International Journal of Educational Development 24 (2004) 637–648
www.elsevier.com/locate/ijedudev
Education and corruption
Stephen P. Heyneman
International Education Policy, Peabody College, Vanderbilt University, Nashville, TN 37138, USA
Abstract
This paper will draw on standard international definitions of ‘corruption’ and apply them to the education sector.
It will define corruption in education, explain why it is important, and describe various types of corruption and their
causes. Emphasis will be placed on the role of higher education institutions in educational corruption, but the paper
will not limit itself to higher education. In the end the paper will suggest four categories of reforms designed to
minimize the risk of educational corruption. These include reforms to: (i) educational structures, (ii) the processes of
management and adjudication, (iii) the mechanisms of prevention and when wrongdoing occurs, (iv) the system of
sanctions.
# 2004 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
1. The definition of educational corruption
The definition of education corruption derives
from the more general set of corruption issues.
Like other areas, it includes the abuse of
authority for material gain (Anechiarico and
Jacobs, 1996; Kalnins, 2001; Frimpong and
Jacques, 1999).1 But because education is an
important public good, its professional standards
include more than just material goods; hence
the definition of education corruption includes
the abuse of authority for personal as well as
material gain.
Tel.: +1-615-322-1169; fax: +1-615-343-7094.
E-mail address: s.heyneman@vanderbilt.edu (S.P. Heyneman).
1
The existence of corruption is not the only issue of importance. A separate but related question is the perception of
corruption. According to data from Transparency International for instance, Romania ranks 69 (out of 91 nations) in
terms of corruption perception; Uzbekistan ranks 71 and the
Russian Federation ranks 79. See www.transparency.org/
2. Why is it important for a nation to be free
of education corruption?
Since the time of Plato, it has generally been
understood that a key ingredient in the making of
a nation/state is how it chooses its technical, commercial, and political leaders. In general it is agreed
that no modern nation can long survive if leaders
are chosen on the basis of the ascriptive characteristics, i.e. the characteristics with which they are
born, race, gender, social status. On the other hand
it is common for families to try to protect and
otherwise advantage their own children and relatives. Every parent wishes success for his own
child; every group wishes to see the success of children from their particular group. This is normal.
Schooling provides the mechanism through
which these opposing influences can be fairly
managed.2 It is the common instrument used by
2
These remarks apply to all systems of education whether
delivered by the state, supported financially by the state, or
regulated by the state.
0738-0593/$ - see front matter # 2004 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.ijedudev.2004.02.005
638
S.P. Heyneman / International Journal of Educational Development 24 (2004) 637–648
nations to ‘refresh’ the sources of its leadership.
Economists have tried to estimate the sacrifice in
economic growth if there is a serious bias in the
selection of leaders (Klitgaard, 1986). It has been
estimated that developing countries could
improve their GNP/capita by five percentage
points if they were to base their leadership upon
merit as opposed to gender or social status
(Pinera and Selowsky, 1981). In fact by some estimates, the economic benefit to developing countries of choosing leaders on the basis of merit
would be three times more than the benefit accruing from a reduction in OECD trade restriction
on imports (Kirmani et. al., 1986).
Success in one’s schooling is one of the few
background characteristics seen as necessary for
modern leadership. Although it is possible for
leaders to emerge through experience or just good
fortune, nevertheless, getting ahead in schooling
itself is seen as essential.3
But what if schooling itself is not fair? What
if the public comes to believe that the provision
of schooling favors one social group? What if
the public does not trust in the judgment of
teachers on student performance? What would
happen if the process of schooling had been
corrupted?
The fact is that in a democracy, the public
takes a very active interest in the fairness of its
education system. If the public does not trust the
education system to be fair or effective, more may
be sacrificed than economic growth. It might be
said that current leaders, whether in commerce,
science, or politics, had acquired their positions
through privilege rather than achievement. If the
school system cannot be trusted, it may detract
from a nation’s sense of social cohesion, the principal ingredient of all successful modern societies
(Heyneman, 2000a, 2002).
