A Matching Model of the Academic Publication Market
Radu Vranceanu, Damien Besancenot, Kim Van Huynh
To cite this version:
Radu Vranceanu, Damien Besancenot, Kim Van Huynh. A Matching Model of the Academic Publication Market. 2010, 19 p. hal-00554710
HAL Id: hal-00554710
https://essec.hal.science/hal-00554710v1
Submitted on 11 Jan 2011
HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access
archive for the deposit and dissemination of scientific research documents, whether they are published or not. The documents may come from
teaching and research institutions in France or
abroad, or from public or private research centers.
L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est
destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents
scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non,
émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de
recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires
publics ou privés.
Document de Recherche ESSEC / ISSN : 1291-9616
Il est interdit de reproduire ce document ou d'en citer des extraits
sans l'autorisation écrite des auteurs.
It is forbidden to quote all or part of this document without the written consent of the authors.
- DR 10003 -
A Matching Model of the Academic Publication Market
Damien BESANCENOT*, Kim HUYNH**, Radu VRANCEANU***
February 2010
CEPN and Université Paris 13, Villetaneuse, France. E-mail: besancenot.damien@univ-paris13.fr
LEM and Université Paris 2, Paris, France. E-mail: kim.besancenot@univ-paris2.fr
*** ESSEC Business School, PB 50150, 95021 Cergy, France. E-mail: vranceanu@essec.fr
*
**
A Matching Model of the Academic Publication Market
ABSTRACT:
Given the myriad of journal titles in economics and business administration, scholars can sometimes
target the wrong journal. This paper provides a dynamic analysis of the market for academic publications
that brings into the picture this type of informational friction. The key modelling device is a paper-tojournal matching function, similar to the matching function traditional in labor economics. An
equilibrium is defined as a situation where both editors and authors implement their optimal publication
strategies. The model is then solved for the equilibrium submission fee, desk rejection rate and ratio
between the number of editors and the number of authors.
Key-Words:
- Academic Journals
- Editors
- Imperfect Information
- Matching
RESUME :
L'article propose un modèle d'appariement pour étudier le fonctionnement du marché des publications
académiques. Il permet d'analyse le phénomène de "desk-rejection" et propose une explication pour la
montée en puissance de droits de soumission d'articles.
Mots-clés :
- Appariement
- Editeurs
- Information imparfaite
- Revues académiques
JEL classification : C78, A14
February 12, 2010
A MATCHING MODEL
OF THE ACADEMIC PUBLICATION MARKET
Damien Besancenot, Kim Huynhy, Radu Vranceanuz
Abstract
Given the myriad of journal titles in economics and business administration, scholars can sometimes target
the wrong journal. This paper provides a dynamic analysis of the market for academic publications that
brings into the picture this type of informational friction. The key modelling device is a paper-to-journal
matching function, similar to the matching function traditional in labor economics. A equilibrium is
de…ned as a situation where both editors and authors implement their optimal publication strategies. The
model is then solved for the equilibrium submission fee, desk rejection rate and ratio between the number
of editors and the number of authors.
Keywords: Academic journals, Matching, Editors, Desk-rejection, Imperfect information.
JEL Classi…cation: C78, A14.
CEPN and Université Paris 13, Villetaneuse, France. E-mail: besancenot.damien@univ-paris13.fr
y LEM
and Université Paris 2, Paris, France. E-mail: kim.besancenot@univ-paris2.fr
z ESSEC
Business School, 95021 Cergy, France. E-mail: vranceanu@essec.fr.
1
Introduction
The publication market can be de…ned as the place where scholars supply and editors demand
academic papers. An important characteristic of this market is the huge ‡ows of papers written,
submitted, revised and rejected every year, ultimately leading to a relatively small number of
papers published. In the last twenty years, driven by a stronger institutional race for top research
positions in the now ubiquitous rankings, the number of scholars committed to research and the
number of submitted papers have increased dramatically (Bence and Oppenheim, 2004; Frey,
2009). For instance, the Editor Report 2010 of the American Economic Review states that the
number of submissions to the journal has increased from 641 in 1980 to 1398 in 2009 (for a stable
number of published papers).1
In turn, this change in volumes brought about several signi…cant changes in the organization of
the publication market: …rstly, the number of journal titles has also increased, but at a smaller pace
than the number of submitted papers, leading to higher congestion. Secondly, while twenty years
ago almost no economic journal charged submission fees, these days submission fees are almost
generalized; they vary from modest amounts to quite substantial ones (some journals require now
submission fees as high as 250 $). Some authors have pointed out that editors would resort to
submission fees only to deter authors of low quality papers from submitting their work to their
journal (Leslie, 2005; Azar, 2006).2
Thirdly, more and more journals are implementing "desk-
rejection procedures", according to which the editor can decide to turn down a paper without
sending it to referees, if he considers that the paper does not …t to the aim and scope of the
journal (or that the paper is really poorly written). The standard rationale is clearly stated in
the Editor Report 2010 of the American Economic Review :
Beginning in January 2006, the Editor and Coeditors have reserved the right to
1
The American Economic Review, Report of the Editor, January 2, 2010. See: www.aeaweb.org/aer/index.php.
2
Wang (1997) analyzes in a similar way application fees in the labor market.
