Whither Currency Union in Greater China?
By
Zhaoyong Zhang* and Kiyotaka Sato**
*School of Accounting, Finance and Economics
Edith Cowan University
** Yokohama National University
School of Accounting, Finance and Economics & FIMARC Working Paper Series
Edith Cowan University
November 2005
Working Paper 0509
Correspondence author:
Zhaoyong Zhang
School of Accounting, Finance and Economics
Edith Cowan University
100 Joondalup Drive
Joondalup, Western Australia WA 6027
Australia
Phone: 61+ (8) 6304 5266
Fax: 61+ (8) 6304 5271
Email: zhaoyong.zhang@ecu.edu.au
Abstract
The paper attempts to evaluate the prospect of creating a currency union in
the “Greater China” economic area including Mainland China, Hong Kong
and Taiwan. Despite of the political deadlock and military confrontation in
the Taiwan Strait, the Greater China area has experienced rapid and
spontaneous regional integration in the past decades as a result of
increasingly cross-border trade, foreign direct investment (FDI), technology
contracts, and other arrangements in accordance with changes in
comparative advantage and industrial upgrading in these economies. In this
study, we focus on the symmetry in shocks that is perceived as one of the
major preconditions of a currency union. In contrast to the previous studies,
we investigate the time-varying correlation of supply and demand shocks by
using the Kalman filter technique in order to reveal whether the Greater
China economies show a convergence trend. We also examine the costs of
forming a currency union in the area that are caused by the loss of monetary
autonomy in each economy. Our results emphasize an increasing symmetry
in demand shocks and, to a lesser extent, in supply shocks, implying that
these economies would not suffer too much from abandoning their monetary
policy as an instrument of absorbing shocks.
JEL Classification: E32, F33, F41
Keywords:
Optimum currency area; structural shocks; vector
autoregression; Kalman filter; output losses; Greater China
Acknowledgements: An earlier version of the paper was presented at the
9th International Convention of the East Asian Economic Association in
Hong Kong and the CITS Research Workshop at Yokohama National
University, Japan. The authors wish to thank Rasmus Rüffer, Masahito
Kobayashi, Hiroyasu Uemura, Craig Parsons, Masaru Inaba, and
participants in the conference and seminar for their helpful comments and
suggestions. The authors wish to acknowledge the financial support of the
JSPS through the Grant-in-Aid for Scientific Research (B), 116330059.
1.
Introduction
Despite the political deadlock and military confrontation in the Taiwan Strait, the
Greater China area including Mainland China, Hong Kong and Taiwan1 has undoubtedly
experienced rapid and spontaneous economic integration in the past decades. Hong Kong has
been an important intermediary linking up Mainland China with the rest of the world for
foreign trade and investment, and had achieved a high degree of integration with the Mainland
well before its handover in 1997. On the other hand, Mainland China is also the largest source
of inward investment in Hong Kong. In contrast to this integration pattern, the economic
integration process of Taiwan with the Mainland is very different. On the one hand, the
bifurcation of low and high politics across the Taiwan Strait has been the dominant feature of
cross-strait relations since the end of the Cold War. On the other hand, economic forces in the
form of increasing trade and investment tend to bridge the strait, to integrate the two societies,
and to dilute political control. However, since the “full three links”, i.e., direct trade,
transportation, and communications links between Mainland China and Taiwan have been
“frozen” for the past half century, cross-strait trade and investment have to be conducted
indirectly via a third territory, mostly through Hong Kong, and also other parties such as
Japan and Singapore. Complementary factor endowment and mutual economic interests,
geographical proximity and cultural affinity also meant possible low transactional costs and
have enabled both economies to develop a rather intense trade and investment linkages in the
past decades. This process is also accompanied by a rapid labor mobility, even though mostly
a one-way flow. It was estimated that the presence of Taiwanese in Shanghai has grown from
tens of thousands in the early 1990s to as many as 250,000-350,000 by 2001. To many
Taiwanese, Shanghai has become their “second home” after Taiwan.
It is believed that high degree of integration in the Greater China area would greatly
shape their own economic structure and has direct implications for the effectiveness of
domestic stabilization policy and policy coordination. Consider the recent proposals for
exchange rate management or coordination in East Asia, it remains an interesting question to
ask if it is feasible for the “Greater China” economic area to create a currency union from
purely economic perspective.
This paper attempts to evaluate the prospect of creating a currency union in the Greater
China economic area by focusing on the (a)symmetric issues of the structural shocks between
2
the concerned economies. Early studies2 in addressing the (a)symmetry in shocks typically
employ the structural vector autoregression (VAR) technique developed by Blanchard and
Quah (1989). However, this approach does not necessarily reveal how the (a)symmetry in
shocks has evolved over time especially when economic interdependence between the
economies concerned has deepened substantially. In this paper, we employ the time-varying
parameter estimation technique developed by Haldane and Hall (1991), Boone (1997) and
Babetskii et al. (2004) to measure the time-varying correlation of the identified shocks and the
convergence trend. Following Ghosh and Wolf (1994), we also apply the output loss function
analysis to assessing the costs of renouncing autonomous monetary policy instruments in
forming a currency union in this region.
The remaining of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 reviews the changing
dynamics of foreign trade and business linkages in the Greater China economic area during
the past decades. The theoretical framework and methodology of this study are presented in
Section 3. Section 4 conducts an empirical assessment of convergence in shocks, with a
dynamic approach, between China and the rest of the Greater China as well as the other
regional economies. We then conduct a sensitivity analysis of forming a currency union
between the Greater China economies to determine the costs of the union due to the loss of
monetary autonomy in each economy. Finally, Section 5 draws concluding remarks towards
the feasibility of forming a currency union in the Greater China region.
2.
Dynamic Linkages of Trade and Business Between Greater China Economies
2.1
Trade linkage Between Greater China Economies
Contrasting to the enduring political deadlock and military confrontation in the Strait, to
tie Taiwan to Mainland China through “economic rope” has been very effective. Two factors
might have contributed to this integration process: the emergence of the Mainland economy as
a trading nation and manufacturing center since its adoption of the open-door policy in the
late 1970s (see Lardy, 1992; Naughton, 1996), and the rapid and spontaneous regional
integration in East Asia in the past decades (Dobson and Chia, 1997; Zhang, 2001). Figure 1
shows the evolution of the cross-strait trade since the late 1980s. It can be seen that Taiwan’s
exports to the Mainland rose rapidly from less than US$1 billion in the middle of the 1980s to
the peak of US$26.14 billion by 2000. Since 1993 China has become Taiwan’s second largest
3
export market, next only to the United States. However, due to Taiwan’s “relaxing indirect
exports control and restricting imports” trade policy implemented in the 1980s3, cross-strait
trade has been developed highly unbalanced, continuously in favor of Taiwan’s trade balance.
The accumulative trade surplus in 1987-2001 for Taiwan reached US$163.3 billion, which is
3.5 times of its trade surplus with the rest of the world during the period4. It has become
evident that the cross-strait trade helped Taiwan’s trade balance and also enhanced the
economic interdependence across the Taiwan Strait.
