Chapter 8
Wood, Fuelwood, and Non-wood Forest Products
Coordinating Lead Authors: Nigel Sizer, Stephen Bass, James Mayers
Lead Authors: Mike Arnold, Louise Auckland, Brian Belcher, Neil Bird, Bruce Campbell, Jim Carle, David
Cleary, Simon Counsell, Thomas Enters, Karin Fernando, Ted Gullison, John Hudson, Bob Kellison,
Tage Klingberg, Carlton N. Owen, Neil Sampson, Sonja Vermeulen, Eva Wollenberg, Sheona
Shackleton, David Edmunds
Contributing Authors: Patrick Durst, D.P. Dykstra, Thomas Holmes, Ian Hunter, Wulf Killmann, Ben S.
Malayang III, Francis E. Putz, Patricia Shanley
Review Editors: Cherla Sastry, Marian de los Angeles
Main Messages . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 259
8.1
Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 260
8.1.1
8.1.2
8.2
8.3
Overview and Selection of Responses . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 262
Multistakeholder and Extra-sectoral Policy Processes . . . . . . . . . . . . 263
8.3.1
8.3.2
8.3.3
8.4
8.4.3
8.4.4
Public and Consumer Action
Third-party Voluntary Forest Certification
Wood Technology and Biotechnology
Commercialization of Non-wood Forest Products
Land Management Institutions, Investment, and Incentives . . . . . . . . 279
8.6.1
8.6.2
8.6.3
8.6.4
8.6.5
8.7
Direct Management of Forests by Indigenous Peoples
Devolution and Local Forest Management and Local Movements for
Access and Use of Forest Products
Small-scale Private and Public–Private Ownership and Management of
Forests
Company–Community Forestry Partnerships
Demand-side, Market-driven, and Technological Responses . . . . . . . 271
8.5.1
8.5.2
8.5.3
8.5.4
8.6
International Forest Policy Processes and Development Assistance
Trade Liberalization
National Forest Governance Initiatives and National Forest Programs
Rights to Land and Resource Management . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 268
8.4.1
8.4.2
8.5
Driving Forces of Change in the Ecosystems that Provide Forest Products
Problems and Opportunities Created by the Driving Forces of Change
Natural Forest Management in the Tropics
Tree Plantation Management
Fuelwood Management
Carbon Management
Fire Management
Summary Lessons . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 283
REFERENCES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 291
257
Ecosystems and Human Well-being: Policy Responses
258
BOXES
TABLES
8.1
Public–Private Partnerships in Forest Management: Some
U.S. Case Studies
8.1
Typology of Company–Community Forestry Arrangements,
by Partner
8.2
Conservation Concessions
8.2
8.3
Selected Forest Certification Programs
Conditions under which Companies, Communities, and
Landscapes Win or Lose in Partnership Arrangements
8.4
Wood Products Manufacturing Technology: A U.S. Case
Study
8.3
Lessons Learned from Forest-based Carbon Sequestration
Projects
8.5
Reduced Impact Logging
8.4
How Responses Can Differ in Various Contexts
8.6
Dendro Power
8.5
Summary Assessment of Responses: Wood, Fuelwood, and
Non-wood Forest Products
Wood, Fuelwood, and Non-wood Forest Products
Main Messages
Strategies to address the impacts of forest product use on ecosystem
health and human well-being are strongly affected by actions outside the
forest sector. Some responses to problems related to forest products are
achieving far more impact than others. Outcomes tend to be shaped as much
or more by policies and institutions related to trade, macroeconomics, agriculture, infrastructure, energy, mining, and a range of other ‘‘sectors’’ than by
processes and instruments within the forest sector itself. The objectives of
some sectoral responses might be better achieved by non-forest measures; for
example, land reform might benefit poor communities more than collaborative
forest management. When considering responses, it is important to understand
the degree to which each may be undermined or overridden by driving forces
beyond the forest sector and the degree to which each can engage with and
influence such forces.
Forest product trade tends to concentrate decision-making power over
(and benefits from) forest management in the hands of powerful interest
groups, rather than spreading it to include poorer and less powerful players. It ‘‘magnifies’’ the effect of governance, making good forest governance better and making bad forest governance worse. This threatens
prospects for long-term sustainability. Both increased trade and trade restrictions can make impacts worse if underlying policy and institutional failures are
not tackled. Trade liberalization can stimulate a ‘‘virtuous cycle’’ if the regulatory framework is robust and externalities are addressed.
International forest policy processes have made some gains within the
forest sector. Attention now needs to turn to integration of agreed forest
management practices in financial institutions, trade rules, global environment programs, and global security decision-making. The last decade
saw many intergovernmental and civil society ‘soft’ policy responses to define
sustainable forest management and to produce guidelines that could be interpreted locally. These responses included the United Nations Conference on
Environment and Development, the International Tropical Timber Organization,
and the Convention on Biological Diversity; they have both enabled much local
progress and linked forest debates between local and global levels. Much
critical intergovernmental policy work within the sector has been done. National
policy and the interpretation and implementation of international policy at the
national level are increasingly influenced by extra-sectoral policy and planning
frameworks. Forest sector frameworks will have to adjust to more directly serve
these wider goals or their influence will diminish.
Forest governance initiatives and country-led national forest programs
are showing promise for integrating ecosystem health and human wellbeing where they are negotiated by stakeholders and strategically focused. Multilateral and bilateral accords to combat illegal logging, its associated trade, and the governance frameworks that might prevent it are becoming
important venues for developing action plans and agreements. National forest
programs are now being strongly promoted on the understanding that they
follow a country-led approach. To be most effective, these programs should
have multistakeholder involvement in forest decision making; be a means for
cooperation, coordination, and partnership; promote secure forest resource access and use rights; involve research and traditional knowledge; and be built
upon the study and policies on underlying causes of deforestation and degradation. In addition, they should include codes of conduct for business. They
should have built in monitoring, evaluation, and reporting on their progress and
effectiveness. To date, the new breed of national forest programs, although
quite widespread, shows more promise than tangible results.
Local responses to problems of access and use of forest products have
proliferated in recent years. They are collectively more significant than
259
efforts led by governments or international processes but require their
support to spread. A wide range of local responses have emerged ‘‘spontaneously’’ over the last decade, each with locally appropriate organizational forms
and proven or potential impact in improving the contribution of ecosystems to
human well-being and poverty alleviation. They often have a strong emphasis
on gender equity. These include campesino forestry organizations in Central
America, forest user groups in Nepal, the National Council of Rubber Tappers
in Brazil, people’s natural resource management organizations in the Philippines, and the Landcare movement in Australia. Policy frameworks could better
assist such groups to build on what they are already doing and to enable new
partnerships. Multistakeholder poverty-forests learning processes could be fostered with codes of conduct for supporting local initiatives. These could be
integrated into national forest programs and poverty reduction strategies.
Government-community collaborative forest management can be highly
beneficial but has had mixed results. Most collaborative management has
promoted arrangements that maintain and even extend central government
control. Local people generally have better legal access to forests and some
have higher incomes but many have lost access and benefits. As a result the
‘‘co-management’’ response is shifting. Management increasingly involves not
just a local group and the government but a range of stakeholders, and acknowledges overlapping systems of management and diverse interests. Local
people are able to win more benefits for themselves where they have strong
local organizational capacity and political capital to mobilize resources and
negotiate for better benefits. NGOs, donors, federations, and other external
actors also have a key role in supporting local interests. Where local groups
manage their own forests without state intervention, however, they are not
necessarily better off. Without government support, they often have difficulty
implementing or enforcing their decisions. Improved formal access to forests
has helped in many cases to protect a vital role of forests as safety nets for
rural people to meet their basic subsistence needs. The benefits to be gained
beyond the subsistence-level, however, are limited.
There is a widespread need for support to enable people in forest areas
to secure their rights and strengthen their powers to negotiate fair division of control, responsibility, and benefits with other actors. Many governments have realized that they cannot secure a balance of public and private
benefits from forests. Some have transferred control to private entities under
lease agreements requiring public benefits to be guaranteed. Others have
recognized, returned, or created rights for local communities to own forests,
manage them, benefit from them, and bear certain costs and risks. Such communities often lack adequate recognition, powers, organization, capacity, and
information to make use of these rights. Ways to cover the transaction costs
of collective action are still sought. Checks and balances need to be in place
to ensure that no group, including the local elite, controls benefits and decisionmaking. Processes are needed that acknowledge plural interests among the
different groups and give special attention to livelihood needs of the poor.
Culturally appropriate and technically sound cooperation between indigenous
and non-indigenous organizations to reinforce natural resource management
on indigenous lands is rare. This is much needed given the rapid growth in
areas over which indigenous peoples have control.
Where information, tenure, and capacity are strong, small private owners
of forests may deliver more local economic benefits and better forest
management than larger corporate owners. Individuals and families have
proven their potential to practice good forestry over the long term. However,
many conditions are required for this to be effective. These include good
knowledge, capacity to manage, market information, organization among
smallholders to ensure economies of scale, long-term tenure, and transfer
rights. Private ownership (or ‘‘family forestry’’) is common in Western Europe
and in the southern United States, and is increasingly common in Latin
260
Ecosystems and Human Well-being: Policy Responses
America and Asia. It may lead owners to assume a greater sense of responsibility and foster long-term thinking, prompting them to pursue sustainability,
partly for risk reduction. Experience in Nordic countries and in many continental European countries shows the positive effects generated by information
flow, education, and training and that it can be in the self-interest of owners to
‘‘do right.’’
Company–community partnerships can be better than solely corporate
forestry, or solely community or small-scale farm forestry, in delivering
benefits to the partners and the public at large. Companies may seek to
improve long-term survival and competitiveness. Communities may prioritize
gains such as secured land tenure or improved local infrastructure. Effects on
equity and rural development are mixed. Financial returns often have proven
insufficient to lift community partners out of poverty. Making the most of partnerships requires iterative approaches to developing equitable, efficient, and
accountable governance frameworks (at the contract level and more broadly),
raising the bargaining power of communities, particularly through association
at appropriate scales, fostering the roles of brokers and other third parties
(especially independent community development organizations), sharing the
benefits of wood processing as well as production, and working toward standards that give equal opportunities to small-scale enterprises.
Public and consumer action has resulted in some important forest and
trade policy initiatives and improved practices in some large forest corporations. Public and consumer action has been key in the development of
forest and trade policy initiatives in ‘‘timber consuming countries’’ and in international institutions. The operating standards of some large corporations and
institutions, as well as of those whose non-forest activities have an impact on
forests, have been improved. Consumer campaigns have provided the underpinning for forest certification and served as a useful mechanism for bringing
public attention to, and engagement with, issues that are often geographically
remote. Such campaigns can potentially continue to play an important role
both in maintaining public awareness of forestry issues and in encouraging
improved forest management.
Forest certification has become widespread; however, most certified forests are in the ‘‘North,’’ managed by large companies and exporting to
Northern retailers. The early drivers of certification hoped it would be an
effective response to tropical deforestation. There has been a proliferation of
certification programs to meet different stakeholders’ needs with the result that
no single program has emerged as the only credible or dominant approach
internationally. Many certification programs have developed group certification
of small growers, or certification of regions with a single management regime.
Stepwise approaches to certification, starting with legality verification, are now
emerging and hold promise for wider applicability and adoption in tropical regions and Russia. National certification programs in Brazil, Malaysia, Indonesia, and elsewhere have increased adoption of this response in the ‘‘South.’’
Commercialization of non-wood forest products has achieved modest
successes for local livelihoods but has not always created incentives for
conservation. There has been significant growth in some NWFP markets.
This has followed extension of the market system to more remote areas; increased interest in natural products such as herbal medicines, wild foods,
handcrafted utensils, and decorative items; and development projects focused
on production, processing, and trade of NWFPs. Few NWFPs have large and
reliable markets. Those that do have tend to be supplied by specialized producers using more intensive production systems. Many other NWFPs are vital
to the livelihoods of the poor but have little scope for commercialization. Such
commercialization has achieved modest impacts for livelihoods through combinations of technical and capacity-building interventions to improve raw material
production, processing, trade, and marketing, and through development of co-
operatives, improved policy, and institutional frameworks. There are often problems, however, with stronger groups gaining control at the expense of weaker
groups and with overexploitation of resources. Increased value does not automatically translate into effective incentives for conservation and can have the
opposite effect.
Sustainable natural forest management in the tropics should be focused
on a range of forest goods and services, not just timber, to be more
economically attractive. Low-cost new technology has made a difference to
some forest management functions. Diverse cultures can be expected to arrive
at local solutions to securing both wood supplies and forest environmental
services. While the ‘‘best practices’’ of global corporations are worthy of scrutiny, there is also much to be gained by exploring ‘‘what works’’ in traditional
forest management and the work of local (small) enterprises. Since the early
1990s, considerable interest has developed in the application of reduced impact logging, especially in tropical forests, which lowers environmental impacts
and can also be more efficient and cost-effective.
Development of farm woodlots and large-scale plantations is an increasingly widespread response to growing wood demand and as natural forest areas decline. Without adequate planning and management, the wrong
growers, for the wrong reasons, may grow forest plantations in the wrong sites,
with the wrong species and provenances. In areas where land degradation
has occurred, afforestation may play an important role in delivering economic,
environmental, and social benefits to communities and help in reducing poverty
and enhancing food security. In these instances, forests and trees must be
planted in ways that will support livelihoods, agriculture, landscape restoration,
and local development. There is increasing recognition that semi-natural and
mixed-species, mixed-age plantings can provide a larger range of products,
provide ‘‘insurance’’ against unfavorable market conditions, reduce the effects
and economic consequences of insect and disease attacks, harbor greater
diversity of flora and fauna, contain the spread of wildfires, and provide greater
variety and aesthetic value.
Fuelwood remains one of the larger outputs of the forest sector in the
South. If technology development continues, then industrial-scale forest
product fuels could become a major contributor to sustainable energy
sources. Consumption of fuelwood has recently been shown to be growing
less rapidly than earlier thought. This follows increasing urbanization and rising
incomes as users switch to more efficient and convenient sources of energy.
In some regions, including much of developing Asia, total fuelwood consumption is declining. Efforts to encourage adoption of improved wood burning
stoves have had some impact in urban areas of some countries but little success in rural areas due to cultural and economic obstacles to their adoption.
Recent attention to improved stoves has shifted from increasing efficiency of
fuelwood use to reducing damage to health from airborne particulates and
noxious fumes associated with the burning of wood and charcoal. In Northern
regions, as renewable options gather more momentum and the technology
becomes more fine tuned, it can be expected that dendro power options, using
wood to fuel electricity generation, will become more competitive and investor
friendly.
8.1 Introduction
This chapter assesses the impact on ecosystem health and human
well-being of actions taken to influence the production and use
of wood, fuelwood, and non-wood forest products (also known
as non-timber forest products). These actions are responses to the
ecosystem and human well-being conditions and trends associated
with forest products that are assessed in MA Current State and
Wood, Fuelwood, and Non-wood Forest Products
Trends (Chapters 9 and 21). The effectiveness of these responses is
also assessed in relation to the possible scenarios in MA Scenarios.
The chapter discusses (1) driving forces of change in ecosystems that produce wood, fuelwood, and non-wood forest
products, and the problems and opportunities they create; (2) interventions and actions to tackle the problems; (3) an assessment
of selected responses; and (4) lessons learned. Other chapters in
this and other MA volumes assess ecosystems and services closely
linked to the provision of wood, fuelwood and non-wood forest
products. Gaining a full picture of the state of forests and woodlands, the provisioning services of wood and NWFPs, and the
human actions taken to address problems linked to wood and
NWFPs requires looking at them as well. (See Chapters 5, 7, 15,
16, in this volume; MA Current State and Trends, Chapters 10, 13,
14, 17, and 24; and MA Scenarios, Chapter 10.)
8.1.1 Driving Forces of Change in the Ecosystems
that Provide Forest Products
There is a range of strong proximate (or direct) drivers of change
in the ecosystems that produce wood, fuelwood, and non-wood
forest products. Some of these drivers are natural phenomena.
Almost all interact in complex and unpredictable ways with
human activities to influence the ability of wildlands, forests,
plantations, and agricultural systems to produce wood, fuelwood
and non-wood forest products.
Fire is the most immediate and dramatic agent of ecosystem
change, and is an important process in many forest systems. Fireaffected forests have developed under characteristic fire regimes,
ranging from frequent, non-lethal ground fires to infrequent, lethal, stand-replacing events (Pyne et al. 1996). Traditional societies used fire extensively to encourage the growth of food plants,
to encourage new growth and attract animals for easier hunting,
to control insects and disease, and to develop defensible space
around villages (Pyne et al. 1996). Traditional forest management
techniques stemming from Europe, combined with the fear of
fire damage to wooden houses, fences, and settlements, and the
desire to prevent the loss of valuable trees, led to increasingly
effective fire prevention efforts in many forested areas, including
North America, Europe, and Australia. These efforts, which often
had the effect of removing fire as an ecosystem process, created
significant ecological changes in many fire-adapted forests (Covington and Moore 1994). One result has been increasing concerns
with forest health and the changing nature of wildfire, with
greatly increased incidence of uncharacteristically large, intense,
and severe fire events. These events, which may consume 5–20
times as much fuel as historical fires in these systems, can permanently damage soils (Giovannini 1994), alter ecosystem recovery
rates (Cromack et al. 2000), create significant air pollution and
human health impacts (Neuenschwander and Sampson 2000), and
threaten significant population centers (NCWD 1994).
Both native and introduced diseases, fungal infections, and insects
are important disturbance agents in forest ecosystems as well, and
often these vectors interact with fire (Harvey 1994). While epidemics can occur in healthy forest ecosystems, most often in connection with periods of climate stress, they occur more frequently
in forests where the vegetation is stressed and unhealthy due to
overcrowding, lack of moisture or nutrients, or the invasion of
ill-adapted species (NCWD 1994; Pyne et al. 1996). Large areas
of uniform, mature forests in the boreal zone are similarly susceptible. Where trees have been killed by insect or disease epidemics,
they are much more susceptible to large, uncharacteristic wildfires. Conversely, large areas of fire-killed timber are open invitations to insect epidemics that can then advance into adjoining
261
unburned forests (Harvey 1994). These interrelated forest health
problems are made worse in areas where forest management (or
the lack of it) has created large, unbroken tracts of forest that lack
age, structural, or species diversity (Sampson and Adams 1994).
Extreme weather, such as strong winds and floods can also be
dramatic. Anthropogenic climate change is likely to exacerbate
such weather events and to bring about more widespread shifts in
the ecosystems that provide forest products (see MA Current State
and Trends, Chapter 14). Unnatural changes such as simplification
of ecosystems, dam building, and heavy pesticide use can exacerbate the natural forces described above.
Movements and migration of people, rising consumption of
natural resources and land, changing human values, urbanization,
and many other shifts in human behavior are having a huge impact
on forests, farming, and use of wood. In many parts of the world,
such as Southeast Asia and Africa, demographic change puts increasing pressure on land where wood is available or being produced. In wealthy countries, such as the United States and Japan,
per capita demand for wood products continues to grow and already is many times greater than in poor countries.
Land and resource management practices are shifting as wood and
related products are derived more intensively, such as through
large-scale plantations of genetically cloned trees that grow faster
than their natural ancestors. Ownership is shifting as large forestry
enterprises continue to consolidate globally to achieve greater
competitiveness through economies of scale, and as governments
recognize traditional forest managers such as native peoples in
South America. Protest is common from farmers groups, environmentalists, communities, and others over who owns and controls
forest resources. Where violent conflict between political or ethnic groups occurs in rural areas, it often plays out in remote forests
and woodlands. In several countries, governments and insurgent
forces have used revenue from timber to finance military activities.
All of these proximate drivers of change are influenced by a
range of underlying, interconnected processes; some of these and
their possible impacts are examined here.
Globalization has impacts through trade liberalization, which
changes the key centers of demand and production and enhances
competition. This tends to concentrate wood and fiber production on intensive, controllable, and accessible land (though ownership of the land may be disputed by local communities) where
costs of production are lower. Fewer, larger companies increasingly control a larger portion of wood and fiber production, processing, and trade. Products are increasingly standardized in form
and quality. Meanwhile there is globalization of knowledge and
advocacy about what is ‘‘good’’ or ‘‘responsible’’ production and
awareness of issues associated with wood.
Governments still own much forest land, but privatization of
forest resource ownership, fiber production, and forest management services, such as third-party certification, are dominant
trends. This may improve the efficiency of production and the
quality of products, but it also can result in declining access to
resources for some of the world’s poorest people.
Decentralization of authority and responsibility to local government, communities, and the private sector is common in many
parts of the world, including in large forest-rich countries such as
Indonesia and Brazil. This shifts power closer to the people most
affected by local resource use and might improve management
where local institutions are adequate and accountable.
Changing patterns of wood consumption are emerging along with
new technologies, fashions, and substitutes. Engineered and more
highly designed wood products are replacing simple solid wood,
resulting in lower resource intensity for some uses such as home
262
Ecosystems and Human Well-being: Policy Responses
construction. Nonetheless, fuelwood continues to be the major
source of energy for many poorer and rural families. The geography of consumption is also shifting as huge new import markets
emerge in China and India, set to rival Europe and the United
States as sources of growing demand.
Technology is changing the way wood is produced, processed,
and used. Biotechnology is given increasing emphasis in commercial plantations with cloned trees to standardize production and
quality and to increase growth rates. Much experimentation is
done to develop new generations of ‘‘super trees’’ using genetic
modification. These modified trees are being criticized by interest
groups concerned about possible environmental impacts. Wood
engineering is allowing the use of more species and smaller pieces
of wood in processing. Wood-fiber-gasifying energy generators
are also being developed and could one day produce large
amounts of renewable electricity using trees harvested from fastgrowing plantations.
Food production and processing have a large impact on forests and
wood production. The dynamics that affect food production in
turn affect the forest–farm interface geographically, economically,
and socially.
Stakeholder values and opinions are changing. Environmental
and social responsibility is increasingly mainstream and calls for
pro-people and pro-environment approaches are ever stronger.
There is also pressure for greater transparency of how forest and
forestland are administered and managed. Increasingly there are
expectations of multistakeholder approaches to decision-making
by governments and increased partnership with civil society by
business.
Yet governance systems that can manage forest stakeholder
values effectively and equitably are often weak where their need
is great. Where there is limited provision of social services, weak
justice systems, and slow economic growth, the interests of the
few come to dominate the many and there is little incentive for
the local population to be loyal to national government. In some
such contexts, violent conflicts have emerged.
8.1.2 Problems and Opportunities Created by the
Driving Forces of Change
Ecosystems and human well-being face a range of problems as a
result of the driving forces described above. The area of provisioning ecosystems is declining due to deforestation, desertification, and forest degradation. There is also declining quality of
ecosystems (productivity, diversity, standing stock quality, and
health support services), and increasing vulnerability of ecosystems (increase in fires, climate change, and pathogens). Resource
extraction and management technologies for wood, fuelwood and
non-wood forest products can have impacts on biodiversity, water
quality, carbon storage, and cultural values.
