Institute of
Social Studies
I
I
"WHERE DO STATES OF SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA MEET WITH SOCIETY
IN THEIR PUBLIC POLICY MAKING PROCESS?"
A Research Paper presented by
Haimanot Wudu Fanta
(Ethiopia)
In Partial Fulfilment of the Requirements for Obtaining the Degree of
MASTER OF ARTS IN DEVELOPMENT STUDIES
Members of the Examining Committee
Dr. P. van der WeI
Dr. D. Gasper
The Hague, December 1992
This document represents part of the author's study
programme while at the Institute of Social Studies; the
views stated therein are those of the author and not
necessarily those of the Institute.
Research papers and theses are not made available for
outside circulation by the Institute.
Enquiries:
Postal Address:
Institute of Social Studies
P.O. Box 90733
2509 LS The Hague
The Netherlands
Telephone -31-70-3510100
Cables SOCINST
Telex 31491 ISS NL
Telefax -31-70-354 9851
Location:
Baduisweg 251
2597 JR The Hague
The Netherlands
"WHERE DO STATES OF SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA MEET WITH SOCIETY
IN TIlEIR PUBLIC POLICY MAKING PROCFSS1"
BY
HAIMANOT WUDU FANTA
IN PARTIAL FULFILMENT OF TIlE REQUIREMENTS FOR OBTAINING
TIlE DEGREE OF MASTER OF ARTS IN DEVELOPMENT STUDIFS
MEMBERS OF TIlE EXAMINING COMMfITEE
1. P. VAN DER WEL
2.D.GASPER
INSTITUTE OF SOCIAL STUDIFS
DECEMBER. 1992
ACKNOWLEDGEMENfS
I would like to acknowledge, with gratitude the assistance I received from the Netherlands
Government and the Institute of Social Studies at the Hague, for providing me with all necessary
funds and facilities enabling me to continue my post-graduate studies.
I particularly acknowledge the help of Drs. P. Van Der WeI and Dr. d. Gasper. They went
over the first draft in detail and proposed many changes in formulation, and pointed out a number
of important inconsistencies as well as errors in logic and formulation.
I should also like to thank my wife Saba Medehin, for encouraging me at all stages for
making sure that I kept the centre purpose in right. and my feet on the ground.
However, it is needless to say, I alone am responsible for whatever weaknesses may be
detected in this research.
ABSTRACf OF THESIS
BY
HAIMANOT WUDU FANTA
M.A IN DEVELOPMENT STUDIES
INSTITIITE OF SOCIAL STUDIES
THE HAGUE, THE NETHERLANDS
1992
The relationship of society, state and government with respect to political
practice is an old but still a very important and contentious question for policy
studies in particular and social science in general. Some political philosophers,
namely the society-centred ones, argue that the source of policy and of policy
change are determined by the relationship of power and domination among groups
and social classes. But the state-centred ones start their principal unit of analysis
on the decision maker or on the organization responsible for the outcomes.
This research paper attempts to investigate the current policy crises of subSaharan Africa using both the society-centred and the state-centred approaches
simultaneously.
.... We must often study history to get rid of it by this I mean that what are often
taken as historical explanations would better be taken as part of the statement of
that which is to be explained. Rather than "explain" something as a persistence
from the past, we ought to ask "why it has persisted"? The sociological
imagination, I remind you, in considerable part consists of the capacity to shift
from one perspective to another, and in the process to build up an adequate view
of a total society and of its components. It is this imagination, of course, that set
off the social scientist from the mere technician. Adequate technicians can be
trained in a few years. The sociological imagination can also be cultivated;
certainly it seldom occurs without a great deal of often routine work. Yet there is
an expected quality about it, perhaps because its essence is the combination of
ideas that no one expected were combinable - say, a mess of ideas from German
philosophy and British economics. There is a playfulness of mind back of such
combining as well as truly fierce drive to make sense of the world. which the
technician as such usually lacks. Perhaps he is too well trained, too precisely
trained. Since one can be trained only in what is already known, training
sometimes incapacitates one from learning new ways; it makes one rebel against
what is bound to be at first loose and even sloppy. But you must cling to such
vague images and notions. if they are yours, and you must work them out. for it
is in such forms that original ideas, if any. almost always appear.
Charles Wright Mills
(The Sociological Imagination 1959:154)
TABLE OF CONTENTS
CHAPTER I
CHAPTER II
Page
BACKGROUND
1.1 Introduction
1
1.2 The problem
2
1.3 Working hypothesis
4
1.4 Methodology
4
1.5 Scope of the study
5
LITERA TURE REVIEW
2.1. The historical debate on the state-society ties.
7
2.1.1. The society-centred response to the role of the state.
10
2.1.2. The role of the state as viewed by state-centred approach.
14
2.2. The characteristics of sub-Saharan Africa states.
19
2.2.1. The peculiar characteristics of states and state formation
in sub-Saharan Africa.
21
2.2.2. The usefulness of different Public policy models in
26
the sub-Saharan Africa context.
CHAPTER III SURVIVAL STRATEGIES OF SOCIETY IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA
AND THEIR IMPACT ON THE POLICY MAKING PROCESS.
3.1. Why do societies of underdeveloped countries in general,
and societies of sub-Saharan Africa in particular, create and
institutionalize survival strategies?
30
3.2. Essential characteristics of societies under survival strategies.
33
3.3. The response of societies who are under short-term survival strategies
セ@
to public policies of the state aimed for the long run.
37
CHAPTER IV
THE IMPACT OF SURVIVAL STRATEGIES ON PUBLIC POLICIES.
(CASE STUDIES)
4.1. Rural socialism in Tanzania.
43
4.2. Some experiences with smallholder's tea development
policy in Kenya.
52
4.3. The land reform policy and the subsequent cooperativization
CHAPTER V
and villagization policies of the Ethiopian Government.
57
FINDINGS, RECOMMENDATIONS AND CONCLUSIONS
62
BIBLIOGRAPHY
CHAfYfER I
1. BACKGROUND
Over the past several years, the economics of sub-Saharan Africa alarmed a growing
number of analysts; it generated analysis about what has gone wrong and prescriptions about what
should be done. In the absence of a unified conceptual approach to these phenomena, these
prescriptions sometimes converged and sometimes clashed. Because of the methodological and
prescriptive differences, little can be achieved by picking one of the prescriptions, unless major
policy making and implementation strategies are undertaken and sustained by developing
countries. Thus, the massive food crises and apparent failures of public policies in sub-Saharan
Africa have led most policy analysts to focus attention on the issues of state-society ties in the
public policy process. Although most sub-Saharan Africa states attempted to modify their policies
within the broad philosophical views of development i.e., either on (l)the development thinking
of modernization or neo-modernization, or on (2) dependency and the world system of MarxistLeninist thinking or on (3) World Bank-IMF thinking of structural adjustment - institutionbuilding, the policy crises all over the sub-continent still continued with an alarming rate. Based
on these philosophical views and the macro policies pursued the sub-Saharan Africa states claimed
either liberal economies (Malawi, Senegal, Ivory Coast, Niger and Chad); nationalistic (Nigeria,
Ghana, Zambia and Kenya); or socialist (Tanzania, Mozambique, Angola, Ethiopia).
Although the ultimate goal of these states was to improve the quality of African life, these
broad styles of development thinking and public policy making failed to bring the desired results.
Indeed, after a series of "Development Decades" of public policies after public policies, it became
evident that no approach produced the goods and services required. The writer of this research
paper believes that social problems are not just out there waiting to be dealt with. Policy making
is not merely problem solving, it is a matter of setting up and defining problems in the first place.
For most of the states of sub-Saharan Africa, and even for most of the serious scholars the
problem seems to be underdevelopment. But in actual fact underdevelopment is not a problem by
itself. The problems of sub-Saharan Africa states lie in formulating and implementing
development oriented public policies of long term perspective in a society where the majority of
the people have their own survival strategies. Therefore, this research paper will address the
question on how these numerous interventions of the state are administered to society and why
they are a failure. To these effects, this paper advances some principal arguments.
1. The researcher is convinced that most major policies of sub-Saharan Africa are
a failure, however sound they may look at statement level.
2. The researcher shares Ndulu's argument that in most sub-Saharan African
political systems, whether civilian or military, the majority of the people are
politically impotent while the elites (in the modern sense) are the main actors in
the public policy making and implementation process.
3. As noted earlier, empirical evidence suggests that the broad generally held views
in the state-society ties in sub-Saharan Africa, failed to reflect the actual
problems. Something is indeed wrong in sub-Saharan Africa. But dependency,
modernization, Marxism-Leninism, structural adjustment, market mechanisms,
etc., and the associated theories of public policy and implementation are not facts,
they are reasons, a theory about facts. Debates on how to formulate and implement
public policies are not debates about facts, but debates about theories. This final
point will lead us to our final argument.
4. Most policy formulation and implementation debates are not about empirical
evidences of why public policies fail but about what these factors mean in terms
of theoretical appreciation of the policy making and implementation process. This
was precisely the main reason which has led the researcher to look for the missing
link in the state-society ties of sub-Saharan Africa. Thus, the researcher will
attempt to treat the causes of policy crises in sub-Saharan Africa based on
empirical evidences.
2. THE PROBLEM
Everyone of us may agree on the nature of present day society, and yet disagree on the
process by which this society was brought into being and in what direction it will develop in the
future; and if we believe on the existence of such disagreement, then it is virtually certain that
there will be disagreement on, what must be done? With the same token, policy makers and
scholars of sub-Saharan Africa had been debating on the causes of Africa's problems. A number
of scholars attempted to explain the current policy crises by changing structure of production and
exchange, demographic considerations, migration patterns, African dependency on world prices
on primary products, the rising costs of imports, and lately on the intervention of the World Bank
and the IMF, to the unequal incorporation of sub-Saharan Africa in global economy, changes in
environment, natural disasters, and ecological situations (Chazan 1988:125). However, the shocking
crises in sub-Saharan Africa, the starvation, displacement of people and civil war continued
without significant policy action. Indeed, if there is a need for qualitative development; subSaharan African public policy needs qualitative improvement. But what actually happened in subSaharan Africa was quite to the contrary. As noted by Chazan, state institutions in Africa have
2
undergone a cycle of attempted consolidation, the entrenchment of hegemonic domination,
deterioration (Chazan 1988:326); and more recently disintegration. Some scholars like Ayoade,
Ninsin, Lemarchand, MacGaffey, Callaghy, Parpart and Shaw consider the predatory and abusive
officials of sub-Saharan Africa as the main causes for the crises. Others like Rothchild, Foly,
Young, Ravenhill, Olorunsola and Chazan explain the crises based on institutional explanations.
Other contributors like Azarya (whose view I Share), explain the weakening of the state as a
function of the detachment of social groups from involvement in central activities. The writer of
this research paper also attempts to address the problem of policy crises in sub-Saharan Africa
basing the argument on the state-society ties.
Empirical evidences over the last three or so decades suggest that, the sub-Saharan Africa
policy makers are reluctant to undertake public policies aimed at strengthening the survival
strategies of society, rather they usually attempt to destroy it. As noted earlier neither
underdevelopment nor the logical outcomes of underdevelopment (Le., poverty and survival
strategies of society) are problems by themselves in the real (strict) sense, because they had been
present in those societies so long, however hard the states attempt to get rid of and repress them.
The irony was that, almost all the states of sub-Saharan Africa promised their people
improvements in the standard of living, prosperity, more education and health facilities without
adequate emphasis
to
the missing link in the state-society ties. Indeed, the current realities don't
live up to expectations; at times, by attempting to break and dismantle the basic survival strategies
of those societies, most sub-Saharan African states accelerated mass hunger and frequent "coups
d' etat". Therefore, this paper will argue that underdevelopment and survival strategies actually
are not problems by themselves, rather, the proper formulation and implementation of public
policies calls for a much disciplined use of survival strategies themselves because, society with its
short-run survival strategies in no way displays a commitment towards public policies aimed for
the long-run unless the policy strengthens the survival strategies themselves. Nevertheless, here
we have to note that sub-Saharan Africa is a region including about 45 countries and a population
of 450 million people. Even though it is a vast continent that defies easy generalization. Amid its
diversity and complexity some important common characteristics stand out.
A. Most people in sub-Saharan Africa live in the rural areas and work in the agricultural
sector. The average for the sub-continent is eighty three percent with strong lj.R'd agricultural
concentration of people, however, "it is also the only region in the developing world where per
capita food production declined over the last two decades" (Spencer 1986:215).
B. In spite of various policy efforts with different orientations, the sub-continent is still
unable to feed its people, to cope up with the increasing rates of population, and to breakaway
with the staggering malnutrition and pervasive poverty problems.
C. In most sub-Saharan Africa, colonialism failed to integrate society into a larger and
viable systems. Consequently, the post-colonial states of sub-Saharan Africa does not exist in the
3
context of the morality of the sub-Saharan Africa society. And finally it is the only region where
a high degree of institutionalized survival strategies are widely practised.
Therefore, after thoroughly viewing the glaring disparities between the short term survival
strategies of sub-Saharan societies and the long term development oriented public policies of the
state this paper hypothesises the following.
4. WORKlNG HYPOTI-IESISES
1. This research paper hypothesises that the causes for the current policy crises in
sub-Saharan Africa lies in formulating and implementing development oriented
public policies of long-term perspective in a society where the majority of the
people have their own short term survival strategies of different form.
2. It also hypothesise that society with its short-run survival strategies in no way
displays a commitment towards public policies aimed for the long-run unless the
policy strengthens the survival strategies themselves.
3. Those policies
which strengthen the survival strategies themselves bring
qualitative improvement for the public policy making process and the society at
large.
5. METHODOLOGY
The starting point for the analysis is survey of literature. This survey will contain
inf ormation on the historical debates' of state-society ties; on the important elements and
characteristics of the long-range state-building public policies of sub-Saharan Africa; on the
short-run survival strategies of society and on how they affect public policy making and
implementation.
The second step in the analysis will be a look at practical policy formulation and
implementation practice from three countries in sub-Saharan Africa; one which considers the
basic survival strategies of society and which was a success; and the other two which do not
consider the survival strategies of society and which were a failure.
The third step in the analysis will indicate where states and societies could positively meet
in the public policy making and implementation process. This step also highlights an alternative
policy formulation and implementation options. To these effects, the research will assess the
effectiveness of the current theoretical approaches towards policy making and implementation
practice in light of state-society ties in sub-Saharan Africa.
Thus, the sequence of the analysis logically follows the propositions and hypothesises
4
stated, and attempts to show the impact of survival strategies on public policies of state,
theoretically and empirically. To begin with, the historical debate on the state-society ties in
general and the peculiar characteristics of the state and state formation in sub-Saharan Africa will
be explored. And secondly our investigation will concentrate on defining the general causes and
ways of manifestations of survival strategies in the context of sub-Saharan Africa. The exploration
of state-society ties in general and state-society ties in sub-Saharan Africa in particular, coupled
with brief investigation of the responses of societies to public policy, will give us the chance to
ascertain the validi ty of our hypotheses i.e, hypothesis No.1 and hypothesis No.2. And finally
based on the theoretical findings of chapter II and chapter III the research attempts to investigate
three public policies from sub-Saharan Africa namely, from Ethiopia, Kenya, and Tanzania.
These public policies were selected for a number of reasons.
1. All of them deal with the agricultural sector, and since most of the sub-Saharan
African countries are characterized by subsistence peasant producers, the
treatment of the peasants and their survival strategies vis a vis the long range
agricultural policies of the state is of paramount importance for analysis and
generalization.
2. All the three policies were very sound at statement level and were aimed at
improving the chronic problems of the majority i.e, the agrarian poor, however,
both the villagization efforts were a failure because they were very ambitious and
aimed for the long run while the Kenyan case was a success because it was aimed
at the survival strategies themselves.
3. It was also possible to find adequate materials and data on all of the three cases.
Therefore, using both the theoretical and the empirical findings the researcher believes that, it
is possible to draw valid conclusions at least for the survival strategies of the peasant vis a vis
agricultural policies.
6. SCOPE OF TIlE STUDY
Although some of the findings of the research may be extended to all underdeveloped
countries where survival strategies are highly institutionalized, the study will be limited to subSaharan Africa alone; all examples of the long run strategies of the state and survival strategies
of society will be drawn from this region, particularly from the agricultural sector and the peasant
respectively. Moreover, an attempt to treat failures of public policies based on survival strategies
is relatively a new approach and all new approaches and theories have their own limitations; this
approach is no an exception. Although it may serve as a spring board for new ways of thinking
amid failures of different approaches, different policies and different theories; it also requires
5
further treatment and test in the general underdevelopment context. Moreover, its level of
generalization and lack of access to adequate data are severe constraints in the investigation
process.
6
CHAPTERD
2. LITERATURE REVIEW
2.1. TIlE I-DSTORICAL DEBATE ON TIlE STATE-SOCIETY TIES.
In every age there are certain key words which, by their continuous use and significance,
mark greater influence upon the nature and directions of men's thinking. Throughout the history
of organized thought, such words as society, state and government have been notable not merely
for their wide use as a linguistic tools but for their symbolic value in the thoughts and convictions
of different philosophers and scholars. In the history of political thought, the term state and its
role have been treated by different scholars differently, both as normative and descriptive
concepts. Normative theorists tried to show that obedience to the state is the highest form of
political obligation; they also believed that power concentration in the hands of a single
authoritative body is an indispensable part of the political order. In contrast, the descriptive
theorists singled out the state among all social institutions as the only one that is distinctively
political and regard the description and analysis of the state as the central problems of political
science. Christopher Lloyd, in his introductory remarks on social theory and political practices
said
The specifications of the political domain and political action have long been
a problem for theorists and philosophers. Should politics be seen primarily; say,
as a set of techniques for achieving the particular social goals of particular groups,
or perhaps as a set of ideas and practices which has the effect of legitimating the
implementations of such goals? Or is it necessary that there be a public space for
distribution about society and political goals - a forum for ideas - before there can
be said to be politics" (Lloyd 1983:3).
ft ••••
This statement indicates the problems associated in determining the actual actors in the
policy making process. Nonetheless, human life is full of decisions; decisions are made every day
of our lives and the results of these decisions depend on a number of controllable and
uncontrollable factors. Our success and failure depend on how well we control and take care of
these factors to attain our goals. Of course, despite our efforts to control and take care of the
factors, we may make wrong decisions. And beyond these decisions at the personal level there are
decisions made by governments which directly or indirectly affect a group, or a society at large.
But how, why and when these decisions are arrived at and are implemented are the central
questions for contemporary political scientists. All political scientists attempt to investigate the
policy making process with government focusing on the factors that influence decision makers.
Bjorkman on his mini-lecture on Perspective of Political Analysts emphasized
7
"Since observers tend to see different things from different perspectives it is
important to be aware of these distinguishable models - - or lenses - - and their
use."
With the same line of argument, the current theoretical approaches to explain policy outcomes
are faced by two major alternative responses. The society-centred approach address the question
based on the premises that
"... causes of decisions made to adapt, pursue and change public policies lie in
understanding relationships of power, and competition among individuals, groups
or classes in society or in international extensions of class based societies (Grindle
and Thomas 1989:216).
Consequently, the society-centred approach views the state as a political arena in which basic
social and economic conflicts are fought out. And to arbitrate these social concerns - - such as
ethnicity, religion and other shared values - - and economic conflicts the actors operating within
the state use power, authority and influence. This society-based approach is a commonly held
assumption both by the liberals and a variety of Marxists. In Theda Skocpol's words,
".... This general way of thinking about the state is in fact common to liberal and
Marxist varieties of social theory. Between these broad traditions of social theory,
the crucial difference of opinion is over which means the political arena
distinctively embodies: fundamentally consensually based legitimate authority, or
fundamentally coercive domination. And this difference parallels the different
views about the basis of social order held by each theoretical tradition" (Skocpol
1979:25).
Indeed, for the society-based approach, the government is no more than the people's
instrument for shaping their own history. But, the state-centred approach deals with the state
seriously as a macro-structure and conceives it not merely as an arena where socio-economic
struggles are fought out, but also as a set of administrative, policing and military organization
headed and more or less well coordinated by, an executive authority and different institutions.
Thus, the fundamental state institutions are assumed to be autonomous from the dominant classclass control. Therefore, the approach maintains that the perceptions and interactions of policy
elites and the broad orientations of the state are the most determinant factors for policy choices
and their subsequent implementations. Consequently their principal unit of analysis in the policy
making process revolves around the decision maker or the institutions directly involved in policy
outcomes
An enquiry to the role of the state in the political and economic life of organized society
had been a subject of discussion throughout the medieval and contemporary era. Basically, some
view the state as a body of persons who are politically organized at large; others, consider the state
as the institute of the government alone. Therefore, it was natural for the political philosophers
to view the role of the state differently. Nevertheless, almost all the scholars assume that the
primary function of the state is to maintain order and security by some sort of force. Since this
assumption in turn requires an establishment of different institutions with the capacity to form
8
policies and laws, and a body to implement these policies and laws, the limits of the state's
activity, the accountability and relative autonomy of the state, are an on going debate.
9
2.1.1.The society-centred response to the role of the state
The attempt to enquire into the roots of the society-centred approach is a complicated
matter, and any effort to address the roots of this approach will require us to discuss the history
of the human race. But being less ambitious we can start our enquiry from the secularization of
modern culture. About two hundred years ago two books appeared which between them raised
the major issues that have dominated political thought for the two centuries since. These books
were Rousseau's "Social Contract" (1762) and Adam Smith's "Wealth of Nation" (1776.).