1
return manuscripts to authors without referee review. The decision to return a manuscript without review is based upon a number of considerations, including expected
probability of meeting the standards of the Review, breadth of topic, interest to the
AER audience, and other factors.3
Our paper analyzes the publication market in a dynamic model with trade frictions that
explicitly brings into the picture submission fees and the desk-rejection phenomenon. One key
assumption is that academic journals are specialized or have their own philosophy. Therefore,
a good quality paper, well suited for one journal, might not match the editorial line of another
journal. In a world where the number of journal titles in business and economics counts in
hundreds, authors might target the wrong journal. If a paper does not match the editorial line of
journal, it will be desk-rejected; in the opposite case, it will be sent to referees for an assessment of
its quality. The traditional refereeing process is then represented in a simpli…ed way, by considering
a …xed probability of having a paper accepted for publication. Hence, in this paper we focus on
"horizontal" di¤erentiation between identically demanding journals. The quality of the papers is
not explicitly brought into the picture; the only assumption we made is that authors of a refereerejected paper realize that its quality is too low for the going standards and will not send it to
another journal.4
To the contrary, the author of a desk-rejected paper will submit it to another
journal, hoping for a better …t.
As an original contribution, we introduce at the editor pre-screening level a matching function
that connects the number of successful matches to the total number of submitted papers and the
number of journal titles. For sure, in a market with horizontally di¤erentiated journals, the more
papers each journal gets, the larger the number of papers …tted for that journal; the larger the
number of journals, the deeper their specialization (Frey et al., 2009), thus the better are chances
3
See for similar policies the Instruction to Authors web page of Econometrica, Journal of Monetary Economics
or the Scandinavian Journal of Economics.
4 The structure of the problem would not change is we assume that the author submits a referee-rejected paper
to a …nite number of journals before withdrawing it, but calculations would be more cumbersome.
2
for an author to target the right journal.5
Our approach builds on the classical literature in
labor economics. In this …eld, the matching function between …rms and job-seekers, pioneered by
Pissarides (2000), connects the number of successful matches to the number of unemployed persons
and vacant jobs.6 A journal in the academic publication market is thus similar to a "large …rm"
in the labor market framework, given that every journal publishes several papers every period.
Thus, the paper-to-journal matching function can be seen as a useful "macroeconomic" device,
able to describe in a simple way the informational frictions between authors and editors.
An equilibrium of this model is de…ned as a situation where both scholars and editors implement
their optimal plans, given the existing matching process and the socially determined rent-sharing
rule. The model has three key endogenous variables: the desk-rejection rate, the tension in the
publication market, de…ned as the ratio between the number of editors (journals) and the number
of authors (papers), and the submission fee. We show that the model presents a single equilibrium.
Comparative statics with parameters of the model can account for some of the recent trends in
the academic publication market. For instance, an increase in the scholars’ intertemporal utility
from a published paper would lead to an increase in submission fees, in the number of submitted
papers and in the desk rejection rate.
While analyses of the academic publication market belong now to a well established …eld of
research, there are not many theoretical analyses that take into account informational frictions
speci…c to this market. As a related work, we can refer to Besancenot et al. (2009) who worked
out an equilibrium search model, where authors submit papers and editors search for papers.
Editors can be either highly demanding, thus accepting only top papers with a small probability,
or tolerant, accepting all papers. In equilibrium, authors optimally decide whether to write high or
low quality papers. Lee (2009) argues that matching frictions are a key feature of the publication
5 This argument has been put forward by Stigler et al. (1995) in a di¤erent set-up. Taking the perspective of
scholars searching for new ideas, they argue that the normal reaction of congestion in publication market is journal
specialization; this process should reduce the readers’ e¤ort for identifying the relevant journals.
6 The substantial contribution of Dale Mortensen to this literature should also be acknowledged here (Mortensen,
1994; Mortensen and Pissarides, 1994). See also Cahuc and Zylbeberg (2004) for a thorough description of the
matching approach to labor markets.
3
market, enhanced by the rule according to which a paper cannot be submitted to several journals
at the same time. He works out a paper allocation model, similar to an equilibrium search model,
and analyses the equilibria. The main result is that frictions in the market, leading to higher
delays in publication, could support an e¢cient separating equilibrium where high-quality papers
are published by top-tier journals, and lower quality papers are published by second-tier journals.
Without providing a formal model, Pujol (2008) also acknowledges that journals are vertically
di¤erentiated, and, due to imperfect information, authors can sometimes target a too high quality
journal relatively to their work, thus bearing a high risk of referee-rejection. At di¤erence with
these existing studies, in our model journals have identical qualities. This is the price to pay for
developing an explicit dynamic analysis of the matching process that is not available elsewhere.
The paper is organized as follows. The next section introduces the main assumption. Section
3 presents the equilibrium and study its main properties. We present our conclusions in the last
section.
2
Main assumptions
2.1
Authors, papers and editors
At every period, each author writes one paper, and, following the standard rule in academic
publication, he submits it to only one journal. Submissions are uniformly distributed over the
existing journals. Each journal is run by one editor. Authors have no perfect information about
the editorial line of a journal and can target a wrong journal. Editors must decide whether to
have them published or not. The number of editors, denoted by E; is given. The number of
authors is denoted by A (with A
E). We assume that authors can freely enter or exit this
market, depending on their outside opportunities. Hence A can vary (and will be endogenously
determined).
The paper selection mechanism operates in two steps. In the …rst step, the editor must decide
whether the paper matches the aim and scope of the journal. If the match is not successful, the
4
editor decides to desk-reject the paper. The author will keep on submitting it to other journals
until a correct match occurs. If the match is successful, the editor will send it to the referees for
an assessment of its quality. A paper sent to referees actually exits the submission process: after
the referees deliver their verdict, the paper is either published or withdrawn.