Stakeholder equity problems are widespread. There is often
inequitable access to wood, fuelwood and non-wood forest products; poor sharing of costs and risks of production; and conflicts
and mistrust between stakeholders. Conservation efforts in some
places creates burdens for others; for example, China is currently
protecting its own natural forest and importing much wood from
Russia and Indonesia, which, given forest governance weaknesses
in those countries, leads to excessive and illegal harvesting.
Since many of the driving forces of change originate in processes beyond the forest sector (extra-sectoral), many of the problems in the use of forest products stem as much or more from
extra-sectoral policies and institutions—trade, structural adjustment, poverty reduction, debt, agriculture, infrastructure, energy,
mining—than from processes and institutions within the forest
sector itself. Such extra-sectoral policies and institutions often
override or undermine priorities negotiated by forest stakeholders.
Further problems with the current policies and institutions
that constitute forest governance are abundant (WCFSD 1999;
IPF 1996). These include the following:
• Forest rights are often insufficiently well negotiated, established, and legally and institutionally backed-up for effective
and equitable forest management.
• Policies and investment conditions sometimes create perverse
effects and make it impossible to tackle problems and realize
opportunities associated with changing driving forces. Elsewhere policy ‘‘inflation’’ has occurred—with an excess of international precepts and lack of real capacity and mechanisms
to deliver local benefits.
• Decentralization is often incomplete and coordination of institutional roles insufficient to support effective and equitable
forest management.
• Smaller forest enterprises, fuelwood-dependent stakeholders,
and users and managers of non-wood forest products, many
very poor, are often ‘‘invisible’’ to policy processes (their values and forest management practices are ignored or misunderstood).
• Information about specific wood-producing ecosystems—
including their location, extent, capability, and vulnerability—is inadequate, and forest research capabilities are weak.
• Corruption and weak regulation or enforcement lead to poor
forest management in some places.
In addition, there are problems linked with the markets. Many
pro-sustainability approaches are unviable financially. Viable approaches are not always socially and environmentally responsible
and market prices often do not reflect social and environmental
values, a situation worsened by competition between producers.
Despite these potential problems, there are also opportunities
arising from anthropogenic driving forces. Technology allowing
concentration of fiber and fuel production on small areas of land
has the potential to release other areas for environmental and livelihood purposes, though this depends heavily on other factors.
There is potential for cash-poor producers to access high-value
markets as market information improves. There is greater transparency to forest resource information and strengthening of
government-led reporting such as through the various criteria and
indicators processes. Knowledge of sustainable practices is now
being shared more easily among groups and nations. Decentralization offers opportunities to match wood production with local
livelihood needs and constraints.
8.2 Overview and Selection of Responses
In the past, governments made the majority of responses to the
issues summarized above through laws and regulations covering
the ownership, management, and use of forests; the harvesting,
transport, and trade of forest products; and the extraction and use
of income from public lands. These responses were designed to
shift the balance between public and private benefits toward the
public end of the spectrum (for example, environmental services
for public benefits, rather than wood production for private ends).
In the last three decades, a richer range of responses has
emerged that spans a spectrum from ‘‘pure’’ public regulation to
‘‘pure’’ private, voluntary approaches. Across this spectrum,
market-based approaches have emerged to allocate costs and benefits. Some nongovernmental responses, such as voluntary forest
certification, are proving to be just as effective as state regulations.
Wood, Fuelwood, and Non-wood Forest Products
Some approaches described here as ‘‘responses’’ are explicit policy
instruments and intervention programs; others can be better seen
as ‘‘spontaneous’’ local reactions and social movements.
Not all responses to change in the ecosystems that produce
wood, fuelwood, and non-wood forest products are assessed here.
Rather, fifteen responses have been selected for investigation on
the basis of the following criteria: whether the response attempts
to address a major problem or opportunity; whether it evokes
political interest or contention; whether a major investment has
been made in it; and whether there are strong indications of positive impact. The response options fall into the following four
main types:
• Multistakeholder and extra-sectoral policy processes. These include
international forest policy processes and development assistance; trade liberalization; and national forest governance initiatives and national forest programs.
• Rights to land and resource management. These include direct
management of forests by indigenous peoples; collaborative
forest management and local movements for access and use of
forest products; small-scale private and public-private ownership and management of forests; and company–community
forestry partnerships.
• Demand-side, market-driven, and/or technological responses. These
include public and consumer action; third-party voluntary
forest certification; wood technology; and commercialization
of non-wood forest products.
• Land management institutions, investment, and incentives. These
include natural forest management in the tropics; forest plantation management; fuelwood management; and carbon management.
The following sections assess the various response options in
terms of their impact on ecosystem health and human well-being;
the final section summarizes lessons learned.
Truly extra-sectoral responses, which have clearly improved
impacts of forest product use on ecosystem health and human
well-being in mind, are rare. Trade is one arena in which such
responses are visible and these are discussed below, with some
additional examples given in Chapter 15. Most of the responses
discussed have an extra-sectoral dimension—relying on engagement with driving forces beyond the forest sector—and should be
judged in part by their effectiveness in this.
A number of other important options are not addressed here.
For example, importing wood is an option for an individual country that cannot produce wood cost-effectively. This shifts any
ecosystem problems to another country, but is positive if comparative advantage can be realized. Producing substitutes for wood
products (such as metals, plastics, concrete, and non-wood fibers)
results in a different set of ecosystem issues (often agricultural, as
in the case of non-wood fiber); the major drawback is that many
substitutes may neither invest in renewable resources (the bulk of
plastics manufacture is petroleum-dependent) nor exhibit the
same degree of concern for ecosystem services that the various
wood-producing sectors are increasingly doing. These alternatives
are also often more energy and water intensive than wood (Hair
et al. 1996; Koch 1991; Meil 1994).
Some key responses are omitted here because they are covered
in other chapters (for example, protected areas, which are covered
in Chapters 5 and 15). Some new ‘‘paradigms’’ gaining significant
currency, such as ecosystem approaches and landscape restoration,
are not included because their impacts have yet to become clear.
Single powerful institutional frameworks, such as the World
Bank’s forest strategy and policy, are not covered directly but are
treated indirectly where their influence is strong. Other key arenas of problem and opportunity in forest product impacts on
263
ecosystem health and human well-being seem to lack major responses. For example, concerted initiatives to address these links
from the standpoint of forestry labor are difficult to identify.
Implementation of the full set of responses assessed here is not
the norm in the forest sector. Indeed some places demonstrate
hardly any of these responses. Nevertheless, each of the selected
responses has substantial and generally growing significance globally for the way wood, fuelwood, and non-wood forest products
are developed and used.
8.3 Multistakeholder and Extra-sectoral Policy
Processes
8.3.1 International Forest Policy Processes and
Development Assistance
A host of international processes and initiatives engage with forest
issues. Many are intergovernmental, some are civil society approaches, and others are driven by the private sector. They can be
clustered in four groups: forest, environment, trade, and development policy.
8.3.1.1 Forest Processes
The core international policy process on forests includes the debate, negotiations, and decisions stretching from the 1992 Rio
Earth Summit to the current United Nations Forum on Forests.
UNFF’s objective is to promote the management, conservation,
and sustainable development of all types of forests and to
strengthen the long-term political commitment to this end. It has
been catalytic in developing a number of distinct forestry response
options, which are considered elsewhere in this chapter. It has
achieved the following (Bass 2003; Sizer 1994):
• kept forests on the international agenda, especially in the context of sustainable development;
• provided opportunities for collaboration and lesson learning at
inter-sessional meetings on a wide range of technical and some
cross-cutting issues;
• promoted consensus around a set of U.N. Forest Principles
and identified 20 main voluntary ‘‘Proposals for Action’’ (incorporating a total of 270 detailed proposals that some countries find hard to interpret and thus implement);
• helped define and give legitimacy to country-led national forest programs as the main means to implement the Proposals
for Action;
• developed sets of criteria and indicators for sustainable forest
management that have provided a common language that has
brought stakeholders closer together, but allowed national and
local differences in interpretation. These have influenced the
development of voluntary forest certification;
• sought to improve collaboration and coordination with other
policy processes and international organizations under the
Collaborative Partnership on Forests; and
• promoted NGO involvement in U.N. processes.
However, UNFF also has weaknesses. To date, it has:
• failed to reach agreement on the voluntary monitoring of implementation in ways that could provide evidence of direct
impact;
• remained very sectoral, and has struggled to make any significant progress on key cross-cutting issues (finance, trade and
environment, technology transfer).
• failed to achieve a consensus on the nature and justification
for a legally binding instrument but will continue to absorb
time and energy in an attempt to do so; and
264
Ecosystems and Human Well-being: Policy Responses
• remained excessively dominated by governments, despite
pioneering NGO involvement within U.N. processes establishing a multistakeholder dialogue and the Collaborative
Partnership on Forests.
framework at national level. Internationally, interventions are
likely to be needed from agencies previously little linked to forest
issues—for example, the United Nations Security Council being
called upon to take action on conflict timber.
8.3.1.2 Environment Process
Of the key environment processes and initiatives, the Convention
on Biological Diversity, the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change, and the Global Environment Facility
have been most influential to date. The United Nations Convention to Combat Desertification is starting to have an impact
through national action programs. The main impact of the CBD
has been the development of national biodiversity strategies and
action plans; its revised work program on forest biodiversity has
potential, but its ambition far exceeds the resources available for
its implementation. CBD’s benefit sharing objective has been of
great interest to many developing countries, but it has generated
difficult debates about intellectual property rights and trade that
go well beyond biodiversity. UNFCCC introduces the subject of
markets for environmental services. The wide array of experiments to test market approaches for provision of watershed
services, biodiversity, and carbon are creating a body of understanding that is reaching an ever-wider audience.
8.3.1.4 Development
International development assistance for forestry has passed
through four different phases, with considerable overlap, over the
last 40 years: industrial forestry, social forestry, environmental forestry, and sustainable management of natural resources. Recently
forestry assistance entered a fifth phase, framed by the new poverty agenda that emerged from ideas about how to reduce poverty
based on providing opportunity (growth), empowerment, and security. Forestry assistance now links the United Nations Millennium Development Goals, with poverty reduction foremost
among these, with a set of mechanisms and instruments for delivering aid that includes poverty reduction strategy papers,
medium-term expenditure frameworks, sector-wide approaches,
and direct budgetary support. The development community is
still adjusting to these new changes. There has been a distinct
move away from discrete sectoral projects and a sharp decline in
related funding from the peaks reached during the early 1990s.
This decline has been particularly marked in rural development and within forestry. Poverty reduction strategies involve political choices. Where a national consensus is hard to reach and
where urban biases exist, the voices of the rural poor are heard
less distinctly. SWAPs favor social sectors where it is public expenditure that largely determines outcomes and where institutional
relationships are manageable. Productive sectors and crosscutting
themes like forestry do not sit comfortably with the SWAP
model. Direct budgetary support places responsibility for choice
of development strategy and sectoral allocation of resources in the
hands of developing countries themselves.
Response options within the new poverty agenda must demonstrate that they contribute to growth (including reduced vulnerability), empowerment, and security. This will take many
forms, including:
• helping to understand and express how forest-related interventions can be supportive of wider policy objectives;
• supporting institutional change in public sector organizations
in ways that contribute to wider social and economic goals;
• scaling up community forestry as part of wider livelihood
strategies, in ways that stress political and legal change as much
as local forest management arrangements;
• helping community–company partnerships respond to market
opportunities; and
• working with a range of partners to tackle illegal logging and
associated trade.
8.3.1.3 Trade
The International Tropical Timber Organization is a unique
commodity agreement that balances concern for improving trade
with conserving the resource base on which trade depends. It has
been effective in its purpose of facilitating discussion and international cooperation on the international trade and utilization of
tropical timber and the sustainable management of tropical forests
(Poore 2003). ITTO has achieved the following:
• It was influential in the 1980s and early 1990s when it was
effectively the only intergovernmental forum on forest issues.
• It captured public and political attention with its assessment of
the sustainability of tropical forest management.
• It made a significant contribution to the concept of criteria
and indicators.
• It developed a series of guidelines on management practices
that has been well used.
• It has the potential to contribute to the development of trade
in marketable environmental services of tropical forests.
Concern with forest law enforcement, governance and trade
gathered pace in the late 1990s, when the scale and impacts of
illegal logging, and the power of some forest industries to run
amok, became better understood. The Group of 8 and other international forums took up the issue. The forest law enforcement,
governance, and trade initiatives now under way address the governance, policy, and market failures that cause and sustain illegal
logging and associated trade. The FLEGT processes took advantage of the political space created by an East Asia Ministerial Conference and the African ministerial process (where exporting
countries spoke with a frankness not heard before, and importing
countries acknowledged their role in sustaining demand for illegally logged timber). In addition to East Asia, FLEGT processes
are also under way to varying degrees in Europe and Africa.
New multistakeholder regional initiatives are also emerging
that hold promise to better address governance and enforcement
issues. These include the Asia Forests Partnership (Sizer 2004). It
is too early to assess the utility of these approaches.
As these processes evolve, they are more likely to need to
grapple with more aspects of governance (Colchester et al, 2004).
National forest programs are potentially the ideal integrating
8.3.1.5 Policy Challenges
Much critical intergovernmental policy work within the sector
has been done. Short-term priorities are reaching agreement on
how countries should monitor, assess, and report on forests and
reaching a conclusion on a legally binding instrument. More attention should now be focused on policy implementation at the
regional, eco-regional, and national levels. It is easier for countries
to identify issues of common interest at the regional and ecoregional levels; in many cases, institutions or processes are available that can be used.
More attention is needed in the integration of agreed forest
management principles and practices in multilateral financial institutions, trade rules, and the Global Environment Facility. The
U.N. Security Council should play its part in curbing trade in
Wood, Fuelwood, and Non-wood Forest Products
conflict timber. National policy (and the interpretation and implementation of international policy at the national level) will be
increasingly influenced by these and other extra-sectoral policy
and planning frameworks. Forest sector frameworks will have to
adjust, to more directly serve these wider goals, or their influence
will diminish.
8.3.2 Trade Liberalization
Trade in forest products is growing rapidly, involves every country in the world, and is worth about US$330 billion annually.
Conventional trade theory predicts economic benefits to both
trading partners, which is broadly observed in forest product trade
(Sedjo and Simpson 1999; USTR 1999). Three problems complicate matters: unanticipated levels of benefits and costs due to market imperfections; inequitable distribution of those benefits and
costs; and disputed values ascribed to different types of benefits
and costs, especially between market and non-market values
(World Bank 2002; IIED 2003). Different interest groups perceive the relative importance of these problems differently, and
consequently promote different initiatives to solve them.
8.3.2.1 Initiatives to Influence Forest Products Trade
Trade liberalization is the dominant economic paradigm; however, when non-tariff measures and effects of subsidies are taken
into account, the net trend internationally is probably slightly
toward increased protection rather than liberalization (Rice et al.
2000; Bourke 2003). In addition to forest products trade policy,
and macroeconomic policies affecting interest rates, stability, and
risk, significant effects are created by other policies. Logging bans
displace logging problems to other locations and countries rather
than solving problems (Brown et al. 2002). Forest tenure is affected by privatization, and decentralization measures are creating
new trade players (White and Martin 2002). Sectors competing
for inputs or land dictate whether there are any forest products to
trade. Policies that support large-scale agriculture have had particularly significant effects (Hyde forthcoming).
There are more than a hundred regional agreements that affect
forest trade in some way (IIED 2003). Regional trade agreements
are the most prominent of these, including Asia-Pacific Economic
Cooperation, the North American Free Trade Agreement, and
the European Union. Regional mechanisms to control illegality
in forest trade have also begun to receive support and provide
platforms upon which to develop new ideas (see earlier discussion). Internationally, influence over trade is dominated by the
World Trade Organization negotiations, which have not installed
pro-forest principles and clarified forest trade uncertainties. Other
international agreements influencing forest trade include those on
forestry, climate change, trade in endangered species, biodiversity
conservation, core labor standards, guidelines for multinational
enterprises, and combating bribery.
Voluntary initiatives (demand-side processes such as certification and labeling, supply chain management and product
campaigns; and supply-side initiatives such as environmental
management systems, investment guidelines, and corporate citizenship) have made significant headway in recent years but their
influence on trade is still relatively small.
8.3.2.2 Impacts
Trade liberalization and initiatives to influence its course in the
forest sector have produced several strong trends:
• increasing consumption and production, and increasing trade
as a percentage of production. These trends are particularly
265
pronounced in developed countries and for highly processed
products;
• a continuing strong segregation of trade into regional trade
flows (Wardle and Michie 2001; Rytkonen 2003); and
• a transition of tropical countries from net exporters to net
importers of wood (IIED 2003).
In terms of the maturity of markets, trade with regions in the
early stages of market development increases unsustainable harvesting from open access and mature natural forests. It is only at
the mature stage of market development that good forestry practice becomes economically attractive in comparison with agricultural land values and the cost of protecting property rights (Hyde
forthcoming).
For most developing markets, existing regulatory capacity is
too weak to control external demands on the resource, and trade
liberalization is likely to result in an increase in unregulated logging (Sizer et al 1999). Where windfall resource rents occur, public sector corruption is often rife (Ross 2001; Wunder 2003).
However, there is strong evidence that, where there is strong regulatory and institutional backup, reducing trade restrictions reduces public sector corruption (Richards et al. 2003). In some
situations, trade liberalization may not bring about a real reduction in corruption, merely a change in the pattern of winners and
losers.
Trade liberalization is usually promoted within a package of
measures, and its impact depends on what else is in the package,
such as state downsizing, decentralization, deregulation, privatization, concession bidding and forest taxation, and the capacity and
will of the government to implement it. The way in which trade
policies interact with these changes determines whether they improve or reduce policy and institutional capability for sound forest
management (Seymour and Dubash 2000; Tockman 2001).
Recent analysis has concluded that the impacts on policies and
institutions of trade liberalization are positive where there are robust policies and institutions (a virtuous cycle) and negative where
they are weak (a vicious cycle). Trade appears to be a magnifier
of existing policy and institutional strengths and weaknesses rather
than a major driver of change (Anderson and Blackhurst 1992;
Ross 2001; IIED 2003).
The forest products sector is less concentrated than many
other industrial sectors, although in developing countries concentration is much more marked. There is a clear trend toward
greater involvement of transnational companies in the sector, particularly for pulp and paper products, but their importance varies.
Transnational companies have played a major role in the exports
of tropical timber in West and Central Africa, and Southeast Asia,
but in countries such as Brazil and the Philippines, they have not
been a major factor driving development of the sector (ITTO
2002). Transnational companies may generate wealth through
trade, which may provide the basis for improved policy and institutional frameworks in the forest sector (Young and Prochnik
2004). On the other hand, there is a tendency for more exploitative transnational companies to target weaker governance structures (Sizer and Plouvier 2000).
8.3.2.3 Policy Challenges
A range of policy and practice measures have been identified as
priorities for improving the impact of trade on forest management
(IIED 2003), including:
• revise distorted agricultural trade policies and improve regional development policies (this will have greater beneficial
impacts on forestry practice than changes in forest or forest
trade policies);
266
Ecosystems and Human Well-being: Policy Responses
• improve engagement of ‘‘underpowered’’ groups in trade policy decision-making;
• ensure that institutional strengthening occurs before trade liberalization;
• require cost internalization as well as liberalization, and consider the case for protection to achieve the social component
of sustainability;
• link trade to improved property rights;
• install policies for equitable and efficient allocation of forest
land;
• develop graded incentives for value-added processing that are
more closely linked to sustainable forest management;
• prevent tariff escalation on processed products; and
• promote foreign direct investment in responsible forest business.
The most effective way to improve the beneficial impacts of
trade is to link trade liberalization to improved, impartially administered property rights—either nationally through decentralization or locally through the empowerment of local and
community institutions (IIED 2003).
8.3.3 National Forest Governance Initiatives and
National Forest Programs
The United Nations Food and Agriculture Organization estimates
that about 190 countries are currently involved in national forest
planning of various kinds. There have been two main sources of
multistakeholder policy reform processes in recent times: responses to pressure from local levels and responses to international
opportunity or to international soft law.
8.3.3.1 National Governance Reform Initiatives Affecting
Forests
Significant policy change with many stakeholders involved has
emerged from initiatives to support participatory forestry at the
local level. Since the early 1970s, many projects have been based,
often with donor support, on the notion that local people should
be able to participate more in forestry development. The best of
these projects subsequently resulted in increased local responsibility for forest resources, improved local rights, increased bargaining
power of local actors at the national level, and multistakeholder
policy reform as other actors recognized the imperative for it and
came to the negotiating table. The greatest positive effects were
probably felt in countries of low forest cover such as Nepal and
Tanzania, where, as the capacity of local people to manage forests
was given greater policy support, the condition of the resource
also improved (Brown et al. 2002).
In Europe and North America, experience has been different.
Reform has also been generally stimulated by business and environmental agendas. Differences in national government styles and
cultures, and in the strength of business and civil society networks, have produced a wide range of national forest planning
processes.
Translation to the national level of opportunities and agreements stemming from international policy dialogue has stimulated
various approaches to forestry reform (Mayers and Bass 2004).
These include the following:
• National Forestry Action Plans. National forestry action plans
called for by the international Tropical Forests Action Plan
were launched by FAO, UNEP, the World Bank, and the
World Resources Institute in 1985. Never before had there
been such multi-country attention aimed at benefiting tropical
forests. Many donors and larger NGOs supported the initiative and at one point more than one hundred countries were
implementing or developing national forestry action plans
within the framework of TFAP. The TFAP could be characterized as a top-down, quick but comprehensive fix to the
perceived tropical forest crisis, the perception being promoted
by NGO and media concern about ‘‘deforestation.’’ TFAP set
a ‘‘standard’’ for a balanced forest sector for the next decade
and defined a new liturgy for forestry aid planning. But in
practice it resulted in fewer improvements than had been
hoped. TFAP was not able to challenge the inequities and
perverse policies that underlay deforestation, and then to build
the necessary trust between governments, NGOs, local people, and the private sector. Its standardization within a global
framework and the exigencies of the aid system that supported
it meant that the TFAP did not adequately recognize diverse
local perceptions, values, capacities, and needs. Because of
such weak links between causes of problems and identified
desired impacts (a persistent problem in the forestry context),
TFAP in effect contained few measures that could be reasonably expected to achieve its objective of reducing deforestation (Shiva 1987; Sizer 1994).
• Forestry Master Plans. Forestry master plans were led mainly by
the Asian Development Bank (with Finland as a frequent codonor) and consisted of extensive studies of all parts of the
sector. The studies were not very participatory nature, and
they constituted the basis for a forest policy and investment
plan principally directed at commercial functions. Agreement
was reached with TFAP that a country could be involved with
TFAP or forestry master plans but not both. The countries
that used forestry master plans included Sri Lanka, Nepal,
Bangladesh, the Philippines, Thailand, Pakistan, and Bhutan.