The
history of the modern society-centred response and state centred response to the role of the state
gained popularity in the works of both Rousseau and Adam Smith and their followers. Adam
Smith considered consumption as the sole end purpose of production. Consequently, for the
achievement of this end he recommended a system of economic freedom.
".... Given a certain framework of law and order and certain governmental services (of
which more hereafter), they conceived that the object of economic activity was best
attained by a system of spontaneous co -operation. As consumers, the citizens should be
free to buy what best pleased their fancy. As producers, as worker, or as owners and
organizers of the means of production, they should be free to use their labour or their
property in ways which, in their judgement, would bring them the maximum reward in
money or satisfaction. It is the impersonal mechanism of the market which, on this view,
brings it about that the interests of the different individuals are harmonized" (Lord
Robbins 1978:11)
Indeed, the maxim of Adam Smith and his followers was "that government which governs
the least is the best." Consequently, the role of the state was viewed to be efficient if it is minimal.
Prior to Adam Smith, Rousseau, responding to Hobbes, indicated how society should act
to optimize a single value, namely, internal order. He advocated both freedom for the citizen and
a well-ordered society that would avoid both anarchy and tyranny. Identification with the society
and the elimination of special interest organizations are, then, among the main conditions that
according to Rousseau will permit a state to be stable though the members feel free in it. Even
though they have some major differences on the question of the civic virtue, both of them
accepted the absence of intermediary organizations. Thus, in both Smithian and Rousseauian
versions of the theory of the individual and the state, the societal system with its institutions and
relationships disappears.
In response to these vital differences pointed out by Adam Smith and Rousseau,
sociological writers of the nineteenth and twentieth centuries attempted to address the role of the
state more exhaustively.
Following Adam Smith's atomistic model which sees society as a locus of collaboration and
rivalry between independent agents with their individual goals, there will be a natural struggle and
10
was a result of the pressures placed upon it by organized groups in society. Therefore, policy
change for them was a result of changes sought by the social groups. The ideas of the pluralist are
also shared by public choice theory. Public choice theory assumes organized interests as the major
actors in the political life of society. For them, policies are made in a political market place where
individuals seek benefit through public policy and the officials seek to benefit from reelection.
Even though there seems to exist a common understanding between the pluralist and the public
choice theory, unlike public choice theory, the pluralist'S assume that wise policy results from
fragmented interest articulation in the political arena.
When one considers the society-centred approach, one will find the sociologist Max Weber
to be ambivalent. For Weber, politics and political imperatives are based on the realm of power
and violence. Weber considered politicians and decision makers as professionals where the crucial
actors are the political careerists and entrepreneurs. For him the politicians join the profession as
a life choice and commitment; hence, these men must be not mere sentimentalists but men of
perspective. Decision making in his ideal bureaucratic model was to take place based on
conformity to commitment,
popular appeals and careers. He assumed such decisions to be
consequential for society, and for the decision makers themselves. He advocated quick diagnoses
immediately applicable to concrete pressures and conditions. So the ideas of Weber seem to lie in
between the society-centred and state-centred approach. In one side, he points out cultural strains
and their consequences and in the other shows the tendency of politicians and political scientists
to became estranged and decisive because their roles grow more burdensome and life absorbing.
"Even though he regarded bureaucracy as technically superior, he was deeply concerned about its
effects both in the individual and on the society at large" (Etzioni 1983:31) However, in Weber's
model the existence of the charismatic leadership of the magically potent warrior chief and the
legal - rational legal authority seems to place him in between the two extreme societal and state
centred approaches. Due to the ambivalent character of Weber's thought, scholars such as Peter
Blau and Amitai Etzioni have expanded his theoretical framework of behavioral analysis and its
application and followed a different path while Michels in contrast stressed elitist elements.
Generally, the society centred approach which had been shared by different scholars
assumes that the rational citizen considers the various alternatives, decides which he believes in
and acts according to the various alternatives, (for example according to the Smithian model the
individual considers which alternative best serves his interest; in Rousseau's model which confirms
to the general will; on the Marxian model based on the class struggle)
Even though their analysis and rules differ, all the scholars in one way or the other
believed that society reaches a conviction by evaluating alternatives against a clear rule of
judgement. In a nut shell, the society-centred approach studied public policies based on the
societal vantage point by analyzing specific social groups in relation to their identity, interest and
cooperation. As Chazan puts it, this society-rooted research examines political and economic
12
competition over policy and position among the individuals concerned. This approach sees the
political system as open to inputs in the form of demands and supports, and producing output in
an authoritative allocation of values. But contrary to this argument, other scholars who followed
Rousseau's notion of social contract and certain form of social decision, believed that,
" ... the state is thus of the essence of man's potential being, and far being a check
upon his development, it is the sole means of that development"(Nisbet 1962:143).
But after Adam Smith and Rousseau, a majority of scholars started to regard the
implications of all forms of associations such as kinship, ethnicity, religion, class and cultural
associations. Of all the scholars who followed, the works of Bentham and Marx drastically changed
the role of the modern state and the whole ideology of the political community. The works of
these two philosophers were very significant and influential, mainly, due to their promise to the
freedom of society related to the political power. Bentham believed that political power to be
elevated to a point where it becomes the sole power in men's lives. Therefore, the idea of the
centralized administrative state becomes central in Bentham's thought.
As often stated,
co
... centralization of the administration became almost an obsession with Bentham" (Ibid).
According to Bentham the state and its power must extend to all areas of society covered by a
network of custom and tradition. He further underlined that the people must be represented by
a single body, a unified legislature which will be omnicompetent; the state has to work to
exterminate the separation of the individual from the rational political order.
Similarly, Marx's sociological society-centred approach has the same vision of the
omnicompetent state; however, Marx tried to translate the moral values of socialism into the
structure of the centralized political power. Moreover, he regarded the state and state power as
purely having a transitional role dependent upon the economics of exploitation and class straggle.
For Marx, the differences of locality, religion, and grouping must be abandoned in favour of a
rational, centralized society. Thus, for Marx, political interaction derives from economic conflict,
and policies of the state were the manifestation of class conflict. Therefore the role of the state
according to him was to ensure the legal, institutional, and ideological hegemony of the dominant
ruling class. Consequently, he viewed the state as an instrument of domination. Generally, for the
marxists, the process through which decisions are made is not relevant, but the most important
determinant in the policy initiative and in the impact of any policy is the social class formation
and the degree of class struggle.
In another dimension, the pluralist's VIew public policy as an outcome of conflict,
bargaining and coalition formation among societal groups organized to protect a certain economic,
neighbourhood, religion or other shared values. As emphasised by Grindle and Thomas
II
•••
pluralist political society is composed of a large number of such groups that compete and coalesce
around the promotion of common policy goals" (Grindle and Thomas 1989:218). Consequently, the
pluralist'S reduced the role of the state as a referee and they claimed that the response of the state
11
process from the bottom up. The unit of analysis is the specific social group or local community;
the level of analysis is the macro collectiveity; the object of analysis is socio-economic process as
well as political dynamics. Thus, the role of the state is constrained by different political
variables outside the state's parameters. And it is also largely manipulated, constrained, dependent
and responsive entity which plays only an arbitrative role. Public officials are dependent upon
political support.
But the behavioral inclination which began to have its roots in the works of Max Weber
started to attract most of the contemporary political philosophers. Most of them argued that,
leadership when backed by charisma will have more influence on the behavioral model of the
society at large. Pool indicated this by saying "... the change from Eisenhower to Kennedy as a
national leader produced great changes in the national posture toward political life" (Pool 1967:38).
T'herefore, the logical outcome of this opposite trend was what was actually termed as "statecentred" approach.
13
2.1.2. The role of the state as viewed by the
state-centred approach
The state-centred approach makes a sharp distinction between state and society. For them
Aristotle's triadic scheme of evolution of family to community to state does not seem to work.
They held the assumption that the state is more than superstructure. They argue that ancient
Athens, Rome, England and France had formed political states in spite of powerful opposition
from kinship and other traditional authorities. For them the state is power and it is absolute. They
also assume the modern state to be monistic where its authority extends directly to all individuals
within its boundaries. However, this view is not recent, it dates back to the days of Plato and
Aristotle. The idea that the state alone can provide the basis for truly political behaviour goes back
to the beginning of western political thought. For Plato and Aristotle the city state, or polis, was
the ultimate expression of man's intrinsic capacity for social action. Although many social needs
could be met by lesser associations, such as the family and the village, the city state alone was
sufficiently comprehensive to enable man to realize his full potentialities; and thus, to develop
the good will which was the proper goal of his social existence. For Plato the good man was one
who lived in close and harmonious association with all his fellow citizens in a perfectly integrated
polis. Indeed, "The zeal of the state had come upon Plato" (Nisbet 1962:115).
Following Plato the political philosopher Bodin also made a sharp distinction between the
state and society. However, his distinction emphasized the social aspects of human association,
status, membership, custom and moral control. For him the state resets upon force while social
groups in society rests upon a reciprocal principle of friendship. Due to this, he considered the
role of the state as a referee. Following Bodin, another political philosopher Hobbes took his
theoretical departure from order, but he assumed the political state as necessarily determining its
environment of society. Consequently, unlike Bodin, Hobbes was against affection for local
associations, interest and faith. Furthermore, be it family, church or any other form of system of
authority, is not allowed by him to significantly intervene between members of society and the
sovereign. For him there are only two essential elements of civil society, the individual and the
sovereign. Before the advent of the state, Hobbes argued, that there was no society. As Nisbet
suggested, "if we are to understand the historical importance of the state in the western world we
must be clear in our appreciation of certain general characteristics of the state as an historical
entity" (Ibid:98).
This approach thus considered the state as an independent actor and independent variable
with a historically important role to play. Consequently, they saw policy making within the
context of the state. The state is viewed as an autonomous entity with the ability to formulate and
implement its own policy choices into authoritative actions. Based on this assumption
14
contemporary states are categorized as strong, independent, responsive and weak states based on
their autonomy.
Discussing the state autonomy Nordlinger indicated the four subjective
properties of the state as followers; "... its malleability, insulation, resilience,and vulnerability.
Their variations are in turn explained by four structural features:the state's boundedness,
differentiation, cohesiveness, and policy capacities" (Nordlinger 1987:384).
Indeed, for the state-centred approach any state extracts resources from society and uses
these resources to create supportive and coercive administrative organizations. Nevertheless, like
the society-centred approach, they assume that the state operates within the context of class
divided society. However, in the final analysis the administrative and coercive organizations are
the basis of state power. According to Skocpol, "... these fundamental state organizations are at
least potentially autonomous from direct dominant-class control" (Skocpol1979:29). Even though
at timesthe state may work in line with the interest of the dominant class or social group, they
argue, on a majority of cases it does not work contrary to its own interest. They also justify the
autonomy of the state by the geo-political environment and its interactions with other states. The
involvement of the state in the international arena is the basis for its autonomous action, even
against the interests of society at large within its jurisdiction. Thus the state centred approach
view the state as the "Greek God of Janus," with dual faces and dual roles to play, one in its own
class, ethnic or religious group and the other in the international system of states.
Some scholars considered such power holders as power elites. For Mill for example, power
elites are not economic classes but are a unified group based on the similarity of outlook,
programmes and values. No matter what kind of social background they have, they remain an
independent source of power and policy with the ability to negate societal demands if they deem
it necessary.
In discussing the state, the followers of the state-centred approach themselves differ in
outlook. Some express the role of the state by the behaviour of the decision maker or the
organization responsible for decisional outcomes. For example, the rational actor model considers
the extent to which the policy makers can be rational actors in achieving an optimal solution to
a given problem. It further emphasises that the decision makers, however they strive to satisfy
their basic criteria for acceptable alternatives, due to the complexities and conflicts, they argue,
that changes are only incremental or marginal.
In another dimension, the bureaucratic politics approach argues that state policies are the
results of bureaucratic entities and actors influenced by their skills and capacities thereof
competing for preferred solutions based on their positions. The other significant approach which
deserves treatment is the state interest approach which claims autonomy of the states in defining
the nature of public problems and in developing solutions. In contrast to the Marxian approach
of the class based society, states are separated from society and are considered to have their own
interests. This approach argues that policy or institutional reform comes about because of the
15
interaction of policy makers attempting to generate responses to public problems and the
constraints placed up on them by political, economic, and social conditions and by the legacy of
the old policy.
In discussing the state, this approach used different models to express the behaviour of the
decision maker or the organization responsible for decisional outcomes. For example, the rational
actor model considered the extent to which the policy makers can be rational actors in achieving
optimal solutions to a given policy issue. They also underline the complexities and conflicts of the
policy environment which constrains the policy makers to adopt acceptable criteria to make
changes incremental or marginal. In another dimension, the other trend of the bureaucratic politics
approach argues that the state policies are the results of bureaucratic entities and actors. However
varied the models could be, all models took the state as an independent variable in the policy
making and implementation process.
Basically, both approaches discuss the state-society ties and their relative impact on public
policies. Consequently, both talk about on how policies are formulated and how changes in public
policies and public institutions came about. In practical policy terms the extent to which society
and the state should be treated as an independent or dependent variable used to have significant
impact on the state formation process of the newly independent countries. In Pye's words,
"... the general assumption of the colonial powers was that, since level of education,
economic performance and institutional base determined governmental and
political performance, independent states were not expected to exist in societies
that had not achieved certain levels of economic and social development" (Pye
1967:189).
However, proper treatment of the state-society relationships reveals the ambivalence of
political activities, and the political exchange between the state and society. Both approaches show
the political relations of state and society and their wide fluctuations, fluidity, violent, active and
subdued nature of these relationships. The approaches depict the cultural and political
interconnections with their multiple combination of incorporations and disagreement in their
interacting. As Chazan pointed out, "these actions provide a good foundation for understanding
the substance of state-society relations and lay the groundwork for grasping the topics around
which conflict and competition revolve" (Chazan 1988: 131).
However their methodology may differ, both approaches alternatively show state-society
ties and their relative impact on public policies at large. Nevertheless both of them have their
shortcomings. For example, the state centred approach view is too limited as a lens through which
to examine the dynamics of contact and conflict, relative autonomy and degree of
interdependence, coalition building and the actual construction of social hierarchies (Ibid:136).
It also does not deal adequately with the evidence that decision makers are also systematically
constrained by societal interests, past policies, historical and cultural legacies. Therefore, they are
not able to comprehend the status of decision makers and the distinct circumstances and timing
16
of the decision making process.
Moreover, this approach does not make a distinction to different types of states and their
relative autonomy and cOJ'!.straints. For example, in most of the developed countries of the west
the legitimacy of the state is viewed by them as purely an independent entity; however, legitimacy
in these countries more or less involves the civilizing of power where there are limits, constraints,
and responsibility upon power. Legitimacy in a developed western states to some exte,nt means the
mere reflection of the basic values and attitudes of society. This approach fails to understand that
the decision making capacity of the state is dependent upon the strength, power and autonomy
of the states and their cohesiveness rather than their mere existence. Above all social revolutions
accompanied by a transformation of societies, states and class structures, like that of the French
Revolution, were carried out by class based revolts from below. In a nutshell, it is not only the
state that is ihesole actor in societal affairs, but also religious groups, ethnic identities and
influence groups also play an important role ,in shaping public policy.
Generally speaking, this approach does not consider participation of the citizens in the
state as necessary and desirable. Consequently, it fails to appreciate the different political
variables such as type and rate of political participation, the level of working class mobilization,
the amount of party competition, the number of political and non political associations, the impact
of trade unions, ethnic groups and religion on the formulation and implementation of public
policies. However, the relative autonomy of the state can only be analyzed in terms of its
particular political environment and historical and international circumstances.
In another dimension, the society-centred approaches also has their own drawbacks. First
and foremost, they fail to observe the relative autonomy of the state. For them, social revolutions
are the results of class, ethnic, interest group or religious contradictions. But in actual fact some
revolutions were the direct expressions of the contradictions centred in the structure of the state
itself. And these revolutions changed class relations, societal values, and social institutions.
Consequently changes in society had been closely intertwined with the collapse of the state power
of the old order and with the consolidation and functioning of the new order and the new political
system. This approach also views the legitimization of power based on existing societal groupings;
however, historical evidence shows us that in the developing countries the legitimacy of the state
does not necessarily depend upon its responsiveness to the existing societal values. Rather,
legitimacy depends upon the commitment to use power to change the values of the different social
groupings. Of course, the state may contain institutions through which the interests of different
social groups are represented in policy making and policy implementation. However, the
administrative and coercive organizations which are to some extent independent are the bases of
state power as such.
The level of the political maturity achieved by any given society depends upon the
relationships between the state and the social forces it comprises. "Social forces include ethnic.
17
religious, territorial, economic or status groups." (De Boer Sep, 30 class session). "The state, on the
other hand, has a legitimate power over society." (Bjorkman Sep, 16 class session). In simple
words, the state is the arrangement for maintaining order, resolving disputes, selecting
authoritative leaders among two or more social forces. But some societies may be heterogeneous
and complex while others may have mechanical solidarity. Nevertheless, one can not live
independently of the other. As Khoshkish pointed out,
"The view from the top is not the same as the view from the bottom .... This does
not mean that the view from the top is necessarily correct(which is a relative
qualification anyway). At times it may see wide over the horizon but be divorced
from the realities of the base on which it stands. The fact that views are not the
same at different heights, whether mountains or social strata, implies the
possibility of different attitudes towards the exercise of authority by those who
hold it and those who submit. The extent to which those submitting have a say in
choosing the authority, can control its policies and actions and can ascend to that
position themselves, will decide the degree a polity may approach democracy and,
adversely may be subdued by an autocrat"( Khoshkish 1979:310).
The distinction between the state and the social forces is not a clear cut and demarcated
one. Those who engage in political activity could be members of a certain social grouping.
Therefore, the level of policy development of that society may to some extent depend upon the
extent which this social grouping also identifies their interest with the actions of the state.
Nevertheless, the power and influence of these social groupings also depends on the heterogeneity
and homogeneity of that society. Especially in societies with greater heterogeneity, it is very hard
for one single social force to rule. In both ways society cannot achieve a lot without creating a
state which has some independence from the social forces that gave birth to it. And the state
cannot rule independently of society. Every individual or group in society is bound by some sort
of principle, tradition, myth, purpose or code of behaviour. Men are united by common agreement
upon law and rights, and their coming together is also institutionalized. Such institutions of the
state, in turn give, new meaning to the common purpose and create new linkages. To these effects,
they formulate policies and implement them. The impact of these policies is felt by the society,
and the acceptance or the opposition depends on the level of the state's institutionalization.
18
2.2. The characteristics of sub-Saharan Africa states
For simplicity of analysis, states in sub-Saharan Africa can be viewed in relation to state
formations that took place in other parts of the world. Basically, classical political theory defines
states in terms of territoriality, sovereignty, institutions of rule, nationality and rule of law;
contemporary schools view the state in terms of the forces it comprises and interests it presumed
to serve (Young 1986:26). In any ways, the process of state formation in sub-Saharan Africa can
be seen in relation to other similar processes that took place all over the world. In a world scale,
three major types of state formation can be identified.
For example, in Europe, state formation was as a result of the rise of capitalist relations,
and also due to the dominant position of this region in the world economy. Thus, state formation
in Europe was a long process of transformation of the state structures towards centralization the
process that Weber called, "expropriation of the immediate bearers of political power" (Weber
1948: 82).
The second type of state formation refers to ancient states whose existence dates back
centuries. These old states are Janus faced, one face looking back at tens of centuries of past
existence, while the other looks for renaissance.
The third type refers to states formed in a pre-capitalist world system, but with no
\
centuries old tradition of state formation.
Despite the existence of these three distinct types of state formation in a world scale; there
are also essential similarities that are prevalent in all the cases. Some of these essential similarities
include,
"... territorial integration, centralized authority (the degree of centralization varying
according to the degree of economic and cultural cohesion), the predominance of
the role of the army in the initial process of state formation, a more or less defined
boundary and an elaborate system of taxation" (Teshale 1988:18).
Nevertheless, state building in Africa was more or less different from other parts of the
world. For example, the cost of state building in Europe was very high. State formation in Europe
and other parts of the world involved building differentiated autonomous, centralized
organizations with effective control of territories accompanied by eliminating and forceful
subordinating of thousands of semi-autonomous authorities. As indicated by Tilly,
"... the prevalence of tax rebellions, food riots, movements against conscription and
related forms of protest during the great periods of state-making help gauge the
amount of coercion it took to bring people under the state's effective control"
(Tilly 1971:42).
Thus, following Finer's argument, one can consider the formation of the modern state in
Europe as a twin process, "one from consolidated service to differentiated service and two from
differentiated territory to consolidated territory (Finer 1962:87). Basically, this is the same as
19
Anderson's distinction between "Parcelized Sovereignty" and "Centralized Sovereignty"; and a
change from the former to the latter.
After this brief global survey of state formations in the world scale lets attempt to enquire
about the process of state formation in sub-Saharan Africa, and lets try to identify to which of
the types does state formation in sub-Saharan Africa belong.
20
2.2.1 The Peculiar Characteristics of states and
state formation in sub-Saharan Africa
Prior the colonial era there were various successful and unsuccessful attempts at state
formation in sub-Saharan Africa. Generally, there were two essential process at work in an
attempt to form a state in sub-Saharan Africa;
(1) an attempt to expand territorial possessions; an effort to bring under central authority
of various previously autonomous or semi-autonomous regions, the predominance of the use of
force; and when successful the imposition of tribute on the newly incorporated regions. These
tributes ranged from manpower to army as was the case in Ethiopia.