3
Education is also for purposes of personal consumption,
cultural development and social cohesion. Corruption of these
purposes deeply threatens the nation as well.
3. The characteristics of an education system free
of corruption
A school system, which is free of corruption, is
characterized by the following:
. Equality of access to educational opportunity
. Fairness in the distribution of educational curricula and materials4
. Fairness and transparency in the criteria for
selection to higher and more specialized training
. Fairness in accreditation in which all institutions are judged by professional standards
equally applied and open to public scrutiny
. Fairness in the acquisition of educational
goods and services
. Balance and generosity in curricular treatment
of cultural minorities and geographical neighbors5
. Maintenance of professional standards of conduct by those who administer education institutions and who teach in them, whether public
or private.
4. Categories of educational corruption
4.1. Corrupted functions
4.1.1. Selection
There is no nation in which the proportion of
the age cohort attending at the end of the postcompulsory system is as large as it is in compul4
Access to equal resources is not the same as providing
identical educational inputs—the same book for every student,
etc. The latter was the standard among many party/state
regimes in the Middle East, Africa and Europe and Central
Asia. While identical inputs are a form of equality, in educational terms it is counter productive. It must be acknowledged, on the other hand, that good teaching and honest
teachers can be found even in unequal and corrupt education
systems; and the opposite: poor teaching and unfair teachers
can be found even in systems widely reputed to be excellent
and fair.
5
Among the more important education challenges of the
post cold war world is the danger that education may be
hijacked by political or religious extremists creating threats to
domestic social cohesion and to political security more generally (Heyneman, 1997; 2000a; 2002/3; 2003a,b).
S.P. Heyneman / International Journal of Educational Development 24 (2004) 637–648
sory education. Educational opportunity is
shaped not like a rectangle, but like a pyramid. If
one defines ‘elite’ as meaning only those who are
able may enter, then all nations have education
systems with elite characteristics.6 Therefore, the
question is not whether a system selects a few to
proceed, since all nations must select. Rather, the
question is how that selection is made.
Educators sometimes argue that certain kinds
of selection test techniques are ‘better’ than others. For instance some might argue that essay
questions, or oral examinations are better than
multiple-choice questions. This kind of discussion, when divorced from context, is spurious.
Three principles help determine the choice of
appropriate selection techniques: (i) available
resources, (ii) logistical challenges, and (iii) the
level of public accountability. Maintaining the
same standard of reliability, cost differences in
grading an essay versus a multiple-choice question can be as much as 10:1 (Heyneman, 1987).
Moreover, as test-taking populations expand, the
difference in costs will expand as well. The cost
difference between grading an oral and a multiple-choice exam may be 10:1 if the number of
test takers is 1000, but if the number of test takers is one million, the cost difference may be
100:1.
The appropriate system in Sweden might be to
have each teacher individually design and grade
selection examinations. However, with about one
percent of Sweden’s education resources, about
100 times the number of university applicants,
and an extensive geographical challenge, the
appropriate system in China must be more standardized and machine gradable (Heyneman and
Fagerlind, 1988).
A key difference among nations is not the kind
of test used, but whether whatever technique is
chosen can be corrupted. How selection is managed is deeply important for maintaining an
equality of education opportunity. Since the
Second World War, the technology of administering examinations has changed radically in OECD
countries, but in many parts of the former Soviet
6
The purposes of selection may vary, but selection for leadership is universal among those purposes.
639
Union and other parts of the world, the technologies have not kept pace. Often, each faculty
within each higher education institution administers examinations independently. Many examinations are delivered orally. And many can only be
taken at the university where they are designed.
This system of selection is unfair, inefficient, and
low quality. It is unfair because examinations
have to be taken where they are designed; those
who cannot easily travel have less opportunity.
The effect of this is to limit access to higher
education to students who can afford to travel.