• Forestry Sector Reviews. Forestry sector reviews were required
by the World Bank in a range of countries to qualify for sectoral support. Their format was similar to that of the forestry
master plans. Countries that developed forestry sector reviews
included Kenya, Malawi, and Zimbabwe. The long lists of
policy prescriptions contained in forestry sector reviews were
largely ignored once support had come and gone.
• National Environmental Action Plans. National environmental
action plans were undertaken from the mid 1970s to the early
1990s at the behest of the World Bank; in some countries,
they overlapped with forestry sector reviews. They were effectively a form of conditionality and today have been eclipsed
by comprehensive development frameworks and poverty reduction strategy papers.
• National Conservation Strategies. National conservation strategies were popular in the 1970s and early 1990s when about
100 countries prepared them, many with technical support
from IUCN and some showing creativity in both multistakeholder processes and practical linkage of environment and development. While many fell by the wayside, a few (such as the
Pakistan National Conservation Strategy) are now providing a
valuable platform for addressing economic growth and poverty alleviation.
Several initiatives stem from the UNCED 1992 multilateral
environmental agreements and have a mixed record in influencing national forestry planning, including the following (OECD
and UNDP 2002):
• National Biodiversity Strategies and Action Plans. National biodiversity strategies and action plans were stimulated by the
requirements of the 1992 Convention on Biological Diversity.
About 70 countries have completed them, some supported by
the GEF. They often lack analysis of forestry’s use of biodiversity as well as integration with other plans and strategies. A
few highly participatory NBSAPs have considerable momen-
Wood, Fuelwood, and Non-wood Forest Products
tum and potential impact on forestry decision-making, for example in India and Guyana.
• National Action Programs. National action programs to combat
desertification were a response to the 1994 Convention to
Combat Desertification. Many dryland countries have developed NAPs, with 50 of them receiving funding from UNDP’s
Office to Combat Desertification and Drought. A few national action plans have analyzed and stimulated actions in forestry. They vary greatly but have tended to be developed by
ministries of environment with only weak links to key processes such as decentralization and land reform that may have
major effects on land use and desertification.
• National Communications. Annex 1 parties to the UNFCCC
must submit periodic national communications to the
UNFCCC Secretariat reporting on their actions to address
climate change. By April 2003, some 100 developing countries had submitted such reports, with only a few covering
carbon source and sink dimensions of forests.
Despite their best endeavors, the net effect of the multilateral
environmental agreements is at best to provide a source of ideas
to national-level debate about forests. They do not provide an
integrated legal regime that views forests, and those that depend
on them, in a holistic way. Countries both poor and wealthy are
thus generally able to escape from their commitments. Two integrating frameworks currently holding sway in international debates aim to have more power at the national level:
• National Sustainable Development Strategies. National sustainable
development strategies are to be adopted by all governments
following the 1992 Earth Summit. The 2000 Millennium Development Goals were signed by 147 heads of state, accompanied by targets, including to ‘‘integrate the principles of
sustainable development into country policies and programs
and reverse the loss of environmental resources.’’ There are
few national sustainable development strategies, although the
recent development of guidance and lessons for practitioners
(OECD and UNDP 2002) may stimulate more.
• Poverty reduction strategies. Poverty reduction strategies were
initially required by the IMF and World Bank as a basis for
access to debt relief in highly-indebted poor countries. Poverty reduction strategy papers have been required by all countries supported by the International Development Association
since July 2002. Interim poverty reduction strategy papers
(I-PRSPs) are road maps to full PRSPs. As of April 2003, 26
full PRSPs and 45 I-PRSPs had been prepared. Bilateral donors are also increasingly subscribing to poverty reduction
strategies and they have thus emerged as a central determinant
of the development agenda in many countries. The recognition of forests as a development asset has so far been limited in
many poverty reduction strategies. Of the 11 PRSPs and 25
I-PRSPs in sub-Saharan Africa, 74% touched on forestry issues but almost none were convincing about forests–poverty
links and forests’ future potential (Oksanen and Mersmann
2002).
8.3.3.2 National Forest Programs
National forest programs are now being strongly promoted on the
understanding that they follow a country-led approach, rather
than an international program or precept in the style of the TFAP
(UNFF 2002; FAO 2004). The notion of NFPs was developed
by the international Forestry Advisers Group (an informal group
of aid agency forestry advisers), adopted by FAO (FAO 1996),
then endorsed by the Intergovernmental Panel on Forests (SixCountry Initiative 1999).
267
All countries that have taken part in U.N. forest policy dialogues have adopted the requirement for a national forest program. It is consensus-based soft international law. Agenda 21, the
UNCED action plan (UNCED 1992), invited all countries to
prepare and implement national forest programs and stressed the
need to integrate these activities within a global, inter-sectoral,
and participatory framework.
The post-UNCED intergovernmental negotiations on forests
stress the role of NFPs, and the current United Nations Forum
on Forests action plan commits countries to pursuing NFPs
(UNFF 2002). Regional approaches to pushing NFPs are also beginning in Europe (MCPFE 2002). Meanwhile the European
Union requires countries to have NFPs or their equivalent in
order to receive forest subsidies (Glück et al. 2003). The NFP
concept currently promoted at the international level (FAO 2004;
World Bank 2002) puts particular emphasis on the following:
• multistakeholder involvement in forest decision making;
• means for cooperation, coordination, and partnership;
• secure access and use rights;
• research and traditional knowledge;
• forest information systems;
• study and policies on underlying causes of deforestation/
degradation;
• integrating conservation and sustainable use, with provisions
for environmentally sensitive forests, and for addressing low
forest cover;
• codes of conduct for the private sector; and
• monitoring, evaluating, and reporting on NFPs.
Although there is probably no example of a contemporary
NFP that has achieved optimal systems for all of the above, Malawi, Uganda, Brazil, Costa Rica, Vietnam, India, Finland, Germany, and Australia are leading the way (Bird 2002; Humphreys
2004; Mayers et al. 2001; Savenije 2000; Thornber et al. 2001).
However, it is too early to see significant results. Many NFPs
were judged to be ‘‘stalled,’’ due to lack of institutional, human,
and financial capacity, as well as lack of adequate policies, poor
institutional co-ordination, and deficient mechanisms for public
participation (FAO 2004). Widespread agreement on the need for
‘‘country-driven, holistic’’ processes is not matched with implementation.
If NFPs are to succeed, they need to avoid the mistakes of
many NFAPs, FMPs, FSRs and the like that remained exercises
on paper only. They failed to catalyze the detailed actions expected of them, in general because they failed to engage with
political and economic reality to show not only what needs to
change, but also how it can change, and how such change can be
sustained.
8.3.3.3 Policy Challenges
Experience suggests that the best hope lies in developing local
processes and systems that bring together the best that exists locally,
and filling gaps where needed with the help of international
thinking (Mayers et al. 2001; OECD and UNDP 2002). These
processes include the following:
• political processes that install and maintain forestry’s potential
and NFP priorities at a high level, and provide the means to
revise policies;
• participation systems that enable equitable identification and
involvement of stakeholders, including previously marginalized groups, and create space and responsiveness for negotiating, vision, roles, objectives, and partnerships;
• local-benefit ‘‘screening’’ processes that ensure that the forest sector keeps working to optimize its contributions to povertyreduction and local livelihoods;
268
Ecosystems and Human Well-being: Policy Responses
• information and communication systems that generate, make accessible, and use interdisciplinary research and analysis; form
clear baselines; and get plans well communicated with strong
‘‘stories’’;
• monitoring systems that can pick up and communicate the key
changes in forests and human well-being;
• financial systems that generate and manage adequate resources
and ensure investment conditions, internalize externalities,
and promote cost-efficiency;
• human resource development systems that promote equity and
efficiency in building social and human capital, with an emphasis on holding on to tacit knowledge and promoting innovation;
• extra-sectoral engagement processes that put synergies and potential conflicts with other sectors and macro-plans at the heart
of thinking and action; and
• planning and process management systems that demonstrate efficiency (strategic, not overly comprehensive actions with realistic timeframes), transparency, accountability, and therefore
legitimacy in decision-making.
8.4 Rights to Land and Resource Management
8.4.1 Direct Management of Forests by Indigenous
Peoples
Direct management of forests by indigenous and traditional peoples occurs in its purest form in two utterly different institutional
contexts: where states exercise little or no effective control over
territory, creating space for autonomous management of forest
resources, or where a highly sophisticated state with an indigenous population acknowledges significant sovereignty to native
polities. Canada and New Zealand, and to a lesser extent Australia
and the United States, are examples of the latter. The former scenario is almost exclusively restricted to the tropical world. Most
indigenous peoples inhabit a more ambiguous political and institutional landscape, where land tenure can be restricted to usufruct, conceded but heavily regulated, or denied altogether. Even
where sovereignty is formally conceded to indigenous peoples,
such as in Canada, its recognition in practice may be weak
(Colchester 2004). In these contexts, complex interactions with
governments and a surrounding non-indigenous civil society determine natural resource management, including management of
forests (Redford and Mansour 1997).
8.4.1.1 Impacts of Forest Management by Indigenous Peoples
The processes of colonization and globalization have affected indigenous peoples for centuries, and provoked major changes for
most of them, with transitions from permanent to shifting agriculture and back again, geographical displacement, rapid modifications in trading patterns, and economic articulation with the
outside world. This universal historical experience is contrary to
the many mythic representations of indigenous expertise in natural resource management as linked to very longstanding occupation of a particular natural environment.
The defining characteristics of natural resource management
by indigenous peoples across cultures are flexibility, versatility,
adaptability to change, and heavy investment in the training of
resource management specialists with broad expertise. Indigenous
natural resource management tends to be geared toward broadly
based livelihoods composed of the simultaneous exploitation of
multiple ecological niches and processes. Its defining characteristic
is the ability to adapt effectively to the many externally forced
changes of habitat and economy that history has imposed upon
indigenous peoples.
For forests, this has usually involved a paradoxical combination of intensive but diffuse management—intensive in the sense
that a wide variety of ecological processes in forests (succession,
species composition, forest structure) are heavily manipulated by
indigenous peoples, but diffuse in the sense that this manipulation
is so geographically widespread that it often becomes difficult to
draw the boundary between anthropogenic and natural forests.
This has two common consequences: a mimicking of natural
processes through cultural means, which underlies the greater integrity and functionality of forests in indigenous areas, and difficulty in handling specialization and intensification. This has
become a perennial problem in sustainable development projects
involving forest management or natural resource management in
general in indigenous areas.
Indigenous control of traditional homelands is often presented
as having environmental benefits by indigenous peoples and their
supporters, although the dominant justification continues, rightly,
to be based on human and cultural rights. While little systematic
data yet exists, preliminary findings on vegetation cover and forest
fragmentation from the Brazilian Amazon, where this work is
most advanced, suggests that the creation of an indigenous area is
at least as effective a protection strategy as the creation of a strictuse protected area.
However, many well-documented examples exist of local exhaustion of a particular natural resource in indigenous areas, for a
variety of reasons (Robinson and Bennett 2000). The conquest of
land and usufruct rights and expansion of indigenous areas systems
is often followed by population increases and greater pressure on
natural resources, at least in the short term. The very consolidation of cultural autonomy and a legal and property regime
inherent in a successful indigenous claim to land opens up the
possibility of new arrangements, such as leases, concessions, and
compensation payments, whose net effect is to reduce direct natural resource management by indigenous peoples, or render it controversial.
8.4.1.2 Policy Challenges
There are many documented examples of successful environmental management in individual indigenous areas, either directly or
in some form of shared management in which indigenous representatives have a significant say. Nevertheless, the non-indigenous
institutions with technical expertise in natural resource management, both governmental and non-governmental, have generally
failed to devote the same attention to the development of applied
knowledge and methodologies for indigenous areas as they have
to national parks.
Indigenous organizations across the world are often poorly
informed about technologies and techniques that are routine for
other resource management agencies—remote sensing, satellite
imagery, zoning, monitoring, and formal management plans—
that may have potential for reinforcing natural resource management in indigenous areas. In their absence, there is a shortage of
quality field data to inform policy, a demand increasingly heard
from indigenous organizations themselves.
Culturally appropriate and technically sound cooperation between indigenous and non-indigenous organizations to reinforce
natural resource management on indigenous lands is rare; achieving it should be a concern for governments and civil society alike.
8.4.2 Devolution and Local Forest Management and
Local Movements for Access and Use of Forest
Products
Governments and donor projects have developed diverse institutional arrangements to provide rural people more formal rights to
Wood, Fuelwood, and Non-wood Forest Products
forests and their management. Millions of the rural poor have
participated in local forest management policies and programs
during the last two decades. The results have been mixed. Most
arrangements have maintained and even extended central government control (Sundar 2001; Fisher 1999; Malla 2000; Balad and
Platteau 1996; Edmunds and Wollenberg 2003; Shackleton et al.
2002). While local people generally have better legal access to
forests and some have higher incomes, many have also suffered
negative trade-offs (Sarin 2003). Forestry has not often been the
best entry point for integrated resource management and rural
development. Local people have usually not shown a consistent
interest in forest conservation (Shackleton and Campbell 2001).
Triggered by these experiences and the increasing complexity
of demands from different interest groups, local forest management policies are shifting. They increasingly involve not only collaborative management arrangements between a local group and
the government, but a range of stakeholders and acknowledgement of overlapping systems of management and diverse interests.
There is more emphasis on facilitating decisions through negotiation. There is also increasing recognition of the need for
frameworks that better emphasize local peoples’ rights to selfdetermination and enable more effective representation of the
rural poor in negotiations. The rural poor and their federations
and advocates are bringing a new sophistication to negotiations
and increased demands for their voices to be heard (Singh 2002;
Britt 1998; Colchester et al. 2003).
8.4.2.1 Scope and Scale of Local Forest Management Policies
Local forest management programs now occur around the globe.
In India, more than 63,000 groups have enrolled in joint forest
management programs to regenerate 14 million hectares. In
Nepal, 9,000 forest user groups are trying to regenerate 700,000
hectares of forest. In Brazil, farmers participate in managing 2.2
million hectares as extractive reserves. Half the districts in Zimbabwe have CAMPFIRE (Communal Area Management Programme for Indigenous Resources) schemes. More than half of
the natural forest in the Gambia (17,000 hectares) is under community forest management. The programs generally have resulted
in significant levels of improved resource management and have
improved access of the rural poor to forest resources, but have
fallen short in their potential to benefit the poor (Upreti 2001).
The institutional arrangements of the different approaches to
local management have strongly influenced how policies affect
local people. Formal arrangements include corporate, legal organizations composed of rights holders (such as rubber tappers’ organizations in Brazil, ejidos in Mexico, trusts in Botswana,
conservancies in Namibia, and communal property associations
in Makuleke, South Africa). There are also village committees
facilitated by government departments, such as the village natural
resource management committees in Malawi, and forest protection committees in India. The Gambia’s ‘‘Community-controlled
State Forests’’ program encourages communities that have designated community forests to help protect the surrounding state
forest area in exchange for a share of the resulting income. In
the Philippines and China, contractual agreements between the
government and households or individuals have been developed
where individuals exercise varying degrees of authority over species selection, harvesting practices, sale and consumption, and the
distribution of benefits. In addition, there are local government
organizations such as rural district councils in Zimbabwe and panchayats in India, and multistakeholder district structures aligned to
line departments such as Tambon councils in Thailand and wildlife
management authorities in Zambia. Arrangements allocate vary-
269
ing degrees of rights to forest and land. Many impose forest management requirements.
Self-initiated local responses to problems in access and use of
forest products have also proliferated in recent years; they are collectively more significant than efforts led by governments or international processes, but they require the latter’s support to
spread. Such local organizations include campesino forestry organizations in Central America, forest user groups in Nepal, the National Council of Rubber Tappers in Brazil, people’s natural
resource management organizations in the Philippines, and the
Landcare movement in Australia and elsewhere.
8.4.2.2 Effectiveness of Devolved Control
The degree of control transferred by the state under these different institutional arrangements has affected the outcomes for local
people. Bureaucratic control was higher and the responsiveness of
programs to local needs lower where arrangements allocated control to higher levels of social organization, local government, or
district structures. In such cases, state interests in resource production, revenues, and environmental conservation more strongly
overrode villagers’ interests in livelihood needs. Existing capacities for management were weakened (Edmunds and Wollenberg
2003).
Local people were able to win more benefits for themselves
where they had strong local organizational capacity and political
capital to mobilize resources and negotiate for better benefits.
NGOs, donors, federations, and other external actors had a key
role in supporting local interests. Where local groups managed
their own forests without state intervention, however, they were
not necessarily better off, since without government support, they
often had difficulty implementing or enforcing their decisions
(Shackleton and Campbell 2001).
Although access to some important subsistence products improved, access to other important local resources such as timber
or game remained restricted. Where financial benefits occurred,
governments often failed to deliver on their promised share of
incomes. Benefits from timber and valuable NWFPs were often
reserved for, or at least shared with, the state or local elite (Shackleton and Campbell 2001). Only in a few exceptional cases did
poor communities receive substantial financial benefits.
The improved formal access to forests has helped in most cases
to protect a vital role of forests as safety-nets for rural people to
meet their basic subsistence needs. However, the benefits to be
gained beyond the subsistence-level were limited. Property rights
would need to extend to more secure rights over valuable resources, for the poor to benefit substantially. Programs focused on
organizing collective action around the management of a single
resource such as forests may also divert effort from other sources
of livelihood. Forests are not always the most important resource
for poor people; the economic and social environment can create
pressures to convert forests. Many of the poor might be better off
with land reform measures that are not linked to forest management, but these programs are not in the interest of forest departments.
Co-management has demonstrated the difficulty of dividing
roles and responsibilities, especially where the interests of the
groups involved are highly divergent. Forest agencies have had
varying experiences in organizing collective action. Romantic
ideals about harmonious communities and the local knowledge
and capacities of ‘‘traditional peoples’’ have been counterbalanced
by the internal conflict and lack of leadership in many communities and the difficulty of organizing collective action where local
social capital is weak (Stanley 1991; Gibson et al. 2000). Many
270
Ecosystems and Human Well-being: Policy Responses
co-management efforts rely on the role of outside agents to facilitate group action and sustaining group action has proven difficult.
Other stakeholders such as local governments or NGOs often create their own sets of incentives or pressures for local people that
work against co-management initiatives (Edmunds and Wollenberg 2003).
8.4.2.3 Policy Challenges
State officials and local people have had different expectations of
what devolved management was supposed to achieve and how.
Forest departments have mostly controlled the terms of devolution and co-management schemes. There is now a need to develop the institutional arrangements and capacities that enable
people in forest areas to have the rights and power to bring about
a fair division of control, responsibility, and benefits between government and local people. Checks and balances need to be in
place to ensure that no one group, including the local elite, controls benefits and decision-making.
Frameworks for natural resource management that are developed more locally and then linked to national objectives have
been shown to be more flexible and responsive to local interests.
Relevant local stakeholders can develop these frameworks, with
special support given to the disadvantaged poor to negotiate for
their interests. Experience suggests that local responsiveness will
be higher to the extent that effort is made to monitor and evaluate
impacts and that institutional arrangements facilitate good communication and learning about these impacts among stakeholders.
The learning process should include both local interest groups and
national policy-makers to best manage different interests.
Policy frameworks could better assist self-initiated local responses to problems in access and use of forest products to build
on what they are already doing, and to enable new partnerships.
Multistakeholder poverty–forests learning processes could be fostered with codes of conduct for supporting local initiatives and
integrating them in national forest programs and poverty reduction strategies.
8.4.3 Small-scale Private and Public–Private
Ownership and Management of Forests
Small-scale private (non-industrial, non-community) ownership
(or ‘‘family forestry’’) is very common in Western Europe and in
the southern part of the United States. In Sweden, half of the
forest area (with 60% of the production of wood) is owned by
over a quarter of a million people. In Finland, over 75% is privately owned. An average holding in Sweden is around 50 hectares; in Finland, 30 hectares; in Germany, 7 hectares; and in
France and Spain, below 5 hectares. Experiences from Scandinavia and from continental Europe indicate that privately operated
forestry has strong sustainability credentials (National Board of
Forestry 2001).
Since the discussion below is based on experiences mainly
from Western Europe, some lessons may be possible to apply to
forestry in other parts of the world, while some may not. Fundamental differences in the institutional framework and in culture
will affect the outcomes. Private ownership is not merely a judicial matter—it is a matter of culture and tradition. More positively, some factors mentioned may be of importance also in
countries with quite different institutions, such as local community or village control (or ownership) over the forest.
Small-scale private ownership may lead to closer management
and more efficient economic use in the self-interest of the owner.
Planting, pre-commercial thinning, and collection of firewood
are well suited for do-it-yourself work. Gathering of berries and
mushrooms, hunting, and recreational activities can often be conveniently combined with planning or supervision of forest production activities. Private ownership may lead to a greater sense
of responsibility assumed by the owner, which may foster long
term thinking such that sustainability is naturally sought, partly as
a risk reduction strategy.
When the imperative of biodiversity conservation was
brought to the fore in Scandinavia in the 1970s, a difference was
observed between privately owned forests and large-scale corporate or public forests. In general, the private forests were more
biologically varied (especially at a landscape level). This led, in
Sweden, to private forest ownership being fully recognized in
policy whereas previously large-scale forestry had been seen as the
priority model (Klingberg 2004).
Constraints that have arisen, and ways in which they have
been overcome primarily in the Scandinavian context, are assessed
below (Klingberg 2004):
• Efficiency. Small holdings can be technically inefficient, leading
some owners to cooperate with neighbors. Originally, these
associations worked as wholesalers, assembling round wood
and negotiating prices with large pulp mills and sawmills.
Today they are large economic enterprises, organizing harvesting operations with modern machinery and professional
staff, which single owners cannot afford. The associations have
also invested in sawmills, pulp mills, and bioenergy production, thereby securing demand for wood harvested.
• Knowledge and competence. Lack of knowledge can result in
mismanagement or even destruction of the holding. Do-ityourself activities also tend to have higher accident rates than
professional lumbering. Both the associations and the government work to solve these problems through training and information provision.
• Raising standards. The associations in Sweden are active in raising both forest production and the level of environmental
protection. Certification is being pushed, with higher standards than those found in the legislation.
• Long-term perspective. A fundamental factor is the long-term
thinking by many private owners, who plan to pass on their
holdings to younger generations. Regenerating harvested forests is an established norm.
• Combined activities. Many small owners combine other jobs
with the income from the forest, thus forming viable rural
livelihoods.
Property rights are fundamental to the prospects for family
forestry. Laws and regulations must back up smallholders’ ownership and property rights. In many countries, ownership legislation
and the system of land registry may not be conducive for private
forestry holdings.
In the Nordic countries and many continental European
countries, training and dissemination of knowledge has been used
systematically to improve small-scale private forestry. For example, the Swedish Regional Forestry Boards have for over 50 years
both been responsible for enforcing the Forest Act and for disseminating extension material and running study circles and courses
with forest owners.