In West Africa due to the flourishing of a large number of slaves for local use, a powerful
movement of state formation and Islamization took place. For example, Sokoto Caliphate was such
a case. In the process of state formation which did not take place without territorial expansion,
the earlier signs of conflict with Europeans were manifest. The most pertinent case of state
formation in an intense conflict with European Imperialism was Samori Toure's attempt. "For
more than three decades he formed a large multi-ethnic state while at the same time engaging in
a series of battles with the French" (Teshale 1988:22). In 19th century west Africa, Islam was a
great agent of state formation as well as slavery. As noted by Teshale, "Islam filled the vacuum
left by the end of trans-Atlantic slave trade by forming vast and powerful centres of political
legitimacy" (Ibid), that we call states. For example, Sokoto Caliphate which was the biggest
political entity in the 19th century West Africa, was a product of Jihad; manifesting the triple
process of Islam-Slavery and State formation; where Islam providing the outward justification for
slavery and state formation.
Nevertheless, behind the religious justification there was also a need to create a favourable
political super-structure. This move served the symmetrical relationship between the economic
demands of incorporation with that of the political needs for states that belong to the inter-state
system through which their sovereignty was to be recognized.
In another dimension, even though, state formation and consolidation in Eastern Africa
was not directly run by Islam, Arabic-Islamic presence was considerable. The primary concern
of the Arabs by that time was the slave trade. However, men like Tuppu Tip, who was the greatest
slave dealer of 19th century East Africa never engaged in attempts at state-formation. Unlike
Tuppu Tip, the Zanzibar Sultanate, which had slave plantations as its economic foundation was
the only case where Islam, slavery, state formation were triple symbiosis. Kabaka Mutusa I of the
Buganda Kingdom also felt the presence of Islam and was attempting to further consolidate his
kingdom.
In southern and central Africa also there were various attempts at state formation. The
21
most famous and most ambitious attempt of state formation in southern Africa was the one by the
Zul us. "Shaka of Zulu succeeded in creating the most well disciplined army ever attempted in 19th
century Africa" (Ibid:23) ..
Nevertheless, except Ethiopia and West Africa the establishment and accomplishment of
ones own African state with strong centralization through incorporation was almost impossible in
sub-Saharan Africa; mainly, due to the intense imperialist pressure. Ironically, superiority of
European firepower brought to a halt the various attempts of state formation in Africa. Indeed,
from Zululand to Sokoto from Luba to Swaziland, the various states newly formed, and attempts
made to form centralized sovereignty succumbed to the dictatorship of European military
technology. As noted by Young, while military superiority was a necessary condition for
establishing hegemony, it had to be secured through institutionalization.... Generally, the new
colonial economy required destruction of intra-African trading systems which were not Europeoriented and the capture of resources (Young 1986:28).
(2) Consequently state formation in Africa took place in a process quite simple; the
Europeans abolished all the previous institutions of state and state formation and formed one of
their own. Taking these two hostile and colliding processes as the key to understanding state
formation in sub-Sahara.n Africa, one can see the peculiar characteristics of state and state
formation across the sub-Continent. The coming to an end of the trans-Atlantic slave trade and
the beginning of the so-called entities called states were suddenly disrupted which otherwise
would have legitimate control over their territory conducive for the incorporation and eventual
peripheralization of these regions in the world economy.
When the imperialist powers colonized Africa, the two important attributes of state i.e,
centralization of power and bureaucratization were not fully developed, rather they were at the
most embryonic stages. But in reality these two important attributes of state would have been
developed if there was some time to overcome the rarity of writing, the non-existence of wheeled
vehicles which, by limiting long distance travel limited centralization, the late arrival of fire arms,
which prevented state absolutism, and the absence of religions with ambitions of universality and
the rarity of unifying language. In spite of the lack of the above mentioned factors which limited
centralization one can not conclude that the family and kinship systems were the only social and
political structures of importance in this period. Rather, in sub-Saharan Africa of the pre-colonial
era, there were also ideal' principles which governed society. According to Bgoya and Hyden,
these ideal principles include,
1. Limitation of power
2. Sharing of power
3. Rule of law (Bgoya and Hyden 1986:9)
In order to realize the first principle societies of sub-Saharan Africa assigned roles,
responsibilities and power according to age, to the places one occupy's in the production process
22
and his place in the social hierarchy. This effective mechanism of tradition and custom to some
extent limited the power that one occupies in society effectively. Moreover, there was an extensive
freedom of expression, to. speak on behalf of family, caste or clan, even though they were at a
rudimentary stage.
Prior to the colonial era in sub-Saharan Africa, society believed that the best way to keep
power was to share it with as many groups as possible so that each had interest in its preservation.
Finally, the indigenous sub-Saharan African states were governed by the rule of law. The
law was prescribed by custom and not even the chief or the king was above it. As pointed out by
Bgoya and Hyden, "in some sub-Saharan African societies the king was merely the representative
of the ancestors in whom power resided or the stool descended from heaven which was the real
symbol of authority (Ibid: 10).
Inquiry into the origin, nature and extent of the policy crises in sub-Saharan Africa
inevitably lead us to examine the state as the structure of that society which shoulders the
responsibility for maintaining the status quo and which are the only means of over coming it.
Currently, a lot of scholars recognize that the most fundamental reality which the present features
of the policy crises originate in is the inherited colonial state, it's method of conquest legitimation
and perpetuation in the different phases of colonialization. As
, indicated earlier the development
of the autonomous sub-Saharan African societies and institutions has been hampered by muslim
trans-Sahara and trans-Indian ocean slave trade and the subsequent colonialization process. These
process destroyed the political and social formation which hitherto had provided protection of the
individual. Consequently, this reinforced the dependence on kinship groups and kinship systems.
These basic units of social organization ultimately served as the corner stones for the establishment
of the institutionalized survival strategies. Thus, this system of survival, remained and retained
the function of being, in the absence of state, the most valued social defence of the African
individual. Moreover, slavery and colonialization also deprived sub-Saharan Africa of the
possibility of developing the feudal mode of production which in Europe and Asia encouraged
political structures and social cohesion that gave the primacy of the state over the defence of the
individual against external danger and in arbitrating and reconciling social conflict.
In societies where feudalism fully developed, submission to legitimate political authorities
and to demands as were made by those authorities, was recompensed by defence and duties were
established and scrupulously followed and the notion of citizenship took place. Systems of
demarcation between public and private interests were evolved, in the long history of conquests,
regrouping and domination, from small territorial units and different ethnic groups to larger and
politically and culturally more integrated societies in which traditions of leadership and
accountability were preferred and firmly rooted (Ibid:11).
In sub-Saharan Africa in contrast, colonialism failed to integrate society into a larger and
viable systems. Rather, using its effective law of "divide and rule" dominated and subjugated all
23
of these societies. Indeed, the colonial state used excessive force and achieved its primary
objective in a very short time. Unlike the developments in other parts of the world where state
formation was over a centuries experience, in sub-Saharan Africa colonialism formed states within
a very short period of time mainly because of the monopoly of arms. The societies in sub-Saharan
Africa responded by withdrawing into pre-colonial survival systems like that of kinship in which
the individual was protected and his needs were fulfilled. Even though, this system enabled the
individual to survive it also weakened the individual capacity to separately pose any threat to the
then existing colonial order. The implication of this withdrawal was very significant to the study
of public policy.
Society by instituting its own survival strategy set itself apart from the state and the vise
versa. The state also did not exist in the context of the morality of the sub-Saharan Africa society.
This disparity between the state and society put the state in a permanent situation of war with
society which in turn led society to further institutionalize its survival strategy in order to
strengthen it's permanent resistance. The state-society relations which developed out of the slave
trade and colonialism engendered two realms in constant conflict: an immoral and ill conceived
civic realm on one hand and circumscribed community-based moral realm on the other. Attitudes
towards organization, management and control of public affairs and resources reflected, and
continue to reflect this basic divergence of interests of state and society. This divergence of
interests of state and society currently manifests itself in the broad realms of social life. For
example, some of the survival institutions like that of extended family, clan or ethnic group will
tax themselves willingly because the taxes go for common survival and in another dimension,
government taxes are considered as a punishment. Therefore, in a holistic approach, the policy
crises facing sub-Saharan Africa today centres around the state-society ties. In actual fact the
contemporary sub-Saharan African states can be considered as an empty shell inherited from the
colonial masters. A state which attempts to formulate and implement public policies, development
programmes and projects with unrealistic long term time horizons with out the necessary social
base and without an attempt to create harmonious state society ties.
Moreover, African struggle for independence was the outcome of contradictions inherent
in the colonial system itself. Education has served as a means through which the colonial state
indoctrinated the helpless colonized people to accept the unquestionable legacies of the colonial
state, which includes hegemony, inviolability and security. Consequently, the sub-Saharan elite
which led the independence movement and were the chief architects of the post-colonial subSaharan Africa states, were thought not only "to give God his due, but to caesar as well"
(Matthew:22), in proportion set by the missionaries and the colonial masters, respectively. Thus,
their orientation and education that they were exposed, and the place they occupied in the colonial
state administration, and their non-productive role in the economy and their appetite for foreign
goods and foreign culture made them superficial links with a society of ゥョウエオセッ。ャコ・、@
24
survival
strategy. The Nigerian writer Chinua Achebe quoted by Hyden, made the following ironic
comment about the sub-Saharan Africa state.
"A man who has just come in from the rain and dried his body and put on dry
cloths is more reluctant to go out again than another who has been indoors all the
time - the trouble with our new nation - as I saw it then lying on that bed - was
that none of us had been indoors long enough to be able to say "To hell with itw•
We had all been in the rain together until yesterday. then a handful of us the smart
and the lucky and hardly ever the best - had scrambled for the one shelter our
former rulers left, and had taken it over and barricaded themselves in. And from
within they sought to persuade the rest through numerous loud speakers, that the
first phase of the struggle had been won and that the next phase - the extension
of our house - was even more important and called for new and original tactics;
it required that all argument should cease and the whole people speak with one
any more dissent and argument outside the door of the shelter
voice 。ョ、Nセエィ@
would subvert and bring down the whole housew (Hyden 1983:34).
Generally, the leaders of post-independence sub-Saharan Africa saw as their primary
mission the replacement of foreign rule by African rule. Nevertheless, the last 30 or so years of
independence gave us adequate experience that these states who are basically detached from
society failed to provide a platform for an in depth process of thought and action, geared towards
the creation of a new domestic order that is culturally relevant, morally justifiable, economically
viable and politically geared to real liberation of society, and the realization of such kind of
factors can only be meaningful if we start with an inward looking consciousness emphasizing the
state-society ties.
25
2.2.2. The usefulness of different public policy models
in the sub-Saharan context
Public policy is a conscious goal-selecting process undertaken by actors in the decision
making system and it also includes the identification of the means of achieving such goals.
Therefore, we have to consider it as a dynamic social process which maybe an aggregation of
numerous smaller decisions which run overtime rather than isolated, single act. In any public
policy making process, what we perceive as the final decision could mark not the end, rather the
beginning of a much wider process of alternative considerations.
Following Saasa's argument, one can identify two types of variables that operate in most
public policy situations. "One the internal environment located within the country's political
boundary and the second the external environment situated outside it. (Saasa 1985:312).
Consequently, to understand the policy choices made by sub-Saharan Africa states we have to
understand the degree to which the internal and external environment both "objective" and
"perceived" interact and shape the actions of the policy makers. As correctly put by Saasa, "the
extent to which the internal and external environments are thought to have an impact on the
policy making processes is influenced not only by the real world situation but also by the images
or ideologies held by decision-makers in the system (Ibid:312). Thus, public policy formulation
and implementation involves not only the policy context in terms of demands, support and
available resources; but also the perception by the state which is supposed to be the central actor
of policy.
When one assesses the available policy making techniques and their general applicability,
in the sub-Saharan African context he will be faced by a number of problems. To list some, lets
assume that the states of sub-Saharan Africa behave based on the concept of rationality.
According to one of the assumptions held by this model the decision maker attempts to maximize
"net value achievements" by formulating and implementing a policy that fulfil the social
requirements. But this approach suffers from numerous limitations especially in the context of
sub-Saharan Africa. Initially, it always assumes that the decision maker knows and fully
understands the citizens value preferences, which is not the case. Secondly it considers there is
harmony and working relationship between the state and society. But in actual fact, states of subSaharan Africa have neither the capacity, financial resources, nor the organizational set-up and
above all the will to address the real problems of the society who in most cases are under survival
strategies.
Thus, to overcome the drawbacks of the rational actor model, Lindblom also constructed
a different model called "successive limited comparisons" or "disjointed incrementalism". Unlike
the rational actor model, this model acknowledges the presence of such constraining factors,
26
posing limitations in the decision-makers analytical capabilities, time, and the difficulty of
assessing fragmented societal value preferences (Lindblom 1972:479). Even though, this model
may seem to have an obvious merits as compared to rational decision theory, it also has several
limitations especially in the sub-Saharan Africa context. As argued by Saasa, the strategy of
limited incremental changes may be useful only on those systems in which (a) the existing policies
and their outcomes are generally acceptable not only to the policy makers themselves but also to
their citizens so that marginal changes are sufficient to society's aspirations, (b) the nature of the
problem towards which those changes are directed is fixed over a long period of time; and (c) a
considerable degree of continuity in the means necessary to solve the perceived problem
(especially capital and organizational structures) exists (Saasa 1985:313). But in sub-Saharan Africa
societies, where there are institutionalized survival-strategies, this conservative approach may not
make any difference in improving the society unless the increment starts from the survival
strategies themselves and this has never been the case.
As a result of the limitations of both the rational actor and limited incrementalism models,
Dror prescribed a hybrid model that synthesizes both models of policy making. His "normative
optimum model", includes some extra rational element which has never been discussed by the
previous two models. However, he also precisely indicated the typical characteristics of an
underdeveloped country and its implication for the policy making process. In what he termed, "the
pure avantgarde developing state" he enumerated a number of peculiar characteristics of such
states. Moreover, he also attempted to ascertain the actual quality of policy output in terms of a
secondary criteria based on process patterns and he found out the following basic characteristics
of the policy making process. According to Dror, (1) the basic characteristics of the policy making
process are shaped by inherited pre-independence patterns, by imitating modern countries, and
by the personal work pattern of new policy making elite. The policy making system is sometimes
radically changed by ideological revolutions or by personal takeovers, but not by systematic and
rational evolution and redesign. (2) Learning feed back is dampened. (3) The optimal strategy of
public policy making in developing states is often one of maximax, with low security level and
high risks. In other words, he says achieving accelerated development often requires a sharp break
with the past. (4) The priorities of values and to some extent operational goals are rather more
spelled out than in the developed countries. (5) Search for alternatives is some what more intense
than in developed countries, mainly because of the absence of policy precedents and because the
quality considered satisfactory is so much higher than the actually achieved quality that the policy
makers are under pressure to improve. (6) Cut off horizons are almost never explicitly established.
The implicit cutoff horizon is indeterminate and inconsistent; both long range and short term
effects are considered without being clearly distinguished. (7) The cultural ecology within which
the public-policy making system operates, and which conditions its basic characteristics, is not
conducive to rationality. (8) The extra rational components are relatively better developed than
27
rational components, but also show their pre-independence roots quite clearly (Dror: 1978: 107).
Thus, following the logical corollary of Dror's characterization, one can argue that the
structure of society has an· important effect on policy formulation and implementation practices.
Consequently, to recommend a sound model it is wise to see how a given society with fragmented
social control and an institutionalized survival strategy weakens the state's ability to formulate
policy and implement them. Experience shows us that important patterns of political change and
inertia that were made in any society and social change are actually the results of accommodations
between, states and other powerful survival institutions in society. Generally, public policy
demonstrates the state's effort, and its ability to make rules and consequently change the
behaviour of the society.
Nevertheless, this policy effort by the state represents and requires very complicated
process, often involving the flow of a huge amount of resources from society to the state and the
vice versa. This two way complicated process is in most cases under constant conflict especially
in sub-Saharan Africa and it is not adequately understood. For example, many of the existing
approaches to understanding social and political change and the means of achieving such changes
in sub-Saharan Africa either underestimate the existing conflict altogether (e.g. much of the
modernization theory) or have missed this particular sorts of conflicts and emphasized class based
conflicts alone (e.g.much of the Marxist literature), or have down played the important dynamics
within the society itself (e.g. dependency and world system theories). Indeed, all these approaches
fail to appreciate the most important and central patterns of societal change and societal inertia
which exists between states and social organizations. Especially, by thoroughly investigating how
public policies are implemented at the grassroots level one would be able to see the responses of
society especially in sub-Saharan Africa where there are independent institutionalized survival
strategies. In Migdal's words, in talking about the formulation of conflicting strategies of survival
by states and social organizations he says he runs the risk of making the ground-level struggles
in the third world sound as if they hinge on voluntearistic impulses. He further argues that it is
needless to say vulnerable workers and peasants are not simply shoppers in a strategy or rules
supermarket. It is important, nevertheless, to portray the structural dimensions of the environment
in which policy is implemented (Migdal: 1987: 400).
Thus, the peculiarity of the contemporary sub-Saharan Africa hostile public policy making
environment stems from the nature of the post colonial state and itsdetadiment from the
individual, the household. This gave the sub-Saharan Africa societies an initial imputes to develop
survival strategies aimed at diversifying and maximizing economic gains within the existing fragile
economic and social environment.
While such a system has its own development potential, strategies adapted by governments
and donors to date have failed to transform it or enable it to develop on its own terms. Ironically,
rather than narrowing the gap, post-independence efforts in most sub-Saharan African countries
28
separated state and society to a greater degree apart and consequently, the state today sits
suspended in mid air above society, unable to influence the existing survival strategies of society.
Development strategies and sound public policies failed to have a real positive impact in most subSaharan African countries, because they have been formulated using criteria applicable to more
homogeneous and harmonious technologically advanced societies. As has been correctly pointed
out by Hyden,
"... governments and donors alike have ignored the narrow margins of survival that
characterize African countries at all levels. Above all, they have failed to
adequately look for African solutions to African problems .... The present crises in
Africa is recognized to a very large extent as the product of human arrogance and
impatience in years past Africa's problems are not primarily its backwardness and
poverty, but unwillingness of those concerned to accept that the continent is
caught in its own historical process of development. Such an awareness requires
patience, humility and respect for those institutions that already serve the
continents people (Hyden: 1986:53).
29
CHAPTERID
3. SURVIVAL STRATEGIES OF SOCIETIES IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA
AND TIlEIR IMPACf ON TIlE POLICY MAKING PROCESS
3.1. WHY DO SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA SOCIEI'IES
CREATE AND INSlTfUTIONALIZE
SURVIVAL STRATEGIES
The people in sub-Saharan Africa especially the peasants, workers and those vulnerable
groups of society have been sensitive to what the detached state prescribes. The state being highly
detached from society attempts to make key decisions about production and distribution as well
as consumption of goods through its public policy. However, society also has the means to protect
its basic livelihood by devising different methods which assures its survival. Moreover, society
is also the best judge of its pain and pleasure. Fredrich Heer spoke of such judgments of the
European farmers in the medieval era. He pointed out, the conflicting forces, the pull and counter
pull, between which the peasants were caught. The "good old law" of the state promised the
peasants a new status in society he said, but the nagging fear abject of poverty, of impotence
before the law, of landlessness, all made the peasants of medieval Europe to hesitate before
abandoning those forces that opposed the imposition of the state law (Heer 1962:51).
Members of any society combine available symbols with possible opportunities to solve
their crucial needs for food, housing, and the like and to create their strategies of survival-blue
prints for action and belief in a world that hovers on the brink of a Hobbesian state of nature;
where there is "war of all against all." Consequently, these strategies in providing personal survival
also link the individual's political economy or self serving action into the broad realms of
communal moral economy, and group identity. As noted by Migdal,
"in stitching together strategies of survival, people use myths or symbols to help
explain their place and prospects in an otherwise bewildering world. Their
strategies rest upon concrete foundations; they provide material needs and
aspirations, such as jobs, housing, and protection sewn from symbols, rewards and
sanctions, are the road maps used to guide one through the maze of daily life,
ensuring one's existence and, in rare instances pointing the way toward upward
mobility (Migdal 1988:27).
Without the' existence of institutionalized survival strategies, these otherwise would have
been impossible for the individual poor to achieve them in the formal fragile state structure.
Nevertheless, the choice of different kinds of strategies of survival is greatly constrained by
. available resources, ideas and organizational means. To put it differently. even though every
member of a given society can construct his or her survival strategy, the existing resource base
30
and the control over access to resources limit the range of strategies in an area. Thus, the success
of any public policy rests on the organizational ability of the state to deliver favourable public
policy components for individuals strategies of survival.
In a society where there is acute social problems, survival strategies are always crucial;
and every member of that society creates methods of survival as part of their daily experience for
the short run. These survival strategies could be crude, isolated or institutionalized depending
upon the severity of the problem. Empirical evidences show that the people of sub-Saharan Africa
are faced by gross poverty, swollen shanty towns; simply put society in absolute poverty. Amid
such crisis it is natural for societies to develop its own survival strategies for all activities of
cooperation and conflict; and institutionalize it. The majority of the people in sub-Saharan
Africa, especially those who are usually at the edge of starvation, death, uncertainty and crisis,
devise a certain survival strategy in order to adapt successfully to their natural, social and political
environment. Thus, they innovate effective survival strategies in relation to the problems and
opportuni ties encountered in their day to day uncertain poverty ridden existence. These
institutions of societies with their short term survival strategies provide their members with a wide
range of normative, phenomenological and existential values aimed at the short run.
In a nut shell, societies in sub-Saharan Africa devised survival strategies and
institutionalized different actions against the state, the state of nature, and against any problems
that they may face. When institutionalized these short term survival strategies of society are
manifested in the economic, political and socio-cultural spheres of the society.
