be learnt from it,
Ethiopia's remains the most under-studied revolution of the Third
World. Apart from a few small volumes arising mainly out of direct
personal acquaintance with the revolution, there has been no consistent
class analysis of the revolution.1 In the wake of a full-blown social
upheaval, the field has been left wide open for scholars like Paul
Brietzke to busy themselves with 'land reform' and 'rural development'
which he views as the central policies of the Dirgue? And in the event,
it should be hardly surprising that other scholars have produced a
detailed interdisciplinary study whose sole purpose is to explore ' basic
developmental problems' of the military regime (whose concern is seen
as the 'politics of development'), and to examine the relevance of
'modernisation theories' from Samuel Huntington and his ilk.3
1
John Markakis and Nega Ayele, Class and Revolution in Ethiopia (London, 1978), is in this
author's opinion the best account of the revolution available. See also Heinrich Scholler and
Paul Brietzke, Ethiopia: revolution, law and politics (Munich, 1976), and David and Marina
Ottaway, Ethiopia: Empire in revolution (New York, 1978).
a
Paul Brietzke, 'Land Reform in Revolutionary Ethopia', in The Journal of Modem
African Studies (Cambridge), xiv, 4, December 1976, pp. 637-60.
3
John M. Cohen, Arthur Goldsmith, and John Mellor, Revolution and Land Reform in
Ethiopia, Centre for International Studies, Cornell University, 1976.
THE REVOLUTION BETRAYED: ETHIOPIA, 1974-9 361
But then it hardly matters because such issues are not of any concern
to anyone in Ethiopia, least of all the ruling Dirgue. The two fundamental
issues affecting the momentum of the revolution in Ethiopia are first,
a'determination of which social class shall wield state power, and secondly,
the question of political self-determination of nationalities subjected
over the years to imperial oppression and Amharic feudal chauvinism.
It all bears close resemblance to the Bolshevik experience, but to
understand the social basis of the twin problems it is necessary to explore
the social origins of the revolution in greater detail.
THE SOCIAL BACKGROUND TO THE REVOLUTION
The nature of the social formation in pre-revolution Ethiopia has
been the subject of considerable debate for some time. Margery
Perham argued in 1948 that Ethiopian society could not be character-
ised as feudal because, among other reasons, the nobility had never
managed during many centuries to impose a clear and lasting hegemony
over the peasantry.1 Gene Ellis has recently stated that Ethiopia was
not feudalist because the constituent elements found in Europe -
warrior classes, a hereditary nobility, and vassalage - were either ab-
sent or minimal.2 Others point to the existence of a vast landowning
peasantry in order to counter the feudal argument.
What characterises the feudal mode of production, however, is not
the presence of a uniform set of mediaeval social organisations - these
differed even in Europe - but the fact that the direct producer remains
the 'possessor' of the means of production (land, farming equipment,
etc.). He determines the labour conditions necessary for the production
of his owns means of subsistence, while surplus labour is extracted from
him by non-producer classes, directly through a host of extra-economic
pressures, including force. Surplus extraction takes the form of corvee
labour, tribute, rents, cash, or part of farm produce.
A whole array of political and ideological institutions are at the same
time necessary to reproduce these conditions. Marx himself saw religion
in feudal society as a prime formula for fetishising exploitation by making
it appear to be divinely ordained.3 Coercion and the law have their
special place, too. It is by no means necessary that the organisational
1
Margery Perham, The Government of Ethiopia (London, 1969 edn).
2
Gene Ellis, 'The Feudal Paradigm as a Hindrance to Understanding Ethiopia', in The
Journal of Modem African Studies, xvi, 2, June 1976, pp. 275-95.
• This is what of course leads Nicos Poulantzas to assert that religion as ideology is the
'structure in dominance' in feudal society; Political Power and Social Classes (London, 1975),
362 MICHAEL GHEGE
forms which these social elements take be similar through time and space
to qualify a mode of production as feudal. Indeed, as Jairus Banaji
argues, feudalism is quite consistent even with the preponderance of
peasant holdings over demesne land. 1
This applied to Ethiopia, a country with an extremely complex land-
tenure system. For simplicity, land tenure outside the sparsely populated
pastoralist areas fell under two categories.2 In the northern Tigre-
Amharic provinces, land ownership was vested with the kinship group
under the rist land-tenure system; rist land was seldom alienated and
there was no land market to speak of. The interstices of rist lands were
taken up by imperial land grants to the nobility (known as gult) and
church lands granted in perpetuity to Ethiopia's monophysite Coptic
Church. Both extracted surpluses from the peasantry in tribute, prod-
uce, rents, and services. The classic feudal trinity of nobleman, priest,
and peasant was thus completed.
The second category of land ownership applied principally to the
southern provinces, and had come into force in the last quarter of the
nineteenth century following Menelik IPs conquest of these areas.
Imperial allocation of gult rights to Amharic and other northern
nobility, and the elevation of local balabbat (chiefs) to landlord status,
brought the feudal frontier to the Empire's southern border. It also
turned over 60 per cent of the peasantry into tenants.
The subjugation of the southern peoples by a predominantly Amharic
nobility, and the high premium which the ruling class placed on
Amharic culture in the interests of its own cohesion (even to the extent
of making Amharinya the official language, and the medium of educa-
tional instruction in all schools), helped to make sure that class struggles
would don the mask of ethnic ideologies. The question of oppressed
nationalities was destined to loom large after the revolution. In the
meantime, monarchical despotism would keep it in check.
The political fusion of the interests of landed upper classes with those
of a weak bourgeoisie in predominantly peasant societies is seen by
Barrington Moore as the prime recipe for the emergence of dictatorship.
The configuration of class forces underlying monarchical despotism
under Haile Selassie is almost symmetrical with that observed by Moore
in the French ancien regime:
Up until about the middle of the eighteenth century the modernization
of French society took place through the crown. As part of this process
1
Jairus Banaji, 'The Peasantry in the Feudal Model of Production', in Journal of Peasant
Studies (London), m, 3, 1976.
2
See John Markakis, Ethiopia: anatomy of a traditional polity (London, 1974), pp. 73—140.
