College of Law
University of Iowa
Legal Studies Research Paper
Number 14-15
August, 2014 Revised
INCORPORATING LEGAL CLAIMS
Maya Steinitz
University of Iowa, College of Law
This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network electronic library at:
http://ssrn.com/abstract=2423541
Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2423541
DRAFT. ___ Notre Dame L. Rev. ___ (forthcoming 2015)
INCORPORATING LEGAL CLAIMS
Maya Steinitz*
ABSTRACT
Recent years have seen an explosion of interest in commercial litigation funding. Whereas the judicial, legislative and scholarly treatment of litigation finance has
regarded litigation finance first and foremost as a form of champerty and sought to
regulate it through rules of legal professional responsibility (hereinafter, the ‘legal ethics
paradigm’) this Article suggests that the problems created by litigation finance are all
facets of the classic problems created by ‘the separation of ownership and control’ that
have been a focus of business law since the advent of the corporate form. Therefore, an
‘incorporation paradigm,’ offered here, is more appropriate. ‘Incorporating legal claims’
means conceiving of the claim as an asset with an existence wholly separate from the
plaintiff. This can be done by issuing securities tied to litigation proceed rights. Such
securities can be issued with or without the use of various business entities. The incorporation paradigm also opens up the possibility of applying practices of corporate governance to litigation governance.
Indeed, in certain previously–overlooked real life deals, creative lawyers used
securities tied to litigation proceed rights as well as corporate governance mechanisms.
The Article analyzes and then expands upon such instances of financial–legal innovation suggesting how various business entities can be used to deal with the core challenges
presented by the separation of ownership of and control over legal claims, specifically,
the problems of (1) extreme agency problems; (2) extreme information asymmetries; (3)
extreme uncertainty; and (4) commodification.
In addition, the Article discusses how incorporation of legal claims can reduce
various costs that litigation imposes in other transactions, such as mergers & acquisitions.
Associate Professor, University of Iowa College of Law. A special thanks to Tom Gallanis, Herb
Hovenkamp, Shelly Kurtz, Robert Miller, Todd Pettys, [xxx], and the participants of the Washington & Lee workshop on litigation finance and of the Iowa Legal Workshop.
*
7/15/2014
Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2423541
2
M. STEINITZ
TABLE OF CONTENTS
DRAFT
Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2423541
7/15/2014]
INCORPORATING LEGAL CLAIMS
3
INTRODUCTION
The law and economics movement has revolutionized our understanding of law by placing economic cost-benefit analysis at its center.
One of the achievements of this movement, for better or worse, has been
the conceptual commodification of legal claims. Now, we are witnessing
one of the most breathtaking consequences of this turn in the history of
(legal) ideas: the rise of markets in legal claims, a phenomenon also known
as “litigation finance.” Legal claims are being commoditized in the literal
sense of the word: they are being traded like other assets.
In recent years, legal scholars, regulators, and the media have focused intensely on the visible segment of this new market: new investment
firms, such as Burford and Juridica, that invest in litigation by making
capital contributions covering litigation costs in return for a share of the
litigation proceeds, should any be awarded (hereinafter: “private equity
litigation funding” or “PELF”). Indeed, it was the historically-unprecedented going-public of Juridica and Burford1 that has launched the media
frenzy,2 academic interest,3 and nation-wide regulatory wave that has
washed over the U.S. in recent years,4 even though the trade in legal claims
in the U.S. has been ongoing for more than two decades.
Unfortunately, because of path dependence, the academic and
regulatory analysis has been trapped in what I call a “legal ethics paradigm”: the view that litigation finance, where legal, is an extension of the
1
Caroline Binham, Juridica Attracts Investment as the First Specialist Litigation Fund to Float in the UK,
THE LAWYER (Jan. 14, 2008), http://www.thelawyer.com/juridica-attracts-investment-as-the-first-specialist-litigation-fund-to-float-in-uk/130705.article; Elisa Martinuzzi, Burford Capital Amasses 80 Million
Pounds in IPO, BLOOMBERG (Oct. 16, 2009), http://www.bloomberg.com/apps/news?pid=newsarchive&sid=aM4f5weps7UQ.
2
See, e.g., Mark Cobley, Sparkling Return for Buford as Litigation Investment Comes of Age, FINANCIAL
NEWS (Jan. 11, 2014), http://www.efinancialnews.com/story/2013-01-24/burford-capital-results-2012;
Jennifer Smith, Litigation Investors Gain Ground in U.S., WSJONLINE (Jan. 12, 2014),
http://online.wsj.com/news/articles/SB10001424052702303819704579316621131535960.
3 See, e.g., Geoffrey McGovern, et, al., conference proceedings, Third Party Litigation Funding and Claim
Transfer: Trends for the Civil Justice System, UCLA-RAND Center for Law and Public Policy (2009),
available at http://www.rand.org/content/dam/rand/pubs/conf_proceedings/2010/RAND_CF272.pdf;
Northern Kentucky Law Review Symposium Focuses on Third-Party Litigation Finance, NORTHERN KENTUCKY UNIVERSITY (Feb 2, 2011) http://nku.edu/display_news.php?ID=4307; Clifford Symposium: A
Brave New World” Focuses on Litigation Finance, DEPAUL UNIVERISTY COLLEGE OF LAW (Apr. 18,
http://depaullaw.typepad.com/depaul_law_school/2013/04/clifford-symposium-a-brave-new2013),
world-focuses-on-litigation-finance.html; Symposium, The Economics of Aggregate Litigation, 66 VAND.
L. REV 1641 (2013)
4
See infra note 24.
DRAFT—DO NOT QUOTE
4
M. STEINITZ
contingency fee exception to the champerty doctrine (below) and the consequent regulation of litigation finance via the champerty doctrine and the
rules of lawyers’ professional responsibility. This Article offers an alternative theoretical and regulatory paradigm: the “incorporation paradigm”
according to which litigation finance should be understood as a pocket of
the finance industry, not as an extension of the contingency fee. According to this new paradigm, commercial legal claims can and should be “incorporated” (as defined in subsection 1 below) in order to minimize or
even resolve the concerns that both proponents and opponents of litigation finance are seeking to solve through the ethics paradigm. These concerns (detailed in subsection 2) center on conflicts of interest, information
asymmetries, risk, and commodification (collectively, the Funding Challenges). Indeed, perhaps the most revolutionary aspect of reframing the
debate in this way is that it helps reconceive of the Funding Challenges,
which occupy in some form or another most of the scholarship and public
debate surrounding litigation finance, as an instance of the familiar problem of the separation of ownership and control; a problem at the heart of
corporate law.5 The problem of the separation of ownership and control
is the problem of understanding the survival—or in our case, the emergence—of organizations in which important decision agents do not bear
a substantial share of the wealth effects of their decisions. 6 Indeed, decision agents may even seek to line their own pockets and engage in selfdealing at the expense of the owners. Since Adam Smith first raised the
problem of the separation of ownership and control in The Wealth of
Nations,7 more than two centuries ago, the practice and law of business
entities has made great strides in understanding and controlling the associated problems (though certainly not eliminating them altogether).
The theoretical argument for a paradigm shift rests on a description and analysis of deals that have heretofore been overlooked by scholars in which creative merger and acquisition (M&A) lawyers have incor-
Eugene F. Fama & Michael C. Jensen, Separation of Ownership and Control, 26 J.L. & ECON., 301
(1983) (seeking to explain the survival of organizations characterized by separation of ownership
and control and characterizing that enigma as “a problem that has bothered students of corporations from Adam Smith to Berle and Means and Jense and Meckling.” Id.). See also, R. Kraakman,
5
et. al, THE ANATOMY OF CORPORATE LAW: A COMPARATIVE AND FUNCTIONAL APPROACH 21 – 71 (Oxford University Press 2004).
6
Id.
(1st ed. London 1776) (Cannan ed. 1904) quoted in The Separation of Ownership and Control, supra note
5, at n2, together with the seminal works of Adolf A. Berle & Gardiner C. Means, THE MODERN CORPORATION AND PRIVATE PROPERTY (1932) and; Michael C. Jensen & William
H. Meckling, Theory of the Firm; Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership Structure, 3, 305 (1976).
7
DRAFT
7/15/2014]
INCORPORATING LEGAL CLAIMS
5
porated legal claims and argues that this practice can replace existing practices through which ownership and control of legal claims are traded, in
whole or in part, in the litigation finance context.
The incorporation paradigm also calls for extending financial regulations, not the regulation of attorneys, to regulate the litigation finance
industry. By better solving the Funding Challenges the incorporation paradigm should increase both acceptance of litigation finance and liquidity
of legal claims and those, in turn, will increase access to justice.
Finally, while the argument focuses on solving problems plaguing
litigation finance, incorporating legal claims has important implications in
the corporate context for three reasons. First, because it reduces what I
call “hidden costs,” sometimes prohibitive, that litigation imposes on mergers, acquisitions and major equity investments in certain (uncommon but
important) scenarios. Second, because spinning off large litigations into
Special Purpose Vehicles (SPVs) can create accounting benefits for corporations. Third, because simplifying and reducing the costs of litigation
finance of large commercial claims by incorporating them may assist corporations and governments to pursue claims that currently go unprosecuted.
Part I describes the rise of litigation finance, the ethical concerns
it raises, the ethical constraints currently imposed upon it through the legal ethics paradigm, and economic inefficiencies caused by the simultaneous over- and under regulation of litigation funding under the legal ethics
paradigm. Part II presents a set of deals in which corporations have used
business entities (Delaware statutory trusts) and various types of securities
to reduce the hidden costs of litigation and facilitate corporate transactions and two deals where incorporation presented itself in the litigation
finance context. After describing these complex and innovative deals, Part
III first generalizes from the deals how incorporation can minimize (or
exacerbate if misused) the Funding Challenges. It then outlines a broader
vision of how corporate entities other than statutory trusts can be used to
solve both the problems of the hidden costs of litigation and facilitate
efficient and ethical trade in commercial claims. The paper concludes with
some remarks on further implications of the incorporation paradigm that
can be explored in future works such as the idea of “litigation governance,” modeled on corporate governance, and the question of the proper
regulation of litigation finance arrangements understood as securities and,
more generally, as financial products.
1. The Legal Ethics Paradigm and its Limitations
Currently, liquidity of legal claims is greatly hampered by the fact
that the mechanics of claim trading are placed in a strait-jacket woven out
DRAFT—DO NOT QUOTE
6
M. STEINITZ
of antiquated doctrines and rules (described below) that are aimed at regulating a relationship different in kind. This legal ethics paradigm rests on
a flawed analogy between the contingency attorney-client relationship and
the financier-financed relationship:
Because the similarities between attorney funding and
third-party funding are extensive, most of the discourse
surrounding litigation funding is characterized by what
some economists call an ‘attribute substitution’: a cognitive bias whereby individuals who need to make a complex
judgment, here – regarding the desirability of the novel
phenomenon of litigation finance, substitute that complex
judgment for a more easily calculated heuristic. In our
case, the easiest calculation is the desirability of contingency fees. In other words, commentators simply apply
their preconceived views of contingency fees to litigation
finance.8
The substitution is understandable. As discussed below, there are
indeed important similarities between the concerns that arise in the context of the contingency attorney–client relationship and that of the funder–plaintiff, including (1) extreme agency problems (conflicts of interests); (2) extreme information asymmetries; (3) extreme uncertainty; and
(4) inappropriate commodification namely, the doing away with nonmonetary relief.9 But while contingency lawyers do provide financing, they
primarily provide lawyering services. They are officers of the court, with
privileges conferred by the courts and by society at large and corresponding obligations to those constituencies and are therefore subject to an
elaborate regulatory regime embodied in the codes of professional responsibility.
Conversely, funders are financiers only. The current direct and indirect regulation of litigation finance, through common law doctrines
such as champerty (direct) and legal ethics (indirect) should be radically
8
Maya Steinitz, Whose Claim Is This Anyway? Third-Party Litigation Funding, 95 MINN. L. REV. 1268
(2010).
These problems as they present themselves in litigation finance have been discussed at length in
The Litigation Finance Contract, 54 WM. & MARY L. REV. 455 (2012) [hereinafter The Litigation Finance
Contract] (arguing that litigation finance is analogous to venture capital because it is similarly characterized by extreme agency costs, extreme information asymmetry and extreme risk, for similar
reasons, and that these problems can be minimized by adapting solutions from venture capital). A
detailed discussion of the specific conflicts of interests created by the tripartite attorney – client –
funder relationship is available in Whose Claim Is This Anyway? supra note 8.
9
DRAFT
7/15/2014]
INCORPORATING LEGAL CLAIMS
7
revised to reflect economic reality.10 That reality, as the deals described
below exemplify, is that sophisticated plaintiffs and funders are best understood as co-venturers. Or, in other words, as business partners (as the
term ‘partners’ is used colloquially). Consequently, they can adopt existing
deal structures, use legal entities and the regulations that govern them, as
well as contractual mechanism including corporate governance mechanisms developed through the practices and laws of business entities in
order to avail themselves of built-in solutions to the Funding Challenges.
These can and should replace the ethics paradigm which both
over- and under regulates litigation finance. Legal ethics over-regulates in
that it leads to the prohibition of joint ventures (between plaintiffs and
funders) that most would find inoffensive, indeed facilitative of access to
justice as can most clearly be seen in “David vs. Goliath” disputes between tech start-ups with no resources to pursue patent infringements, on
the one hand, and established industry incumbents who infringe, on the
other. Legal ethics under-regulates in that it does nothing to deal with the
problems of finance e.g., by requiring that funders be adequately capitalized, registered and licensed; mandating appropriate disclosures to the investors in PELF; controlling for the moral hazard that creating litigationbacked securities might create in the future; imposing fiduciary duties and
duties to fund, and more.
In short, expanding the practice of incorporating commercial legal
claims beyond the M&A context to the litigation finance context can help
minimize or even solve some of the key problems identified by scholars
of litigation finance. Once such problems are addressed, litigation finance—currently suspect by lawyers, judges, legislators and investors—
may face less resistance and more expansion allowing more meritorious
claims to be litigated than otherwise would be and solving the problem of
the value destruction caused to plaintiffs by meritorious claims that go
unremedied. Corporations, which are generally conservative about suing,
10 This, in turn implies a normative argument that litigation finance is a positive development. For
normative arguments favoring litigation finance, see, e.g., Richard W. Painter, Litigating on a Contingency: A Monopoly of Champions or a Market for Champerty?, 71 CHI-KENT L. Rev. 625 (1995); See also
Michele DeStephano, Nonlawyers Influencing Lawyers: Too Many Cooks in the Kitchen or Stone Soup? 80
FORDHAM L. Rev. 2791 (2012). Reasonable minds certainly differ, however. Views opposing litigation funding include e.g., John Beisner et al., SELLING LAWSUITS, BUYING TROUBLE: THIRDPARTY LITIGATION FUNDING IN THE UNITED STATES 3, (Released by the U.S. Chamber Institute
for Legal Reform, Oct. 2009), http://www.instituteforlegalreform.com/sites/default/files/thirdpartylitigationfinancing.pdf; Stephen B. Presser, A Tale of Two Models: Third Party Litigation in Historical and Ideological Perspective 27 and; Paul H. Rubin, On the Efficiency of Increasing Litigation, 10-11
(Sept. 24-25, 2009) (unpublished manuscript), (on file with author) available at
http://www.law.northwestern.edu/searlecenter/papers/
Rubin-ThirdPartyFinancingLitigation.pdf.
DRAFT—DO NOT QUOTE
8
M. STEINITZ
currently are experiencing value destruction in the form of un-prosecuted
claims. To the extent their claims are not prosecuted because of the difficulty in ascertaining value, the difficulty in ascertaining the likelihood of
success prosecuting meritorious claims, negative accounting treatment
during claim conduct, unfavorable tax treatment or because of the cost of
the capital that would be used to prosecute a claim (including opportunity
costs), a more vibrant and liquid litigation finance market may provide
access to justice. Sovereigns, domestically as well as foreign, are another
type of sophisticated owner of large-scale claims, face the same kind of
analysis when having to decide whether to pursue litigation. In addition,
in the case of sovereigns such decisions are subject to public scrutiny and
using public funds to pursue speculative litigation may not be a popular
decision. Here, the value destroyed from having to forgo litigation is foregone public resource.
Recognizing the full commodification of claims created by their
incorporation and a liquid market in claims, I draw one major limit: I exclude from consideration the incorporation of non-commercial claims.11
Commercial claims, more than all others, involve damages that can be
remedied through monetary compensation. When a claim’s natural remedy is monetary, commodification does not distort justice. In all other
instances, however, the drive toward commodification can distort justice.
While this article will identify ways to ameliorate this dynamic through
deal structure at bottom, injuries that call for non-monetary remedies need
to be sheltered from commodification. Thus for the purposes of cleanly
demarcating the incorporation of claims and its benefits, I exclude noncommercial claims.
2. Incorporation of Legal Claims
The market in legal claims is much vaster, and older, than the discourse on commercial litigation finance recognizes. As this paper documents, long before the emergence of PELF, companies advised by creative lawyers have experimented with trading in legal claims by incorporating them. Specifically, by ‘incorporation’ of a claim I am referring to a
11 American litigation finance serves two different markets. One is consumers bringing personal
claims sounding, e.g. in torts, matrimonial or workers’ compensation law and who need bridge
financing while their attorney delivers a settlement or judgment. The other is corporations, many
repeat players already, who want the money to pay the litigation’s expenses so they can free up the
capital for operations, or who are faced with a claim too big for them to bring without financing.
The public policy concerns are quite different, in that consumers have less bargaining power and
sophistication and therefore need more protection; personal claims are not always resolvable with
cash alone and; the contracts involved are totally different. Further, consumers can enter form
contracts; commercial claims are always negotiated deals. On consumer lending, see consumer lending literature review infra note 18.
DRAFT
7/15/2014]
INCORPORATING LEGAL CLAIMS
9
practice of giving the claim a legal existence separate from its plaintiff, and
thus making it an asset that can be sold. There are two archetypical ways
to incorporate claims which I will call loose and strict.
‘Loose incorporation’ means embodying the value of the litigation
in a security which until claim resolution derives value solely from the
expected value of the litigation and at claim resolution has a fixed value
that is conveyed to the security holders. Placing the claim in the “corpus”
of a security is “incorporation” in a loose, literary sense only. “Strict incorporation” involves creating an SPV to embody the claim and/or its
proceeds, and is a literal usage of “incorporation,” though not intended
to connote that corporations are the only, or even most appropriate, legal
entities for this purpose. When strictly incorporating, the SPV may issue
securities, but that is not a definitional constraint.
Claim incorporation can address the issues raised by separation
and control in two basic ways: by contract, and by the statutory and common law that come with the different forms of SPV. Regardless of which
of the possible forms the incorporation takes, claim incorporation forces
the transparent allocation of ownership and control as people will not buy
a litigation-backed security without disclosure as to how the litigation will
be managed. Even without a security, SPVs by their nature require structuring the funder-plaintiff-claim relationship.
Examples of both loose and strict incorporation are discussed in
Part II. Nearly all of the examples are of deals done in the 1990s to solve
merger pricing problems created by litigation. In those deals the claim was
so large and hard to value the parties could not agree on what the target
was worth. So the target spun-off the value of the claim to its shareholders, and the deal priced without consideration for the claim. The spun-off
securities traded on the Nasdaq12 (for the most part), and thus the target’s
shareholders were able to realize immediate value and the pricing problems was solved by the actual market pricing the shares. That in turn allowed strangers to the claim to own the right to some claim proceeds.