Hence, in the steady state, the total number of papers submitted for publication each period
does not vary. It is made up of the newly written papers (in number A) and all the papers written
at the previous periods that have not got yet a successful match. Let us denote the steady state
number of submissions by N and the probability for a submitted paper to match the editorial line
of a journal by 1
; the steady state desk-rejection rate is . Then, the steady state number of
submitted papers per period is related to the number of new papers by a simple relationship:
N =A
1
X
k
k=0
2.2
=
A
1
:
(1)
The matching function
We denote the per-period number of successful matches between authors and editors by M . We
assume that M can be written as a twice di¤erentiable function with the general form M =
M (E; N ); with @M (; )=@E = ME > 0; and @M (; )=@N = MN > 0: The rationale behind these
properties is easy to grasp: on the one hand, for a given number of journal titles, the more papers
are submitted, the more papers per journal and the more of them should …t any of these journals;
on the other hand, for a given number of papers, the more journal titles, the greater specialization
and the smaller will be chances to target a wrong outlet. Furthermore, this matching function
must comply with one important restriction: the number of matches cannot exceed the smallest
number between the number of papers: M (E; N )
N:
In this paper, in order to get an analytical solution, we will assume that the matching function
5
takes the speci…c form:7
M (E; N ) = E N 1
The matching probability 1
1
with
2]0; 1[:
(2)
is then:
=
()
M (E; N )
=
N
1
=
E
A
E
N
E
A
=
(1
)
1
:
(4)
Hereafter, formula can be written in a more compact form if we denote by
of accessibility" of the academic publication market (a higher
path to publication for an author), with
(3)
= E=A the "degree
being representative of a an easier
2]0; 1[. The matching probability can be written:
1
=
(5)
1
Another interesting measure is the number of submissions per journal:
N
A=E
1
=
=
E
1
(1
2.3
)
=
1
1
> 1:
(6)
The expected intertemporal utility of the scholar, W
As already mentioned, at each time period, the scholar writes one paper and he submits it for
publication to only one journal. Because of informational frictions in the publication market, he
will meet an editor interested in his work with probability (1
): When an editor gets a paper
well-…tted to his journal, he will proceed to an evaluation of the quality of the text through a
standard refereeing process. To keep the model as simple as possible, we consider that there are
only two possible outcomes of the refereeing process: the paper can either be referee-rejected with
the probability (1
p); or accepted with the probability p:8 Denoting by
the scholar’s discount
7 The model could be numerically solved for any function homogenous of degree one M ( E; N ) = M (E; N );
8 . This property is intuitively appealing: indeed, doubling the number of papers and the number of titles, it is
reasonable to assume that the number of matches would double.
8 The structure of the model would not change if we consider a two stage evaluation, were we add a revise
and resubmit option, followed by accepted or rejected. Formulas would become more cumbersome due to the
compounded discount. See for a more powerful analysis of the paper selection process, Enger and Gans (1998),
Besancenot and Vranceanu (2008) or Heintzelman and Nocetti (2009).
6
factor, his intertemporal expected utility prior to sending his paper to a journal is:
S=
S + (1
)f s +
[pWA + (1
p)WR ]g :
(7)
In this expression, the …rst term is the expected gain if the match was unsuccessful; in this case,
that occurs with probability ; at the next period the scholar will re-submit his paper to another
journal and expect the same reward S.9
The second term is the expected payo¤ if the match
is successful (which happens with probability (1
)): the scholar pays the submission fee s and
waits for the editor’s decision. The latter takes advice from referees, then either rejects the paper,
which worth then WR ; or accepts it, which worth then WA for its author
When a paper is referee-rejected, the author must decide if he will try to …nd another suitable
journal for his article. For the sake of parsimony, we will consider here that after a motivated
rejection, the paper is de…nitively withdrawn from the publishing game by its author. Hence, the
expected utility of the author of a referee-rejected paper is: WR = 0:
Many theoretical and empirical analyses have shown that a scholar’s pay, promotion and tenure
decision depend to a large extent on his publication record (Gomez-Mejia and Balkin, 1992; Swidler
and Goldreyer, 1998; Swanson, 2004). Hence, we merely assume that the author gets a positive
intertemporal utility from publishing one additional paper: WA = u; with u > 0:10
Then equation (7) can be solved for an explicit value of S:
S=
(1
) ( s + pu)
:
1
(8)
Denoting the cost of drafting a new paper by c, the net expected intertemporal value from writing
a paper can be written:
W
= S
=
(1
c
) ( s + pu)
1
c
(9)
9 Remember that when a paper is desk-rejected, the author will keep on trying to …nd a suitable journal. He
will do so as long as the paper has not been accepted or rejected by a referee.
1 0 Here we assume that the utility of every new publication is constant. Paul and Rubin (1984) argue that, for
signaling motives, the value of the …rst publications should be larger than the value of subsequent ones.
7
We notice that the problem is meaningful only for W > 0. The intertemporal utility of the author
is a decreasing function in the submission fee s:
2.4
The expected intertemporal utility of the editor, V
At any time period, each editor gets N=E submissions. At a the …rst stage of the selection process,
each paper is screened by the editor. Given the matching process de…ned here-above, M=E papers
match the aim and scope of the journal and will be send to referees; the remaining (N
M )=E
papers will be desk rejected. The e¤ort of screening one paper involves a cost g for the editor.
Denoting by VDR the expected utility of a desk rejected paper, and by VS the expected utility
of a paper sent to the referees, the expected intertemporal payo¤ of the editor (from being in the
publication market) can be written as:
V =
g
M
N M
N
+
VS +
VDR :
E
E
E
(10)
The value of a desk-rejected paper is elementary VDR = 0: When the editor decides to send the
paper to referees, he will charge the author a submission fee s > 0. At the next period, he will
pay the referees an amount r
0 and, according to the referees’ reports, he will either accept the
paper (and get the reward VA ) or reject it (and receive VR ). The expected utility VS of a paper
sent to the referees can be written:
VS = s +
[pVA + (1
p)VR
r] :
(11)
The intertemporal utility of the editor from an accepted paper is VA = v and the intertemporal
utility of the author from a referee-rejected paper is VR = 0: Thus, the expected intertemporal
payo¤ of the editor (Eq.10) becomes:
V
=
=
=
N
M
+
VS
E
E
N
M
g+
[s + (pv r)]
E
N
N
f g + (1
) [s + (pv r)]g :
E
g
8
(12)
where we recall that
N
E
1
=
1
and (1
) =
. The editor’s intertemporal surplus is
1
increasing with s.