For example, these manifestations of survival strategies in the economic sphere reflect
various modes of coping with severe scarcity and chronic shortages. According to Chazan,
"... the society alters its consumption patterns, shifting from scarce imported
products to local goods. Frequently they have had to change their use of time in
order to search for necessary commodities at イセッョ。「ャ・@
prices.... In the rural areas
there is a move from export to food crops." (Chazan 1988:125).
The second manifestation of the survival strategies revolves around the introduction of
different techniques mostly centred on the construction of parallel or informal economy. This
parallel system, in many parts of sub-Saharan Africa gradually developed its own institutions,
revenue and rules of the game.
Political exchange in sub-Saharan Africa is also manifested between the long range
development oriented public policies of the state and the survival strategies of society. The
existence of survival strategies created massive power vacuums between state and society,
sometimes enabling society to a disruptive resistance to the extent of undermining the integrity
of the state framework (e.g Somalia, Ethiopia, etc.,) as a whole. And in some countries they are
expressed less violently but more fundamentally by quite, sustained and embarrassing detachment.
The socio-cultural implications of the survival strategies are also very immense. For
example, societies in sub-Saharan Africa are characterized by linages, familial network, extended
31
family, chiefdoms, secret societies and local communities. Thus the normative interactions
between these short term survival strategies range from the narrowly economic to include the more
broadly defined political, cultural to symbolic activities. But in another dimension the states of
sub-Saharan Africa attempt to extract resources from the same society and distribute; attempt to
maintain internal and external security, social harmony, political and economic wellbeing with
development oriented long term public policies.
Generally, as pointed out by Goulet, survival strategies of society rests on two important
concepts of "vulnerability" and "existence rationality" (Goulet 1971:38). "Vulnerability" refers to
the exposure of a society to forces which one cannot control. Thus, "vulnerability" shows the
inability of sub-Saharan Africa societies to decide on their own fate amid pressing social forces.
In another dimension, "existence rationality" refers to those survival strategies employed by subSaharan Africa ウッセゥ・エ@
to process information and make practical choices designed to assure their
continued survival needs, safety, liberation and freedom. The sub-Saharan African societies in
an attempt to control the uncertain future with confidence and in their own ability in the face
of helplessness, usually attach themselves to their values. Consequently, they devise conscious
survival strategies, and take survival as their minimum goal. Although, sub-Saharan societies are
unable to maximize their material satisfaction; they have abundant choice to optimize their
minimum demands of survival, identity, solidarity and self esteem.
Any sound policy of the state must therefore, strengthen the outer b,oundaries of a
society's survival strategy, not eliminate its core. As suggested above, the core of pre-modern
survival strategy must be respected and innovative policy measures be taken to develop the
margins of that survival strategy. As indicated by Goulet, even narrow existence rationalities
offer considerable scope for achievements provided thef§ reinforce the dominant strategy adapted
by society to assure life-sustenance, the search for esteem, freedom from unwanted constraints
(Ibid:188). Therefore, any long term perspective public policy has to take in to consideration the
challenges of societal survival strategies. Survival strategies keep the society alive and allow them
to preserve a cultural identity within their impoverished and precarious state.
In a nut shell, survival strategies enable the individual to achieve maximum advantage
from a seemingly hopeless situation. They also help the member of such a group to resist
disruption in the face of poverty, discrimination and isolation. Nevertheless, these resistances to
disruption or government interventions operate mainly below certain thresholds. In this struggle
against change, it is not change which is considered unacceptable, rather the threat change poses
to survival, to the society. Once there is assurance to these values there may be little or no
resistance.
32
3.2. ESSENTIAL CHARACfERISTICS OF SOCIETIES UNDER
SURVNAL STRATEGIES
An inward looking approach aimed at the essential characteristics of societies under
survival strategies may help us to curb the underling causes of the policy crisis in sub-Saharan
Africa. As pointed out by Chazan by, "concentrating on the web of relations and the networks of
interactions" (Chazan 1988:129), it might be possible to attain a better understanding of the
rhythm of unfolding process and to overcome the intellectual confines that have given birth to the
desperate images of African politics today. The web of these relations in societies under survival
strategies is qualitatively different from that observed in developed countries.
Even though development by its very nature may imply the process of modernizing
economic, technical and behavioral patterns it is also a painful effort on the part of vulnerable
societies to adapt themselves to interrelated processes over which they can gain only marginal
control. In Goulet'S words these wider changes "not only disrupt the precarious "harmonies"
. enjoyed by all societies in their part, they also condition the manner in which societies and
individuals can react to change stimuli" (Goulet 1971:16).
First and foremost, societies under survival strategies resist change because these people
ignore the existence of a state of development as possible for them. It is not that they have a
wrong feeling about development, this notion of development is not important for their
aspirations. Societies under survival strategies consider themselves as potential agents in shaping
their own destiny. Consequently, they never consider themselves as powerless. Generally their own
survival strategies will enable them to stop regarding themselves as naturally poor, illiterate, badly
housed, having ill health or poor employment chances; rather it will help them imagine themselves
as possibly less poor and better housed, better fed, and better clothed. Once they have been
"shocked" into considering their "normal" state of affairs as aberrant and reversible men are
psychologically ready to begin playing different roles as favourable to their interest; indeed,they
have become organizable.
As precisely predicted and established in human psychology, individuals and societies
resort to all kinds of defence mechanisms to avoid the shock of an unwanted phenomenon. So
generally, societies under survival strategies need and cooperate with measures of developmental
programmes, if and only if there is rapid short run development, but in reality rapid development
within the short run is impossible in sub-Saharan Africa. Amid drastic demographic increases,
limited resource basis, insufficient capital, shortage of skilled managerial, entrepreneurial, and
technical personnel and limited manoeuvring room in the world political arena rapid development
is not achievable. But in another dimension society in sub-Saharan Africa having no adequate
defense against the contending development forces prefers to reject the process of change if it is
33
aimed for the long run. In order to survive in the short run they prefer to make their own tools,
tame nature, and protect themselves from the uncertain tomorrow. Simply put they create certain
kinds of survival strategies which may enable them control nature and other contending forces
right now.
Once this is achieved they will be aware of their poverty, and the misery that it bring's
to their existence. They will easily understand the prosperity of the very few others and the
greater choices they enjoy; and their own hopelessness in the face of diseases, natural catastrophe
or even development. Therefore, in majority of cases societies of sub-Saharan Africa feel that
their survival strategies are worthy of respect. The society resistance to long term public policies
in general depicts the priority goals held by society and the state. The society view the state with
suspicion.
The first of these values is survival or life sustenance. All objects that satisfy the societies
basic requirements for food, shelter, healing can be called survival goods. For example, in a lot
of instances peasants under survival strategies may resist proposed agricultural inputs such as
fertilizer, new seed and modern agricultural inputs. This can be best explained that survival is too
important and too precarious to warrant risk taking in their part. Due to this, little bargaining
exists over the survival goods. Moreover, such survival goods such as medicine, shelter and
protection may not be desirable for poor societies if one is not sure of the possibility of achieving
it. In most of the cases they thank god for not making their lives worse than they already are. And
as long as men remain convinced that it is the will of gods that their children die or that to combat
certain diseases is sacrilege they will adjust to hard, brutish reality.
The other universal component of good life which poses a great difficulty to address is the
question of self esteem. All societies seek self esteem, identity, dignity and respect, honour
recognition. Because of the material values attached to development which all public policies
attempt to bring, self esteem that the traditional societies and elders have had has been neglected
and increasingly conferred only on those who possess material wealth and technological power.
Consequently, societies under survival strategies resist what public policies claim to achieve
because they feel deeply threatened in their own sense of self esteem. Therefore, states of
underdeveloped countries are in contradiction. In one side they need long term development and
public policies of that sort in order to gain esteem in the international arena, and in the other
society is not ready to give up its self esteem in the development process. Thus, the need for self
esteem in sub-Saharan societies is the most important reason why development and public policies
at large are largely resisted, "if the impact strategy consciously or unconsciously employed by
change agents humiliates a community. it's need for self-respect must lead it to resist charge
(Goulet 1971 :90). Whether development is accepted or rejected, these values lie behind the
choices.
The third trans-cultural component of good life which is important for both developed
34
and underdeveloped societies but which is valued differently by societies under survival strategies
is freedom. Freedom widens the range of available choices with the least minimum cost which
could be internal or external. In societies under survival strategies the pursuit of freedom is
directed to some survival goods. Therefore, within the context of sub-Saharan societies freedom
is seen as freedom from unforeseen or uncontrollable dangers. These people need a very limited
freedom in the spheres of social life in which they feel competent and in areas in which they are
able to use their skills and judgments. Consequently, societies under survival strategy have a lower
valuation on the individual freedoms than developed societies.
These processes place the sub-Saharan societies in a vulnerable posture when their own
survival strategies are endangered. Even if they realize the benefits of public policies as
contributing to their capacity to sustain survival, they may fear that it may destroy their
conceptions of respect and freedom. Consequently, societal responses to public policies of the state
in sub-Saharan Africa, primarily depend on the manner in which change is proposed, not on any
basic hostility towards change. The key to understanding why public policies are rejected is
survival strategies, which can be defined as the process by which a society devises a conscious
short term strategy for survival and obtaining its goals.
Thus, the crucial problem in sub-Saharan Africa is how public policies can be
implemented in societies whose survival strategies is based on the needs of its own short term
existence. As stated above, the core of these survival strategies must be respected and innovative
efforts be taken by policy makers. Goulet, naming these survival strategies existence rationalities,
pointed out that even narrow existence rationalities offer considerable scope for new
achievements, provided these reinforce the dominant strategy adopted by society to assure lifesustenance, the search for esteem (especially in group esteem), freedom from unwanted
constraints, and some form of actualization of its own choosing (Ibid:188). Goulet further
recommended tangible rewards to those in the underdeveloped group who remain faithful to the
core of their existence rationality while contributing to its expansion (Ibid:190). Generally,
societies under survival strategies have their own inner and outer boundaries of "existence
rationality", to use Goulet's words, where the inner one represents indispensable core values and
aspirations of society. And these core values of society gives the individual cohesiveness, cultural
identity, etc. In another dimension, the outer boundaries of survival strategies includes the broad
zones of altitude and behaviour in which departures to strength the survival strategies could be
made possible.
In a nutshell, societies in sub-Saharan Africa are underdeveloped, in a sense where the
bulk of the population is rural or recently moved to the city while physically remaining distant.
Nevertheless, societies in these countries have the ability to create strategies to attain goals of
survival and cultural preservation as well as to choose between different ends within the limits of
the existing conditions. Structural constraints of poverty and accompanied psychological
35
deprivations lead them to create survival strategies which enable them to preserve their cultural
identity. Therefore, they have created a realistic strategy for coming to terms with their
impoverished and precarious state. For example, to benefit maximum advantage out of a hopeless
situation, they have made an excellent use of their ethnicity by devising "esoteric" forms which
maintain in group solidarity and protect them from outside intrusion.
In the face of absolute poverty, discrimination and isolation survival strategies enable the
member to resist disruption. Paradoxically, societies under survival strategies feel better and a
sense of security if the entire society remain at the same poverty level. Because, with marginal
developments they feel they will be left with no marketable skills and without any means of
survival. Thus, for societies under survival strategies it is impossible to make plans, or allocate
time, attention and energy to the future, unless one already possess enough money or goods to
assure his survival in the present and immediate future. As psychological evidences suggest, a
person who is under survival strategy cannot entertain realistic expectations that any conceivable
increment to his available wealth will not immediately be swallowed up by the satisfaction of basic
urgent "basic needs". If this is so, the desire to offer gratification is impossible until that person
has began to improve his material position. Moreover, having internal solidarity and the brakes
on desire placed by their survival strategy, it seems that they have a predominantly group-focused
image of change.
Above all, even an effort to educate societies under survival strategies seems to have its
own problems. Ironically, education can leave the survival strategy of society intact and simply
may increase its frustration at not being treated in accordance with achievement standards by life
in general and by the state in particular. Therefore, education in these societies has to be directed
towards the survival strategies themselves, a strategy which helps that society to survive, maintain
its integrity and identity. Consequently, significant public policy impact on these societies can be
best made at the margins of their survival strategy.
As pointed out earlier, development strategy thus must aim, at protecting the inner limits
of "existence rationality while expanding its outer boundaries by providing rewards to innovators
who remain faithful to core values while contributing to the expansion of existence rationality.
These core values combine available symbols with opportunities to fulfil severe needs of survival
and social control. In these sorts of cases, the state cannot achieve predominance over society
through its ability to formulate and execute public policies. As Migdal indicates, the state's actual
battle may be with social values held over the rules of education and socialization, with ethnic
groups over territory, with religious organization over who sanctifies sexual unions, (Migdal
1988:28), or with the informal economy for control of resources at large. In reality the conflict is
over who had the right and ability to make rules in that society. Indeed, in many sub-Saharan
societies the state actually have not gained the proper ability to formulate and properly execute
public policies as they would like.
36
3.3. 1HE RFSPONSE OF SOCIETIES WHO ARE UNDER SHORT-TERM SURVIVAL
STRATEGIES TO PUBLIC POLICIES AIMED FOR 1HE LONG-RUN
With a land area of almost two and half times larger than the United States, sub-Saharan
Africa, a region with 45 countries, is one of the least developed areas in the world. With estimated
450 million people residing in this area, measured by basic development indicators, much of the
continent regressed over the last 30 years. After growing at an average of 3.8 percent per year
between 1960-1970, gross domestic product grew at an annual average rate of only 3.0 percent
between 1970-1982. And as sub-Saharan Africa's population growth rates have increased steadily
from an annual average of 2.4 percent in the 1960's to a rate of 3.8 percent today, per capita GDP
has dropped markedly, from an annual average of 1.4 percent between 1961 and 1970 to 0.4
percent between 1971 and 1979, to -3.6 percent in the early 1980's (Sai 1986:129).
In spite of subsequent failures there has been little attention given to linking characteristics
of policies and programmes to their subsequent implementation, to relating implementation
problems to characteristics of political regimes in which they are pursued or to explaining the
general nature of implementation in the third world (Grindle 1980:3).
In terms' of the state-society ties and the broad macro-economic management public policies pursued in sub Saharan Africa, one can observe so called liberal economies, so called
nationalistic regimes and socialist oriented ones. Literally speaking all kinds of systems and
theories of development paradigm were attempted and implemented one way or the other.
However, none of these prescriptions delivered the goods and services required. Moreover policy
makers in sub-Saharan Africa constantly attempted to force their public policies in society.
However the use of force alone is fruitless. The question that has to be asked is how to correlate
knowledge and power. As correctly underlined by Dror, there are several ways on how new
knowledge could possibly be better integrated into society. One would be to try to achieve a
working equilibrium by explicitly limiting the freedom of scientific research, so as to forestall or
contain new findings that might endanger society either physically or by undermining to many
of its basic values. In another dimension one can restrict the dissemination of new knowledge or
reform social institutions and culture in the light of the new knowledge (Dror 1978:6). However,
the former possibility is usually rejected by contemporary western ideology and the latter which
is acceptable to contemporary ideologies in the west has its own difficulties because we do not
know how much the society allow them to successfully be integrated by changes in social
institutions and in culture.
Indeed, the problems of sub-Saharan Africa are controversial and out of reach at least in
the short-run. It is so critical to the extent of requiring the U.N attention. For the first time in
the history of the U.N, a session entirely devoted to African policy crises had been held in May
37
1986 and the African states also proposed to the U.N, Africa's priority programme for economic
recovery adapted by the OAU and ECA from the 1980 Lagos Plan of Action. According to this
programme the recovery cost was estimated to be around 128 billion dollars. According to the
World Bank estimates, the total debt of sub-Saharan Africa increased from 14.8 million dollars
in 1984 to 102 billion dollars in 1986. This 102 billion debt represented 69.8 percent of the total
GNP and 312.6 percent of total export of goods and services.
Generally, public policy entails the attempt by the state to use their organization to make
different interventions and consequently change the behaviour of the society and this kind of
crisis. But inevitably policies directed against this kind of crisis and towards the society at large
represent massive undertakings, usually involving the movement of significant resources through
the state apparatus from the society and back to the society. Nevertheless, as Migdal persuasively
. }, GNセ@
..
put it, resistance of one sort or another is nearly inevitable (Migdal 1987:399). The conflicting
values held both by the state and the society portray the structural dimensions in which public
policies are formulated and implemented. The existence of survival strategies in sub-Saharan
Africa portrays the existence of rule making organizations outside the domain of the state.
Societies under survival strategies have their own rules which are quite complex and binding. In
societies where survival strategies are institutionalized the society has its own local and regional
informal leaders. These local and regional leaders provide viable strategies of survival for
numerous peasants and workers, through credit, access to land and water, protection, bullying
etc. Although, the rules of the game and systems of justice are drastically different from that of
the state, nonetheless, they provide social stability in the short run against the long run
development oriented public policies of the state.
These local leaders provide sound short term survival conditions for the villagers, ethnic
groups etc, as the case may be. Due to this, there are no chances for the state to properly
implement development oriented public policies unless they are accepted by the informalleaders
of that society. Where strongmen have been able to maintain tight grips on local resources, state
mobilization of the population has been all the more difficult, and the dilemma of state leaders
has been acute. On the other hand, where strongmen have been weakened in their control, more
opportunities have existed for penetration of state authority (Ibid:403). But in sub-Saharan Africa
societies; i.e, societies who are under survival strategies, the people through their own informal
leaders set the rules of daily behaviour, and in another dimension, public policies entail conveying
to the society that the daily routines, symbols, and ways of behaving recommended by the state
are essential to their well being.
The existence of such disparities between the state and society more or less forced the
states in sub-Saharan Africa to develop their own politics of survival. And the politics of survival
at the top has an important effect on the policy making and implementation process. Especially
at the implementation level, those who take programmes, legislation, and policy statements of the
38
state at ground level are usually affected by non-state local informal leaders, who fashion the
societies strategies of survival, rules of behaviour. Indeed, these localleaders attempt to maintain
their social control, thus they consider new policies as a treat to their strategy and the societies
strategy in general. Therefore, policy implementers will be faced by the unexpected web of statesociety relationships, society in one side, state and party officials on the other. Grindle for
example summarized these web of local politics in as a system of accommodation and payoff
(Grindle 1980:179). Accommodation in this sense means that no single actor monopolizes power
at the local level. Local politics reflects the bargaining strength of each of the actors. Societies
under survival strategies through their informal leaders use the share of the state resources at their
disposal to maintain their own rules, their own criteria for who gets against the state and state
leaders. While the state busy itself to create a single jurisdiction and the rule of law applicable all
over the country, the society works precisely the opposite effect. Amid such contradictory
impulses the informal leaders of society attempt to maximize control as much as possible, and
sometimes they may succeed to capture parts of the state or state power as it has happened in
Ethiopia,or they may ensure the allocation of state resources according to their rules rather than
the rules outlined in the policy statements. Thus, the state becomes an arena of accommodation
where local, regional and top implementers and policy implementers and policy formulators
accommodate one another in a web of political, economic and social exchanges. Moreover, state
leaders at times may accept the overall strategies of survival as long as they are useful for the
stability of the regime. On such instances, the informal leader end up with a profound bargaining
position and may assume a post in the state structure and influence the application of important
policy decisions and the allocation of resources.
In societies where there is institutionalized survival strategy, social control is vested in
numerous local level social organizations. Here rule of behaviour is directed by informal leaders.
The informal leaders of this society having the capacity to allocate scarce resources such as land,
money and job among the society enabled them to devise viable strategies for survival for their
client better than the state. This structure of society, which Migdal termed fragmented social
control denied the state the ability to mobilize the society politically. According to Migdal this
situation created altered priorities of state leaders (Survival over social change), the style of state
politics ("big shuffles", "dirty tricks", etc.), the structure of the state organization (redundant
agencies), the difficulties in implementihg policies, an immense pressures on the implementor, and
the capture of the tentacles of the state which are a derivative of a fragmented societal structure
(Migdal 1971:425).
What we see in sub-Saharan Africa is the strengthening of survival strategies consequently
affecting the characteristics of the state itself, which in turn reinforces the survival strategies of
these societies. Thus the prospects for building cohesive policies effectively look dim. Scholars
who have observed these limitations of states in underdeveloped countries, particularly who have
39
studied what happens after a policy is adopted have put forth the concept of the "weak state". In
a society where weak states prevail, reshaping the same society through long term development
oriented public policies is' beyond the current realities of most sub-Saharan African countries.
Policies aimed for the long run have usually the opposite effect on the short term perspective
survival strategies, and actually strengthen them rather than change them. Consequently states in
sub-Saharan Africa are deemed to remain areas for accommodation than to became the main
actors in the policy making process. The state therefore, is no longer able to change social
behaviour in its social, economic, and political exchange. In Chazan's words, if state institutions,
resources and values appeal to specific "social constellations" which is termed institutionalized
survival strategy by the author of this research paper specifically in the sub-Saharan African
context, society will ally themselves with state policy and act in accordance with its guidelines.
If however, state interventions adversely affect the well being or reduce their prospects for
advancement of these groups, which is always the case in sub -Saharan Africa, then they will
work to minimize their exposure and vulnerability to these forms of interference (Chazan
1988:123). '
Based on these relationships one observes total and partial detachment in the state-society
ties in sub-Saharan Africa. Apparently this analysis indicates that politics, power and politics in
sub-Saharan Africa is not necessarily held by the state. As pointed out earlier, politics as the
competition for access and control over resources, takes place beyond the narrower public domain
in African countries. Power, the capacity to control resources, and authority, the right to so, may
legitimately be vested in local social structures (Ibid), which are mainly directed towards survival.