THE REVOLUTION BETRAYED: ETHIOPIA, I974-9 363
there grew up a fusion between nobility and bourgeoisie quite different from
that in England. This fusion took place through the monarchy rather than
in opposition to it and resulted, to speak in what may be here a useful if
inaccurate shorthand, in the 'feudalization' of a considerable section of the
bourgeoisie, rather than the other way round.1
Donald Levine depicted the emerging Ethiopian bourgeoisie as a
'new nobility' by virtue of its modern technocratic abilities, use of land
for commercial purposes, and investment in commerce and urban real
estate.2 Yet at the same time, this admittedly small bourgeoisie was
irrevocably beholden to the Emperor and his feudal entourage, while
non-Amharic capitalists - mostly Muslims, Greeks, Arabs, and Italians -
were systematically excluded from state power. Foreign capital - the
dominant fraction of capital - was unquestioningly loyal to the
Emperor.
In France, royal absolutism finally succumbed to a bourgeois
revolution supported by a peasantry trapped between the pressures of
feudalism and an encroaching agrarian capitalism. This was not to be
the case in Ethiopia, where the intrusion of capitalism in the countryside
remained minimal precisely because those class forces which would
have wished to undertake it were held on a tight leash by the feudal
classes. Even when international finance capital intervened to promote
petty commodity production based on family households, it did so on
an extremely limited scale.3 Overall, Marina Ottaway thinks that there
were only about 5,000 large commercial farms covering perhaps
750,000 hectares in Ethiopia as of 1975,4 in a country with an estimated
8*5 million hectares of land under cultivation.
Yet the Ethiopian bourgeoisie did attempt to take up commercial
agriculture as is evidenced by the activities of the Ethiopian Agricul-
tural and Industrial Development Bank. This was particularly so with
coffee, whose small modern plantation sector was dominated entirely
by Ethiopian capitalists.5 This class, however, could not push for the
institution of a land market since, as scions of aristocratic families or
1
J . Barrington Moore Jr., Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy (Boston, 1966), p . 109.
* Donald N . Levine, Wax and Gold: tradition and innovation in Ethiopian culture (Chicago,
1965). PP- 183-90.
• Projects of this kind were not only few, but involved small numbers of peasants. In 1971
the famous Chilalo Agricultural Development Unit had 4,426 tenants, while the World
Bank-supported schemes at Setit Humera and Wollam involved only 500 and 700 familes,
respectively. See Patrick Gilkes, The Dying Lion: feudalism and modernization in Ethiopia (London,
1975). PP- 127-30.
4
Marina Ottaway, 'Social Classes and Corporate Interests in the Ethiopian Revolution',
in The Journal of Modem African Studies, xiv, 3, September 1976, p. 472.
5
See Gilkes, op. cit. pp. 142 and 160-1.
364 MICHAEL CHEGE
beneficiaries of imperial land grants, they had more than enough land
at their disposal. Like the bourgeoisie in Tsarist Russia, they were too
closely identified with feudalism to be its destroyer and thus usher in'a
democratic capitalist regime, as had happened in England. The
Ethiopian bourgeoisie did make an attempt to assume state power
under Endalkatchew Makonnen from February to July 1974, and even
produced a 'classic bourgeois constitution' for the country,1 but they
never came out decisively against landlordism. Against the rising
militancy of the working class and the urban petite bourgeoisie, this
failure proved to be their undoing.
Neither did the peasantry feature as a revolutionary force, contrary
to expectations by Frantz Fanon and others. This owes a lot to the low
development of agrarian capitalism, which left the traditional modes of
existence of the peasantry largely undisrupted. As Eric Wolf has
demonstrated, peasant uprisings in the present century have been
characteristically the business of socially uprooted or semi-proletarian-
ised peasantries.2 In a different historical context, Barrington Moore
has shown how the double pressure of encroaching capitalism and
continued feudal exploitation act in unison to produce peasant rebel-
lions.3 None of these conditions was met in Ethiopia. We have already
shown the small extent of plantation agriculture. Even more striking is
the fact that most of Ethiopia's coffee — the country's largest export
crop - was gathered in its wild state in Kaffa, Illubabor, and Wollega.4
The production of hides and skins, the second largest export commodi-
ties, involved no capitalist enterprises, but rather traditional husbandry.
What is more, the social bonds between the peasantry, the Church, and
the nobility, particularly in the North, had remained strong, unlike in
pre-revolutionary Russia and China.5
Under the circumstances, such peasant resistance as was bound to
occur remained sporadic, short lived, and backward-looking, as most
peasant rebellions tend to be without outside leadership. ' The peasant
Utopia', wrote Wolf, 'is the free village, untrammeled by tax collectors,
labour recruiters, large land-owners and officials. ' 6 Indeed, in Ethiopia
1
Ottaway, loc. cit. p. 479.
2
Eric Wolf, Peasant Wars of the Tiventieth Century (New York, 1969).
* Moore, op. cit. pp. 473-83. * Gilkes, op. cit. p. 141.
5
Barrington Moore, op.cit. p. 469, argues that 'where the links arising out of the rela*
tionship between overlord and peasant community are strong the tendency toward peasant
rebellion (and later revolution) is feeble'. This relationship is predicated on low levels of
material exploitation of the peasantry. For evidence in Ethiopia, see Markakis, op. cit.
pp. 100-2, speaking of the North.
• Wolf, op. cit. p. 294.
THE REVOLUTION BETRAYED: ETHIOPIA, I974-9 365
there is evidence of tax rebellions in Bale in 1964, Gojjam in 1968, and
even riots against eviction by capitalist landlords elsewhere. These,
however, were confined to the narrower frontier of capitalist develop-
ment in the countryside. For the most part, the peasantry remained
politically inert. Nothing illustrates this better than the fact that even
though the 1974 revolution broke against the background of a drought
in which 200,000 peasants perished, there were no attacks on the full
grain-bins of the landords by starving peasants trekking to the cities to
beg for food.1
With the bourgeoisie and the peasantry unable to carry out a
revolution, the mantle fell to the oppressed urban social classes: the
working class, the petite bourgeoisie, and the students.