Boxes 8.1 and 8.2 provide assessment of two important examples of larger-scale private involvement in forest management—
public-private partnerships and conservation concessions.
8.4.4 Company–Community Forestry Partnerships
8.4.4.1 Spread and Effectiveness of Company–Community
Forestry Partnerships
In recent years, a range of partnerships has emerged between forestry companies and communities or groups of smallholders, and
Wood, Fuelwood, and Non-wood Forest Products
BOX 8.1
Public–Private Partnerships in Forest Management: Some
U.S. Case Studies
In the United States, 70% of commercial forests are privately owned.
Hundreds of initiatives of public–private collaboration represent a new
wave in forest management. Some examples:
• The Conservation Fund developed a broad public–private coalition to seize the opportunity represented by Champion International Corporation, which put 120,000 hectares of forestland on
the market, much of it within the Adirondack Park of upstate New
York. With funds from government and private forest management organizations, TCF purchased the entire 120,000 hectares.
Today, some of the lands are protected while others operate as
working forests with private forest managers where the future
forested state is ensured by conservation easements.
• Seven Islands Land Company is among the oldest and largest
owners of forests in Maine. With dozens of heirs and nearly
400,000 hectares, there are few similar ownerships anywhere
in the world. The owners worked with the New England Forest
Foundation to negotiate a conservation easement covering more
than 280,000 hectares in northern Maine. The multiyear campaign to raise nearly $30 million dollars was successfully completed in 2002.
• Safe harbor is an approach developed by Environmental Defense
to engage private owners in endangered species conservation.
Private landowners enter a voluntary agreement with the U.S.
Fish and Wildlife Service whereby the owner limits his exposure
and potential impacts from threatened and endangered species.
The parties identify a baseline and if future management results
in an expansion of the population, the landowner’s regulatory
obligation is limited to the baseline population.
271
ships are foremost a means to share the risks of production and
marketing (Mayers and Vermeulen 2002).
Partnerships entail costs that can outweigh benefits under certain conditions, such as inappropriate government policy. (See
Table 8.2.) Some impacts of company–community forestry partnerships remain debatable. Effects on local equity and rural development are mixed, and financial returns have often proven
insufficient to lift community partners out of poverty, either
through direct membership or through knock-on effects such as
new employment and upstream/downstream small-scale business
opportunities. Furthermore, equity in power between company
and community partners is seldom achieved, and often actively
avoided by the company partner in spite of the obvious reductions in risk of interacting with a more equal, legitimate partner
(Mayers and Vermeulen 2002).
8.4.4.2 Policy Challenges
Making the most of partnerships centers on five key themes:
• iterative approaches to developing equitable, efficient, and accountable governance, both at the contract level and more
broadly;
• raising the bargaining power of communities, particularly
through association at appropriate scales;
• fostering the roles of brokers and other third parties, especially
independent community development organizations;
• sharing the benefits of wood processing as well as production;
and
• working toward standards (for example, in licensing requirements or certification) that give equal opportunities to smallscale enterprises.
8.5 Demand-side, Market-driven, and
Technological Responses
8.5.1 Public and Consumer Action
many are widespread globally. They vary widely in terms of types
of forest products, types of partners, and the degree of development and equity between the partners. (See Table 8.1.) Outgrower schemes and joint ventures predominate, but several other
kinds of arrangements, many informal, have arisen in response to
local circumstances. Company–community partnerships are globally widespread, occurring in at least 23 countries in North
America, South America, Europe, Africa, Asia, and the Pacific
(Mayers and Vermeulen 2002).
Behind the range of partnership types lie a range of motives
for entering into partnership. Globalization of investment, trade,
and technology, coupled with increasing decentralization and
grassroots demands for autonomy, provides strong impetus to
both companies and communities. Neither party on its own can
access and secure all the means for producing the goods and
services it needs. Third parties are also pivotal participants in company–community deals: local and central government; development agencies and NGOs; providers of credit and insurance;
certification bodies; and cooperatives, federations, and trade
unions.
Evidence to date shows that partnerships can be better than
solely corporate forestry, or solely community or small-scale farm
forestry, in delivering the wide range of benefits now expected by
the partners and by the public at large. Importantly, partnerships
are able to provide superior economic returns to both partners in
addition to public benefits. But direct economic returns are not
always the most highly valued output to either partner. Partner-
8.5.1.1 Evolution of Public and Consumer Action
Consumer action emerged in the early 1970s as a means of addressing the global loss of forests. Initially, campaigns focused on
tropical forests. As well as aiming to bring about actual changes in
flows in the trade of commodities deriving from tropical forest
areas, they were also used as a means of informing the public in
countries such as the United Kingdom and the Netherlands about
a distant environmental issue by identifying international trade
linkages.
Wider public and political action also developed at this time,
and for similar reasons. Various interest groups, such as Friends of
the Earth in Europe and the Environmental Defense Fund in the
United States, were identifying linkages between multilateral institutions such as the World Bank and bilateral donor agencies and
forest-destructive programs in the tropics. As these programs were
at least partly designed and managed by agencies accountable to
industrial-country democratic governments and, ultimately,
funded through taxpayers contributions, the public was encouraged to express concern and demand cessation of the funding of
such damaging activities. Mass letter-writing campaigns urged
governments to take the appropriate action within the relevant
global institutions and to adopt suitable domestic policies and
safeguards concerning the use of development cooperation
funding.
Such actions continued to grow during the late 1970s and
1980s and, following the lead of interest groups in the United
Ecosystems and Human Well-being: Policy Responses
272
BOX 8.2
Conservation Concessions
A ‘‘conservation concession’’ is a voluntary agreement whereby governments and other affected stakeholders are compensated for foregoing
economic development on public lands. Conservation concessions are
modeled after typical resource extraction contracts, such as logging concessions; however, rather than paying for the right to extract natural resources from public lands, the investor pays for the right to preserve the
forest.
The conservation concession is a relatively new mechanism, and only
two applications have been completed to date. The first is a 100,000
hectare area in Guyana. The second is a 135,000 hectare concession
along the Madre De Dios River in Peru. Other conservation concession
deals are at various stages of development in countries such as Indonesia, Mexico, and Bolivia. The rate of implementation is significantly impeded by two factors. First, the in-country capacity and organization of
many developing-country NGOs to implement conservation concessions
is poor; for example, capacity in resource valuation, contract law, and
stakeholder analysis is often weak. Second, because of the general unavailability of financing for recurrent management costs or compensation
payments, financing for conservation concessions tends to be available
only on a project basis.
The components of a conservation concession contract that the conservation investor and the government must negotiate include the following:
• Payments. The cost of the conservation concession is calculated to
reflect the ‘‘opportunity cost’’ of conservation. This includes the
value of foregone employment and taxes incurred as a result of
creating the concession.
• Duration. The duration of a conservation concession is flexible, but
typically is the same as the duration for land use contracts that it is
replacing.
• Management plan and objectives. The final component of the negotiated agreement is to develop a management plan for the conces-
Table 8.1.
sion area. The management plan includes a clear statement of the
conservation objectives for the concession and performance indicators that demonstrate whether these objectives are being met.
The conservation concession approach is novel. Nevertheless, there is
enough experience to identify some of the strengths and weaknesses of
the concession relative to other conservation mechanisms. The conservation concession transfers the cost of conservation to stakeholders who
are better able and willing to bear it. This apparent strength of the concession can also be a great limitation if resource rights are very valuable, for
example, in Southeast Asian forests or in temperate forests with high
commercial stocking. Conservation funding may simply be unable to compete with other land uses in these areas.
Because they are not permanent, conservation concessions may encounter less political resistance to implement. Concessions may also be
useful to obtain an interim conservation status after which a more permanent mechanism may be sought. The temporary nature of a concession
can also be a weakness in some contexts, as it cannot guarantee the
permanent protection of any particular forest.
Accountability is one of the greatest strengths of the conservation concession. Annual payments are made only if periodic monitoring and evaluation indicate that the conservation objectives for the concession are
being met. Increased accountability also brings with it a greater risk of
detecting failure.
One of the strongest criticisms of the conservation concession approach is that it may inadvertently create perverse impacts. For example,
countries may be unwilling to create new protected areas if they think that
they can attract investors to finance conservation concessions. However,
it should be possible to develop policies to mitigate this risk. For example,
conservation concessions could be restricted to being a ‘‘phase two’’ conservation mechanism, used only after a country has established a representative network of protected areas.
Typology of Company–Community Forestry Arrangements, by Partner
Company Type
Forest product buyer,
processor (largescale)
Individual Tree
Growers
Individual Tree
Users
outgrower schemes
for timber, pulp,
commodity wood, or
NWFPs
Group of Tree Growers
Group of Tree Users
product supply
contracts
outgrower schemes
product supply contracts
joint venture for timber or pulp
farmer outprocessing
corporate social responsibility project
community processing or
farmer outprocessing
contracts by communities
farm forestry support
and crop share
arrangements
Forestry concession
or plantation owner
(large-scale)
land leased from
farmers
Small local
production or
processing enterprise
credit/product supply
agreements
Environmental
service company
group certification with company
support
co-management for
NWFPs
concessions leased from
communities
co-management for NWFPs
corporate social responsibility project
product supply
agreements
credit/product supply agreements
joint ventures
forest environmental service agreements
product supply agreements
Wood, Fuelwood, and Non-wood Forest Products
273
Table 8.2. Conditions under which Companies, Communities, and Landscapes Win or Lose in Partnership Arrangements
Outcome
Without Partnership Arrangements
With Partnership Arrangements
Companies lose
inadequate supplies from restricted land and resource
access
transaction costs of developing deals too high
high risk of non-cooperation or resistance from
communities
process too complicated
absence of pressure from communities, law, or market
secure supplies of raw materials and/or workforce
profitable to buy community land, pay off local elites, and
massage opinion with public relations
‘‘social licence to operate’’ granted by communities and
wider society
lack of livelihood-improving opportunities in rural areas
become locked into dependency, or ripped off by
companies
lack of legal or bureaucratic permissions to develop land
or trees without companies
pushed into unwise or sub-optimal land uses
livelihoods not skewed by single strategies, commodities,
or markets
income generated or services provided where few other
rural alternatives available
self-determination unaffected by company agendas
capacity for community-run development options
enhanced
forest asset stripping by companies seeking out weak local
governance
inappropriate trees used or natural forest felled
non-forestry land uses may be less optimal or landscapedegrading
other land uses like grazing squeezed or displaced
causing degradation
land use systems and product diversity more optimal
without forestry
reduced micro-level erosion from forest land uses
land and resource control pattern more sustainable without
deals
more forest goods and services in the landscape
Companies win
Communities lose
Communities win
Environmental deterioration
Environmental benefits
Kingdom and United States, were also taken up in other countries, including Australia, Germany, France, Japan, Denmark,
Austria, and the Netherlands. Consumer action continued to
focus on the tropical timber trade. Significantly, almost all campaigns took a nuanced approach, calling not for a total boycott of
tropical rainforest timber but for a ‘‘selective boycott’’ of products
that had not been derived from ‘‘sustainable sources.’’ This provided the basis for the later development of forest certification
schemes. Consumer action campaigns worked through networks
of locally affiliated activists, reinforced through media campaigns
that served to highlight the connections between high-profile retail and manufacturing companies and forest management problems in identified areas (such as Brazil and Sarawak). Specific
actions included picketing of, and dramatic protests outside, retail
outlets, and the application of stickers and posters to shops and
wood products. One particular target of such activities was the
trade in Brazilian mahogany, which research had shown was
largely derived from illegal exploitation of areas supposedly protected for indigenous communities. By the early 1990s, such actions had substantially reduced levels of imports of Brazilian
mahogany into some countries.
Related to consumer actions were efforts to ensure that local
and national governments in tropical timber ‘‘consuming countries’’ adopted purchasing policies that encouraged the use of timber from ‘‘sustainable sources.’’ As a result of these efforts (also by
local and national activist networks), by 1992, several hundred
local authorities, including major metropolitan authorities,
throughout Europe, North America, and Japan, had adopted such
policies. Several national governments (including those of Austria
and the Netherlands) also moved toward such policies, though
these evidently ran foul of both EU and GATT trading rules and
were never fully implemented. They did, however, send a strong
political message to tropical timber producing nations.
Campaigns aimed at the international financial institutions
succeeded in drawing public attention to the role of agencies such
as the World Bank, and by implication the governments that supported them, in specific projects with major impacts on tropical
forests. In some cases, such projects were either halted or significantly altered to reduce environmental and social impacts. Public
pressure also succeeded in bringing about multilateral policy
change, most notably the adoption by the World Bank of a new
forest policy in 1993 that prohibited the use of Bank funds for
commercial logging operations in tropical moist forests (World
Bank 1991).
Possibly one of the most important results of consumer action
between the mid-late 1970s and the early 1990s was the development of forest certification and labeling schemes. In 1987, Friends
of the Earth established the ‘‘Good Wood Seal of Approval’’
scheme, which aimed to help consumers distinguish between
products derived from ‘‘environmentally and socially acceptable
sources’’ and products derived from ‘‘destructive’’ sources. It was
underpinned by the belief that, by developing guaranteed markets
for ‘‘acceptable’’ products, possibly with a price premium, an incentive would be provided for forest managers to adopt sustainable forest management practices.
The establishment of the Forest Stewardship Council in 1993
coincided with a decline in mass public action concerning forests
in a number of ‘‘consumer countries,’’ and the onset of ‘‘media
fatigue’’ on these issues. The source of ‘‘pressure’’ on the timber
trade thus partly shifted from consumers and the wider public
274
Ecosystems and Human Well-being: Policy Responses
to trade groupings such as the ‘‘1995 Groups’’ organized by the
Worldwide Fund for Nature. Through high-profile marketing
campaigns, WWF has encouraged the public to selectively purchase FSC-certified wood products, while simultaneously working collaboratively with timber producing, manufacturing and
retailing companies to assist them in gaining FSC certification.
However, during the later 1990s and continuing today, a more
radical form of protest has emerged. Focusing on the trade in
illegal and ‘‘conflict’’ timber (and capitalizing on various international research initiatives which have documented the wide extent of this problem), environmental pressure groups such as
Greenpeace, Environmental Investigation Agency, and Global
Witness have conducted high profile ‘‘naming and shaming’’
campaigns against specific forest sector corporations and government agencies. Such campaigns have been waged in many European countries, as well as in North America. These campaigns
have contributed to the signing of bilateral agreements concerning illegal wood products between the government of Indonesia
and various timber importing countries and the development of a
draft policy by the European Union (EU FLEGT) concerning the
use of voluntary licensing as a means of distinguishing legal from
illegal wood.
Public attention has now shifted to other environmental issues, especially global climate change. The deliberations on global
forest issues within the UN framework (such as the Intergovernmental Forum on Forests and UNFF) have not been seen by
many civil society organizations as likely to result in significant
improvements ‘‘on the ground,’’ and therefore have not provided
a useful focus for mass public action and political lobbying (UK
TFF 1998). Much of the debate between the various stakeholders
on issues such as forest management standards, conservation, and
human rights takes place within the context of certification, in
which the wider public is little involved.
8.5.1.2 Effectiveness of Public and Consumer Action
Public action has undoubtedly had a number of important and
positive consequences (Elliot 2000). However, it is also evident
that such actions are very difficult and costly to sustain, particularly as they are dependent on the use of mass media, which suffers
from ‘‘issue fatigue.’’ Because of the need for media attention,
such campaigns have tended to focus on targets with a high public
profile in the countries in which the campaigns take place, especially large companies with operations in tropical forest areas. The
response from the target corporation is likely to be to be withdraw from the operation altogether (rather than improve its standards) and there have been instances where such operations have
been taken over by other companies with lower operating standards (Amazon Financial Information Service 2001–2).
Consumer campaigns and media exposes—such as those concerning illegal logging—do not always fully address the underlying causes of forest loss and degradation, especially the problems
of inequitable land tenure and forest community poverty in developing countries.
Where public and consumer actions concern tropical forest
issues, they are dependent on a strong understanding of local conditions, which can usually only be derived through close working
relationships between civil society organizations in northern and
tropical countries. However, few NGOs in developing countries
actually have the resources or capacity to sustain such work over
long periods of time, and therefore there is a danger that public
actions in Europe or North America strongly reflect the views
and priorities of ‘‘northern’’ NGOs rather than groups in the
countries concerned.
8.5.1.3 Policy Challenges
Consumer campaigns can potentially continue to play an important role both in maintaining public awareness of forestry issues
and in encouraging improved forest management. However, it is
likely that the only institutions likely to be capable of sustaining
the information and media exercises necessary for such campaigns
are governments. While these are pressing policy challenges, it
would be unrealistic to assume that governments will prioritize
them without further concerted work by NGOs to mobilize consumers.
8.5.2 Third-party Voluntary Forest Certification
Certification is the procedure by which a third party provides
written assurance that a product, process, or service conforms to
specified standards, on the basis of an audit conducted according
to agreed procedures. It may be linked with product labeling for
market communication purposes. Certification offers independent assessment of the quality of forest management in relation to
prescribed standards. It is voluntary, the forest manager being
driven primarily by the prospect of access to markets that demand
forest products produced in a responsible way, but also by improvements to company reputation and capacity.
8.5.2.1 Current Status of Certification
Forest certification has evolved rapidly. In only a decade, it has
become routine practice in an increasingly large range of countries and forest conditions, and several schemes have sprung up.
Three concerns are uppermost in assessing its effectiveness as a
response to forest problems. First, the early drivers of certification
hoped it would be an effective response to tropical deforestation.
Now, however, most certified forests are in the north, managed
by larger companies and exporting to northern retailers. Second,
there has been a proliferation of certification programs to meet
different stakeholders’ needs, with the result that no single program has emerged as the only credible or dominant approach internationally. Third, the competitiveness of small and mediumsized enterprises, which may have advantages for sustainability
and local livelihoods, is called into question where certification
becomes the preserve of larger companies only.
Forest management certification assesses the performance of onthe-ground forestry operations against a predetermined set of
standards. If the forestry operations are found to be in conformance with these standards, a certificate is issued, offering the
owner or manager the potential to bring products from the certified forest to the market as ‘‘certified’’ products. This market potential is realized by a supplementary certification, which assesses
the chain of custody of wood from the forest, through timber
processor to manufacturer, to importer, to distributor, to retailer.
In this sense, forest certification is market driven.
Accreditation is the process of recognition against published criteria of capability, competence, and impartiality of a body involved in certification, and results in licenses to operate a
particular certification scheme. It ‘‘certifies the certifiers.’’
Certification schemes often make provision for the following:
• multiple source chain of custody to enable certification for paper,
composite wood, and other products. This may allow processors a mix of certified and uncertified material where this reflects local supplies, and so reduces cost. It may also favor
mixture with recycled materials;
• group certification of smallholders, to allow several small enterprises to be covered by one certificate, held by the group
manager. This can reduce costs, provided group members are
sufficiently similar to create scale economies;
Wood, Fuelwood, and Non-wood Forest Products
• forest manager certification, where a professional manager is responsible for several small areas; this, too, reduces costs and
creates economies of scale;
• recycled wood certification, which accords certified status to reclaimed or recycled wood where chain of custody is known;
and
• ecological zone harmonization of national standards, to ensure that
standards covering similar ecological zones can be rationalized.
Since its emergence in 1993, the FSC has certified forests in
all continents, with a rapid increase in the area covered. Numerous other international and national forest certification schemes
have more recently been launched, including in the United
States, Malaysia, and Brazil. (See Box 8.3.) Many local stakeholders wanted to take charge of the process of developing certification schemes, to ensure they were appropriate to their forest
types, enterprise types, and governance systems (Confederation of
European Paper Industries 2002).
Where there is contention over a certification scheme, it tends
to concern one or some of the following:
• perceived dominance or exclusion of certain parties,
• perceived lack of comparability between standards in a given
region, and
• the degree of challenge or ‘‘stretch’’ represented by the gap
between normally applied legal standards and the particular
certification standards.
Where once there was some hostility between schemes and
their supporters, there has been increasing collaboration and mutual support. There is a genuine desire to see certification play a
key role among the responses to forest problems. To the extent
possible, the individual schemes are beginning to put their differences aside to find an enduring role for certification.
8.5.2.2. Effectiveness and Policy Challenges in Certification
Observations on the effectiveness of certification as a response
option include the following (Bass et al. 2001; Eba’a and Simula
275
2002). First, overall effectiveness in reducing poor forest management and deforestation depends critically on the incentive effects
of market-based certification. In practice, the high threshold levels of certification standards (and FSC’s in particular) have provided incentives only to already ‘‘good’’ producers rather than to
improving bad practice. However, these ‘‘good’’ producers also
now meet all current legal requirements, including those that they
might normally not bother to meet. Most of them have also tightened management systems, especially for managing environmental impact. Thus certification has encouraged competition
between producers at the high end of competence (just above and
below the ‘‘certified’’ threshold). However, there are few incentives to cause the really bad producers to change behavior and be
certified. The need for several thresholds (step-wise or phased
approaches) is now being discussed, along with ways to complement certification with instruments for illegal logging.
Second, at the level of their standards, most schemes are applicable to many types of forest. Most certification schemes have
been able to develop and apply one overarching standard agreed
by many stakeholders and there are considerable similarities between the standards. Certification has coped effectively with complexity (in standards and their interpretation) and yet also delivers
a simple message to consumers and producers.
Third, in practice, larger producers find it easier to benefit
from certification, as they have better access to information and
markets, scale economies, formal management systems on similar
forest types, and an ability to bear risks and costs. The area of
certified forest under community or small enterprise management
is correspondingly much smaller. Many certification schemes have
responded with special schemes for group certification of small
growers or for certifying entire regions with one management
regime. But there are those that question why a small community
group occasionally harvesting timber on its own land should be
held as accountable as a major corporation harvesting each day on
leased public land.
BOX 8.3
Selected Forest Certification Programs
The Forest Stewardship Council’s objectives are to promote global standards
of forest management, to accredit certifiers that certify forest operations according to such standards, and to encourage buyers to purchase certified
products. FSC is one of the first institutions to have been deliberately designed to sustainable development principles. It is a membership organization, with decisions made through meetings of a General Assembly, which is
divided into three equal chambers: social, environmental, and economic. All
three chambers have Northern and Southern sub-chambers, each with half
of the total chamber votes. Governments are not entitled to participate in
FSC’s governance, even as observers, although government employees
have been very active participants in some FSC national initiatives. FSC has
a set of ten principles and related criteria (P&C) covering environmental,
social, economic, and institutional aspects of forest stewardship, which apply
to all forests, both natural and plantations. These P&C serve as a basis
for the development of national and regional forest management standards.
Certification standards that are consistent with both the P&C and with FSC’s
process guidelines for standards development are eligible for FSC endorsement. Such standards have been developed by both FSC-organized national
working groups and by independent processes. FSC owns a trademark,
which may be used to label products from certified forests. It has so far
certified 37 million hectares in 55 countries (as of April 2003).