3
Main relationships and the equilibrium
3.1
Author free entry condition and the s = ( ) relationship
In general, people who can play the publication game are highly trained individuals who can use
their human capital for alternative activities. For instance, in many higher education institutions,
faculty members, at some stage of their career, choose to teach more hours in executive education
programmes or do administrative work. If the reward from academic publication increases, some
of them might be tempted to reduce their teaching or administration hours and do more research
(Fox and Milbourne, 1999; Taylor et al., 2006). Consulting or nice jobs in public administration
or international organizations are also accessible to many well trained scholars (Faria, 2001; 2002)
In our model, these outside opportunities provide the would-be author with a reservation
intertemporal utility level, denoted by W (with W > 0): Under free entry, new authors enter the
publication market as long as they expect that the intertemporal gain from this activity is larger
than W , and leave the market in the opposite case. In the steady state equilibrium, the expected
intertemporal utility W is driven to W . The condition W = W allows us to put forward a …rst
relationship between the degree of accessibility,
= E=A; and the submission fee, s: Given the
de…nition of W (Eq. 9), we can write:
W
=
W
) f s + pug
c=W
1
h
, s = pu
W + c (1
)
,
Denoting by
( ) = pu
(1
W +c
h
(1
)
1
+
i
1
+
i
:
(13)
; the last equation can be written in the
compact form:
s=
( ):
9
(14)
with
@ ( )
@
> 0;
@2 ( )
@ 2
< 0 and lim ( ) =
!0
as de…ned by Eq. (8); we can check that
The graph of
1; (1) = pu
W + c : Given that W +c = S such
(1) > 0:
( ) is plotted in Figure 1:
s
Φ(θ)
∆θ>0
∆θ<0
0
θ
1
Figure 1: Author free-entry condition
Recall that authors’ intertemporal utility W is decreasing with s: All points above the line
s=
( ) correspond to situations where the intertemporal gain of a scholar is lower than W , thus
scholars are attracted by non academic activities and exit the publication market. The number
of authors decreases and
desk rejection
increases. In turn, given (5), (1
) increases and the probability of
declines.
Points below the line correspond to an author’s intertemporal utility greater than W , thus
some new scholars decide to enter the publication market. A increases and
= E=A decreases
over time.
3.2
The rent sharing rule and the s =
( ) relationship
In a normally functioning publication market, the representative author obtains from writing a
paper the intertemporal utility W and the representative editor gets from running his journal
the intertemporal utility V: With A authors and E editors in the market, the overall welfare
10
generated by the publication market is given by:
EV + AW =
(15)
How this total welfare is divided between the two types of players is a matter of social organization
of this special market, prevailing institutional arrangements and ultimately the balance of powers
between the two groups of players. It is beyond the scope of this paper to provide an in-depth
analysis of the surplus sharing mechanism. In the following we merely assume that editors gets a
share
of the total surplus while authors gets a share (1
). In other words, we have:
EV =
(16)
AW = (1
)
This surplus sharing rule allows us to write:
EV
=
AW
(1
)
() V =
A
W:
)E
(1
(17)
Given that W = W ; this last equation implies:
V
=
()
()
Denoting by
( )=
(1
)W
A
W
(1
)E
N
( g + (1
E
s=
(1
[pv
)
) (s +
W
r]+g
[pv
[pv
r])) =
r] + g
1
(1
A
W
)E
:
(18)
; the last equation can be written in the compact
1
form:
s=
with
@ ( )
@
< 0;
2
@
@
( )
2
> 0; and lim
!0
Figure 2 represents the graph of
( ) = +1;
( )
(1) =
(19)
(1
)W
[pv
r] + g:
( ):
Recall that editors’ intertemporal utility V is increasing with s: All points below the curve
s=
( ) represent situations where editors’ reward EV is too low relatively to scholars’ utility
AW ; to restore the balance, the submission fee is expected to rise. All points above the curve
11
s
∆s<0
∆s>0
Ψ(θ)
0
θ
1
Figure 2: The rent sharing agreement
s=
( ) correspond to situations where the submission fee must decline to restore the socially
agreed balance of welfare shares.
3.3
The steady state equilibrium
An equilibrium solution is a pair (s; ) with s > 0 and
s=
2]0; 1[ that simultaneously ful…lls equations
( ) > 0 (the free entry condition, Eq. 14) and s =
( ) > 0 (the surplus sharing condition,
Eq. 19). Such an equilibrium is represented as the point Z in Figure 3.
The equilibrium
( )
is implicitly de…ned by
=
( )
()
pu
W +c
2
=4
()
h
( )=
+ (1
)
W + c (1
p (u + v)
1
( ) : We can obtain its explicit form:
i
=
(1
)+g
(r + c)
+
1
W
W
)
31
5
[pv
r] + g
:
1
(20)
The equilibrium matching probability results from equation (5):
1
=
1
=
(1
p (u + v)
) W +c +g
(r + c)
12
+
:
(1
)
W
(21)
The number of submissions per journal (Eq. ??) can also be inferred in a straightforward way:
N
=
E
2
1
p (u + v)
=4
1
(r + c)
+
W + c (1
1
W
)+g
31
5 :
(22)
Finally, the equilibrium submission fee is:
s
=
(1
)
W
[pv
r] + g
1
p (u + v)
()
s=
(1
)
W
[pv
W + c (1
()
)
s=
h
r] + g
)W
(1
(pv
W + c (1
(r + c)
W + c (1
i
r) + g pu
+
(1
)
W
)+g
c
W
:
)+g
(23)
A single equilibrium exists under the necessary and su¢cient condition:
(1)
<
,
(1) ,
1
(1
)
(1
)
W
[pv
r] + g < pu
W + r + g + c < p (u + v) :
W +c
(24)
(25)
Chances that this condition is ful…lled are better if direct and opportunity cost of each player are
relatively small, or if the utility from publishing a paper for either the author or the editor is large
enough.