Poulantzas breaks down the petite bourgeoisie into two class fractions:
the 'old' merges petty capital and personal labour in itself-shop-
keepers, craftsmen, small traders, etc. - while the ' new' is made up of
management, the civil service, and in general the 'intermediate layers'
of both private and public bureaucracies. Characteristically, Poulantzas
traces the unity of the petite bourgeoisie to the ' political and ideological
determination of social classes', thus ruling out a commonality of
objective economic interests.2 Markakis and Ayele observe a unity of
these 'old' and 'new' elements in Ethiopia, but transcend Poulantzas
by tracing this to the marginalisation suffered by both groups at the
hands of more or less the same forces: landlordism, and the big capital-
ists.3 Both fractions of the petite bourgeoisie, for instance, were excluded
from commerical land enterprises at a time when the bourgeois scions
of the aristocracy were increasingly investing in them. The real bene-
ficiaries of small-scale agricultural development projects, such as the
Chilalo Agricultural Development Unit, were in fact not the peasants
but the ' merchants, officials and a small number of the educated petty
bourgeoisie'.4 Yet only with the break-up of feudal land ownership
could more of such projects be undertaken; this explains the zeal with
which land reform was advocated by the petite bourgeoisie, notably the
planners and technocrats in government ministries. In addition, the
inflationary spiral experienced in the 1970s, emanating from both
international and domestic sources, consolidated the unity of this
class, given the elimination of small capital savings which inevitably
accompanies capitalist crises, and the devaluation of earnings of the
' n e w ' petite bourgeoisie.
1
See Martin Meredith's account in the Sunday Times (London), 25 November 1973, p. 8.
1
Nicos Poulantzas, Classes in Contemporary Capitalism (London, 1975), pp. 208-50.
3
Markakis and Ayele, op. cit. pp. 48-54. * Ibid. p. 58.
366 MICHAEL CHEGE
The militancy of the working class is much easier to explain. The
unionisation of labour in Ethiopia became legal as recently as 1963.
Even then, the policy of officially harassing unions with the expressed
view of producing a docile labour force to attract foreign capital con-
tinued in much the same way as it had before. 'In its first seven years',
wrote Markakis, ' CELU [Confederation of Ethiopian Labour Unions]
managed to secure only thirteen collective agreements throughout the
country.' 1 Even worse, in the years immediately preceding the revo-
lution, the scandalously low wages had been severely whittled down by
inflation. The retail price index for Addis Ababa jumped about 30
points between December 1972 and July 1973, with food, clothing, and
household goods leading the way. In the first three months of 1974 -
the most active phase of the revolution - Gilkes estimates that prices
were rising 'uncontrollably at the rate of 80 per cent per quarter'. 2
When the Ethiopian labour force joined the revolutionary fray, it did so
with a sense of radicalism never associated with it at any time in the past.
The task of infusing ideological cohesion into the various petty-
bourgeois and working-class forces fell to students in general, and in
particular to Marxist-Leninist militants at Haile Selassie I University.
Even then, one must reckon that the revolutionary movement remained
largely unco-ordinated and without a recognisable political vanguard. 3
Like so many things in Ethiopia, the class background of the students
in Addis Ababa is difficult to determine. Ottaway argues that from the
mid-1960s on, 'the largest number [of students] at the one University
came from urban families of traders, clerks, policemen, lower-level
government employees - in other words, the Ethiopian petty bourgeoi-
sie'. 4 If so, and in the light of the foregoing analysis of the Ethiopian
petite bourgeoisie, there was clearly a very good reason for their struggle
against the backward landed-class forces which fettered the creation
of productive forces and thus obstructed the development of the
petite bourgeoisie in the process. In fact, given the uncontested fact that
80 per cent of the students were Amhara—Tigre — that is, from areas
where rist family tenure existed - it could be argued that what prompted
their cry 'land to the tiller' was the clear need to draw the southern
peasantry into a political coalition against the landlords. And that is
exactly what happened.
As in the Bolshevik revolution, the final collapse of the Ethiopian
imperial order was signalled by a succession of military mutinies,
1 a
Markakis, op. cit. p. 169. Gilkes, op. cit. p. 169.
3
This was to prove to be the Achilles heel of the revolutionary movement.
4
Ottaway, loc. cit. p. 475.
THE REVOLUTION BETRAYED: ETHIOPIA, I974-9 367
1
popular demonstrations, and industrial unrest. On 12 January 1974
the Fourth Army at Negele mutinied over' trade union '-type grievances,
to be followed the next month by other mutinies at Asmara, Massawa,
Harar, and Addis Ababa. In the meantime, school-teachers went on
strike in mid-February demanding pay increases and the repeal of the
World-Bank inspired 'Education Sector Review'. 2 High-school students
joined the ever-rebellious university students. When the teachers finally
received an audience from the Emperor, they added land reform to
their grievances.
The political action of the 'new' petite bourgeoisie, articulated in this
manner, took place alongside agitation emanating from the 'old'
petite bourgeoisie. Taxi drivers and transporters went on strike in February
to protest against directives that fares should not be increased at a time
when oil prices had tripled. In April 1974, urban Muslims — the
traditional small trader class - staged a demonstration, estimated at
100,000 strong, calling for democratic rights, an end to discrimination
against Muslims and, most important, the right to own land like all other
Ethiopians.
In the previous month, the C.E.L.U. had called a highly effective
general strike, followed by a series of stoppages by workers in public
companies, Addis Ababa municipality, and nearly all public utilities,
even though unionisation was still illegal there. From then on till the
end of May, ' a wave of strikes, boycotts and other types of militant
action paralyzed the public sector, threw the country into a turmoil, and
maintained the momentum of popular movement'. 3
The lame-duck administration of Prime Minister Akillu Habte Wolde
gave way in February 1974 to the bourgeois regime of Endalkatchew
Makonnen with its putative anti-feudal disposition. Hoping to exorcise
the revolutionary spectre with sweet promises of land and constitutional
reforms, the regime watched the upheaval with characteristic political
infirmity. When the Endalkatchew regime resigned in August, it was at
1
The events of this period are summarised in Colin Legum (ed), Africa Contemporary
Record, ig/74-75 (London, 1975), pp. B 160-80.
2
The package of policies proposed in Education: challenge to the nation. Report of the Education
Sector Review (Addis Ababa, Ministry of Education, 1972), posed a further economic threat
to the petite bourgeoisie. They would have restricted secondary and university enrolment,
ostensibly because the absorptive capacity of the state bureaucracy had been exhausted, but
actually in order to siphon more state revenues into capital investment of the sort needed to
prop up the bourgeoisie. Further, the report also called for resources to be channelled into
technical and non-formal education in the countryside in order to boost commodity pro-
duction. That the World Bank should take an interest in this hardly calls for explanation, but
the teachers found it patently objectionable.
* Markakis and Ayele, op. cit. p. 93.
368 MICHAEL CHEGE
the request of a paralysed monarchy dancing to the tunes of the military
- from this moment onwards, in fact, Ethiopia became an armed dic-
tatorship in all but name. By September 1974 the military ascendancy
was secure enough for the soldiers to do away with the Emperor.