Hong Kong had achieved a high degree of integration with the mainland well before its
handover to Mainland China. It served as an important intermediary to develop the trade and
investment linkages between Mainland China and Taiwan as well as the rest of the world.5
Sources: Taiwan Ministry of Economic Affairs, and Almanac of China’s Foreign Economic
Relation and Trade (Beijing).
Figure 1: Taiwan Trade and Trade Balance with Mainland China
Since 1985 the Mainland has been Hong Kong's largest trading partner. Share of the Mainland
in Hong Kong's global trade rose from 9.3% in 1978 to 43.1% in 2003. The Mainland was
Hong Kong's largest import source, accounting for 43.5% of Hong Kong's total imports, and
the largest export market, accounting for 42.6 % of Hong Kong's total exports in 2003. Hong
Kong's trade with the Mainland is to a large extent related to outward processing activities.
More than 80% of Hong Kong manufacturers have established production facilities in the
4
Mainland, which have substantially boosted outward processing activities and Hong Kong's
re-export growth. In 2003, 43.9% of Hong Kong's total exports (of which 68% of Hong
Kong's domestic exports and 42.7% of re-exports) to the Chinese Mainland were related to
outward processing activities. Meanwhile, 71.7% of Hong Kong's imports from the Mainland
and 79.4% of Hong Kong's re-exports of the Mainland origin to all countries other than China
were related to outward processing.
2.2
Trade Interdependence
Although cross-strait trade has to be conducted indirectly, their trade relationship has
become increasingly interdependent. As indicated in Table 1, the Mainland is much more
important as an outlet for Taiwan's exports rather than as a source of supply for Taiwan’s imports
even though the latter’s share has been growing since the middle of the 1990s. Taiwan’s
dependence on the Mainland market as an outlet for its exports grew rapidly from about 2.3
percent in 1987 to about 20 percent by 2001. In contrast, imports from Mainland China
accounted for less than 1 percent of Taiwan's total imports before 1992 and rose gradually to 5.5
percent by 2001. Mainland China’s trade dependence on Taiwan as a source of imports supply
rose rapidly to 14.4 percent in 1997 and declined since then to less than 10 percent by 2001.
Taiwan as an outlet for the Mainland’s exports remained insignificant during the period,
accounting for a share of smaller than 1% before 1992 and only 2.2% by 2001. Moreover, it is
interesting to note the significant change in the commodity composition of cross-strait exports
and imports. During the early stage of the cross-strait trade, Taiwan’s exports to the Mainland
consisted mainly of consumer goods, while imports from the Mainland mainly raw materials.
In recent years, Taiwan’s imports from the Mainland were mainly composed of mechanics
and electronics, clothes and textiles, coals, steels and containers, and exports to the Mainland
were dominated by raw materials of plastics, raw materials of textile, machine equipment and
parts and steels (Zhang, Xu and Zhang, 2003). These significant changes in the commodity
composition reflect the “dynamic” nature of their trade relationship despite of the political
constraint, a result of which has been the shifting and relocating, at least partially, of certain
industries in which Taiwan has been losing or lacking comparative advantage relative to
Mainland China.
5
Table 1: Trade Interdependence between the Greater China Economies (in percentage)
Of the Mainland's
Total Imports (%)
Year:
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
Of Taiwan's Total
Exports (%)
Of the Mainland’s
Total Exports (%)
Of Taiwan's Total
Imports (%)
HK's
TW's
HK's
TW's
Imports
Imports
Imports
Imports
HK's
TW's
TW's
HK's
from
from
from
Exports to Exports to Exports to Exports to from
Mainland Mainland Mainland Mainland Mainland Mainland Mainland Mainland
17.46
21.31
33.35
29.59
2.84
26.12
2.29
23.29
0.00
38.13
0.00
31.05
4.02
30.76
3.67
26.95
0.00
41.83
0.00
31.20
5.49
31.82
4.89
25.74
0.28
47.65
0.28
34.95
7.82
37.78
6.21
24.75
0.55
48.30
0.62
36.75
10.86
41.86
9.10
27.12
0.83
52.47
0.95
37.65
12.03
43.25
11.90
29.63
0.88
53.47
1.04
37.09
12.35
42.16
14.96
32.36
1.12
56.70
1.32
37.51
12.67
42.93
15.75
32.81
1.54
50.36
2.18
37.62
13.86
43.78
16.03
33.34
2.08
46.82
2.99
36.18
13.78
44.61
16.52
34.33
2.02
48.79
2.99
37.15
14.41
46.13
16.81
34.91
2.14
42.96
3.42
37.67
13.11
42.63
16.62
34.45
2.24
40.80
3.93
40.61
12.81
35.00
17.45
33.37
2.32
40.19
4.09
43.61
11.62
30.98
17.63
34.53
2.50
36.84
4.45
43.04
9.88
28.77
19.58
36.92
2.22
32.89
5.50
43.44
22.72
25.10
44.69
23.25
41.14
Sources: ADB: Key indicators 2003; Taiwan Ministry of Economic Affairs: indirect trade across the
Taiwan Straits; and MOFTEC: Almanac of China’s Foreign Economic Relation and Trade, with
authors’ calculation.
With a different pattern, Hong Kong and the Mainland have become increasingly
mutually interdependent in trade. As an outlet for China’s exports and imports, Hong Kong
has been playing an important intermediary role to link China with the rest of the world. The
share of its exports in China’s total exports reached the peak of over 46 percent in 1997 and
the imports share at about 57 percent in 1993. Since then both shares show a declining trend,
down to about 23 percent by 2002, thanks to Mainland China’s direct trade with the rest of the
world. On the other hand, the Mainland has become increasingly important as an outlet for
Hong Kong’s both exports and imports, accounting for a share of about 45 percent and 41
percent of its total in 2002, respectively. Bear in mind of Hong Kong’s huge capital flows to
the mainland, the dependence of Hong Kong on the mainland economy will be enhanced
further.
6
2.3
Intra-Industry Trade
Regional integration has also important adjustment implications for the concerned
economies. One widely used empirical method to assess possible adjustment pressures is to
look at intra-industry trade (IIT) patterns. A high share of IIT in overall trade is considered to
reflect relatively less labour market disruption, with workers tending to move more within
rather than between industries, a result of which would be low adjustment costs. We use 5digit SITC bilateral export and import data to calculate the IIT shares in the manufacturing
(SITC categories 5 to 8) between China and Hong Kong and Taiwan. As it can be seen in
Table 2, the bilateral trade in Chemicals and related products (Category 5) between China and
Hong Kong contains the highest share of intra-industry trade, followed by machinery and
transport equipment (Category 7) and manufactured goods (category 6). The results are in
support to our casual observation that most of Hong Kong’s manufacturing has been relocated
to the mainland since the late 1980s due to its less competitive operation costs. The crossstrait trade contains less IIT, but it shows an increasing sign especially in the recent years. The
low intensity of IIT between the Mainland and Taiwan is largely explained by Taiwan’s
export restriction policy guiding trade with the Mainland.