It is inefficient because students must take a
new examination for each institution to which
they apply, and since they cannot do this at a
single sitting, they must wait for a new test-taking
occasion. This may delay their entry by a year
or more. It is of low quality because questions
are often designed by elderly faculty members
who are isolated from modern changes in the
labor markets. They use skills that are out of
date and they design tests whose administration
cannot be standardized. But the key issue is
corruption.
Tests that are centrally scored can still be corrupted by leaks. In some parts of South Asia,
questions are privately sold to high-paying candidates before the test is administered. Being more
subjective and administered in private, oral
examinations are even more open to corruption.
As faculty salaries decline in value, and higher
education institutions require alternative sources
of income, bribery surrounding the admissions
process can become a matter of routine. Candidates may even know how much a ‘pass’ will cost
and be expected to bring the cash ahead of time.
This may have been the case in the 1990s for
instance, in the Russian Federation (World Bank,
1995; Heyneman, 1987, 1997; Plomp and Voogt,
1995; Xuequin, 2001; Heyneman and Fagerlind,
1988).
4.1.2. Consequences of a corrupt selection system
The process of academic selection is the linchpin of any education system, and overall national
cohesion. It represents the essence of the public
good. If the system is corrupt or widely believed
to be corrupt, little else in the education system
640
S.P. Heyneman / International Journal of Educational Development 24 (2004) 637–648
can be successful. Inattention to corruption in
selection will place all other aspects of a nation’s
economic and social ambitions at risk.
4.1.3. How to avoid corruption in selection:
the case for an autonomous examination agency
Designing selection examinations is technically
complex. It requires a high degree of professionalism, modern equipment, and staff with scarce
technical skills able to garner high salaries in the
private sector. Unless they are in very wealthy
countries, few government ministries are able to
perform selection functions well. The alternative
is to create an autonomous agency, staffed with
internationally recognized expertise, guided by
public education standards and policies, but
financed by modest fees to sit for the examinations themselves (Heyneman, 1987, Heyneman
and Fagerlind, 1988).
4.2. Corrupted systems of accreditation
The way in which institutions of higher education are publicly ‘recognized’ is though a system of accreditation. When all institutions were
state owned and administered, the system was
managed within the central ministries. In the
1990s two things have happened which have corrupted many systems of accreditation. First,
because of the openness to new economic systems
and new labor markets, higher education institutions in Asia, Africa, and Eurasia have responded
with a flowering of new degree programs. All
need to be ‘recognized’. Second, the number of
private institutions has blossomed, many of
which claim to be as high in quality as the older,
more established public institutions.
Both of these tendencies are positive and
should be encouraged. The problem is not that
there are non-governmental providers of private
education. The problem is that the system of
accreditation has not sufficiently changed in
response to the new programs and institutions. In
many instances accreditation committees remain
in the hands of rectors of public institutions who
have an interest in preventing competition.
The higher education system of accreditation is
often corrupt because the connection between
higher education, and the system of ‘licensing’
professionals or ‘certifying professionals’ has not
been reformed.7 Whenever higher education institutions are associated with licensure and/or certification, the stakes for accreditation are high.
Therefore the price—on the corrupted market—
for accreditation is high.8
Institutions that seek recognition of new programs, or private institutions which seek institutional recognition, often have to pay a bribe
(Sadlak, 1994; Bogdanov, 2001). This places the
nation at risk because an institution of low quality may be licensing individuals who may not be
of sufficient professional standard. There are
many instances of corrupted accreditation leading
to poor medical schools, law schools, and programs of business and accounting. On the other
hand, the correct response should not be to confine a nation only to old programs and traditional
institutions. All nations need innovation in higher
education in response to social and labor market
challenges (Teferra and Altbach, 2003).
How can a nation encourage educational innovation and, at the same time, protect itself from
poor quality higher education programs? The
answer comes in two ways. First the process of
accreditation must be liberalized. It should be
simple and inexpensive for a new program and
new institutions to operate. Control over quality
should not be made at stage of accreditation.9
Second, the process by which individuals leave
higher education and apply to practice or be certified in their professions should be separated
from the higher education institutions themselves.