Claim incorporation was born.
See infra Part III. In addition, some litigation finance firms are publically traded: The Australian IMF is traded on the Australian exchange and Juridica and Burford are traded on London’s
AIM exchange. John O’Doherty, Litigation Fund Poised for AIM Debut, FIN. TIMES (London),
Oct. 17, 2009, at 14. As such, conceptually, their shares are securities of pools of litigations. Interestingly, Professor Stephen Yeazell used the idea of “a NASDAQ for legal claims for lawsuits” in his argument in favor of pricing transparency in the market of civil suits’ settlements.
Stephen C. Yeazell, Transparency for Civil Settlements: NASDAQ for Lawsuits?, CONFIDENTIALITY, TRANSPARENCY AND THE U.S. CIVIL JUSTICE SYSTEM (Joseph Doherty & Robert Reville eds., 2012).
12
DRAFT—DO NOT QUOTE
10
M. STEINITZ
While most of the deals arose in the M&A context, each explicitly
contemplated the possibility of issuing additional securities to finance the
litigation and their structures are well-suited for usage directly for litigation finance.13 In addition, two other examples of strict incorporation
come directly from the litigation finance context. One was contractually
agreed to but apparently never created. The other came about in the legally distinctive bankruptcy context and the claim’s incorporation in that
case was inadvertent rather than intentional. It is appropriate to speak of
that claim as incorporated simply because the facts leading to the bankruptcy so stripped the company of value that its sole remaining asset was
its multi-billion dollar claim. Importantly, that litigation finance deal involved the formal allocation of ownership and control through the medium of both the plaintiff’s corporate form and by contract.
I.
LITIGATION FINANCE AS A SQUARE PEG IN A ROUND
HOLE AND THE INHIBITION OF LIQUIDITY IN LEGAL
CLAIMS
1. The rise of litigation finance and the liquidity in legal claims
Recent years have seen an explosion of academic interest in commercial litigation funding which is regarded as a new phenomenon in the
United States.14 The timing of the public awareness in academia and in the
financial, trade and general media is probably due to the launch of two
publically-traded litigation finance firms—Juridica in 2008 and Burford in
2009.15 It appears, however, that some private entities have been funding
commercial cases in the United States for at least a couple of decades,
either ad hoc, in the case of certain hedge funds, or through specialized
13 Whether it is possible to do an IPO, rather than a spinoff, of litigation proceeds-backed securities
is an open question, as underwriters may reject participating in such a deal. However, securities
could still be privately placed. See Richard Painter, The Model Contract and The Securities Laws, Part IIV, A MODEL LITIGATION FINANCE CONTRACT, supra note 16.
14 See, e.g., Steven Garber, Alternative Litigation Financing in the United States, RAND CORP. (2010)
(occasional
paper),
http://www.rand.org/content/dam/rand/pubs/occasional_papers/2010/RAND_OP306.pdf.; Jonathan T. Molot, Litigation Finance: A Market Solution to a
Procedural Problem, 99 Geo. L. J. [xx] (2010) Stephen Gillers, Waiting for Good Dough: Litigation
Funding Comes to Law, 43 AKRON L. REV. 667 (2010); Deborah Hensler, Financing Civil Litigation: the
US Perspective, NEW TRENDS IN FINANCING CIVIL LITIGATION IN EUROPE (Mark Tuil & Louis
Visscher, eds., 2010).
See IMF (AUSTRALIA) LTD, http://www.imf.com.au/ (last visited Mar. 21, 2013); JURIDICA CAPITAL MANAGEMENT LTD, http://www.juridica.co.uk/about.php (last visited Mar. 23, 2013); BURFORD, supra note Error! Bookmark not defined..
15
DRAFT
7/15/2014]
INCORPORATING LEGAL CLAIMS
11
private firms that simply did not catch the eye of the financial media nor
the academe.16 Since the high-profile launch of Juridica and Buford a
number of privately-held litigation firms have emerged including Bantham Capital, BlackRobe Capital, Fulbrook Capital, Themis Capital and
Gerchen Keller Capital LLC, to name a few.17
Moreover, the current commercial litigation funding industry, variously referred to as third party funding, alternative litigation funding, litigation investment, and more was preceded by a number of closely-related
practices. A first wave of litigation funding, broadly defined, includes the
law lending industry, also known as consumer litigation funding, and it
encompasses the financing of personal claims such as personal injuries
and workers’ compensation claims.18 Also included in this wave was the
rise of the so-called IP-trolls;19 a market in bankruptcy claims (corporate
debt);20 a market in ICSID awards (sovereign debt)21 and; the rise of various forms of alternative funding—including that of class actions—in the
pioneering jurisdictions, the UK and Australia.22 Lastly, related financial
16 This is based on communications this author received in associating with her web-based research
project The Model Litigation Finance Contract, supra note 9.
See BANTHAM ASSET MANAGEMENT, http:// http://www.benthamam.com/; FULBROOK CAPITAL MANAGEMENT LLC, http:// http://www.fulbrookmanagement.com/; THEMIS LEGAL CAPITAL. http:// http://www.themislc.com/; GERCHEN KELLER CAPITAL LLC, http://
17
http://www.gerchenkeller.com.
Susan Lorde Martin, Financing Plaintiffs’ Lawsuits: An Increasingly Popular (and Legal) Business, 33 U.
MICH. J.L. REFORM 57, 79–83 (1999); Susan Lorde Martin, Litigation Financing: Another Subprime
Industry that Has a Place in the United States Market, 53 VILL. L. REV. 83, 86–87 (2008); Susan Lorde
Martin, The Litigation Financing Industry: The Wild West of Finance Should Be Tamed Not Outlawed, 10
FORDHAM J. CORP. & FIN. L. 55, 68 (2004); Julia H. McLaughlin, Litigation Funding: Charting a Legal
and Ethical Course, 31 VT. L. REV. 615 (2007).
18
19 See e.g. Peter N. Detkin, Leveling the Patent Playing Field, 6 J. MARSHALL REV. INTELL. PROP. L. 636
(2007).
20 Drain, Robert D & Elizabeth J. Schwartz, Are Bankruptcy Claims Subject to the Federal Securities
Laws?, 10 AM. BANKR. INST. L. REV. 569 (2002).
21
An industry described in PROFITING FROM INJUSTICE: HOW LAW FIRMS, ARBITRATORS AND FINAN-
ARE
FUELLING
AN
INVESTMENT
ARBITRATION
BOOM
available
http://www.tni.org/sites/www.tni.org/files/download/profitingfrominjustice.pdf.
CIERS
at
See generally, Tuil & Visscher, supra note 14,and CIVIL JUSTICE COUNCIL, THE FUTURE
FUNDING OF LITIGATION–
22
ALTERNATIVE FUNDING STRUCTURES 54 (2007), http://www
.civiljusticecouncil.gov.uk/files/future_funding_litigation_paper_v117_final.pdf.
DRAFT—DO NOT QUOTE
12
M. STEINITZ
products such as litigation insurance for plaintiffs and after-the-event insurance for defendants have been available in foreign jurisdictions for
some time including, respectively, Germany and the UK.23
The first wave of litigation finance has led to some regulatory efforts—with state level legislation24 and some investigations by states attorneys general25—as well as an expansion of the market. This expansion
included new ‘asset classes’ such as divorces26 and the rise of dedicated
commercial funders (including publically-traded ones) described above.
With public awareness and attendant growing demand for litigation funding, as well as a lot of R&D (research and development) of new
financial products by existing and start-up litigation funding firms, we are
now witnessing what can be termed the third wave of litigation funding
in the United States. One development characteristic of the third wave is
that commercial funders are emboldened to seek overt control and not
mere influence over the litigations they invest in.27 Under this revised business model funders seek to enhance the value of their investment by actively managing them, as is done in more traditional asset classes. Another
characteristic is that new market entrants have positioned themselves as
Marie Gryphon, A Loser-Pays Model Would Make the Civil Courts System a Winner, MANHATTAN
INST. FOR POLICY RESEARCH DAILY J., Dec. 5, 2008.
23
24 Legislation to regulate at least some types of litigation funding is currently pending before three
state legislatures - Indiana, Oklahoma, and Mississippi. S.B. 378, 2013 Gen. Assemb., Reg. Sess.
(Ind. 2013); S.B. 1016, 54th Leg., 1st Sess. (Okla. 2013); H.B. 503, 128th Leg., Reg. Sess. (Miss.
2013) and S.B. 2378, 128th Leg., Reg. Sess. (Miss. 2013). A 2010 Delaware House Bill passed out
of committee, but went no further. H.B. 422, 145th Gen. Assemb. (Del. 2010). Three other
states—Maine, Ohio, and Nebraska—have already passed legislation regulating litigation financing. An Act to Regulate Presettlement Lawsuit Funding, 2007 Me. Laws 394 (codified at ME. REV.
STAT. tit. 9-A, §§ 12-101 to -107 (2007)); H.B. 248, 127th Gen. Assemb., Reg. Sess. (Ohio 2008)
(codified in OHIO REV. CODE § 1349.55 (2008)); L.B. 1094, 101st Leg., 2nd Sess.
25 Several consumer financing companies doing business in New York State have entered into a
stipulation with the Attorney General of New York that requires the law lending firms who are
members of the American Legal Finance Association to follow certain guidelines. See Eliot Spitzer,
Att’y Gen. N.Y., Assurance of Discontinuance Pursuant to Executive Law § 63(15), (Feb. 17, 2005).
See Binyamin Appelbaum, Taking Sides in a Divorce, Chasing Profit, N.Y. TIMES, Dec. 5, 2010, at
A1.
26
See Selvyn Seidel, Time to Pass the Baton? COMMERCIAL DISPUTE RESOLUTION MAGAZINE,
Nov.-Dec.
2012,
available
at
http://
http://www.fulbrookmanagement.com/2012/11/01/time-to-pass-the-baton. Sean Coffee, the principal of the litigation funding firm BlackRobe (now dissolved) termed this “litigation 2.0”. His explanation for the shift is
that when Juridica and Burford sought to go public their deal advisors were unsure that funding
which involves control of the litigation is permissible and so those entities sought a more conservative approach than the privately-held entities that followed in their footsteps. John (Sean)
Coffey Presentation at the Institute for Law & Economic Policy’s 19th Annual Symposium on The
Economics of Aggregate Litigation, Naples, Fl. (April 2013).
27
DRAFT
7/15/2014]
INCORPORATING LEGAL CLAIMS
13
providing methods of corporate finance for businesses that could otherwise afford to bring claims,28 and incumbent market participants have
added such products to their offerings.29 Other new financial products
include law firm financing30 and defense financing.31
2. The concerns raised by litigation finance
Most of the literature relating to litigation funding has focused on
the ethical challenges posed by litigation funding, on the one hand, and
on archaic regulation that stands in the way of litigation funding, on the
other. Such regulations prohibit litigation funding in certain states, and in
others, raise its costs and constrain its users into financial arrangements
with convoluted structures which operate in a legal gray zone. One set of
concerns arises from the historic perception of litigation as a necessary
evil to address personal harms which are perceived, in the words of one
scholar, as ‘authentic claims.’32 The corollary is a historic distaste of ‘officious intermeddling’ by nonparties, especially for a profit.33 The broadest
prohibition designed to avoid such intermeddling and to ensure that only
authentic claims are brought to the courts is the doctrine of champerty,
which bars profiting from financing lawsuits, and related (though functionally different) prohibitions against claim assignment.34 Champerty and
assignment limits can apply regardless of claim type, serving to prohibit
both commercial and consumer claims.35
See generally What We Do, GERCHEN KELLER CAPITAL,http://www.gerchenkeller.com/what-wedo; specifically for plaintiff services at http://www.gerchenkeller.com/what-we-do/claimholders.
28
29 As this Article goes to print an innovative form of funding in which the funding firm provided
a plaintiff with a conventional recourse loan with a contingent value right to receive a portion of
an arbitration award has been announced. The funds were to be spent on the plaintiff-corporation’s business needs, rather than litigation costs. See http://www.burfordcapital.com/wp-content/uploads/2014/06/2014-06-03-BUR-Rurelec-press-release-Final.pdf and; See Jan Wolfe, Burford Touts 73% Return on Arbitration Case, THE LITIGATION DAILY, June 3, 2014.
See http://www.burfordcapital.com/how-we-help/for-law-firms/;
ler.com/what-we-do/law-firms.
30
http://www.gerchenkel-
Gerchen Keller Capital describes its defense products at http://www.gerchenkeller.com/whatwe-do/defendants.
31
32
Anthony J. Sebok, The Inauthentic Claim, 64 VAND. L. REV. 61 (2011).
33
See, e.g., definition of “champerty” in BLACK’S LAW DICTIONARY (9th ed. 2009).
34
See N.Y. JUDICIARY LAW §489 (prohibiting buying claims).
Each state’s doctrine varies and certain exceptions can be made. For example, New York allows
the free assignment of claims that are sufficiently large or of certain types. See Anthony Sebok,
35
DRAFT—DO NOT QUOTE
14
M. STEINITZ
Underlying this broad bar are concerns about claim ownership,
which is reflected in a focus on whether or not the funder has received
control of the litigation.36 Much of legal ethics can be explained as safeguards that ensure that the client, not the lawyer (especially pertinent in
the case of contingency lawyering), ultimately controls her claim. For example, the Model Rules of Professional Responsibility specifically carve
out permission for attorneys to make day-to-day decisions;37 this carveout is necessary as a deviation from the rule that the client ultimately controls her case. In contrast, only the client can make key decisions with the
most privileged decision being the decision to settle, including the option
to abandon the litigation.38 Because litigation funding has generally been
discussed as an extension of the contingency fee—the best known and
the most important of the exceptions to champerty—there is a natural
tendency to assume that funders should similarly have no control over the
litigation generally and over settlement specifically (though influence is
permissible).39
Incorporating The Claim, A MODEL LITIGATION FINANCE CONTRACT, (Feb. 4, 2013 7:59
AM), http://litigationfinancecontract.com/incorporating-the-claim.
36 A Texas Appellate court listed as factors potentially creating a problematic transfer of control:
“permitting appellees to select counsel, direct trial strategy, or participate in settlement discussions,
[or] to look to [ ] trial counsel directly for payment.” See Anglo-Dutch Petroleum Int'l, Inc. v.
Haskell, 193 S.W.3d 87, 104 (Tex. App. Houston 1st Dist. 2006). A Florida District Court concluded a funder had so much control of the litigation it was the real party in interest. See AbuGhazaleh v. Chaul, 36 So.3d 691, 693 (Fla. Dist. Ct. App. 2009); see also the landmark Australian
case, Campbells Cash and Carry Pty. Ltd. v Fostif Pty. Ltd. (2006) 229 CLR 386 (Austl.), in which
the Australian High Court permitted the funder to have broad control, and the English Court of
Appeals equally groundbreaking decision in, Arkin v. Borchard Lines Ltd., [2005] EWCA (Civ)
655 (Eng.), in which it established that third-party funding is acceptable, even desirable, to increase
access to justice, but fell short of sanctioning the transfer of control to funders. See also N.Y.C.
Bar, Formal Op., at Section E (notes that a client may agree to permit a financing company to
direct the strategy or other aspects of a lawsuit including whether and for how much to settle,
similarly acknowledges the potential value of funder involvement but leaves it to private contracting rather than interpret the law as allocating any control to the funder).
MODEL RULES OF PROF’L CONDUCT R. 1.2 (authorizing the attorney in part to “take
such action on behalf of the client as is impliedly authorized to carry out the representation.”).
37
38
Id., saying in part “A lawyer shall abide by a client’s decision whether to settle a matter.”
See N.Y.C. Bar Opinion, infra note 40, ABA Comm. on Ethics 20/20, White Paper on Alternative
Litigation Financing (2011) (draft), available at http://www.americanbar.org/content/dam/aba/administrative/ethics_2020/20111019_draft_alf_white_paper_posting.authcheckdam.pdf. But cf. The Litigation Finance Contract, supra note 9, at [xx] (arguing that sophisticated plaintiffs in commercial cases should be allowed to sell control in exchange for a control premium).
39
DRAFT
7/15/2014]
INCORPORATING LEGAL CLAIMS
15
A related concern is conflicts of interest as the introduction of a
financier into the attorney-client relationship can produce conflicts or reinforce existing ones.40 In addition to conflicts that are similar to those
that exist between a contingency fee lawyer and her clients—such as incentives to settle early in order to maximize profits across a portfolio rather than in a particular case; incentive to prioritize reputation over monetary relief; and an incentive to prioritize monetary relief over non-monetary relief41—interesting examples of conflicts unique to the funder-client relationship include those that may arise if a funder decides to securitize its pool of litigations42 or to invest on both sides of the “v.” Conflict
concerns are often also concerns about control. Instead of overt control,
like formal settlement authority or the right to dictate choice of counsel,
conflicts can generate hidden forms of control. For example, any repeatplay relationship between funder and the litigation counsel gives funder
informal but significant influence over the conduct of the case.
As is already implied, litigation funding both affects and is affected
by attorneys’ ethics. Therefore, attorneys’ professional responsibility duties function as indirect regulation of litigation funding. Like authentic
claim issues, one such duty is a broad bar: the prohibition on fee-splitting
40 See
Whose Claim Is It Anyway?, supra note 8 at 1291–92, 1323–25, and The Litigation Finance Contract,
supra note 9, at 481–88. Specifically, N.Y. State Rules of Prof’l Conduct R. 1.2(d); 1.6(a); 1.7(a);
1.8(e), (f); 2.1; 2.2; and 5.4(c). More generally, the MODEL RULES OF PROF’L CONDUCT R.
1.0(E) (informed consent), R. 1.6–1.11 (confidentiality of information; conflict of interest: current
clients, specific rules; duties to former clients; imputation of conflicts of interest: general rules,
special conflicts of interest for former and current government officers and employees), R. 2.1
(counsel as “advisor”), and R. 2.3 (counsel’s evaluation of a matter for use by a third party). These
are the rules addressed in the New York City Bar’s formal 2011 opinion on the ethics of third
party litigation finance. See N.Y.C. Bar Opinion from October 2011 n. 10 and accompanying text.
The American Bar Association’s has draft opinion on the ethics of third party litigation financing,
discussing the practice in light of the model rules. See ABA Comm. on Ethics 20/20, supra note
39.
HERBERT M. KRITZER, RISKS, REPUTATIONS, AND REWARDS: CONTINGENCY FEE
LEGAL PRACTICE IN THE UNITED STATES 9 (2004) (applying modern portfolio theory to
contingency fee practice and, among other things, analyzing the conflicts that a portfolio of contingency fee cases creates); Whose Claim Is It Anyway?, supra note 8(analyzing the effects of portfolio
management to litigation finance.).
41
For an analysis of the conflicts that may arise if funders ever securitize litigation see Whose Claim
Is It Anyway?, supra note 8 at 1312.