Table 2: IIT Shares in the Manufacturing between China and
Hong Kong and Taiwan (in Percentage)
ISIC
Hong Kong 5
6
7
8
Taiwan
5
6
7
8
1992
0.214
0.482
0.287
0.195
0.068
0.086
0.078
0.188
1994
0.461
0.454
0.428
0.201
0.054
0.080
0.145
0.245
1996
0.475
0.389
0.424
0.177
0.052
0.086
0.191
0.230
1997
0.446
0.330
0.422
0.107
0.066
0.090
0.261
0.248
1998
0.448
0.327
0.411
0.121
0.076
0.087
0.292
0.264
1999
0.483
0.326
0.371
0.150
0.070
0.089
0.264
0.261
2000
0.503
0.315
0.383
0.177
0.070
0.090
0.229
0.281
Source: OECD: International Trade by Commodity REV3.
2.4
Business Linkages
Similar to its trade pattern with the Mainland, Taiwan’s investments in the Mainland were
essentially carried out indirectly through a third party, which first appeared in the early 1980s,
7
but remained small and also was not captured in official statistics until the end of the 1980s.
According to the Taiwan Ministry of Economic Affairs, by 2002 Taiwan has approved
investment applications in the Mainland totalling 27,276. The total investment value
amounted to US$26.61 billion, and more than 48 percent of Taiwan’s total outward direct
investment was directed to the mainland (Wang, 2003). The figures would make Mainland
China the largest recipient of Taiwan’s outward direct investment. One estimate by Taiwan’s
Central Bank indicates Taiwanese firms have invested more than US$66.8 billion during the
period in 1990-2002 (Wang, 2003). According to the sources from Mainland China, the total
number of approved Taiwanese investment projects reached 55,700, the total contracted
investment amounted to US$61.47 billion, with realized investment reaching US$33.1 billion.
Taiwan would be listed as the second-largest source of investment after Hong Kong should
investment via the third party be counted. Another interesting feature for Taiwanese
investment is its change in sectoral distribution and geographical location. Since the middle of
the 1990s, especially in the most recent years, there was a clear shift of investment interests
towards electronic and electric appliances, information and high technology, capital-intensive
industries (Zhang, Xu and Zhang, 2003). Concerning the geographical distribution, Taiwanese
investments in Mainland China are largely committed into the coastal provinces and
municipalities, accounting for over 80% of Taiwan’s total FDI in the Mainland in 1992-2001.
In particular, Jiangsu and Shanghai experienced a rapid expansion of their shares in attracting
direct investment from Taiwan, increasing from about 14% in 1992 to 51% by 2001, thanks to
the establishment of the Pudong New Zone (a super special economic zone (SEZ)) in Shanghai
in 1990, while Fujian and Guangdong, on the other hand, experienced a sharp drop, down
respectively from 12% and 45% in 1992 to 4% and 28% by 2001. Finally, in recent years
there have been increasingly more and more Taiwanese living, working and studying in the
Mainland, although the mobility of people to Taiwan from the Mainland is still restricted.
Most of Taiwanese live in Shanghai and Shenzhen. With its tradition of liberal business and
international atmosphere, Shanghai has become the “second home” of most Taiwanese after
Taiwan. It was estimated that the presence of Taiwanese in Shanghai has grown from tens of
thousands in the early 1990s to as many as 250,000-350,000 by 2001.
As a financial centre in the region, Hong Kong is the largest source of overseas direct
investment in Mainland China. According to MOFTEC, by the end of 2003, among the
465,277 foreign investment projects registered in Mainland China, 48.3% were tied to Hong
Kong interests. Contracted and utilized capital inflow from Hong Kong amounted to
8
US$414.5 billion and US$222.6 billion, accounting for 44% and 44.4% of the national total.
The increasing use of outward processing facilities in the Mainland has enhanced production
flexibility and helped maintain the price competitiveness of Hong Kong products in the world
market. According to a survey conducted by the Federation of Hong Kong Industries in
December 2002, 11 million Chinese workers were employed either directly or indirectly in
the Mainland by industrial ventures with Hong Kong interests, of which 10 million were in
Guangdong. This, in effect, provides Hong Kong with a substantial production base across the
border. On the other hand, Mainland China is also the largest source of inward investment in
Hong Kong. Based on the Hong Kong statistics, the Mainland's cumulative direct investment
in Hong Kong were HK$594.6 billion at end-2002, accounting for 22.6% of the stock of
inward direct investment. According to market estimation, there are over 2,000 mainlandbacked enterprises registered in Hong Kong, with total asset exceeding US$220 billion. Over
100 mainland and state-owned enterprises were listed on the Stock Exchange of Hong Kong
and the Growth Enterprise Market (GEM). Although there are no official statistics available,
it is generally believed that the mobility of labour between Hong Kong and the Mainland is
the highest in the Greater China area. With China's accession to the World Trade Organisation
(WTO) in late 2001 and the signing of the Closer Economic Partnership Arrangement (CEPA)
between the Mainland and Hong Kong in 2003 as well as the various policy initiatives to
enhance economic cooperation between Guangdong and Hong Kong, economic integration
between Hong Kong and the Mainland is expected to be further strengthened.
Source: ADB: Key Indicator 2003 and IMF: IFS, various issues, with authors’ calculation.
Figure 2: Dispersion of Per Capita GDP for Greater China
9
2.5
Economic Convergence among the Greater China Economies
We group the Greater China economies and calculate a time-series of the coefficient of
variation using GDP per capita data for each year for the period in 1985-2003. Figure 2
presents the results. It is interesting to note that for all samples including the mainland
economy a growing divergence in GDP per capita is the major phenomenon up to 1994, and
since then there is a clear tendency for these economies to approach each other. Even if we
control for the effect of China’s dual exchange rates reunification in 1994, there is a sign of
declining coefficient of variation during the period, indicating the trend of economic
convergence in the Greater China area in the long run.
3.
Analytical Framework
The early literature in addressing the desirability of forming monetary union suggests
that similarity in terms of disturbances and economic structure between the candidates would
be an important criterion (Mundell, 1961; McKinnon, 1964). A large literature in the recent
years attempts to evaluate empirically the degree of business cycle synchronization and the
correlation in structural shocks by employing the structural vector autoregression (VAR)
technique developed by Blanchard and Quah (1989).6 However, this approach does not
necessarily consider how the symmetry in shocks has evolved over time, especially when the
situations concerning the economic interdependence between the candidates economies have
been changed. This study attempts to examine the changes in structural shocks among the
economies by employing the Kalman filter technique. More specifically, we identify the
supply and demand shocks for each economy by the structural VAR technique, and then
employ the time-varying parameter methodology developed by Haldane and Hall (1991) and
Boone (1997) to examine the dynamics of the (a)symmetry in shocks.