One important lesson could be distilled from the course of the
Ethiopian revolution as of then: the social classes involved were small
in absolute and relative terms. This speaks against those who rule out
prospects of rapid structural change in Africa because the would-be
revolutionary classes are small. Markakis estimated that in 1970 thepetite
bourgeoisie - educated administrators, merchants, and officials - totalled
only a 'few tens of thousands' in a society then of 25 million.1 The
working class in 1974 numbered no more that 150,000, about 80,000
of whom were G.E.L.U. members. And amongst the working class, it
was the highly skilled technical and white-collar workers who were
most militant, namely the much maligned 'labour aristocracy' of
African radicalism, frequently presumed to be a trusted ally of inter-
national capital.2 Some, like Ottaway, thought it paradoxical. In fact,
that this was the case ought to have come as no surprise to anyone
conversant with Marxian analysis of exploitation, and the inevitable
devaluation of labour power among skilled workers which comes with
the advance of capitalism.3
CLASS AND STATE POWER
'The key question of every revolution', Lenin wrote, 'is undoubtedly
the question of state power: which class holds power which decides
everything'. 4 In Ethiopia this fundamental question was already at the
forefront in August 1974 when the military, as one fraction of the
petite bourgeoisie, took advantage of the vacuum created by the lack of a
1
Markakis, op. cit. p. 182.
2
Though old in socialist literature, the African variant of this view owes much to Frantz
Fanon. It was elaborated in 1967 by Giovanni Arrighi, 'International Corporations, Labor
Aristocracies, and Economic Development in Tropical Africa', in Arrighi and John S. Saul
(eds.), Essays on the Political Economy 0/Africa (New York, 1973), pp. 105-51.
3
Ottaway, loc. cit. expresses the 'paradox' that it was white-collar and skilled workers
who were most militant. The rate of exploitation of labour is expressed as the ratio between
surplus value and variable capital (in short, wages). By this formula skilled labour produces
value many more times than its counter value. The ratio is lower for unskilled labour. Hence
skilled labour is more exploited. See Geoffrey Kay, Development and Underdevelopment (London,
1975), p. 54. For observations of similar exploitation and militancy among skilled agricultural
workers and bank employees in Kenya, see Michael Cowen and Kabiru Kinyanjui, Some
Problems of Capital and Class in Kenya, Occasional Paper No. 26, Institute for Development
Studies, University of Nairobi, 1977, pp. 32-55.
4
V. I.Lenin, 'On the Fundamental Questions of the Revolution', in Collected Works
(Moscow, 1972 edn.), Vol. 25, p. 366.
THE REVOLUTION BETRAYED: ETHIOPIA, I974-9 369
revolutionary organisation and imposed itself at the vanguard of the
movement. When Haile Selassie was led from the Imperial Palace on
12 September 1974 to the simple house where he eventually died, it
was by the soldiers, not by an organised vanguard of militants like the
pro-Bolshevik Petrograd Soviet of 1917.
It was the Co-ordinating Committee of the Armed Forces (the
Dirgue), slowly edging into power since the mutinies early in the year,
which arrested, prosecuted, judged, and executed leading members of
the nobility and the bourgeoisie, most notably in the massacres of 22—24
November 1974. It was as if General Kornilov's attempted coup d'itat
in September 1917 had succeeded in toppling Kerensky and suppressing
the Bolsheviks. Indeed, had the Ethiopian Marxist intelligentsia pon-
dered the fate of Kornilov at the hands of the Petrograd Soviet, they
would have done more to organise a proletarian constituency in
the capital. As it was, the Ethiopian People's Revolutionary Party
(E.P.R.P.) which was best placed to do this, only fought ideologically
through its newspaper, Democracia, in the underground without overt
mobilisation. Other radical elements preferred to school the new rulers
in Marxism-Leninism, oblivious of the fact that the idea of the military
as a vanguard for social change had more to do with Morris Janowitz
than either Marx or Lenin.
Although the Dirgue was from 1975 onwards to parade itself to the
outside world as the champion of Marxism-Leninism in Africa, it is
vital to remember that its coup d'itat was based on a solid bourgeois
and nationalist platform, epitomised in its slogan Ethiopia Tikdem, or
'Ethiopia First'. In his initial public speech on this new policy, Colonel
Mengistu Haile Mariam explained that it called for an end to selfish-
ness, with the emphasis now on hard work, unity, diligence, heroism,
and love for country. 1 Jomo Kenyatta, south of the border, leading a
solid bourgeois regime, couched his speeches in almost exactly such
terms. True to form, the Dirgue had on 16 September 1974 declared its
policy as anti-capitalist and anti-Marxist, a position that Mobutu and
Senghor, among others, have also espoused.
The Dirgue, it must be remembered, took unto itself the task of
destroying what it called the 'feudal-bourgeois' order only after the two
civilian Premiers it had given the task of instituting a bourgeois govern-
ment had failed. Even as late as March 1975, the Dirgue was still toying
with the idea of a constitutional monarchy and the preservation of
church estates.
1
See Africa Contemporary Record, 1974-5, PP- B 188-9.
370 MICHAEL CHEGE
In February 1975 the Dirgue took the 'socialist' measure of national-
ising 101 leading companies. Hardly different from what several
African capitalist regimes have done, this involved in some cases out-
right acquisition of firms but in most cases partial government owner-
ship and government - i.e. military - participation in management.
For the moment, the much debated worker committees would have to
be shelved. In April, the Dirgue decreed the abolition of land rents, and
' nationalised' all rural land, declaring this to be the ' collective property
of Ethiopian people'. Individual families were granted 'possessory
rights' over rural land not exceeding 25 acres, and one urban house. In
effect, this 'nationalisation' measure only served to confirm the rist
family-holdings in the North, and to restore peasant land-holder rights
in the South. With all its intonations of collective effort, the profound
accent of the 1975 land reform proclamation lay in its emphasis on
expanded peasant production to serve as a basis for industrialisation.1
All this is part and parcel of the philosophical underpinning of most
African regimes. What made Ethiopia special is that the feudal class
had to be destroyed for this to happen. The men responsible for
this traditionally bourgeois mission were the putative revolutionaries
in uniform. The Dirgue will be remembered in history for having com-
mitted the infamous act of carrying out a capitalist revolution in the
name of Marxism and, even worse, for having destroyed Ethiopian
socialists in the name of socialism. For, having eliminated feudal and
bourgeois power on the right, the military now trained their guns to the
left.