42
DRAFT—DO NOT QUOTE
16
M. STEINITZ
(that is splitting the fee between a lawyer and a non-lawyer).43 This prohibition prevents business models that make economic sense,44 and it distorts contractual relationships among lawyers, plaintiffs and funders. The
same is true of the prohibitions on the unauthorized practice of law45 and
on multidisciplinary practices (i.e. the practice of law and other professions, such as accounting, in a single firm).46 Each of these in isolation and
in combination means, for example, that finance or accounting specialists
cannot partner up with lawyers in a single firm that engages in the practice
of law. (However, litigation finance firms are firms in which former attorneys partner up with such finance specialist. They must therefore be careful not to overstep the bounds and engage in the practice of law.)47
Another set of ethical regulations again relates to control: an attorney’s ethical duty to exercise independent judgment,48 free from funder
influence, and to zealously and loyally represent her client even if it means
being in conflict with the funder.49 These obligations, combined with the
fee splitting prohibition, for example, limit a direct engagement between
the funder and the attorney for the financing of litigation and require that
funder contract directly with the client. Finally, attorneys’ ethical duties
also limit or prohibit specific financial arrangements between the attorney
and funder such as paying referral fees.50
In addition to industry-wide challenges such as champerty and attorney ethical duties, other doctrines challenge the terms of individual
43
MODEL RULES OF PROF’L CONDUCT R. 5.4.
Victoria Shannon, The Funder as Co-Counsel: A glimpse Into the Future of Law Firm Ownership, A
MODEL LITIGATION FINANCE CONTRACT, http://litigationfinancecontract.com/thefunder-as-co-counsel-a-glimpse-into-the-future-of-law-firm-ownership/.
44
45
MODEL RULES OF PROF’L CONDUCT R. 5.5.
46
See Shannon supra note 44.
47 The line can be blurry the more financiers seek to be active funders who monitor and seek to
actively enhance the value of their investment. See the back and forth discussion here http://litigationfinancecontract.com/funders-as-lawyers/, here http://litigationfinancecontract.com/funders-as-lawyers-a-response/, and Maya Steinitz, Funders As Fiduciaries, http://litigationfinancecontract.com/funders-as-fiduciaries/.
48
MODEL RULES OF PROF’L CONDUCT R. 5.4.
49
MODEL RULES OF PROF’L CONDUCT R. 1.3, comment.
50
See A Model Litigation Finance Contract, supra note 9 at 30 (referrals and repeat play).
DRAFT
7/15/2014]
INCORPORATING LEGAL CLAIMS
17
deals or deal types namely, the doctrines of usury,51 unconscionability52
and abuse of process.53 All but the last of these doctrines focus on potentially exploitative financing terms, and as a general matter, are raised by
consumers rather than plaintiffs involved in the large commercial deals
conducted pursuant to bespoke contracts. Nonetheless when a commercial plaintiff seeks to invalidate a deal because it does not like the financing
terms in hindsight—after the claim resolved—such arguments have come
up.54
A final set of concerns arising from litigation finance include the
pressure to commodify claims by resolving them all with money, as opposed to with injunctive or other non-monetary relief.55 Again, underlying
the tension is the issue of claim control or influence; if the funder has
none there’s no pressure to commodify the claim. Claim commodification
reflects perhaps the purest tension between the justice and economic/finance models of litigation and is the reason why financing of certain categories of claims, e.g. torts or claims arising under public international
law, should proceed with great caution and may require different regulation than financing of commercial claims.
***
In sum, path dependency—an evolutionary path focused on
avoiding champerty and the greater philosophy that underlies this doctrine according to which there’s simply something vaguely distasteful56
51 Susan Lorde Martin, Litigation Financing: Another Subprime Industry that Has a Place in the United
States Market, 53 VILL. L. REV. 83, 86–7 (2008).
52 Julia
H. McLaughlin, Litigation Funding: Charting a Legal and Ethical Course, 31 VT. L. REV. 615, 643
(2007).
See LISA BENCH NIEUWVELD & VICTORIA SHANNON, THIRD-PARTY
TIONAL ARBITRATION (2012) (discussing the abuse of process doctrine).
53
FUNDING IN INTERNA-
54 S&T Oil Equipment & Machinery, Ltd. v. Juridica Investments Ltd. (S.D. Tex. 2011) is an example of a financed large commercial claim in which a remorseful buyer—the plaintiff—tried to
invalidate the financing arrangement. See Anglo-Dutch Petroleum Int'l, Inc. v. Haskell, 193 S.W.3d
87 (Tex. App. Houston 1st Dist. 2006)[] at 95-101 (usury argument), 101-103 (unregistered securities argument), 103-105 (discussing public policy); See also Anglo-Dutch Petroleum Int’l, Inc. v.
Smith, 243 S.W.3d 776 (Tex. App. Houston 14th Dist. 2007) (noting the arguments made by the
plaintiff that the funding was a usurious loan, or an unregistered (and thus invalid) security, or void
as against public policy).
55
See infra note 59.
Michael Herman, Fear of Third Party Litigation Funding Is Groundless, TIMES ONLINE (Oct. 25,
2007) (“Detractors [of third party litigation funding feel that]… there is something distasteful,
some say unethical, about a third-party that has no involvement in a legal dispute being allowed to
profit from it”). This is the notion underlying Anthony J. Sebok, The Inauthentic Claim, 64 VAND.
L. REV. (2011). See also W. Bradley Wendel, Alternative Litigation Financing and Anti-Commodification
56
DRAFT—DO NOT QUOTE
18
M. STEINITZ
about litigation funding—has obscured a simple fact. The fact is that some
plaintiffs have come to regard their claims as assets they wish to monetize
i.e., sell in whole or in part.57 To the extent that they wish to sell parts of
the asset they are bringing in business partners. Business partners are a
known beast: they are allowed contracting for control, they are allowed
participating in the management of their investment and the underlying
asset, in certain circumstances they owe and are owed fiduciary duties (if
structured as a partnership) or at least a duty of good faith,58 they must
avoid self-dealing and are generally subject to the various laws and doctrines that address conflicts of interest, they can request to review books
and records, and more.59
In other words, there is an entire area of law, as law students learn
as soon as they commence their legal education, that has evolved during
modern times, since the advent of limited liability, to deal with these kinds
of commercial relationships: the law of business entities. There is no good
reason to prevent parties to litigation funding arrangements from availing
themselves of the mechanisms, laws and practices that have evolved in
the law of corporations to deal with these very same problems. Some concrete examples are provided in Part III.
But first, the next Part demonstrates that these issues of ownership and control can be directly addressed when issuing securities tied to
litigation proceeds, either directly or through an SPV, or when using an
SPV to embody and distribute the value of the claim to the SPV’s owners,
rather than to litigation proceed-backed security holders. Understanding
how control and conflicts were addressed in these deals will lay the foundation to bringing general principles of corporate law to bear.
Norms, DEPAUL L. REV. (Forthcoming) (theorizing the “ick factor” that is often cited in discussions of Alternative Litigation Finance).
57 As is recognized by the literature on claim assignment. See Michael Abramowica, On the Alienability of Legal Claims, 114 YALE L. J. 697 (2004); Sebok, supra note 56.
58 Anthony J. Sebok & W. Bradley Wendel, Characterizing the Parties’ Relationship in Litigation Investment: Contract and Tort Good Faith Norms, 66 VAND. L. REV. (forthcoming 2013).
59
See infra Part IV.
DRAFT
7/15/2014]
INCORPORATING LEGAL CLAIMS
19
II. CLAIM INCORPORATION AND LITIGATION GOVERNANCE
IN THE EXAMPLES OF WINSTAR, INFORMATION RESOURCES,
CRYSTALLEX AND TRECA60
Legal claims are notoriously difficult to value.61 Consequently,
they are very difficult to account for on a corporation’s books. 62 And
when a claim is materially large relative to a plaintiff company’s value as a
going concern, legal claims can, and have, become insurmountable obstacles to pricing a merger, acquisition, or major equity investment. I call this
kind of problem a “hidden cost” of litigation. Hidden costs are major restrictions imposed on a business simply because a large legal claim exists.63
Importantly, when litigation causes difficulties in entering into mergers or
acquisitions, transacting into large equity infusion or effects the cost of
capital the hidden costs can dwarf the expense of pursuing a claim.
60 I thank Abigail C. Field for her assistance with this section. Her many insights have been invaluable to its development.
Maya Steinitz, Pricing Legal Claim, 16 VAND. L. REV 1890, 1903-1906 (2013) spp. and especially
the literature review nn. 56-89. See also, Jonathan T. Molot, A Market In Litigation Risk, 76 U. CHI.
L. REV 367 (2009).
61
62
A note on individual plaintiffs: While beyond the scope of this paper, individuals have
an access to justice problem as well as a problem in valuing legal claims and receiving
accounting and tax benefits on causes of action and pending litigation, as opposed to on
damages they received. These are beyond the scope of this paper but I hope to see
others investigate them.
Jonathan Molot introduced a similar idea in the defense context dubbing it the “tertiary cost” of
litigation and concluded the solution was a market in legal defenses:
63
“[I]n some instances, litigation’s largest expense may stem from the ‘tertiary’ effects that
pending litigation may have on litigant conduct. A $50 million lawsuit against a company
can easily prevent that company from raising $250 million or even $500 million in debt
or equity to finance new, productive business activities. At the very least, the uncertainty
surrounding a significant potential liability may increase a company’s cost of capital by
depressing its stock price or increasing the interest rate it must pay on its debt. Where
litigation risk interferes with an equity investment, a debt refinancing, or a merger or
acquisition the tertiary costs of litigation can dwarf the primary costs.”
A Market In Legal Claims at 374 -75. For empirical work on the effects of litigation on a
company’s stock price see David M. Cutler & Lawrence H. Summers, The Costs of Conflict
Resolution and Financial Distress: Evidence from the Texaco-Pennzoil Litigation, RAND J. OF
ECON., Vol. 19, No. 2, pp. 157-172, (Summer 1988) (estimating that the Texaco-Pennzoil litigation had reduced the combined equity value of the two companies by about $2
billion and that further losses may have been incurred by Texaco’s bondholders).
DRAFT—DO NOT QUOTE
20
M. STEINITZ
In addition, corporations, which are generally conservative about suing, currently are experiencing value destruction in the form of un-prosecuted claims. These too should be included in any analysis of the hidden
cost of litigation to the extent that claims are not prosecuted because of
the difficulty in ascertaining value, the difficulty in ascertaining the likelihood of success prosecuting meritorious claims, negative accounting
treatment during claim conduct or unfavorable tax treatment. Potential
corporate plaintiffs face a decision to dedicate significant sums to cover
litigation fees and costs in return for an outcome that is uncertain.64 The
larger the potential recovery, the higher usually are the costs of pursuing
the litigation and with those the larger the down-side risk and the opportunity costs. Often, the funds required to pursue litigation can be employed by the company with less risk on other activities such as operations
or marketing.
Even where valuation is straight forward, accounting treatment
can be unfavorable from the plaintiff corporation’s perspective, deterring
the corporation from bring meritorious claims. For starters, all the costs
of litigating are accounted for as expenses, a negative impact that particularly hurts EBITDA businesses.65 Next, accounting rules do not allow
recognition of the potential upside while the claim is pending. The Financial Accounting Standards Board (“FASB”) prohibits evaluating and listing a claim as an asset on a balance sheet.66 In addition, as paradigmatic
examples of gain contingency,67 pending court cases and legal claims can-
64
Id.
See Financial Acumen--Taking Litigation Off the Balance Sheet, BURFORD,
http://www.burfordcapital.com/casestudies/financial-acumen-taking-litigation-offthe-corporate-balance-sheet/#sthash.ppJmSBlw.dpuf. (last visited Mar. 21, 2013)
66 Selvyn Seidel & Sandra Sherman, Corporate Governance Issues regarding “Stock Price Manipulation” and “Insider Trading”, (and other matters) are coming to in Third Party Financing, (forthcoming) (discussing FIN. ACCOUNTING STANDARDS BD. No. 5).
67 Defined in FASB ASC 450 “an existing condition, situation, or set of circumstances
involving uncertainty as to possible gain (referred to as a ‘gain contingency’)… to an
enterprise that will ultimately be resolved when one or more future events occur or fail
to occur.”
65
DRAFT
7/15/2014]
INCORPORATING LEGAL CLAIMS
21
not be recognized in the income statement of a company until all contingencies have been resolved.68 Last, even when a claim is resolved favorably, the accounting is not helpful, particularly for EBITDA businesses, as
the income must be listed as a non-recurring item.69
The accounting difficulties are likely the reason why banks do not
consider legal cases to be assets and why they do not lend based on the
value of contingent fees, no matter how large the potential contingency:70
Most business can turn to banks for help, but law firms
are often stuck. Banks don’t consider legal cases to be assets and won’t lend based on the value of ‘contingent fees’
since there’s no guarantee of getting them. So the only way
to get a bank loan is for the partners to borrow money
personally or use their credit cards.
But besides being costly and putting the partners’ own
money and assets at risk, the interest on personal loans is
not tax deductible. Also, until the case is finished, attorneys can’t deduct the enormous legal case expenses that
are incurred.71
In addition, banks do not invest in litigation financing because it
is financing provided upfront with no expected cash flow for an extended
period of time.72 Last but not least, funding litigation can pose business
conflicts for banks. This problem on the plaintiff side is analogous to the
difficulty that litigation poses to defendants’ ability to raise debt and equity.
Sovereigns, domestic as well as foreign, are another type of sophisticated owner of large-scale claims that face the same kind of analysis
68
[Accounting for Contingencies at 2]. Disclosure of such gain contingencies can be
made when the probability that it will be realized are high but “care should be exercised
to avoid misleading implications as to the likelihood of realization.” Id. Consequently,
“it is unusual to find information about contingent gains in [a] financial statement." Id.
69 See supra note Error! Bookmark not defined..
70 See Jonathan D. Epstein, An Unusual Financial Niche: Lending Money to Lawyers, BUFFALO NEWS, Sept. 30, 2007, at C1. See also, Ben Winograd, Specialized Lenders Help Fill
Financing Void for Law Firms, AM. BANKER, Nov. 2, 2006, at 3 (“No matter how large
the potential verdict, banks generally will not make loans beyond the existing assets of a
firm or its attorneys.”) Both discussed in Nora Freeman Engstrom, LAWYER LENDING: COSTS AND CONSEQUENCES (forthcoming) at n.56.
71 See Epstein, supra note 70. See also, Winograd, supra note 70.
72 I thank Victor Goldberg for this comment.
DRAFT—DO NOT QUOTE
22
M. STEINITZ
when having to decide whether to pursue litigation. In addition, such decisions are subject to public scrutiny and using public funds to pursue
speculative litigation may not be a popular decision. Here, the value destroyed from having to forgo litigation is a foregone public resource.
The reconceptualization of legal claims as assets that the American legal world is currently undergoing, combined with (i) the newfound
purchasing power of corporations and their consequent ability to lower
their legal costs73; and (ii) a solution to the problem of the hidden costs,
may all combine to a new reality in which corporate and sovereign plaintiffs are able to monetize the value of all their meritorious legal claims,
rather than forgo some.
While the existence of hard-to-value litigation that actually threatens M&A is an unusual situation, it arose several times in the 1990s, and
some innovative lawyers correctly concluded that incorporating and trading in legal claims through the use of securities74 would help their clients
overcome the hidden costs. Those are most of the deals described below.
There is some evidence that these deals are not sui generis. For example,
preceding the Winstar deals described below were deals by banks which
“had established trusts for shareholders, assigning them contingent rights
in litigation.”75 All of these legal innovations operate in a similar legal gray
73
See Jonathan D. Glater, Billable Hours Giving Ground at Law Firms, N.Y. TIMES, Jan. 30,
2009, at A1, available at 2009 WLNR 1784153 (“‘Clients are more concerned about the
budgets, more so than perhaps a year or two ago.’” (quoting Evan R. Chesler, presiding
partner, Cravath, Swain & Moore LLP)).
74 On issuing securities as a mechanism for litigation funding for reasons other than those discussed herein, see A Model Litigation Funding Contract, supra note 16. There, a co-author and I suggested issuing Litigation Proceed Rights, a kind of privately placed, heavily restricted security, in
order to implement the idea that litigation finance can be modeled on venture capital. In that
context start-up companies issues securities that compensate the venture capitalists for their investment. We suggested that, just as in venture capital, securities can be used to effectuate staged
funding which allows for minimizing the extreme uncertainty, information asymmetry and agency
costs that characterize litigation as an investment. While we did not use the incorporation paradigm
to describe that security, the deal we proposed would constitute a “loose incorporation” of the
claim. Professor Richard Painter commented on some of the securities laws implications of using
such securities. See Richard Painter, The Model Contract and The Securities Laws, Part I-IV, A MODEL
LITIGATION FINANCE CONTRACT, supra note 16.
See Margaret Cronin Fisk, ‘Winstar’ Litigants Bet on Future Damages Awards, NATIONAL LAW
JOURNAL, Jan. 11, 1999, at A19 (going on to note that “this was rare, and you couldn’t buy or
sell these rights” (quoting Victor Lewkow, partner, Cleary, Gottlieb, Steen & Hamilton LLP)).
Another early financial instrument tied to litigation proceeds were the Tabaco settlement bonds.
These too implicated the issues of control and conflicts of interests. See, e.g. Jody Sindelar and
Tracy Falba, Securitization of Tobacco Settlement Payments to Reduce States’ Conflict of Interest, HealthAffairs, July (“the issue [raised by securitization] is lack of commitment to tobacco control by states.
Further, securitization can mitigate states’ conflict of interest between keeping tobacco companies
fiscally healthy to ensure their [Master Settlement Agreement] payments and reducing tobacco
75
DRAFT
7/15/2014]
INCORPORATING LEGAL CLAIMS
23
zone as the financial innovation that is litigation finance, for the same
underlying reasons. Consequently, these efficient and commonsensical
market solutions seem to be very rarely used.76
This section describes litigation proceed-backed securities tied to six
claims, and then a litigation finance deal that involved regular corporate
securities as part of a secured lending litigation finance deal for a bankrupt
plaintiff. I classify the claim incorporation as ‘loose’ or ‘strict’, depending
on whether the plaintiff issues a security directly (loose) or the claim/right
to receive all proceeds of the claim are transferred to an SPV while the
litigation is pending, whether or not the SPV issues a litigation-backed
security. Each incorporation, whether loose or strict, is always coupled
with a formal allocation of control and ownership of the claim, as well as
a pre-emptive resolution of conflicts or a voting process by which such
conflicts are resolved.
Specifically, below are (1) examples of both strict and loose incorporation that arose from litigation against the federal government filed in
the mid- and late-1990s by failed or nearly failed Savings and Loans, collectively known as the Winstar cases, after the case name in the U.S. Supreme Court decision determining the government’s liability. The merger
pricing problem arose in a non-Winstar context too. Information Resources needed to spin off its anti-trust claim in order to complete a deal
in which it was acquired and taken private. (2) The Crystallex deal, which
involves that bankrupt company’s massive arbitration claim against Venezuela. (3) An example of a trust contemplated in connection with the
funding of transnational mass tort litigation known as the Chevron – Ecuador litigation. The trust incorporation contemplated in this funding arrangement would have been a strict incorporation.
sales for health reasons. States should not align with tobacco companies with the common interest
of keeping tobacco companies fiscally healthy”).
76 The author was only able to identify the Treca, Winstar, IR and the Crystallex examples. A
special thanks to Abigail C. Field for bringing to my attention the IR deal. In researching these
deals, I have found no instances in which such transactions ended up being challenged through
litigation on issues such as champerty. Two deals were involved in litigation, both while the plaintiff company in bankruptcy. The creditor status attached to being a Dime warrants holder was
litigated in Washington Mutual’s bankruptcy, as discussed below, and in the debtor-in-possession
financing deal for Crystallex, which was a litigation funding deal, was challenged by dissident
Crystallex bondholders who wanted the bankruptcy judge to accept their debtor-in-possession
financing deal instead. Neither litigation sought to void the transactions on the basis of litigation
finance concerns.
