What Do People Live On? Living Wages in India
Subhadra Mitra Channa, University of Delhi
Abstract
The question of what people are expected to live
on raises many issues, foregrounding the rather
metaphysical question of how people are viewed as
people. To argue for the implementation of a really
viable living wage one would have to argue against
the dehumanization of bodies, of construction of
personhoods that demean humans, and to visualize a
change in worldview and perceptual categories.
Living wage discussions on India must go beyond
economies to address the cultural/cosmological
factors that mark power relations and shape social
categories, and this must be done against the backdrop of overpopulation and abject poverty.
Keywords: living wage, right to work, Indian
state, caste values, unorganized labor
Introduction
The concept of living wage
In this paper I will focus on the issue of the constitutional (the Indian Constitution) introduction of
the concept of ‘‘living wages’’ in India and the problems in its implementation. My main focus will be on
the cultural and ideological values that foster notions
of inequality between human beings in India and situate the argument in the caste/class system, in view
of the fact that in South Asia, the caste system provides the basis of most of one’s identity both socially
and politically (Zinkin 1962:8; see also Dirks 2001:7,
16).1
To talk about a living wage raises many interesting philosophical and ethical questions. First of all,
unlike the concept of ‘‘minimum wage’’ that assumes
a direct relationship between labor and compensation
for labor or work done, the concept of living wage
raises issues of human rights, especially the right to
survival and dignity. The concept of living wage does
not match wages with work done but with the requirements or needs of the laborer. As a concept it is
on a different plane than the mere concept of wages or
even minimum wages. It does not evaluate merely the
quality or quantity of work but the quantity and
quality of the worker’s needs, thereby taking the concept of wages out of the market equation of exchange
and putting it in the realm of larger human values.
The concept of living wages, then, is situated
away from the market; it is not an exchange, it is an
Volume XXXI, Number 1
assessment of humanity and of the needs that a
humanized subject is visualized to have. In other
words, in a market economy the laborer is an abstract
entity, a figure that is placed on an exchange network.
But as soon as we talk about a living wage we bring in
a concept of a living human being with the needs of
being human and not merely a unit of labor. The immediate issues that are raised in this respect are with
how social personhood is defined, whether the society
in question views all human beings as equal, and
what the defining criteria of rights are: do they attach
themselves to humans in general, or to culturally defined social positions?
In this context it is relevant to bring in the notion
of ‘‘entitlement’’ as introduced by the Nobel laureate
economist Amartya Sen, who defines it as ‘‘the set of
alternative commodity bundles which a person can
command’’ (Sen 1981:46). This concept directs attention away from pure economics to the political, social,
and cultural relations whereby entitlements are
worked out among the market exchange, the state,
and its subjects, and also within the same household.
As Sen had rightly pointed out, individuals are not
simply numbers but have distinct social, political,
and cultural identities including gender (Kapadia
1995:214).2
To talk about living wages is to weave the argument around this notion of entitlement, what is
expected to be the entitlement of a person in terms of
his/her social personhood, rather than labor contribution. What anyone receives as food and wages is
often determined by such factors as caste and gender
and other factors such as race and ethnicity. Hussain
(1999:3) further enriches the concept of entitlement
by saying, ‘‘The other side of entitlement, which is
less abstract and more immediate, is the notion of
‘‘vulnerable group,’’ sharing some common features
which make them susceptible to deprivation.’’ As
Dreze (1999:72) states, in India it has traditionally
been the landless laborers and rural artisans who
have had to face discrimination in terms of consumption and often have to face hunger as a result of that.
To this I must add that both these groups are largely
comprised of the lower castes and untouchables in the
Indian caste system, a category not deemed quite
human and therefore deprived of their rightful
entitlement (Mendelsohn and Vicziany 1998:7, 13).3
& 2010 by the American Anthropological Association. All rights reserved.
15
Anthropology of Work Review
To get people a living wage one must calculate this
entitlement in terms of a universal category of needs.
We may therefore situate the argument in the cultural
historical conditions of construction of this subject, a
subject that is denied its rights by the very virtue of its
being.
I shall first examine the approach of the Indian
state towards living wage that shows the state as
having humanistic concerns and the notion of a ‘‘citizen’’ of India as one who is endowed with human
qualities within a democratic and equalitarian framework. The post-colonial Indian state is comprised of
democratically elected leaders and a bureaucracy of
educated elite, who enter it through competitive examinations. While the leaders are overtly involved in
policymaking, they are both guided and informed by
the bureaucratic intellectuals, especially the members
of the planning commission and the state secretaries.
The state in abstraction is also to be viewed as the
representations of the ideals on which the nation is
founded, thus the term nation-state has been used in
the post-colonial context. When I refer to the state it is
this combination of ideals and personnel that are being referring to. The apex leader, the prime-minister,
is viewed as providing the broad vision on which the
state is based; he/she acts in unison with the ideals of
the party represented by him or her, but ultimately it
is the bureaucracy and then the lower-level officials
who are responsible for implementation of these policies.4 In discussing the various policies of the state
directed towards ensuring livelihood and survival of
its citizens, it must be remembered that the state is not
always uniform in its ideals, as different political
parties and individuals have been in power and successive governments have held varying views. But
broadly the welfare programs are implemented
through the planning commissions and bureaucracy
and thus have a continuity that may override the
changes in political parties and governments.
In the second part of the paper (the most comprehensive, as I have greater expertise in this area
with my experience as an anthropologist), I shall describe the reality of the social and economic situation
in India and show that there is a huge gap between
the constitutional vision and the ground-level realities. In the third part of the paper, I shall discuss why
this gap exists and the age-old values and prejudices
that hinder the effective implementation of the state’s
well-meant intentions and principles. Since these
values are held by the people and it is ultimately
the people who form both the bureaucracy and the
government, it is to be expected that at the level of
implementation the human factor is to play a more
decisive role than at the level of policymaking,
which subscribes to the more abstract character of the
nation.
Volume XXXI, Number 1
The state, policymakers, and policies
The modern Indian state is an end product of
several hundred years of colonial rule and like most
other previously colonized countries, based upon a
vision of modernity inspired by the West. The persons
who formed the first set of leaders to both free the
nation from colonization and also give it its initial
government were largely educated in the west and
also upper class and caste, the reason being that only
the elite could avail of education having both money
and the opportunity for it.5 Shyamlal looks towards
‘‘untouchability’’ as having kept the low castes out of
the political struggle to free India.6 ‘‘Those agitating,
opposing the British rule and demanding the national
freedom were the Brahmins and other high caste
people . . . their fear of getting polluted from the untouchables prevented them from being associated
with them in such struggle’’(2008:97; see also Narayan 2009). Thus there was a contradiction inherent
from the beginning that those professing equality and
liberty overtly may not all have been in their private
ideals free from traditional prejudices, especially
those of caste. Therefore in the initial period modernity was equated more with technology than with
social reform.
The first prime minister of the Indian nationstate was a British-educated lawyer, Pandit Jawaharlal Nehru (A Kashmiri Brahmin), with a liberal
outlook. He had a vision of a very modern India
(Mendelsohn and Vicziany 1998:14), based upon
principles of socialism and with an industrialized
economy. Nehru was known for his liberal socialist
ideas, and India began as a mixed economy with
many of the key economic sectors such as steel and
mines under state control. Even today the government of India is the largest employer that exists in
India. As Doron (2008:49–50) describes, ‘‘The modern
Indian state was premised upon the democratic ideal
of social justice, universal rule of law and the constitutional granting of rights to its citizens’’ (see also
Bayley 1999:154–162). In fact, builders of modern India, in the shape of its leaders, mostly represented by
the Indian National Congress confronted the colonial
regime with exactly these values of equality and liberty.7 At the time the Constitution of India was
drafted it was unanimously assumed that all citizens
of India were equally human and deserved to be
given equal rights. There was never a question regarding universal suffrage and giving equal rights of
vote, liberty, and education to all irrespective of caste,
religion, and sex. India was imagined as a nation
based on the values of equality and liberty, for as
Anderson (1991:7) points out, a nation is ‘‘imagined as
a community because regardless of the actual inequality and exploitation that may prevail in each, the
nation is always conceived as a deep, horizontal
& 2010 by the American Anthropological Association. All rights reserved.