No matter how excellent, no university should
7
The license allows a person to practice a given profession;
certification allows a person to practice a specific specialization. For instance, a license may allow someone to practice
medicine; certification may allow medical doctors to practice
surgery.
8
For guidance on how to create a corruption free accreditation system contact the Center for Quality Assurance in
International Education. www.inqaahe.nl.
9
In nations that have a wide variety of quality among
accredited institutions, the function of accreditation changes.
Instead of creating institutions of identical quality, it creates
institutions with identical transparency in public accounting of
their purposes, staffing, and results. The public is then free to
choose a wide range of educational quality at different prices.
S.P. Heyneman / International Journal of Educational Development 24 (2004) 637–648
641
Fig. 1. As economies grow, more is spent on goods and services per student.
provide a license to practice medicine.10 The
license to practice medicine should be made of a
board of medical examiners that manages a system of testing to which all medical applicants
must pass. Similar systems must be established
for law, accounting, and others. Key to this new
system is to allow many new higher education
institutions to compete with one another. This
will allow both low and high quality institutions
to operate freely and at different prices. Having a
variety of quality allows some low quality institutions to attract new students, to innovate, and to
improve. Open competition may allow some institutions of high quality to slip in status and competitiveness. At the same time as this variation in
quality occurs, the public is protected from malpractice by the rigor of the licensing and certification examinations. And because accreditation is
no longer associated with a license to practice, the
process of accreditation can be more liberal. And
having a more open system of accreditation takes
the pressure off it. The effect of this will be to
10
In parts of the world with significant portions of higher
education in private hands, such as the United States, the process of licensing and certification is totally separate from
higher education. A law degree from the University of Chicago
or Yale will not allow anyone to practice law. For that, they
and all others must sit for external examinations. It is the law
examinations that weed out potentially low quality lawyers,
not the law schools. Hence, there is no problem of bribery in
the accreditation process.
eliminate graft and corruption in the process of
accreditation.
4.3. Corrupted supplies
It is rarely recognized that, in fact, education is
a big ‘business’.11 In North America, education
and training accounts for 10% of GDP. Education and training is the economy’s largest sector
after health care, and the fastest in growth. In
considering only compulsory education for a
moment, expenditures can be divided first into
capital and recurrent categories, then into salary
and non-salary categories. In terms of non-salary
expenditures there is a wide variation from one
country to another, with Sweden spending about
$US 2394/pupil and India spending less than
$1.00/pupil (Heyneman, 2001). Nevertheless, as
countries develop economically, more resources
are allocated to support educational quality
(Fig. 1).
This process of development raises the size of
the education markets around the world, particularly in countries with healthy rates of economic growth. Across the world, public education
11
The entrance of universities into the world of commerce
has produced controversy new risks (Heyneman, 2000a,b;
Senter, 1996; Roche, 1994), but there is no viable alternative
to these new university commercial and managerial roles.
What remains is to have these new roles managed and at the
same time, preserve the essence of higher education’s unique
responsibility.
642
S.P. Heyneman / International Journal of Educational Development 24 (2004) 637–648
Table 1
Large growth of education expenditures per region
Continents, major areas and groups
of countries
World total
Africa (North and SSA)
America
Asia
Europe
Oceania
Industrializing countries
SS Africa
Arab states
LAC
EAP
S. Asia
Poorest countries
Industrialized countries
Public expenditure on education per inhabitant ($)
1980
1985
1990
1994
126
48
307
37
418
467
31
41
109
93
12
13
9
487
124
40
375
39
340
439
28
26
122
70
14
14
7
520
202
41
521
66
741
715
40
29
110
102
20
30
9
914
252
41
623
93
982
878
48
32
110
153
36
14
9
1211
expenditures doubled between 1980 and 1994
(Heyneman, 2000b). In North America they grew
by 103%; in Western Europe by 135%. But in
East Asia and the Pacific, they grew by over
200% in the same time period (Table 1).