DRAFT—DO NOT QUOTE
24
M. STEINITZ
1. Loose and Strict Incorporation to Reduce Hidden Costs: the
Winstar Savings & Loans Litigations and Information Resources
In the 1980s, following the S&L crisis, the federal government
facilitated mergers between failing institutions and relatively healthier
ones. A crucial deal point was regulators’ blessing that ‘goodwill’ associated with the transactions could be counted as part of the merged S&L’s
required capital and written off over decades. In 1989, Congress enacted
the Financial Institutions Reform, Recovery, and Enforcement Act
(FIRREA), that attempted to both prevent future S&L failures and facilitate accountability for the one that had happened. One part of FIRREA
focused on making S&Ls sounder by forcing them to be better capitalized.77 One capitalization-related change imposed by FIRREA was that
the S&Ls were forced to write down the “supervisory goodwill” much
faster, with an immediate and major impact on the balance sheets of the
merged companies. Many such companies sued the federal government
on both breach of contract and constitutional bases.
In its July, 1996 decision upholding the government’s liability on
the breach of contract claims,78 the U.S. Supreme Court gave this recitation of the history:
The impact of FIRREA’s new capital requirements upon institutions that had acquired failed thrifts in exchange for supervisory
goodwill was swift and severe… Despite the statute’s limited exception intended to moderate transitional pains, many institutions
immediately fell out of compliance with regulatory capital requirements, making them subject to seizure by thrift regulators. 79
Three S&Ls were involved in that case, and the claim of one of
them, Glendale Federal Bank, became the focus of one of the litigation
securities discussed herein. As the Court noted:
77
See United States v. Winstar Corp., 518 U.S. 839, 857 (U.S. 1996).
78 Glendale filed its suit in 1990 and won its partial summary judgment motion on the contract
claims in 1992. See Glendale Federal Awarded Damages in Supervisory Goodwill Suit Vs. U.S. Government,
BUSINESS WIRE, April 9, 1999. The government won its appeal to the Federal Circuit, but Glendale
won an en banc rehearing in August 1995. Winstar Corp. v. United States, 64 F.3d 1531 (Fed. Cir.
1995).
79
United States v. Winstar Corp., 518 U.S. 839, 857-58 (U.S. 1996).
DRAFT
7/15/2014]
INCORPORATING LEGAL CLAIMS
25
Respondents Glendale Federal Bank, FSB, Winstar Corporation,
and The Statesman Group, Inc., acquired failed thrifts in 1981,
1984, and 1988, respectively. After the passage of FIRREA, federal regulators seized and liquidated the Winstar and Statesman
thrifts for failure to meet the new capital requirements. Although
the Glendale thrift also fell out of regulatory capital compliance as
a result of the new rules, it managed to avoid seizure through a
massive private recapitalization. 80
Importantly, while Winstar established the idea that the government could be liable—and was liable to Glendale, whose parent Golden
State Bancorp eventually issued securities tied to that litigation—the various S&L deals involved different language and facts and thus liability
could not be assumed in all S&L cases. Thus, when Cal Fed, Dime, and
Coast Federal issued litigation proceeds-based securities, as discussed below, liability in those cases had not been determined. Only Golden State’s
security issuance was founded on established liability.81 In fact, when Cal
Fed issued its securities, the Winstar Supreme Court decision quoted
above had not yet been issued. These deals thus highlight that the tremendous risk inherent in litigation, particularly early stage litigation, is not itself a bar to issuing securities, even ones that trade on public markets.
Because Cal Fed was the first issuer, I begin with its deal.
A. Loose Incorporation in the Cal Fed litigation: Participation
Right Certificates
The Cal Fed case arose from its acquisition of four thrifts in 1982
and 1983.82 Cal Fed filed suit in 1992, but its case was stayed while the
Winstar cases were litigated. In July 1995, prior to the U.S. Supreme Court
80 Id. With regard to Glendale, it agreed to take over a failed Florida thrift in 1981 and regulators
allowed it to offset bad loans with “supervisory goodwill” that it would then write off over the
next 40 years. When FIRREA passed, Glendale Federal still had $565 million in supervisory goodwill remaining. To compensate for the FIRREA requirements, Glendale said it was forced to decrease its assets by more than $10 billion. See Deborah Adamson, Glenfed Parent Announces Earnings
Up, Trading Plan Byline, DAILY NEWS OF L.A., October 29, 1997.
81
See Coast S-4 “The Litigation—Related Cases” at [SEC page 17 / internal page no. 11].
U.S. Court of Appeals Rules Golden State Bancorp May Seek Damages For Lost Profits In Cal Fed Supervisory Goodwill Case, BUSINESS WIRE, April 3, 2001.
82
DRAFT—DO NOT QUOTE
26
M. STEINITZ
decision in Winstar, Cal Fed issued the first of two securities (“Participation Right Certificates”) related to its supervisory goodwill claim.83 These
Participation Right Certificates entitled holders to a share of approximately 25% of the net proceeds if ever realized,84 and were issued directly
by Cal Fed, with Cal Fed retaining control of the claim. Thus the Participation Right Certificates represent a partial, and “loose” incorporation of
Cal Fed’s claim.
The first Cal Fed issuance was not done to solve a hidden cost
problem; some speculated it was done purely to line the pockets of the
executives and directors at the expense of shareholders.85 Nonetheless the
market price of that first security was used to value the claim when Cal
Fed entered a merger agreement with First Nationwide Holdings, and the
second litigation security was issued as part of the terms of that merger to
resolve the hidden cost problem.86 That second security was similar to the
first, in that holders were entitled to a fraction of any net cash recovery
after other claims, such as those of the first security’s holders, had been
paid. Because both securities were redeemable for cash, they had negative
tax consequences for the shareholders who initially received them.87 Both
securities traded on the NASDAQ.
From both a champerty and privilege waiver perspective, it is nigh
impossible to see an issue created by Cal Fed’s approach. From the champerty perspective, all that has happened is that shareholders were given
something they were always entitled to—the right to receive the value of
83
California Federal Bank Goodwill Participation Securities Declared Effective; Record Date Set, PR NEWSJune 28, 1995.
WIRE,
84
Id.
Kurt Eichenwald, INVESTING IT: INVESTMENT GRADES; No Toasters at This Bank. It’s
Giving Away a Lawsuit, N.Y. TIMES, March 26, 1995. (also explaining that “if markets work the way
they should, for every penny the shareholders receive in this new security, they should lose a like
amount in their Cal Fed shares… Some Cal Fed executives say they don't buy that. Instead, they
assert that, by shedding 25 percent of a potential asset, the share price of the company could
actually go up. The way the logic goes, creating the new security could force the market to come
to grips with the possible value of a lawsuit once kissed off as negligible.”)
85
For the valuation of the suit using the first security’s trading value, see the unaudited pro forma
financial data reflecting the financial condition of the proposed merged company at page P-4 attached to the AMENDED AND RESTATED AGREEMENT AND PLAN OF MERGER dated July 27, 1996,
filed as an exhibit to the 8-K announcing the closing of the merger filed with the SEC on January
3, 1997. For a discussion of the secondary security issued as part of the merger, see Article I of the
Merger Agreement.
86
See Nantahala Capital Partners, LP v. Wash. Mut., Inc. (In re Wash. Mut., Inc.), 464 B.R. 656
(Bankr. D. Del. 2012) (Discussing the development of litigation tracking warrants to avoid the
taxation issue posed by certificates that could be redeemed for cash.) See also Ferve Ozturk,
Nantahala: Litigation Tracking Warrants Are Equity, Not Debt 31-4 ABIJ 22 May 2012.
87
DRAFT
7/15/2014]
INCORPORATING LEGAL CLAIMS
27
the claim. True, by trading the certificates to people who were not shareholders of Cal Fed, investors who were ‘strangers’ to the litigation stood
to profit if the litigation were successful. Nonetheless they had not actually
financed the litigation; Cal Fed did not receive payment in those transactions. Finally, no claim transfer occurred; the plaintiff retained full control
of its litigation. From a privilege perspective, the company simply did not
reveal any privileged information to shareholders or certificate holders,
and no funder or other party was inserted into the attorney client relationship.88
The Cal Fed-First Nationwide merger closed in January, 1997.
Later that year Cal Fed began merger talks with Golden State, setting in
motion that S&L’s spinoff of its Winstar litigation, discussed below. Cal
Fed was the surviving company in that transaction, which closed in 1998.
That year Cal Fed’s litigation securities were trading as high as $16-$17.89
In April, 1999 the court awarded Cal Fed a mere $23 million, and the
certificates plummeted in value.90
In 2002, Citigroup acquired Cal Fed, and thus it absorbed both
Cal Fed’s goodwill claim and Golden State’s, and their related securities
obligations.91 In October, 2005 the $23 million Cal Fed judgment became
final when the U.S. Supreme Court denied cert. As a result, Citi notified
the Cal Fed certificate holders they would get nothing.92
B. Loose incorporation by Golden State: Litigation Tracking
Warrants
In 1997 Glendale Federal’s parent, Golden State Bancorp, announced its intention to merge with Cal Fed Bancorp. In October, 1997,
88 Disclosure is one of the interesting challenges regarding claim-based securities. While these deals
suggest the securities laws’ command to disclose material information can be met without disclosing privileged information, it is possible to imagine a claim that involves privileged information
that investors would find material if they knew it to exist. On the possible operation of securities
regulation see Wendy Couture, Securities Regulation of Alternative Litigation Finance, (forthcoming).
Paul Sweeney, INVESTING; How to Win Big in Court And Never See a Lawyer, N.Y. TIMES November 1, 1998, § 3, at 10, Col. 5. (at the time of the article, the first issuance traded at $16.125
and the second one traded at $17.75).
89
90 Richard B Schmitt, Investors Betting On Judgment For Thrift Take A Hit In California Federal Ruling,
WALL ST. J., April 20, 1999, at B11.
Laura Mandaro, In Brief: Citi Closes Purchase of California Federal (Citigroup Inc. acquires California
Federal Bank) (Brief Article), AM. BANKER, Nov. 15, 2002.
91
Citibank (West), FSB, Announces Supreme Court Action in California Federal Bank v. United States, BUS.
WIRE, Oct. 4, 2005.
92
DRAFT—DO NOT QUOTE
28
M. STEINITZ
while negotiations were ongoing, Golden State declared it would issue
Litigation Tracking Warrants (warrants, LTWs or Golden LTWs) tied to
the Glendale claim. The Golden LTWs were a ‘loose incorporation’ of the
Glendale claim because they were issued by Golden State instead of a
Special Purpose Vehicle (SPV). Control of the litigation remained with
Golden State. If the Glendale claim ever resulted in proceeds, the warrants
allowed holders to purchase shares of Golden State common stock with
an aggregate value pegged to the value of the proceeds received. The
spinoff of the Glendale claim was done this way instead of via CalFedlike certificates that could be redeemed for cash to avoid the income tax
consequences of the CalFed approach.93
The warrants were issued to solve the hidden cost problem.
Golden State asserted the claim’s value was $1.5 billion, a number that
would be material in many deals even today. 94 The Chairman of Cal Fed
explained that the “two sides had been unable to agree on how much
Glendale is really worth once the anticipated damages on its goodwill suit
against the federal government are factored out of its stock price.”95 The
warrants gave the companies a “market mechanism” to resolve the dispute, namely a “collar.”96 Specifically, if “Glendale’s stock is worth $32 or
less in a specified period after the goodwill litigation tracking warrants
have been issued, its shareholders get 55% of the combined company. At
$33 or more, they get 58% of the company.”97 Market analysts reacted
favorably:
“[According to analysts,] the warrants make it easier for the thrift
to be taken over since it separates the company’s legal claims
against the government from the company’s core business because it certainly removes a major stumbling block in the event of
See Wash. Mut., Inc., 464 B.R. 656; See also Ferve Ozturk, Nantahala: Litigation Tracking Warrants
Are Debt, Not Equity 31-4 ABIJ 22 May 2012.
93
In its pleadings, Glendale asserted damages of $1.5 billion, and indeed publicized its offer to
settle for that amount a month after announcing its intention to issue the warrants. See Brad Finkelstein & Brian Collins, Glendale Offers to Settle its Goodwill Lawsuit, NAT’L MORTG. NEWS, Dec. 1,
1997, at 17.
94
Snigdha Prakash, Despite Deal's Complexities, CalFed Really Is the Buyer, AM. BANKER, Feb. 12, 1998,
at 22.
95
96
Id.
97
Id.
DRAFT
7/15/2014]
INCORPORATING LEGAL CLAIMS
29
an acquisition… Now we can value it on its earnings and franchise.” 98
The Litigation Tracking Warrants were issued in May, 1998 to
holders of Golden State common stock on a one-share, one LTW basis.99
If a ‘triggering event’ occurred, meaning, if sufficient litigation proceeds
were received, warrant holders were entitled to purchase Golden State
common stock for $1 per share up to an aggregate value of 85% of the
net proceeds. The remaining 15% were to be retained by Golden State.
The warrants came without voting rights, liquidation preferences, dividend or other distribution entitlements,100 and were freely tradable, registered on the NASDAQ.101 If Golden State underwent future mergers,
the LTWs would be exerciseable against the surviving company’s common stock on the same terms.102
How many shares could be purchased upon the receipt of sufficient proceeds to be a triggering event could only be determined at such
time as it involved two unknowns—first, the amount of net proceeds received, and second, the market price of Golden State stock.103
The prospectus is clear that Golden State owns and controls the
litigation:
[Golden State] will retain sole and exclusive control of the Litigation and will retain 100% of the proceeds of any recovery from
the Litigation. The Litigation will remain an asset of the Bank and
the Bank intends to pursue the Litigation with the same vigor as
98
Adamson, supra note80 (internal quotation marks omitted).
Golden State Bancorp Inc., Current Report (Form 8-K) (April 21, 1998) available at,
http://www.sec.gov/Archives/edgar/data/1019508/0000898430-98-001724.txt Golden State
Bancorp Inc., Current Report, (Form 8-K & Press Release) (May 5, 1998). Golden LTWs were
also held in reserve to be distributed to those who had the right to Golden State common stock
via convertible securities but had not yet exercised that right as of the record date. No other LTWs
were to be issued. See Warrant Agreement section 2.1, available at, http://www.sec.gov/Archives/edgar/data/1019508/0000898430-98-001506.txt, exhibit 3.
99
100
Id. at 9.
101Id.
at 4.
102
Id.
103
The formula is described in Golden State Bancorp Inc., PROSPECTUS, at 6 (May 22, 1998).
DRAFT—DO NOT QUOTE
30
M. STEINITZ
it has in the past. The Bank reserves the right, however, to terminate the Litigation in any manner it deems appropriate to serve
the Bank’s best interest. 104
Golden State was similarly clear that the resulting conflict between
it and the LTW holders was resolved in its favor:
The LTW(TM) Holders will not have any rights against the Company or the Bank for any decision regarding the conduct of the
Litigation or disposition of the Litigation for an amount less than
the amount it has claimed in damages in the ongoing trial in the
Claims Court, regardless of the effect on the value of the
LTW(TM)s. Although the Bank currently intends to continue
prosecuting the Litigation and to seek a cash recovery in the
amount claimed, there can be no assurance that the Bank will not
make a different determination in the future. 105
Perhaps to reassure LTW holders that the claim conduct would
be managed well, Golden State and Cal Fed entered a ‘litigation management agreement’ to govern the conduct of the two goodwill claims,
Golden State’s and Cal Fed’s.106 The litigation management agreement
created two committees of the board of directors, one for each of the
Glendale (Golden State) and Cal Fed cases, and vested in those committees the full power of the board of directors of the merged company in
each committee as regards the respective litigation. The litigation management agreement further provided that two Golden State executives with
knowledge of the underlying facts would be employed by the company as
‘Litigation Managers’ for both cases, reporting to both committees.107
Subject only to the ultimate authority of the committees, the Litigation
Managers could retain or fire counsel, hire agents, and take all steps appropriate relating to both litigations and the associated litigation securities.108
104
Id.
105
Id.
106
Golden State Bancorp Inc., Current Report, (Form 8-K Exhibit) (Feb. 17, 1998).
Litigation Management Agreement by and among the Registrant, Glendale Federal Bank, A
Federal Savings Bank, Stephen J. Trafton and Richard A. Fink Article I. The Cal Fed committee
had the power to reduce the Litigation Managers control of that case, but the Litigation Managers
would still be paid as if they were managing that case.
107
108
Id. Article II.
DRAFT
7/15/2014]
INCORPORATING LEGAL CLAIMS
31
Even though the Litigation Managers were to be employees of the
merged company (Executive Vice Presidents) reporting to committees of
the boards of directors, and even though the company owned the litigation and stood to receive substantial financial benefit from a successful
conclusion of both cases, including expense reimbursement and 15% of
the value of the proceeds, the litigation management agreement imposed
a duty to cooperate on the merged company.109 The litigation management
agreement further provided that the company would not merge or otherwise effect a change of control unless the rights of both the Litigation
Managers’ and the LTW holders were unaffected.110
Just as with the Cal Fed security, this loose incorporation approach poses no problems from either a champerty or privilege waiver
perspective. Indeed, with the LTWs the distance from champerty is even
greater, as the litigation proceeds are simply a reference number, like LIBOR, and do not have a direct connection to the securities. Golden State
retains the claim and 100% of its proceeds.
Because the legal claim was now reified—incorporated in the sense of
having a legal identity separate from the plaintiff—it not only solved the
merger pricing problem but rather the Golden State LTWs also forced a
change in the accounting of a second merger,111 had a role in the mechanics of a third merger,112 and were part of the consideration of the redemption of some preferred securities,113 all of which occurred before the Cal
Fed deal closed. The merger between Golden State and Cal Fed closed in
September 1998.114 Ultimately the litigation and the warrants tracking it
were assumed by Citigroup as part of its November, 2002 merger with
CalFed.115 As a result Golden LTWs became exerciseable for shares in Citi
if a triggering event occurred, which it did in 2005.
109
Id. at 2.2.
110
Id. at 3.1(a).
Golden State Bancorp Announces Change in Accounting for Acquisition of CENFED Financial Corp.,
BUS. WIRE, Jan. 27, 1998.
111
See California: News And Insight On Business In The Golden State; The State / Banking; Golden State
Bancorp Plans Stock Buyback Byline, L.A. TIMES, May 20, 1998, at D2.
112
113
Golden State Bancorp to Redeem Series A Preferred Stock, August 19, 1998.
114
California Federal Bank and Glendale Federal Bank Complete Merger, BUSINESS. WIRE, Sep. 11, 1998.
Laura Mandaro, In Brief: Citi Closes Purchase Of California Federal (Citigroup Inc. acquires California
Federal Bank) (Brief Article), AM. BANKER, Nov. 15, 2002.
115
DRAFT—DO NOT QUOTE
32
M. STEINITZ
On March 15, 2005 the government paid Citi $381,538,695 to satisfy
damage and costs judgments in the Golden State/Glendale litigation.