16
Anthropology of Work Review
comradeship.’’ Even today India is a signatory to almost all charters of human rights, women’s rights,
and environmental rights. Almost every elected or
nominated head of state of India has had a reputation
for being secular and liberal in their attitude.8 Dr. B. R.
Ambedkar, alumnus of Columbia University and
the London School of Economics and a prominent
lawyer and labor activist, was the first law minister
in Nehru’s cabinet, chairing the committee that
framed the first Constitution of India. He belonged to
the one of the lowest untouchable castes, the Mahars,
and he began his political life as a labor leader of the
factory workers in the then Bombay state in Western
India during the last phase of the colonial rule
(Omvedt 1993).9 The vision that was promoted by
Ambedkar in the constitution encompassed his own
experience living in the coolie barracks in the factory
areas. The welfare of labor was something that must
have been close to his heart (Bayley 1999:270–271).
But even as he read out the constitution, Ambedkar
had been skeptical of its proper implementation for
he knew that within Indian society were ingrained
hierarchical values derived from a worldview
engendered in a feudal caste-based society. Thus
Ambedkar’s observation in this final address to the
Constituent Assembly: ‘‘In our social and economic
life, we shall, by reason of our social and economic
structure, continue to deny the principle of one man
one value’’ (CAD 1950:979). In another place
Ambedkar had observed, ‘‘The Hindus are the only
people in the world whose economic order – the relation of workman to workman – is consecrated by
religion and made sacred, eternal and inviolate’’
(Ambedkar 1987).
With reference to the Varna hierarchy as embodied in the ancient texts, the social order is based on
the separation of the universe into four hierarchical
divisions: the Brahmins occupy the highest position
and are the ritual performers and intellectuals (the
only people who can read and teach the shastras; the
Kshatriyas (warriors and kings) are next; the Vaishyas
(traders, cultivators-landlords) the third; and the
Shudras (those who perform menial labor) the last
and lowest (see Smith 1994:7).10 Even among the last
those who perform degrading and more polluting
tasks like scavenging, cleaning, washing clothes, etc.,
are often considered untouchables. Thus labor is
ideologically delegated to the lowest position in
the Indian social hierarchy and subsequently the entire concept of a living wage was lost in the evaluative
framework of caste and inequalities of personhood
that is still pervasive in India (Bayley 1999:29; Massey
1997; Badri Narayan 2009). Although such discriminations may manifest themselves in other societies in
terms of class, race, and ethnicity and may be as deeply rooted, in India and South Asia in general, they
Volume XXXI, Number 1
are marked by the social concept of caste that has a
near-genetic connotation, and also by a philosophy of
devaluing physical labor against mental activities. So
here it is not simply that people are graded but work
is graded also. The manual work done by labor is put
at the bottom of the scale and all such work, often
unpaid, was traditionally done by the lowest caste,
often untouchables. In rural India the agrarian system
was based on an exchange of labor for grain and other
essentials so that one got from the system according to
one’s social status and not one’s equivalence in terms
of work. As has been shown by numerous ethnographies, those at the bottom of the social and ritual
scale received the least (Mendelsohn and Vicziany
1998:30–34; Kapadia 1995; Bama 2005).11 In an essay
based on census and survey data such as from the
National Sample Survey Organization (NSSO),
Deshpande (2003) confronts with a rich array of facts
and figures that show conclusively that the lower
castes and the marginal tribes are among the most
poor and disadvantaged in terms of jobs and calorie
deficient of the Indian population.
Thus the elite leadership, responsible for forging
policies and also implementing them, were also part
of the feudal, divisive inequalities and deeply
ingrained values that were in opposition to the universal humanity professed in the Constitution of
India. With reference to Indian society, Stephen Tylor
has said it is divided into ‘‘the dominant,’’ ‘‘the dependent,’’ and ‘‘the degraded’’ (c.f. Omvedt 1993:35).
One can safely presume that the leadership came
mostly from the dominant rather than the other two
groups. In fact Omvedt (1993:89) describes the Indian
National Congress at the time of its nationalist struggle as a party of upper-caste landlords who ‘‘up to the
very end tended to oppose anti-landlord legislation
and the efforts to protect peasants and tenants’’ and
gives the example of one prominent congress leader,
Balgangadhar Tilak’s, support of money lenders
usurping the lands of poor peasants saying it was
their ‘‘right and should not be confused for the sake of
‘‘humanity.’’ The nationalist movement precipitated
upper caste hegemony ‘‘within an emerging racially/
ethnically based ‘Hindu nationalism’ or Hindutva’ in
which upper castes were identified as ‘Aryans’ ’’
(Omvedt 1993:89; see also Chakravorty 1990:50) and
Ambedkar too dubbed the Congress party as ‘‘Brahmin and Bourgeois.’’12
Thus referring to the historical and political
analysis of the situation that existed in India at the
time of its emergence as a nation, there were cultural,
historical values and deeply ingrained social divides
that made the imposition of a just and fair legislative
system nearly unattainable and which still keeps a
majority of India’s population below the poverty line.
Even most elected leaders had their own reluctance to
& 2010 by the American Anthropological Association. All rights reserved.
17
Anthropology of Work Review
implement such liberal legislations. Shah (2001:36)
corroborates by saying, ‘‘These leaders belonging to
the ruling parties have done little to implement laws
enacted for the benefit of the poorer strata of their
communities.’’
Legal measures in India regarding a living wage and
labor welfare
Thus the article on living wage described below
represents the ideals of the abstract nation, the secular
and just society that was imagined but that was not
supported, and is still not supported, by the lived
realities of Indian society. Therefore as we see, the
paperwork often remained on paper and it took many
years for any kind of actual action to take place, but in
this process the actual philosophy of living wage that
is the equivalence of ‘‘one person, one wage’’ envisaged by Ambedkar was lost and so were most of the
notions of fair wages, equality, and justice for all.
Article 43 of the Constitution of India under the
title of ‘‘living wages’’ states: ‘‘The State shall endeavor to secure, by suitable legislation or economic
organization or in any other way, to all workers, agricultural, industrial or other wise, work, a living
wage, conditions of work ensuring a decent standard
of life and full enjoyment of leisure and social and
cultural opportunities and, in particular, the State
shall endeavor to promote cottage industries on
an individual or co-operative basis in rural India.’’
However, this article was never actually implemented
in any way as a living wage act but was converted to
its practical manifestation as a minimum wage act. In
principle this act, too, incorporated some ideas of
what a decent wage should be in fairly comprehensive terms.
The groundwork for framing the constitution
had begun early, even before India actually gained
independence. In 1943, a Labour Organizing Committee was appointed to investigate questions of
wages, housing, social conditions of labor, etc., and a
Committee for Fair Wages was set up in 1948 to provide guidelines for wage structure in the country. The
report of this committee was a major landmark in
the history of formulation of wage policy in India.
Its recommendations set out the key concepts of the
living wage, minimum wages, and fair wage, besides
setting out guidelines for wage fixation. From the
onset the values incorporated were liberal and universal. In its formulation, particular attention was
also paid to Article 39 of the constitution that states
(a) that the citizen, men, and women equally shall
have the right to an adequate livelihood and (b) that
there is equal pay for equal work for both men and
women.
A Minimum Wages Bill was considered by the
Indian Labor Conference in 1945 and a bill by that
Volume XXXI, Number 1
name only was introduced and passed in 1946 and
came into effect from March 15th, 1948. The ‘‘social
conditions’’ mentioned in 1943 are effectively debated
only in the Indian Labour Conference held in 1957,
which lays out the following guidelines for considering a minimum wage, ostensibly incorporating within
it the concept of a living wage:
1. Three consumption units per earner.
2. Minimum food requirement of 2,700 calories per
average Indian adult.
3. Clothing requirements of 72 yards per annum per
family.
4. Rent corresponding to the minimum area provided
for under the Government’s Industrial Housing
Scheme (Indian Government).
5. Fuel, lighting, and other miscellaneous items of
expenditure to constitute 20% of the minimum
wages.
6. Children’s education, medical requirements, minimum recreation including festivals/ceremonies,
and provision for old age, marriage, etc., should be
25% of the minimum wages.
The last clause was not there in the original considerations but was incorporated as late as 1991 in a
judgment issued by the Supreme Court of India in the
case of Reptakos Brett & Co. vs. Its Workers.