First it might be noted that corruption in
school supplies can be found in countries at all
levels of economic development, from Kenya and
Uganda (Kigotho, 2002; Heyneman, 1975, 1983)
to Dallas, New York and other more well
endowed environments (Linden and Beck, 1981;
Segal, 1997; Bellamy, 2002). To understand the
problem of corruption in educational supplies,
one must divide the supply process into three distinct parts: (i) design (such as with pedagogical
materials and textbooks); (ii) manufacturing (the
printing); and (iii) distribution. The source of the
problem may be different with each category.
The corruption of the design process usually
occurs when a public agency, such as a ministry
of education, contracts for designs (such as the
writing of textbooks) among a short list of privileged authors or providers.12 Sometimes these
authors or companies provide educational offi12
There may be shadow companies owned by relatives or
friends of senior education officials. The ministry of education
may request and receive three bids from companies owned by
the same individual (anonymous reviewer).
Percent change 1980–1994
100
15
103
151
135
88
55
22
1
65
200
1
0
149
cials with a gift or bribe for the privilege of
designing educational materials. If an author
receives a proportion of the sales, the level of
illegal earnings can be significant. In terms of
book sales in North America, for instance, two
thirds of the publishing profits come from educational publishing; hence the receipt of contacts
for textbook design can bring an automatic benefit to the authors (Heyneman, 1990).
In the manufacturing process, the hazard of
corruption is similar. Benefits will accrue to the
firms that are given contracts for printing or
making the materials, and because of the guarantee level of educational sales, the profits are often
high.
Most corruption in school supplies stems from
the use of ‘protection’. Protection is a well-known
notion in other fields—the manufacturing of
automobiles, furniture, glass, steel, etc. If a country sets up barriers to trade against imports, these
barriers have an economic cost. Governments
may believe that the costs are worth it, and that
protection is justified on the basis of five common
arguments.
4.3.1. National interest, image, and pride
To appear strong, some believe it necessary to
‘protect oneself’ from foreign products. This
argument is very common in education. All
S.P. Heyneman / International Journal of Educational Development 24 (2004) 637–648
nations believe they have the right to educate
their citizens in the way they choose. What may
not be well understood is that to do this well, curriculum, supplies, and materials need not be a
public sector monopoly.
4.3.2. Safeguard of local jobs
This is rarely made in education by comparison, say, to textiles, but it can be used when other
arguments appear weak.
4.3.3. Grace period for ‘infant industries’
This is commonly heard with respect to local
textbook publishers, and providers of tests and
standardized examinations.
4.3.4. Saving foreign exchange
This is an argument typical of very low-income
countries with artificial restrictions on foreign
exchange. The problem with this argument is that
the cost in local exchange may be considerably
higher than an imported product.
4.3.5. Unavailable supply from non-government
sources
In education this is the most common argument heard, particularly with respect to textbooks. This is common in countries where the
language of instruction is local. It is argued that
since no local suppliers exist, the government
therefore must manufacture the nation’s textbooks. The argument rests on the assumption
that the ‘supply response’ would be near zero if
open competitive bidding were allowed, in
essence, there would be market failure. In many
instances this assumption rests on the experience
of there being no fair or open competition in the
past. It also must be remembered, that given market principles, international suppliers—Oxford
University Press, Microsoft, World Book Encyclopedia—are usually quite happy to produce the
products in whatever language is required, and
they are quite prepared to lease copyrighted
materials to local publishers and manufacturers.
4.3.6. How to avoid corruption in educational
supplies
Corruption risk can be minimized by following
three distinct steps.
643
First is to treat the educational procurement
process in the same way as the procurement of all
other goods and services. Educational supplies
should not be singled out as distinct in any way.13
This first step will bring the procurement process
in education in line with the procurement process
in other areas: pharmaceuticals for the health
care system, office supplies, vehicles, etc.