Those proceeds, after netting, resulted in an Adjusted Litigation Recovery
of $153,776,991.116 The impact of costs and taxes is clear: 85% of the gross
proceeds would have been $324,307,890.75, more than double the
amount the LTW holders were entitled to. In the end, each LTW was
exercisable for 0.02302 share of common stock of Citigroup and $0.6725
in cash, with the result that Citi would distribute up to 1,944,415 shares
of Citigroup common stock and $56,802,378, depending on how many
LTWs were redeemed.117 The total cash value of each LTW on the day
the distribution was determined was $1.7931,118 which compares favorably
with the $1.38-$1.75 trading range of the LTWs in the first quarter of
2005.119 However that amount was well below the $6 and 11/16 valuation
on the close the first day of trading after issuance.120 The initial, much
higher valuation in 1998 and the very close to accurate valuation in 2005
demonstrate the impact of information challenges on litigation valuation.
Early in the litigation—but after an initial liability determination—the
market price wildly overstated the securities’ value. But when sufficient
information was revealed—by the quarter prior to claim resolution—the
litigation was more accurately valued through a market mechanism.
C. Loose Incorporation in the Dime/Anchor Savings litigation:
Litigation Tracking Warrants
Anchor Saving’s claim was based on eight acquisitions of failing S&Ls
in 1982-85, four of which were facilitated by regulators.121 When FIRREA
was enacted in 1989, Anchor’s books still carried over $500 million of
related capital, including the ‘goodwill.’ As a result, Anchor claimed it
Citigroup Inc., Prospectus Supplement (Sept. 2, 2004), available at http://www.sec.gov/Archives/edgar/data/831001/000104746905009106/a2154892z424b3.htm.
116
117Citigroup
Announces That the 60-Day Exercise Period for Its Litigation Tracking Warrants Commenced
Today, BUSINESS WIRE, April 5, 2005.
118
Citigroup Inc., supra n. 90, at S-6.
119
Id. at S-3.
120
In Brief: Warrants Fall, DAILY NEWS OF L.A., May 6, 1998.
WASHINGTON MUTUAL: Goodwill Lawsuit Over 4 Acquisitions Pending, LLOYD'S CORP. LITIG.
REP, .Oct. 3, 2008.
121
DRAFT
7/15/2014]
INCORPORATING LEGAL CLAIMS
33
faced severe limitations on its activities and was forced to liquidate valuable assets at fire-sale prices.122 In 1994, Anchor and Dime Savings Bank
agreed to merge. In January, 1995 Anchor filed the suit against the government. Shortly thereafter, the merger closed, and as a result of the merger, Dime became entitled to the proceeds.123 Because filing the claim did
not disrupt the merger pricing previously negotiated by Anchor and
Dime, Anchor had no motivation to issue litigation securities at that point.
However, a later deal did face the pricing problem.
In early 2000, North Fork Bank attempted a hostile takeover
Dime. Dime found a white knight in Warburg Pincus. As Dime and Warburg did not agree on the value of the litigation, that major equity investment faced the hidden cost issue. As a result, Dime issued Litigation
Tracking Warrants on December 29, 2000.124 Again, because these were
issued directly by Dime they represent a “loose” incorporation. Dime retained control of the litigation. The Anchor/Dime LTWs were conceptually similar to the Golden State LTWs and were similarly worth stock
representing 85% of the net recovery. Also like the Golden State LTWs,
the Dime LTWs traded on the NASDAQ and, because of merger, were
ultimately redeemable for shares in a different company than Dime.
In 2001 Dime announced its intention to merge with Washington Mutual, and that deal closed in 2002.125 Not much happened until 2008, when
the trial court awarded $356 million in damages.126 The decision was appealed.127 Later in 2008, regulators seized WaMu and sold most of its assets to JPM Chase.128 The hollowed out parent company filed for bankruptcy the next day.129 In 2010 the appeals court remanded for further
WASHINGTON MUTUAL: Broadbill Asserts Claim Over Breach of Contract, 14 TROUBLED CO.
REP., May 28, 2010.
122
123
Id.
See Warburg Pincus, Dime Announces Major Investment, BUS. WIRE, July 6, 2000; Randi Feigenbaum & Tami Luhby, Dime's Move May Quash Rival's Bid, NEWSDAY (N.Y.), July 7, 2000, at A55.
See Dime Announces Distribution of Litigation Tracking Warrants, BUS. WIRE, Dec. 18, 2000.
124
125 See Washington Mutual to Extend National Banking Franchise With $5.2 Billion Merger With Dime
Bancorp, BUS. WIRE, June 25, 2001; Washington Mutual Completes Acquisition of Dime Bancorp, BUS.
WIRE, January 7, 2002.
See WASHINGTON MUTUAL: Court Declares LTWs as Equity, Not Debt 16 TROUBLED CO.
REP February 9, 2012.
126
127
Id.
128
Id.
129
Id.
DRAFT—DO NOT QUOTE
34
M. STEINITZ
damage calculations, suggesting the damages should be $63 million
more.130
Shortly thereafter LTW holders began negotiating with the WaMu estate. One group decided to settle, and received some cash, some stock in
a reorganized WaMu, and some “Run-off Notes”.131 Other LTW holders
sued, seeking a declaration of their rights and creditor status above equity
holders. In 2012 the court ruled the LTWs were equity, and the litigating
LTW holders were assigned such status and their related claims subordinated.132 As a result of that decision, $337 million in proceeds were released into the estate.133
D. Strict Incorporation in the Coast Savings litigation: Trust
Certificates
Coast Savings Financial took over the failed Central Savings and
Loan Association from regulators in 1987, in a deal that involved a $298
million ‘capital credit’ that was wiped out by FIRREA in 1989.134 Coast
filed its goodwill claim in July, 1992.135 The litigation was stayed while the
Glendale/Winstar litigation went all the way to the U.S. Supreme Court,
and was not scheduled to be tried until 1999 at the earliest.136 However,
in 1997 Coast began negotiating merger terms with H. F. Ahmanson &
Co.
Again, litigation’s valuation difficulty created hidden costs. As part
of the merger agreement executed in October 1997, Coast Savings announced it would spinoff the value of its claim immediately pre-merger.
Coast effectuated its claim spinoff via a “strict” incorporation approach:
it created a trust to receive the value of the claim, the trustees of which
130
Id.
L. John Bird, Decision in Washington Mutual, Inc. holds that litigation tracking warrants are equity instruments, ASS’N OF CORP. COUNSEL, Feb. 23, 2012, http://www.lexology.com/library/detail.aspx?g=3f6bcffd-8198-492c-9677-4ea62b7434e8. June 19, 2012.
131
Nantahala Capital Partners, LP v. Washington Mut., Inc. (In re Washington Mut., Inc.), 464
B.R. 656 (Bankr. D. Del. 2012).
132
WASHINGTON MUTUAL: Judge Approves Deal With Warrant Holders 16 TROUBLED CO. REP.,
Mar. 12, 2012. (ISSN: 1520-9474).
133
Coast Federal Litig. Contingent Payment Rights Trust, Registration of Securities, Business
Combinations (Form S-4) at 11 (Jan. 13, 1998).
134
135
Id. at 10.
136 Id. at 12 explains that before the Coast trial could happen the Court of Claims had scheduled
several other S&L cases.
DRAFT
7/15/2014]
INCORPORATING LEGAL CLAIMS
35
controlled the litigation, and then the trust issued Contingent Payment
Right Certificates to Coast’s pre-merger shareholders.
The basic structure of the deal was as follows. A trust was formed
with certain powers, approximately $20 million (earmarked for litigation
expenses), and an asset called “the Commitment.” Securities embodying
the right to receive a part of payments made pursuant to the Commitment
were issued to existing Coast Savings shareholders. Coast Savings merged
into H.F. Ahmanson and Ahmanson, as successor to Coast Savings,
owned the claim and the right to receive the proceeds. If proceeds were
ever received, Ahmanson would be required by the Commitment to give
them to the trust. Monies received by the trust were to be paid to certificate holders, net of certain costs.
More specifically, on January 8, 1998 the Coast Federal Litigation
Contingent Payment Rights Trust (CPR Trust) was created, with the powers and limitations conferred upon it by an Amended and Restated Declaration of Trust signed by Coast Savings (as Sponsor), Bankers Trust
Company (as Trustee),137 and the CPR Trust (through its four Litigation
Trustees). On January 13, 1998 the CPR Trust registered Contingent Payment Rights Certificates (CPR Certificates) with the Securities and Exchange Commission. 138 On February 13, 1998, moments before the merger closed, Ahmanson entered the Commitment Agreement with the CPR
Trust, contributed approximately $20 million to the CPR Trust to fund
the Litigation, and the CPR Trust issued the CPR Certificates to Coast
shareholders.139
This transaction is the purest strict incorporation of a claim I have
found, although the Treca Trust (discussed below) would be equally pure
if it were ever created. That is because the Litigation Trustees were given
complete control of the claim; Ahmanson, which nominally owned the
Because the CPR Trust is a Delaware Statutory Trust, Banker’s Trust wears two trustee hats:
“Institutional Trustee” and “Delaware Trustee”. Banker’s Trust’s real power comes from its Institutional Trustee status. For simplicity I simply speak of “Trustee”.
137
Coast S-4, supra note 81, available
gar/data/1052801/0000950150-98-000043.txt
138
at
http://www.sec.gov/Archives/ed-
139 See [the deal documents re the steps]; for the date see e.g., Coast Litigation Trust Announces Judge's
Entry of Order Regarding Government Liability, PR NEWSWIRE, Mar. 25, 199. While innovative in being
used for litigation, contingent payment rights, as a financial instrument, are old. E.g., a U.S. Supreme Court case ruled on the correct tax treatment for a contingent payment right in 1931. See
David Hasen, Financial Options In The Real World: An Economic And Tax Analysis, 37 FLA. ST. U.L.
REV. 789, 797 (2010).
DRAFT—DO NOT QUOTE
36
M. STEINITZ
claim and showed it on its books, had none.140 Moreover, the trustees’
primary loyalty was to the trust, that is, to certificate holders, even at the
expense of Ahmanson, the claim owner.141 Thus in every sense except the
most formal, the CPR Trust embodied the claim.
While it is true that the litigation trustees were former executives
of Coast with knowledge of the litigation’s facts, putting them in charge
of the litigation in this manner, rather than via a management agreement
like Golden State entered, creates unnecessary issues under the legal ethics
paradigm.
From an ethics perspective the Coast Savings deal created an ambiguity as to whom litigation counsel represents: the trustees, who controlled the litigation and who had duties to maximize the claim’s monetary
value on behalf of certificate holders, or Ahmanson, who nominally
owned it? Similarly unclear is the implications of the answer to the latter
question to the application of the attorney-client privilege. Also, do the
trust and Ahmanson share a common legal interest that protects privilege
regardless of who the client actually is?142 And how should this structure
be viewed from the champerty perspective?
Ultimately, the Court of Claims entered a judgment of no damages
in 2001 so the CPR Certificates were worthless.143 The CPR Trust appealed and won at the Federal Circuit in 2002,144 but then the Government
sought and won a re-hearing en banc.145 In 2003 the full court upheld the
The Coast S-4/Prospectus explains at 15/11 under “Formation of the CPR Trust”: A more
detailed list of the Litigation Trustees’ power to control the litigation is in the Trust Agreement
appended to the prospectus at B-22 and B-23 “Article VI Management of the Litigation.”
140
141 The Trust Declaration states: “any attorneys, experts, advisors, consultants and investigators retained by or at the direction of the Litigation Trustees …shall be authorized by this Declaration to
accept directions from the Litigation Trustees with respect to the Litigation, notwithstanding any conflict of
interest that may arise by reason of such directions with the interests of any party to this Declaration. The
Litigation Trustees shall have no duty to [Coast/Ahmanson] to consider any interest [such entity] may have with
respect to the Litigation.” See Trust Declaration at Section 6.2(a) at B-23 (emphases added).
The Trust Declaration flatly states that communications among the trustees, Ahmanson and
counsel are privileged, see Section 6.2(a) on B-23, but parties cannot create privilege by agreement
where the law does not afford it.
142
Coast Litigation Trust Announces Claims Court Entry of Judgment for Government, PR NEWSWIRE, Oct.
29, 2001.
143
144
Coast Litigation Trust Announces Appellate Court Decision in Favor of Coast Federal Bank, PR NEWSOct. 9, 2002.
WIRE,
Coast Litigation Trust Announces Order Granting Government Petition For Rehearing of Appellate Court
Decision, PR NEWSWIRE, Feb. 15, 2003.
145
DRAFT
7/15/2014]
INCORPORATING LEGAL CLAIMS
37
Court of Claims’s judgment of no damages,146 and the CPR Trust decided
not to appeal to the U.S. Supreme Court.147 The CPR Trust terminated
and the CPR Certificates were de-listed on May 23, 2003.148
E. Strict Incorporation in the Information Resources Antitrust
Litigation: Contingent Value Rights
In July of 1996 Information Resources sued The Dun & Bradstreet Corp and others, alleging antitrust claims. Information Resources
alleged damages exceeding $350 million, prior to trebling.149 The suit came
nearly three months after the European Union had begun formal proceedings against the defendant for abusive practices. Three months after
the suit was filed, the defendant entered into an agreement with the European Union to end its abusive practices.150 A trial was scheduled for
September, 2004.151 However, in 2003 Information Resources was negotiating a merger with Gingko Corporation and the litigation posed the
hidden cost problem.
To solve the problem, Information Resources formed a special
purpose [statutory] trust which issued ‘Rights Certificates’ tied to the proceeds of the antitrust claim. Unlike the Coast deal, however, Information
Resources did not transfer control of the claim to the trust. As a result it
is more accurate to say the trust received the monetary value of the claim
rather than the claim. In some jurisdictions, the distinctions between (a)
transferring the value of the claim versus the claim itself and/or (b) transferring control over the claim versus the value of the claim differentiated
between a void champertous transaction and a valid non-champertous
transaction.152 Instead, a separate contract governed the conduct of the
claim. Under that contract the company that survived the merger (and
146
Coast Litigation Trust Announces Appellate Court En Banc Decision in Favor of Government, PR NEWSMar. 25, 2003.
WIRE,
147 Coast Litigation Trust
Announces Decision Not to Seek Supreme Court Review and Termination of Litigation,
PR NEWSWIRE, April 24, 2003.
148 Coast Litigation Trust Announces Termination of Designation of CPR Certificates for Trading on NASDAQ
and Termination of the Trust, PR NEWSWIRE, May 23, 2003.
Info. Res. Litig Contingent Pymt Rights Trust, Registration of Securities, Business Combinations, (Form S-4), at 8 (Sept. 8, 2003).
149
150
Id. at 17.
151
Id. at 2.
E.g., New York distinguishes, at least to some extent, between claim transfer and claim proceed
transfer. See Model Litigation Finance Contract at [xx].
152
DRAFT—DO NOT QUOTE
38
M. STEINITZ
thus owned the claim) retained control of the settlement decision as well
as influence over major strategic choices. Nonetheless, executives from
the pre-merger claim owner retained significant influence over major strategic decisions.
The Information Resources transaction was a more complicated
deal overall than the CPR Trust, largely because several investors/companies were coming together to form a company that would merge into
the publicly traded Information Resources and take it private. Thus there
were more parties and more steps to the overall transaction. In addition,
the privately held status of the surviving company and the newness of the
trust created in the deal meant that the certificates it issued could not be
listed on the NASDAQ, although they were tradable over the counter.153
(Complicating the discussion of the deal further, the surviving entity retained the name “Information Resources” while becoming a wholly
owned subsidiary of Gingko. To facilitate this discussion, when speaking
of the post-merger entity, I use the term ‘pmIR’; pre-merger, it is simply
‘IR’; and because the trust was created and certificates issued pre-merger,
they are the ‘IR Trust’ and the ‘IR Rights Certificates.’)
The most important aspect of the IR deal, for the purposes of
expanding the analysis of how claim incorporation can address the ethical
issues raised by litigation finance is how the deal addressed control of the
litigation. Thus the agreement laying out those terms will be the focus of
the discussion below.
Within our narrow focus, certain core elements of the deal are the
same: A Delaware statutory trust was created via Declaration (IR Trust
Agreement) among the acquirer, target, trust and three trustee types—
litigation, institutional, and Delaware. The main asset of the trust was the
merged company’s parent’s contractual commitment to pay proceeds of
the litigation. The trust was given an initial endowment by the acquiring
company to fund the litigation, after which the trust had to raise funds on
its own by selling certificates or borrowing funds.154 The litigation itself
was “owned” by the acquiring company and appeared on its books as a
contingent asset.155 The trust issued the certificates immediately before the
merger closed, the certificates were tradable but highly speculative and
See SEC Declares Registration Statement for CVRs Effective; CVRS to Be Quoted on OTC Bulletin Board
on Completion of the Offer for Information Resources, Inc. by Gingko Acquisition Corp., PR NEWSWIRE October 30, 2003.
153
154
Info. Res. Litig Contingent Pymt Rights Trust, supra note 149 at 3.
155
Id. at 15.
DRAFT
7/15/2014]
INCORPORATING LEGAL CLAIMS
39
came with very limited rights. And, if the claim was successful, the certificates could be redeemed for cash based on the amount of net proceeds
received.156
However, the control of the litigation is crucially different than in
the Coast deal. Under Coast Savings, the Litigation Trustees controlled
the litigation, and conflicts with the claim owner were resolved in favor
of the trust. In contrast, the IR Litigation Trustees were only empowered
to raise funds for the litigation by selling more certificates or borrowing
money; to enforce the Contingent Value Rights Agreement and the IR
Trust Agreement; to ensure the IR Trust’s compliance with the securities
laws; and to undertake various trust/certificates related tasks. 157 To manage the litigation, the parties entered into a contingent value rights agreement (“rights agreement”) that both governed the conduct of the litigation and contained Ginko’s promise to pay the trust when/if litigation
proceeds came in. 158
The rights agreement provided that five rights agents would manage the litigation.159 Two would be appointed by IR (the “CVR Rights
Agents”), two by Gingko (the “Parent Rights Agents”), and one chosen
by the other four (the “Independent Rights Agent”). The rights agreement
explains the breadth of the control granted:
(c) The Rights Agents shall have the sole power and duty to direct
and supervise all matters involving the Litigation (including trial strategy and planning and settlement strategy) on behalf of Parent, the
Company, the Company Subsidiaries and their Affiliates; provided
that all decisions and determinations with respect to the Litigation (including, without limitation, any Settlement Decision or Strategic Decision) shall be made in accordance with Section 3.1(d) hereof. 160
And that as a general matter, the appointees of IR—the original,
pre-merger plaintiff—will have day to day litigation management:
156
Summary- The Contingent Value Rights Agreement, Id. at 1.
157
Id. at A-13-14.
See
the
IR
Prospectus,
available
at
http://www.sec.gov/Archives/edgar/data/1260946/000104746903034778/a2119115zs-4a.htm.
158
159 See generally the form of Contingent Value Rights Agreement appended to the Prospectus as
Exhibit B at Article III-The Rights Agents at B-11.
160
Rights Agreement 3.1(c) at B-11.