The Programme for Endorsement of Forest Certification Schemes
(previously called the Pan-European Forest Certification Framework) is a
voluntary private-sector initiative, designed to promote an internationally
credible framework for forest certification schemes and initiatives. Its criteria are consistent with the intergovernmental Pan-European Criteria and
Indicators for Sustainable Forest Management, thereby attracting considerable support from both European and national governments. National
certification schemes that meet PEFC requirements can apply for endorsement and the right to use the PEFC trademark for product labeling.
National PEFC governing bodies set standards and operate national
schemes, and are represented on the PEFC Council Board. The initiative
was given strong impetus by Finnish, German, French, Norwegian, Austrian, and Swedish forest owners, who wished to ensure that small woodland owners are not disadvantaged by certification and that local
conditions are accounted for. It was supported by the national forest certification schemes that had been emerging in some of these countries,
which felt themselves to be individually too small to develop an adequate
presence. PEFC started in 1999; as of June 2003, it had certified 47
million hectares in 14 countries.
At the level of individual countries, the number of national certification
programs under development is increasing rapidly. These include the Sustainable Forestry Initiative in the United States, and systems in Canada,
Brazil, Malaysia and Indonesia.
276
Ecosystems and Human Well-being: Policy Responses
Fourth, certification is largely document-based, and is predicated on formal, structured means of planning and monitoring. In
practice, this assumption is biased against traditional societies and
‘‘part-time’’ foresters. Some current certification standards and
procedures cannot recognize good management in some of the
complex land use systems of indigenous and community groups.
Fifth, some environmental and social services are produced at
levels other than the forest management unit (such as the landscape or the nation), which may not be under the control of the
certified enterprise but which require its active engagement. Further developments are needed to ensure that certification encourages and recognizes improved relations between the forest
management area and surrounding land uses.
Sixth, certification is a cost-effective complement to traditional administrative regulation. In all countries, certification is, at
a minimum, encouraging some companies to meet legal requirements. In some countries, state forest authorities support certification as a ‘‘privatized’’ form of forest monitoring, and are making
incentives available. In countries where regulation and enforcement is weak, certification has ensured that at least some producers are meeting not only legal requirements but also higher
standards, and that this is monitored.
Seventh, certification depends for success on its credibility.
The key ingredients are participation in defining standards to ensure they reflect many stakeholders’ needs, consultation of local
stakeholders when certifying forest management, and verification
by third parties using tried-and-tested mechanisms with precedents in other sectors. Proliferation of certification schemes,
which is leading to consumer confusion and a reluctance of some
firms to be certified at all, has undermined the credibility of the
approach and prompted considerable efforts by the wood products industry to investigate the potential of mutual recognition
among schemes.
Eighth, in practice, certified products command only a minority of the forest products market (about 4% globally in 2003),
with highest market penetration in Western Europe. Certified
producers tend to gain market access, rather than a price premium
(although a premium is available in some segments). More needs
to be done to educate consumers about sustainable forestry and
certification if the demand is to rise significantly. However, if
market benefits have proven elusive, other incentives for certification are becoming apparent, such as certification to secure access to resources such as land, finance, and insurance.
8.5.3 Wood Technology and Biotechnology
Wood technology responses to date have been focused primarily
on species used in industrial plantations, which must have wood
properties suited for the products to be manufactured (Zobel and
van Buijtenen 1989). There is considerable variation within a species, from pith to bark at a given height in the tree, and from base
to top of tree, among trees within a stand, among stands within a
region, and among regions (Kellison 1967). The phenomenon
holds true regardless of the property, whether it be basic density,
fiber dimensions, cellulose content, lignin content, moisture content, resin content, or any other trait of interest. This variation
allows for genetic selection for any trait of economic importance
(Zobel and Talbert 1984).
The wood properties of greatest economic importance for industrial manufacturing are basic density, fiber dimensions (length,
width, lumen diameter, cell wall thickness, microfibril angle),
number of fibers per unit area, and cellulose content. Conventional breeding programs have been effective in changing commercially important wood properties (Zobel and Talbert 1984).
The property that has received most attention is wood-specific
gravity or wood density. The reason for concentrating on wood
density is its correlation with chemical pulp yield, strength properties of paper and paperboard, and strength properties of solid
wood products, especially lumber.
The trend is for wood production to be shifting from the
temperate and boreal regions of the world to certain parts of the
tropics and subtropics (Kellison 2001). The major reason for that
trend is the high growth rates of the trees, almost all of which are
exotics, at the lower latitudes. While it will be many years before
pulp production from northern plantations is greatly reduced,
these plantations will represent a declining share of the global
market. The reduction may be quickened if depreciation and amortization continue to exceed capitalization, which in the North
American industry for example, has been the case every year since
1996 with the exception of 1999 (Connelly et al, 2004).
From a biological standpoint, the major species groups that
are being intensively managed in plantations are Pinus, Eucalyptus,
and Acacia. The pines receiving greatest attention are P. taeda and
P. elliottii from the southern United States, P. radiata from California, P. caribaea var. hondurensis from Central America, and P. patula
from Mexico. The eucalypts species of greatest importance are
E. grandis, E. urophylla, and E. globulus, E. teriticornus, and E. camaldulensis, all of which have their origin in Australia and the
islands of Indonesia. The acacias, too, have Australia as their origin; they include A. mangium, A. mearnsii, A. aulicoliformis, and A.
crassifolia.
Using the same silvicultural practices, forest productivity of
the Pinus species is at least twice as great in the exotic environments as in their indigenous habitats, and the rotation ages are
typically 20% shorter. Similarly, the species of eucalypts and acacias produce 20–to 60 cubic meters per hectare per year, with
harvest ages ranging from 5 to 12 years. Only with the most intensive silviculture, including fertigation (the application of fertilizers and water in metered amount through a drip-irrigation
system), can angiosperm plantations in the temperate zones approach these growth rates. Even where plantation forestry is practiced in the temperate zone, a cost disadvantage exists in the
economics of producing the wood.
The advantages of plantation forestry in the tropics and subtropics for fiber production so far outweigh the opportunities in
the temperate and boreal zones that the developing countries to
either side of the equator will benefit at the expense of their
northern neighbors. The prognosis is that the plantation forests in
the temperate and boreal zones will increasingly be managed for
solid wood products. Fiber processing will be only a by-product
of saw log forestry. (See Box 8.4.)
8.5.4 Commercialization of Non-wood Forest
Products
Commercialization of non-wood forest products has become a
means, promoted by researchers, conservation and development
organizations, and, more recently, governments, to achieve rural
livelihood improvement in an environmentally sound way. The
category NWFP includes all products that are derived from forests
with the exception of timber. In practice, the definition of the
term has been ambiguous and inconsistent (Belcher 2003). Some
authors restrict the category to products of natural reproduction,
while others include managed or cultivated products. Generally
speaking, the category includes plant, animal, and fungus species
used for fuel, food, medicine, forage, and fiber, that have valuable
chemical components or that are used for ritual purposes.
Wood, Fuelwood, and Non-wood Forest Products
277
BOX 8.4
Wood Products Manufacturing Technology: A U.S. Case Study
Over the past 20 years, most operating North American softwood sawmills
have been re-equipped with a wide assortment of highly automated equipment optimized for processing small logs. Lumber recovery factors have
increased by nearly 50%, and productivity has nearly doubled. As sawmill
recoveries have improved and plywood production has declined, chip production from these wood products manufacturing facilities has also been
reduced. During this same period, raw material demand from the pulp and
paper industry has increased nearly 20 percent. The industry has satisfied
nearly all of this demand with recycled fiber, and that trend is expected to
continue.
Total demand for roundwood has almost doubled in the United States
over the past 25 years, only part of which is due to increases in the
demand for pulpwood. Most of the increase has come from rapid growth
in the strand products industry, and most of that added demand has been
for hardwood, which has helped create a market for this low-cost wood.
Strand-based products use softwoods as well, and that industry will likely
Interest in NWFPs began in earnest in the late 1980s and early
1990s, in conjunction with increasing global concern about deforestation and rural poverty. Forests gained heightened appreciation as sources of multiple products and services, and as important
sources of livelihood for forest-based people (de Beer and McDermott 1989; Falconer 1990; Plotkin and Fomolare 1992). Researchers began to document the tremendous range of products
used by forest people. Optimistic comparisons suggested that total
NWFP values approached or exceeded timber values from the
same forests (e.g., Peters et al. 1989). More realistic assessments
followed, giving lower estimates (Godoy and Bawa 1993), but a
movement had started. Environmentalists and social activists
championed the idea that NWFPs extracted from the forest could
provide an environmentally sustainable basis for livelihoods, leading to the establishment of ‘‘extractive reserves’’ for rubber, Brazil
nuts, and other NWFPs in the Brazilian Amazon beginning in
1990, and exploration of the potential for similar approaches
throughout the tropics (Ruiz-Pérez and Arnold 1996; Neumann
and Hirsch 2000).
The underlying assumptions, often implicit, were that NWFP
harvesting is more benign and valuable than timber harvesting,
that it benefits poor people, and that it provides incentives for
local people to conserve forests. In fact, none of these premises
is necessarily true, and positive outcomes are only likely under
restricted conditions (Ruiz-Perez et al. 2004).
8.5.4.1 Constraints on Implementation
The vast majority of NWFPs are consumed directly by the people
that collect them and their families. Some are important mainstays
in the household economy. The ubiquitous use of bamboo in the
construction of buildings and utility items in rural areas, or the
regular consumption of wild meat and vegetables, are examples.
Other NWFPs are used infrequently, but can be critically important as sources of food when other sources are unavailable. Such
emergency foods can make the difference between life and death.
A smaller, but still considerable, number of NWFPs are produced for sale or barter. These include various fruits, nuts, and
vegetables that are primarily traded in local and regional markets
and ‘‘bush meats’’ that are traded in large quantities in urban markets (Brown and Williams 2003). Other products find demand in
more distant markets. High value mushrooms are collected in re-
expand into softwood growing areas where the price is competitive with
hardwood sources. In the 1990s, the trend away from large diameter logs
accelerated with the virtual elimination of timber sales from federal lands
in the Pacific Northwest. With the reduced availability of large diameter
logs and the growth of oriented strand board and engineered products,
the demand for (and relative value of) these large logs has also declined.
Shorter rotations are more economically competitive than the long rotations needed for large logs, and improved efficiency in processing
smaller sawlogs plus rising prices for fiber grade logs combine to support
intensively managed forests in the United States. These forests can produce nearly 100% more annual growth than forests managed to produce
large sawlogs.
In 1980, plywood manufacturing was concentrated mainly in the southern and western part of the United States. The net effect of substituting
oriented strand board for plywood has been a net migration of panel
industry jobs from the west to the north.
mote forests in China and sold the next day in supermarkets in
Tokyo, and various herbal medicines and essential oils are sold in
the growing western health and beauty markets.
A combination of factors has led to growth in some NWFP
markets. The extension of the market system to more remote
areas has created both the demand and the opportunity for increased cash incomes by NWFP producers. Globalization and
growing interest in various kinds of natural products such as
herbal medicines, wild foods, handcrafted utensils, and decorative
items have increased demand and trade in these products. And
development projects have increasingly sought to increase income
opportunities, including through the production, processing, and
trade of NWFPs. Still, the majority of traded NWFPs are sold in
relatively small quantities (per producer; collective quantities can
be very large), and for relatively low prices by the raw material
producers. They are important in helping households to meet
current consumption needs, and some are relied on as the main
or the only regular source of cash income. Few NWFPs have
large and reliable markets, and these tend to be supplied by specialized producers using more intensive production systems
(Belcher et al 2003).
There is strong evidence that the poorest of the rural poor are
most dependent on NWFPs (Neumann and Hirsch 2000), that
the poor frequently use NWFPs as an ‘‘employment of last resort’’
(Angelsen and Wunder 2003), and that NWFPs serve an important safety net function (McSweeney 2004). Cavendish (1998) explains this in terms of the economic characteristics of forestdependent people and of the products themselves. Many forest
products are available as common-property resources in traditional systems or as de facto open-access resources, in state forest
lands for example. They can be harvested and used with little
processing, using low cost (often traditional) technologies. Some
NWFPs are likely to be available for direct consumption or sale
when crops fail due to drought or disease, or when shocks hit the
household such as unemployment, death, or disease (Cavendish
1998).
The same factors that tend to make them important in the
livelihoods of the poor also limit the scope for NWFPs to lift
people out of poverty. Markets for many of these products are
small and many are ‘‘inferior products.’’ Naturally reproducing
products tend to be dispersed, with seasonal and annual fluctua-
278
Ecosystems and Human Well-being: Policy Responses
tions in quantity and quality of production. Individual harvesters
are limited in the amount that they are able to harvest. Open
access resources are highly susceptible to overexploitation. The
remote locations where wild NWFPs tend to be produced often
have poor market access. All of these factors put producers in a
weak bargaining position relative to traders who typically provide
transport, market connections, and credit to NWFP collectors in
classic patron-client relationships. In some respects, such products
can be viewed as ‘‘poverty traps’’ in that people rely on NWFPs
because they are poor and do not have better alternatives, but
they are unable to use these resources to break out of poverty
(Neumann and Hirsch 2000).
As Dove (1993) noted, in those cases where NWFPs have
high value, they tend to be appropriated by people with more
power, more assets, and better connections. This might happen
through coercion and physical control of the trade, but more
often control is achieved through domestication, when market
forces lead to intensified and specialized production.
Homma (1992) developed a simple economic model that
shows how high demand for NWFPs can over time lead to overexploitation of the naturally regenerating resource base, production on plantations outside of forests, and increased competition
from synthetic substitutes. Empirical studies such as that by
Belcher et al (2003) found strong evidence for this trend in a
comparison of commercially traded NWFPs.
8.5.4.2 Effectiveness of Commercializing Non-wood Forest
Products
There have been successful efforts to promote NWFP commercialization through combinations of technical and capacitybuilding interventions to improve raw material production, processing, trade, and marketing, and through improved policy and
institutional frameworks. Resource tenure is a key factor, and
considerable effort has been invested to help communities gain
recognized rights and responsibilities to manage and use forest
resources (as discussed in the section on collaborative forest management).
Simple interventions can be very effective. Providing a weigh
scale and information on commodity prices and quality requirements of wholesale buyers in a trading center can help remote
producers gain a better bargaining position. Collective investment
in a building for storage or in a drying machine gives producers
of perishable commodities more flexibility in their marketing.
Improvements in processing and marketing, to improve product
quality and reach more valuable markets, add value, creates more
income downstream in the market chain, and increases demand
and earnings for raw material producers.
The empirical evidence is mixed. There are success stories
where production has been improved, markets have increased,
and income generation has improved. Problems may also arise
however, with inequitable distribution of benefits, stronger
groups gaining control at the expense of weaker groups, and
overexploitation of resources.
On the conservation side, success has been limited. The idea
that NWFP harvesting has a lower impact than timber harvesting
may be true in extensive, subsistence-oriented systems. But as
products enter commercial markets, pressure on the resource base
increases. Open-access resources are notoriously susceptible to
overexploitation, and species-level impacts can be severe. All
cases based on naturally regenerating resources in one major study
of commercial NWFP cases (Belcher et al. 2003) reported declining resource bases. Harvesting that reduces stocks (for example,
agarwood, palm-heart, wood for carving), especially of slow
growing, slow-reproducing species, typically has faster and more
severe impacts than harvesting of flows (for example, fruit, nuts).
But harvesting pressure can also reduce reproductive success (by
removing flowers or fruit), threatening longer-term sustainability.
At the ecosystem level, the hypothesis that increasing NWFP
value could provide incentives for forest conservation has not
been confirmed. To be true, it would require that the people who
benefit from NWFP production are major agents of deforestation
or that they have influence over those agents, and that lowintensity NWFP production is the most economically rewarding
use of the forest. In practice, this linkage is often missing. The
intended beneficiaries of NWFP development activities often are
not the main agents of deforestation and do not have control or
even influence over decisions to log or convert forest. Increased
value does not automatically translate into effective incentives for
conservation (Salafsky and Wollenberg 2000). Moreover, successful commercialization may create incentives to intensify NWFP
production through enrichment planting or cultivation. To the
extent that this is done in natural forest areas, it will result directly
in reduced biodiversity or outright conversion of the management unit to an NWFP plantation.
8.5.4.3 Policy Challenges
Many NWFPs do not have scope for commercial development
but are extremely important in millions of households. This has
not been recognized adequately; for example, the contribution of
forests to livelihoods has been chronically overlooked in poverty
reduction strategy papers (Oksanen and Mersmann 2002). These
values alone may be enough to justify forest conservation and
enhancement.
A smaller but still substantial subset of the NWFP category has
important local, regional, or international markets. Some of these
markets are growing, and there are opportunities to increase incomes and employment-generation through targeted policy and
project-level interventions. Typically, NWFPs have been ignored
by policy. They are often covered by forest regulations designed
for timber management, for example, or are not considered at all.
Management of naturally regenerating resources can be improved
with policy that more effectively gives incentives for sustainable
management. Rattan harvesting concessions in Asia, for example,
are frequently allocated over large areas to non-local concessionaires for very short periods. The concessionaires thus have no
incentive to harvest sustainably or to invest in regeneration and
local people benefit only from low- paying jobs as harvesters.
Basic biophysical research is lacking for many valuable NWFPs,
constraining efforts to improve management. More investment is
needed in this area. One promising area is joint-production of
timber and non-wood products. Improvements will require appropriate sivicultural research and new kinds of company–
community partnerships.
For livelihoods improvement, the key interventions may be
in resource control and in market development and capacity
building for small-scale producers to enable them to compete in
tough markets. In this vein, it is necessary to keep in mind that
the rural poor typically have diverse economic activities and are
risk averse. NWFP-oriented interventions should try to keep
other options open and not focus exclusively on one activity.
There are inherent contradictions between commercial development and biodiversity conservation, at least at the level of the
management unit. Increased demand leads to overexploitation of
naturally regenerating resources, especially under the open-access
conditions that prevail in many natural forest areas. Where conditions allow, producers tend to increase their management inten-
Wood, Fuelwood, and Non-wood Forest Products
sity, moving toward cultivation in horticultural or plantation
systems. At the management unit this means converting forest to
domesticated systems, with associated biodiversity loss. Conservation objectives might be achieved if such systems successfully reduce pressure on remaining natural forest.
8.6 Land Management Institutions, Investment,
and Incentives
8.6.1 Natural Forest Management in the Tropics
Whenever management was attempted with the intent to conserve and utilize natural forests, one model became dominant
(Troup 1940). Based on the earlier concept of sustained yield,
wood supply was designed to be continuous over generations,
with harvests planned not to exceed growth. Maintaining environmental quality and safeguarding rural employment were other
key objectives of this response. Knuchel (1953) provided an early
description of the technical approach. However, the practice of
natural forest management in the tropics, and in particular the wet
tropics where stocks of high value timber species are found, has
proved problematic (Bruenig 1996; Dawkins 1957; Putz et al.
2000). Controversy has long raged over the potential for ‘‘sustainable’’ forest management as a viable economic activity in the
tropics (Leslie 1977; Poore 1989; Dawkins and Philip 1997), in
part as a result of the restrictions it places on timber harvest levels.
This dispute continues (Rice et al. 2000; Pearce et al. 2003). Land
allocations or appropriations for other purposes, and overexploitation of other forest resources for subsistence use or commercial
gain, have also undermined the prospects for long-term natural
forest management.
Nevertheless, since the early 1990s, huge investments have
been made to promote improved management of natural forests
and see it put onto an operational footing in a large number of
countries (ITTO 1998). Over the last decade, an increasing (although ill-determined) amount of tropical forest has come under
some form of management, which aims to achieve product utilization while conserving the natural resource. Reduced impact
logging techniques have been especially popular. (See Box 8.5.)
8.6.1.1. Constraints on Implementation
In a large number of tropical timber-producing countries, poor
governance undermines the management system (Brown et al.
279
2002). Timber licensing systems are frequently opaque, subject
to considerable political patronage, and the beneficiaries are not
publicly known (Gray 2002; Sizer 1995 and 1996). As a result,
forest managers have limited influence over those given the rights
to harvest timber and find it difficult to exert sufficient control to
safeguard ecosystem health. However, interest in, and support for,
forest law enforcement has recently become a major policy concern, as the extent of illegal logging has become more widely
known and recognized as a significant constraint on new forest
management initiatives (World Bank 2002).
Forest management has tended to be more successful where
no viable land-use alternative exists. However, even then, low
yields together with heterogeneous species distribution patterns
have limited the viability of natural forest management. In contrast to temperate regions, valuable tree species occur at very low
stocking levels over much of the tropics, and their spatial distribution is poorly understood (and therefore difficult to predict). In
addition, many tree species suffer from a high incidence of natural
defect in the wood that precludes otherwise desirable trees from
being felled. High levels of previous timber exploitation are a
further limiting factor that is becoming increasingly important in
forest areas where access is good. The considerable cost of specialized machinery for logging heavy tropical hardwoods also poses a
constraint, particularly for small-scale operators. Sustainable forest
management in the tropics is frequently uneconomic if viewed in
timber production terms alone.
Natural forest management has proved difficult to implement
on a large scale, especially where access is limited. An annual felling coupe of 500 hectares in mixed tropical forest seems about
the maximum that can be managed within one planning unit,
without exceptional levels of management inputs. Many timber
concessions in the tropics exceed this limit, despite lacking staff
with the necessary management skills and associated resources.
A history of forest management in the region is helpful. Natural forest management is an information demanding process,
which relies heavily on written records due to the long-term nature of many of its constituent activities. Where management records have been lost, this has proved to be a serious constraint to
reviving forest management after periods of neglect.
Staff continuity within many forest authorities has suffered
during the diverse changes in their structure and function in recent years. Despite much attention to institutional reform, roles
and responsibilities have not always been clarified or backed-up
BOX 8.5
Reduced Impact Logging
Reduced impact logging comprises a set of harvesting practices that reduce impacts to residual vegetation, soils, and other environmental attributes compared with unplanned harvesting practices. RIL can reduce
damage by as much as 50% compared with conventional logging (Pinard
and Putz 1996; Holmes et al. 2002; Killmann et al. 2002).
Typically, RIL requires thorough resource inventories and careful harvest planning. Roads, skid trails, and log landings are planned and constructed so that they adhere to engineering guidelines designed to
minimize soil disturbance. Directional felling techniques are applied to
minimize damage to the residual stand and stumps are cut low to reduce
waste. Heavy machinery is required to remain on skid trails and roads in
order to limit soil disturbance and damage to vegetation. A post-harvest
assessment is essential in order to provide feedback to loggers, concession holders, and forest department personnel (Dykstra 2002, 2003).
RIL can also be more efficient and cost-effective than unplanned harvesting. In the Brazilian Amazon under RIL, the overall cost per cubic meter of
wood produced was 12% less than under conventional logging (Holmes et
al. 2002). However, under different conditions, applying RIL can be costly.