3.1
Estimation of Structural Shocks
We first employ the conventional 2-variable VAR with the log of home output (y) and
home price level (p) to identify the fundamental supply and demand shocks. Let
′
′
Δxt ≡ [Δy t , Δpt ] and ε t = [ε st , ε dt ] where Δ represents the first-difference operator and ε st
10
and ε dt denote supply and demand shocks, respectively. The structural model can be
compactly written,
Δxt = A0 ε t + A1ε t −1 + A2 ε t − 2 + ⋅ ⋅ ⋅ = A( L)ε t ,
or
⎡ Δy t ⎤ ⎡ A11 ( L)
⎢Δp ⎥ = ⎢ A ( L)
⎣ t ⎦ ⎣ 21
(1)
A12 ( L) ⎤ ⎡ε st ⎤
,
A22 ( L)⎥⎦ ⎢⎣ε dt ⎥⎦
(2)
where Aij ( L) = a ij0 + a ij1 L + a ij2 L + ⋅ ⋅ ⋅, is a polynomial function of the lag operator, L. We
assume that the structural shocks are serially uncorrelated and have a covariance matrix
normalized to the identity matrix.
In order to identify the structural Ai matrices, we follow the method developed by
Blanchard and Quah (1989). We impose the following long-run restrictions based on standard
macroeconomic theory: only supply shocks affect output in the long-run, but both supply and
demand shocks have a long-run impact on prices. Thus, the restrictions require A12 (1) = 0
which is sufficient to identify the structural Ai matrices and, hence, the time series of
structural shocks.
We estimate a reduced-form VAR as:
Δxt = B( L)Δxt −1 + u t ,
(3)\
where u t is a vector reduced form disturbance and B(L) is a 2 × 2 matrix of lag polynomials.
An MA representation of equation (3) is given as:
Δx t = C ( L)u t ,
(4)
where C ( L) = (1 − B( L) L) −1 and the lead matrix of C (L) is, by construction, C 0 = I . By
comparing equations (1) and (4), we obtain the relationship between the structural and
reduced form disturbances: u t = A0 ε t . As the shocks are mutually orthogonal and each shock
11
has unit variance, C (1)ΣC (1) ′ = A(1) A(1) ′ where Σ = Eu t u t′ = EA0 ε t ε t′ A0′ = A0 A0′ . Letting H
denote the lower triangular Choleski decomposition of C (1)ΣC (1) ′ , we obtain A(1) = H since
our long-run restrictions imply that A(1) is also lower triangular. Consequently, we obtain
A0 = C (1) −1 A(1) = C (1) −1 H . Given an estimate of A0 , we can recover the time series of
structural shocks.
3.2
The Convergence Test
To address the dynamic issue of convergence in structural shocks, we apply the timevarying parameter convergence approach developed by Haldane and Hall (1991), Boone
(1997) and Babetskii et al. (2004) to analyzing the feasibility of a currency union in the
Greater China area. We set the following observation equation:
(ε ti − ε t j ) = α t + β t (ε ti − ε tk ) + ω t ,
(5)
where ε represents the structural shocks and superscripts i, j, k denote the regional key
economy, regional economies and the rest of the world, respectively, and ω t is an
independently and normally distributed error term with zero mean and a constant variance,
σ ω2 . α and β are time-varying coefficients and characterized by the following state
equations:
α t = α t −1 + η t ,
β t = β t −1 + ν t ,
(6)
(7)
where η t and ν t are random error terms with zero mean and variances, σ η2 and σ ν2 ,
respectively.
The time-varying parameter β coefficients in equation (5) measures the temporal
relationship in shocks among three countries (i, j and k), for the purpose of distinguishing a
global trend of convergence from a more specific convergence between two economies.7 If β
approaches to one, the spread on shocks between country i and j is explained by the spread
12
between country i and k, showing that the country j converges toward the country k. If β
tends toward zero, shocks for country j are explained by those for country i, implying that the
country j converges toward the country i.
In this paper we define China as a reference country i and the United States or Japan as
another reference country (i.e., alternative attractor) k. Taiwan, Hong Kong and other East
Asian economies are treated as country j. Accordingly, equation (5) indicates that if the
shocks of an East Asian country are correlated more with those of China than the U.S. or
Japanese shocks (or the shocks of the East Asian country is independent of the U.S. or
Japanese shocks), the parameter β tends to be zero. Conversely, if the shocks of the East
Asian country are correlated more with those of the U.S. or Japan (or the former is
independent of the Chinese shocks), we expect the parameter β to approach to one.
We estimate the time-varying α and β coefficients in equation (5) by using the
Kalman filter technique.8 In employing the Kalman filter technique, the specifications of the
state equations must be carefully considered. Among others, starting values of the state
coefficients may substantially affect the results in small samples. Following McNelis and
Neftçi (1982), we first perform the constant parameter estimation by OLS, and then use the
OLS estimates as the starting values of the state coefficients, which will minimize any
possible variation in the parameters. For the specification of the variance-covariance matrix of
the state equations, we employ the estimated variance-covariance matrix obtained by OLS.
4.
Empirical Analysis
4.1
Data Description
We use real GDP and consumer price index (CPI) as proxies for real output and prices,
respectively. All data are quarterly, expressed in natural logarithms and seasonally adjusted.9
The sample period covers 1986Q1-2003Q4 for all economies except Korea.10
The data for real GDP are obtained from the web sites of the statistic authorities in
respective economies and the NUS ESU databank11. The data for CPI are collected from IMF,
13
International Financial Statistics, Online Version, and the web sites of the statistics
authorities in China, Taiwan and Hong Kong.
4.2
Shock Convergence
Following Blanchard and Quah (1989), we first estimate a structural VAR with 2variables of real output and prices to identify respectively the supply and demand shocks
using the whole sample period from 1986Q1 to 2003Q412. Then, we conduct the correlation
analysis of the identified shocks for both the whole sample period and the sub-sample periods.
Table 3: Correlation of Structural Shocks between China, Taiwan and Hong Kong
1986Q2-2003Q4
1986Q2-1993Q4
1994Q1-2003Q4
1986Q2-1990Q4
1991Q1-1996Q4
1997Q1-2003Q4
China
China
China
China
China
China
Supply Shocks
Taiwan
HK
0.23
0.26 *
0.17
0.20
0.27
0.33 *
0.20
0.26
0.15
-0.14
0.33
0.42 *
Demand Shocks
Taiwan
HK
0.04
0.10
-0.21
0.08
0.22
0.09
-0.07
-0.10
0.11
0.06
0.11
0.29
Notes: Shaded figures and a single asterisk denote positive and significant at the 5 percent and
the 2.5 percent level (one-tailed test), respectively, under the null hypothesis that correlation
coefficient is zero. Significance levels for correlation coefficients are assessed using the
Fisher's variance-stabilizing transformation (see Rodriguez, 1982).