DRAFT—DO NOT QUOTE
40
M. STEINITZ
Either one or both of the CVR Rights Agents (as they may mutually
decide in their discretion) shall have primary responsibility for the dayto-day direction and supervision of the Litigation and may, without
the approval of any of Parent, the Company, the Company Subsidiaries or any of the other Rights Agents, make decisions and determinations in accordance with Section 3.1(d) hereof with respect to the dayto-day conduct of the Litigation and such decisions shall be deemed
to made on behalf of all of the Rights Agents.161
Nonetheless, the rights agreement explained, the two IR appointees/CVR Rights Agents’ power was not unlimited because certain decisions required the approval of at least three of the five rights agents:
Notwithstanding the foregoing, (i) the approval of a majority of the
Rights Agents (including the Independent Rights Agent) shall be required for any Strategic Decision and (ii) the approval of a majority of
the Rights Agents (other than the Independent Rights Agent) shall be
required for any Settlement Decision;162
That is, for “Strategic Decisions” either the Independent or Parent
Rights Agents could provide the third vote, but for settlement decisions,
the Parent Rights Agents had to agree. Through this majoritarian provision the claim owner, the parent, is retaining ultimate control of the litigation. This delegation of authority is akin to the way legal ethics allow
attorneys to make day to day decisions for their clients, but unlike legal
ethics—and like business entities—it creates a voting mechanism for resolving conflict between the parties and tailors the voting mechanism to
allocate influence and control much more finely than attorney ethics does.
In fact, the rights agreement contained a further constraint on the
rights agents’ discretion by dictating what they had to consider in making
litigation decisions of any kind:163
[T]he Rights Agents shall act in good faith with a view to maximizing
the present value of the Litigation Proceeds to the Company, the
Company Subsidiaries and the CVR Trust. Without limiting the generality of the foregoing, in connection with any Settlement Decision,
the Rights Agents shall consider:
161
Id.
162
Id.
163
Id. at 3.1(d) at B-11 to B-12.
DRAFT
7/15/2014]
INCORPORATING LEGAL CLAIMS
41
(A) the aggregate amount of After-Tax Litigation Proceeds to be received in connection with the proposed settlement;
(B) the benefit to the Company and the Company Subsidiaries of any
agreements, commitments or undertakings to be made in connection
with such settlement that restrict future anti-competitive or allegedly
anti-competitive conduct by one or more parties to the Litigation;
[and the potential value of a future settlement if the current offer is
rejected, discounted to reflect the time value of money.]164
The criteria in (B) is striking and reflects the fact that while the IR
Certificate holders would prefer (A) to be the only consideration—that is,
maximum cash—the anti-trust nature of the litigation means that any
remedy of type (B) could be far more valuable to pm-IR. (B) is a contractual requirement to put the interests of pm-IR ahead of the certificate
holders. This allocation of power and preference to pm-IR/Gingko is further underscored by the settlement veto the parent has per the provisions
discussed above. Combined, they illustrate how the commodification of
claims that seems at first blush inescapable can actually be avoided, and
by preemptively and transparently resolving the conflict of interest
through both (B) an the settlement veto.
The prospectus makes this dynamic explicit and counsels potential IR Certificate purchasers that:
The interests of Gingko Corporation in any settlement of the antitrust
litigation will not necessarily be aligned with the interests of the rights
certificate holders. For example, Gingko Corporation may prefer a settlement that includes, in addition to cash payments, agreements by the defendants to refrain from future unlawful anti-competitive conduct over an alternative
settlement that includes no such agreements, even if the alternative settlement offers
higher cash payments. On the other hand, the rights certificate holders… presumably would prefer the alternative settlement offering higher cash payments,
which would result in correspondingly higher payments on the rights
certificates. In those circumstances, however, the rights agents appointed by Gingko Corporation would be able to veto the alternative
164
Id. at 3.1(d)(C), (D) and (E).
DRAFT—DO NOT QUOTE
42
M. STEINITZ
settlement, and any veto of that settlement alternative would be final
and binding.165
On other key strategic issues, Gingko lacks a veto but gains influence because 3 of the 5 Rights Agents must agree, and Gingko has two of
the five, and those two have an equal say in a third. Those key strategic
issues in which the merged corporation (successor to the claim) retains
influence though not control are:
the appeal of any aspect of the antitrust litigation; the addition of any claim or party; changing legal counsel or the basis
for payment of attorneys’ fees; any admission of liability with
respect to any claim against Information Resources in the
antitrust litigation; and any other proposed decision or determination that …would represent a material change or
development in strategy … and result in a substantial likelihood that the recovery or receipt of any amount of antitrust litigation proceeds …will be delayed;.166
Because the selection of counsel and the retainer agreement is one
of the aspects of the litigation that the claim owner (Gingko) no longer
controls, champerty and attorney ethics may be implicated. Regardless the
situation is not as extreme as the CPR deal because of the retained influence on those decisions and because of the claim owner’s relationship to
the entity its shares control with. Unlike the CPR deal, the trust is not the
source of Gingko’s loss of control. Instead, it is the way the IR deal attempts to preserves the corporate DNA of the pre-merger IR: Gingko
split control with the ghost of a company that was now its subsidiary.
Champerty and attorney ethics concerns seem very distant in this situation.
The issue of preventing privilege waiver is also simplified in the
IR scenario. Since the litigation managing Rights Agents are not beholden
to the trust:
The Rights Agents shall be deemed to be agents of [Gingko] and
[IR/pm-IR] for all purposes relating to evidentiary privileges, including attorney-client privileges.167
165
Id. at 11 (emphasis added).
166
Id. at 20.
167
Id. B-13 3.1(i).
DRAFT
7/15/2014]
INCORPORATING LEGAL CLAIMS
43
The IR litigation settled on February 16, 2006 for $55 million. On
May 16, 2006 the IR Trust announced the net share to be received by the
trust and disbursed to certificate holders was $23,051,687, and that payment would begin on June 15. Each Rights Certificate was worth
$0.7152.168
2. Inadvertent Incorporation: Crystallex
Crystallex International Corporation169 is an example of a strictly incorporated claim that is striking in many respects, not least its inadvertent
nature. Crystallex is a gold mining company currently in bankruptcy in the
Canadian court system, because Venezuela voided its rights to operate a
massive mine in that country. As a result of Venezuela’s action,
Crystallex’s single major asset is a multi-billion dollar international arbitration claim against Venezuela.170 The claim is the company.
As part of the bankruptcy process, Crystallex received “debtor-inpossession” financing. Normally such financing is intended to enable a
company to restructure itself and emerge from bankruptcy. In this situation, however, nearly all of it served as litigation funding.171 The money
came from a specialized investment fund that agreed to provide four
tranches of capital, tied to milestones (some of which were pegged to litigation developments),172 in exchange for control rights, a commitment
See, Information Resources, Inc. Litigation Contingent Payment Rights Trust Announces Commencement of
Distribution Process for Holders of Contingent Value Rights Certificates, May 16, 2006,
http://www.sec.gov/Archives/edgar/data/1260946/000110465906035301/a0612014_1ex99d1.htm.
168
Crystallex International Corporation v. Bolivarian Republic of Venezuela, ICSID Case No.
ARB(AF)/11/2.
169
170
Tenth Report of the Monitor at ¶ 59-60, In re A Plan of Compromise or Arrangement of Crystallex
International Corporation, Ontario Sup. Ct. (June 4, 2013) (No. CV-11-9532 00CL), available at
http://documentcentre.eycan.com/eycm_library/Project%20Gem/English/Monitor's%20Reports/Final%20Crystallex%20-%20Tenth%20Report%20of%20the%20Monitor.pdf (calling the arbitration the
company’s “main asset” and noting that other than “minimal surplus mining equipment”, the company has
no assets other than the arbitration).
171 Id.
at paragraphs 7-10 (pp 3-4 for the description of what the DIP budget was based on: funding
the arbitration, covering the costs of the bankruptcy proceedings (including litigation and negotiation with bondholders), paying the lender’s expenses, and revenue from selling excess mining
equipment.
Id. at ¶ 7-10 (describing what the DIP budget was based on: funding the arbitration, covering
the costs of the bankruptcy proceedings (including litigation and negotiation with bondholders),
paying the lender’s expenses, and revenue from selling excess mining equipment).
172
DRAFT—DO NOT QUOTE
44
M. STEINITZ
to repay principal and interest,173 and a substantial slice of any eventual
arbitral proceeds. The Credit Agreement174 gave control rights to the funder through two vehicles: issuance of a special class of stock that empowered the funder to nominate directors of the company, and contractual
requirements to get the assent of the funders’ directors to certain steps
within the litigation.
Specifically, the funder was issued 100 Class A preference shares,
Series 1. Upon the trigger—drawing the second tranche—the funder had
the right to nominate two of the company’s five directors,175 and to conominate a third director who was given “sole and ultimate authority”
over the bankruptcy proceedings, the rights of the parties under the funding agreement, the management incentive plan, and the retention of professionals for any of those purposes.176 While this power generally gave
the funder significant influence over the company, more specific powers
were conferred as well. For example, the assent of a funder-appointed
director was necessary for board approval of transactions involving affiliates, certain types of executive pay, retention of certain advisors, and a
redacted term.177 Further, at least one of the two funder directors had to
agree before the company could remove the arbitration counsel.178 In addition to those powers, at least one funder appointee’s assent is needed
for the company to take actions or decisions described in several redacted
provisions.179
Beyond to the indirect control of the claim that the funder gained
by having significant influence and control over the company itself, the
funder gained certain direct control and influence over the conduct of the
173 See Senior Secured Credit Agreement dated April 23, 2012 (pp. 72-156) at 78, In re A Plan of
Compromise or Arrangement of Crystallex International Corporation, Ontario Sup. Ct. (May 31,
2013)(No. CV-11-9532-00CL) available at http://documentcentre.eycan.com/eycm_library/Project%20Gem/English/Motion%20Materials/CCAA/Redacted%20Motion%20Record%20returnable%20June%205,%202013.pdf
174 See Senior Secured Credit Agreement, available at http://documentcentre.eycan.com/eycm_library/Project%20Gem/English/Motion%20Materials/CCAA/Redacted%20Motion%20Record%20returnable%20June%205,%202013.pdf (providing the agreement and its amendments, attached as an exhibit)
Secured Credit Agreement at 6.13a(1); see id. at 108, available at http://documentcentre.eycan.com/eycm_library/Project%20Gem/English/Motion%20Materials/CCAA/Redacted%20Motion%20Record%20returnable%20June%205,%202013.pdf
175
176
See Secured Credit agreement at 6.14 and 6.15.
177
Id. at 6.16.
178 178
179
Id. at b(iii).
See Credit Agreement at 6.16 (a)(iv); 6.16 (b)(i), (b)(ii); and (b)(v), all of which are redacted.
DRAFT
7/15/2014]
INCORPORATING LEGAL CLAIMS
45
arbitration. For example, the Credit Agreement requires the company to
get the funder’s written consent before it decides not to follow any material advice of its arbitration counsel, and before it agrees settle for so little
that the proceeds would be insufficient to repay the funder its principal
and interest.180 While the various redacted terms make it impossible to
fully assess how Crystallex and its financier allocated control of the company and the claim, certain terms—needing funder permission to reject
counsel’s advice, change arbitration counsel, or accept a small settlement—are problematic under the current legal ethics paradigm perspective (though trading in bankruptcy claims is a .
A final set of financing provisions applied only if the arbitration
were successful, and were designed to give the funder flexibility with respect to how it received its payout. One approach involved direct payments, however these were limited in amount each year to avoid criminal
usury; the alternative would allow the funder to convert its right to proceeds into equity in Crystallex, special shares with voting, dividend and
preference rights.181
As of this writing, the Crystallex arbitration is ongoing.
3. The Treca Litigation Financing: Litigation Proceeds Trust
In October 2010, Buford Capital (‘Burford’) invested in the socalled Chevron-Ecuador dispute182 (the ‘Burford Ecuadorian deal’183), an
on-going mass-tort litigation brought by Ecuadorians against Chevron
over oil drilling-related pollution. Two facets of this deal are relevant to
the incorporation discussion.
180 180
181
Id. at 7.16a.
Id. at Ex. G.
Aguinda v. ChevronTexaco, App. Ct. of Ecuador, Case 11:1150 (2012) available at http://chevrontoxico.com/assets/docs/2012-01-03-appeal-decision-english.pdf.
182
183 This deal, and specifically the underlying contract, is discussed in great detail in The Litigation
Finance Contract. The financing contract was by and between Treca Financial Solutions and Claimants (including Friends of the Defense of the Amazon), dated October 31, 2010 (“Treca Agreement”). Treca was created solely to invest in the litigation. See Settlement Agreement, April 15,
2013, by and among Chevron, the Burford Parties (Burford Capital and related entities), and Ecuadorian Ventures, LLC. (herein “Burford Settlement Agreement”) Section 4. (a)(vi) (page 6) In
addition to Treca, the Burford Ecuadorian deal involved other SPVs. One is a Guernsey company
called Nugent Investments Limited (“Nugent”), which is Treca’s largest shareholder, and until
December 30, 2010, was its only shareholder. Id. On that date Nugent sold four of the 15 shares
of Treca that it owned to Ecuadorian Ventures LLC, an Illinois limited liability company ("Ventures"). Id. at recitals, Section 4(a)(v), Section 4(b)(iv). Through Treca, Burford was the major funder of the litigation, although a number of other funders participated as well. See The Litigation
Finance Contract, supra note 9 at 494 & nn. 174-75.
DRAFT—DO NOT QUOTE
46
M. STEINITZ
First, Burford made use of a number of SPVs and received partial
control over the conduct of the claim; however Burford’s investment did
not constitute claim incorporation under my taxonomy. These SPVs were
not devices created by the plaintiff to embody the claim (in whole or in
part) but simply were created and used by the funder to further the funder’s financing objectives. This function can be seen in both the investment mechanism, which was indifferent to whether the funder was Burford or the SPV,184 and in the funder’s partial control, i.e. influence over
counsel, 185 which would also have been the same regardless of whether
the funder was Burford or the SPV. 186 Given that the powers granted the
contracting SPV were not different than those that Burford would have
negotiated for itself directly, the SPV approach was presumably used because doing so gave Burford tax, accounting or other advantages unrelated to its relationship with the Ecuadorian plaintiffs or their counsel.
Second, the financing contract contemplated a later, strict incorporation of the claim. Specifically, the parties agreed a trust would be created, and that the claim and any value due or received for it would belong
to the trust.187 Until such time, the trustee would have the sole right to
For example, the financing contract called upon the funder to invest $4 million immediately,
and tentatively committed it to invest another $11 million split evenly into two more tranches. See
The Litigation Finance Contract, supra note 9, at 467. Burford itself could have simply given the initial
$4 million to the Ecuadorian plaintiffs; its use of an SPV to do so related to its own purposes, not
the plaintiff’s financing needs.
184
Burford gained partial control by installing Patton Boggs, a firm with close ties to Burford, as
an “Active Lawyer” shaping the litigation and as the “Nominated Lawyers” who controlled the
purse strings. Going forward, the plaintiffs could replace Active Lawyers as they wished, but replacing the Nominated Lawyers would require the SPV’s/Burford’s approval. Regarding the relationship between the firms, see PATTON BOGGS, ATT’Y WORK PROD., PATH FORWARD:
SECURING AND EN-FORCING JUDGMENT AND REACHING SETTLEMENT (report
authored by plaintiffs’ counsel, setting out the details of their enforcement strategies),
185
http://www.earthrights.org/sites/default/files/documents/Invictus-memo.pdf (last visited Feb.
27, 2012). See The Litigation Finance Contract, supra note 9, at 497 & nn182-88. Regarding the role of
the Active and Nominated lawyers and how they could be replaced, see the Treca Agreement at
Subsection 2.3; Section 3; Subsections 5.1, 5.2, 5.4, 5.5, 6.1, 7.6, 7.7, 7.9, 8.5(c), 10.2 (10.2 is interesting because it treats disclosure to the Nominated Lawyers as equivalent to disclosure to the
Funder/Burford), 13.1, 13.5, Schedule 1; and Schedule 3, including definition of “Nominated Lawyers”.
Burford invested several months after the law firm of Patten Boggs began advising the Ecuadorian plaintiffs; absent Patten Boggs’s involvement, Burford would not have invested. As a result,
it is hard to imagine Burford would have negotiated different terms regarding the Nominated and
Active lawyers had Burford been directly investing. See Roger Parloff, “Litigation finance firm in Chevron case says it was duped by Patton Boggs” FORTUNE.COM; and Jan Wolfe, Patton Boggs Accuses Burford
of Betrayal in Chevron Case, LITIG. DAILY, June 21, 2013.
186
187
Treca Agreement at 8.1(a).
DRAFT
7/15/2014]
INCORPORATING LEGAL CLAIMS
47
control the conduct of the claim and the enforcement of any judgment,
except that the trustee would itself be controlled, either by certain of the
plaintiffs’ lawyers or by a ‘board of managers,’ a term which was not defined.188 It is possible that a trust was contemplated because the Ecuadorian judgment required that any funds paid by defendants would be placed
in a trust. The judicially contemplated trust, in turn, appears to be a solution devised to deal, at least in part, with agency problems which may
emerge when non-monetary relief (remediation, in that case) was involved. The Ecuadorian judgment ordered that a trust be established for
the benefit of an NGO purporting to act on behalf of the class (the Amazon Defense Front, or ADF), or those the ADF designates, and that
Chevron pay the damages awarded to that trust. The judgment further
“directed that the trust’s board of directors be made up of the “representatives of the Defense Front”… and provided that the board would choose
the contractors who would perform the remediation.””189 (This kind of
litigation governance through the use of legal entities, especially common
law trusts, may be expanded to structured settlements, but I leave an elaboration of this idea for another day).
Regardless of whether the claim was ultimately incorporated, this
investment has not gone well. At first, it looked like a winner: an Ecuadorian judge awarded the plaintiffs a $19 billion USD judgment for compensatory and punitive damages in February 2011.190 However, Chevron
contends that the judgment was fraudulently obtained and is currently
fighting its enforcement on that basis. As of this writing, the judgment is
subject to an appeal in Ecuador, an ICSID arbitration, an anti-enforcement injunction in the United States, and numerous enforcement actions
around the globe.191 In addition, Chevron has sued the lead plaintiffs’ lawyers alleging RICO and other violations in connection with alleged fraud
and corruption through which the judgment was allegedly obtained. It has
recently won the action (which is subject to an appeal)192 Patton Boggs
188
Treca Agreement at 8.1(b).
Chevron Corp. v. Steven Donziger, et al., case 1:11-cv-00691-LAK-JCF [at pg. 180-1 of the 497page PDF] available at http://www.theamazonpost.com/wp-content/uploads/Chevron-Ecuador-Opinion-3.4.14.pdf [hereinafter: Chevron Corp.]
189
Roger Parloff, No-show Judge Bolsters Chevron's Attack On $19 Billion Judgment, FORTUNE.COM,
http://features.blogs.fortune.cnn.com/2013/05/17/judge-chevron-ecuador-2/ (last visited May
17, 2013).
190
All discussed in Manuel A. Gómez, The Global Chase: Seeking The Recognition And Enforcement Of
The Lago Agrio Judgment Outside Of Ecuador (forthcoming).
191
192
See generally Chevron Corp.
DRAFT—DO NOT QUOTE
48
M. STEINITZ
was named as a “co-conspirator” but not a defendant in that suit and has
settled it.193 In April, 2013 Burford, Chevron and others entered a settlement agreement under which Burford renounced its right to receive any
proceeds of the litigation, and Chevron and Burford agreed to release each
other from any claims relating to the Chevron/Ecuador litigation.194 Burford also agreed as part of the settlement to dissolve the primary SPV,
Treca Financial Solutions, through which the funding was effectuated.195
Beyond illustrating funder financing tactics and a possible form of
claim incorporation, this deal illustrates the very features of litigation finance that render bringing corporate law and practices, especially corporate governance practices, obviously beneficial for both funder and
funded. First, it exposes the high degree of risk funders face. Burford may
very well have been defrauded by the plaintiffs and the controlling lawyers
it selected. The jury on that is, quite literally, still out.196 But even if it has
not been Burford has faced great cost and reputational harm for having
made this particular investment. And since it has become, de facto if not
de jure, a real party in interest to the Chevron / Ecuador litigation through
its investment, it has gotten enmeshed as a (potential) party in the underlying litigation. Second, it exposes the extreme information asymmetry
characterizing litigation funding deals. And, third, in Burford’s re-alignment with Chevron and renouncement of the plaintiffs, while an unusual
Roger Parloff, Chevron Seeks To Sue Patton Boggs For Fraud And Deceit, FORTUNE.COM. (May 13,
2013, 6:16 AM), http:// http://features.blogs.fortune.cnn.com/2013/05/13/chevron-seeks-tosue-patton-boggs-for-fraud-and-deceit.