Confronted by denial of democratic rights, wage freezes, continuing
inflation, and exhortations to support ZhVgae-appointed managements,
labour under the C.E.L.U. took to the streets against the Dirgue
(particularly in September 1975) as it had under the ancien regime. This
time, however, the demonstrations were not to work. The C.E.L.U.
had not heeded Trotsky's maxim:
In order to conquer power, the proletariat needs more than a spontaneous
insurrection. It needs a suitable organization, it needs a plan, it needs a
conspiracy. Such is the Leninist view of this question.2
The price the proletariat paid for this neglect was its own destruction as
a political force. With the leadership of the C.E.L.U. largely emascu-
lated by detention and assassination, the Dirgue moved to dismantle what
1
According to the Proclamation to Provide for the Public Ownership of Rural Lands,
No. 31 of 1975, p. 94, 'it is necessary to distribute land, increase rural income, and thereby
lay the basis for the expansion of industry and the growth of the economy by providing for
the participation of the peasantry in the national market'.
a
Leon Trotsky, The History of the Russian Revolution (Ann Arbor, 193a), Vol. m, p. 170.
THE REVOLUTION BETRAYED: ETHIOPIA, I974~9 37I
was still a militant labour movement in late 1975, but not before the
soldiers had shot dead some protesting workers.1 In place of the C.E.L.U.,
the Dirgue substituted another of its repressive arms: the All-Ethiopian
Trade Union. The cycle of violence was completed when the new
A.E.T.U. leaders were assassinated by workers and militants protesting
against the policies of the Dirgue? The greatest irony of all lay in the
massacre of an estimated 600-1,000 workers and students preceding
and following the 1977 May Day demonstrations.3
The political forces of the radical intelligentsia proved more durable
than those of the working class, but they too in the end had to give way
to armed repression more ferocious than that experienced by the
working class.
By late 1975, when it became clear that the Dirgue had no intention of
handing over power to civilians, the intelligentsia split into two camps:
the Meison (All-Ethiopian Socialist Movement) and the Ethiopian
People's Revolutionary Party (E.P.R.P.). Popular interpretations of the
first as a pro-Soviet and European-trained organisation, and the latter
as Maoist and American-educated, out to be dismissed for the analytical
incantations which they are. The Meison grouped together 'many sons
and daughters of former aristocratic families who had spent years in
exile', thoroughly alienated by the decadence of the feudal regime.4
Though calling themselves Marxists, they were prepared to countenance
a military dictatorship which clamped down on all democratic rights
and suppressed the working class violently. This they did on the
spurious grounds that the oppressed classes in Ethiopia lacked organisa-
tional and political sophistication to carry on the revolution, which
only the military had. The Meison leaders imagined that as the ' Marxist'
ideological mentors of the Dirgue, they could tele-guide the revolution
to a point where they could control the state bureuacracy, relegating
the military to the barracks.5 Hence the zealous work on political
1
On 26 September 1975, the military shot seven Ethiopian Airline workers and wounded
43 others for protesting against the arrest of union leaders detained for distributing anti-
Dirgue literature. More than 500 Airline employees were detained in this incident. The reac-
tionary use to which' labour aristocracy' theories can be put is illustrated by the official plea
that these workers were a 'privileged caste' after all.
• For the Dirgue's admission that the C.E.L.U. had become infiltrated by E.P.R.P.
militants and so-called 'non-conformist' petty bourgeois leadership, see Ethiopian Herald
(Addis Ababa), 27 April 1977, p. 5, and Africa (London), April 1977, p. 12.
3
Markakis and Ayele, op. cit. p. 168.
4
Colin Legum (ed.), Africa Contemporary Record, 1976-7 (London, 1977), p. B180.
6
In a sense, therefore, the Meison would have completed the capitalist class mission
undertaken by the Dirgue and 'rationalised' government in the Weberian sense, something
quite consistent with their class origins. The Meison sought to succeed where their parents
had failed, but, like the military, in the name of Marx.
372 MICHAEL GHEGE
education by the Meison at the Provisional Office for Mass Organisation
Affairs, and the Yekatit '66 Ideological School.1 When the Dirgue woke
up to this strategy in August 1977, it reacted in characteristic fashion
by meting out ' revolutionary justice' (which simply means murder) to
at least 60 Meison functionaries. The head of the movement, Haile Fida,
was jailed (and is now presumed dead), while other leaders fled to exile.
In contrast, the E.P.R.P. was not only the first modern political party
in Ethiopia, but also the only genuine Marxist-Leninist organisation.
Having been forced to operate underground since its inception in 1972,
the E.P.R.P. has been the object of much vilification at the hands of the
Dirgue, as well as by western and eastern news media.2 Recruited from
urban intellectuals and workers, the party has roots that go back to the
anti-monarchy Marxist cells organised in the 1960s. From August 1975,
the E.P.R.P. carried out a determined campaign for a 'National
Democratic Revolution' that would permit the political participation
of all organisations opposed to feudalism and exploitation. It also
advocated the granting of all democratic rights to the masses.
Taking the promised 'National Democratic Programme' of the
Dirgue for the dead letter that it was, the E.P.R.P. was driven to take
up arms against the Dirgue in September 1976, after the military had
declared 'total war' on the E.P.R.P., which had successfully infiltrated
the labour movement and peasant associations. In December 1977,
diplomats in Addis Ababa were reporting gun battles between the
E.P.R.P. and the Dirgue 'lasting for some hours at a time in the past
months \ 8 Driven to desperation, the Dirgue ushered in its notorious' Red
Terror' campaign, giving itself and its sponsored gangs unrestricted
licence to murder any suspected E.P.R.P. member or sympathiser.
The E.P.R.P. responded by the calculated assassination of members of
the Dirgue, as well as Meison leaders and sympathisers. A bloodbath
ensued - indeed, according to an eyewitness report in March 1978,
the streets were littered with bodies.4 By the end of the year the E.P.R.P.
was finished as a political force, although by no means physically
annihilated. As bourgeois commentators love to say, 'the revolution
devours its own children'. In this case, however, it looks as if the
Dirgue's reign of terror devoured the children of the revolution. And in
1
The institutions were set up by the Dirgue under the May 1976 ' Programme for National
Democratic Revolution', another hollow promise to involve the masses in politics.
* For some useful information, see Markakis and Ayele, op. cit. pp. 154-5 an -d 162-5; a^so
Africa Contemporary Record, igj6-j, pp. B 185-7. T h e E.P.R.P.'s political programme is spelt
out in their information bulletin, Abyot, Special Issue, February 1978.