In the Malaysian State of Sabah, profits reportedly fell substantially when a
switch was made from conventional logging to RIL (Tay et al. 2002). Other
studies confirm that log production under RIL is often 20% lower than under
conventional logging, due mostly to restrictions on logging in environmentally
sensitive areas (Killmann et al. 2002). Financial benefits associated with the
application of RIL are largely due to better planning and improved supervisory control. To obtain these savings, technically competent planners, loggers, and supervisors are essential. Personnel with the skills needed to
apply these practices are rare in many parts of the tropics, so human resource development is a critical requirement for the adoption of RIL.
280
Ecosystems and Human Well-being: Policy Responses
with development of capabilities. The desirable separation of the
functions associated with forest management, forest regulation,
and revenue collection have often not been made. The decline
in forest management expertise has diminished the capacity of
institutions to adopt flexible responses and has led to standardization of forest management prescriptions. Without increased funding to strengthen forestry institutions, this situation will remain a
significant constraint to the successful application of this response.
Forest management is a field activity where the sequencing of
a number of operations is critical to success. However, difficult
working conditions are frequent, and matters are made worse by
the lack of attention given to the health and safety of field staff
in many countries. Education and training requirements remain
poorly addressed, resulting in a lack of appropriately trained staff
and the non-functioning of local professional associations.
Finally, in the species-rich tropics botanical identification is a
constraint, particularly where emphasis is now given to the management of rare and non-tree species. Another shortcoming is the
lack of attention given to the regeneration of the forest, despite
considerable research investment. Studies continue to have limited impact on the implementation of forest management in many
countries. More could be done to design effective dissemination
strategies of research results that target forest managers.
8.6.1.2 Effectiveness of Response
Natural forest management has been successful in maintaining
ecosystem health when it has also provided direct benefits to local
communities. State authorities, without the involvement of local
communities, carry out much forest planning with forest revenue
appropriated by central government. This approach became common in tropical forests with disappointing results, in that it was
unable either to safeguard the forest resource or to support local
human well-being. The situation is now slowly changing. Not
only is this helping to conserve the forest ecosystem, it is making
a wider contribution to human well-being by offering an example
for application in other public sectors.
from other land uses; providing rural employment; and, if planned
effectively, diversifying the rural landscape and maintaining biodiversity. These contributions have been recognized by a number
of the U.N. conventions. Afforestation and reforestation qualify
for support under the Clean Development Mechanism of the
UNFCCC for development of carbon sinks, the Global Mechanism of the Convention to Combat Desertification, and the
Global Environment Facility for rehabilitation of degraded lands
under the CBD.
Trees are increasingly being planted to support agricultural
production systems, community livelihoods, poverty alleviation,
and food security. Communities and smallholder investors, including individual farmers, grow trees in shelterbelts, home gardens, and woodlots and in a diverse range of agroforestry systems
to provide wood, non-wood forest products, fuelwood, fodder,
and shelter.
There is a strong trend toward commercialization and privatization of state forest plantation resources in an endeavor to manage these resources more effectively and efficiently in response to
free market forces. However, about half of the global forest plantation estate is grown primarily for environmental and ecological
rehabilitation and protection, and so is not suitable for management for industrial purposes.
Plantation managers in many countries are under pressure to
ensure that their forest plantations form an environmentally and
socially friendly source of world roundwood, fiber, fuelwood, and
non-wood forest products. Certification, government procurement policies, and public pressure in relation to forest plantation
siting and management are behind this.
8.6.2 Tree Plantation Management
8.6.2.1 Constraints
Not all afforestation has positive economic, environmental, social,
or cultural impacts. Without adequate planning and appropriate
management, forest plantations may be grown in the wrong sites,
with the wrong species or provenances, by the wrong growers,
for the wrong reasons. Examples exist where natural forests have
been cleared to establish forest plantations or where customary
owners of traditional lands may have been alienated from their
sources of food, medicine, and livelihoods. In some instances
poor site and species matching and inadequate silviculture have
resulted in poor growth, hygiene, volume yields, and economic
returns. In other instances, changes in soil and water status have
caused problems for local communities. Land-use conflicts can
occur between forest plantation development and other sectors,
particularly the agricultural sector and with communities who
may be alienated from their traditional land resources.
The global area of tree plantations was 187 million hectares in
2000, a significant increase over the 1990 estimate of 43.6 million
hectares (FAO 2001a). Although plantations are equivalent to
only 5% of global forest cover, they were estimated to supply
about 35% of global roundwood in the year 2000, and it is predicted that this figure will increase to 44% by 2030. (See MA
Current State and Trends, Chapters 9 and 21.) Plantations will play
an increasing role as natural forest areas decrease (largely in developing countries), are designated for conservation or other purposes (largely in developed countries), or are economically
inaccessible (CIFOR 2003).
In addition to wood, it is possible for forest plantations to
provide other environmental, social, and economic benefits,
including NWFPs such as honey, resin, and medicinal plants;
combating desertification; absorbing carbon to offset carbon
emissions; protecting soil and water; rehabilitating lands exhausted
8.6.2.2 Lessons Learned
Incentives (direct and indirect) have often been used by governments to encourage investment by the private sector to stimulate
accelerated rates of afforestation. However, these have sometimes
stimulated inappropriate activities (CIFOR 2003).
Surplus or marginal agricultural and degraded lands are increasingly targeted for afforestation. However, land-use conflicts
can arise when the land perceived as available and accessible is
actually used for grazing and provision of non-wood goods and
services, often according to customary or traditional land-use
rights (Anon. 2003).
Price pressures may threaten the range of forest plantation
benefits as approximately half of all forest plantations are driven
by wood profitability. There are early warning signs that leading
countries in forest plantation development (New Zealand, Chile,
8.6.1.3 Policy Challenges
Diverse, locally tailored solutions are needed for securing both
wood supplies and forest environmental services. Wherever such
solutions are developed, governance frameworks should become
sufficiently flexible to support them. There is a compelling case
for governments to give greater weight to locally determined approaches that provide solutions to the trade-offs associated with
the management of natural forests.
Wood, Fuelwood, and Non-wood Forest Products
Australia, Finland, and Sweden) are feeling the pressure of depressed prices for a range of forest products.
There are strong pressures toward short rotation, fast growing,
lower-valued forest plantation products, which provide fiber for
breakdown and reconstitution into a wide range of products in
the form required by the consumer. Productivity can be sustained
through reduced impact harvesting and practices that reduce soil
erosion, conserve water, and maintain soil fertility through subsequent rotations. Appropriate management techniques for planted
forests can also help conserve or even enhance biological diversity.
Protection from fires, insects, and disease is critical (FAO 2001b
and 2001c; Evans and Turnbull 2004).
There have been serious concerns regarding large-scale
monocultures. There is increasing recognition that semi-natural
and mixed-species, mixed-age plantings can provide a larger
range of products, provide ‘‘insurance’’ against unfavorable market conditions, reduce the effects and economic consequences of
insect and disease attacks, harbor greater diversity of flora and
fauna, contain the spread of wildfires, and provide greater variety
and aesthetic value in the landscape (Evans 1999; CIFOR 2003).
8.6.2.3 Policy Challenges
In areas where land degradation has occurred, afforestation can
play an important role in delivering economic, environmental,
and social benefits to communities. In these instances, forests and
trees must be planted in ways that will support livelihoods, agriculture, landscape restoration, and local development aspirations
(Anon 2003).
Caution is widely urged on the complex issues of bio-security
(particularly relating to invasive insects, diseases, and forest plant
species and the adoption of sound phyto-sanitary procedures) and
the application of biotechnology (genetic modification, cloned
germplasm, hybrid stock). Both these issues have potential positive and negative impacts on forest plantation health, vitality, productivity, and sustainability. In unregulated situations, there is
increasing evidence of insufficiently proven germplasm (insufficient laboratory, field and demonstration trials) being used and
incidences of bio-prospecting, which increase the potential for
genetic pollution.
8.6.3 Fuelwood Management
Woodfuel remains one of the larger outputs of the forest sector,
in some situations the largest. However, consumption of fuelwood has recently been shown to be growing less rapidly than
had been estimated earlier. Increasing urbanization and rising incomes are reflected in a slowing down in the rate of increase in
use of fuelwood as users switch to more efficient and convenient
sources of energy. In some regions, including much of developing
Asia, total consumption is now declining. In others, it appears to
be approaching a peak (FAO in press). Charcoal use, on the other
hand, is still growing, forming a much larger proportion of the
woodfuels total in Africa and South America (and some countries
in Asia). Charcoal is the main transition fuel to which fuelwood
users shift as they move up the ‘‘energy ladder,’’ and it is often a
major urban fuel. It is also an important industrial fuel in some
situations.
8.6.3.1 Impacts on Ecosystems
Supplies of fuelwood and wood for charcoal are drawn from a
much wider base than just forests. Information from 13 countries
in Asia showed that, in five countries, more than 75% of fuelwood came from outside forests (RWEDP 1997). Much fuelwood production for sale is a by-product of land clearance for
281
agriculture. Significant pressures on forest and woodland from
woodfuel harvesting are mainly associated with areas supplying
urban demand for charcoal (SEI 2002; Ninnin 1994). In dryland
forests in parts of Africa, production of charcoal as the main wood
output can materially alter the structure and productivity of the
forests.
Overall, demand for fuel is seldom likely to deplete or remove
forest cover on a large scale. There is not a ‘‘fuelwood crisis’’ of
magnitude, and with such potentially dire consequences in terms
of forest depletion, as to require major interventions to maintain
or augment supplies (Dewees 1989). Areas of concern are generally limited to situations where there is concentrated and growing
urban demand for charcoal.
8.6.3.2 Impacts on Users
Use of wood as a fuel may be less of a concern to the security of
the forest estate than has in the past been feared, but it constitutes
a large part of the contribution that forestry can make to livelihood security and poverty alleviation. Most use is still of a rural
subsistence nature. Gathered supplies of fuelwood still constitute
rural households’ main source of domestic energy.
The poorest tend to be disadvantaged by shifts to bring remaining common pool resources under sustainable management.
Fuelwood harvesting tends to be restricted in this process, and
women’s needs for fuelwood commonly have lower priority than
those of men for forest products for sale. Women practice a range
of measures to respond to reduced access to fuelwood supplies,
and seldom list this high among their concerns, but it is still likely
to involve a cost to them, if only in terms of increasing collection
time or having to shift to less favored fuels.
8.6.3.3 Fuelwood Opportunities and Response Options
Though wood is the principal source of energy for cooking and
heating for so many of the poor, it is the least efficient. Unless
they have access to technology to convert wood and charcoal into
modern forms of energy, real costs of energy from woodfuels can
be high even for the poor. In contrast, industrial scale dendro
power is gaining in interest in some parts of the world. (See Box
8.6.)
Considerable efforts have been devoted to encouraging adoption of improved wood-burning stoves. These have had some
impact in urban areas of some countries, but little success in rural
areas. Assessments indicate that lack of success was often due to
failure to understand that users valued stoves for reasons other
than fuel economy and that ‘‘improved’’ stove designs had not
addressed these needs, or due to the constraints posed by the cost
of purchasing stoves. Some evidence suggests that where stoves
are seen as saving money (in towns) they are popular, but where
they are merely saving time or biomass (in rural areas) men are
not prepared to spend money purchasing them.
Recent attention to improved stoves has shifted from increasing efficiency of woodfuel use to reducing damage to health from
airborne particulates and noxious fumes associated with the burning of wood and charcoal (IEA 2002).
The effective transfer and enforcement of local rights are important considerations. Issues that often remain to be resolved include the continuing role of forest departments, community
leaderships with interests at variance with those of their members,
and difficulties in devising and putting in place control and management mechanisms with transaction costs less than the value of
the woodfuel.
The potential and constraints of woodfuel selling as a source of
income for the poor are poorly recognized in forestry or poverty
282
Ecosystems and Human Well-being: Policy Responses
BOX 8.6
Dendro Power
Dendro power involves the use of wood-based materials for power generation (RWEDP 2000). One useful feature of dendro power is its potential
to use sustainably grown fuelwood . Interest in dendro power is gathering
momentum due to its multiple benefits of renewable power, reforestation,
and income generation (especially in rural areas). On a global scale, it
has potential to reduce air pollution, and increase carbon sinks. It is considered to be an environmentally benign power source, with zero carbon
emissions if properly managed. Dendro power is used on a limited scale in
countries such as Sweden, Finland, Netherlands, United Kingdom, Brazil,
United States, as well as in many Asian countries, including Thailand,
China, India, Malaysia, Indonesia, and the Philippines.
At present, most of the biomass-fuelled electricity generation is through
steam turbines with net efficiencies of about 20–25%. In thermo-chemical
processes, the biomass product is heated to break it down into gases,
liquids, and solids. These are considered to be higher value and more
reduction initiatives. Market demand for woodfuels can provide
an important source of income for the poor. But reliance on it
can also impede progress out of poverty, especially with large and
rapid structural changes in urban market demand for woodfuels.
There is a need for better understanding of such changes, and
how best to support producers.
There has been a general failure of control measures to put
commercial woodfuel production on a more sustainable basis. Initiatives to raise prices closer to replacement values, and to capture
some of this in ways that would contribute to meeting the costs
of management and regeneration, have not had much success.
Transaction costs of trying to control collection from natural forests, and to differentiate in the marketplace between fuelwood
from natural and planted sources, are often too high compared to
the value of the wood being traded. This might be overcome by
implementing such controls more effectively. However, this
would raise costs for producers and lead to higher prices for urban
users, resulting in considerable hardship for the latter, and aggravating problems of underinvestment and poor productivity by the
former (SEI 2002).
8.6.3.4 Policy Challenges
The need to incorporate woodfuels more fully into the forestry
mainstream has not been adequately addressed, despite the growing focus on giving forestry a stronger livelihood orientation. At
the policy level, more effective recognition of the needs of the
landless and very poor is needed in the process of making decisions about changes in land tenure and use. These considerations
can also reinforce the case for conversion of open access use into
common property rights. While privatization can create a more
favorable environment for those with rights to land to invest in
woody production, it can severely disadvantage those without
land, unless their needs are recognized and taken into account.
Significant constraints are too often imposed on those who
can participate in production, and can create distortions to trade
and markets: competition from subsidized woodfuel supplies from
government forests; taxes and other charges to generate government revenue from fuelwood trade; restrictions imposed in the
name of conservation and prevention of ‘‘excessive’’ forest harvesting; and other regulations governing private sale of and trading in woodfuels. Such interventions are often unnecessary,
counterproductive, or poorly designed and implemented, and
need to be critically examined.
convenient products. Further processing produces gases and liquid fuels like
methane and alcohol. Methane can be used in gasification processes to
produce electricity and liquids that are used as transportation fuels. Gasification technologies have the potential for higher conversion efficiencies of up
to 45%. Integration gasification combined cycles are the latest development
that combines gas and steam turbines to produce even higher efficiencies.
The success of dendro power generation depends on its ability to
supply adequate fuel at low costs on a regular basis without over-exploiting
the source. The generation of power requires a huge quantity of wood. A
project in the range of 20–40 megawatt requires some 12,000 hectares
of fuelwood plantation, or a $50–100 million investment (Hulcher 1995, as
quoted in Bhattacharya 2001). Fuel sources can be grown on degraded
land, thereby utilizing land not suitable for other activities. The energy
source can be grown and managed as dedicated plantations, or as agroforestry systems or in woodlots (Fernando 2003).
8.6.4 Carbon Management
Though there is not yet agreement on the modalities for implementing carbon forestry projects under the Kyoto Protocol, a
wealth of experience has been developed as a result of more than
a decade of pilot programs. Although many of the early initiatives
were based on forest conservation or management, afforestation
activities now predominate, perhaps reflecting the international
decisions to allow only afforestation and reforestation activities
into the CDM for the first commitment period. Afforestation and
deforestation activities are attractive from a development point of
view, and their carbon benefits are real, measurable, and marketable. Countries are increasingly recognizing the importance of
forest cover for their water and soil management and for reduced
vulnerability to extreme climatic events.
There are a number of issues that remain undecided in relation
to the implementation of carbon forestry activities. These can be
broadly grouped into technical, policy, and market uncertainties.
• Technical uncertainties. Issues relating to the validity of land use
activities as a carbon sink and the quantification of net greenhouse gas benefits remain controversial among the scientific
and policy making community.
• Policy uncertainties. The lack of agreement, at the international
level, on the eligibility of forestry activities in mitigating climate change has to date been a major factor in restraining the
extent of project development on the ground.
• Market uncertainties. The market for purchasing forestry based
carbon offsets or investing in projects has reflected the ongoing technical and policy uncertainties and controversies of
the land use sector. In particular, the withdrawal of the United
States from the Kyoto Protocol process has reduced the market for forestry-based Joint Implementation and CDM projects substantially.
The likely impact of JI and CDM is largely dependent on the
specific rules still being developed and the response of the carbon
market to increased supply of forestry-based carbon offsets. Despite the early stages of implementation of climate change initiatives, experience to date has identified some important lessons
that could inform the future debate on these issues. (See Table
8.3.)
8.6.5 Fire Management
There is a major effort underway to re-introduce fire as an effective ecosystem process in those forest areas where the lack of fire
Wood, Fuelwood, and Non-wood Forest Products
Table 8.3. Lessons Learned from Forest-based Carbon
Sequestration Projects
Experiences and Lessons
Possible Action and Future
Opportunities
Fragmentation: the carbon benefits
of land-based activities tend to be
dealt with in isolation, rather than
with other benefits or objectives
Integration: the integration of carbon benefits with other objectives,
services, products, and benefits at
the landscape level is essential.
Costs: the project development
cycle has high transaction costs that
act as a barrier to many projects,
specifically small or development
oriented projects
Cost reduction: approaches are
needed to reduce the costs of project development to individual initiatives (e.g., provision of seed capital,
simplified procedures for technical
analyses, bundling, etc.)
Scale: small projects often result in
multiple local benefits but are often
not feasible due to high costs and
limited carbon products
Bundling: the gathering together of
small-scale projects under an umbrella scheme will result in the economy of scale, ensure local benefits
are secured, and add robustness to
smaller projects.
Limited funding: the income generated through the sale of carbon offsets is rarely enough to fund the
development and implementation of
projects
Innovative financing: measures
that attract additional financing are
needed, for example, through integration with other objectives and
conventions or higher pricing for additional benefits.
has contributed to forest health problems and the increasing occurrence of uncharacteristically severe wildfires (USDA Forest
Service 2000). The objectives have been severalfold: protect
human life and property in fire-adapted ecosystems, reduce ecological damage to forests, avoid excessive suppression costs, restore ecosystem integrity and health, protect wildlife habitats and
biodiversity, and lower air pollution problems (Mutch et al. 1993;
Neuenschwander and Sampson 2000; USDA Forest Service
2000). Significant technical and political obstacles must be addressed if the effort is to be successful. The technical obstacles
generally revolve around the current fuel conditions in these forests, or the existence of large, uniform areas of unhealthy or mature stands. These require careful management interventions that
either reduce fuels to levels that allow fire to burn in historically
characteristic ways or break up large areas of uniform conditions
so that landscape patchiness is restored (Covington and Moore
1994; Mutch et al. 1993; USDA Forest Service 2000).
While most of the techniques have been well tested at research plot levels, there is limited experience at the large landscape
levels needing treatment in areas like the western United States,
northern Canada, or Russia. These problems are made more
complex in those areas where significant human populations exist.
Even with fuel reductions and carefully prescribed burning to
restore fire to its ecologically required levels, the amount of air
pollution created may exceed what people will tolerate (Neuenschwander and Sampson 2000). Political opposition to the inevitable risks of using fire as a forest management tool, the
considerable costs involved in effectively managing an active fire
program, and the pollution and human health impact that will be
intentionally generated are significant and will require carefully
crafted strategic approaches that generate widespread public support if they are to be overcome (USDA Forest Service 2000).
283
8.7 Summary Lessons
Civil society and private sector players are becoming as important as
government in developing responses; furthermore, their involvement helps ensure that policy outcomes are more durable. Urban
and market players are increasingly significant. This reflects growing public concern to secure a range of ecosystem services from
forests and other wood-producing ecosystems. Innovative responses, such as many forms of partnership to create balanced land
use for wood and other benefits, and certification to assure such a
balance, are offering new forms of ‘‘soft policy’’ that influence
government strongly.
Consequently, multistakeholder policy processes, from local to international levels, are becoming significant in developing, debating, and reviewing response options. They are important in
deciding on the balance between the public and private benefits
to be obtained from wood-producing ecosystems. However, they
are still often poor at identifying and involving marginal groups,
for which brokers can be helpful. Many are also one-off, rather
than installing continuous improvement systems that keep up
with the dynamics of wood supply and demand and deal with
change.
Ultimately, public perceptions and beliefs are key. For example,
progress needs to be made in improving public understanding of
the wide land use spectrum that potentially provides wood, and
therefore of the legitimacy of plantations as wood-producing ecosystems, potentially freeing up other land for other ecosystem
benefits.
There has been a strong trend toward privatization or decentralization of control over forests, forest management services, and
enterprise. This, together with other forms of liberalization and
structural adjustment, has helped to remove perversities that acted
against sustainable wood supply. It has helped to create a wider
range of ‘‘willing stewards’’ of forests and wood-producing lands
but has not always conferred adequate rights and powers on them
to enable them to exercise stewardship.
Market-based responses are redistributing rights to stakeholders,
making them more effective in securing both wood supplies and
other ecosystem services. Market approaches to allocating use
rights to public lands, and voluntary certification, are helping to
change the structure of wood industries. However, it is usually
existing ‘‘good practice’’ companies that are benefiting. Step-wise
incentives are needed to encourage the bulk of wood producers
to gradually develop existing capacity from a low base, to cover
transaction costs, and hence to improve forest management practice. Other responses are needed to ‘‘close doors’’ to bad practice;
these are unlikely to be market-based, but will need legal action
and enforcement.
To shift wood production toward sustainability is a challenge
that goes beyond selecting individual ‘‘responses’’ toward restructuring governance of the sector. Progress is made by coherent sets
of interacting responses that suit a particular case, country, wood
market, or governance structure. A coherent, effective ‘‘set’’ of
response options might differ depending on the prevailing context. (See Table 8.4.) Developing an effective set of responses is,
therefore, largely a governance and institutional development question.
Urgent requirements for institutional strengthening tend to be at
the local level, for it is only through local institutions that sustainable forest management can be precisely defined and pursued, and
decisions made on the balance with other activities. A clear institutional separation of forest regulation, management, enterprise,
and revenue collection tends to be needed among government
authorities for environmental services such as carbon storage as
well as for wood.