To all practical purposes, although a minimum
wages bill existed, no action seems to have been taken
until 1996, when the national floor minimum wage
was fixed at 35/- rupees a day per person. The Central government raised it to Rs. 45 per day in 1998,
which went into effect on December 1st, 1999. It was
further raised to Rs. 50 per day (September 1st, 2002)
and Rs. 66 per day (February 1st, 2004). The minimum
wages bill is also implemented differentially in the
different regional states of India.13 If anyone has any
idea of cost of living in India, even in the most remote
area, this sum of money can in no way guarantee a
full diet as well as minimum requirements of housing,
clothing, medicine, and health care. Education of
children, recreation, and marriage are out of the
question.
An idea of a minimum wage was mooted in 1943
and was developed in fits and starts until about 1991,
when the first legal judgment favoring labor was
passed by the Indian apex law court. Nothing was
said about the actual amount fixed until much later,
and even then it in no way fulfilled the ideals set out
in the constitution and the practical translation of it as
discussed in the Labor Conference in 1957.
The prominent social worker and human rights
activist Swami Aginivesh has in one of his publications and circulars clearly chalked out a comprehensive living wage program, much in line with the
international discussions on this issue. According to
& 2010 by the American Anthropological Association. All rights reserved.
18
Anthropology of Work Review
Aginivesh, a need-based minimum wage should be
based on the following calculations:
Minimum food requirement calculated on the basis
of a net intake of 2700 calories per consumption
unit.
Minimum clothing requirement estimated at a per
capita consumption of 18 yards per annum.
Minimum housing requirement of 400 sq. feet per
family at the rent charged by government for
similar accommodation under any subsidized Industrial Housing Scheme for low-income groups.
Fuel, lighting, and other requirements estimated to
constitute 25 percent of the minimum wage.
In estimating the above basic needs for determination
of the minimum wage, the standard working class
family shall be taken to consist of three consumption
units (husband or wife as the case may be, and two
children) for one earner, the earnings of women and
children being disregarded.
The need-based minimum wages will thus be
50% more than the total cost of food, lighting, and
housing, when we add the 25% as decided in the
Raptakos Brett case (already reported above). While in
calculating a decent living wage Agnivesh comes to
the conclusion that it should be at least 80 rupees per
day per person, he is also mindful of the fact that the
amount of wage, especially when calculated on the
basis of a day-based or contract laborer, is meaningless unless at least there is a guarantee of at least 250
labor days per year or 25 days per month.14
Agnivesh is critical of those who try to say that
such a payment is not feasible:
The only question that remains is what the several
ingredients (of food, clothing and housing) of
Need Based Minimum Wage will work out to, in
money terms, in different parts and places in the
country. Of these, the most difficult is in regard to
food, as the composition of the diet is a matter of
dispute, particularly as to whether it is acceptable
in terms of nutritional requirements or affordable
in financial terms. In the kind of dispute, some
tend to forget, rather conveniently, that article 47
of the Constitution of India mandates that the
state shall regard the raising of the level of nutrition and the standard of living of its people and
the improvement of public health as among its
primary duties. Affordability in financial terms
also comes up as an argument, among the elite
and the ruling classes, only when the satisfaction
of the basic needs of the poor and vulnerable is
the issue! (www.swamiagnivesh.com)
By the end of the twentieth century, the then
head of state, Rajiv Gandhi, had aspirations to modernize and push India as one of the most developed
Volume XXXI, Number 1
nations of the world. He floated the idea of the decentralized governance by the medium of the
Panchayati Raj and made serious efforts to bring
governance closer to the grass roots.15 The Narasimha
Rao (Congress) led government in 1992 was able to
get the bill passed and implement the constitutional
reforms in terms of the 23rd Amendment, that would
bring governance closer to the people. Realizing that
getting to the roots of inequality was essential for
future development of the country and also to
maintain internal peace, the state further put forward some improved programs, like the NREGA. In
order to give some degree of secure employment to
people, especially those working in the unorganized
sector or those who are self-employed (especially in
the rural areas), the National Rural Employment
Guarantee Act (NREGA) was introduced. With this
program a new perspective, namely a human rightsbased approach, was introduced under the right to
work.16
This program came into force in September 2005
(largely guided by the congress president Social
Gandhi and prime minister Manmohan Singh) as a
rights-based program that makes the state legally accountable to provide wage employment to those who
demand it. It also aims to strengthen decentralized
planning and implementation by making Panchayati
Raj Institutions (PRIs) the implementing agency for
the scheme.17 However, this too comes across as a
half-hearted scheme as the state stipulates a guarantee
of only 100 days a year under the NREGA. Also, the
amount of money to be paid varies from 45–60 and
does not go up to Rs. 80/- as calculated by Swami
Agnivesh.
Even in this rather deficient scheme, the results
on the ground are way below expectations. According
to a Ministry of Rural Development (MoRD) report, a
mere 10 percent or 0.22 crore (of 2.10 crore) employed
households received the full 100 days of promised
work. The average employment per household was
43 days in 2006–07 and 35 days in 2007–08; thus the
overall impact on the economic well-being of a poor
household is clearly small as of now. At its very best,
even within the human rights paradigm, the best that
the state is willing to do is far below the fair requirements of a living wage.18
Although a minimal unemployment allowance
is mandatory under the NREGA, state governments
in general have desisted from paying unemployment
allowances to below the poverty level (BPL) job seekers under this act. At least that was the finding of a
national study on the role of Panchayati Raj Institutions (PRIs) in the implementation of NREGA during
April to December 2007 by PRIA, an NGO. As much
as 68 percent of the 4,680 households surveyed in 20
districts of 13 states covered by the NREGA had not
& 2010 by the American Anthropological Association. All rights reserved.
19
Anthropology of Work Review
been provided with a job within the stipulated period
of 15 days as specified under the law. Yet, the state
authorities had denied payment of unemployment
allowance to them. The functionaries of PRIA, Manoj
Rai and Rakesh Kumar Sinha, maintained that no
beneficiary under the scheme had been paid unemployment allowance by the state governments in
violation of the law. The states surveyed were
Bihar, Chhattisgarh, Gujarat, Haryana, Himachal
Pradesh, Jharkhand, Kerala, Madhya Pradesh, Orissa,
Rajasthan, Uttarakhand, Uttar Pradesh, and West
Bengal. The reason: these states were unwilling to
dole out the money. Such payments reflected poorly
on the performance of the state and the officials concerned, who could invite penal action. (The Hindu
11th Oct, 2008).
Thus there is a further complexity involved: the
complete apathy of the state officials towards implementing any program for the poor. The last part of the
news item is also interesting in that if they pay unemployment allowance it would be revealed that they
have made no efforts to provide employment in the
first place. One must also question why there is such
an anti-poor attitude of the state officials, a fact that is
often brought to light by reports and studies. For example, in the human rights watch report prepared by
Smita Narula (1999:28) it is explicitly mentioned that
‘‘regulations that prohibit alienation of Dalit lands, set
ceiling on a single landowner’s holdings, or allocate
surplus government lands to scheduled castes and
scheduled tribes have been largely ignored, or worse
manipulated by upper castes with the help of district
administrators.’’
The Indian state is run by a huge machinery of
bureaucrats, not unlike the German context (Weber
1947), known in popular parlance as ‘‘Babu raj,’’ referring back to the colonial era when the British ran
their empire with the help of locally recruited people,
selected mostly from the upper castes, to implement
their rule (often tyrannical) on the local people. It is
well recognized in India that even after independence
the ‘‘babus’’ (name by which the British called their
clerical staff) retain their attitude of indifference and
are sometimes hostile towards the common man. In
popular media the ‘‘babu’’ is often stereotyped as
corrupt and inefficient. For example, in the advertisement of a reputed tea company (Tata Tea), the camera
spans over various images of officials accepting bribes
and then says,‘‘ They eat [accept bribes] because we
give them to eat. Now wake up, stop eating and start
drinking’’; a steaming cup of tea appears on the
screen. The advertisement is to be interpreted as a
complex of several messages: first that officials are as
a rule corrupt, second that they are corrupt because
the civil society allows them to be so by giving in to
their demands, and third, of course, that if you drink
Volume XXXI, Number 1
this popular brand of tea your thinking will improve
(see also Chowdhury 2006).