* Daily Nation (Nairobi), 12 December 1977.
* Hans Eerik, The Times (London), 22 March 1978, p. 1.
THE REVOLUTION BETRAYED: ETHIOPIA, 1974-9 373
the process, it must be remarked, the Dirgue received ample assistance
from those self-confessed friends of the African revolution: the Soviets
and the Cubans.
In his pamphlet, What is to be Done?, Lenin delineated the respective
roles in a socialist revolution of, on the one hand, professional revolu-
tionaries drawn from 'the young generation of educated classes', and
the working classes on the other. 1 In Ethiopia, the Dirgue had on the
contrary eliminated the revolutionary intelligentsia and suppressed the
working class in the name of Marxism-Leninism. In the face of this
gigantic blasphemy it should surprise no one that the military Govern-
ment proceeded to build its power on social classes (and in a manner)
that neither Marx nor Lenin would have approved. The Dirgue began
by arming urban kebeles - associations composed of illiterate members
of the lumpenproletariat - which survived by extracting surpluses in cash
or kind at gunpoint, much like Idi Amin's Nubian mercenaries,
including part of the rents collected from nationalised houses. Corrupt,
undisciplined, and undisciplinable, the urban kebeles came to be dreaded
by the population for their unrestrained terror: they were used by the
Dirgue to exterminate the E.P.R.P. and radical youth who were in
favour of a popular democratic revolution.2
In the countryside, the regime increasingly came to rely upon the
support of those with medium-sized landholdings. Although the evidence
is sketchy, it seems that they dominated the newly created 'peasant
associations' under the aegis of the All-Ethiopian Peasant Movement.3
Yet this is the class which had played the most counter-revolutionary
role against the dissolution of small estates in the land redistribution
campaign of 1975. When the military sent students into the countryside
under the zemecha campaign in 1974 to implement the land reform
programme, they encountered the stiffest resistance from this latter-
day Ethiopian version of the Vendee.* Most landords had fled. At
another level, all peasants rich and poor, though united in breaking
up feudal estates, were opposed to land collectivisation which zemecha
1
V. I. Lenin, 'What is to be Done?', in Collected Works (Moscow, 1972 edn.), Vol. v.
2
Africa, March 1978, p. 26; and Eerik, loc. cit. This tallies with Marx's doubts about the
lumpenproletariat as a revolutionary force, a point raised in the African context by Robin
Cohen and David Michael, 'The Revolutionary Potential of the African Lumpenproletariat:
a sceptical view', in Sussex: I.D.S. Bulletin (Brighton), v, 2/3, October 1973, pp. 31-42.
a
Cohen, Goldsmith, and Mellor, op. cit. pp. 47-8.
4
Ibid. pp. 61 and 65. This was mostly in the South. In the North no substantial changes
were made to traditional family landholdings. Yet even there overt hostility to anything
amounting to collectivisation or break-up of holdings was evident. See Markakis and Ayele,
op. cit. pp. 26-7.
26 MOA
374 MICHAEL CHEGE
1
actively promoted. Like the Russian peasants who claimed they were for
the Bolsheviks who allocated them land, but against the Communists who
forced them to collectivise, so too in Ethiopia. When peasant resistance
on both fronts against students erupted into violence leaving many of
them dead, the Government put a halt to the campaign, leaving the
'middle peasantry' - and even some of the former landlords - dominant
in the countryside, notwithstanding land allocation to former tenants.
The effectiveness of peasant associations remained eccentric and
highly uneven. They most certainly did not endear themselves to the
peasantry by assuming the role of tax collector and land-fee gatherer
for the Government.2 On top of that, the attempt to mobilise peasants
for the war in Eritrea in mid-1976 was a monumental debacle in which
thousands of ill-prepared soldiers fell to the bullets of well-trained Eri-
trean guerrillas.8 There is, so far as one can tell, no evidence of any battle
won by the largely peasant 90,000-strong People's Militia recruited in
1977, though there are incidents of mutiny and indiscipline.4
On the political role of the peasantry, T. Shanin comments that 'in
the long run it is the basic weaknesses of the peasantry which have
tended to stand out'. This class has proved no match for smaller,
closely knit, better organised, technically superior groups and has,
time and again, been 'double-crossed' or suppressed politically by
force of arms.5 In Ethiopia, the peasants had been used by practically
all of the leading protagonists: the military, the students, the E.P.R.P.,
the counter-revolutionary landlords and bandits, and even by the most
reactionary ethnic movements. In the end, the peasants could not sway
the destiny of the revolution, much less that of their own.
THE NATIONAL QUESTION
In the course of it all, the only social class to have gone politically
and economically unmolested was the petite bourgeoisie; indeed, the
conditions for its prosperity in both the towns and the countryside had
been secured.6 The contradiction in the policy lay in that, by regenera-
1
Ibid. pp. 69-72.
a
A portion of which (like the urban kebeles) they retained.
3
For a graphic account of this debacle, see Africa Contemporary Record, 1976-7, pp. B 196-7.
* Mew African Development (London), February 1978, p. 24. According to Africa, March
1978, 80,000 members of the militia were deployed in the Ogaden against the Western
Somali Liberation Front. As everyone knows, the Ethiopian army, let alone the peasants,
were unable to halt the Somali advance - it took the Cubans and the Soviets to do this.
6
T. Shanin, The Awkward Class (Oxford, 1972), p. 124.
6
Dirgue policies in 1975 also included substantial 'Ethiopianisation' of small businesses
previously run by foreigners. About 30,000 posts in the nationalised industries under Ethiopian
management had been created. See Markakis and Ayele, op. cit. pp. 128-9.
THE REVOLUTION BETRAYED: ETHIOPIA, 1974-9 375
ting the petite bourgeoisie, the regime also regenerated the traditional
Amharic dominance in this class. This was fiercely resisted by petty
bourgeois elements from other nationalities which now married their
forces with those of discontented peasantries in their own homelands;
a marriage made all too easy by the petty bourgeois orientation of the
peasantry which Lenin observed over six decades ago. The offspring of
this political marriage of forces was the proliferation of ethnic move-
ments seeking autonomy from Amharic domination or bidding for
outright secession. Apart from the determination of the class basis of
power, this constituted the most intractable problem for the Ethiopian
revolution.
On this score nowhere was the regime tested as severely as in Eritrea.