Second is to establish bidding procedures in
which there are no hidden ‘wires’. Specifications
should not be written which would in any way
benefit a single group of manufacturers.
Third is to open up the bidding process in parallel with the new guidelines on education services
circulated by the World Trade Organization.14
Strong resistance to open and competitive bidding often emerges from the education community. It might be noted that protection in
educational manufacturing—whether software or
computer hardware, furniture, textbooks, or even
testing items—has the same cost as protection of
any industrial product. It raises the real price, it
constrains the quality, and it lowers the effectiveness. Most industrialized nations have come to
realize that the natural public responsibility for
education is to establish the curriculum principles
and objectives of education. It is then a public
responsibility to establish professional specification for the delivery of products and services to
meet important national goals. The rest should be
in the hands of the competition. The more limited
the role of the government in the manufacturing
process, the lower the chance for corruption in
the process of educational supply.
13
It might be relevant to note that no OECD country, not
even France or Japan with centralized school systems, designs
or manufactures school supplies from public ministries. In all
OECD countries, the specification for school supplies is a public function, but their design, manufacture and distribution is
contracted out to private suppliers. Foreign suppliers are
invited to participate in the bidding process so long as they
adhere to curricular specifications set by the local Ministry of
Education.
14
These can be obtained from doconline.wto.org/genhom.
asp language = 1.
644
S.P. Heyneman / International Journal of Educational Development 24 (2004) 637–648
5. Professional misconduct
Since education is a public good, education
corruption must include an element broader than
illicit material gain for personal use; it must
include an element of professional misconduct.
Misconduct can be found in other professions—
legal, architectural, accounting, engineering etc.
But when misconduct affects children and youth,
citizens who are not adults or who are young
adults, the implications are more serious and the
safeguards must be more stringent.
Elements of professional misconduct in education include:15
. Accepting of material gifts or rewards in
exchange for positive grades, assessments or
selection to specialized programs;
. Assigning of grades or assessments biased by a
student’s race, culture, social class, ethnicity,
and other ascriptive attributes;
. Insisting on a student’s adoption of the
instructors’ personal values and philosophy;
. Disclosing confidential information regarding
a student;
. Sexually or otherwise exploiting, harassing, or
discriminating against particular students;
. Adopting an inadequate textbook or educational materials because of a manufacture’s
gifts or incentives;
. Forcing students to purchase materials that are
copyrighted by the instructor;
. Ignoring the inadequate teaching of colleagues,
the unequal treatment of students, or the misconduct of fellow professionals;
. Utilizing school property for private commercial purposes.
Definitions of faculty misconduct may differ
from one country to another.16 But no nation can
long ignore the existence of significant misconduct. In some countries it is common for teachers
to accept payment for allowing students to pro15
Adapted from Braxton and Bayer, 1999: 137.
If a faculty member were to assign only reading from his
own book, it would be interpreted as misconduct in higher
education institutions in the United States, but not in all parts
of the world.
16
ceed to the next grade. In some countries it is
common for teachers to offer after school tutoring for a price, and to suggest that students might
fail if they did not pay for after school tutoring.
In some countries, faculty may operate a ‘private’
school in the after school hours, hence using public property for private gain. In some instances, a
school administrator, or university rector may
rent school property, or use it for manufacturing
or agriculture commerce and not report the
income.
In some instances, the misconduct constitutes a
criminal offense.17 Theft or misuse of public property for personal gain is a crime. With the installation of new tuition and fees, it is common for
them to be used for private profit rather than for
the benefit of school or university (Heyneman,
1975, 1983, 1984, 1994, 1997, 1998). In these
instances, misconduct needs to be judged by the
criminal court system. In other instances, the misconduct may be limited to professional ethics. A
teacher’s bias against a certain category of student is an illustration. In these instances, strong
professional boards with the authority to fine and
dismiss should be encouraged. The public needs
to feel protected from faculty misconduct, and
the effectiveness of the professional review boards
may be an essential ingredient in their protection.