In spite of legislations for reservation of posts for
members of the lower castes and marginal groups,
most upper echelon officials continue to be members
of the elite caste/class groups of society (Ram 2008:17;
Deshpande 2003:196). In fact, data quoted by Deshpande (198) shows that in addition to the upper echelons of government service, upper castes predominate
even in the high ranks of the private sector, where
Brahmins are represented in disproportionately large
numbers. ‘‘There is also less formal or micro-level evidence that the lower castes are severely underrepresented in all the modern professions including
the academic professions’’ (Deshpande 199). Thus
there is enough data and research to indicate that
most people responsible for implementation of policies – and even to influence them, such as higher-rung
government officials, professors, and economists – are
upper caste and class.
It becomes evident that the attempts at the more
abstract level of legislation to create conditions legally
and politically for a just society failed at the level of
actuality where little by way of social justice has yet
been achieved in India.
The Reality
The poorest and most exploited sector of labor in
India is in the unorganized sector because they are
comprised largely of the untouchables, or Dalit castes
of society. They are the landless poor who are pushed
out at the slightest exigency. ‘‘Most of the fast growing number of Untouchables who have migrated for
work outside their village are to be found on building
sites and roads in the towns and cities, quarrying rock
and making bricks, pulling rickshaws and handcarts,
scavenging for waste materials or occasionally performing some acquired but low prestige skill such as
repairing motor vehicles’’ (Mendelsohn and Vicziany
1998:34). Again no one can claim that the untouchables are the only poor people in India. The tribes,
often displaced from their homelands by projects such
as dams, are also desperately poor and form part of
such workforces as do other marginalized caste
groups who have lost their traditional work in the
spate of capitalist penetration, such as Gaduliya
Lohars (blacksmiths) and folk artists and performers).
There are also the minorities such as poor Muslims
and other groups including the poor from the upper
castes. But there is an ideological convergence of the
categories of being poor, working class, and low caste.
People may be stigmatized as equivalent to untouchables because they are performing menial labor.
For example, in a television report, the poor Brahmins
were caught on camera saying that they would
rather starve than do menial work alongside the
& 2010 by the American Anthropological Association. All rights reserved.
20
Anthropology of Work Review
untouchables. Thus there is an inextricable link
between poverty, caste, and discrimination that
pervades most sections of Indian society.
In any of India’s large cities, what one gets to see
on a construction site are men, women, and children
huddled into temporary shelters built on site near
any major construction work, made out of pieces of
cloth, rubber or tarpaulin sheets, raw bricks, etc.
They are little more than kennels that barely cover
the head and body of a person in a sitting position.
While mothers are working, small babies are put
inside temporary cloth hammocks hung on a nearby
tree, or are simply left on the ground to play in the
dirt. Quite often one hears a baby wailing for its
mother who may be away or too busy to attend to it.
With the strong legislation against child labor
children are not employed formally at such sites
but may work informally with their parents, or help
by taking care of smaller siblings or cooking and
cleaning up.19 They are always meagerly dressed,
barefoot and dirty, with noses running and matted
hair.
If one watches what the people eat for a meal –
never more than two per day– it is always either a
stack of dry wheat roti (a kind of flat bread) or rice (if
they are from a rice-eating zone) and water. There is
no effort to provide potable water, and the laborers
drink any kind of water available at the construction
site. To get work is highly competitive and ‘‘claims for
higher wages are the stuff of bitter, even violent conflict’’ (Mendelsohn and Vicziany 1998:32).
Quite often if the poor ask for their rights they
are subjected to violence and are sure to lose the job.
Based on published government reports, Massey
(1997:27) has summed up the three main reasons for
violence committed on vulnerable and weak sections
of Indian society. They are: ‘‘1) unresolved disputes
related to allotment of government land or distribution of surplus land to landless; 2) tension and
bitterness created by non-payment or underpayment
of minimum wages prescribed by state governments;
and 3) resentment against the Dalit’s manifestation of
awareness of their own rights.’’
I remember once talking to a young couple from
Rajasthan who were struggling to keep out the cold
on a chilly winter night, sitting out in the open since
they had no hut or shelter, as they were at that time
not employed. They just sat out in the cold, smoking
hemp, to somehow create an illusion of comfort. Their
story was so typical of thousands of such men and
women. The man was too shy to speak about their
misfortune. But the woman said:
There was a drought in our village two years
back. We have no land in the village and we got a
living by working on other people’s fields but
Volume XXXI, Number 1
since there was no rain, there were no crops and
no work for us. We came to the city to look for
work and worked on a construction site. But my
husband fell down from a height while working
and sustained a lot of injuries. We had to get him
treated but incurred a lot of debt in the process.20
We are now wandering from here to there, doing
whatever work we can. When we have food we
eat or we have to rely on this [indicating her ganja
cigarette] to suppress our pangs of hunger. [She
pointed to a small huddle sleeping inside a tiny
improvised tent.] That is our daughter. We also
have to think about getting her married. But for a
long time my husband could not work because of
his injuries. I did whatever I could but it was
never enough.
This is a common enough story. The landless are
the first to be pushed out of the agrarian economy for
they are at the bottom of the ladder, and when supplies dry up as in a drought or even flood, they are
first to lose their subsistence. Dreze (1999:73) refers to
a recurring scenario where ‘‘landless labourers found
little employment as field activity was brought to a
standstill while general impoverishment simultaneously enlarged supply of casual labour.’’ More
importantly, such deprivation is not necessarily an
outcome of overall lack of resources, for ‘‘another important aspect of the received analysis of nineteenth
century famines is the view that entitlement failures
occurred among plenty rather than in the context of
fierce battle for scare food’’ (Dreze 73). Thus some
people get pushed out of the system because of their
vulnerable social position and the city streets are
the only place where they can come and their labor
the only thing they can sell. But the bodies are vulnerable to malnutrition and accidents – for which
there is no insurance – and disease. The body cannot
always provide the means to subsistence and then it is
only starvation.
For the contractors or middlemen who round
them up for employment, the landless are only figures, and if injured or sick, all they get is a reprimand
or cut wages or unemployment. In a country of a billion people, there is always enough of a labor supply
to fill in the gaps. Even more than 50 years after India
got a constitution that vowed to put human rights and
a decent life for all citizens on its agenda, India still
has the world’s largest number of poor people in a
single country. Of its nearly 1 billion inhabitants, an
estimated 350–400 million are living below the poverty line, 75 percent of them in the rural areas. More
than 40 percent of the population is illiterate, with
women, tribal, and scheduled castes particularly affected. The definition of poverty line as given by the
government of India is at Rs.10 per day per person,
& 2010 by the American Anthropological Association. All rights reserved.
21
Anthropology of Work Review
and the number of people at present in India who are
expected to be below the line of poverty is 300 million,
which roughly approximates to about the same as the
number of unemployed. However, the latter category
includes only those who are employable, which tends
to mean able-bodied, adult, and not too old. The real
number of poor people would actually be much
higher if we include those who would be dependent
or unable to work.
Work itself is of varying degrees of security, and
again the most secure work is provided by the organized public sector – that is, by the state, which
employs about 19 million people in India. It is only in
this sector that a minimum wage is ensured. The organized private sector that includes multinational
companies employs about 8 million, and among these
8 million are also some of the most well-paid people
in India, to the tune of more than a hundred thousand
rupees a month. However, most people in India work
in the unorganized sector, like the couple I described,
and have little or no job security and are not protected
by any laws. The number of such people is about 320
million.
Political rhetoric on this issue has been ongoing.
For example, the Hindu, a prominent national
newspaper in India, reported the following news
item:
Centre of Indian Trade Unions (CITU) secretary
and former MP Dipankar Mukherjee on Sunday
exhorted workers employed in the organized
sector to work for the welfare of their counterparts in unorganized sector. Expressing concern
over the ‘‘exploitation’’ of unorganized sector
workers, Mr. Mukherjee said despite several agitations to mount pressure on the government to
ensure minimum wages to unorganized sector
workers, the government did not enact legislations that would help in alleviating the conditions
of the unorganized sector. Mr. Mukherjee said a
majority of the more than 40 crore workers in the
country were in unorganized sector and over 15
crore of them were unemployed most part of the
year.21 There was a steep increase in the number
of people opting for jobs in unorganized sector as
the unemployed felt that ‘‘some job is better than
no job.’’ This was, in turn, leading to their exploitation by the capitalist class, he added. (Hindu 1st
Dec, 2008)
Numerous speeches like this made on many platforms and by many interested political agents indeed
show that if anything else, there is no lack of awareness of what should be done or what the problem is,
and also most are aware of the ‘‘correct approach’’ to
the issue.