193
Burford Settlement Agreement. Burford, through Treca initially invested $4 million thereby
purchased the right to receive 1.48% of the proceeds. See Treca Agreement at Schedule 1, Section
3(h). Although it refused to make further investments and later terminated the funding contract,
it retained the right to that percentage until renouncing it in the settlement. See Burford Settlement
Agreement, supra note 183, at recitals and Section 1; Treca Agreement at Section 7 and Subsection
11.3.
194
Although Burford’s settlement agreement with Chevron is not explicit on this point, it appears
that Nugent (Treca’s largest shareholder and originally, sole sharedholder) exists for reasons beyond the Chevron/Ecuador investment because the agreement does not require Burford to dissolve Nugent though it does require Burford to dissolve Treca. Burford Settlement Agreement
Section 4.(a)(vi) (page 6). Similarly suggestive but unclear is the Settlement Agreement’s reference
to other companies as part of the “Burford Parties” namely, Litigation Risk Solutions, a Delaware
LLC, and a company identified only as “Glenavy.” Glenavy is defined in the recitals as one of the
Burford Parties and is identified in one of the recitals as having received a subpoena from Chevron
as part of its RICO suit against the Ecuadorian plaintiffs, but otherwise does not appear in the
document, nor is there any indication of where it was formed or whether Glenavy is its full name.
195
196
Chevron Corp. at [page 175/497 in PDF version].
DRAFT
7/15/2014]
INCORPORATING LEGAL CLAIMS
49
scenario, we find an illustration of the types of conflicts these arrangements may give rise to.197
III. THE INCORPORATION PARADIGM: USING LEGAL ENTITIES TO ELIMINATE THE HIDDEN COSTS AND GOVERN LITIGATION
1. The problems solved and the problems created in the real
world examples
As discussed at the outset, the use of securities tied to litigation
proceeds, the use of an SPV, and at times both, is a single mechanism that
can both resolve certain hidden costs of litigation and assist in managing
the ethical challenges implicated by litigation finance. The following paragraphs generalize and elaborate on how they do so beyond the deal-specific analysis in the previous Part.
A.
Corporate deal making and corporate finance
(i)
Reducing the hidden costs of litigation in certain mergers, acquisitions and large equity investments.
As illustrated by the discussion of the deals above, both loose and
strict incorporations can and have been used to solve company valuation
problems when a claim’s value is material relative to the value of the company, but not so large that the claim becomes the company, and the company wants to merge, be acquired, or receive a large equity investment.
Without incorporation of the claim, the difficulties in valuation have made
it very difficult or even impossible to undertake such transactions creating
the problem of the hidden cost of litigation – a cost which may well dwarf
the apparent costs of litigation namely attorneys’ fees and legal expenses.
(ii)
Monetizing claims that currently go unremedied and litigation finance as corporate finance.
The ability to cabin off a litigation in an SPV, the liquidity that can
be provide by embodying a litigation in a security (with or without an
SPV),198 and the ability to raise funds directly for the pursuit of a litigation
On extreme information asymmetry, extreme risk and extreme agency costs (conflicts of interests) as characteristics of litigation as an asset. See generally The Litigation Finance Contract, supra note
9.
197
198
On the significance of the possibility of a market in shares as a significant upside of organizational law
generally see, e.g., H. Hansman, R. Kraakman & Richard Squire, Law and the Rise of the Firm, 119,
Harvard L. Rev. 1333, [xxxx] (2006).
DRAFT—DO NOT QUOTE
50
M. STEINITZ
and do so on an ongoing basis (by issuing additional securities), may induce corporations, governments and other sophisticated actors to pursue
legal claims that currently go unremedied. As the risk of incurring the hidden costs of litigation are reduced the incentive to commence and pursue
(as opposed to settle too early at a discount) meritourious claims increases.
(Depending on one’s view of the desired level of litigation in society this
is either a benefit or a detriment).199
B. Litigation Finance
(i)
Control and conflicts of interests
As discussed above, the primary concern raised by both critics and
proponents of litigation finance is that funders may obtain control of the
claim and use it to further their interests at the expense of the interests
of the authentic owners of the claim, the plaintiffs. As also discussed, this
is the well-familiar problem of the separation of ownership and control.
Shareholders often have little control over how their companies are managed. Shareholders have little ability to propose alternative directors,200
to shape executive compensation,201 and otherwise control their agents.
Because this problem is both profound and old, corporate law has developed mulitple responses.
“[F]ive legal strategies that the law employs [] address
[agency] problems… Some legal strategies are regulatory
insofar as they directly constrain the actions of corporate
actors: for example, a standard of behavior such as a director’s duty of loyalty and care. Other legal strategies are
governance-based insofar as they channel the distribution
of power and payoffs within companies to reduce opportunism. For example, the law may accord direct decision
rights to a vulnerable corporate constituency, as when it
Steven Shavell, The Fundamental Divergence Between the Private and the Social Motive to Use
the Legal System, 26 J. LEGAL STUD. 575 (1997); Steven Shavell, The Level of Litigation: Private Versus Social Optimality of Suit and of Settlement, 19 INT’L REV. L. & ECON. 99 (1999)
(the privately determined level of litigation can depart from the socially optimal level in
either direction because litigants do not take into account either the negative or positive
externalities their litigation creates. Corrective social policy may help to remedy the divergence).
199
See Key Issues: Proxy Access, PWC.COM http://www.pwc.com/us/en/corporate-governance/proxy-access.jhtml.
200
Jesse Eisinger, In Shareholder Say-On-Pay Votes, More Whispers Than Thoughts, DEALBOOK, NYTIMES.COM (Jun. 26, 2013, 12:00 PM.
201
DRAFT
7/15/2014]
INCORPORATING LEGAL CLAIMS
51
requires shareholder approval of mergers. Alternatively,
the law may assign appointment rights over top managers
to a vulnerable constituency, as when it accords shareholders - or in some jurisdictions, employees - the power
to select corporate directors. Finally, the law may attempt
to shape the incentives of managers or controlling shareholders, as when it regulates compensation or prescribes
an equal treatment norm such as the rule that dividends
must be paid out ratably.”202
Lets illustrate how to apply these strategies to the incorporation
of legal claims. Among the most fundamental mechanisms are the fiduciary duties that directors and officers owe shareholders, namely the duty
of care and the duty of loyalty.203 These duties aim to prevent self-dealing,
bad faith, and actions against the corporation’s and shareholders’ best
interest. Under certain structures, the use of an SPV could mean that
funders become officers, with fiduciary duties, not only owners.
Further examples of how corporate governance principles can inspire litigation governance can be gleaned by turning to the area of incentive alignment through executive compensation.204 For example, compensating executives with options has become a popular practice on the theory that it aligns the managers’ interests with those of the owners. As the
limitations of this method became evident, it has been refined.205 For example, some corporations require executives to hold on to some or all of
202
H. Hansmann & Reinier Kraakman, Agency Problems and Legal Strategies, [at SSRN Abstract] in R.
Kraakman, et. al, THE ANATOMY OF CORPORATE LAW: A COMPARATIVE AND FUNCTIONAL APPROACH
(Oxford University Press 2004). The authors detail ten strategies that generally comprise the law’s methods of dealing with agency problems, four regulatory and six governance-related. Since these are general
strategies all can be applied to the regulation and governance of incorporated legal claims.
See, e.g., Fiduciary Duties and Liabilities of Directors and Officers of Financially Distressed Corporations,
http://apps.americanbar.org/buslaw/newsletter/0003/materials/tip3.pdf; § 4.01 Duty of Care
of Directors and Officers; the Business Judgment Rule, Principles of Corp. Governance § 4.01
(1994); § 5.01 Duty of Fair Dealing of Directors, Senior Executives, and Controlling Shareholders,
Principles of Corp. Governance § 5.01 (1994). See, Anthony J. Sebok & W. Bradley Wendel, Characterizing the Parties’ Relationship in Litigation Investment: Contract and Tort Good Faith
Norms, 66 Vand. L. Rev. [xx] (2013) (good faith rather than fiduciary duties).
203
For a review of various approaches to aligning executive compensation with the interests of the
corporation see Wulf A. Kaal, Contingent Capital in Executive Compensation, 69 WASH. & LEE L. REV.
1821 (2012).
204
On the promise of using restricted stock options, see Sanjai Bhagat & Roberta Romano, Reforming Executive Compensation: Focusing and Committing to the Long-Term, 26 YALE J. on Reg. 359, 363
(2009). On the shortcomings of using options and other equity approaches to compensate executives see Kaal, supra note 204, at 1828-29 (citing Regulating Bankers’ Pay, 98 GEO. L.J. 247, 249 (2010),
at 249-50, Lucian A. Bebchuk, Alma Cohen & Holger Spamann, The Wages of Failure: Executive
Compensation at Bear Stearns and Lehman 2000-2008, 27 YALE L. J. ON REG. 257 (2010), at 259.
205
DRAFT—DO NOT QUOTE
52
M. STEINITZ
their options, have ‘skin in the game,’ to disincentivize short-termism. Another option is claw-backs: contractual rights to have compensation returned in case of under-performance in the long run.206 Similarly, funders
can be required to hold on to some or all of their litigation proceed rights
until the litigation is concluded.207
There are other efforts to address agency problems that tend to
be embedded in corporate practices and are executed via contracts rather
than statutes. In two of the deals, potential agency problems were resolved
via contracts that specified principles of litigation governance in detail. As
part of the Golden State-CalFed merger, both the Golden State LTWs
and the Cal Fed participation rights were governed by the litigation management agreement, which demarcated precisely how the litigation would
be managed. That contract also spelled out whom the agents reported to,
and how the agents could be removed.208 The IR deal similarly involved a
litigation management contract which allocated control of the litigation,
giving some of it to the pre-merger company, and some—including settlement—to the post-merger parent company.209 Litigation governance
contracts like these, which specify who has how much power to take
which decisions, are perhaps the most direct way to resolve the agency
issues.
Where an SPV is used the constitutional documents of the entity
can also be used to define the purpose of the entity and the obligations of
its officers in a manner that minimized conflicts. Thus, a single SPV may
be used for multiple litigations should a plaintiff and funder choose to
join forces on more than one suit. In such a case, an SPV would reduce
the transaction costs of negotiating a separate contract for each litigation.210
206
L. A. Bebchuk & J. M. Fried Pay without performance: Overview of the Issues, Journal of Applied
Corporate Finance (2005).
Indeed, the Coast Litigation Trustees had to retain at least 50% of their certificates during their
tenure as Litigation Trustees. See Coast Amended and Restatement Declaration of Trust, Ex. B to
the Coast S-4, at Section 3.7(b) at B-11.
207
Golden State Bancorp Inc., Current Report, (Form 8-k Exhibit) (Feb. 17, 1998). Litigation
Management Agreement by and among the Registrant, Glendale Federal Bank, A Federal Savings
Bank, Stephen J. Trafton and Richard A. Fink At Articles I and II, The Litigation Management
Agreement designated litigation managers for each case, who reported to committees of the board
of directors specifically create for each case and were vested with the power of the board as regards
the litigation, including rights to remove the litigation managers for cause.
208
209 See generally the form of Contingent Value Rights Agreement appended to the Prospectus as
Exhibit B at Article III-The Rights Agents at B-11, and specifically at 3.1.at B-11 through B-12.
210
The question of what legal entities add to mere contracts, given that at core they can be understood as
standard contracts, is an important question when selecting between loose and strict incorporation and a
question that has received substantial treatment in corporate legal theory but a full treatment of it is beyond
DRAFT
7/15/2014]
INCORPORATING LEGAL CLAIMS
53
Using an SPV can also help clarify the duties of the attorney in the
attorney-client-funder triumvirate thus resolving or minimizing the set of
conflicts between the client and its attorney that are created once a third
party, the funder, pays the attorneys’ bill and, especially if that funder–
attorney relationship is a repeat–play relationship.211 Now, the SPV can be
the client of the attorney and, so long as the funder is either a director or
officer of the SPV and thus owes it fiduciary duties, those conflicts can
be regulated. Using an SPV to manage funder-funded conflicts would fail,
however, if the funder does not have such a duty to the SPV.
The continuum described in Part III—of transferring no control,
some control, or total control of the claim when incorporating it—represent different modalities of dealing with the agency problems that arise
once ownership and control are separated in the context of a financed or
spun-off litigation. Loose incorporation always resolves these tensions by
contract. In the context of a publicly issued security, whether as a spin off
or, if an underwriter were willing, through a litigation-funding IPO, control stays with the original plaintiff. The claim ownership rights embodied
in the security are too fragmented for a security holder to be given any
control, and in any case, the security holders only enter the transaction
after its terms are set. If the security were done via private placement to a
single funder or a very small number of funders, one could imagine them
contracting for partial or full control transfer. Middle ground is possible,
where a plaintiff sets the terms of its security and then markets its private
placement via a road show to a much larger number of qualified investors.
Such investors need not be PELF investors and may not seek much control.212
The legal ethics paradigm treats these permutations differently because of its focus on the degree of control transfer, and would be more
approving of a funding IPO than the arms’- length negotiated deal with a
PELF. A close examination, however, reveals that this approach is suboptimal in terms of promoting public policies. If underwriters were willing
the scope of this paper. Some of some answers to this question include H. Hansmann & R. Kraakman,
The Essential Role of Organizational Law, 110 Yale L. J. (2000) (“organizational law permits the creation
of patters of creditors’ rights that otherwise could not practicably be established”); H. Hansmann, R. Kraakman & R. Squire, Corporation and Contract, 8 American L&E Rev. 1 (2006) (explaining why publicallytraded corporations rarely deviate from the default terms of state corporation law in their charters);
See, Vicki Waye, TRADING IN LEGAL CLAIMS: LAW, POLICY & FUTURE DIRECTIONS IN AUSTRALIA, UK & US (2008) at [xx]; Whose Claim Is It Anyway? supra note 8, at 1280;
N.Y.C. Bar Opinion supra note 39; A.B.A. Comm. on Ethics 20/20 supra note 39.
211
See Painter, supra note 16; and Maya Steinitz & Abigail C. Field, The Model and The Securities Laws,
Coda, A MODEL LITIFATION FINANCE CONTRACT, http://litigationfinancecontract.com/the-model-and-the-securities-laws-coda/.
212
DRAFT—DO NOT QUOTE
54
M. STEINITZ
to issue litigation funding IPOs, such originate-and-distribute deals could
create a moral hazard (investing other peoples’ money and shifting the
risk to buyers of the securities) and, consequently, a risk to the court system by flooding it with non-meritorious claims.213 This is much less socially desirable than a PELF deal even though the separation of ownership
and control is greater in the latter. The incorporation paradigm in contrast,
allows us to clearly see that such a preference for an IPO over a PELF
deal would be undesirable.
If securities are involved, the potential for tension between ownership and control is greatest with the strict incorporation approach, as
evidenced by the Coast Savings example. But that tension need not exist
if ownership of the claim as well as control of it are transferred to the
SPV. If the entire claim is transferred to the SPV—Coast Federal without
Ahmanson’s continued claim of ownership and accounting for the claim,
or the Treca trust if created—then not only is the tension absent, but by
structuring ownership, the bylaws and roles within the SPV, control can
be allocated among the parties however they wish without necessarily raising any agency issues. The Crystallex deal illustrates some of the possibilities. The Board of Managers envisioned by the Treca Agreement would
perhaps have been another such vehicle. One can envision such Board of
Managers as including plaintiff representatives analogous to lead plaintiffs
in class action, as well as their litigation counsel and a funder representative. The Board of Managers’ membership, like the IR Rights Agents,
could have voting powers that give a settlement veto to the plaintiffs, but
nonetheless give funders a vote and thus influence. The IR deal itself reflects the overall flexibility of the incorporation paradigm. The trust features that made its issuance of the proceed right certificates more deal
appropriate than having pm-IR or the new parent, Gingko, issue them
could be realized, but control transfer could be finely customized by contract. Again, the legal ethics paradigm approaches these deal structures
differently, but its touchstone—claim control—seems to be simply one
of the central, negotiated deal points, rather than the sine qua non deal
point excluded from negotiation amongst sophisticated actors by operation of Bar Association regulation.214 An incorporation paradigm more
appropriately assesses the deal as a business transaction. The judgment of
these deals should use the standards for deal making and decision-making
developed in the business law context.
213
Whose Claim Is This Anyway? supra note 8 at [xx] (on the prospect of securitizing legal claims and
the potential attendant dangers).
214
See, Anthony J. Sebok, Should the Law Preserve Party Control? Litigation Investment, Insurance Law and Double Standards (forthcoming).
DRAFT
7/15/2014]
INCORPORATING LEGAL CLAIMS
55
ii.
Information asymmetry and the attorney-client privilege.
The funder–funded relationship is characterized by information
barriers, predominantly the fear of waiving attorney–client privilege by
communicating with funder,215 and extreme information asymmetry due
to the fact that the plaintiff has better, private information. Funders may
also have material private information.
Information barriers and asymmetry can be addressed using securities structures, whether loose or strict, to the same extent they can be in
the more typical non-recourse loan scenario, so long as the securities issuance is an arms-length private placement. That is, so long as it is practical to enter confidentiality agreements that preserve work-product protection information asymmetry about the facts of the case can been minimized.216 However, if a publicly traded security is used, information asymmetry becomes reinforced rather than mitigated. That is, the plaintiff will
not want to publicly disclose any information that would result in work
product or privilege waiver. Instead, the disclosures will resemble those
of the Coast Trust’s, namely, announcements of case developments otherwise in the public record.
If a strict incorporation approach is used that positioned both the
funder and the plaintiff as officers of the SPV, privilege issues for communications between them would evaporate as they would be co-representatives of the SPV client for all dealings with counsel. Privilege issues
could also be resolved under loose incorporation structures if the funder’s
litigation managers were subject to sufficient control by the plaintiff, as in
the Golden-State example. Whether a funder would agree to such control
is a different question. Also unclear is whether entering a litigation management agreement of the type used in the IR example would preserve
privilege when the parties are not parties to a merger but are instead engaging in a joint venture, which is the essence of claim incorporation in
the litigation finance, rather than hidden costs, context. Perhaps the agreement could serve to demonstrate the common legal interest necessary to
preserve privilege.217
Though in at least some US jurisdictions that risk is greatly minimized through the operation
of the attorney work product doctrine. For a discussion of both see A Model Litigation Finance Contract, supra note 9at 487.
215
See The Model Litigation Finance Contract, supra note 9 at 487 (analyzing the extent to which the
work product doctrine can be preserved despite the introduction of a funder and the extent to
which it overlaps, in scope of protection, with the attorney-client privilege).