The implicit dynamics represented by the arrows in Figure 3 show that the model presents
a Cobweb structure. A su¢cient condition for the equilibrium to be locally stable is that the
curve
() to be steeper than
[ds=d ] >
() (oscillations dampen around the equilibrium). It turns out that
[ds=d ] , W + c (1
) > g: Chances to have this condition ful…lled are better
if the cost of managing papers by the editor is relative low, and if authors direct (c) and indirect
opportunity cost W of writing papers is large.
3.4
Properties of the equilibrium
We can now analyze the impact of changes in the main parameters on the equilibrium values of
s and . For so doing, we have to take into account the impact of parameter changes on the
two curves, s =
( ) and s =
( ). Table 1 presents the partial derivatives @ ( ; i)=@i and
13
s
Φ(θ)
p,u
_
W,c
Z
_
W,r,g,δ
Ψ(θ)
p,v
0
1
θ
Figure 3: Equilibrium in the academic publication market
@ ( ; i)=@i; for i 2 fr; c; p; v; u; g; W ; g: The signs of these derivatives can be inferred without
ambiguity:
i
@ ( )=@i
r
0
c
(1
p
v
1
+
0
u
v
0
u
g
)
@ ( )=@i
p
p
0
0
W
1
(1
)
1
+
(1
)
1
0
(1
)2 W
Table 1. Various partial derivatives
We represent in Figure 3 how the two curves move in response to positive variations of the
parameters r; c; p; v; u; g; W ; ;
by the respective arrows.
14
Table 2 indicates the sign of the variation in the equilibrium values of
and s with respect
to variations in parameters such as indicated by comparative statics with the two relationships in
Figure 3 (or directly through Eq. 20 and Eq. 23).
s
r
c
p
v
u
g
W
+
+
–
–
–
+
+
+
+
–
?
–
+
+
?
+
Table 2. Impact of parameter change on s and
In the last few years, in many regions of the globe (mainly Europe and Asia), governments are
implementing reforms aiming at strengthening ties between academics’ compensation and their
research performance (Groot and Garcia-Valderrama, 2006). In Europe, substantial momentum
to the reform of higher education and R&D systems was brought by the Lisbon Summit of 2000,
where leaders of the EU member countries acknowledged that lasting growth can be achieved only
if the performance in these two areas improves in a substantial way. At the school playing level,
the emergence of ubiquitous rankings is setting additional pressure on deans to reward research
performance more aggressively. The direct consequence of these policy changes is an increase in
scholars’ utility from publishing a paper (u). According to our analysis, when the net utility u of
the author from publishing a paper increases, their expected intertemporal gain W goes up. New
scholars are thus attracted by the publication market and start submitting papers,
declines.
The rise in the number of submissions also presents an adverse e¤ect on the editors’ utility as it
increases the editors’ overall screening cost that is not fully compensated by the increased number
of published papers. To restore the agreed shares of surplus, the submission fees must increase
in order to o¤set the relative decline in editors’ surplus V . This partially o¤sets the initial rise
in authors’ intertemporal gain W: In the steady state, at the term of the adjustment process,
the submission fee (s) has increased, the ratio between editors and authors has decreased and,
consequently, the number of submissions per journal have increased. These implications of the
model are much in line with the observed stylized facts. Indeed, as mentioned in the Introduction,
15
in the last few years the number of submitted papers has increased dramatically, which prompted
editors to implement "defense strategies" such as the systematic recourse to desk-rejection or the
introduction of large submission fees.
The model suggests that some factors, such as a lower probability of the referees accepting
papers, a higher writing cost or an increased Editors’ power might o¤set the former trends.
For instance, Ellison (2002) argues that over time referees tend to become more demanding. If
the probability p of accepting a paper is reduced, both the editors and the scholars can expect a
deterioration of their respective surpluses. If some authors leave the publication market,
= E=A
goes up and and the probability of desk rejection declines. At the same time, a smaller number
of submissions entails a smaller editorial processing cost. Depending on the relative strength of
the two e¤ects (on the one hand, a smaller number of publications per journal pushes down the
editor’s expected reward, on the other hand, the falling number of submissions brings down the
editorial cost), editors would see their surplus raising or not and would adjust submission fees
accordingly.
In the same line of reasoning, in order to comply with a tougher publishing norm, authors might
have to bear larger writing costs (c). This would also push some authors out of the publication
market and help containing the raise in submission fees.
Finally, one could notice that traditionally the publication of academic papers was driven by a
concern for serving the academic community. In the early years of the 20th century, most academic
journals were published by national and regional associations of scholars. Over time, pro…t-driven
businesses such as the major publishing houses (Elsevier, Springer, Sage, Blackwell, etc.) have
gradually increased their participation to the academic publication market. Such institutional
change could be responsible for a change in the surplus sharing rule in favour of the editors. If
the balance of power between editors and authors changes such as a bigger share of the surplus
goes to editors ( goes up), the submission fee must increase. In turn, since W < W ; some
scholars leave the publication market, the ratio
16
= E=A will increase and so does the matching
probability (1
). Given that it becomes now easier for authors to have their papers published,
that evolution partially o¤sets the initial increase in fees. At the term of the adjustment process,
both s and
4
would have risen.
Conclusion
For many years, the ‡ow of papers submitted for publication in academic journals in business
administration and economics has been increasing steadily. The number of journal titles is also
growing, but at smaller pace. The resulting journal congestion is at the origin of substantial
frustration and criticism on behalf of both authors and editors. In this context, editors are testing
new strategies aimed to preserve the quality of their journals and attract the best contributions.