6. Corrupted educational property and taxes
Educational facilities often occupy prime locations in urban areas. These can be rented or
leased for both educational and other purposes.
Almost all higher education institutions, and also
many institutions in compulsory education, must
supplement public with non-public resources. But
how should educational property be considered:
as a private or public income? And how should
alternative sources of income be taxed or should
they be taxed at all? And if there is reason not to
tax educational institutions, or to tax them at a
17
In some instances corruption may be confused with mismanagement. Mismanagement is serious because it fosters
inefficiency and inefficiency wastes a student’s and the public’s
resources. But however inefficient, mismanagement is not the
same as an abuse of authority for personal or material gain.
S.P. Heyneman / International Journal of Educational Development 24 (2004) 637–648
645
different rate from commercial businesses, should
one treat all educational institutions the same?
Should income to public education institutions
from non-traditional sources be taxed the same as
non-traditional income in private educational
institutions? Should equity owned private educational institutions (which share profits among
the owners) be treated the same as a charity
which reinvests all profits back into the institution?
One reason why corruption is so common in
education is because the answers to these questions have never been adequately sorted out.
Since the time government ministries ‘owned’ all
property in the Soviet Union, and other parts of
the world now emerging from the era of the
party/state, it has never been quite clear which
portion of government had ownership. Take the
illustration of a local vocational school: would it
be owned by the enterprise on whose land it
might sit? By the local municipality? By the
region? By the national sector ministry? Take a
technical university, previously under the ministry
of industry: Does the land still belong to that
ministry? Or does land at all higher education
institutions now belong to the Ministry of
Education? Or does it belong to the local municipality? Or does it belong to the Rectors Council?
Or would different authorities ‘own’ different elements? Would the state-owned-enterprise own the
equipment, the ministries of education own
the building, and the local municipalities own the
land?
. As long as they are not commercial (i.e. equityowned), neither public nor private educational
institutions should pay tax on income.
. Gifts from individuals and from corporations
should be public information and tax deductible.
6.1. How to avoid corruption of land and taxes
8. Summary
The single most important factor in reducing
the risk of corruption is to clarify the situation of
educational land and educational tax obligations.
Some recommendations:
It has not been common to focus attention on
corruption in education. There were many other
pressing problems in business, banking, the
judicial and legal system, manufacturing, and
agriculture. However, it may be necessary now.
Collapsing public expenditures have driven all
institutions to generate their own resources, for
which there is no precedent, and no regulatory
structure in place to give them guidance. One
thing is abundantly clear: whenever rules and regulations are confusing one must expect a high
level of corruption.
. Higher education land should belong to the
Board of Trust of higher education institutions
themselves. This board of trust may be government appointed, and would guide the longterm institutional interests.
. Profit-making educational institutions which
are equity owned should pay the same taxes as
all commercial businesses.
7. What can be done about educational corruption?
In some respect solving the problem of educational corruption is not significantly different
from solving the problem of corruption in other
sectors. Misappropriation of public property,
bribery in conjunction with public procurement,
whether in education or housing these behaviors
are governed by similar rules and regulations. If
the rules and regulations fail to deter the corruption in these other sectors they will be similarly
ineffective in education.
On the other hand, there are certain preventative measures specific to education corruption.
These fall into four categories: (i) Structural
reforms necessary to reduce the opportunity for
corruption, (ii) improvements in adjudication and
management to help anticipate questions of definition and interpretation, (iii) measures necessary
to actually prevent corruption practice, and (iv)
sanctions required to demote or punish when
infractions occur. These are displayed below in
Table 2.
646
S.P. Heyneman / International Journal of Educational Development 24 (2004) 637–648
Table 2
What can be done about corruption?
S.P. Heyneman / International Journal of Educational Development 24 (2004) 637–648
The burgeoning for profit and not-for profit
private education, and the entrance of public
institutions into private education, has blurred
the lines between what is public and what is private. Few within the public may understand what
is in the private interest and should be taxed, or
in the public interest and should not be taxed.