The results of the correlation analysis (reported in Table 3) indicate that demand and
supply shocks between China, Hong Kong and Taiwan have become increasingly correlated
over time, especially since the 1990s. The correlation coefficients of supply shocks between
China and Taiwan rose from 0.17 in 1986-1993 to 0.27 in 1994-2003, and from 0.20 to 0.33
for Hong Kong during the respective sample periods. For demand shocks, the correlation
coefficient changed from negative 0.21 in 1986-1993 to 0.22 in 1994-2003 for the case of
Taiwan, an indication of increasing symmetry in shocks; and a little change in shocks
correlation for Hong Kong during the respective periods. It is interesting to note that the
regional financial crisis has improved the significance of shock correlations between these
economies. However, these results may not be able to reflect the on-going process and to
reveal the dynamics of convergence in shocks. We then estimate the time-varying coefficients
specified in equation (5) by using the Kalman filter technique.
14
Convergence toward China is defined to be evident if the estimated time-varying
coefficients trend downwards, approaching to zero; and weak if constant but not necessarily
zero or declines over the latest part of the sample (see also Boone, 1997; Babetskii et al.,
2004). As α -coefficient represents “autonomous” convergence and should have an expected
value of zero over the long-run, we focus on β -coefficient only.13 Figures 3 and 4 present the
shock convergence of Hong Kong and Taiwan to Mainland China against respectively the U.S.
and Japan as an alternative attractor.14 The results show that the convergence patterns in both
cases are similar. With the U.S. as an alternative attractor, Taiwan’s supply shocks seem to
remain stable and converge to Mainland China only in recent years; while Hong Kong
appears to have converged toward China, especially since the 1990s, although this
convergence process is not completed. When using Japan as the alternative attractor, both
a) Supply Shock: Hong Kong
b) Supply Shock: Taiwan
1.0
1.0
0.8
0.8
0.6
0.6
0.4
0.4
0.2
0.2
0.0
0.0
-0.2
-0.2
86
88
90
92
94
96
98
00
02
86
88
90
Hong Kong (Supply Shock)
92
94
96
98
00
02
00
02
Taiwan (Supply Shock)
c) Demand Shock: Hong Kong
d) Demand Shock: Taiwan
1.0
1.2
0.8
1.0
0.8
0.6
0.6
0.4
0.4
0.2
0.2
0.0
0.0
-0.2
-0.2
86
88
90
92
94
96
98
00
Hong Kong (Demand Shock)
02
86
88
90
92
94
96
98
Taiwan (Demand Shock)
Figure 3: Convergence to Mainland China as Opposed to the USA: β -coefficients
15
Taiwan and Hong Kong show a diverging trend from China during the 1990s and exhibit
weak convergence toward China after 2000. This finding is in line with our early discussion
that the increasing trade and business linkages among the Greater China economies have
shaped these economies structurally. Given the transition status of the Chinese economy
toward market, it is not surprising to note the existence of structural difference and the
incompleteness of the convergence process. However, it is important to see the trend of
convergence in recent years. In favor of a dynamic process, we may conclude that there is a
rising structural symmetry between those economies.
a) Supply Shock: Hong Kong
b) Supply Shock: Taiwan
1.0
1.0
0.8
0.8
0.6
0.6
0.4
0.4
0.2
0.2
0.0
0.0
-0.2
-0.2
86
88
90
92
94
96
98
00
86
02
88
90
92
94
96
98
00
02
00
02
Taiwan (Supply Shock)
Hong Kong (Supply Shock)
c) Demand Shock: Hong Kong
d) Demand Shock: Taiwan
1.0
1.0
0.8
0.8
0.6
0.6
0.4
0.4
0.2
0.2
0.0
0.0
-0.2
-0.4
-0.2
86
88
90
92
94
96
98
00
Hong Kong (Demand Shock)
02
86
88
90
92
94
96
98
Taiwan (Demand Shock)
Figure 4: Convergence to Mainland China as Opposed to Japan: β -coefficients
In contrast, convergence in demand shocks is much more evident than in supply shocks.
Both Hong Kong and Taiwan show a clear convergence trend in demand shocks to Mainland
16
China, especially since the early 1990s. As demand shocks are transitory and essentially
policy induced/corrected, the results indicate that business cycles among these economies
have become more synchronized. As a matter of fact, the deflationary pressure exerted by
China on the Hong Kong price level is a manifestation of the close ties and business cycles
synchronization between the two economies (Cheung, Chinn and Fujii, 2003).
For comparison purposes, we have also estimated the shock convergence for the rest of
East Asian economies (see Appendix Figures B1-B4). Concerning the supply shocks, it is
interesting to note that with the U.S. as the alternative attractor, Korea, Singapore, Indonesia,
Malaysia and Thailand converge with a clear trend to China, whereas the β coefficient shows
a considerable increase in 2003. However, when using Japan as the alternative reference, the
six economies diverge from the Chinese pattern of supply shocks or exhibit a weak
convergence after 2000. For demand shocks, the convergence trend of these East Asian
economies to the demand shocks pattern of China is very evident, especially since the middle
of the 1990s, in both cases of using the U.S. and Japan as the alternative reference. This
finding implies the increasing importance of China as an emerging economy in the region,
and to certain context it also indicates that macroeconomic policies implemented in these
economies have become more cooperative.
4.3
Sensitivity Analysis of Forming a Currency Union
If countries adopt a common currency, they typically relinquish the monetary policy
autonomy and conduct a common stabilization policy in the union. However, if each economy
faces idiosyncratic shocks, such common monetary policy cannot work well as stabilizing
instruments and, hence, the cost of joining a currency union will be quite large. In this section,
we conduct a sensitivity study by employing the output loss function analysis approach to
assess the costs of forming a currency union between the Greater China economies.
Following Ghosh and Wolf (1994), we employ the following output loss function to
assess the country’s output costs of joining a currency union and pursuing a common
monetary policy:
[
]
Lt = 1 − exp (ε t − ε tc )α /(1 − α ) if ε t < ε tc ,
(8)
17
where ε t denotes the productivity shock to the individual country, ε tc the shock to the
currency union, and α the labor share.15 Before joining a currency union, individual countries
conduct their own monetary policy and react to shocks to maintain full employment under the
assumption of nominal wage rigidity. After joining a currency union, however, member
countries have no choice but to use a common monetary policy to accommodate a union-wise
shock. Unless the individual shocks are equal to the union-wide ones, member countries will
suffer from the output loss caused by joining a currency union and renouncing their own
monetary policy autonomy. Whereas this is a highly simplified model, it enables us to assess
empirically the costs of forming a currency union.