For example the economic implications of these local social structures is so immense that the
damages of the informal economy such as smuggling and black marketing are on the top of the
agenda in most sub-Saharan Africa countries. Thus, the economic detachment between the state
and society is one of the outcomes of survival strategies. Indeed, the parallel economy by itself
is a response to abject poverty and to the total breakdown of the formal production mechanisms.
Apart from the informal economy, economic outward migration of the sub-Saharan skilled
professionals as well as urban and rural manual labourers represents the societies' precarious and
poverty ridden economic situation. Even though, this mass exodus can be viewed as a quest for
survival, it also creates continuous political and economic instability. Consequently, the economic
field is syncretic, both domestic forces and outside intervention have combined in recent years
to reorient relations in this crucial sphere. Because of the heterogeneity of these activities and
their fluidity, the state does not control all resources and expertise, and power concentrations do
exist beyond its reach. In another dimension, the political exchange of the sub-Saharan countries
can also be considered as a logical corollary of the economic relationships. Social incoherence,
overdeveloped state structures, insufficient state legitimacy, and inadequate state coercive power
etc" are all outcomes of scarcity and survival.
40
All over sub-Saharan Africa from Ethiopia to Somalia, from Zaire to Uganda, from Ghana
to Mozambquie, from Angola to Guiana armed groups challenged the legitimacy of the official
state structure.
oョ・セ[ウゥ、イ@
this internal fragmentation as the political corollary to the prevailing
intense poverty and subsequent survival strategies. Moreover, despite the attempts for a national
culture and social cohesion as pointed out earlier, society in most sub-Saharan Africa still adheres
to lineages, extended families, chiefdoms,secret societies and local communities.
Any public policy takes place with in the context of a given state, an institute designed
by the same society. As indicated earlier, progress in any society can only be possible with the
existence of a given state only. But in sub-Saharan Africa most states were established by the
colonial powers, consequently, they have no structural relation to the society who are under
survival strategies. In any policy making process power plays a significant role and it is an
inherent component of the policy making process. However, in sub-Saharan peculiar social
realities it is possible for society to "exit" out of the system, to use Hirschman's words. The
implications of survival strategies is that those who make public policies at the top do not have
the same power to shape the perceptions, cognitions and preferences of the society.
To arrive at a better understanding and better conclusions on the economic relations
surrounding survival strategies in sub-Saharan Africa and the public policy instruments that may
make a difference in that setting, it is helpful to assess the predominant agrarian structure of the
economics of sub-Saharan Africa, where 80 percent of the total population and labour force are
still dependent on agriculture, and where survival strategies better institutionalized and are in
effect. Especially with the peasants survival strategies playa very substantive role against the long
term public policies of the state. Hyden named these survival strategies of the rural poor as "The
Economy of Affection" (Hyden 1983:8). According to him the economy of affection is
fundamental for any understanding of indigenous forms of economic and social organization in
African societies. Generally societies' in sub-Saharan Africa have a net work of support,
communication and interactions among structurally defined groups basically formed for survival
and connected either by blood, kin, community or other affinities etc. In a broader sense, the
principal functions this economy of affection or survival strategy provides can be from the
narrower basic survival, to the broader social maintenance.
In sub-saharan Africa, mainly due to the existence of survival strategies society can meet
its productive and reproductive needs without the support of the state. Therefore, as often stated
in sub-Saharan Africa the relation between those who rule and those who till the land is not
firmly rooted in the production system as such. The relationship that emerges out of such
conditions limits the degree of social control. (fonsequently, a lot of scholars consider sub-Saharan
Africa as a stateless society. Critically viewed the state is suspended in mid-air over society and
is structurally superfluous from the point of view of the individual producer. Any public policy
which aims at improving agriculture is usually considered as foreign interventiop. As pointed out
41
by Hyden, although the economy of affection is most prevalent in the rural community it is also
an integral part of society at large. Its influence also stretches right from the grass-roots to the
apex of society (Ibid:9). Indeed, in such kind of precarious situation public policies do not really
shape development in society. The central social base of most sub-Saharan Africa is still centred
around the survival strategies, and the irony is that the latter offers little base for its own
development as a macro-system other than sustaining short term survival. Consequently this is
a serious challenge for the public policy making process where it has been generally assumed that
the basic properties of modern state are already in effect in sub-Saharan Africa. However, as
pointed out by Apter,
"... we have to evaluate the diverse consequences of development. the effects it has
on people in different kinds of societies. H one query is how best to foster
development another is how to live with the consequences when development
cause grave injustices and discomforts people reacts. Sometimes their reaction is
violent, assassinations, coups, coercion - sometimes despairing. The task of our
theory is to make choice more comprehensible and amenable to improvement, for
we want development to lead to increased efficiency and social pride" (Apter
1971:41).
Acceptance of the survival strategies has an immediate implication for the discussion of
the sub-Saharan Africa society as a decision-maker. Consequently as Ekeh emphasised, there is
no monolithic public realm morally bound to the private realm. Instead there are two public
realms in post colonial Africa with different links with the private realm. At one level is the
public realm in which primordial groupings, ties and sentiments influence and determine the
public behaviour of individuals. This premoridial public realm is moral and operates on the same
moral imperatives as the private. At another level there is a public realm which is historically
associated with the colonial role and based on the civic structures of the civil service, the
judiciary, the police and so on (Ekeh 1975:95). What Ekeh calls the primordial public realm, or
the survival strategies as we prefer to call it here, manages to survive and exercise its influence
over public policy unless there is a significant change in emphasis.
42
CHAPTER IV
4.THE IMPACT OF SURVIVAL STRATEGIES ON THE DEVELOPMENT
ORIENTED PUBLIC POLICIES OF THE STATE
(CASE STUDIES)
4.1 R URAL SOCIALISM IN TANZANIA
The Arusha Declaration was passed in 1967 with an aim to make Tanzania a socialist and
self -reliant nation. Twenty five years after the Arusha Declaration and after the subsequent
villageization efforts Tanzania is neither socialist nor self -reliant. Indeed, Tanzania's record over
the last three decades after the Arusha declaration indicates a decline in real GDP growth from
an average of 7.5 percent per annum in 1970-1976 to less than 2 percent per annum between
1977-1986; the decline in real per capita income by more than 15 percent over the 1976-86 period;
the soaring of inflation from an annual rate of less than 5 percent in the 1966-70 period; through
11 percent in the 1970-6 period, to 30 percent after 1979; the deepening external imbalance as the
balance on current account deteriorated abruptly from deficit of $ US 49 million in 1977 to a
deficit of $ US 539 million in 1982, the growing overall deficit in public finance which rose by
more than 6.5 times between 1978-9 and 1984-5 reaching an unprecedented 20 percent of GDP
in 1980 (Maliamkono and Bagachwa 1990:2).
According to the initial elements of Tanzania's attempt for self-reliance and socialist
development, the rural people were to be persuaded by education and example to live together in
villages, to work together communally, and to share the products of their collective work.
Consequently, after some 6 years of the Arusha Declaration, Tanzania embarked on its own
version of villageization. These villages were to be democratically run by their members and
production decisions were to be coordinated with regional and national economic development
plans.
Basically the villageization programme began as a voluntary movement. The Arusha
Declaration of 1967 set forth the policy of socialism and self -reliance and announced the
nationalization of the commanding heights of the economy, which was to include the major
financial, manufacturing and trading institutions. With respect to the rural poor it anticipated the
concept of Ujamma which simply mean familyhood and the use of local ideas and resources. The
principal assumptions underling the traditional Ujamma living are outlined in Nyerere's pamphlet,
"Socialism and Rural Development". This pamphlet set forth the principles of Ujamma-living
together and working together for the good of all in democratic communities. It called for a shift
to traditional values of mutual respect, common ownership, and obligation to work and for a new
43
departure away from the class system, emerging in the rural areas out of the colonial connection
and towards a nation of Ujamma villages (Nyerere 1967:365). Following the massive resettlement
operations earlier carried ·out in Rufijhi, Dodoma and the Kijoma regions, the government
extended its villagization programme all over the country. Nevertheless by the end of 1973 there
was an important change in the voluntearistic impulse, party and government directed that by
1976 all rural Tanzanian's were to live in nucleated settlements.
During the 1967-69 period the villageization policy seems to follow a selective approach,
but beginning 1969 the second five year plan called for a frontal approach to Ujamma. As
indicated earlier the tempo of village creation picked up quietly after 1969, under the "Operation
Rufijhi", "Operation Dodoma" and Operations in Chunya and Kigoma. Nonetheless, the 1972
Iringa Declaration of TANU (Tanganyika African National Union), "Siasa ni Kilimo", which
means politics is agriculture reflected the stagnation of agriculture. Following this declaration, the
process of so called decentralization and villageization operation followed throughout rural
Tanzania and the education and inducement strategy was abandoned. And in 1975 when the law
on the Registration of villages and recognition of Ujamma villages passed, there were 5010
villages with 2,560,472 members all over the country.
As noted earlier, Ujamma basically refers to the habitual of cooperation among villagers
in certain peak seasons, such as cultivating, planting, harvesting, etc., or in cases of emergency
where someone needs to finish a certain job in a day or two with the help of his neighbours and
relatives, instead of weeks or months by doing it alone. Although the Ujamma ideology meant to
develop the basic philosophical underpinnings of the survival strategies of society into a wider
realms of modern objectives, what it required of the peasants was far beyond what the traditional
Ujamma considered as a guiding principle of survival in the community. Of course,the traditional
Ujamma concept implies mutual aid and reciprocal help but not in a sense of communal
ownership. Under the traditional Ujamma arrangement the neighbours in no way expected to
share the benefits derived from their contributions. This new policy which was described by
Mushi as, "Modernization by traditionalization" (Mushi: 1971), i.e, new Ujamma as a guiding
principle of life and work required the peasants to share their benefits. Ultimately, one of the
problems that Ujamma faced was related to the formalization of these customary principles of
survival into laws and regulations. These rules and regulations anticipated possible policy
implementation guides for the transformation of the Tanzanian peasants from traditional village
communities, via cooperative units to communal production villages. Even though the initial
emphasis seems to be towards short-term survival strategies, it was also aimed for the long-run.
Therefore, this policy of villageization contained within itself two contradictory conditions. On
the one hand the rules and regulations are important to make systematic party and government
possible. On the other hand it also weakened the survival strategies themselves. Because there is
no longer much room for spontaneous application of values shared by people in the same
44
community. The parameters of action are no longer local but imposed on the rural communities
by the authorities.
In the initial stages of the villageization process the policy emphasized village selfgovernment and its right to make its own mistake on all local matters. However, the policy also
stressed leadership, which pursues and teaches the people. Therefore, this spontaneous strategy
of self -government was soon backed by administrative inducements and some Ujamma villages
were imposed by force and threats. Indeed, the government abandoned its earlier strategy of
voluntary inducement and shifted by compulsions. Beginning 1979 sites for the new villages were
in most cases centrally and hastily selected without consulting peasants, and were often chosen on
such general criteria as being near roads and having sufficient land to support a certain amount
of families. Consequently the neglect for soil fertility, potential natural hazards or availability of
pasture, increased:the risk and uncertainty of the peasants, which basically peasants attempt to
avoid them through their survival strategies. The villageization program, thus in the short-run
caused disruption in peasants production schedules resulting in short-term output declines. The
., 1973 villageization directive emphasized a shift from communal cultivation to increased
subsistence production. This was a backhand admission that Ujamma Vijijni was a failure.
Therefore, the initial directive that the peasants must cultivate block fields of the village was
accompanied by another directive that all households receive equalized cultivation units for
subsistence crops. As pointed out by Seavoy, the government's failure to take control of land use
from peasants meant that the national government had no means of forcing peasants to make
greater labour inputs into agriculture, or of appropriating a share of the harvest (Seavoy:
1989:192). Indeed, 1979 onwards Ujamma villages became development villages and communal
cultivation ceased throughout Tanzania.
During the great move and immediately afterward several regions experienced hunger. By
the end of 1974 and beginning of 1975, all of Tanzania's foreign exchange had been spent to
purchase food grains. As pointed out by Coulson, in both years rainfall was near normal in most
regions of Tanzania. The cause of food deficit was political mismanagement of villageization
aggravated by peasants making minimal labour inputs into cultivation. Most peasants refused to
increase labour inputs as long as famine relief food was being given to them and as long as low
prices for exchange commodities coincided with a shortage of manufactured items to purchase
(Coulson 1977:260).
Villagization, then has brought many new problems of an immediate as well as long term
nature bearing serious implications for the present and future. Apart from this the increased risk
of hazards; such as, the outbreak of fire, disease, and water contamination which the farmers used
to avoid them through their settlement patterns as far as possible were now rampant.
Consequently, the villagization model was not a workable solution to Tanzania.
For example, prior the villagization programme, one of the strengths of the Tanzanian
45
traditional agriculture was that there is no single staple food, but area specific food crops.
Consequently, the whole of Tanzania has never suffered simultaneously from food shortages
except some specific regions; nevertheless, after the villagization process, the vulnerability of
Tanzania in the cultivation of staple food has increased which the farmers did not automatically
follow the new way. Indeed, Tanzanian farmers preferred multiple cropping rather than depend
on a single crop because it increases their security and continue to use traditional tools and plants
because this permits participation and gives them a chance to engage in some commercial
agriculture at a price that the farmers can afford.
Innovations, if they are to be accepted must be designed to meet these basic survival needs
of the peasant community. The shift to villagization neglected the realities of the individual and
family identities. In fact the realities of the individual and family identities are not mere attitudes
of mind or only traditional outlooks rather they are rooted in the specific survival strategies of
that society. As pointed out by Barker, "if it is not a question of a generalized prejudice, then the
ways in which individual and family identities are accommodated should vary with circumstances.
The minimum requirement appears to be explicit legal recognition of individual and family rights
in the collective property and some scope for family and individual production (Barker 1979:115).
As pointed out by Seavoy, the 1965 constitution reflected president Nyerere's vision of the
poli tical future of Tanzania. Tanzania would be democratic, egalitarian, and self-governing entity,
where neighbours will accept a moral responsibility for the welfare of each other. The moral basis
of Tanzanian society would be the social values of peasant villages where decisions about justice
and development were made and enforced by consensus (Seavoy: 1989:180). In effect Nyerere
realized the importance of survival strategies. He interpreted this social behaviour of the peasants
as "African Socialism". Nevertheless, his assumption that once independence was achieved,
peasants would respond to exhortation by TANU leaders and produce more goods and services
than under colonial rule was wrong. Due to this, African socialism worked differently than
Nyerere anticipated. Even though, the peasants replay with the villagization programme
favourably so as not to be punished, but their concern with production did not go beyond what
they considered desirable and feasible within the context of their survival strategy. Ujamma with
its revolutionary terms required the peasant farmers to accept a social relation which is not
conceivable for their own immediate survival. Thus viewed from the short-run angles of the
survival strategies, peasant conception of Ujamma differed from the official view.
Basically, the social values that motivate the Tanzanian peasants are embodied in the
survival strategies. In most cases the Tanzanian peasants before villagization are limited to grow
only enough food to satisfy their subsistence needs. Under this strategy the peasants attempt to
maximize labour expenditure. Of ten, the peasant concept of good life is the minimum expenditure
of physical labour, particularly the labour of cultivation. Following Seavoy's argument, one finds
what are termed subsistence insurance institutions; such as: (1) Equalized allocation of the
46
communities land. (2) Partible inheritance. (3) Equalized sharing of harvest in poor crop years.
(4) Transfer of subsistence sharing labour to landless or near landless households in exchange for
food. (5) Joint family households. (6) Patron-client relationships with feudal landlords,
storekeepers, or money lenders. However, the Tanzanian peasants were able to practice this
strategy of survival as long as they control land use. But the villagization policy made them lose
control of their land use and forced them to greater labour inputs, peasants were further frustrated
by exhortation from the government, especially during 1973-5 economic crises, which decreed
that peasants plant at least three acres of food crops and a minimum of one acre of cash crop. This
decree increased risk, because labour time is sometimes devoted to communal activities which does
not have a direct impact on survival and which is less productive than household activities. Due
to this, both food:production and cash crop production declined sharply. The basic reason for this
,"
'I
decline was that, this rural socialist policy was never made reconcilable with the survival strategies
of the peasants. Dumont argues that, "the tradition of African mutualism cannot constitute a
sufficient basis for allowing a general acceptance of rural socialism. And with respect to what he
termed village government, the democratic principles were scarcely accepted (Dumont 1969:5).
One broad conclusion that we can take from this is that, traditional survival strategies,
family ethics and reciprocal assistance between families on the one hand and communal living,
working and sharing for a better life on the other hand are two different things. Mushi,
commenting on the response to a national sample for the 1970 election study, to the question "what
is Ujamma?" notes that, the overwhelming majority of the respondents defined Ujamma in
accordance with the traditional norms of co-operation and living together and working together
in harmony. But in reality the modern Ujamma living entails several changes in survival strategies
and social behaviour, offends deeply held social practices and material fabrics of living and
producing. It was a failure because the peasants attempted to preserve the relative autonomy and
self-subsistence of the family of production unit. As noted by Barker, families resist giving up
this autonomy and men and elders resist diluting the economic and social power they held in the
family when family function are given over to village bodies (Barker 1979:117). Therefore, there
was a major conflict inherent in this whole situation. Basically most of the Tanzanian ecology does
not allow permanent settlement. The system of agriculture employed prior the villagization
process in most parts of the country and in adaption to the ecology, made it necessary for the
people to shift from time to time to use land. Living to close to each other would thus constitute
a hinderance to expansion. Where extensive areas of good land were available, "there was also no
advantage in living close together. Over large parts of the country that were semi-arid in nature
and where water is not available throughout the year, dense settlements were also out of the
question. Pastoral groups had to move from place to place in search of food for their livestock and
this too precluded permanent neculated settlements (Mascarenhas 1979:147). Even though there
was a need for solid long term development results from the centre, circuTI;lstances in rural
47
Tanzania where survival strategies of the short-run prevail did not lend themselves to a
revolutionary transformation. Consequently, results were generally far short of expectations.
Post independence Tanzania followed both the rational actor and incremental models in
its policy making. Especially, in relation to the agricultural sector both the rational actor and
incremental models had been attempted extensively. For example, after the World Bank
recommendation, to transfer peasant agriculture through settlement schemes, some thirty
government planned settlements were set up in various regions. Nonetheless, the peasants in these
village settlements were both unwilling and unable to support the costs of the over mechanized
and over-administered schemes and consequently this "transformation approach" which was mainly
a result of the rational actor model was a failure. In another dimension there was also an attempt
to bring social change through incremental policy making model. Under this "improvement
approach" institutions were established to cater for the farmers. A number of farmers training
centres were built and courses organized for interested farmers. Agricultural education at the
university level as well as agricultural research was expanded. However, most peasants showed
dis-interest to this "improvement approach" and most university graduates in agriculture saw their
future in bureaucratic careers. Consequently as the two cases demonstrate both models of policy
making were of no significant use.
The Ujamma policy reduced the status of the informal leaders and increased the power
of the bureaucrats whose primary loyalty lay with the president and TANU. Nevertheless, the
Ujamma policies gave the bureaucrats few opportunities to relate to the peasants in conservative
and positive manner. The nature of institutionalized survival strategies, and the subsequent
production and reproduction values held by the peasants did not call for state participation. The
survival strategies simply appeared too strong for the state to conquer.
In any ways peasants were doing what they considered a good job. However, as McHenery
concludes, the poorer members of the Ujamma villages had little room to gamble with their food
supply. The better-off households and those which for one reason or another could spare labour
were the main contributors to communal farming. This explains why attendance on the communal
farms was so irregular and why it differed drastically among members of the same village. It also
explains why communal farming was given such limited attention and why, therefore, it ended
up appearing so unprofitable to the peasants. Indeed to the peasants, work in the communal farms
was never considered an end in itself. To them it remained
a supplemefital attivity -t6their
survival strategy, one of the survival strategies in rural Tanzania has been essentially concerned
with providing everybody's right to subsistence. Within this mode of behaviour social inequalities
are accommodated without tension by following the principles of the institutionalized survival
strategies. Consequently no one was prepared to trade his own survival strategy that protected him
for centuries for the modern concept of equality, nor he were fully willing to work communally
in order to fulfil the aspirations of other classes. Ujamma being a radical strategy of development
48
aimed by the state has no adequate room to accommodate the central principles of the societal
survival strategies. For example, in 1968 when Rufiji river over flooded its banks in the low lands
the government moved the peasants into the highlands and resettled them into the Ujamma
villages. Although this move was meant to save the peasants from occasional flooding hazards
many of the resettled villagers returned to the lowlands. In spite of occasional flood the movement
of these people back to the river was more rational than living in a land where because of
uncertainty of the rain their survival will be on a permanent threat. Thus, the real challenge of
Ujamma was that the material base of institutionalized survival strategies were aimed at the shortrun against a rapid long-term social transformation.
Even though the modest villagization policy which was carried out after 1973 drought was
not successful, both set of policies, (l) the removal of all informal leaders who were considered
as a barrier between government and peasants and (2) the reorganization of party and government
structures to reach the peasants more effectively brought a significant change in the traditionally
held societal structure. Initially because of the severe drought the movement of people was
facilitated. Nevertheless, the peasant farmers concentrated on production of food crops to meet
their immediate survival needs in the new settlements. According to the economic survey of the
Tanzanian Government the production in subsistence agriculture mostly food have grow up 10.5
percent while production in cash crops for export increased by only 1.9 percent. Hyden quoting
one of the few studies of villagization made by Omari pointed out that the villagers have the view
that they should be left on their own in agricultural production. We should however remember
that despite its scarce rainfall the districts and the region (Mtwara) as a whole has never
experienced food shortages (crop failures) for a long time. One factor behind this is the growing
of such drought resistant crops as cassava and millet. Confidence has been built among the people
that if they have survived through all these generations without food shortages, they can and will
survive in future without someone telling them what to grow, how to grow, where to grow and
at what quantity (Hyden 1980:147).