Volume XXXI, Number 1
The values regarding labor and the vision of a third
world country
In the living wage ordinance of the Santa Fe City
Council, passed on February 27th 2003, clause H.
says:
When businesses do not pay a livable wage, the
community bears the cost in the form of increased
demand for taxpayer-funded social services including homeless shelters, soup kitchens and
health care for the uninsured. Coupled with high
real estate values, low wages reduce the ability of
low and moderate income residents to access
affordable housing.
In addition, mention is made of supplementing
schools, recreation facilities, and so on. In India, although the state is morally and legally responsible to
provide for basic needs of its citizens under the various acts of its constitution, the actual implementation
of such provisions were not given much importance.
The reasons affecting this lack of actual action to
implement the written laws are complex and multivariate. First the image of India as a third-world
country: from immediately after the country became
independent in 1947, the leaders proclaimed that
overall growth, rather than individual needs, was of
primary concern. In the name of national interest and
patriotism, it was proclaimed that India should first
invest in mega-projects like dams and industries, and
then look towards the people. Political rhetoric, for
example, often includes phrases that refer to the
‘‘sacrifices’’ that people are expected to make in national interest. An added factor may be the successive
wars India was forced to fight with its neighbors until
the mid 70s.
The importance given to larger and more pressing issues such as national security, overall growth,
and patriotism may be among the reasons that while
the concept of a living wage was introduced as early
as 1943, no action on its basis has been taken until as
late as 1991, when the Supreme Court passed a judgment in favor of labor. The state (including the
governments led by different political parties) had
considered its prime duty to project figures of gross
GDP and statistical growth indexes rather than focus
on how each individual was doing. It is almost still
the case. When Indian leaders proclaimed that ‘‘India
is Shining’’ on the basis of statistics they obscure the
fact that people are dying of hunger or committing
suicide because of debt (Nagesh Kumar 1998).
There is also the vested interest of political parties across the board to hide the caste inequalities that
are obviously at work in the poverty equation. As
Deshpande (2003:181) explains it, ‘‘This active postIndependence antipathy towards caste was the joint
product of, first, the nationalist movement and its
& 2010 by the American Anthropological Association. All rights reserved.
22
Anthropology of Work Review
campaign against caste distinctions, and second, a reaction against what were seen as deliberate colonial
policies to create and sharpen divisions among the
Indian people.’’ Thus there was and is in India a tendency for the political elite of all parties to project the
best and hide the worst in the name of national pride.
Next, we must consider the role of community
and family. In India, individuals are seen as the responsibility of the family and community rather than
the state. It is expected that individuals who fall below the level of subsistence or require care will be
taken care of by family members, or even the larger
community like the village or caste councils. To a very
large extent this is also true. Until very recently most
Indians never felt the need of foster homes, or old age
homes, or orphanages. Still a majority of them do not.
However when in distressed circumstances, the family has to bear the brunt of the exigency which might
lead them into more distressing situations or force
some family members to make sacrifices. Almost every family in India has stories to tell about how an
elder brother had to sacrifice his studies to look after
his younger siblings when the father suddenly died,
or a sister who did not marry for the same reason;
there are brothers who brought up the children of
dead sisters and so on. In fact in my own experience I
hardly know of any Indian family that does not have
such a story, not even one. Dickey (2002:219–224) describes the collective efforts of a financially vulnerable
family to keep itself afloat and also to educate and
improve the lot of its members. (see also Jeffery and
Jeffery 2002:23–36).
To a large extent the community plays an important role, especially the caste-based community.
In my own fieldwork on the launderers (Dhobis) of
Delhi, a low caste with the traditional occupation
of washing clothes, I had shown that many people
preferred to stay on with their traditional occupation
and in proximity to their caste members because of
the notion of ‘‘brotherhood’’ of the caste members
who form a support group and also in many cases
effective ‘‘micro-credit’’ systems (Channa 1985).
Villages, too, will normally pool in to take care
of any members who were unable to take care of
themselves. When a collective disaster strikes, like a
famine or a drought, there would definitely be some
people who fall through and may not survive. Thus
the state is motivated into action only when it perceives the situation as beyond the management level
of family and community, or in other words a major
disaster. But it does not feel committed to individuals,
as the state feels they are to be taken care of by the
family, and families are to be taken care of by the
community. In fact more work is done in this respect
by the religious groups and nongovernmental organizations than is done by the state.
Volume XXXI, Number 1
The Values About an Unequal World
Most in India look upon the universe as a divinely ordained unequal world in which everyone has
their own duty (dharma) and must do their tasks accordingly (karma). Thus the wealthy upper castes
have as their duty to look after the poor and lower
castes, who also as their duty must serve those who
are providing them with food. The traditional caste
system worked on this principle and there was no
concept of evaluation of labor in terms of equivalent
returns whether in terms of cash or kind (Leach 1960;
Milner 1994; Deliege 1997). The lower castes provided
all kinds of services only in return for maintenance
that was entirely dependant upon the munificence of
the provider. In fact one of Ambedkar’s first efforts as
a labor leader was to try to convert unpaid village labor into wage labor.
Even today in the interior and rural areas, such
unpaid servants provide much of the labor. Many
people who live in the city try to get some poor person
from their native village to come and work for them
for free, only in return for food and lodging. I talked
to a young man who was driving a rickshaw in Delhi,
having migrated from his native village in Bihar. He
told me that he had had his first cash earning only after coming to the city; in the village they were only
paid in kind. The level of such food and lodging was
always minimal; a few handfuls of rice or rotis (Indian
bread), a few worn-out clothes, and a corner to sleep
in. In a recent article in a leading newspaper, Madhok
(2010) writes with reference to the urban poor, ‘‘The
problem is one of an elitist politician-bureaucrat
nexus marked by a common barely disguised hostility
to the urban poor. . . . Some issues arise. If the Delhi
government were to implement its own laws and enforce the minimum wages that it declares at periodic
intervals, then homeless daily wagers may be able to
afford rented housing.’’ In fact this report, which tells
about laborers being ill-treated by employers and the
system, both encapsulates and illustrates much of
what I have been arguing in this paper.
There is a definite dehumanization of working
people in India reflected also in the treatment meted
to domestic workers (servants). While most people,
even if only slightly well to do, employ servants (not
because they are wealthy but because to do any kind
of menial work is socially stigmatized), few treat them
as fellow human beings. If you asked someone why
they do not give a piece of warm clothing to their
servant shivering in the cold, they would be very
surprised and say, ‘‘They do not feel cold.’’ More
would be shocked if you suggested that they share
what they ate with their servants. ‘‘How can you even
think about that!’’
Conversely, for the upper castes and classes, it is
meritorious to be charitable. They must give to the
& 2010 by the American Anthropological Association. All rights reserved.
23
Anthropology of Work Review
poor and reap the merits of such good deeds. When
India became independent, the leaders of the country
called upon the big industrialists to help rebuild the
country and many of them opened up huge charitable
organizations, like schools, colleges, hospitals, and
guest houses as well as established trusts for education of poor children, etc. But many of the companies
run by these wealthy people still paid low wages to
their low-rung employees.
Even in the case of domestic help and smaller
unorganized sectors most people think that wages
should not be high, for it would make the worker feel
that he/she is earning that much as a result of their
own worth. The basic value or principle running
through Indian society is that by paying the workers
well, we shall raise their self esteem, make them feel
proud of their achievement, and ultimately put them
in competition to the upper castes and classes. On the
other hand, if they are paid poorly and then given
extra benefits or goods as charity, they will
feel beholden to the giver, will maintain respectful
attitude and continue to believe that they are poor
and the rich are rich by divine ordinance. This is explicit in the statement recorded by Josiane Racine and
Jean–Luc Racine (2002:191) of an untouchable agricultural laborer, Viramma, in a Tamil village in South
India:
God only left us these eyes and these hands to
earn our living. By working hard at the Reddiar’s
we’ve been able to lead our lives in the proper way.