Table 4: The Average Output Losses in Percentages: Group A (China, Taiwan and
Hong Kong; Weighted Average)
α=0.7
China
Taiwan
Hong Kong
α=0.6
China
Taiwan
Hong Kong
α=0.5
China
Taiwan
Hong Kong
α=0.4
China
Taiwan
Hong Kong
α=0.3
China
Taiwan
Hong Kong
1986-2003
1986-1990
1991-1996
1997-2003
0.144
0.230
0.242
0.204
0.118
0.213
0.111
0.186
0.252
0.135
0.336
0.252
0.106
0.193
0.202
0.152
0.105
0.181
0.081
0.146
0.212
0.099
0.287
0.206
0.077
0.157
0.164
0.112
0.088
0.150
0.058
0.112
0.173
0.072
0.237
0.165
0.055
0.122
0.128
0.080
0.070
0.119
0.041
0.083
0.135
0.051
0.186
0.127
0.037
0.088
0.093
0.054
0.051
0.087
0.027
0.057
0.098
0.035
0.137
0.092
Note: The output losses in percentages are calculated based on supply
shocks estimated from the Blanchard-Quah method. It is assumed that a
currency union consists of China, Taiwan and Hong Kong, and also that the
monetary authorities in the union accommodate the GDP-weighted average
of the shocks to its member countries. α is a labor share that ranges from
0.3 to 0.7.
To calculate the output loss of joining a currency union, the identified supply shocks in
the previous sub-section are used in equation (8). The shocks to the currency union, ε tc , is
18
defined as the GDP-weighted average of individual member country’s shocks.16 The labor
share parameter, α , ranges from 0.3 to 0.7 for our analysis. We also attempt to assign a
specific value to the individual country’s labor share in line with the existing studies. For cost
comparison purposes, we estimate the output losses for each economy (Hong Kong and
Taiwan) when joining a currency union with different leading country, i.e., China or Japan.
Table 4 reports the results of average output losses with different labor shares caused by the
union-wide shocks for a currency union consisting of the Greater China economies only, and
Table 5 reports the results of output loss when Hong Kong and Taiwan form a currency union
with Japan.17 In Table 6, we calculate the average output losses by assigning a specific labor
share for each economy adopted from Young (1995, 2000).
It is noted from Tables 4 and 5 that the estimated output losses for the member countries
are positively correlated with the labor shares. The higher the labor share, the higher the
output losses would be if a currency union were formed. In the case where a currency union
consists of Mainland China, Taiwan and Hong Kong, the percentage of output losses
increases over time for Taiwan and declines for Hong Kong during the 1990s. It is interesting
to note that, when a currency union is formed with Japan, the average output costs decline
over time for Hong Kong and increase for Taiwan during the 1990s. Moreover, the estimated
output losses for each economy in this case would be larger than forming a currency union
with Mainland China. The results suggest that it would be more costly for Hong Kong and
Taiwan to form a currency union with Japan than with China.
19
Table 5: The Average Output Losses in Percentages: Group B (Japan, Taiwan and
Hong Kong; Weighted Average)
α=0.7
Japan
Taiwan
Hong Kong
α=0.6
Japan
Taiwan
Hong Kong
α=0.5
Japan
Taiwan
Hong Kong
α=0.4
Japan
Taiwan
Hong Kong
α=0.3
Japan
Taiwan
Hong Kong
1986-2003
1986-1990
1991-1996
1997-2003
0.054
0.273
0.322
0.023
0.266
0.377
0.082
0.164
0.309
0.049
0.369
0.299
0.037
0.234
0.276
0.015
0.240
0.321
0.056
0.129
0.267
0.032
0.320
0.257
0.025
0.195
0.227
0.010
0.208
0.265
0.039
0.099
0.220
0.022
0.269
0.211
0.017
0.155
0.178
0.007
0.170
0.210
0.027
0.073
0.172
0.015
0.216
0.164
0.011
0.115
0.130
0.004
0.129
0.155
0.018
0.050
0.125
0.010
0.162
0.120
Note: The output losses in percentages are calculated based on supply
shocks estimated from the Blanchard-Quah method. It is assumed that a
currency union consists of Japan, Taiwan and Hong Kong, and also that the
monetary authorities in the union accommodate the GDP-weighted average
of the shocks to its member countries. α is a labor share that ranges from
0.3 to 0.7.
Table 6: The Average Output Losses in Percentages for Specific Labor Shares
1986-2003
1986-1990
Group A: China, Taiwan and Hong Kong
China
0.106
0.152
Taiwan
0.249
0.124
Hong Kong
0.210
0.188
Group B: Japan, Taiwan and Hong Kong
Japan
0.035
0.015
Taiwan
0.291
0.276
Hong Kong
0.285
0.332
1991-1996
1997-2003
0.081
0.208
0.220
0.099
0.361
0.215
0.054
0.182
0.276
0.031
0.392
0.265
Note: Labor share: 0.60 for China, 0.59 for Japan, 0.749 for Taiwan, and
0.62 for Hong Kong (see Young 1995 and 2000).
When we assign a labor share estimated by Young (1995, 2000) to our estimations, the
above argument does not change much (see Table 6). The results still indicate that the
20
estimated output losses would be smaller for Hong Kong and Taiwan to form a currency
union with Mainland China than with Japan.
4.
Concluding Remarks
Despite of the political deadlock and military confrontation in the Taiwan Strait, the
Greater China economies have experienced rapid integration in the past few decades, which is
believed to have shaped their own economic structure and has direct implications for the
effectiveness of domestic stabilization policy and policy coordination. In this study, we have
used a dynamic measure of shock convergence to assess if there is an increasing symmetry in
shocks among the Greater China economies, in particular, to assess whether there is a process
of convergence at work during the sample period in 1986-2003. The results show that Hong
Kong displays a pattern of supply shocks that looks increasingly similar to that of China,
while there is little indication of convergence for Taiwan except during the recent years. Most
importantly the results indicate an on-going process of convergence. The demand shocks of
Hong Kong and Taiwan have become increasingly synchronized with the Mainland, which to
certain extent may reflect the capacity of these two economies to mimic the policy mix of the
mainland Central Banks.
We have conducted a sensitivity analysis of forming a currency union between the
Greater China economies versus the one consisted of Japan, Hong Kong and Taiwan. The
results show that the estimated output losses of forming a currency union would be far greater
in the latter case than with Mainland China. This finding provides additional evidence to our
conclusion that there is an increasing trend of shocks symmetry among the Greater China
economies and, hence, these economies would not suffer too much from abandoning their
monetary policy as an instrument of absorbing shocks.
21
Appendix A
Analysis of Output Losses
Ghosh and Wolf (1994) set up a simple macroeconomic model and assume that nominal
wage is only rigid downward. Let a country’s output at time t be given by:
Qt = eθ t l tα , (A1)
where θ t is a productivity shock, l t is labor employed in period t, and 0 < α < 1 is a labor
share. The real wage is equal to the marginal product of labor. The nominal wage is assumed
to be set based on information available at t − 1 to reach labor market equilibrium:
log(wt ) = log( Et −1 pt ) + log(α ) + Et −1θ t + (α − 1) log(l ) ,
(A2)
where pt is the price level, E t −1 is the expectations operator based on information available at
t − 1 , and l is the equilibrium employment level.