284
Ecosystems and Human Well-being: Policy Responses
Table 8.4. How Responses Can Differ in Various Contexts
(Mayers et al. 2002)
Prevailing Governance
Command and control
Potentially Effective Response
Options: Key Entry Points for
Governance Change
role, powers, and accountability of
authorities
legislation development
extension and enforcement
Privatization to corporate or civil
society interests
deregulation
standards and certification
market reforms, royalties, and rents
ombudsmen
monitoring
Nationalization of enterprises and
services
major institutional and legal changes
user rights
compensation mechanisms
Devolution of power to local
authorities and/or civil society
groups
empowerment
costs/transition problems of
divestment
capacity development
Other approaches to
decentralization
empowerment
rights assurance
capacity development
negotiation
Cross-sectoral consensus and
partnerships
participation/representation
mechanisms and resources
availability of information
capacities of civil society groups
Better information is also needed both about the dynamics of
wood supply and demand, and about the costs and benefits of the
different response options and their distributional effects. Some of
the more recent responses appear to have caused significant
changes, but there have been relatively few independent assessments of what they have achieved. Furthermore, there is inadequate information about how forests and other wood-producing
ecosystems behave under multi-purpose production regimes, especially in terms of the best possible balance between wood and
other benefits. Casting responses in stone will rarely, therefore, be
a good idea. Whatever its form, sustainable forest management
will be information-intensive and all response options may need
to invest more in integral information and review functions. Table
8.5 summarizes the assessment of response options.
Table 8.5.
Summary Assessment of Responses: Wood, Fuelwood, and Non-wood Forest Products
Degree of Uptake
Constraints
Links and Tradeoffs
Quality of Evidence
Assessment of
Effectiveness
Key Policy
Challenges
Title of activity
Key contextual factors
required before
response can be
effected
Indication of spread
and degree of
adoption of
response
Key obstacles
preventing up-take
Relationship with
other responses
Strength and credibility
of information on the
response and its
impacts
Impact of response in
improving ecosystem
health and human
well-being
Governance
actions required to
support response
International forest policy
processes and development assistance
High level of public concern. Willingness of
stakeholders to engage,
particularly governments. Moderate national political
commitment.
Thirteen years of
inter-governmental
policy dialogue. Several major NGO-led
and private sector-led
initiatives. Forestryspecific development
assistance declining.
Excessively dominated by governments. Engagement
with extra-sectoral
frameworks still
weak. No consensus on a legally
binding international
instrument in forestry.
Strong links with
national forest governance initiatives/
programs and certification; moderate
with natural forest
and plantation
management;
rather weak with
trade liberalization
and others.
Strong, in international
convention and U.N.
Forum on Forests secretariats and among monitoring and ‘‘watchdog’’
NGOs.
Weak direct impact.
Moderate effect in setting overarching framework and catalyzing
other response actions.
Moderate effect in establishing common language on sustainable
forest management.
Integration of agreed
forest management
principles and practices in financial
institutions, trade
rules, global environment programs, and
global security decision-making. Implementation at regional
to national levels.
Trade liberalization
Few factors required—
since trade liberalization
is pushed by most international agencies.
Widespread adoption
of liberalization prescriptions. When
non-tariff measures
and effect of subsidies are taken into account, the net trend
internationally is
probably toward increased protection
rather than liberalization.
Agricultural trade
policies and regional development
policies have
greater impacts
than forest trade
policies.
Weak links to international forest policy dialogue.
Moderate links and
some trade-offs
with national forest
governance initiatives, natural forest management,
and plantation
management.
Weak. Trade flows information is strong—but impacts information is
weak. Beginning to improve in international
agencies and NGOs.
Impact contingent on
governance. Magnifies
the effect of governance—making already
good forest governance
better, making bad forest governance worse.
Tends to concentrate
control over forest management. More positive
impacts when linked to
improved, impartially
administered property
rights.
Improve engagement of ‘‘underpowered’’ groups in trade
policy decision-making. Ensure institutional strengthening
occurs before trade
liberalization. Require cost internalization as well as
liberalization, and
consider the case for
protection to achieve
the social component of sustainability.
National forest governance
initiatives and national forest programs
High level political commitment and stakeholder
willingness to engage required.
Major forestry process, acknowledged
by many countries; at
best, main overarching response into
which others fit; at
worst, irrelevant to
more focused responses.
Lack of political engagement of forest
planners; weak institutional, human,
and financial capacity; weak stakeholder negotiation
processes.
Strong to international policy processes; weak to
local-level implementation.
Strong, on the formal national steps taken (FAO
database); weak on local
assessment of impact.
Moderate in many contexts and promising to
be strong in some, but
as yet uncertain. Previous related planning
processes have had
limited impact.
Foster genuine
stakeholder negotiation and buy-in;
keeping objectives
strategic, politically
high-profile and focused; implementing
agreed actions. Ensure NFPs drive
progress to good forest governance.
(continues)
285
Pre-conditions
Wood, Fuelwood, and Non-wood Forest Products
Response
286
Table 8.5.
Continued
Pre-conditions
Degree of Uptake
Constraints
Links and Tradeoffs
Quality of Evidence
Assessment of
Effectiveness
Key Policy
Challenges
Title of activity
Key contextual factors
required before
response can be
effected
Indication of spread
and degree of
adoption of
response
Key obstacles
preventing up-take
Relationship with
other responses
Strength and credibility
of information on the
response and its
impacts
Impact of response in
improving ecosystem
health and human
well-being
Governance
actions required to
support response
Direct management of forests by indigenous peoples
State exerting no control
over territory, or state
concedes significant
sovereignty to native polities.
Limited to date; prevails in a few ‘‘failed
states’’ and in North
America Australia,
and New Zealand.
Poor recognition of
indigenous peoples
by states. Weak uptake of methodologies that can
improve management in indigenous
areas.
Weak links to many
other responses.
Strong links to specific international
conventions.
Weak on impacts—
heavily dependent on
coarse-filter, secondary
data. Strong information
on indigenous peoples in
forest areas.
Uncertain since information is weak (recognition of indigenous
land claims does not
often lead to direct forest management by indigenous peoples).
Initial evidence suggests that is as effective as strict-use
protected area.
Culturally and technically sound cooperation between
indigenous and nonindigenous organizations for natural
resource management.
Collaborative forest management and local movements for access and use
of forest products
Effective local institutions (for collaborative
forest management) and
concerted government
devolution and support
for devolved arrangements.
Widespread around
the globe although
not an abundant response.
Internal conflict and
lack of leadership in
many communities.
Over-bureaucratic
government—or reluctance to cede
sufficient control.
Strong links to national governance
initiatives and moderate links to natural forest
management in the
tropics and commercialization of
non-wood forest
products.
Strong—many rigorous
case studies and situation analyses.
Strong on improved resource management
and access to forest resources for participating groups, but much
more uncertain in impact on poverty and
human well-being.
Develop the institutional arrangements
and capacities for
people in forest
areas to have the
rights and power to
bring about a fair division of control, responsibility, and
benefits between
government and
themselves.
Small-scale private and
public-private ownership
and management of forests
Private long-term tenure
and transfer rights over
forest and plantation
areas.
Country specific, dependent on tenurial
system—small-scale
private ownership
prevalent in Europe
and North America,
and increasing in
Latin America and
Asia. Public-private
ownership and conservation concessions limited in area
and maturity.
Economic viability of
small forest areas—
opportunity cost of
other land uses
often too great.
Public-private arrangements constrained by few
private investors.
Conservation concessions untested
as yet.
Strong links to national forest governance initiatives
and plantation
management.
Conservation concessions link or
trade-off with natural forest management in the tropics.
Strong in Europe and
North America. Experimental response only for
conservation concessions.
Strong for small-scale
private management
where tenure is secure,
information is well focused, and economies
of scale are achieved
through association of
owners.
Support for security
of tenure, effective
market and technological information,
and development of
management capability.
Ecosystems and Human Well-being: Policy Responses
Response
Companies requiring secure forest asset base
but restricted in own abilities to control it. Degree
of organization of smallholders or communities.
Evident in several
countries in each of:
North America, South
America, Europe, Africa, Asia and the Pacific. Increasing
emphasis in some
countries (e.g.,
China); shifts from
tight partner contracts to looser arrangements in others
(e.g., India).
Lack of policy or
public pressure for
companies to engage. Mistrust of
companies by potential local partners. Weak third
party ‘‘brokering’’
agencies.
Strong links to
plantation management. Moderate
links to national
governance initiatives, public and
consumer action
and natural forest
management in the
tropics.
Moderate. Information
base on the response
only recently developing
through case study and
global review work.
Moderate. Where preconditions are met, better than solely
corporate or smallscale farm forestry. Impacts often indirect
(e.g., companies improving long-term survival and communities
better securing tenure
through partnerships).
Development of governance frameworks
that require accountability of partnerships; support for the
bargaining power of
community-level associations; enabling
the emergence of
third-party support
agencies.
Public and consumer
action
Effective use of analysis
of problems in generating appropriate messages for the public and
consumers.
Widespread in the
north, growing in the
south.
Relies on strength
of NGOs to mobilize
public and consumers. Periodicity of interest from public
and media, and
from governments
and corporations in
responding.
Strong links as
stimulus to national
forest governance
initiatives and forest certification.
Moderate links to
international forest
policy processes,
natural forest management in the
tropics, and commercialization of
non-wood forest
products.
Moderate–extensive
media reports on the effectiveness of campaigns, rather weaker
cause-effect evidence.
Strong but specific impact, and sometimes
perverse: has caused
the emergence of certification, some trade initiatives, and
improvements in practices of some companies; has stimulated
some policies that undermine local tenure
security and benefits to
poor communities from
forests.
Enable public mobilization strengths of
NGOs. Government
action to sustain information flows and
enable improvements in practices
that public actions
highlight.
Third-party voluntary forest certification
Market signals demanding improved and verified forestry practice.
Rapid spread since
1993. Occurs in all
continents but most
certified forests are in
the North, managed
by larger companies
and exporting to
Northern retailers.
Little incentive to
adopt in contexts of
tropical deforestation. Proliferation
of certification programs, diluting credibility. Threat that
competitiveness of
small and mediumsized enterprises reduced where certification only used by
larger companies.
Strong links to public and consumer
action and plantation management.
Moderate links to
international forest
policy processes
and national governance initiatives.
Weak links to natural forest management in the tropics.
Moderate. Certification
has a short history; experience to date is muchanalyzed, but few independent assessments.
Moderate. Has improved already good
practice rather than
tackling bad practice
and has done so for
larger rather than
smaller operations. Key
knock-on benefits in improving forest policy
debates and provisions.
Development of
step-wise
approaches to certification, and approaches more
appropriate for
smaller and community operations. Integrate landscapewide priorities better.
Explore mutual recognition of schemes
and support more
education of consumers about sustainable forestry.
287
(continues)
Wood, Fuelwood, and Non-wood Forest Products
Company–community forestry partnerships
288
Continued
Response
Pre-conditions
Degree of Uptake
Constraints
Links and Tradeoffs
Quality of Evidence
Assessment of
Effectiveness
Key Policy
Challenges
Title of activity
Key contextual factors
required before
response can be
effected
Indication of spread
and degree of
adoption of
response
Key obstacles
preventing up-take
Relationship with
other responses
Strength and credibility
of information on the
response and its
impacts
Impact of response in
improving ecosystem
health and human
well-being
Governance
actions required to
support response
Wood technology
Changing market demand. Research and development.
Technology developments have stimulated a wide range of
new plantations and
processing methods—the trend being
toward locations in
the tropics.
Dependent on high
levels of capital outlay for research and
development, and
hence not available
to smaller enterprises.
Strong link to plantation management
and dendro power
(see fuelwood
management).
Moderate link to
national forest governance initiatives
and carbon management.
Strong information on
utility of technology in
production, weaker on
impacts of this on ecosystems and human wellbeing.
Moderate. Technology
development leads to
changes in locations of
production (trend to
fiber production in the
tropics) and structure of
the wood industry with
winners and losers in
terms of jobs and environments.
Enable private sector investment in
technology that internalizes environmental and social
costs and is accessible to a greater
range of scales of
enterprise.
Commercialization of nonwood forest products
High demand for NWFPs
over time leads to overexploitation of the naturally regenerating
resource base first, and
then specialized production if market access, secure tenure over the
resource base, sufficient
labor and capital to invest, and entrepreneurial
skills are available.
Significant growth in
some NWFP markets
with extension of
market system to
more remote areas;
growing interest in
natural products such
as herbal medicines,
wild foods, handcrafted utensils, and
decorative items; and
development projects
focused on production, processing, and
trade of NWFPs.
Few NWFPs have
large and reliable
markets, and those
tend to be supplied
by specialized producers using more
intensive production
systems. Many
other NWFPs are
vital to the livelihoods of the poor
but have little scope
for commercialization.
Strong links to national forest governance initiatives
and collaborative
forest management. Moderate on
impacts of commercialization,
weak on basic biophysical research
for many valuable
NWFPs, thus constraining efforts to
improve management.
Moderate. Impacts for
livelihoods through combinations of technical and
capacity-building interventions to improve raw
material production, processing, trade, and marketing, and through
development of cooperatives and improved policy
and institutional frameworks. Problems with
stronger groups gaining
control at the expense of
weaker groups and overexploitation of resources.
Increased value does not
automatically translate
into effective incentives
for conservation.
Improved understanding of the role of natural
resources in rural livelihoods in poverty reduction strategies and
related frameworks.
Policy that more effectively gives incentives
for sustainable management of NWFPs, including exploration of
joint production of timber and non-wood forest products.
Ecosystems and Human Well-being: Policy Responses
Table 8.5.
Needs to be focused on
a range of forest goods
and services, not just
timber, to be economic.
Large investments
since the early 1990s
to promote improved
management of natural forests, and an increasing area now
under some form of
management.
Low timber yields,
complexity of system, high labor inputs. Uncertain
financial viability of
reduced impact logging.
Strong links to national governance
initiatives and collaborative forest
management.
Moderate links to
public and consumer action, company–community
partnerships, and
commercialization
of NWFPs. Moderate trade-offs with
plantation management.
Moderate to weak. Information often not readily
available. Information
being acquired on reduced impact logging
Moderate. Natural forest management implemented by some of the
best transnational corporations and by some
local enterprises has
been successful in
maintaining ecosystem
health when it has also
provided direct benefits
to local communities.
Poor management
characterizes many of
the operations in the
spectrum between
these two scales of enterprise.
Identification of longterm funding
sources. Support for
diverse, locally tailored solutions to securing both wood
supplies and forest
environmental services—giving greater
weight to locally determined approaches that
provide solutions to
the trade-offs associated with the management of natural
forests.
Tree plantation management
Surplus or marginal agricultural and degraded
lands. Supportive policy
and investment frameworks
Widespread—some
187 million hectares
in 2000, constituting
5% of global forest
cover but supplying
about 35% of global
roundwood.
Conversion of natural forest. Undermining customary
ownership. Without
good planning and
management, forest
plantations may be
grown in the wrong
sites, with the wrong
species or provenances, by the
wrong growers, for
the wrong reasons.
Strong links to
company–
community partnerships, carbon
management wood
technology. Moderate links with trade
liberalization and
national governance initiatives.
Strong data on areas,
species, and long-term
trends. Weaker on social
impacts.
Strong impacts as response to growing
wood demand and as
available natural forest
areas decline through
deforestation, designation for protection
and economic inaccessibility. Most positive
impacts where developed on degraded sites
where rural investment
most needed. Moderate
increasing local returns
from smallholder plantation management.
Development of policy and incentive
structure to ensure
environmental and
social costs are internalized; development responds to
both growing consumption and declining harvest from
natural forest; and
bio-safety is secured.
(continues)
Wood, Fuelwood, and Non-wood Forest Products
Natural forest management
in the tropics
289
290
Table 8.5.
Continued
Pre-conditions
Degree of Uptake
Constraints
Links and Tradeoffs
Quality of Evidence
Assessment of
Effectiveness
Key Policy
Challenges
Title of activity
Key contextual factors
required before
response can be
effected
Indication of spread
and degree of
adoption of
response
Key obstacles
preventing up-take
Relationship with
other responses
Strength and credibility
of information on the
response and its
impacts
Impact of response in
improving ecosystem
health and human
well-being
Governance
actions required to
support response
Fuelwood management
Market incentive and
supportive policy.
Fuelwood is one of
the larger outputs of
the forest sector. Its
consumption appears
to have reached a
global peak. It is
rising in Africa and
declining in
developing Asia.
Charcoal use
continues to rise.
Attempts to manage
fuelwood are as
widespread as its
use. Power from
wood-based
materials (dendro
power)
spreading—still on a
pilot scale.
Often faces
competition from
subsidized woodfuel
supplies from
government; taxes
to generate
government
revenue from
fuelwood trade;
restrictions imposed
in the name of
conservation; and
regulations
governing private
sale of and trading
in woodfuels.
Improved woodfuel
stoves not valued
for fuel economy by
rural people.
Dendro power
requires huge
quantities of wood.
Strong links to
national forest
governance
initiatives and
commercialization
of NWFPs.
Moderate links to
collaborative forest
management.
Dendro power in
the North strongly
linked to plantation
management.
Moderate. Information on
impacts of attempts to
manage fuelwood
recently greatly
improved. Strong
information on dendro
power—but unproven
impact to date.
Weak: a general failure
of control measures;
initiatives to raise
prices closer to
replacement values
unsuccessful;
transaction costs of
trying to differentiate in
the marketplace
between fuelwood from
natural and planted
sources are too high;
uncertainty as to the
extent and nature of the
impacts of improved
stoves. Dendro power
likely to spread, mostly
in the North.
Support studies that
help map the location,
nature, and causes of
woodfuel problems,
and interactions
between woodfuel
use, energy policies,
and forestry and
livelihood
interventions.
Development of
policies that enable
users to evolve new
‘‘tenurial niches’’ that
give them some
access to woodfuel
resources in the new
landscapes; remove
distortions introduced
by regulations on
trade and markets;
and balance dendro
power with other
energy sources.
Carbon management
Afforestation and reforestation activities allowed into the Clean
Development Mechanism under the Kyoto
Protocol for the first
commitment period.
Pilot activities only—
distribution of activities to date shows a
developing country
bias, with a particular
focus in Central and
South America.
Major uncertainties:
technical (validity of
land use activities
as a carbon sink
and the quantification of net greenhouse gas reduction
benefits); policy (eligibility of forestry
activities in mitigating climate change);
and market (reflecting the ongoing
technical and policy
uncertainties).
Strong link to international policy
processes and
plantation forest
management.
Moderate. Information
base being rapidly developed.
Weak to date. The
likely impact of Joint
Implementation and the
CDM is largely dependent on rules still being
developed and response of carbon market to increased supply
of forestry based carbon offsets. Project development has high
transaction costs that
act as a barrier to many
projects, specifically
small or development
oriented projects.
Promote policy processes that install
livelihood priorities
as well as environmental safeguards in
carbon
management; integrate carbon benefits with other
objectives at the
landscape level; and
foster collective approaches for smallscale projects to
achieve viable scale.
Ecosystems and Human Well-being: Policy Responses
Response
Wood, Fuelwood, and Non-wood Forest Products
References
Amazon Financial Information Services, 2001–2002: Peru: Camisea gas
field and pipeline project, updates. Accessed 12 July 2004. Available at http://
www.redlisted.com/peru_camisea.html.
Anderson, K. and R. Blackhurst (eds.), 1992: The Greening of World Trade Issues,
University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor, MI.
Angelsen, A. and S. Wunder, 2003: Exploring the forest-poverty link: Key
concepts, issues and research implications, CIFOR occasional paper no. 40,
CIFOR, Bogor, Indonesia.
ANON, 2003: The Role of Planted Forests in Sustainable Forest Management, Report of the UNFF Intersessional Experts Meeting, 25–27 March, Wellington,
New Zealand.
Balad, J. and J. Platteau, 1996: Halting Degradation of Natural Resources: Is There
a Role for Rural Communities, Clareden Press, Oxford, UK.
Bass, S., K. Thornber, M. Markopoulos, S. Roberts, and M. Grieg-Gran, 2001:
Certification’s Impacts on Forests, Stakeholders and Supply Chains, IIED, London,
UK.
Bass, S.M.J., 2003: International commitments, implementation and cooperation, Proceedings of the XII World Forestry Congress, Quebec City, September 2003, FAO, Rome, Italy.
de Beer, J.H. and M. McDermott, 1989: The Economic Value of Non-timber Forest
Products in Southeast Asia with Emphasis on Indonesia, Malaysia and Thailand,
Manuscript by Netherlands Committee for the IUCN, Amsterdam, The
Netherlands.
Belcher, B.M., M. Ruiz-Perez, and R. Achdiawan, 2003: Global patterns and
trends in NTFP development, Paper presented to the international conference rural livelihoods, forests, and biodiversity, 19–23 May 2003, Bonn, Germany.
Belcher, B.M., 2003: What isn’t an NTFP? International Forestry Review, 5(2),
pp. 161– 168.
Bhattacharya, S., 2001: Commercialization options for biomass energy technologies in ESCAP countries, Background paper, Regional seminar on commercialization of biomass technology, 4–7 June 2001, Guangzhou, China.
Bird, N., 2002: National forest programmes, Key sheets for sustainable livelihoods no. 17, Overseas Development Institute, London, UK.
Bourke, I.J., 2003: Trade Restrictions and Trade Agreements Affecting International
Trade in Forest Products, Report for IIED, April, IIED, London, UK.
Britt, C., 1998: Community forestry comes of age: Forest-user networking and
federation-building experiences from Nepal, Paper presented at the 7th
Common Property Conference of the International Association for the Study
of Common Property, 10–14 June, Vancouver, BC, Canada.
Brown, C., P.D. Durst, and T. Enters, 2002: Forest Out of Bounds: Impacts and
Effectiveness of Logging Bans in Natural Forests in Asia-Pacific, RAP Publications,
October 2001, FAO, Bangkok, Thailand.
Brown, D., K. Schreckenberg, G. Shepherd, and A. Wells, 2002: Forestry as an
entry point for governance reform, ODI forestry briefing no. 1, Overseas
Development Institute, London, UK.
Brown, D. and A. Williams, 2003: The case for bushmeat as a component of
development policy: issues and challenges, International Forestry Review, 5(2),
pp. 148–155.
Bruenig, E.F., 1996: Conservation and Management of Tropical Rainforests: An Integrated Approach to Sustainability, CAB International, Wallingford, UK, 339 pp.
Cavendish, W., 1989: Rural livelihoods and non-timber forest products, Paper
presented at CIFOR workshop on the contribution of non-timber forest
products to socioeconomic development, October, Zimbabwe.
CIFOR (Center for International Forestry Research), 2003: Fast-Wood Forestry:
Myths and Realities, C. Cossalter and C Pye-Smith (eds.), CIFOR, Indonesia,
Earthscan, London, UK.
Colchester, M., M. Boscolo, A. Contreras-Hermosilla, F. Del Gatto, J. Kill, et
al., 2004: Justice In The Forest: Rural Livelihoods and Forest Law Enforcement,
CIFOR, Bogor, Indonesia.
Colchester, M., T. Apte, M. Laforge, A. Mandondo, and N. Pathak, 2003:
Bridging the gap: Communities, forests and international networks, CIFOR
occasional paper no. 41, CIFOR, Bogor, Indonesia.
Confederation of European Paper Industries, 2002: Comparative Matrix of
Forest Certification Schemes, CEPI, Brussels, Belgium.