. . . Thanks to the Reddiar, thanks to his fortune –
and it is a great one, especially in land – we have
enough to eat without worrying. (Emphasis
mine)
Viramma does not praise her own hard work; she
does not even connect it with the fact that she has food
to eat. She thanks the Reddiar’s fortune, not herself, for
her good luck, just to have enough to eat. Anything
else the Reddiar may do for her is seen as his benevolence and not as his need.
Thus the toiling millions in the fields and homes
of the rich upper caste Indians feel that the rich are
feeding them and the rich must retain their fortune
to continue to feed them. The proper way is to keep
serving the masters. With the passage of time, not
everyone at the bottom thinks like that, but the fragmented nature of the caste system itself makes
consorted action difficult if not impossible. Elsewhere
I have discussed the concept of ritual giving, or dân, in
the relationship of payments made to lower castes
and labor (Channa 2005:58).
Although Ambedkar did manage to consolidate
some kind of an identity under the name Dalit, the
reality of this movement has been very limited as a
labor movement. The shared ideology of caste in
Volume XXXI, Number 1
India still puts labor at the bottom of the list of social
status. Most Dalits, including Ambedkar, have therefore sought higher positions in life by moving away
from being manual laborers, getting educated, and
striving for a position outside of the caste system.
In my work on the Meghwals of Rajasthan, I have
shown how they turned their traditional role of
weaving as unpaid laborers to the upper castes in the
village to a commercial enterprise and are now using
their skills for the market, thereby improving both
their economic and social position (Channa 1995). The
Dalits have tried to project caste as a system of social
disability rather than economic disability, thereby
rejecting the Marxist framework of class. It is by such
claims that they want positive discrimination to be
operative outside of the limitations of economic
status. But this has also situated the Dalit movement
away from a labor movement. Combining this
with the given reality of most lower-status laborers as
low or untouchable castes, a consolidated labor
movement has failed to take off in most of India;
where it does appear in the Marxist-run states, the
internal fragmenting on caste lines acts as a deterrent
to positive political consolidation on the lines of
class (see for example Arundhati Roy’s God of Small
Things).
As recorded by almost all scholars who have
done ethnographic studies of untouchable and low
castes, there had been age-old enforcements on such
castes to subject their bodies to humiliating inscriptions in terms of clothes, mannerisms, housing, food,
etc. (Bama 2005). For many of them, these have become a way of self- identitification that inhibits them
from asking for things that they feel they need not have.
In fact needs have come to be redefined in terms of such
imposed definitions. I had a woman helping me with
the housework. In India, all except the very poor have
some kind of help; even middle class office-going
women like me, even if on a part-time basis.22 Every
now and then my helper would ask me for a good
saree and I would give her one as best as I could. But
after some time I realized that she never wore any of
those. ‘‘Why, Ambika?’’ I asked. ‘‘Why do I never see
you wearing all the good sarees I give you?’’ ‘‘Oh Didi,
how can I wear such good clothes! I keep them for the
marriage gifts of my nieces and daughter,’’ she replied. At the same time rising aspirations and
reworking of the worldview in which the realization
exists that all humans are equal meets with both resistance and violence.
Thus although many may feel that they deserve
better few see a better future in being laborers or being in a job in the lower rung of job hierarchies. The
raising of a minimum standard of living is not something that is envisaged at either the level of civil
society or the state level. The poor feel they need to get
& 2010 by the American Anthropological Association. All rights reserved.
24
Anthropology of Work Review
out of the labor class and become white-collar workers, and most upper classes – including political
leaders – think that it is good to keep a section of
people deprived so that they can keep playing their
roles of benevolence.
An almost universal response to my query to
anyone as to why they do not like to pay fair wages to
their servants was, ‘‘They will get spoiled.’’ Everyone
would advise me, ‘‘If you feel bad about them give
away things but do not raise their wages. They will then
get spoiled.’’ As Punalekar (2001:238) points out, Dalit
writers and intellectuals do recognize the negativity
of paternalism professed by the upper castes/classes.
‘‘Pity, compassion and compromise derail one’s self
worth and dignity. Dalits should stay away from such
trappings, the Dalit writers’ advocate.’’
Conclusion
No amount of legislation or calculations and legal strictures will change anything in India, then,
unless society itself is subjected to a radical process of
re-socialization. The privileged must realize that the
poor and especially the laborers are human, too; they
are not just sponges to absorb their sins (Parish
2002:179). The entire concept of an equivalence of
work and wages and the fact that all human beings
have some basic requirements in terms of human
dignity does not exist for a majority of Indians. This is
the ideological edge to address in a living wage
movement. Unless such a transformation of values
takes place, we cannot expect the successful implementation of a fair or living wages act. It is something
that will remain on paper as it has been lying for so
many decades.
Notes
1 ‘‘To break caste is to cut oneself off from one’s group,
which means from one’s family, one’s friends and from
all those who live exactly as one does one self’’ (Zinkin
1962:8). However in contemporary India although such
adherence to the cultural values of caste may be diluted,
especially in terms of lifestyle, in terms of marriage and
kinship and group identity caste is still most prominent,
as can be seen in matrimonial advertisements in leading
newspapers of the country where people are still looking
for prospective partners largely within one’s own caste
group, or ‘‘jati.’’ More importantly the bottom layer of
Indian society still comprises predominantly of people of
lower castes. Thus there is a caste/class homologous relationship that can be supported by factual evidence
(Deshpande 2003).
2 ‘‘[O]n those rare occasions when a woman performs
waged ‘‘male’’ labor, she is not paid a male work-wage
Volume XXXI, Number 1
(Rs.10). Instead, though she has done a man’s job, she
gets a woman’s daily work-wage (Rs.4). Thus, when
Bathma, a strong young woman of about twenty-five
did a ‘‘male’’ digging job with the large hoe one day, she
was paid only Rs. 4, not Rs. 10. But she was not aggrieved. When my assistant and I asked her what she
thought about it, she simply said that she had known
from the first that she would not be paid a man’s wage.
So, even for waged ‘‘male’’ work, a woman is paid less
than a man, and she accepts this as normal.’’
3 The term untouchables refers to the practice of physically
keeping distance from the lowest categories in the hierarchical Indian caste system. These are those who
perform tasks deemed impure within the ideology of
caste. The term ‘‘Dalit’’ refers to a political category and
means ‘‘oppressed’’ or quite literally ‘‘crushed.’’ Dalit is a
self-designation that also tries to unite all categories of
persons suffering from systemic exclusion in Indian society. It was coined by political leaders from the marginal
groups in order to forge an inclusive political identity of
all such people. The term Scheduled Caste (and Scheduled
Tribes) refers to those people who were put into a
government schedule for the purposes of positive discrimination or similar political and legal action such as
the Prevention of Atrocities on Scheduled Castes and
Tribes Act. The relationship between the three, though
often taken as synonymous is not uncomplicated and is
beyond the scope of this paper.
4 The Indian state is based on the British Parliamentary
model where the prime minister is the head of the Lok
Sabha (House of Commons) and the president is the
head of the Rajya Sabha (House of Lords). The difference
is that the president is replacing the hereditary nobility
as a nominated head and as symbol of the Indian nation,
while the prime minister is chosen out of elected representatives and is the effective, decision-making head of
state. It is the prime minister who provides ideological
leadership to the country.
5 As per the traditional caste system the lower castes were
prohibited from going to school or even learning to read
and write. Only the men of the upper caste/class availed
of British education when it was made available to them.
Some very few elite women were also educated but very
few lower castes, men or women.
6 Untouchability refers to a feature almost unique to the caste
system where some people are considered so impure that
their touch itself is polluting. The system like most others
in India is highly complex and is manifested in a myriad of
different practices, often localized. But the common theme
is that such people are prevented from inter-dining, sharing food and utensils, and excluded from all social and
ritual occasions involving the upper castes.
7 The Indian National Congress was initially founded by a
British administrator, Allan Octavian Hume, who was supported by another British administrator in India, William
Wedderburn. When the Indians took over the Congress as
a vehicle to fight British Imperialism they retained the secular and western values inherent in this organization as
opposed to more grassroots Indian political parties like the
& 2010 by the American Anthropological Association. All rights reserved.