As nominal wages are downward sticky, the ex post labor demand is conditional on
whether the unexpected productivity shock, ε t ( ≡ θ t − Et −1θ t ), is positive or negative. If the
unexpected productivity shock is positive, nominal wages are assumed to adjust so that fullemployment can prevail. If the unexpected productivity shock is negative, however, nominal
wages do not go down and the ex post labor demand, l t , is given by:
log( pt ) + log(α ) + θ t + (α − 1) log(lt ) = log(wt ) .
(A3)
If the country is not a member of a currency union, it conducts discretionary monetary policy
to offset an adverse shock and set the price at the following level to restore labor market
equilibrium:
log( pt ) − log( Et −1 pt ) = −ε t .
(A4)
22
From equations (A2) and (A3),
log( pt ) + log(α ) + θ t + (α − 1) log(lt ) = log(wt )
= log( Et −1 pt ) + log(α ) + Et −1θ t + (α − 1) log(l ).
(A5)
Suppose, instead, that the country forms a currency union with another country. Let the
productivity shock to the currency union be ε tc , a weighted average shock to the two member
countries. It is also assumed that the monetary authorities in the currency union pursue a
stabilization policy similar to equation (A4) and, hence, the price level ( ptc ) in the currency
union is set based on:
log( ptc ) − log( Et −1 ptc ) = −ε tc .
(A6)
Then, the ex post labor demand when forming the currency union is given by:
lt l = exp[(ε t − ε tc ) /(1 − α )] ,
(A7)
and output, Qtc , is given by:
Qtc / Qt = (eθ t ltα ) /(eθt l α ) = exp[(ε t − ε tc )α /(1 − α )] .
(A8)
Accordingly, when ε t < ε tc , the stabilization policy (A6) does not lead to full employment for
the member country concerned, and the country’s output loss in percentage term is given by:
[
]
Lt = 1 − exp (ε t − ε tc )α /(1 − α ) if ε t < ε tc .
(A9)
23
Appendix B
a) Supply Shock: Korea
b) Supply Shock: Singapore
1.0
1.0
0.8
0.8
0.6
0.6
0.4
0.4
0.2
0.2
0.0
0.0
-0.2
-0.2
86
88
90
92
94
96
98
00
86
02
88
90
92
94
96
98
00
02
00
02
00
02
Singapore (Supply Shock)
Korea (Supply Shock)
c) Supply Shock: Malaysia
d) Supply Shock: Indonesia
1.0
1.0
0.8
0.8
0.6
0.6
0.4
0.4
0.2
0.2
0.0
0.0
-0.2
-0.4
-0.2
86
88
90
92
94
96
98
00
02
86
88
90
Malaysia (Supply Shock)
92
94
96
98
Indonesia (Supply Shock)
e) Supply Shock: Thailand
f) Supply Shock: The Philippines
1.0
1.0
0.8
0.8
0.6
0.6
0.4
0.4
0.2
0.2
0.0
0.0
-0.2
-0.2
86
88
90
92
94
96
98
Thailand (Supply Shock)
00
02
86
88
90
92
94
96
98
Philippines (Supply Shock)
Figure B1: Convergence to Mainland China as opposed to the USA:
β -coefficients for supply shocks
24
a) Supply Shock: Korea
b) Supply Shock: Singapore
1.0
1.2
0.8
1.0
0.8
0.6
0.6
0.4
0.4
0.2
0.2
0.0
0.0
-0.2
-0.2
86
88
90
92
94
96
98
00
02
86
88
90
Korea (Supply Shock)
92
94
96
98
00
02
00
02
00
02
Singapore (Supply Shock)
c) Supply Shock: Malaysia
d) Supply Shock: Indonesia
1.0
1.0
0.8
0.8
0.6
0.6
0.4
0.4
0.2
0.2
0.0
0.0
-0.2
-0.2
86
88
90
92
94
96
98
00
02
86
88
90
Malaysia (Supply Shock)
92
94
96
98
Indonesia (Supply Shock)
e) Supply Shock: Thailand
f) Supply Shock: The Philippines
1.0
1.0
0.8
0.8
0.6
0.6
0.4
0.4
0.2
0.2
0.0
0.0
-0.2
-0.2
86
88
90
92
94
96
98
Thailand (Supply Shock)
00
02
86
88
90
92
94
96
98
Philippines (Supply Shock)
Figure B2: Convergence to Mainland China as opposed to Japan:
β -coefficients for supply shocks
25
a) Demand Shock: Korea
b) Demand Shock: Singapore
1.0
1.2
0.8
1.0
0.8
0.6
0.6
0.4
0.4
0.2
0.2
0.0
0.0
-0.2
-0.2
86
88
90
92
94
96
98
00
02
86
88
90
Korea (Demand Shock)
92
94
96
98
00
02
Singapore (Demand Shock)
c) Demand Shock: Malaysia
d) Demand Shock: Indonesia
1.0
1.2
0.8
1.0
0.6
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.4
0.2
0.2
0.0
0.0
-0.2
-0.2
86
88
90
92
94
96
98
00
02
86
88
90
Malaysia (Demand Shock)
92
94
96
98
00
02
00
02
Indonesia (Demand Shock)
e) Demand Shock: Thailand
f) Demand Shock: The Philippines
1.0
1.0
0.8
0.8
0.6
0.6
0.4
0.4
0.2
0.2
0.0
0.0
-0.2
-0.2
86
88
90
92
94
96
98
Thailand (Demand Shock)
00
02
86
88
90
92
94
96
98
Philippines (Demand Shock)
Figure B3: Convergence to Mainland China as opposed to the USA:
β -coefficients for demand shocks
26
a) Demand Shock: Korea
b) Demand Shock: Singapore
1.0
1.2
0.8
1.0
0.8
0.6
0.6
0.4
0.4
0.2
0.2
0.0
0.0
-0.2
-0.2
86
88
90
92
94
96
98
00
02
86
88
90
Korea (Demand Shock)
92
94
96
98
00
02
Singapore (Demand Shock)
c) Demand Shock: Malaysia
d) Demand Shock: Indonesia
1.0
1.0
0.8
0.8
0.6
0.6
0.4
0.4
0.2
0.2
0.0
0.0
-0.2
-0.2
-0.4
86
88
90
92
94
96
98
00
02
86
88
90
Malaysia (Demand Shock)
92
94
96
98
00
02
00
02
Indonesia (Demand Shock)
e) Demand Shock: Thailand
f) Demand Shock: The Philippines
1.0
1.0
0.8
0.8
0.6
0.6
0.4
0.4
0.2
0.2
0.0
0.0
-0.2
-0.2
86
88
90
92
94
96
98
Thailand (Demand Shock)
00
02
86
88
90
92
94
96
98
Philippines (Demand Shock)
Figure B4: Convergence to Mainland China as opposed to Japan:
β -coefficients for demand shocks
27
Notes
1.
Macau is not included in this study due to the lack of data.
2.
See, for example, Bayoumi and Eichengreen (1994), Bayoumi, Eichengreen and Mauro
(2000), Chow and Kim (2003), and Zhang, Sato and McAleer (2004).
3.