Indeed, even though there was a great effort to transform the peasants through
villagization, the peasants survival know how that they have held prior the villagization had been
invalid because of soil conditions and other factors of production. In the final analysis
villagization have
disrupted the time tested peasant survival strategies in the man-land
relationships. Moreover, this situation created a constant conflict between peasants survival
strategies, as determined by existence rationality and the state rationality as determined by the
long-term perspective development oriented public policies. The traditional survival strategies
among the peasants rested on informal but generally accepted values of social status. For example,
elders and persons of high social status took such major decisions as the allocation of land and
settling disputes. Nonetheless, these traditional structures have been weakened since the inception
of Ujamma and the subsequent villagization programmes. Especially, the village act of 1975 broke
49
the traditional tenure system and the traditional values attached to it.
Though the state viewed the resistance of the peasants against Ujamma at different parts
of the country, to be rooted in the capitalistic tendency among peasants, and lack of ideological
consciousness, there were other reasons for such resistances. In rural Tanzania, there were
institutionalized survival strategies and values which have a time-tested historical background in
the overall development of the area. Therefore, to introduce successful policy impacts, the
survival institutions involved had to be strengthen first to the extent that they change themselves
to accommodate the modern sense of development paradigm. Contrary to this Tanzania's political
leadership has followed a "we - must - run - while - others walk" mode of policy making, some
policies thus were carried out fast to the extent of ignoring people's attitudes and value systems
which hold the community together as a social unit and to the extent of ignoring peoples basic
survival strategies. As correctly put by Omari, "an outside initiative which is not felt as a need,
is not sufficiently understood, or brutally threatens community organization, very often is met
with distrust (Omari 1976:16). The Ujamma policy required of the peasants more than the their
existing mode of thought. And throughout the implementation process, the state followed
Nyerere's core strategy for developing Tanzanian national ideology. According to this strategy
"socialism, like democracy, is attitude of mind" (Nyerere 1967:165). It was this attitude of mind
which, if there was any success, were supposed to be changed. However, as persistently argued,
qualitative change in societies under survival strategies can only be achieved by strengthening that
attitude of mind until they are ready to change themselves.
Basically the Tanzanian policy makers viewed development as a change in the survival
institutions, institutionalized in the form of religious beliefs, economic organization, political
structures, and cultural traits intricately interwoven and demonstrated in the day to day lives of
the masses. Nevertheless, it is unlikely to change these survival institutions from the top unless
the changes are made within dialectically
The state policy also stipulated a household farm, block farm, village farm (Ujamma
Shamba). Nonetheless, peasants expressed discontent with these rules, as they made it difficult to
allocate the scarce resources in the most rational way and increased the time spent on walking to
and from the fields. The Ujamma policy consequently alienated the peasants in a sense of
detachment from one's own initiative and powers i.e, the power to survive. As noted by Rahman,
"the leadership's attempt was to generate real social participation through the villagization
programme. Without, however, judging the merit of this move one may note the dilemma that it
implied - namely that in order to promote participation the peasantry had firstly to be alienated.
Having done this the next move also belonged therefore, to the leadership rather than to the
peasants (Rahman 1980:9).
The outcome of this policy was tragic. The absence of real social participation in Ujamma
and critical resistance by the rural poor, lead to a decline in agriculture productivity. For example
50
between 1967 and 1973, the average annual rise in total output was only 2.7 percent at constant
pricers. So serious was the decline in food production Tanzania was forced to import massive
amounts of Maize, wheat and other cereals to feed its people.
51
4.2. SOME EXPERIENCES W1TII SMALLHOLDER TEA
DEVELOPMENT POLICY IN KENYA.
Kenya became independent in december 1963, under a quesa-federal constitution to
reduce the effective power of the central government by strengthening the regions. At the time
of independence Kenya has no a unified leadership. By the time there were two opposing parties
KANU (Kenyan African National Union) and KADU (Kenyan African Democratic Union).
Basically KADU had been formed to protect the interests of Kenya's smallest tribes, while KANU
was formed out of the pre existing and autonomous district political associations that controlled
grass-roots poli ti cs.
Despite some important differences resulting from Kenya's history as a centre of European
settlement conditions; both Tanzania and Kenya at the time of independence were basically the
same. Even though the policy options open for both of them was like wise similar, Kenya
responded quite differently than Tanzania. Kenya has defined development in terms of the
continued growth and elaboration of the political and economic institutions established, in lieu
of an effective political party, of a serious of informal and regionally based patron-client
hierarchies, composed of local regional and national leaders that function as political machines to
link the grass roots to the political system and to the centre. In contrast Tanzania attempted to
create an extensive, disciplined and ideologically committed political party from the top down to
the grass roots for the purpose of mobilizing the country's population to achieve socialist
development and increasing their participation in the governce of their society. In practice this
party subordinated all institutions including the institutionalized survival strategies of society. As
a result the performance of the two countries greatly varied to the overall and sectorial rates of
economic growth; in the degree of inequality, in the distribution of personal income, purchasing
power, and government services; and above all in the overall level and nature of participation in
the political process. When one views the sectorial rates of economic growth, it is agriculture
where Tanzanian performance has been particularly disappointing while Kenyan experience is
encouraging.
Just to make a brief comparison, the Tanzanian Government increased its expenditures
in agricultural development from 6.3 million dollars in 1967 to $ 56 million dollars in 1976.
However, in the same period the overall agricultural production declined by 1.8 percent and
Tanzania's production of food grains fell by more than 30 percent and the country experienced
serious food shortages that necessitated substantial imports of maize and wheat.
In contrast Kenya's economic relatively expanded on all frontes. And so far the
agricultural sector managed to absorb the large increase in population, which is growing at one
of the highest rates in the world. The most direct way in which this has been achieved has been
52
through the policy of smallholder settlement. This policy helped Kenya to increase the agricultural
sector's capacity to absorb labour, to increase cash production, specifically tea and coffee. And
it also enabled Kenya for a measurable yields overtime. Moreover, there was also an increase in
vegetable, fruit and flower production as well as dairy products.
Apart from the increase in unit value of crops and yield of crops there was also a
significant increase in the area cultivated by the smallholder
The experience Kenya's peasant agriculture immediately after independence is such that
it can be used to illustrate the potentials of smallholder production in Africa. Further more it can
also be cited as an example of how far ordinary peasants are willing to respond to public policies
when the policies are directed at strengthening their survival strategies. Therefore, this research
paper attempts to provide an account of the smallholder settlement of the Kenyan Government,
as an example of a,successful public policy aimed at the short-run survival strategies of society.
Unlike other smallholder rural development policies, in which the African experience has often
brought serious difficulties and disappointing performances like that of Tanzania and Ethiopia,
this policy is widely acknowledged to be a remarkably a successful one.
Especially with respect to black tea, the smallholder were able to plant 54,000 hectares of
tea and they have became a major processor and the largest exporter of black tea in the world.
Smallholder tea exports, which was virtually non-existent before the promulgation of the policy,
have now accounted for about one-third of Kenya's annual tea exports. Due to the expansion of
smallholder tea production, tea became the second most important export commodity and the third
largest source of foreign exchange earnings.
Prior the policy, ninety percent of Kenya's people are rural and most of them are members
of smallholder households. Sixty percent of them operated for subsistence without significant cash
crop production. However, currently Kenya has the most successful major peasant based tea
scheme in the world. The concept of Kenyan smallholder tea operation began to take shape during
the early 1950's. By 1960 the Special Crops Development Authority (SCDA) was established to
promote the production of African-grown teas. In January 1964, just one month after
independence, the SCDA was transformed into the Kenyan Tea Development Authority (KTDA).
From the outset the authority directly aimed at the survival strategies of the society, and aimed
at drawing the smallholder into tea production as an addition to, rather than a substitute for their
current subsistence farming. The policy thus encouraged the peasant to continue in their own way
of life, and in the mean time requiring them to grow tea on land thus far under utilized, but with
suitable attitude, soil, precipitation, To demonstrate the income benefits as broadly as possible the
policy limited the size of the plots. However, the policy also determined the holding in a more
economically viable size, in such a way that the return from the farmers holdings' worth their time
to harvest the tea and carry it to collection centres. Basically the authority responsible for the
implementation of the policy, KTDA performed four main functions.
53
i) supplying planting material and fertilisers to the farmer on credit terms.
ii) supervising cultivation in the field and providing training facilities.
iii) arranging for the inspection, collection and transport of green leaf.
iv) procuring proper arrangements for processing and marketing (Stren 1972:15)
For the first planning programmes seedlings were cultivated in two large nurseries, on
either side of the Rift Valley, These seedlings were distributed at the appropriate planting times.
And the prices of the cutting were kept deliberately low to encourage the smallholder to buy them
from the nurseries. As noted by Stren, KTDA gave advise via its field development section on the
vegetatively propagated, on the tending, pegging, pruning and plucking of tea bushes. Local
courses were held, and also field days when competition for the best tea bushes were organized.
Enthusiasm amongst growers for growing tea was very high and rivalry was fierce (Ibid 1970:16).
As mentioned earlier rural development especially in the context of sub-Saharan Africa presents
peculiar difficulties. Each peasant holding is a complex producing and consuming unit whose
members behaviour is subject to a wide range of institutionalized survival strategies in the social,
cultural, political as well as economic life of that society. Policies which are both stable and
innovative enough to cope with this complexity must deal with an array of activities which are
overwhelming social rather than technical.
The policy has encouraged the peasants to participate in policy discussions and district
tea committees, the provincial tea boards. A second means for the farmer participation has been
ensured through the buying of shares in the individual KTDA tea factories. About ten percent of
all the smallholder farmers who were covered in this policy were holders of about 1.6 million
shares in the 16 tea factories incorporated as public companies. Apart from the monetary
incentives, the policy also gave farmers an interest in the KTDA performance and some voice in
operations. Furthermore a less formal communication channel consisting of periodic visits to
farmers by KTDA senior extension and headquarters staff, to find out about grower progress
firsthand was the usual practice (Lamb and Muller 1982:20). Indeed, the tea growers are better
placed to shape their own destiny and to exert influence on the agencies servicing them, both in
the KTDA Board and Tea Committees formally and by direct discussion with KTDA staff
informally. Consequently, the tea growers are aware of their basic survival needs and quick to
point out shortcomings.
Considering the producers inability to substantial services, KTDA offered with first
regular and second variable payment system providing farmers with a highly prized secure
monthly cash income. This security/incentive mix maintained the production of tea even in the
relatively difficult years. As pointed out by Lamb and Muller, the first of those positive incentives
was that, the policy provides a "full payment", for green leaf on a monthly basis all year around
given the continual growing season for tea, a payment which goes out to growers from KTDA
headquarters against their individual deliveries to leaf collection centres. Growers are therefore,
54
assured of a steady monthly income for their basic survival, based on their previous months
delivery; rather than having wait until the crop is processed and sold. This system of maintaining
their survival is highly prized by the growers. Moreover this security incentive payment system
is also complimented by a price incentive, provided by variable annual "Second Payment" (Ibid:40)
Thus, the tea development policy was very successful in strengthening the survival strategies of
smallholder peasants where the growers own their land and grow tea on only part of it in not more
than 25 percent of the growers total holding coupled with security incentive and price incentive
which are the basic requirements of short term survival. As noted by Stren, this policy is a
valuable one with an estimated social rate of return of 38.8 percent and a social percent value of
12.59 million Kenyan shillings (discounted at 10 percent to 1966/67) for the main part of the
project. The inter.:nal rate of return for the farmer net benefit stream is 13.9 percent (Stern
1972:101).
Unlike its,neighbours, the style of politics encouraged by president Kenyatta and his
successors was directed in strengthening some of the survival institutions of society. For example
the style of leader, encouraged by the government is the ethnically and lineage-based constituency
representative, whose role is to act primarily as ambassador from a constituency. Thus this means
the political system has accepted the informal leaders of society one way or the other. Although
its local political influence is being challenged by the bureaucracy, the rural informalleaders
remain the key architect of the regime; the bureaucracy has encroached upon but not
overwhelmed them. As a result a great degree Jatitude for self help leadership continues to exist,
while national policy is directed towards maintaining and strengthening the institutions of survival
strategies of society the results will be magnificent as demonstrated in the smallholder tea
development policy.
Comparing the two rural development policies both in Kenya and Tanzania, it is evident
that the Tanzanian policy making process undermined local survival strategies thereby
undermining local initiative. In another dimension, the success of the Kenyan rural development
policies, in increasing agricultural productivity, self-sufficiency in food staffs, lower prices of
food staffs as compared to other African countries can be attributed to the emphasis made in
strengthening survival strategies. For example the Kenyan Government's policy towards the rural
informal sector is a case in point. There is no doubt that the richness of the rural survival economy
and the margin of survival of ordinary rural households depend on the extent to which informal
institutions of survival and complimentary survival activities have been developed. To these
effects, following the 1972 ILO recommendations, the Government of Kenya adopted the
following guidelines in order to strengthen the informal sector.
i) harassment should be cease.
ii) research and development on informal sector goods should be intensified.
iii) licences should be freely available to all.
55
iv) links with the formal sector, including government, should be strengthened through
the development of sub-contracting (Sessional paper on employment No.1 0 of 1973).
Thus the Government of Kenya in fact allowed for smallholder an extra income because
it felt the survival needs of the society are not met from farm production alone. Once the
smallholder were encouraged to take a supplemental activi ty alongside their subsistence farm, they
developed cash agriculture thereby increasing the purchasing power of the Kenyan economy and
the size of the market. This move assured a substantial constant flow of foreign exchange, a
favourable foundation for industrial development as well as an expansion of agro-processing
industries and stimulus to various other non-farm activities. Indeed, even the Kenyan schemes for
the distribution of agricultural credit and extension concentrated for poorer peasants who are
attempting merely to survive.
In the final analysis the success of smallholder tea development production from 100 tones
in 1960 to over 30,000 now is deeply rooted in the entire structure of the policy making process.
Generally policy making in Kenya is characterized by strengthening the survival strategies. And
one of the strength of the policy making is largely related to a careful exercise in maintaining the
support of key institutions of survival through the judicious allocation of the scarce resources,
Unlike most African countries the Government of Kenya itself is highly plural, with bargaining
and competition occurring among members of government acting on behalf of supporting group.
Consequently policy makers and governmental decision makers are forced to operate within the
bounds of such structure.
The survival structure of society in Kenya and the attempt by the state to accommodate
it prevents policy making from being exclusively a state-centred affair. Rather whatever their
normative views may be they attempt to fashion their public policies within the parameters set
by such structure. Political and economic principles of strengthening the survival strategies
required a form of policy making which is suggestive and persuasive. The Kenyan policy making
exercise allowed the local people to be extremely involved and pull at the right time. And the
relative success of this policy, and the high rate of economic growth in the last policy making
periods provided the policy makers an additional incentives to meaningfully pursue strengthening
the survival strategies.
56
4.3. THE LAND REFORM POLICY AND THE SUBSEQUENT
COOPERATIVIZATION AND COLLECTIVIZATION
POLICIES OF THE ETIllOPIAN GOVERNMENT
Like most of its sub-Saharan neighbours, Ethiopia is a predominantly agrarian based
society. Agriculture being the main stay in the economy provides employment for roughly 85
percent of the total population. Agriculture is dominated by smallholder who produce most of the
countries food, largely for subsistence. Recent estimates suggest that peasants in average retain
eighty percent of their produce for household consumption and for seeds (Desalenge 1984:67).
With an estimated GNP of US
$
160 per capita, Ethiopia is one of the poorest countries in the
world; with . over thirty million people, i.e, more than sixty percent of the population believed to
be living below the absolute poverty line (Brune 1990:17). Indeed, agricultural output is currently
barely adequate to sustain its own labour. However, prior the 1974 "Ethiopian Revolution", the
Ethiopian agricultural sector did surprisingly well. But in the post-revolution period the level of
food grain production has fallen well below from what has been achieved under Emperor Haile
Selassie's government.
The Land Reform in 1975 was centre-piece of the Ethiopian Revolution, and in some
respects one of the most radical land reforms ever attempted in Africa (Pausewang 1979:213). The
low level of agricultural underdevelopment prior the revolution were attributed to a structural
nature of a land tenure system. As a consequence land reform was considered an important
undertaking for the country's future. Undoubtedly, the public ownership of rural lands
proclamation No. 31/1975 eliminated many of the basic problems of the pre-revolution agrarian
system and it also brought new problems in the forefront.
The basic concept underlying this Land Reform Act was that all land in rural areas be
nationalized: "As of the effective date of this proclamation, all rural lands shall be the collective
property of the Ethiopian people" (Negarit Gazeta Vol. 34 No. 26:2). The Land Reform policy of
1975 is on which all subsequent rural development policies, including those promoting
collectivization and villagization have been formulated
The cornerstone of the Land Reform was the creation of the peasant associations, and it
was the existence of these organizations which has allowed the government to strengthen its grip
in the rural areas, and implement subsequent policies of villagization, collectivization,
resettlement, state grain procurement, and state control of grain marketing and pricing. One of
the most important provisions of the 1975 Land Reform was the setting up of Peasant Associations
in each locality. These were supposed to be organizations of peasants with an elected leadership
and a legally defined set of responsibilities including the maintenance of law and order. However,
the subsequent phases of the revolution witnessed the hardening of the revolution, and the shift
57
of public policy towards rapid collectivization.
The policy directives initiated by this time forced the peasantry to change from an active
force of the revolution to a passive recipient of government directive (Desalegne 1989:7). The
rapid collectivization and villagization processes were the land marks for the beginning of
contradictions between the survival strategies of society with that of the socialist oriented long
term perspective public policies of the government.
The principal phase of the land reform policy was in principle partially compatible with
the traditional systems of landholding in most parts of the country. For example restriction to land
use rights and the shackles placed on mobility of land were after all basic elements of "Rist" [in
the north], "Deissa" [in the south], and the "Geda" System in [the south west]. Even though the
initial articulations of the policy were in line with the survival strategies of the Ethiopian
peasantry it also in some respect contradicted the survival strategies of smallholder owner
cultivators. The provision of the legislation which states that land is the collective property of the
Ethiopian people, and that private ownership in land is prohibited, denied the smallholder ownercultivators of their right to sale, mortgage or lease their land. Thus, the policy deprived all
individual owner cultivators of their property. As Desalegne pointed out all rural households
willing to live by their own labour were turned into mere possessors of usufruct" (Desalegne
1989:19). Thus the reform from the outset disrupted the delicate mechanism of survival by
creating insecurity of holding, thereby creating a decline in performance in the smallholder
agriculture. Moreover, according to the traditional survival institutions both the peasant who leases
his plot and the peasant who rents his land were insuring their survival and supplementing their
incomes respectively, but after the land reform those who do not have access to draft animals and
other essential resources were not able to work their land.
Moreover, to implement the provision of the land reform, peasant associations were to be
formed on a basis of a traditional village or an administrative unit of 800 hectares area. These
peasant associations were empowered to implement the distribution of land on the basis of equity
considering both the size of family and quality of the soil, supervision of land use regulations and
administration of public property, establishment of judicial committees, service cooperatives and
an elementary form of producer's cooperatives and promotion of socio-economic infrastructure
and villagization programmes (Nagarit Gazeta Proclamation No. 71 of 1975). Consequently the
formation of peasant associations, deprived of the traditional informal leaders of their traditional
role and disrupted most of their economic power. As indicated by Wood the political education
of the peasantry further eroded the authority of traditional leaders, and in this situation a power
vacuum had been created (Wood 1984:530). Nevertheless. The Ethiopian Government considered
the peasant association as an alternative to the administrative role of the traditional informal
leaders.
As we have said, proclamation No. 71, of 1975 envisaged a gradual
58
エイ。セウヲッュゥョ@
from
service cooperatives to an elementary forms of producer's cooperatives and finally to advanced
producer's cooperatives. However, this was one of the critical problems that the Ethiopian
Government faced. Prior the proclamation no workable traditional basis existed for collective
organization of agriculture any where in Ethiopia. As Hoben noted, there appears to be little
traditional basis ... for collective ownership of land or voluntary large-scale cooperation in
agricultural activity, .... Group activities were always organized by powerful authority figure
rather than through a voluntary and cooperative effort for the mutual benefit of the members as
a group (Hoben 1973:229). Indeed, the traditional survival institutions were devoid of any kind
of solidarity structure based on the fundamental equality of those involved. Moreover, the marked
individualism of the highlanders, as manifested in economically autarchic households, weakened
cooperativeness ,that the latter was found more or less only in cases of threats from outside.
Obviously a social set up where such survival strategies prevail can not be changed from the topdown in a short time by legislative measures.
"Rist" which was the land holding system in the north did not only impose individualism
but also offered opportunities of considerable social ascent. Consequently those people who were
involved in this system were not happy to the dissolution of the system. Therefore, it was
unrealistic to expect a favourable policy impact in terms of cooperativeness. The agrarian policy
changes of the Derge regime were diametrically opposed to the system of traditional survival
strategies. The traditional settlement pattern in Ethiopia was varied, as did the societies they
created them. The homestead standing in its own fields was far the most common pattern, but in
itself is compatible with social survival institutions of various kind between households. Thus it
was a futile attempt to bring a lasting solution when the basic principles of such attitudinal
changes are diametrically opposed.