25
Anthropology of Work Review
Bharatiya Janata Party (BJP) founded by Shyama Prasad
Mukherjee, an out and out Hindu Indian Nationalist. But
in actual terms the Congress was by virtue of its uppercaste leaders a mostly Hindu organization too, and the
Hindu morality was used by them as a tool to fight western oppression (see Partha Chatterjee 1993).
8 India has the reputation for having people of different
religion and social status as well as high educational
achievements among its top leaders, such as the eminent
philosopher Dr. Sarvapalli Radhakrishan (former president), the nuclear physicist Dr. Abdul Kalam (former
president) and the present prime minister Dr. Manmohan Singh, an eminent economist of world repute.
9 Although a majority of the lower castes were deprived of
education, some reformist upper caste and rich people like
the Maharaja of Mysore sponsored brilliant and
deserving Dalit children, like Ambedkar, to pursue
higher studies. It must also be mentioned that the leaders
of the Dalit movement, like Jyotiba Phule and Periyar, laid
a great deal of emphasis upon modern education as a
means to improve the position of the weaker sections of
society (Omvedt 1993:99). Jyotiba Phule, of Marashtra, one
of the most prominent leaders of the Dalit movement, described the scientific knowledge imparted through
colonial rule as ‘‘vidya’’ as opposed to the Brahmanical
teachings of Hinduism, ‘‘Shashtra.’’ Thus the Dalits also
preferred to emulate the western lifestyle. For example,
unlike all other Hindu upper-caste Nationalist leaders,
wearing Indian dress, Ambedkar is always seen (and depicted) in a western-style suit and tie.
10 Shashtras was the knowledge contained in the Sanskrit
texts, especially the Vedas. Only Brahmins could read
the Vedas and impart the knowledge to the other high
castes like the Kshatriyas and the Vaishyas. The Shudras
and untouchables were kept out of this Sanskritic knowledge. This is what Jyotiba Phule had meant when he
encouraged the lower castes to go for Vidya (western or
scientific knowledge) as opposed to Shastras, the knowledge of the Brahmins.
11 Mendelsohn and Vicziany (1998:33) have shown with the
help of facts and figures that although there are poor
among the Brahmins and upper castes, the majority of
poor, rural landless and urban poor are untouchables.
‘‘We can assume that Untouchables are still disproportionately represented among the poor (measured by
calorie intake). . . . Those Untouchables who are not
‘poor’ are still likely to be found in the ‘Low’ rather than
one of the higher categories.’’ These categories are taken
from Rao and Natarajan (1994:4–5).
12 ‘‘The process of selection also meant a process of exclusion in the formation of the new national identity . . .
Firstly it was clearly a new ‘Hindu’ identity . . . further a
specifically Aryan identity . . . in Bengal . . . led to a simple dichotomization of the population into high castes
comprising Aryan, and laboring groups comprising unAryan’’ (Chakravorty 1990:50).
13 India is a federal democracy with 29 states that divide the
nation regionally, linguistically, and culturally. All central
government acts are implemented regionally and often
Volume XXXI, Number 1
with regional variations. The Minimum Wages Act, 1948,
says, ‘‘Till such time a national wage is feasible, it would
be desirable to have regional minimum wages in regard to
which the Central Government may lay down the guidelines. The Minimum Wages should be revised at regular
periodicity and should be linked with rise in the cost of
living.’’ Accordingly, the government issued guidelines in
July 1987 for setting up of Regional Minimum Wages
Advisory Committees. These committees, renamed subsequently as Regional Labour Ministers’ Conference, made
a number of recommendations which include reduction
in disparities in minimum wages in different states of a
region, setting up of inter-state Coordination Council, consultation with neighboring states while fixing/revising
minimum wages, etc. Steps taken to reduce disparities:
Five Regional Committees
There is disparity in rates of minimum wages in various
regions of the country. This is due to differences in socioeconomic and agro-climatic conditions, prices of essential
commodities, paying capacity, productivity, and local
conditions influencing the wage rate. The regional disparity in minimum wages is also attributed to the fact that
both the central and state governments are the appropriate
government to fix, revise, and enforce minimum wages in
scheduled employments in their respective jurisdictions
under the act. To bring uniformity in the minimum wages
of scheduled employments, the Union Government has
requested the states to form regional committees. At present there are five Regional Minimum Wages
Advisory Committees in the country, which are (Region
States/UTs covered):
Eastern Region (6) West Bengal, Orissa, Bihar, Jharkhand, Chhattisgarh, and Andaman & Nicobar Islands
North Eastern Region (8) Arunachal Pradesh, Assam,
Manipur, Meghalaya, Mizoram, Nagaland, Tripura,
and Sikkim
Southern Region (6) Andhra Pradesh, Karnataka, Kerala, Tamil Nadu, Pondicherry, and Lakshadweep
Northern Region (8) Punjab, Rajasthan, Himachal
Pradesh, Jammu&Kashmir, Haryana, Uttar Pradesh,
Uttarakhand, Delhi and Chandigarh
Western Region (6) Maharashtra, Gujarat, Goa, Madhya
Pradesh, Dadra & Nagar Haveli and Daman & Diu
National Floor Level Minimum Wage – In order to have
a uniform wage structure and to reduce disparities.
14 CALCULATIONS REGARDING MINIMUM WAGES
PER DAY FOR AGRICULTURAL WORKERS
The current figure of poverty line (food of 2,400 calories
in rural area) is Rs. 11,600 p.a. per capita. It is now being
revised. A worker’s family consists of 3 consumption
units. Therefore the breadwinner has to earn
Rs. 11,6003 5 34,800/- to avoid hunger. This is to
avoid falling below the poverty line. If we accept the Indian Labour Conference norms as approved by the
Supreme Court in Workmen Vs. Raptakos Brett & Co. Ltd.
And Standard Vacuum Refining Vs. the Workmen we have
to add cost of cloth of 72 yd. (say @ Rs.10 per yd.), 20%
& 2010 by the American Anthropological Association. All rights reserved.
26
Anthropology of Work Review
15 The Panchayat refers to the five village elders almost
always of the dominant caste group who were traditionally seen as supreme authority, although the workings of
the Panchayat were more democratic, involving consensus from most of the upper caste men. The Panch, five
elders, were seen as God’s mouthpiece and any decision
they took, even if after prolonged discussion, was taken
as final and binding.
with low castes, such as sweeping and washing clothes. For
this reason girls from upper caste/class families often are
not socialized to any kind of physical work, so most
women cannot do even simple household tasks that may
require them to climb or bend and lift heavy objects. One
interesting fact is that women from respectable families are
not to be seen in public doing any physical work. So no
woman will be seen washing her car or the family car. If
there is no help to do it then a male member of the household will do it. But even respectable men are not to be seen
gardening, cutting grass, or fixing roofs.
16 One may look into the booklet, Work for All at a Living
Wage: Towards an Employment Guarantee Act, Jan 2004.
This booklet was prepared by the support group of the
‘‘Right to Food Campaign’’ for circulation at the World
Social Forum (Mumbai 2004). It contains an article of
Living Wage by Jean Drez, the famous economist. It can
be found on the website www.rightoffood.com or by
e-mail from right2food@yahoo.co.in.
References
Ambedkar, B.R. 1987. The Philosophy of Hinduism.
In Writing and Speeches, Vol. 3. Babasaheb Ambedkar Dr. and Vasant Moon, eds. Bombay:
Education Department, Government of Maharashtra.
for fuel, lighting, and miscellaneous items and 25% on
children’s education, medicare, marriage, old age etc.
The figure would then be Rs. 51,180/- p.a.
17 The Panchayati Raj program is a program of decentralized governance making use of the concept of the villagelevel council of elders (panchayats); except that the
panchayats recognized by the state are democratically
elected according to procedures laid down by the state.
18 A newspaper report states, under the headline ‘‘PM,
Sonia admit lapses in NREGA’’ that, ‘‘The prime minister, Dr. Manmohan Singh and Mrs. Sonia Gandhi,
today admitted that there had been ‘lapses’ in the rural
employment guarantee scheme, including the payment
of wages.’’ The Statesman, 3rd February, 2010 (p.5).