Connelly, M.W., D. Cha, and S. McGovern, 2004: The Holy Grail, Credit
Suisse/First Boston Equity Research, Beijing, China.
Covington, W.W. and M.M. Moore, 1994: Postsettlement changes in natural
fire regimes and forest structure: Ecological restoration of old-growth ponderosa pine forests, Journal of Sustainable Forestry, 2(1–2), pp. 153–182.
Cromack, K., Jr., J.D. Landsberg, et al., 2000: Assessing the impacts of severe
fire on forest ecosystem recovery, Journal of Sustainable Forestry, 11(1–2), 177–
228.
291
Dawkins, H.C., 1957: The management of natural tropical high-forest with
special reference to Uganda, Institute paper no. 34, Imperial Forestry Institute, Oxford, UK, 155 pp.
Dawkins, H.C. and M.S. Philip, 1997: Tropical Moist Forest Silviculture and Management: A History of Success and Failure, CAB International, Wallingford, UK,
359 pp.
Dewees, P.A., 1989: The woodfuel crisis reconsidered: Observations on the
dynamics of abundance and scarcity, World Development, 17(7), pp. 1159–
1172.
Dove, M., 1993: A revisionist view of tropical deforestation and development,
Environmental Conservation, 20(1), pp. 17–24.
Dykstra, D., 2002: Reduced impact logging: Concepts and issues. In: Applying
Reduced Impact Logging to Advance Sustainable Forest Management, T. Enters,
P.D. Durst, G. Applegate, P.C.S. Kho, and G. Man (eds.), RAP Publications,
October 14, FAO, Bangkok, Thailand, pp. 9–17.
Dykstra, D., 2003: RILSIM User’s Guide: Software for Financial Analysis of
Reduced-impact Logging Systems, Blue Ox Forestry, Portland, OR.
Eba’a, A.R. and M. Simula, 2002: Forest Certification: Pending Challenges for Tropical Timber, ITTO technical series no. 19, ITTO, Yokohama, Japan.
Edmunds, D. and E. Wollenberg (eds.), 2003: Local Forest Management: The
Impacts of Devolution Policies, Earthscan Publications, London, UK.
Elliott, C., 2000: Forest Certification: A Policy Perspective, CIFOR, Bogor, Indonesia.
Evans, J., 1999: Sustainability of Forest Plantations: The Evidence, Issues paper,
Department for International Development, London, UK.
Evans, J. and J. Turnbull, 2004: Plantation Forestry in the Tropics: The Role, Silviculture and Use of Planted Forests for Industrial, Social and Environmental, and
Agroforestry Purposes, Oxford University Press, Oxford, UK.
Falconer, J., 1990: The major significance of minor forest products: Examples
from West Africa, Appropriate Technology, 17(3), pp. 13–16.
FAO (Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations), 1971: Forest
Resources Assessment Project 1970, FAO, Rome, Italy.
FAO, 1995: Forest Resources Assessment 1990: Tropical Forest Plantation Resources,
FAO, Rome Italy.
FAO, 1996: Formulation, Execution and Revision of National Forest Programmes:
Basic Principles and Operational Guidelines, FAO, Rome, Italy.
FAO, 2000: The Global Outlook for Future Wood Supply from Forest Plantations,
Working paper GFPOS/WP/03, Prepared for the 1999 Global Forest Products Outlook Study, FAO, Rome, Italy.
FAO, 2001a: Global forest resources assessment 2000: Main report, Forestry
paper 140, FAO Rome, Italy.
FAO, J. Evans, 2001b: Biological sustainability of productivity in successive rotations, Forest plantations thematic working paper, D.J. Mead (ed.), FAO,
Rome, Italy.
FAO, T. Waggener, 2001c: Role of forest plantations as substitutes for natural
forests in wood supply: Lessons learned from the Asia-Pacific region, Forest
plantations thematic paper series, Rome, Italy.
FAO, 2004: National forest programmes. Available at http://www.fao.org/for
estry/foris.
FAO, Past trends and future prospects for the utilization of wood for energy,
Working paper no. GFPOS/WP/05, Global Forest Products Outlook Study,
FAO, Rome. In press.
Fernando, K., 2003: An Analysis of Sri Lanka’s Power Crisis, Citizens Trust, Sri
Lanka.
Fisher, R., 1999: Devolution and decentralization of forest management in Asia
and the Pacific, Unasylva, 50(4), pp. 3–5.
Gibson, C.C., A. M. McKean, and E. Ostrom (eds.), 2000: People and Forests:
Communities, Institutions, and Governance, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.
Giovannini, G., 1994: The effect of fire on soil quality. In: Soil Erosion and
Degradation as a Consequence of Forest Fires, M. Sala, and J.L. Rubio (eds.),
Papers from the International Conference on Soil Erosion and Degradation
as a Consequence of Forest Fires, Barcelona, 1991, Geoforma Ediciones, Logroño, Spain, pp. 15–27.
Glück, P., A. Mendes, and I. Neven (eds.), 2003: Making NFPs Work: Supporting
Factors and Procedural Aspects, Report on COST Action, National Forest Programmes in a European Context, Publication series of the Institute of Forest
Sector Policy and Economics, Vol. 47, Vienna, Austria.
Godoy, R. and K.S. Bawa, 1993: The economic value and sustainable harvest
of plants and animals from the tropical forests: Assumptions, hypotheses and
methods, Economic Botany, 47, pp. 215–219.
Gray, D.A., 2002: Forest concession policies and revenue systems: Country
experience and policy changes for sustainable tropical forestry, World Bank
technical paper no. 522, World Bank, Washington, DC.
292
Ecosystems and Human Well-being: Policy Responses
Hair, D., R.N. Sampson, and T.E. Hamilton, 1996: Summary: forest management opportunities for increasing carbon storage. In: Forests and Global
Change, Volume 2: Forest Management Opportunities for Mitigating Carbon Emissions, R.N. Sampson and D. Hair (eds.), American Forests, Washington, DC,
pp. 237–254.
Harvey, A.E., 1994: Integrated roles for insects, diseases and decomposers in
fire dominated forest of the inland Western United States: Past, present and
future forest health, Journal of Sustainable Forestry, 2(1–2), pp. 211–220.
Holmes, T.P., G.M. Blate, J.C. Zweede, R. Perreira, Jr., P. Barreto, et al.,
2002: Financial and ecological indicators of reduced impact logging performance in the eastern Amazon, Forest Ecology and Management, 163, pp. 93–110.
Homma, A.K.O., 1992: The dynamics of extraction in Amazonia: A historical
perspective. In: Non-Timber Products from Tropical Forests: Evaluation of a Conservation and Development Strategy, D.C. Nepstad and S. Schwartzman (eds.),
Advances in Economic Botany, 9, pp. 23–32.
Humphreys, D. (ed.), 2004: National Forest Programmes in a Pan-European Context, Earthscan, London, UK.
Hyde, W. The Global Economics of Forestry. Forthcoming. Draft available from
the author by emailing wfhyde@aol.com.
IEA (International Energy Agency), 2002: Energy and poverty, Chapter 13. In:
World Energy Outlook 2002, OECD, Paris, France.
IIED (International Institute for Environment and Development), 2003: How
can trade promote sustainable forest management? Unpublished report prepared by IIED for FAO, IIED, London, UK.
IPF (Intergovernmental Panel on Forests), 1996: Underlying Causes of Deforestation and Forest Degradation, United Nations IPF, New York, NY.
ITTO (International Tropical Timber Organization), 1998: Criteria and Indicators
for Sustainable Management of Natural Tropical Forests, ITTO, Yokohama, Japan.
ITTO, 2002: Annual Review and Assessment of the World Timber Situation, ITTO,
Yokohama, Japan.
Kellison, R.C., 1967: A geographic variation study of yellow-poplar (Liriodendron tulipifera) within North Carolina, Technical report 33, North Carolina
State University, School of Forestry Research, Raleigh, NC, 41 pp.
Kellison, R.C., 2001: Forestry trends in the new millennium, Proceedings of
the 26th Biennial Southern Tree Improvement Conf., Athens, GA, 5 pp.
Killmann, W., Bull, G.Q., Schwab, O. and Pulkki, R.E. 2002. Reduced impact logging: does it cost or does it pay? In: Applying Reduced Impact Logging
to Advance Sustainable Forest Management. Enters, T., Durst, P.D., Applegate,
G., Kho. P.C.S. and Man, G. (eds.). RAP Publication 2002/14. Food and
Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, Bangkok. pp. 107–124.
Klingberg, T. 2004: Governance of forestry for sustainability: Private ownership and certification in an institutional perspective, Working paper no. 27,
University of Gävle, Gävle, Sweden.
Koch, P., 1991: Wood vs. Non-Wood Materials in U.S. Residential Construction:
Some Energy-Related International Implications, CINTRAFOR (Center for International Trade in Forest Products) working paper 36, University of Washington, Seattle, WA.
Knuchel, H., 1953: Planning and Control in the Managed Forest, trans. M.L. Anderson, Oliver & Boyd, Edinburgh, UK, 360 pp.
Leslie, A., 1977: Where contradictory theory and practice co-exist, Unasylva,
29(115), pp. 2–17.
Malla, Y.B., 2000: Impact of community forestry policy on rural livelihoods
and food security in Nepal, Unasylva, 51(202), pp. 37–45.
Mayers, J. and S. Vermeulen, 2002: Company–Community Forestry Partnerships:
From Raw Deals to Mutual Gains? IIED, London, UK.
Mayers, J., S. Bass, and D. MacQueen, 2002: The pyramid: A diagnostic and
planning tool for good forest governance, Prepared for the World Bank and
World Wildlife Fund Forest Alliance, March, IIED, London, UK.
Mayers, J. and S. Bass, 2004: Policy That Works for Forests and People: Real Prospects for Governance and Livelihoods, Earthscan, London, UK.
Mayers, J., J. Ngalande, P. Bird, and B. Sibale, 2001: Forestry Tactics: Lessons
from Malawi’s National Forestry Programme, Policy that works for forests and
people series, no.11, IIED, London, UK.
MCPFE (Ministerial Conference on the Protection of Forests in Europe), 2002:
MCPFE Approach to National Forest Programmes in Europe, MCPFE.
McSweeney, K., 2004: Forest product sale as natural insurance: The effects of
household characteristics and the nature of shock in eastern Honduras, Society
and Natural Resources, 17, pp. 39–56.
Meil, J.K., 1994: Environmental measures as substitution criteria for wood and
nonwood building products.
Mutch, R.W., et al., 1993: Forest health in the Blue Mountains: A management
strategy for fire-adapted ecosystems. In: Forest Health in the Blue Mountains:
Science Perspectives, T.M. Quigley (ed.), Gen.technical report PNW-GTR-
310, USDA Forest Service, Pacific Northwest Research Station, Portland,
OR, 14 pp.
National Board of Forestry (Skogsstyrelsen), Skogsvårdsorganisationens
utvärdering av skogspolitikens effekter (SUS), 2001: [The Forest Policy
Evaluation made by the Forest Authorities 2001], Meddelande, January 2002,
Jönköping, Sweden.
NCWD, 1994: Report of the National Commission on Wildfire Disasters, April,
R.N. Sampson, chair, American Forests, Washington, DC, 29 pp.
Neuenschwander, L.F. and R.N. Sampson, 2000: A wildfire and emissions
policy model for the Boise National Forest, Journal of Sustainable Forestry,
11(1–2), pp. 289–309.
Neumann, R.P. and E. Hirsch, 2000: Commercialisation of Non-Timber Forest
Products: Review and Analysis of Research, CIFOR, Bogor, Indonesia.
Ninnin, B., 1994: Elements d’Economie Spatiale des Energies Traditionelles: Application au Cas de Cinq Pays Sahelens: Burkina Faso, Gambie, Mali, Niger, Senegal,
Review of Policies in the Traditional Energy Sector, World Bank, Washington, DC.
OECD and UNDP (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development and United Nations Development Programme), 2002: Sustainable Development Strategies: A Resource Book, Compiled by B. Dalal-Clayton and
S. Bass, Earthscan, London, UK.
Oksanen, T. and C. Mersmann, 2002: Forests in poverty reduction strategies:
An assessment of PRSP processes in Sub-Saharan Africa. In: Forests in Poverty
Reduction Strategies: Capturing the Potential, T. Oksanen, B. Pajari, and T. Tuomasjukka (eds), European Forestry Institute Proceedings 47, Joensuu, Finland.
Pearce, D., F.E. Putz, and J.K. Vanclay, 2003: Sustainable forestry in the tropics:
Panacea or folly? Forest Ecology and Management, 172(2–3), pp. 229–247.
Peters, C.M., A.H. Gentry, and R.O. Mendelsohn, 1989: Valuation of an Amazonian rainforest, Nature, 339, pp. 655–656.
Pinard, M.A. and Putz, F.E. 1996. Retaining forest biomass by reducing logging damage. Biotropica 27(3), pp. 277–295.
Plotkin, M. and L. Famolare (eds.), 1992: Sustainable Harvest and Marketing of
Rain Forest Products, Conservation International–Island Press, Washington,
DC.
Poore, D., 1989: No Timber Without Trees, Earthscan, London, UK.
Poore, D., 2003: Changing Landscapes: The Development of the International Timber
Organization and Its Influence on Tropical Forest Management, Stylus Publications,
London, UK.
Putz, F.E., D.P. Dykstra, and R. Heinrich, 2000: Why poor logging practices
persist in the tropics, Conservation Biology, 14(4), pp. 951–956.
Pyne, S.J., P. Andreas, and R. Laven, 1996: Introduction to Wildland Fire, 2nd
ed., John Wiley & Sons, Inc., New York, NY, 557 pp.
Redford, K. and J. Mansour J. (eds.), 1997: Traditional Peoples and Biodiversity
Conservation in Large Tropical Landscapes, Island Press, Washington, DC.
Rice, T., S. Ozinga, C. Marijnissen, and M. Gregory, 2000: Trade Liberalisation
and its Impacts on Forests: An Overview of the Most Relevant Issues, Report, Fern,
Brussels, Belgium.
Richards, M., C. Palmer, C.F. Young, and K. Obidzinski, 2003: Higher international standards or rent-seeking race to the bottom? The impacts of forest
product trade liberalisation on forest governance. Available at www.fao.org/
forestry/foris/data/trade/pdf/richard.pdf.
Robinson, J. and E. Bennett (eds.), 2000: Hunting for Sustainability in Tropical
Forests, Columbia University Press, New York, NY.
Ross, M.L., 2001: Timber Booms and Institutional Breakdown in Southeast Asia,
Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK.
Ruiz-Pérez, M. and J.E.M. Arnold, 1996: Current Issues in Nontimber Forest
Products Research, CIFOR, Indonesia.
Ruiz-Pérez, M., B. Belcher, R. Achdiawan, M. Alexiades, C. Aubertin, et al.,
2004: Markets drive the specialization strategies of forest peoples, Ecology and
Society, 9(2), p. 4.
RWEDP (Regional Wood Energy Development Programme), 1997: Regional
study on wood energy today and tomorrow in Asia, Field document no. 50,
RWEDP in Asia, FAO, Bangkok, Thailand.
RWEDP, 2000: Options for Dendro Power in Asia: Report on the Expert Consultation, Manila, Philippines 1–3 April, FD57, FAO/RWEDP, Bangkok, Thailand. [On line 2003.] Available at www.rwedp.org/dendro.html.
Rytkönen, A., 2003: Market Access of Tropical Timber, Report submitted to the
International Tropical Timber Council pursuant to ITTC decision 6 (XXXI),
Helsinki, Finland.
Salafsky, N. and E. Wollenberg, 2000: Linking livelihoods and conservation: A
conceptual framework and scale for assessing the integration of human needs
and biodiversity, World Development, 28(8), pp. 1421–1438.
Wood, Fuelwood, and Non-wood Forest Products
Sampson, R.N. and D.L Adams (eds.), 1994: Assessing forest ecosystem health
in the inland west, Journal of Sustainable Forestry, 2(1–2), pp. 3–12.
Sarin, M., N.M. Singh, N. Sundar, and R.K. Bhogal, 2003: Devolution as a
threat to democratic decision-making in forestry? Findings from three states
in India, ODI working paper 197, February, Overseas Development Institute,
London, UK.
Savenije, H., 2000: National Forest Programmes: From Political Concept to Practical
Instrument in Developing Countries, Theme studies series 3, Forests, Forestry
and Biological Diversity Support Group, National Reference Centre for Nature management (EC LNV), Wageningen, Netherlands. Available at www
.minlnv.nl/inm.
Sedjo, R.A. and R.D. Simpson, 1999: Tariff liberalisation, wood trade flows,
and global forests, Discussion paper 00–05, Resources for the Future, Washington, DC.
SEI (Stockholm Environment Institute), 2002: Charcoal Potential in Southern Africa, CHAPOSA: Final Report, INCO_DEV, SEI, Stockholm, Sweden.
Seymour, F.J. and N.K. Dubash, 2000: The Right Conditions: The World Bank,
Structural Adjustment, and Forest Policy Reform, World Resources Institute,
Washington, DC.
Shackleton, S. and B.M. Campbell, 2001: Devolution in natural resource management: Institutional arrangements and power shifts: A synthesis of case
studies from southern Africa, CIFOR, Bogor, Indonesia, 79 pp. Available at
http://www.cifor.cgiar.org/publications/zip-file/Devolution-text.exe.
Shackleton, S., B. Campbell, E. Wollenberg, and D. Edmunds, 2002: Devolution and community-based natural resource management: Creating space for
local people to participate and benefit, Natural Resource Perspective no. 76,
March, Overseas Development Institute, London, UK.
Shiva, V., 1987: Forestry Crisis and Forestry Myths: A Critical Review of Tropical
Forests: A Call for Action, World Rainforest Movement.
Singh, N., 2002: Federations of community forest management groups. In:
Orissa: Crafting New Institutions to Assert Local Rights, Forests, Trees and People
Newsletter no. 46, September 2002, pp. 35–45.
Six-country Initiative, 1999: Practitioners’ Guide to the Implementation of the IPF
Proposals for Action, Prepared by the Six-Country Initiative in support of the
UN Ad-hoc Intergovernmental Forum on Forests, Eschborn, Germany.
Sizer, N., 1994: Opportunities to Save and Sustainably Use the World’s Forest
Through International Cooperation, World Resources Institute, Washington,
DC.
Sizer, N., 1995: Backs to the Wall in Suriname: Forest Policy in a Country in Crisis,
World Resources Institute, Washington, DC. (Also available in Dutch.)
Sizer, N., 1996: Profit without Plunder: How to Reap Revenue from Guyana’s Forests
without Destroying Them, World Resources Institute, Washington, DC.
Sizer, N., 2004: Regional approaches to tackle illegal logging and its associated
trade in Asia, Unasylva, 55(40–44).
Sizer, N., D. Downes, and D. Kaimowitz, 1999: Tree Trade: Liberalization of
International Trade in Forest Products, Risks and Opportunities, World Resources
Institute, Washington, DC.
Sizer, N. and D. Plouvier, 2000: Increased Investment and Trade by Transnational
Logging Companies in Africa, the Caribbean and the Pacific: Implications for Sustainable Management and Conservation of Tropical Forests, European Commission,
Brussels, Belgium.
Stanley, D.L., 1991: Communal forest management: The Honduran resin tappers, Development and Change, 22(4), pp. 757–779.
Sundar, N., 2001: Is devolution democratisation? World Development, 29 (12),
pp. 2007–2023.
293
Tay, J., J. Healey, and C. Price, 2002: Financial assessment of reduced impact
logging techniques in Sabah, Malaysia. In: Applying Reduced Impact Logging to
Advance Sustainable Forest Management, T. Enters, P.D. Durst, G. Applegate,
P.C.S. Kho, and G. Man (eds.), RAP Publication 14, FAO, Bangkok, Thailand, pp. 125–140.
Thornber, K., J. Gayfer, and B. Voysey, 2001: NFPs: Agent or product of
institutional change? Unpublished draft. Available at http://www.fao.org/
forestry/foris.
Tockman, J., 2001: The IMF: Funding Deforestation, American Lands Alliance,
Washington, DC.
Troup, R.S., 1940: Colonial Forest Administration, Oxford University Press, Oxford, UK, 476 pp.
UK Tropical Forest Forum, 1998: Record of meeting held on 9 December
1998, Working Group on CSD Intergovernmental Forum on Forests.
UNCED (United Nations Conference on Environment and Development),
1992: Available at http://www.ciesin.org/docs/008–585/unced-home.html.
UNFF (United Nations Forum on Forests), 2002: Report of the SecretaryGeneral on national forest programmes. Available at www.un.org/esa/sust
dev/unffdocs/unff_ss2-nfps.pdf.
Upreti, B., 2001: Beyond rhetorical success: Advancing the potential for the
community forestry programme in Nepal to address equity concerns. In: Social Learning in Community Forests, E. Wollenberg, D. Edmunds, L. Buck,
J. Fox, and S. Brodt (eds.), CIFOR, Bogor, Indonesia, pp. 189–209.
USDA Forest Service (US Department of Agriculture), 2000: Protecting People
and Sustaining Resources in Rire-adapted Ecosystems: A Cohesive Strategy, The
Forest Service Management Response to the General Accounting Office Report GAO/RCED-99–65, 13 October , USDA Forestry Service, Washington, DC, p. 85.
USTR (US Trade Representative), 1999: Accelerated Tariff Liberalization in the
Forest Products Sector: A Study of the Economic and Environmental Effects, Office
of the US Trade Representative and White House Council on Environmental
Quality, Washington, DC.
Wardle, P. and B. Michie, 2001: World trade flows of forest products. In: World
Forests, Markets and Policies, M. Palo, J. Uusivuori, and G. Mery (eds.), World
Forests Volume III, Kluwer Academic Publishers, Dordrecht, The Netherlands.
WCFSD (World Commission on Forests and Sustainable Development), 1999:
Final Report of the WCFSD.
White, A. and A. Martin, 2002: Who Owns the World’s Forests? Forest Tenure and
Public Forests in Transition, Forest Trends, Washington, DC.
World Bank, 1991: A World Bank Policy Paper: The Forest Sector, September,
World Bank, Washington, DC.
World Bank, 2002: A Revised Forest Strategy for the World Bank Group, 31 October, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Wunder, S., 2003: Oil Wealth and the Fate of Tropical Forests: A Comparative study
of Eight Tropical Countries, Routledge, London, UK.
Young, C. and V. Prochnick, 2004: O investimento direto estrangeiro (IDE) e
a estrutura industrial do setor florestal brasiliero. In: Exportando sem crises: a
industria de madeira tropical brasileira e os mercados internacionais, D. MacQueen
(ed.), Small and Medium Enterprises Series No. 1, International Institute for
Environment and Development, London, UK.
Zobel, B.J. and J.P. van Buijtenen, 1989: Wood Variation: Its Causes and Control,
Springer-Verlag, New York, 363 pp.
Zobel, B.J. and J. Talbert, 1984: Applied Forest Tree Improvement, John Wiley
and Sons, New York, NY, 511 pp.