Among these new intriguing policies, one can mention the generalization of (large) submission fees,
the lengthier response time and the implementation of desk-rejection, de…ned as the possibility for
the editor to decide on his own whether a paper matches or not the aim and scope of the journal.
This paper aimed at providing a dynamic model of the academic publication market where
scholars supply and journals demand papers. In our model, due to imperfect information, scholars
can sometimes target a wrong journal in terms of editorial line. The key and original modeling
device is a paper-to-journal matching function, relating the number of successful matches to the
numbers of authors and journals in the market, inspired from the classical matching model in
labor economics (Pissarides, 2000). If a paper overcomes this …rst test, then the editor will send
it to referees who ultimately decide whether to publish it or not.
The model presents a single equilibrium, de…ned as a situation where both editors and authors implement their optimal publishing strategies, given the matching process and the socially
determined share of rent between the two groups of players. Parameter changes have in general
unambiguous consequences on the main endogenous variables: the ratio between the number of
authors and editors, the number of submissions per editor, the desk rejection rate and the submission fee. In the light of our analysis, the recent trends in the market for publication such as
17
the simultaneous increase in submission fees and number of submissions can be interpreted as
a direct consequence of the rise in authors’ utility from publishing a paper, itself related to the
recent institutional changes in the academic publication market.
Like the elementary version of the labor market matching model, our simple model cannot
pretend to provide an exhaustive picture of the academic publication market, but can be seen as a
good starting point for more powerful analyses, where the introduction of heterogenous agents or
a more active role for editors in the paper selection process could bring the model closer to reality.
However, a dynamic model has its own merit, since it can describe in a more thorough way a market
characterized by huge ‡ows of "commodities", such as the market for academic publications. It
also provides policymakers with a better understanding of transmission mechanisms, that should
not be neglected in when working out any reform of the higher education system.
References
Azar, O¤er H., 2006. The academic review process: How can we make it more e¢cient?,
American Economist, 50, 1, pp. 37–50.
Bence, Valerie and Charles Oppenheim, 2004. The in‡uence of peer review on the Research
Assessment Exercise, Journal of Information Science, 30, 4, pp. 347–368.
Besancenot, Damien, Faria, Joao R. and Kim V. Huynh, 2009.Search and research : the
in‡uence of the editorial board on journals’ quality, CEPN Working Paper 09-2009.
Besancenot, Damien and Radu Vranceanu, 2008. Can incentives for research harm research?
A business schools’ tale, Journal of Socio-Economics, 37, pp. 1248–1265.
Cahuc, Pierre and André Zylberberg, 2004. Labor Economics, Cambridge University Press,
Cambridge, Mass.
Ellison, Glenn, 2002. The slowdown of the economics publishing process, Journal of Political
Economy, 110, 5, pp. 947–993.
Faria, Joao R., 2002. Scienti…c, business and political networks in academia, Research in
Economics, 56, pp. 187–198.
Faria, Joao R., 2001. Rent seeking in academia: the consultancy disease, American Economist, 45, 2, pp. 69–73.
Frey, Bruno S., Eichenberger, Reiner and René L. Frey, 2009. Editorial ruminations: Publishing Kyklos, Kyklos, 62, 2, pp. 151–160.
Frey, Bruno S., 2009. Economists in the PITS, International Review of Economics, 56, 4,
pp. 335–346.
18
Gomeiz-Meija, Luis R. and David B. Balkin, 1992. Determination of facutly pay: An agency
theory perspective, Academy of Management Journal, 35, 5, pp. 921–955.
Heintzelman, Martin and Nocetti, Diego, 2009. Where should we submit our manuscript?
An analysis of journal submission strategies, B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy,
9, 1, (Advances), Article 39.
Enger, Maxim and Joshua S. Gans, 1998. Why referees are not paid (enough), American
Economic Review, 88, 5, pp. 1341–1350.
Lee, Sam-Ho, 2009. A theory of self-selection in a market with matching frictions: An
application to delay in refereeing times in economics journals, Journal of Economic Behavior
and Organization, In print, doi:10.1016/jebo.2009.05.027.
Leslie Derek, 2005. Are delays in academic publishing necessary? American Economic Review, 95, 1, pp. 407–413.
Mortensen, Dale. 1994, The cyclical behavior of job and worker ‡ows, Journal of Economic
Dynamic and Control, 18, pp. 1121–1142.
Mortensen, Dale and Christopher Pissarides. 1994, Job creation and job destruction in the
theory of unemployment, Review of Economic Studies, 61, pp. 397–415.
Medo¤, Marshall H., 2003, Editorial favoritism in economics?, Southern Economic Journal
70, pp. 425–434.
Paul, Chris and Paul C Rubin, 1984. Teaching and research: The Human capital paradigm,
Journal of Economic Education, Spring issue, pp. 142–147.
Pissarides, Christopher A., 2000. Equilibrium Unemployment Theory, second edition, Cambridge Mass.
Pujol, Francesc, 2008. Ranking journals following a matching model approach: an application
to public economics journals, Journal of Public Economic Theory, 10, 1, pp. 55–76.
Stigler, George. J., Stigler, Stephen M. and Claire Friedland, 1995. The journals of economics,
Journal of Political Economy, 103,2, pp. 331–359.
Swanson, Edward P., 2004. Publishing in the majors: a comparison of accounting, …nance,
management and marketing, 2004, Contemporary Research in Accounting, 21, 1, pp. 223–
255.
Swidler, Steve and Elisabeth Goldreyer, 1998. The value of a …nance journal publication,
Journal of Finance, 53, 1, pp. 351–363.
Wang, Ruqu, 1997. Competition, wage commitments, and application fees, Journal of Labor
Economics, 15, 1, pp. 124–142.