The collectivization move in many ways was in direct contradiction to the Ethiopian
traditional survival institutes. This hierarchical traditional social system, and its conceptions of
the necessity of subordination to a God-given order, were supported by the religious authorities
of both the major religions. As pointed out by Goricke,
"this philosophy has now been directly assailed by the recognition of the individual
as an active being in his own right and the attendant principle of the legitimacy
of participation and action to change his social status. Already this polarisation of
views has of necessity led to a relativation of the images of self and society
entertained above all by the Amharan Rist peasants" (Goricke 1979:225).
Thus the directives on cooperatives and the continuous propaganda in favour of them was
received with great hesitation with the peasant population. Sometimes the government propaganda
was literally interpreted as an attempt by the government to separate the households from the
means of production and work for the state (Love 1989:33).
To speed up the collectivization process the government issued a villagization guidelines
in June 1986, and a national villagization committee was set up. The major objectives of the
committee was to provide social services for the rural communities, to promote cooperative work,
59
to raise the level of consciousness of the people; to improve village security and defence; to plan
a more rational land use; to develop natural resources and increase agricultural productivity by
introducing modern techniques (Alemayehu 1990:139). Nonetheless, the villagization policy also
failed to bring the desired results. Even though the guidelines instructed to the implementing
bodies was to pay special attention to farmland, pasture, water resources and existing social infrastructure when selecting a village site, in reality, all these things are rarely found close together
in a rural setting. Moreover, the policy lacked a proper criteria for non-farm activities. For
example in one of the regional surveys made in the Welmera Woreda by Alemayehu, the new
villages were found to be difficult for potters, because the new site was too far from the sources
of clay. Attempts to introduce villagization in Ensete-growing areas also created other unforseen
problems, mainly due to high population density of the Ensete growers. Significant increases in
distance between the fields and the new houses of the peasants also created an additional problem.
In majority of the new villages the average distance between the fields and the homes stretched
from 1.6 to 6 kilometres. Due to this, some farmers started renting their new plots of land to the
nearby peasants.
Every household, Gonsequently lost significant part of their crops, and roots, being
effectively unable to protect· their fields from wild animals, pests and thieves from such a
distance. It also became difficult to carry the manure to the farmers and use it as a fertilizer.
Many peasants had to leave straw to decay, which could have been used to feed cattle in dry
season or to plaster walls, had their threshing grounds had not been to far away. Increased distance
grazing land had reduced grazing time by 20 percent, and livestock mortality increased
significantly. Indeed the policy of villagization generally lacked sensitivity to the basic survival
strategies of the Ethiopian peasantry. It also failed to realize, that even the settlement patterns of
the peasantry are directly related to their survival strategy.
The policy of villagizaion restricted the peasants from raising small animals and poultry,
from keeping bees and dry manure, or to attempt other sideline activities to earn an additional
incomes. Problems were also created by the standard construction plans. Houses in the new villages
were supposed to be 30 or 40
rl squire regardless
of the household size. This compact and
standardized dwelling were not sufficient for families with over 10 people. Sixty percent of the
peasants interviewed by Alemayehu in Welmera district reported that their new homes were on
average 20 percent small than their former homes. Similarly, many people were not content with
the standard division of dwellings into three rooms (living room, bed room and store) as this
limited the width of the rooms and made them dim even in day light. Moreover, the separate
kitchen and stable required more than one kerosene lamp at a time. The fact that kitchen and
stable were separate also raised the cost of construction. In the surveyed areas the average cost of
construction for a house and auxiliary facilities was estimated to be birr 1500 to 2500. Even with
a separate stable, many peasants still preferred to keep some of their animals, as calves or horses
60
either in the kitchen or in the house itself.
Another weakness in the guidelines concerned was the time set aside for the house
construction. The government felt that the "Slack" season between December and March was ideal
for this purpose. A varying crop calender, different cropping cultures and diverse religions
customs made this impractical in some areas. For example, most peasants who are growing cereals
during summer use december to march as the peak season for planting maize, sorghum and ensete.
Other studies have also revealed that peasants are rarely idle, even working on holidays, although
they don't plough on these days. It is; therefore, not true that peasants are free between December
and March or that they can devote their time fully to house construction in the slack season and
on holidays.
As a result of all these short comings, there were quite a number of petitions from villages
in 1987. Indeed, the failure of the villagization policy sharply demonstrated how values and
survival strategies held by the Ethiopian peasantry affected a major long-term perspective
development oriented public policy of the state.
In a nutshell the economic promise of the land reform policy and the subsequent
collectivization and villagization moves were largely unfulfilled.
The general lesson is that although the Ethiopian government agrarian policies have
specifically sought to improve the peasant's standard of living, promote better rural health,
eduction and to prevent famine, but the productive potential of the agricultural sector has never
been adequately promoted. This was because of the government's lack of capacity to implement
long term perspective public policies in a society where there is an institutionalized survival
strategy. Consequently, the fact remains that despite all the revolutionary reforms and the rhetoric
which has accompanied them, Ethiopia remains potentially one of the richest but actually one of
the poorest agrarian nations in the world.
Basically, the old settlement patterns were congruent with the survival strategies of the
groups that produce them. These were the outward expressions of their survival strategy. Hence,
the effect of the villagization inevitably disrupted the social institution which went with the
previous patterns. The Ethiopian authorities however, did not accept that the traditional settlement
patters are created by the peasants themselves as an aspect of their survival "instead, denying the
people any social creativity the old settlement pattern is represented as something imposed by
feudalism", (Survival International: 1988:15).
Even though social ties and structures are profoundly affected by the change of residence
patterns, the government believed that the community of the new village is simply the same
community, that previously lived in the area scattered so that the social unit has not in fact been
changed. This is to ignore the other levels of societal survival institutions that existed within these
communities.
61
CHAPTER V
5.1 FINDINGS. CONCLUSIONS AND RECOMMENDATIONS
Roughly some sixty years ago the rapid de-colonialization process entirely changed the
world map. However, we still have a problem in understanding the relationship between state and
society within he context of sub-Saharan Africa. In the years following the rapid decolonialization process there was a great sense of urgency to create modern and developed national
societies in the sub-continent. "It was also eagerly anticipated that the new states could lay the way
for directing the economic and social changes already engulfing their societies (Migdal 1988: 11).
But as it has been indicated in chapter II, these newly formed states being peculiarly distinguished
from their equivalents in other parts of the world, especially in their source of power and
strength, were unable to provide benefits for their citizens. In lights of the above, this research
paper found out the following general and particular features of state-society ties in sub-Saharan
Africa.
As indicated in the literature review the level of political maturity achieved by any given
society basically depends upon the relationships between the state and society that has given birth
to it. Although this may seem applicable in all circumstances and in all societies, the sub-Saharan
Africa reality with respect to state formation preludes our effort to assess the state-society ties.
In sub-Saharan Africa, colonialism actually failed to integrate society into a larger and viable
systems. Moreover, unlike state formations in other parts of the world, in sub-Saharan africa
colonialism formed states within a very short period of time there by disrupting the basic
ingredients of state, state formation and state-society ties. Here it has been observed that colonial
domination led to the destruction of the already existing state formations which were already
under progress, as well as the existing form of production. This process destroyed the political and
social formation which hitherto had provided the protection of the individual. Consequently the
societies in sub-Saharan Africa responded by withdrawing into pre-colonial survival systems in
which the individual was protected and his needs were fulfilled. In another dimension, the leaders
of sub-Saharan saw as their primary mission the replacement of foreign rule by African rule.
However, the state being basically detached from society failed to provided a platform, an in
depth process of thought action, geared towards the creation of a new domestic order that is
culturally viable and politically geared to real liberation of society. The existence of the survival
systems and a detached state from society, provided the African policy making process with its
historical peculiarity. The internal dynamics of the institutionalized survival strategies and the
relations they give rise to policy implementations constitutes a world of their own within which
the society protects and promotes its own interest's often at the expense of the long term
62
development oriented public policies of the state.
The survival strategies of sub-Saharan Africa were found to be net works of support,
communication, and interaction among societies who are usually at the edge of starvation and
death, in their daily survival. These structurally defined groups, connected by different affinities
such as religion, ethnic group, kin or blood etc.,provide the members with structural opportunities
for survival through horizontal as well as lateral expansions both economically and socially within
traditionally known and accepted networks.
As it has been indicated in the literature review, basically the state should be part of
society, with many characteristics not very different from those of other social organizations. But
the nature of the inherited colonial state, its method of conquest, legitimation and perpetuation
preludes this principal assumption. Consequently, by gauging the appropriateness of the policy
making process and the central elements of the state-society ties, it was found out that the
existence of numerous survival institutions that exercises effective social control, has a decisive
effect on the likelihood of a given positive policy impact. However, if the states of sub-Saharan
Africa were the results of the society itself they could have had the right and ability to make the
countless rules that guides peoples social behaviour willingly.
Moreover, due to the lack of institutionalization, the sub-Saharan Africa states lacked the
administrative structures, personnel and the culture necessary for the efficient management and
organization of the state and the society with different objectives. An objective of the state
favourably inclined toward radical changes and long term development oriented public policies
and the objective of society aimed at the short-term survival.
It was also found that the existing development studies to explain the sub-Saharan Africa
policy crises, its origin, nature, magnitude, propose patterns, are in crisis themselves. So far there
is no single country who can be shown to have developed on any of the numerous modes and
prescriptions. As indicated in III many of the existing approaches to understanding social and
political change and the means of achieving such changes in sub-Saharan Africa either
underestimated the existing conflict all together, or have missed this particular sorts of conflicts
and emphasised on class based conflicts alone, or have down played the important dynamics
within the society itself. Indeed, all these approaches failed to understand the most and important
exchange between state and society.
These failures can partially be explained by the existence of peculiar institutions,
structures and process of state-society ties which are non-existent in the western world. Apart
from this the applicability of the current theories of policy making, i.e, the traditional inputoutput schemes; the concept of rationality in policy making; the theory of the disjointed
increamentalism; and the normative optimum model were found to be an able to accommodate all
the variables that exist with in the realities of sub-Saharan Africa state-society ties. Thus neither
of the models have significant utility in the analysis and understanding of policy making in sub-
63
Saharan Africa, however, hard the states in this region attempted to implement them in practice.
Hence, the present policy crises in sub-Saharan Africa can only be found in the state-society ties.
Following the arguments made by the seminar participants of the state and the crises in
Africa, this research paper also emphasises that the present crises in sub-Saharan Africa is largely
an institutional crises and partially it is the crises of the state. The dilemma facing the African
states is that because it was inherited, in many instances just like an empty shell from the colonial
powers, the African leaders, in fulfilling this lacuna, have been forced to devote prime attention
to defining power relations which simultaneously being asked to implement often ill conceived,
usually donor-funded, development programmes and projects with unrealistic time horizon
(participants of the twenty-fifth anniversary of Dag Hammarskjold commemoration 1986:6).
Using an approach based on inward looking consciousness, from the state-society ties, this
research attempted to map out the key dimensions of the state-society relations in sub-Saharan
Africa. As it has been demonstrated in chapter iv, if the public policies of the state strengthens
the specific survival strategies of societies, that society will ally itself with state policy and act in
accordance with its guidelines. If, however, public policies are in contradiction with the
immediate survival strategies of a given society, then they will work to minimize their exposure
and vulnerability to these formes of state interventions. Based on the assessment of these
relationships one observers a high degree of indifference and contradiction in most sub-Saharan
Africa countries.
A through examination of the state-society ties in sub-Saharan Africa reveals that societies
under survival strategies resist what long term development oriented public policies claim to
achieve, because they feel deeply threatened in their own sense of self esteem. Therefore as
indicated in chapter iii, the states of sub-Saharan Africa countries were found to be in
contradiction. In one side they need long term development, and public policies of that sort in
order to gain esteem in the international arena, and in the other society is not ready to give up
its self esteem in the development process. In brief this research paper argued that the structure
of state and society and the subsequent state-society ties have an important direct effect on the
impact of a given policy and on its success or failure. This inward looking approach helps shed
light on why long term development oriented public policies of the state do not achieve their
envisaged goals and why societal references are divergent from that of the state. Our assessment
of the state-society ties within the context of sub-Saharan Africa demonstrated the critical
survival actions by the society in the economic, political and socio-cultural spheres.
Moreover, the basic characteristics of sub-Saharan Africa societies, i.e, lineages, familial
networks, chiefdoms, secret societies, local communities and the associated activities used to
rationalize, justify, and conceptualize these institutions, can only be explained by the existence
of survival strategies. Apart from this what Miller termed as patterns of deference, attitudes
toward seniority, values related to cooperation, friendship, reciprocity and hierarchy, concerns
64
about social maintenance and even development; all these and more could only be explained by
institutionalized survival strategies. As it has been clearly indicated, these economic, political and
cultural interconnections between the state and the society in sub-Saharan Africa were found to
be irreconcilable unless their is a major change in emphasis.
Basically the ideal type of state definition of Max Weber, as an organization, composed
of numerous agencies led and coordinated by the state leadership (executive authority) that has
the ability or authority to make and implement the binding rules of all people as well as the
parameters of rule making for other social organizations in a given territory (Weber 1964:156),
seems to be unapplicable to sub-Saharan Africa realities.
As indicated in chapter iii in a society where there is acute social problem, survival
strategies are always crucial. Within the same line argument this research paper found out a
peculiar set of normative, phenomenological and existential values guiding the traditional survival
systems. These values were found to be effective in ensuring shot-term survival and short-term
social stability as well as in providing social identity to everyone who is member of that
institution.
In another dimension the values that are held by the post-colonial states were mostly
inclined towards nation building and long term perspective public policies. Consequently the two
sets of values and the associated parameters held both by the state and society were of two distinct
universes. In most cases it was found out that the policies aimed for the long-run having the
opposite effect on the short-term perspective survival strategies of that given society.
The research used the agricultural sector to demonstrate the impacts of survival strategies
on the long-term development oriented public policies of state for a number of reasons. First and
for most, agriculture's heavy weight in the economic structure is common to all sub-Saharan
African countries. According to conservative estimates around eighty-five percent of the
population and labour force are still dependent on agricultural incomes. Second, in spite of various
attempts by the state, many sub-Saharan African countries have significantly lost the capacity to
feed their people, and now sub-Saharan Africa stands as the poorest region in the world economy.
Due to the increasing high rate of population increase, lagging food production, malnutrition and
abject poverty, most sub-Saharan Africa countries are receiving the greatest bulk of foreign aid.
Above all, since survival strategies are very much prominent and highly institutionalized in the
rural context,to ascertain our hypothesis, the research singled outthree rural development policies
in sub-Saharan Africa namely from Ethiopia, Kenya and Tanzania.
All the three policies dealt with the agricultural sector, and since most of the sub-Saharan
Africa countries are characterized by subsistence peasant producers, the treatment of peasants and
their survival strategies visa-vis the long range agricultural policies enabled us to draw some
findings, conclusions and recommendations about the agricultural sector in general and the policy
making process in particular.
65
Basically all the three policies of Ethiopia, Kenya and Tanzania were found to be sound
at statement level. Because they were all aimed at improving the chronic problems of the majority
of the rural poor. Nonetheless, the two rural development policies of Ethiopia and Tanzania were
a failure, while the Kenyan smallholder tea development policy was a success. As noted in the
working hypothesis, this research paper took three main premises in relation to public policies in
general and public policies of sub-Saharan Africa in particular. To these effects the research
hypothesised, that the causes for the current policy crises in sub-Saharan Africa is as a result of
formulating and implementing development oriented public policies of long-term perspective in
a society where the majority of the people have their own short-term survival strategies of
different sort. We also underlined that society with short-term survival strategies in no way
displays a commitment towards public policies aimed for the long-run unless the policy
strengthens the s.urvi val strategies themselves. We further hypothesised that those policies which
strengthen the survival strategies themselves bring qualitative improvement for the public policy
making process and the society at large.
Following the hypothesis the research paper made an in depth analysis as to the underling
causes of the success and failures of the three rural development policies of Ethiopia, Kenya and
. Tanzania.
As indicated in chapter iv both the rural development policies of Ethiopia and Tanzania
were a failure mainly because of their lack of emphasis on the survival strategies of societies'.
Both the Ethiopian and Tanzanian policy makers undermined the impacts of local survival
strategies, rather than strengthening the survival strategies of society, policy makers viewed
development as a change in the survival institutions themselves. They failed to realize that, to
bring change on these survival institutions from the top is impossible unless the changes are made
within itself dialectically. And this can only be possible by strengthening the survival strategies
themselves. Both Nyerere and Mengistu felt that socialism is an attitude of mind, and this state
of mind was their centre-foci. But what the two regimes failed to realize was that the long term
societal development by itself has value problems. To this effect, what actually has happened in
Ethiopia and Tanzania is a the case in point. The manners in which this policy changes were
proposed disrupted the delicate mechanism of survival, i.e. their conscious strategy for obtaining
their short term goals, their ability to process information and ultimately to survive.
Unlike the two rural development policies of Ethiopia and Tanzania, the smallholder tea
development policy of Kenya was a success to the extent that, currently Kenya has the most
successful peasant based tea scheme in the world. The Kenyan policy makers realized the
behaviours of the rural poor as the complex producing and consuming unit, and they strengthened
the wide range institutionalized survival strategies in the social, cultural, political as well as the
economic life that society. Thus, the Kenyan policy making strength was largely related to a
careful exercise in maintaining the key institutions of survival through the judicious allocation
66
of scarce resources. This process allowed the local survival institutions to be extremely involved
at the level of policy implementation. Hence, the success of this policy, and the higher rate of
economic growth in these' last policy making periods provided the Kenyans with an additional
incentives to meaningfully pursue to strengthening to the extent of adopting guidelines to
encourage the rural informal rural sector.
Comparing the Ethiopian and Tanzanian experience in one side and the Kenyan on the
other, it was found out that the Ethiopian and Tanzanian Policy makers undermined local survival
strategies, thereby undermining local initiatives. In another dimension the Kenyan policy makers
demonstrated how a policy aimed at the survival strategies of society brings increased agricultural
productivity, self-sufficiency and lower prices for foodstuffs, etc,.
To conclude lets repeat what we have been saying at the beginning. Every individual or
group in society is bound by some sort of principle, tradition, myth, purpose or code of behaviour.
In principle we all believe that men are united by common agreement upon law and rights and
their coming together is also institutionalized through the state. But the sub-Saharan reality is
entirely different. The colonial period suppressed the process of state formation, separated state
and society and consequently strengthened survival strategies.
Apparently the post-independent sub-Saharan states inherited an institution which is a
highly detached empty shell. For example compared to peasant producers in other parts of the
world most sub-Saharan Africa farmers enjoy a relatively high degree of autonomy from the state
mainly due to the existence their survival institutions. There are a lot of evidences that the
peasants in Africa use an exit option, particularly when public policies are viewed as a threat or
as devoid of any apparent benefits (Berry 1983:4), towards their survival strategies. Since most
post-independence sub-Saharan Africa states are only a continuation of the detached state
structure of the colonial era; rather than responding to indigenous values they have often proved
to be the dominant factor in stimulating further changes throughout society. Thus, as Zolberg
persuasively put it, "if we conceive the original African societies as set of values, norms and
structure, it is evident that they survived to a significant extent every where .... Furthermore, the
new set of values norms and structures which constituted an incipient national centre, did not
necessarily grow at the expense of older ones (Zolberg 1973:313). Ultimately this unfavourable
state-society ties restricted states to effectively formulate and implement development oriented
publkpolicies which are aimed for theI6ng-n..in in a society where there are instituHomilized
survival strategies, In view of the above this research paper recommends the following.
From the societal stand point states are desirable if they contribute directly and
significantly to the major short-term survival objectives of a society. Basically the structure of
sub-Saharan Africa societies seeking progress through development oriented public policies seems
to be replete with contradictory problems. On one side there is scarcity-ridden economy and high
development aspirations of the states; on the other there are institutionalized survival strategies
67
of the society with their own orientations. Ultimately, a public policy that is aimed at improving
productivity increasing equity and enhancing self-reliance depends on strengthening the survival
strategies of society. He·re the states have to avoid becoming the only formulators and
implementers of policy. Rather we have to strengthen valued based survival institutions. Even the
legitimacy for the survival institutions need not be drawn from the top of the hierarchy but from
the society itself. Indeed, the sources of policy making should revolve around the traditional
survival parameters rather than the parameters of modern technocratic societies.
In the context of sub-Saharan Africa these two sets of value parameters are likely to be
integrated. In one side the survival parameters which ensured the society with social stability and
a distinct social identity, and on the other the modern public policy making parameters to ensure
long rang development. Thus it is necessary to identify those aspects of survival strategies,
political, economic, and socio-cultural that are particularly relevant to our favourable policy
impact. The states rather than looking to the future, have to be in touch with the past. The past
survival strategies of societies which were an ending source of survival, inspiration, perception,
wisdom, creative ideas, should be kept in mind while the state attempts to intervene in the affairs
of sub-Saharan Africa societies.
Such kind of emphasis requires policy makers to identify and select beneficiary households
and the choice of primary activity by themselves. Moreover, emphasis be given as to who will be
accountable to whom. To this effect consideration should not be confined to the availability of
appropriate technical skills, rather accountability to the target society. The policy directives should
stress decentralized and shared decision making, responsiveness and low cost short-term delivery
rather than coordination and control.
A policy aimed at the
ウィッイエMZセ[ゥカ。ャ@
strategies of societies calls for an open communication
and simplification of policy guidelines rather than adherence to a general set of prescribed
technical recommendation and complex rules. Apart from this the policy needs a direct feedback
through a continuous assessment of beneficiaries.