Taiwan limited the number of items permitted for indirect imports from the Mainland to
29 in 1987 and 2,155 by the end of 1994. In recent years, especially since its entry of
WTO, Taiwan has gradually relaxed indirect imports control. By 2001, the number of
items open for imports increased to 5,350 for industrial products and 484 for
agricultural products, accounting for 64.8% and 23.2% of their respective total. On
average, Taiwan has opened up 56.4% of its total number of agricultural and industrial
products for imports from Mainland China.
4.
Taiwan had a trade deficit with the world for three consecutive years from 1998 to
2000, totaling over US$2.3 billion. The trade surplus with the Mainland exceeds
Taiwan’s total trade balance in any single year from 1987 to 2001, the lowest by one
time in 1997 and the highest by 97 times in 2000 (see Zhang, Xu and Zhang, 2003).
5.
Data used in this section were adopted from ADB: Key indicators 2003 and MOFTEC:
Almanac of China’s Foreign Economic Relation and Trade, various issues, with
authors’ calculation.
6.
Among others, Bayoumi and Eichengreen (1994), Bayoumi, Eichengreen and Mauro
(2000), Chow and Kim (2003), and Zhang, Sato and McAleer (2004) apply the
structural VAR technique to the East Asian region and found that some sub-groups of
the East Asian economies, such as Asian NIEs and/or ASEAN, would be a potential
candidate for a currency union.
7.
Testing the convergence of the variables just between two countries is not sufficient if
the convergence of the variables happens to be a global trend. See Boon (1997) for a
detailed discussion of this issue.
8.
See Hamilton (1994) for the Kalman filter estimation.
9.
We use EViews 5 for empirical analysis. Seasonality is adjusted using Census X-12.
10.
The sample period for Korea is from 1986Q1 to 2003Q3.
28
11.
We are grateful to Tilak Abeysinghe for providing us with the real GDP series for some
East Asian economies.
12.
Specifically, we took the first-difference of real GDP and CPI, and then estimated the 2variable VAR specified in Equation (3). Before conducting the VAR estimation, we
first checked the stationarity of the real GDP and CPI by performing the augmented
Dickey-Fuller (ADF) test and the Phillips-Perron test, and found that all series are nonstationary in level but stationary in the first- difference. Because our main interest is to
identify structural shocks, we do not conduct the cointegration estimation, instead the
structural VAR in first-difference.
13.
We conducted the unit-root test (the ADF test) without constant and trend for the
estimated time-varying α -coefficients and found that they are stationary in level.
14.
We have also conducted estimations of equation (5) with the US or Japan as a leading
country and China an alternative attractor, and the results are very similar to the
reported.
15.
See Appendix A for the details of the Ghosh and Wolf (1994) model.
16.
The output losses of small economies (i.e., Hong Kong and Taiwan) in terms of GDP
will be far greater than those of large countries, such as Japan and China, because the
losses are computed by taking GDP weighted average.
17.
We chose not the U.S. but Japan as an alternative leading country, because our
preliminary analysis of correlation in supply shocks shows that Taiwan and Hong Kong
are far more correlated with Japan than the U.S.
29
References
Babetskii, I., L. Boone and M. Maurel, “Exchange Rate Regimes and Shocks Asymmetry:
The Case of the Accession Countries,” Journal of Comparative Economics, 32, pp.212229, 2004.
Bayoumi, T. and B. Eichengreen, “One Money or Many? Analyzing the Prospects for
Monetary Unification in Various Parts of the World,” Princeton Studies in International
Finance, No.16, 1994.
Bayoumi, T., B. Eichengreen and P. Mauro, “On Regional Monetary Arrangements for
ASEAN,” Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 14, pp.121-148, 2000.
Blanchard, O.J. and D. Quah, “The Dynamic Effects of Aggregate Demand and Supply
Disturbances,” American Economic Review, 79, pp.655-673, 1989.
Boone, L., “Symmetry and Asymmetry of Supply and Demand Shocks in the European
Union: A Dynamic Analysis,” Working Paper No.03, CEPII, Paris, 1997.
Cheung, Y.W., Chinn, M.D. and E. Fujii, “China, Hong Kong, and Taiwan: A Quantitative
Assessment of Real and Financial Integration,” CESifo Working Paper Series No.851,
2003.
Chow, H.K. and Y. Kim, “A Common Currency Peg in East Asia? Perspectives from Western
Europe,” Journal of Macroeconomics, 25, pp.331-350, 2003.
Dobson, W. and S.Y. Chia, Multinationals and East Asian Integration, IDRC and ISEAS,
1997.
Ghosh, A.R. and H.C. Wolf, “How Many Monies? A Genetic Approach to Finding Optimum
Currency Areas,” NBER Working Paper #4805, 1994.
Haldane, A.G. and S.G. Hall, “Sterling’s Relationship with the Dollar and the Deutschemark:
1976-89,” The Economic Journal, 101, pp.436-443, 1991.
Hamilton, J.D., Time Series Analysis, Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1994.
Lardy, N., Integrating China into the Global economy, Washington, DC: Brookings
Institution Press, 2002.
McNelis, P.D. and S.N. Neftçi, “Policy-Dependent Parameters in the Presence of Optimal
Learning: An Application of Kalman Filtering to the Fair and Sargent Supply-Side
Equations,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 64, pp.296-306, 1982.
McKinnon, R.I., “Optimum Currency Areas”, American Economic Review, 53, pp.717-725,
1963.
Mundell, R.A., “A Theory of Optimum Currency Areas”, American Economic Review, 51,
pp.657-665, 1961.
30
Naughton, B., “The Emergence of the China Circle,” in Naughton, B., ed., The China Circle:
Economic and Technology in the PRC, Taiwan and Hong Kong, Washington, DC:
Brookings Institution Press, 1997.
Rodriguez, R.N., “Correlation,” in S. Kotz and N.L. Johnson, eds., Encyclopedia of Statistical
Sciences, Vol.2, John Wiley & Sons, pp.193-204, 1982.
Wang, H.S., “The benefits of and Challenges for Cross-Strait Trade and Business after WTO
Accession,” Monthly Bulletin of the International Commercial Bank of China, Taiwan,
February Issue, 2003.
Young, A., “The Tyranny of Numbers: Confronting the Statistical Realities of the East Asian
Growth Experience,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol.110, pp.641-680,
1995.
Young, A., “The Razor's Edge: Distortions and Incremental Reform in the People's Republic
of China,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol.115, pp.1091-1135, 2000.
Zhang, Z.Y., “Trade Liberalization, Economic Growth and Convergence Evidence from East
Asian Economies,” Journal of Economic Integration, Vol.16, No.2, pp.147-164, 2001.
Zhang, Z.Y., K. Sato and M. McAleer, “Is a Monetary Union Feasible for East Asia?”
Applied Economics, 36, pp.1031-1043, 2004.
Zhang, Z.Y., X. Xu and W.B. Zhang, “The Dynamics of Political and Economic Interactions
Between Mainland China and Taiwan,” Papers in Regional Science, Vol.82, No.3,
pp.373-388, 2003.