19
THE CHILD LABOUR (PROHIBITION
REGUALTION) ACT, 1986
(Act No. 61 of 1986)
[23rd December, 1986]
AND
20 Although free government hospitals are available in India.
the very fact of hospitalization meant loss of daily wages.
Also the wife had to attend to him in the hospital and was
not able to work either. The health care provided at these
hospitals is often poor although prognosis is usually good.
There are good doctors but poor hygiene and facilities like
beds and nursing care are wanting. Quite often the patient’s
attendants are expected to do such tasks as giving bedpans,
giving medicines, and feeding and bathing the patient that
should normally be done by paramedics. This is especially
true if they are poor and low status.
21 One Crore is a 100 lakh where 1 lakh is a hundred
thousand.
22 The reason for this is complex. First, there are many poor
persons who need some kind of job to survive and working
in a household as hired help is seen a soft option for those
who do not want to work in hard labor or those who have
no specific skills. Also most of these workers are women
who see working for another household for money as only
an extension of the work that they do in their own homes.
Second, there is a negative social perception of menial
work. As already mentioned, no high-caste woman, even if
not particularly well off, is expected to do work associated
Volume XXXI, Number 1
Anderson, Benedict. 1991 (First ed. 1983). Imagined
Communities. London: Verso.
Bama. 2005. Sangati: Events, translated from Tamil by
Lakshmi Holmström New Delhi: Oxford University
Press.
Bayley, Susan. 1999. The New Cambridge History of
India: Caste, Society and Politics in India from the
Eighteenth Century to the Modern Age. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
CAD. 1950. Constitutional Assembly Debates, Vol. XI.
New Delhi, India: Lok Sabha Secretariat.
Chakravorty, Uma. 1990. Whatever Happened to the
Vedic Dasi? Orientalism, Nationalism, and a Script for
the Past. In Recasting Women: Essays in India’s
Colonial History. Kumkum Sangari and Sudesh
Vaid, eds. Pp. 27–87. New Brunswick: Rutgers
University Press.
Channa, Subhadra Mitra. 1985. Tradition and
Rationality in Economic Behaviour. New Delhi:
Cosmo Publications.
FFF. 1995. Indian Peasantry, Some Analytical
Issues. In Peasants in Indian History. V.K. Thakur,
ed. Ranchi, India: Janaki Prakashan.
FFF. 2005. Metaphors of Race and Caste based
Discriminations Against Dalits and Dalit Women in
India. In Resisting Racism and Xenophobia: Global
Perspectives on Race, Gender and Human Rights.
Faye V. Harrison, ed. Pp. 49–67. Walnut Creek:
AltaMira Press.
& 2010 by the American Anthropological Association. All rights reserved.
27
Anthropology of Work Review
Chatterjee, Partha. 1993. The Nation and Its
Fragments: Colonial and Post-Colonial Histories.
New Jersey: Princeton University Press.
Massey, James. 1997. DownTrodden: The Struggles of
India’s Dalits for Identity, Solidarity and liberation.
Geneva: Risk books.
Chowdhury, Faizul Latif. 2006. Corrupt Bureaucracy
and the Privatization of Tax Enforcement. Dhaka:
Pathak Samabesh.
Mendelsohn, Oliver, and Marika Vicziany. 1998. The
Untouchables: Subordination, Poverty and the State in
Modern India. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Deliege, Robert. 1997. The World of the
‘‘Untouchables’’: Pariyars of Tamil Nadu. Delhi:
Oxford University Press.
Milner, Murray Jr. 1994. Status and Sacredness. New
York: Oxford University Press.
Deshpande, Satish. 2003. Caste Inequality and Indian
Sociology. In The Practice of Sociology. Maitrayee
Chaudhuri, ed. Pp. 177–221. NewDelhi: Orient
Longman Private Ltd.
Dickey, Sara. 2002. Anjali’s Prospects: Class
Mobility in Urban India. In Every Day Life In
South Asia. Diane P. Mines and Sarah Lamb,
eds. Pp. 214–227. Bloomington: Indiana University
Press.
Dirks, Nicholas B. 2001. Castes of Mind: Colonialsim
and the Making of Modern India. Princeton and
Oxford: Princeton University Press.
Nagesh, Kumar S. 1998. The Killing Fields Frontline
Vol 15(03).
Narayan, Badri. 2009. Shattered Dreams: The Longing
for ‘‘Post Independent India.’’ Asian Studies Review
33(4):443–453.
Narula, Smita. 1999. Broken People: Caste Violence
against India’s ‘‘Untouchables.’’ NewYork, London:
Human Rights Watch.
Omvedt, Gail. 1993. Dalits and the Democratic
Revolution: Dr. Ambedkar and the Dalit Movement
in Colonial India. New Delhi: Sage Publications.
Dreze, Jean. 1999. Famine Prevention in India. In The
Political Economy of Hunger. Jean Dreze, Amratya
Sen, and Athar Hussain, eds. Pp. 69–178. New Delhi:
Oxford University Press.
Parish, Steven M. 2002. God Chariots in a Garden of
Castes: Hierarchy and Festival in a Hindu City. In
Every Day Life in South Asia. Diane P. Mines and
Sarah Lamb, eds. Pp. 174–189. Bloomington: Indiana
University Press.
Doron, A. 2008. Caste, Occupation and Politics on the
Ganges: Passages of Resistance. Surrey: Ashgate
pub.Ltd.
Punalekar, S.P. 2001. Dalit Literature and Dalit
Identity. In Dalit Identity and Politics. Ghanshyam
Shah, ed. Pp. 214–241. New Delhi: Sage Publications.
Hussain, Athar. 1999. Introduction. In The Political
Economy of Hunger. Jean Drez, Amratya Sen, and
Athar Hussain, eds. Pp. 1–11. New Delhi: Oxford
University Press.
Ram, Nandu. 2008. Introduction. In Dalits in
Contemporary India: Discrimination and Discontent.
Nanduram, ed. Pp. 1–34. New Delhi: Siddhant
Publications.
Jeffery, Patricia, and Roger Jeffery. 2002. Allah Gives
both Boys and Girls. In Everyday Life in South Asia.
Diane P. Mines and Sarah Lamb, eds. Pp. 23–37.
Bloomington: Indiana University Press.
Sen, Amratya. 1981. Poverty and Famines. Oxford:
Oxford University Press.
Kapadia, Karin. 1995. Siva and Her Sisters: Gender,
Caste and Class in Rural South India. Boulder: West
View Press.
Leach, Edmund R. 1960. Introduction: What Should
We Mean by Caste? In Aspects of Caste in South
India, Ceylon, and N-W Pakistan. E.R. Leach, ed.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Madhok, Sujata. 2010. Urban Poor at Receiving End.
Statesman. Feb 3rd, 2010. New Delhi.
Volume XXXI, Number 1
Shah, Ghanshaym. 2001. Introduction: Dalit Politics.
In Dalit Identity and Politics. Ghanshyam Shah, ed.
Pp. 17–41. New Delhi: Sage Publications.
Shyamlal 2008. Participation of Untouchables in the
Freedom Movement: The Case of Bairwas in Northern
India. In Dalits in Contemporary India: Discrimination and Discontent. NanduRam, ed. Pp. 92–105.
NewDelhi: Siddhant Publications.
Smith, Brian K. 1994. Classifying the Universe: The
Ancient Indian Varna System and the Origins of
Caste. New York: Oxford University Press.
& 2010 by the American Anthropological Association. All rights reserved.
28
Anthropology of Work Review
Viramma, with Josiane Racine, with Jean-Luc Racine.
2002. High and Low Castes in Karuni. In Every
Day Life in South Asia. Diane P. Mines and Sarah
Lamb, eds. Pp. 190–198. Bloomington: Bloomington
University Press.
Weber, Max. 1947. The Theory of Social and Economic
Organization. Translated by A.M. Henderson
Volume XXXI, Number 1
and Talcott Parsons. London: Collier Macmillan
Press.
Zinkin, Taya. 1962. Caste Today. Issued Under the
Auspices of the Institute of Race Relations. London:
Oxford University Press.
DOI:10.1111/j.1548-1417.2010.01038.x
& 2010 by the American Anthropological Association. All rights reserved.
29