19
ESSEC
CENTRE
DE RECHERCHE
LISTE DES DOCUMENTS DE RECHERCHE DU CENTRE DE RECHERCHE DE L’ESSEC
(Pour se procurer ces documents, s’adresser au CENTRE DE RECHERCHE DE L’ESSEC)
LISTE OF ESSEC RESEARCH CENTER WORKING PAPERS
(Contact the ESSEC RESEARCH CENTER for information on how to obtain copies of these papers)
RESEARCH.CENTER@ESSEC.FR
2006
06001
CAZAVAN-JENY Anne, JEANJEAN Thomas
Levels of Voluntary Disclosure in IPO prospectuses: An Empirical Analysis
06002
BARONI Michel, BARTHELEMY Fabrice, MOKRANE Mahdi
Monte Carlo Simulations versus DCF in Real Estate Portfolio Valuation
06003
BESANCENOT Damien, VRANCEANU Radu
Can Incentives for Research Harm Research? A Business Schools Tale
06004
FOURÇANS André, VRANCEANU Radu
Is the ECB so Special? A Qualitative and Quantitative Analysis
06005
NAIDITCH Claire, VRANCEANU Radu
Transferts des migrants et offre de travail dans un modèle de signalisation
06006
MOTTIS Nicolas
Bologna: Far from a Model, Just a Process for a While…
06007
LAMBERT Brice
Ambiance Factors, Emotions and Web User Behavior: A Model Integrating and Affective and Symbolical
Approach
06008
BATISTA Catia, POTIN Jacques
Stages of Diversification and Capital Accumulation in an Heckscher-Ohlin World, 1975-1995
06009
TARONDEAU Jean-Claude
Strategy and Organization Improving Organizational Learning
06010
TIXIER Daniel
Teaching Management of Market Driven Business Units Using Internet Based Business Games
06011
COEURDACIER Nicolas
Do Trade Costs in Goods Market Lead to Home Bias in Equities?
06012
AVIAT Antonin, COEURDACIER Nicolas
The Geography of Trade in Goods and Asset Holdings
06013
COEURDACIER Nicolas, GUIBAUD Stéphane
International Portfolio Diversification Is Better Than You Think
06014
COEURDACIER Nicolas, GUIBAUD Stéphane
A Dynamic Equilibrium Model of Imperfectly Integrated Financial Markets
06015
DUAN Jin-Chuan, FULOP Andras
Estimating the Structural Credit Risk Model When Equity Prices Are Contaminated by Trading Noises
06016
FULOP Andras
Feedback Effects of Rating Downgrades
06017
LESCOURRET Laurence, ROBERT Christian Y.
Preferencing, Internalization and Inventory Position
06018
BOURGUIGNON Annick, SAULPIC Olivier, ZARLOWSKI Philippe
Management Accounting Change in the Public Sector: A French Case Study and a New Institutionalist
Perspective
06019
de BEAUFORT Viviane
One Share – One Vote, le nouveau Saint Graal ?
06020
COEURDACIER Nicolas, MARTIN Philippe
The Geography of Asset Trade and the Euro: Insiders and Outsiders
06021
BESANCENOT Damien, HUYNH Kim, VRANCEANU Radu
The "Read or Write" Dilemma in Academic Production: A European Perspective
2007
07001
NAIDITCH Claire, VRANCEANU Radu
International Remittances and Residents' Labour Supply in a Signaling Model
07002
VIENS G., LEVESQUE K., CHAHWAKILIAN P., EL HASNAOUI A., GAUDILLAT A., NICOL G.,
CROUZIER C.
Évolution comparée de la consommation de médicaments dans 5 pays européens entre 2000 et 2004 :
analyse de 7 classes pharmaco-thérapeutiques
07003
de BEAUFORT Viviane
La création d'entreprise au féminin dans le monde occidental
07004
BOARI Mircea
Rationalizing the Irrational. The Principle of Relative Maximization from Sociobiology to Economics and Its
Implications for Ethics
07005
BIBARD Laurent
Sexualités et mondialisation
07006
VRANCEANU Radu
The Moral Layer of Contemporary Economics: A Virtue Ethics Perspective
07007
LORINO Philippe
Stylistic Creativity in the Utilization of Management Tools
07008
BARONI Michel, BARTHELEMY Fabrice, MOKRANE Mahdi
Optimal Holding Period for a Real Estate Portfolio
07009
de BEAUFORT Viviane
One Share - One Vote, the New Holy Graal?
07010
DEMEESTERE René
L'analyse des coûts : public ou privé ?
07011
TIXIER Maud
Appreciation of the Sustainability of the Tourism Industry in Cyprus
07012
LORINO Philippe
Competence-based Competence Management: a Pragmatic and Interpretive Approach. The Case of a
Telecommunications Company
07013
LORINO Philippe
Process Based Management and the Central Role of Dialogical Collective Activity in Organizational Learning.
The Case of Work Safety in the Building Industry
07014
LORINO Philippe
The Instrumental Genesis of Collective Activity. The Case of an ERP Implementation in a Large Electricity
Producer
07015
LORINO Philippe, GEHRKE Ingmar
Coupling Performance Measurement and Collective Activity: The Semiotic Function of Management Systems.
A Case Study
07016
SALLEZ Alain
Urbaphobie et désir d'urbain, au péril de la ville
07017
de CARLO Laurence
The Classroom as a Potential Space - Teaching Negotiation through Paradox
07019
ESPOSITO VINZI Vincenzo
Capturing and Treating Unobserved Heterogeneity by Response Based Segmentation in PLS Path Modeling.