216
217 An exception to the doctrine that disclosure to a third party waives attorney client privilege is
called the common interest doctrine. The contours of the doctrine vary by state, and can be incoherent even within a state. Importantly, while parties must agree the common legal interest exists,
DRAFT—DO NOT QUOTE
56
M. STEINITZ
(iii)
Uncertainty, pricing and transparency.
By embodying the value of a litigation in a security which is capable of trading, litigation—notoriously difficult to value because of the
nonmonotonic and discontinuous nature of settlement values218 and because of the absence of comparables and a of transparent market219—becomes subject to pricing via markets. Furthermore, the ability to issue additional shares in the future allows plaintiffs to avoid over-selling (i.e. sell
a larger portion of the claim than they have to) at the outset and/or sell
at a steep discount when their bargaining position is the weakest.220 Instead, as more information is revealed about the value of the litigation
through the litigation process, risk is reduced, and additional shares can
be priced accordingly. If a robust market develops, the accumulation of
transparent pricing data, currently absent with respect to legal settlements,
can reduce pricing problems across deals. Finally, by avoiding uncertainty
as to whether any given deal is champertous or not a risk factor that is
currently raising the cost of financing for plaintiffs will be removed.
(iv)
Commodification.
Embodying a claim in a security, whether in connection to a strict
or loose form of incorporation, is commodification in its purest form.
However, steps can be taken to mitigate the implications. The most potent
is the approach taken in the IR deal, namely to provide explicit direction
requiring certain types of non-monetary relief to be sought and prioritized
even at the expense of a reduced monetary award, coupled with a disclosure of this arrangement to the proceed right holders. One can imagine a
litigation finance contract that funded an antitrust claim containing similar
their agreement alone cannot give rise to such an interest because the parties cannot create privilege by agreement when it otherwise does not exist. A challenge normally for funder-funded relationships is that a common commercial interest is easy to establish, but a common legal one is not.
See A Model Litigation Finance Contract, supra note 16at [xx]. However, if the parties are contractually
agreeing to co-manage a litigation for a common purpose as defined in the litigation management
agreement—the IR agreement, e.g., lays out how settlement offers are to be evaluated—then their
relationship seems much closer than simply that of co-defendants agreeing to cooperate in their
defense, which is the situation the common interest doctrine arose from. Thus a privilege preserving common legal interest would plausibly exist. The idea is simply too novel, however, for any
on-point precedent.
See Joseph A. Grundfest & Peter H. Huang, The Unexpected Value of Litigation: A Real Options
Perspective, 58 STAN. L. REV. 1267, 1272––73 (2006); Robert J. Rhee, The Effect of Risk on Legal
Valuation, 78 U. COLO. L. REV. 193 (2007).
218
See Yeazell supra note Error! Bookmark not defined.(while there are numerous legal settlements, the legal claims market is unusual in that there is no available information about their values
because most settlements tend to be confidential).
219
220
See Model Contract supra note 9 at [xx – yy] (discussion of the “hold-up”).
DRAFT
7/15/2014]
INCORPORATING LEGAL CLAIMS
57
language. That said, the commodification inherent in reducing claims to
securities, tradable or not, is the reason this approach is inappropriate to
claim types other than commercial claims owned by corporations, wealthy
individuals or, in certain cases, sovereigns.
(v)
Transaction Costs.
The transaction costs of doing a private placement of securities
need not be materially larger than negotiating a more typical funding contract, unless a private placement involving a formal offering memorandum and a road show. Then the costs are much higher. However, if retaining full control of the claim is a crucial deal point and the claim is
large enough that litigating it will be so costly that financing is attractive,
these costs may be justified. Similarly, if a claim is embodied in a publicly
traded security, the costs are high. These are all the costs of drafting and
registering the prospectus, and ongoing compliance costs.221 These costs
are even higher if a trust or other SPV is used in conjunction with the
public security, because then there are the additional costs of creating the
SPV, its own compliance costs, and the compensation of the SPV’s directors, officers, or trustees.
Investor protection. Currently, there is a lack of clarity as to whether
(some or all) litigation finance contracts are securities.222 By following
well-recognized deal patterns, whether and what kind of security is involved and what kind of securities regulation applies becomes much easier
to discern.
In sum, incorporating legal claims is a practice that holds the potential of significantly minimizing the Funding Challenges as well as carries additional benefits such as improving investor protection.
2. Trusts and Beyond: Using Various Legal Entities for Financed or Spun-off Claims
Accepting the idea that the funding of a commercial claim is a
joint venture brings to stark relief at least two key features of litigation
finance. One, is the key difference between the funder–plaintiff relationship—which is that of co-venturers—and the contingency lawyer–client
relationship—which is an attorney-client relationship. What follows from
this difference is that while allocating control over key decisions to an
attorney may not be appropriate allocating control to a co-owner is appropriate in certain circumstances. The other, related difference is the fact
221
Painter, supra note 74.
222
See Wendy Couture, supra note 88.
DRAFT—DO NOT QUOTE
58
M. STEINITZ
that conflicts of interests run both ways in the funder-plaintiff relationship. While the funder may be tempted to maximize its profits at the expense of its JV partner, the claimant, the latter may also try to take advantage of its JV partner, the funder. Yes, the funder may push for an
early settlement in order to re-invest in other litigations in its portfolio.223
But the claimant may push to over-invest in its case either because it is
heavily concentrated in it or because the claimant may be more emotional
about it case.224
These conflicts of interest are a direct result of the separation of
the ownership and control of the claim. Business law has developed (partial) solutions to these problems over the years.225 These solutions are embodied in (1) the different types of business entities, understood as sets of
organizational choices which have evolved over time to produce internal
coherence226 and; (2) principles of corporate governance.
The rest of this section looks at a few illustrative examples of business entities, with an emphasis on the different forms of corporate governance they offer, to see how they might address the separation of ownership and control in the context of litigation finance and litigation governance. The section compares them along a few dimensions, including
relative complexity and formality, access to capital, and ease of transfer of
interests. This section seeks only to illustrate how choice of entity can
influence issues implicated by the separation of ownership and control. It
is not intended to be an exhaustive survey of either the entities that can
be used nor of the important dimensions of entity selection analysis.227 In
addition, while the question of what it is that legal entities add to mere
contracts, given that at core organizational forms can be understood as
For an elaborate discussion of the conflicts created by the fact that funders invest in portfolios
of litigations see The Litigation Finance Contract, supra note 9.
223
224 “Litigants litigate not just
for money, but to attain vindication; to establish precedent; ‘to express
their feelings’… their decisions to settle or litigate may be affected by… [their] self-serving biases
concerning the fairness of their position, habit, unyielding conceptions of justice, and myriad other
factors.” Russell Korobkin & Chris Guthrie, Psychology, Economics, and Settlement: A New Look at the
Role of the Lawyer, 76 TEX. L. REV. 77, 79–81 (1997) (surveying the empirical literature establishing
same).
See LEE A. HARRIS, CASES AND MATERIALS ON CORPORATIONS AND OTHER BUSINESS
TIES: A PRACTICAL APPROACH (2011) [hereinafter Corporations and Other Business Entities].
225
226
ENTI-
Riebstien, infra note 236.
227
For in depth analysis of the considerations that go into entity selection see generally, e.g., H. Hansmann,
R. Kraakman & R. Squire, The new Business Entities in Evolutionary Perspective, [xxx]; H. Hansmann,
Firm Ownership and Organizational Form in R. Gibbons et. Al (eds.), THE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL ECONOMICS; L. E. Ribstien, Why Corporations, 1 Berkley Bus. L. J. 183 (2004); Larry E. Rib-
stien, THE RISE OF THE UNCORPORATION (2010).
DRAFT
7/15/2014]
INCORPORATING LEGAL CLAIMS
59
standard contracts is an important question when selecting between loose
and strict incorporation (and a question that has received substantial treatment in corporate legal theory) a full treatment of it is beyond the scope
of this paper.228 It is also important to note that from a deal-specific perspective, additional and possibly idiosyncratic, considerations may come
into play. For example, key deal–specific considerations as to which legal
entity to use are likely to be the tax and accounting consequences of the
structure in the context of the claim and claimant. Such deal-specific considerations are also outside the scope of this paper.
(i) Statutory Trusts
Two of the spinoff deals discussed used statutory trusts as security-issuing entities to which claim proceeds and perhaps control were
transferred. Among the various available forms, these entities have certain
advantages. They are rigid, passive and well understood. Simultaneously,
their rigidity does not eliminate flexibility, in that the powers of the trustee, the corpus of the trust, and the terms of the securities can be customized. In addition, they are routinely used for financing and security issuance. Access to capital is limited solely by the attractiveness of the terms
of the certificates the trust issues, and transferability of the certificates can
be customized within the bounds of the securities laws.
To leverage trust doctrine to minimize or resolve the conflicts of
interest between the funder and the funded, defining the trustees’ powers
is key. The IR and Coast Federal deals show the tension; the certificate
holders want maximum financial return, which may or may not be what
the Plaintiff wants. IR resolved the conflict by retaining control of the
litigation, so it could pursue non-monetary relief freely, and simply told
certificate holders that the conflict was resolved against them. Coast Federal resolved the conflict in favor of the certificate holders, and informed
Ahmanson (the claim owner) accordingly.
One could imagine the optimal use of a trust to finance a claim
and resolve conflicts of interest would be a deal in which the plaintiff and
funder(s) were both trustees and certificate holders, the claim involved
only monetary remedies, the trust corpus was the right to receive the net
228
Some of some answers to this question include H. Hansmann & R. Kraakman, The Essential Role of
Organizational Law, 110 Yale L. J. (2000) (“organizational law permits the creation of patters of creditors’
rights that otherwise could not practicably be established”); H. Hansmann, R. Kraakman & R. Squire,
Corporation and Contract, 8 American L&E Rev. 1 (2006) (explaining why publically-traded corporations
rarely deviate from the default terms of state corporation law in their charters); H. Hansmann, Firm Ownership and Organizational Form in R. Gibbons et. Al (eds.), THE HANDBOOK OF ORGANIZATIONAL ECONOMICS; L. E. Ribstien, Why Corporations, 1 Berkley Bus. L. J. 183 (2004) (corporate form facilitates
regulation).
DRAFT—DO NOT QUOTE
60
M. STEINITZ
proceeds of the claim, and the trustees controlled the litigation. This approach would impose fiduciary duties on both the funder and plaintiff,
binding them to the same commercial goal (maximizing the net proceeds).
Funders are unlikely to find the fiduciary duty attractive, but it is possible
to imagine allocating decisional power among the trustees gave the funder
comfort that the fiduciary duty would not force it to act too strongly
against its own interest. In addition, the ability to raise additional funds by
issuing certificates to other funders without making those second-wave
funders trustees could be quite appealing. Similarly, to the extent a funder
could sell some or all of its certificates while retaining (or even relinquishing) trustee status/litigation control, a funder might find the trust attractive.
(ii) Partnerships
Perhaps the oldest and simplest business form is the partnership.
Partnerships resolve mutual conflicts of interest by imposing a reciprocal
fiduciary duty,229 do not involve the separation of ownership and management, and allocate management responsibility laterally by agreement. Unlike with corporations, management is not stratified into a board of directors and an officer tier.230
The greatest downside of partnerships—liability for other partners’ acts—is a relatively minor issue in the litigation finance context because most actions of the partnership are not directed toward external
clients/customers the way most businesses are. The simplicity of partnerships and the relatively low liability risk makes this arrangement theoretically the most effective, efficient way to resolve the funder-funded conflicts. However, the general historical trend has been away from the partnership form due to the restrictive nature of both the fiduciary duty and
the joint and several liability. For the same reasons it is likely that both
funders and clients may wish to restrict their reciprocal duties and limit
their liability.231
A final consideration is that partnerships’ ability to raise capital is
limited to the partners’ assets and borrowing ability, i.e. they draw on a
For a discussion of fiduciary duties in partnerships, see Michael Haynes, Partners Owe to One
Another A Duty of the Finest Loyalty . . . . or Do They? An Analysis of the Extent to Which Partners May
Limit Their Duty of Loyalty to One Another, 37 Tex. Tech L. Rev. 433, 434 (2005).
229
230
Corporations and Other Business Entities, supra note 225, at [xx].
On the historical shift away from partnerships and towards corporations and uncorporations
and, within the latter category, especially towards the LLC see, e.g., Riebstien.
231
DRAFT
7/15/2014]
INCORPORATING LEGAL CLAIMS
61
limited reservoir.232 This issue is less pressing in the litigation finance context because most funders take on cases assuming they will fund the case
themselves, or through syndicates they have put in place, and thus presumably could bring sufficient capital to the table. Finally, partnership interests are difficult to transfer. One can imagine that funders may lean in
favor of ease of transfer while plaintiffs may be better served by requiring
funders to maintain ‘skin in the game.’ A notable consideration is that
heavily restricted securities do not lend themselves to securitization, a restriction that is beneficial for plaintiffs.233 However, some funders express
the opposite concern, wanting to insure plaintiffs have skin in the game
in the form of retained ownership.
(iii) Corporations
Most corporations are entities that involve a complete separation
of ownership and control for most decisions. While shareholders have the
last word at certain points, for the most part control is vested in a Board
of Directors, and through them, Officers, some or all of whom may also
be shareholders. The exception to this basic structure is the “close corporation,” which is a privately held entity that can give shareholders or third
parties topic-specific Director or Executive level powers (and duties), and
can in fact eliminate the board of directors entirely, effectively incorporating a partnership. 234 Like partnerships, however, close corporations
have been trending down.
Corporate law has long recognized the conflicts of interest created
by separating ownership and control, and has used both statutory and
common law fiduciary duties and governance theories to minimize them.
232
Id. at [xx].
Securitization involves the transfer of the right to receive future payments to a trust that then
issues a security backed by those payments. If the right to receive litigation proceed payments
cannot be transferred to the trust, the trust cannot use litigation proceeds to issue its own securities.
On securitization and its moral hazards see, e.g., Kevin Dowd, Moral Hazard and the Financial Crisis,
29 CATO J. 141, 142 (2009). Securitization of litigation is not only undesirable from a public policy
prospective, because it will likely encourage the funding of unmeritorious claims, but also from
the plaintiffs’ perspective because of its inherent moral hazards. On the risks to the public and to
plaintiffs from creating litigation – backed derivatives see Whose Claim Is It Anyway?, supra note 8 at
[xx].
233
234See, 11 Del. J. Corp. L. 383. A corporation with such few shareholders could be best styled as a
close corporation because of the flexibility gained. Further, a close corporation could flatten management by eliminating the board of directors, increasing efficiency. In these ways close corporations could mimic the advantages of partnerships while adding the benefit of limited liability. See,
11 Del. J. Corp. L. at 395-96.
DRAFT—DO NOT QUOTE
62
M. STEINITZ
Managers must be loyal and avoid self-dealing, while pursuing the company’s—shareholders’—best interests. Governance theories have involved aligning financial incentives through compensation structures, easing accountability by making directorships all expire at the same time, increasing transparency and accountability by having independent directors
and members of compensation and audit committees, and similar efforts.
Finally, Congress and regulators have taken some steps to increase shareholders power versus management.235 All that said, corporate misconduct
continues to make headlines and trigger shareholders suits, demonstrating
that all these measures simply reduce rather than eliminate the problems
created by separating ownership and control. So while a corporate structure could be used to impose various duties, and director and officer roles
allocated among funder and claimant to structure decision-making power
and authority to minimize conflicts, unless the funder and the claimant
held all or essentially all the shares of the corporation the conflict minimization would be imperfect at best.
(iv) Limited Liability Companies.
These entities are far newer, and far more flexible than corporations. The flexibility extends to the degree of separation of ownership and
control. Flexibility in LLCs also means that intra-company relationships
can be structured relatively free from significant statutory and case lawimposed fiduciary duties and other requirements. The de facto de-regulatory effects of the LLC form accounts for its popularity in recent years.236
The great flexibility to embrace or reject the conflict-minimizing duties
and doctrines that come with more traditional business forms, however,
places in doubt the likely effectiveness of this form in minimizing the
problems created by the separation of ownership and control beyond
what sheer bargaining power already affords contracting parties.
While the rise of the LLC and the high likelihood that this business form will be popular in this context as it has increasingly been in
others raises questions about the effectiveness of business entities to minimize problems arising from the separation of ownership and control, it
is important to note that the type of entities used and their internal governance arrangements in the litigation finance context can be dictated or
at least affected by court orders as to the form of settlement structure
where a settlement is court-supervised. Court supervision, in turn, is likely
to play an increasingly important role as defendants and judges become
235
See supra note 24.
On the rise of the LCC see generally, Larry E. Ribstien, THE RISE OF THE UNCORPORATION
(2010). On LCC’s de-regulatory effects as a main reason for this rising tide see Id. at [xx].
236
DRAFT
7/15/2014]
INCORPORATING LEGAL CLAIMS
63
more aware of litigation finance and seek, respectively, to bring the fact
of financing to light and to submit finance arrangements to court scrutiny.
CONCLUSION
The legal ethics paradigm, while superficially very attractive given
certain similarities between contingency attorneys and funders, proves,
upon closer consideration to fall woefully short in explaining and addressing the economic reality of litigation finance. Consequently, it leads to
both over- and under regulation of the practice and falls short in recognizing and addressing the problem of the separation of ownership and
control of legal claims. The legal ethics paradigm also masks the full spectrum of possible deal structures that market players are already experimenting with in the marketplace that is the focus of this Article: commercial claims brought by sophisticated plaintiffs such as corporations, sovereigns and wealthy individuals.
A better view would replace litigation-finance-as-champerty as the
organizing idea in the literature and jurisprudence with litigation finance
as…finance as the organizing idea. What follows, dubbed here “the incorporation paradigm,” better fits the realities of deals actually undertaken by
various market participants and brings a centuries old paradigm of
thought on how to address, i.e. minimize or even solve (but if mismanaged
exacerbates), each and every problem that stems from what is now reframed as the problem of the separation of ownership and control of legal
claims. These problems are, in a nutshell, (1) extreme conflicts of interests;
(2) extreme information asymmetries; (3) extreme uncertainty; and (4) inappropriate commodification. In addition, the incorporation paradigm
simplifies the analysis of the application of securities regulation to litigation finance arrangements.
In addition to this transformation of litigation finance scholarship
and practice, the discussion of incorporation of legal claims contributes
to the scholarship on corporate law. As we have seen, most of the claim
incorporation deals have taken place in the context of mergers, acquisitions or large equity investments. In those cases, claim incorporations
have been undertaken in order to resolve the hidden cost of litigation—
the barriers that pricing legal claims can place on such transactions because of the difficulty in valuing legal claims. These hidden costs, where
they apply, dwarf the visible costs of litigation i.e., attorneys’ fees and legal
expenses. Finally, incorporating legal claims may also provide accounting
benefits and may play a role in corporate finance by allowing corporations
(or governments) to monetize claims that currently go unprosecuted.
DRAFT—DO NOT QUOTE
64
M. STEINITZ
Fully commodifying commercial legal claims and providing for
enhanced liquidity through public trading of securities in the open market,
on security exchanges, can open up additional horizons beyond those this
paper explores or those alluded to in the preceding paragraph. More analysis can be done on the accounting and tax implications of the use of
different types of business entities and securities and on how different
legal entities may lend themselves to different forms of corporate governance cum litigation governance. The full implications of understanding litigation finance contracts as financial products and spun-off litigation from
a regulatory perspective, is a rich field to mine and there can be little doubt
that the analysis herein will launch experimentation by market players and
new scenarios for courts to opine on.
DRAFT