This region fell from the frying pan of Italian colonialism during 1941
into the fire of Amharic feudal domination in 1952, and was finally
absorbed in the Empire in 1962. The Eritrea petite bourgeoisie, a product
of Italian capitalist development, was completely locked out of power
by feudalism. Appealing to the nationalist instincts of the peasants, it
finally determined to mobilise them for guerrilla war. Colonialism had
destroyed feudal structures in Eritrea much earlier than in other parts
of the Empire, giving it a proportionately larger petite bourgeoisie, labour
force, and landless peasantry. It was natural, therefore, that anti-feudal
resistance should have begun there. Even though it has not been easy
to reconcile the interests of the Muslim 'lowland' petite bourgeoisie
grouped under the Eritrean Liberation Front (E.L.F.), with those of
the Christian 'highland' petite bourgeoisie under the Eritrean People's
Liberation Front (E.P.L.F.), both movements had liberated 95 per cent
of the Eritrean countryside by late 1977. They also held all the major
towns in Eritrea with the exception of the capital, Asmara, and the port
of Massawa, which were then under siege.
As if that was not a sufficient problem for the military Government
in Ethiopia, Somali pastoralists under the Western Somali Liberation
Front (W.S.L.F.), with assistance from the Somali army, swept the
Ogaden during September-October 1977, capturing the railway town
ofJigjiga and threatening Harar and Dire Dawa, a mere 60 kilometres
from Addis Ababa. At the same time there were at least three separatist
movements among the Oromo, the second largest ethnic group in the
country, largely based in the South, two in Tigre and one each among
the Afars and the Somali-Abo. 1 During 1977, in fact, theDirgue faced
1
Under the ancien regime, the Oromo aristocracy (often Amharicised) supported the
Emperor. P. T. W. Baxter, a self-confessed advocate of Oromo nationalism, traces its roots
to the politically and economically side-lined Oromo petite bourgeoisie: military officers, civil
26-2
376 MICHAEL CHEGE
localised ethnic rebellions in eight out of its 14 provinces, and in all
cases responded with force. Against the backdrop of the regime's
internal contradictions, Ahmed Nasser of the Eritrean Liberation
Front was justified in commenting that Mengistu was 'wrestling with
the wind'. 1
The Bolsheviks, too, were confronted with the political assertiveness
of nationalities long oppressed by Tsardom and subjected to Russifica-
tion, in the same way that Amharisation had been forced upon various
Ethiopian peoples. Rather than wrestle with the wind, however, Lenin
settled for the principle of national self-determination for oppressed
nationalities, and this has become the standard Marxist-Leninist stand
on the issue,2 though honoured more in the breach than in observance,
as in Ethiopia's case.
To begin with, Lenin was opposed to the fragmentation of the big
states, because they afforded 'indisputable advantages, both from the
standpoint of economic progress and that of the interests of the massess'.
Lenin, however, believed that genuine democracy could only take root
in Russia after the oppressed non-Russian nationalities had been
granted full citizenship rights and their territories given the opportunity
to become politically autonomous or to secede, if they so wished.
National movements could therefore be supported on two grounds:
first, when they arose against backward, reactionary, and imperialist
forces (even if such national movements happened to be bourgeois);
secondly, where they served to promote democracy within the framework
of socialist transformation.
Although the Ethiopian Government's 'Programme for National
Democratic Revolution' of April 1976 contained firm guarantees for
national self-determination, the principle remained a dead letter (just
like the proletarian party which it has repeatedly promised). Instead,
the Dirgue gave every national movement - progressive or reactionary -
the choice between 'fatherland or death'. Having arrogated unto itself
the role of the bourgeoisie, the military was determined to carry this
to its logical conclusion: the building of a strong centralised state to
serve as a market for expanded capitalist production and trade. Thus
it was vital to retain Eritrea, where a third of the country's manufac-
servants, students, and politicians. See his 'Ethiopia's Unacknowledged Problem: the
Oromo', in African Affairs (London), 77, 103, 1978, p. ago.
1
New African Development, December 1977, p . 1185.
1
V. I. Lenin, "The Right of Nations to Self-Determination', in Collected Works, Vol. xx,
pp. 393-454, and "The Socialist Revolution and Right of Nations to Self-Determination',
in ibid. Vol. xxn, pp. 143-56.
THE REVOLUTION BETRAYED: ETHIOPIA, I974~9 377
turing plants were situated, as well as the outlying pastoral areas, the
tapping of whose potential was already on the drawing boards.
In contrast it was the E.P.R.P., true to the Leninist position on the
national question, which managed to build an alliance with progressive
national movements, like the Marxist E.P.L.F. in Eritrea, the Tigre
People's Liberation Front (T.P.L.F.), and the Oromo People's Libera-
tion Organisation. The bonds which united these organisations at war
against the Dirgue only became unstuck with mounting evidence in
1978 that the Ethiopian People's Revolutionary Party had no chance
of assuming state power, at which juncture the T.P.L.F. assumed an
ethnic stand against the 'Amharic' E.P.R.P. in order to make itself
credible to the Tigre peasants.1 By annihilating the E.P.R.P., the Dirgue
also eliminated the prospects of any progressive solution to the national
question.
As a result, the national movements which held out longest were those
of a reactionary variety, the Eritrean People's Liberation Front being
the only possible exception. Nearly all of them appealed to the tradi-
tional peasant (or pastorialist) animosity to Amharic hegemony, and
this swelled their numbers handsomely. In the process, the peasantry
became the political cannon-fodder for ethnic counter-revolutionary
movements which had as little patience for the Dirgue as they had for
its Marxist opponents.2 In its heyday (1976-7) the Ethiopian Democratic
Union (E.D.U.) under the nobleman Ras Mengesha Seyoum, managed
to draw large peasant support from Tigre, Begemdir, and Siemen, often
under traditional command. By another account, 'Wallo peasants
joined the traditional ruler of Lasta [Lalibela] Dejaz-match Berhane
Maskal Desta' in arms.8 In the East, Afar nomads under the command
of the son of their deposed Sultan, Ali Mirrah, engaged in anti-
government banditry. Although the military regime could keep such
1
On the declaration of war on all Amharas by the supposedly 'Marxist' Tigre People's
Liberation Front, see E.P.R.P. News Release, a2 May 1978. Previously the T.P.L.F. and the
E.P.R.P. had fought jointly against the Dirgue.