A Comparison of Alternative Methods by Computational Experiments
07020
CHEVILLON Guillaume, Christine RIFFLART
Physical Market Determinants of the Price of Crude Oil and the Market Premium
07021
CHEVILLON Guillaume
Inference in the Presence of Stochastic and Deterministic Trends
07023
COLSON Aurélien
The Ambassador, between Light and Shade. The Emergence of Secrecy as the Norm of International
Negotiation
07024
GOMEZ Marie-Léandre
A Bourdieusian Perspective on Strategizing
07025
BESANCENOT Damien, VRANCEANU Radu
Multiple Equilibria in a Firing Game with Impartial Justice
07026
BARONI Michel, BARTHELEMY Fabrice, MOKRANE Madhi
Is It Possible to Construct Derivatives for the Paris Residential Market?
2008
08001
BATISTA Catia, POTIN Jacques
International Specialization and the Return to Capital, 1976-2000
08002
BESANCENOT Damien, FARIA Joan Ricardo, VRANCEANU Radu
Why Business Schools Do So Much Research: a Signaling Explanation
08003
de BEAUFORT Viviane
D’un effet vertueux de l’art. 116 de la loi NRE en matière de RSE ? La problématique est posée à échelle de
l’Union européenne
08004
MATHE Hervé
Greater Space Means More Service: Leveraging the Innovative Power of Architecture and Design
08005
MATHE Hervé
Leading in Service Innovation: Three perspectives on Service Value delivery in a European Context
08006
ROMANIUK Katarzyna, VRANCEANU Radu
Asset Prices and Asymmetries in the Fed’s Interest Rate Rule: A Financial Approach
08007
MOTTIS Nicolas, WALTON Peter
Measuring Research Output across Borders - A Comment
08008
NAPPI-CHOULET Ingrid, MAURY Tristan-Pierre
A Spatiotemporal Autoregressive Price Index for the Paris Office Property Market
08009
METIU Anca, OBODARU Otilia
Women’s Professional Identity Formation in the Free/Open Source Software Community
08010
SIBIEUDE Thierry, VIDAL Rodolphe
Le programme « Une grande école : pourquoi pas moi ? ® ». D’une action de responsabilité sociétale de
l’ESSEC à la responsabilité sociétale des grandes écoles françaises
08011
SIBIEUDE Thierry, VIDAL Rodolphe
Enjeux et perspectives du sociétariat des groupes mutualistes complexes face aux stratégies de
développement à l’échelle groupe : quelques enseignements du cas du groupeMACIF
08012
FOURÇANS André, VRANCEANU Radu
Money in the Inflation Equation: the Euro Area Evidence
08013
CAZAVAN-JENY Anne, JEANJEAN Thomas
Supply and Demand for European Accounting Research. Evidence from EAA Congresses
08014
FAYARD Anne-Laure, METIU Anca
Beyond Orality and Literacy: Letters and Organizational Communication
08015
CAZAVAN-JENY Anne, MISSONIER-PIERA Franck, MARGAINE J.
CEO Compensations in a Stakeholders’ Regime: An Empirical Investigation with French Listed Companies
08016
METIU Anca, FAYARD Anne-Laure
Letters and Scientific Communities
08017
BESANCENOT Damien, VRANCEANU Radu
Migratory Policy in Developing Countries: How to Bring Best People Back?
08018
BESANCENOT Damien, VRANCEANU Radu
Financial Distress and Bank’s Communication Policy in Crisis Time
08019
AGID Philippe, TARONDEAU Jean-Claude
Les performances des maisons d’Opéra : une explication statistique
2009
09001
POTIN Jacques
The Selection Effect of Two-way Trade in the Melitz Model: An Alternative Approach
09002
NAIDITCH Claire, VRANCEANU Radu
Migratory Equilibria with Invested Remittances
09003
BARONI Michel, BARTHELEMY Fabrice, MOKRANE Mahdi
A Repeat Sales Index Robust to Small Datasets
09004
NAPPI-CHOULET Ingrid, MAURY Tristan-Pierre
A Spatial and Temporal Autoregressive Local Estimation for the Paris Housing Market
09005
BENCHIMOL Jonathan, FOURÇANS André
Money in a DSGE Framework with an Application to the Euro Zone
09006
VRANCEANU Radu
Four Myths and a Financial Crisis
09007
BESANCENOT Damien, VRANCEANU Radu
Banks' Risk Race: A Signaling Explanation
09008
BESANCENOT Damien, HUYNH Kim, VRANCEANU Radu
Desk Rejection in an Academic Publication Market Model with Matching Frictions
09009
BOUTY Isabelle, GOMEZ Marie-Léandre
Unpacking Knowing Integration: A Practice-based Study in Haute Cuisine
09010
GOMEZ Marie-Léandre, BOUTY Isabelle
The Social Dimensions of Idea Work in Haute Cuisine: A Bourdieusian Perspective
09011
GOMEZ Marie-Léandre
Knowledge Dynamics During Planning Practices
09012
GIRAUD Gaël, RENOUARD Cécile
Relational Capability: An Indicator of Collective Empowerment
09013
MOTTIS Nicolas, PONSSARD Jean-Pierre
Création de valeur, 10 ans après…
09014
PRAT Nicolas, COMYN-WATTIAU Isabelle, AKOKA Jacky
Combining Objects with Rules to Represent Aggregation Knowledge in Data Warehouse and OLAP Systems
09015
NAIDITCH Claire, VRANCEANU Radu
Remittances as a Social Status Signaling Device
09016
GIRAUD Gaël, RENOUARD Cécile
Is the Veil of Ignorance Transparent?
2010
10001
VRANCEANU Radu, LAOT Maxime, DUBART Delphine
Une échelle de mesure de la connaissance en raisonnement économique et résultats d'une enquête menée
en décembre 2009
10002
de TISSOT Olivier, WAGNER-EDELMAN Francine
Analyse prospective de la rémunération des auteurs, artistes-interprètes et producteurs à l'ère de la
numérisation