Following the recommendations made by the global coalition for Africa, this research
paper strongly believes that the role of the people and their survival institutions are central to
realization of popular participation. Thus, the people "have to be fully involved, committed and
indeed, seize the initiative" (Global Coalition for Africa 1992:26).
In this respect it is crucial that the time tested survival institutions of society develop links
across the country to promote cooperation and exchange experience. The policy making models
and development strategies should contain the parameters and aspirations of the society, they have
to include the societal values and the environmental realities. In strengthening these endogenous
survival strategies our policy has to pursue broad-based participation of the society, on a
decentralized fashion.
As it has been mentioned earlier, societies under survival strategies have unique needs
68
arising out of their historical socio-economic backgrounds and conditions. Thus, any public policy
aimed for the poor should consider their capacity to use the envisaged policy outcomes and that
it is within their own priorities. Hence, any sound policy of the state must therefore, strengthen
the outer as well as the inner boundaries of the survival strategies not eliminate its core. The core
of pre-modern survival strategies must be respected and innovative policy measures be taken to
develop the margins of these survival strategies.
69
BIBILIOGRAPHY
Alemayehu Lirenso. 1990. "Resettlement: Policy and Practice". Ethiopia: Rural Development
Options. New Jeresy: Billing and Sons Ltd. Pages 135-141.
Alemneh Dejene. 1990. "Peasants, Environment, Resettlement". Ethiopia: Rural Development
Options. New Jeresy: Billing and Sons Ltd.Pages 164-172.
Altenstetter, Christa and JW, Bjorkman. 1981. "Planning and Implementation: A Comparative
Perspective on Health Policy." International Political Science Review. 2:11-42.
Anderson, James. 1978. "The Study of Public Policy." Public Policy Making. New York: R.E.
Krieger. Pages 1-9.
Anderson, P. 1980. Lineages of the Absolutist State. London: Verso.
Apter, DE. 1965. The Politics of Modernization. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Apter, DE. 1971. "The Structural Theory and Its Boundaries". Choice and The Politics of
Allocation. NewHaven: Yale University Press. Pages 6-42 ..
Ayoade, AA. 1988. "States Without Citizens: An Emerging African Phenomena." The Precarious
Balance: State and Society in Africa. Colorado: Westview Press Inc.
Azaria, Victor. 1988. "Reordering State-Society Relations: Incorporation and Disengagement." The
Precarious Balance: State and Society in Africa. Colorado: Westview Press Inc.
Barkan, JD. and Okumu, JJ. 1979. Politics and Public Policy in Kenya and Tanzania. New York:
Praeger Publishers.
Barker, J. 1979. "The Debt on Rural Socialism In Tanzania". Towards Socialism In Tanzania.
Tanzania Publishing House. Pages 95-125.
Barker, J. 1980. "Can The Poor In Africa Fight Poverty". Journal of African Studies. 7:161-166.
Berry, S. 1977. Risk and The Poor Farmer. Boston: Boston University.
Berry, S. 1984. Fathers Work For Their Sons. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Billings, Dwight. 1990. "Religion As Opposition A Gramscian Analysis." American Journal of
Sociology. 96: 1-31.
Bjorkman, JW. 1992. "Squaring Circles in Public Policy: Development Administration and
Administrative Development." (Inaugural Address as Professor of Public Policy and
Administration at Rijks Universiteit Leiden).
Bjorkman, JW. 1976. "A Conceptual Approach to the Study of Policy Implementation."
(Unpublished Manuscript).
Blondel, Jean. 1982. "The Notion of Government." The Organization of Government: A
Comparative Analysis of Government Structure. London: Saga Publications. Pages 13-30.
Boesen, J. Tanzania. From Ujamaa to Villagization. Copenhagen: RDP.
Boesen, J. 1972. Development and Class Structure in a Smallholder Society and the Potential of
Ujamaa.Copenhagen: RDP.
Brune, S. 1990. "The Agricultural Sector". Ethiopia: Rural Development Options. New Jeresy:
Billing and Sons Ltd. Pages 15-27.
Callaghy, TH. 1984. The State Society Struggle. Zaire In Comparative Perspective. New
York:Colombia University Press.
Carlsen, J. 1980. Economic and Social Transformation in Rural Kenya. Uppsala: Scandinavian
Institute of African Studies.
Chazan, Nahomi. 1988. "Patterns of State Society Incorporation and Disengagement." The
Precarious Balance: State and Society in Africa. Colorado: Westview Press Inc., Pages 3-100
Clapham, Christopher. 1989. "The State and Revolution in Ethiopia." Review of African Political
Economy.44: 1-17.
Cohen, JM. 1984. "Agrarian Reform in Ethiopia: The Situation on the Eve of the Revolution's
10th Anni versary". Development Discussion Papers No.10.
Coulson, A. 1975. "Peasants and Bureaucrats". Review of African Political Economy. 3:51-55.
Dahal, G. 1979. Suffering Grass. Stockholm: University of Stockholm.
Dahl, Robert A. 1967. " The Evolution of Political Systems." Contemporary Political Science. New
York: McGraw-Hill Company. Pages 166-182.
Davis, Babrow and John, Dryzek. 1987. "Toward Policy Design." Policy Analysis by Design.
Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press. Pages 200-211.
Dessalegn Rahameto, 1991. "Survival: Community and Cooperation." Famine and Survival
Strategies. Uppsala: Bohuslaningens Boktryckeri AB. Pages 117-230.
Dessalegn Rahameto. 1990. "Cooperatives, State Farms and Smallholder production". Ethiopia:
Rural Development Options. New Jeresy: Billing and Sons Ltd. Pages 100-107.
Dessalegn Rahmato. 1984. Agrarian Reform. Uppsala: Scandinavian Institute of African Studies.
Dietmar, Herbon. 1988. "The System of Securing Survival". Socio-Economic Strategies of Survival
In Bangladesh. Gottingen: PolyCon. Pages 137-148.
Dietz, AJ. 1987. "Pastoralists' in Dire Straits." Survival Strategies and External Interventions in
A Semi Arid Region at The Kenya/Uganda Border. Amsterdam: University of
Amsterdam.
Dirks, R. 1980. "Social Response During Severe Food Shortages and Famine."
Current
Anthropology. 21: 1
Donald Rothchild and Michael foley. 1983. "The Implications of Scarcity for Governance in
Africa."International Political Science Review. 4:3-315.
Doner, F. Richard. 1992. "Limits of State Strength Toward an Institutional View of Development."
World Politics. 44:398:432.
Dror, Yehezkel. 1968. Public Policy Making Re-Examined. San Francisco: Chandler Publishers.
Drar, Yehezkel. 1987. "Top Administrators in Developing Countries: Needs and Options."
Management Development Senior Administrators. New York: U.N. Pages 1-82.
Dumont, R, 1957. Types of Rural Economy: Studies in Worlds Agriculture. London: Saga
Publications.
Dye, Thomas. 1970. "Basic Concepts in Policy Analysis - A Model for the Analysis of Policy
Outcomes." Policy Analysis in Political Science. Chicago: Markham Publishing Company.
Pages 21-38.
Ekeh, P. 1975. "Colonialism and The Two Publics in Africa: A Theoretical Statement".
Comparative Studies In Society and History. 17:91-112.
Etioni, Amitai. 1967. "Mixed Scanning A 'third" Approach to Decision Making."
セ@
Administration Review. December:385-392.
Etzioni, Halevy. 1983. "Theoretical Perspectives." Bureaucracy and Democracy: A Political
Dilemma. London: Routledge and Paul Kegan. Pages 1-99.
Fatton, Robert. 1989. "The State of African Studies and Studies of the African State: The
Theoretical Softness of the "Soft State. journal of Asian and African Studies. XXIV:170185.
Finer, SE. 1975. "The Man on A horse Back". The Role of The Military in Politics. Westview:
Boulder Co.
Finer, SE. 1974. "State and Nation Building in Western Europe: The Role of the Military". セ@
Science Information. 13:4:79-126.
Finucane, JR. 1974. Rural Development and Bureaucracy in Tanzania. Uppsala: The Scandinavian
Institute of African Studies.
Forrest, Joshua. 1987. "The Contemporary African State: A "Ruling Class"? Review of African
Political
Economy_ 38:66-71.
Freyhold, MV. 1979. Ujamaa Villages in Tanzania Analysis of Social Experiment. London:
Henemann
Garg, PK and Patrikh, I1. 1988. "Values, Design and Development of Strategic Organizations".
Development A New Role of The Organizational Sciences. New Delhi: Saga Publications.
Pages 123-139.
Garry, Hamilton and John, Sutton. 1988. "The Problems of Control in the Weak State." Theory and
Society. 18:1-145.
Geoffery lamb and Lind Miller. 1982. Control. Accountability, and Incentive In A Successful
Development Institution: The Kenya Tea Development Authority. Washington: The World
Bank.
Ghai, Godfrey and Lisk. 1979. "Planning for Basic Needs in Kenya." Performance, Policies and
Prosperity. Geneva: ILO Publications.
Goricke, FV. 1979. "The 1975 Land Reform Legislation". Social and Political Factors Influencing
the application of Land Reform Measures In Ethiopia. Fort Lauderdale: Varlag Breten bach
Publishers. Pages 98-134.
Goulet, D. 1977. The Uncertain Promise. New York: Edwards brothers Inc.
Goulet, D. 1973. The Cruel choice. New York: Antheneum.
Grindle, Merilee S and John W Thomas. 1989. "Policy Makers, Policy Choices and Policy
Outcomes: The Political Economy of Reform in Developing Countries. "Policy Sciences.
23:213-248
Gyllstrom, B. 1977.The Organization of Production As A Space-Modelling Mechanism in
Underdeveloped Countries. The case of Tea Production in Kenya. Lund: Gleerup.
Hansen, E. 1987. Changes in the Land Tenure and Land Use Since Yillagization and Their Impact
on Peasant Agriculture Production in Tanzania. Copenhagen: Centre for Development
Research.
Haugwitz, HW. 1972. Some Experiences With Smallholder Settlement in Kenya. Munchen:
Weltforum-Verlag.
Heer, F. 1962. The Medieval World: Europe 1100-1350. New York: New American Library.
Hirschman, AO. 1970. Exit. Voice and Loyalty. Cambridge: Mass Harvard University Press.
Hirschman, AO.1965. Journeys Towards Progress. New York: Doubleday Anchor Books.
Hoeven, R. Van Der. 1988. "Planning for Basic Needs; A Soft Option or A Solid Policy?" A Basic
Needs Simulation model Applied to Kenya. Aldershot: Gower Publishers.
Hoeven, VD. 1988. "Some Examples of An Early Application of A Basic Needs Approach".
Planning For Basic Needs a Soft Option or A Solid Policy. Aldershot: Gower Publishing
Company. Pages 3-10.
Holmquist,F.1970. "Implementing Rural Development Projects". Development Administration The
Kenyan Experience. Nairobi: Oxford University Press. Pages 201-233.
Hunt, CL. 1966. Social aspects of Economic Development. New York: McGraw-Hill Book
Company.
Hyden, G. 1980. Beyond Ujamaa in Tanzania. Ibadan: The Chaucer Press.
Hyden, GR. 1983. No Shortcuts to Progress: African Development Management in Perspective.
Berkeley: University of California Press.
Hyden, G. 1983. No Shortcuts To Progress. London: Heinemann Educational Books Ltd.
Hyden, GR. 1986. "African Social Structure and Economic Development."Strategies for African
Development. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Hyden, GR. Jackson and T. Okumu. 1970. Development Administration The Kenyan Experiment.
Nairobi: East
Hyden, GR. 1980. Beyond Ujamaa in Tanzania: Underdevelopment and Un captured
Peasantry.London: Heinemann.
Iglesias, Gebrial. 1986. "Implementation and the Planning of Development: Notes on Trends and
Issues. Focusing on the Concept of Administrative Capability." Implementation - The
Problems of Achieving Results. Manila: Europa. Pages XV-Xl.
Khoshkish, A. 1979. "Policy and Polity." The Socio - Political Complex. Oxford: William Clows
Limited. Pages 1-9, 287-330.
Leftwich, A. 1983. "The Politics of European Expansion, Conquest and Control". Redefining
Politics. New York: Methuen and Co. Ltd. Pages 117-157.
Lemarchand, R. 1981. Political Clientelism. Patronage and Development. Baverly Hills: Sage
Publications.
Lindblom, Charles. 1959. "The Science of Muddling Through." Public Administration Review.
20:79-88.
Livingstone, 1. 1981. Rural Development. Employment and Incomes in Kenya. Addis Abeba:
JASPA.
Lloyd, Christopher. 1983. Social Theory and Political Practice. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Luta Malyamkomo and Mboya Bagachwa. 1990. The Second Economy in Tanzania. London:
Viliers Publications.
MacGaffey, Janet. "Economic Disengagement and Class Formation in Zaire." The Precarious
Balance States and Societies in Africa: Colorado: Westview Press Inc.
Maliyamakono, TL and Bagachwa, MSD. 1990. The Second Economy in Tanzania. London:
Villiers Publications.
Mascarenhas, A. 1979. "After Villagization What?" Towards Socialism in Tanzania. Dar es salaam:
Tanzanian Publishing House. Pages 145-169.
Mayntz, Renate. 1978. "Public Bureaucracies and Policy Implementation." International Social
Science Journal. XXXI:633-645.
McHenry, JR. 1976. "Peasant Participation In Communal Farming. The Tanzanian Experience".
(Paper Presented to the African Associations Conference).
McHenry, JR. 1974. Gaining Peasant Confidence: The Colonial Government's Implementation of
Policies Affecting Rural Tanganyika. Dar es Salaam: University of Dar es Salaam.
Mehta, Prayas. 1988. "Organizing for Empowering The Poor." Social Development. New Delhi:
Sage Publications. Pages 174-185.
Mesfin Wolde Mariam, 1986. Rura] Vulnerability to Famine In Ethiopia-1958-1977. London:
Intermediate Technology Publications.
Migdal, JS. 1987. "Strong Sta tes, Weak States: Power and Accommodation." Understanding Political
DevelQpment. Boston: McGraw-Hill Book Company. Pages 391-432.
Migdal, JS. 1974. Peasants. Politics and Revolution. Princenton: Princenton University Press.
Migdal, JS. 1988. Strong Societies and Weak States. New Jeresy: Princenton University Press.
Miller, DB. 1979. Peasants and Politics: grass Roots Reaction to Change in Asia. London: Edward
Arnold.
Mills, C. Wright. 1959. The Sociological Imagination. New York: Dell Publishers.
Milne, RS. 1972. "Decision Making in Developing Countries." Journal of Comparative
Administration. 3:387-491.
Moody, T. 1972. Study of Six Ujamaa Villages in Karagwe District-West Lake Region Cfan 7.anial.
Copenhagen: RDP.
Morss, ER. 1980. "Cross-Cutting Issues Emerging From The Arusha Regional Planning Exercise."
(WDC Development Alternative).
Mushi, SS. 1971. Uiamaa: Modernization By Tradition. Dar es Salaam: University of Dar es
Salaam.
Mushi,SS. 1977. Uiamaa Planning and The Politics of Allocation Dar es Salaam: University of Dar
es Salaam.
Ndulu, Benno. 1986. "Governance and Economic Management" Strategies for African
Development. Berkeley: University of California Press. Pages 81-111.
Negarit Gazeta. No. 71 of 1975.
Negarit Gazeta. No. 35 of 1975.
Newman, Saul. 1991. "Does Modernization Breed Ethnic Political Conflict?" World Politics.
43:451-458.
Nisbet, Robert A. 1969. "The State and Community." The Quest for Community. London: Oxford
University Press. Pages 75-189.
Nordlinger, Eric A. 1987. "Taking the State Seriously." Understanding Political Development.
Boston: Little Brown. Pages 353-389.
Nordlinger, Eric A. 1970. "The Sociology of Political Change." Politics and Society. Englewood
Cliffs: Prentice-Hall, Inc., Pages 197-348.
Nyerere, J. 1967. Socialism and Rural Development. Dar es salaam: Government Printer.
Nyerere, J. 1968·. Freedom and Socialism. Dar es Salaam: Oxford University Press.
Okumu, 11. 1970. "The Political Setting". Development Administration. The Kenyan Experience.
Nairobi: Oxford University.
Omari, CK. 1976. The Strategy for Rura1 Deve1opment; Tanzanian Experience. Kampala: East
African Literature Bureau.
Parpart, JL. 1989. Women and The State in Africa. Boulder: Rienner.
Pausewang, S. 1990. "Meret Le Arrahu". Ethiopian: Rural DevelQpment Options. New 1eresy:
Billing and Sons Ltd. Pages 38-46.
Pausewang, s. 1983. "Land Reform, Famine and Change". Peasants. Land and Society. Munchen:
Weltforum-Verlag GmbH. Pages 87-101.
Pausewang, S. 1990. "The Peasant Perspective". Ethiopia: Rural Development OPtions. New Jeresy:
Billing and Sons Ltd. Pages 205-210.
Pool, lthiel de Sola. 1967. "The Public and Polity." Contemporary Political Science. New York:
McGraw-Hill Book Company. Pages 22-53.
Price, RM. 1975. Society and Bureaucracy in Contemporary Ghana. Berkeley: University of
California Press.
Pye, Lucian W. 1967. "The Formation of New States." Contemporary Political Science. New York:
McGraw-Hill Book Company. Pages 182-204.
Robbins, Lord. 1978. "The Economic Functions of The State." The Theory of Economic Policy:
London:
The Macmillan Press Ltd. Pages 34-61.
Rahaman, A. 1980. Transition To Collective Agriculture. and Peasant Participation-North
Vietnam. Tanzania and Ethiopia. Geneva: ILO.
Redclift, M.1986. "Sustainability and The Market Survival Strategies in The Bolivian Frontier."
Journal of Development Studies. 23: 1.
Saasa, Oliver. 1985. "Public-Policy Making in Developing Countries: The Utility of Contemporary
Decision-Making Models." Public Administration and Development. 5:309-321.
Samuel, Paul and Ashok, Suberamanian. 1983. "Development Programmes for the Poor - Do
Strategies Make A Difference?" Economic and Political Weekly. Special ArticIe:349-358.
Scott, James. 1976. The Moral Economy of The Peasant. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Scott,
Jc. 1976. The Moral Economy Of The Peasant. New Haven: Yale University.
Seavoy, RE. 1989. Famine in East Africa. Connecticut: Greenwood Press Inc.
Skocpol, Theda. 1979. "The Potential Autonomy of the State." States and Social Revolutions.
London: Cambridge University Press. Pages 23-33.
Smith, Thomas. 1989. "Analysis of Policy Failure: A Three Dimensional Framework." The Indian
Journal of Public Administration. XXXV:1-15.
Smith, B. Thomas. 1973. "The Study of Policy Making in Developing Nations." Policy Study
Journal. Summer:244-249.
Southall, Aietan. 1988. "The Segmentary State in Africa and Asia." Comparative Studies of Society
and History. 30:53-82.
Stahal, M. 1974. Ethiopia: Political Contradictions in Agricultural Development. Stockholm: Raben
and Sjorgren.
Stahl, Michael. 1989. "Capturing the Peasants Through Cooperatives-The Case of Ethiopia."
Review of African Political Economy. 46:27-47.
Parsons, Talcott. 1969. "The Concept of Society: The Components and Their Interrelations."
Politics and
Social Structure. New York: The Free Press. Pages 1-34.
Staudt, K. 1985. Agricultural Policy Implementation: A Case Study From Western Kenya.
WestHartFord: Kumarian Press.
Stern, NH. 1972. An Appraisal of Tea Production on Small Holdings in Kenya; An Experiment
with the Little-Mirrlees Method. Paris: OECD.
Survival International. 1988. "Traditional Society and Settlement In Ethiopia". Ethiopian
Yillagization Programme. London: Survival International. Pages 7-10.
Tegegne Teka and Tenassie Nichola. 1984. Rural Poverty Alleviation: The Case Of Ethiwia.
Rome: FAO.
Teshale Tebebu, 1988. "Process of State Formation In Modern Ethiopia". (Unpublished).
The Dutch Ministry of Development Cooperation. 1992. Global Coalition For Africa. (Sessional
Paper on Employment No.1 of 1992).
Tilly, C. 1975. "Reflecting on the History of European State-Making". The Formation of National
States in Western Europe. New Jeresy: Princeton.
Tivey, Leonard. 1981. "States, Nations and Economics." The Nation States: The Formation of
Modern Politics. Oxford: Martin Robertson. Pages 59-79.
Van Doorn, JA. 1963. "Sociology and The Problem of Power." Netherlands Sociological Society.
1:3-51.
Voortman, R. 1978. "Villagization in Tanzania, An Analysis of Development Planning."
Planologisch Studie centrum. Groningen: Rijks Universiteit.
Walter Bgoya and Goran Hyden. 1986. "The State and The Crises In Africa". (The Seminar
Proceedings of The state and Crises in Africa Which Took Place from September 15-19,
1986.
Weber, M. 1948. Essays in Sociology. London: Broadway House.
Wood, AP. 1990. "Natural Resource, Management and Rural Development in Ethiopia". Ethiopia:
Rural Development Options. New Jeresy: Billing and Sons Ltd. Pages 187-197.
Young, Crawford. 1988. "The African Colonial State and its Political Legacy"
The Precarious Balance: State and Society in Africa. Colorado: Westview Press Inc.
Young, M. 1988. The Rhythms of Society. London: Routledge.
Young, Crawford. 1980. "Patterns of Social Conflict: State, Class and Ethnicity." Journal Of
Modern African Studies. 17:531-552.
Zolberg, A. 1973. "The Military Decade in Africa" World Politics. 25:313.