1
Lenin was aware of this danger and hence the need for village Soviets and mechanisation
of agriculture to prevent the poor peasant becoming a follower of kulak opportunism. Gramsci
also saw the danger posed by newly liberated peasantry: ' I t [land] satisfied for the first
moment his [peasant's] primitive greed for land; but at the next moment when he realized
that his own arms are not enough to break up the soil which only dynamite can break up,
when he realizes that seeds are needed and fertilizers and tools, and thinks of the future
series of days and nights to be spent on a piece of land without a house, without water, with
malaria, the peasant realizes his own impotence...and becomes a brigand and not a revolu-
tionary, becomes an assassin of the gentry, not a fighter for workers' and peasants' commu-
nism.' Quoted in James Joll, Gramsci (London, 1977), p. 69. [This seems true of Ethiopia
where the regime had proved incapable of providing seeds or equipment to the peasants,
something rich peasants and even former landlords exploited to the fullest.]
• African Contemporary Record, 1976-7, p . BI8O.
378 MICHAEL CHEGE
movements at bay by armed force, it was quite evident by 1977 that the
soldiers were incapable of achieving victory in Eritrea and the Ogaden.
Having been caught in a trap of its own making, the Dirgue was forced
to depend heavily on Soviet fire power and Cuban soldiers. In the
process, the regime proclaimed its Marxist-Leninist character even
louder, it actions to the contrary notwithstanding.
CONCLUSION
The social forces behind the overthrow of the monarchy in 1974 had
the vision of a democratic future devoid of feudal backwardness and
oppression. Whether it was possible to proceed from there to a socialist
transformation of society was rendered entirely academic by the rise of
a military dictatorship reminiscent of Bonapartism, devoid of any
popular class base, and beholden to the Soviet Union. The ideals
animating the revolution of 1974 had been betrayed.
After 1975, the dominant faction of the Dirgue tried to carry out a
capitalist revolution in a land without capitalists. Historically this
mission has involved the destruction of seigneurial power, the re-
distribution and even nationalisation of land, 1 the creation of a central-
ised administration (as exemplified in Ethiopia by ' peasant associations',
and wars against secession), and industrialisation. As we have seen, the
military rode to power on the crest of a popular Marxist-influenced
uprising. For this reason it had to maintain a fagade of Marxist
rhetoric even as it was eliminating Marxists and brutalising labour.
From the 'right' the threat of a bourgeois-landlord counter-revolution,
supported by factions of the military, still loomed large. This is what
prompted the massacres of November 1974 in which the Chairman of
the Provincial Military Administrative Council, General Aman Andom,
was killed. So too with the elimination of the Head of State, Teferi
Benti, in February 1977, the assassination of the Dirgue Vice-Chairman,
Atnafu Abate, in November of the same year, and the liquidation of one
half of the original 120 members of the Dirgue. Try as hard as it could,
the Dirgue - or what remained of it - could not muster a popular
domestic base.2 External support became a must.
1
On the break-up of feudal estates in Russia, see V. I. Lenin, 'The Agrarian Question in
Russia', in Collected Works, Vol. xx, p. 376: 'Marx amply proved that bourgeois economists
often demanded nationalization of land, i.e. conversion of all land into public property, and
that this measure was a. fully bourgeois measure. Capitalism will develop more widely, more
freely and more quickly under such a measure.'
1
A lot of official propaganda centred on three 'clandestine' but officially sanctioned
'Marxist parties': S.E.D.E.D., M.A.L.E.R.I.D., and W.A.S.L.E.A.G.U.E. These were, in
fact, little more than acronyms for bureaucratic cliques and cabals; S.E.D.E.D., for example,
THE REVOLUTION BETRAYED: ETHIOPIA: I974-9 379
When Colonel Mengistu Haile Mariam arrived at the Kremlin in
the spring of 1977, he must have been fully aware of this brutal fact.
What the military Government needed were two things: armed force
to suppress domestic class opponents and national movements, and capital
investment. W'hile the U.S. had proved amenable to providing military
equipment and capital to the Ethiopian Government (even with the
knowledge of internal repression), it could not - after Vietnam - provide
military assistance to subdue national guerrilla movements. But the
Soviet Union could. Hence the Soviet-Cuban blitzkrieg against the
Somalis in the Ogaden during March 1978, and the military occupation
of all the towns in Eritrea by March 1979. In the cities, red terror
needed red armaments to triumph.
After this, the military became increasingly preoccupied with the
development of state capitalism. The exhortation to extract maximum
output (i.e. surplus value) in the industrial sector came daily from the
state-controlled media. The regime's biggest economic headache, how-
ever, was the sagging productivity in agriculture. On the fourth
anniversary of the revolution, Colonel Mengistu criticised the peasantry
for not producing enough for the market, and also for hoarding. At any
rate, international finance capital was already penetrating peasant
small-holdings and pastoralism the same way it had in Kenya, Tanzania,
and elsewhere.1 In the nationalised state farms, the doubling of pro-
duction was being demanded in March 1979, and managers were
advised to restrict their bank credit and 'to rigidly control special
benefits and overtime pay for workers'.2 Soviet expertise and credit
were being used to extend state farms,3 because the regime's biggest con-
cern was to expand agricultural production under state control. Which-
ever way one looked at it, this was the development of capitalism in the
long run at the expense of the peasantry.
With regard to this, nothing really distinguished the Provisional
Military Administrative Council from other highly bureaucratised
regimes in history which have carried out industrialisation and moder-
nised agriculture, except the degree of repression and the extermination of
the revolutionary intelligentsia. More young revolutionaries died under
the Dirgue than during the regime of Haile Selassie. Those like Peter
was known as 'Mengistu's own party'. Refugees from Addis Ababa in April 1979 reported
dozens of W.A.S.L.E.A.G.U.E. members slain in these inter-clique struggles in December
1978. For an official and timid view of these events, see Africa, April 1979, p. 43.
1
See, for instance, the particulars of the $24 million I.D.A. loan reported in Nairobi
Times, 7 May 1978.
* The Standard, 20 March 1979.
1
According to ibid. 18 April 1979, the U.S.S.R. lent Ethiopia the equivalent of U.S.
$85 million to purchase Soviet equipment and expertise for agricultural mechanisation.
380 MICHAEL CHEGE
Schwab who argue that there had to be oppression for the revolution
to triumph,1 pity the plumage but forget the dying bird. Mao may
indeed have taught us that 'the revolution is not a dinner party', but
he also meant that the revolution is not a coup d'etat, particularly aimed
against the most progressive forces in society who sacrificed so much in
the hope of a better life.
1
See Peter Schwab, 'Human Rights in Ethiopia', in The Journal of Modern African Studies,
xrv, 1, March 1976, pp. 155-60.