Confusion reigns over issues of education property. Who actually owns these institutions? And
without clear ownership of its land, no higher
education institution can successfully approach
the private capital markets for a development
loan. In essence, no higher education institution
can invest in its future until the principles of land
ownership are sorted out.
Because of the lack of modern methods and
technologies, the selection systems to higher education are riddled with bribery. Because the structures are outdated, corruption is common in the
accreditation process, the licensing process and in
the certification process. Textbooks and supplies
often remain under monopolies of the state;
foreign suppliers are often prohibited from participating in the bidding process; designers are chosen
on the basis of unprofessional specification and
through personal connections. Because of these
corruptions and distortions, the education
received by young people suffers in quality and in
efficiency.
Lastly, because of the inadequate instruments
of management and sanctions, it is common to
experience professional misconduct. It is common
for teachers to misuse their professional positions,
to accept favors for normal services, and to
accept bribes for looking with favor on certain
students. And it is common to use tuition and
fees for private profit.
These practices would be serious in any sector
where they occurred. But the fact that they occur
with frequency in education poses a particular
problem. The definition of corruption in education includes both material and professional
elements. The reason is that education is the
linchpin to a nations’ social cohesion, and once
the public comes to believe that the education
system is corrupt, they will also believe that the
future of their nation has been unfairly determined against them and their interests. If this
647
occurs, a nation will not be able to establish an
equal partnership with other democracies.
References
Anechiarico, F., Jacobs, J.B., 1996. The Pursuit of Absolute
Integrity: How Corruption Control Makes Government
Ineffective. University of Chicago Press, Chicago.
Bellamy, C., 2002. Teacher too tough on cheaters to suit
school board. The Tennessean February 7, 8A.
Bogdanov, A., 2001. Education too costly, says Kyrgyz minister. BBC Monitoring January 30.
Braxton, J.M., Bayer, A.E., 1999. Faculty Misconduct in Collegiate Teaching. Johns Hopkins University Press,
Baltimore.
Frimpong, K., Jacques, G., 1999. Corruption, Democracy,
and Good Governance in Africa: Essays on Accountability
and Ethical Behavior. Lightbooks Ltd, Botswana.
Heyneman, S.P., 1975. Changes in efficiency and in equity
accruing from government involvement in Ugandan primary education. African Studies Review April, 51–60.
Heyneman, S.P., 1983. Education during a period of austerity:
Uganda, 1971–1981. Comparative Education Review 27
(3), 403–413.
Heyneman, S.P., 1987. Uses of examinations in developing
countries: selection, research, and education sector management. International Journal of Educational Development 7 (4), 251–263.
Heyneman, S.P., Fagerlind, I. (Eds). 1988. University Examinations and Standardized Testing: Technical Paper no. 78.
Washington, DC.
Heyneman, S.P., 1990. Protection of the textbook industry in
developing countries. Book Research Quarterly Winter,
3–11.
Heyneman, S.P., 1994. Education in Europe and Central Asia:
Policies of Adjustment and Excellence. World Bank,
Washington, DC.
Heyneman, S.P., 1997. Education and social stabilization in
Russia. Compare 27 (1), 5–18.
Heyneman, S.P., 1998. Transition from the party/state to
open democracy: the role of education. International Journal of Educational Development 18 (1), 21–40.
Heyneman, S.P., 2000a. From the party/state to multi-ethnic
democracy: education and social cohesion in the Europe
and Central Asia region. Educational Evaluation and Policy Analysis 22 (2), 173–191.
Heyneman, S.P., 2000b. Educational qualifications: the economic and trade issues. Assessment in Education: Principles,
Policy and Practice 7 (3), 417–439, (Little A. (Ed.)).
Heyneman, S.P., 2001. The growing international market for
education goods and services. International Journal of
Educational Development 21 (4), 345–361.
Heyneman, S.P., 2002/3. Defining the influence of education
on social cohesion. International Journal of Education
Research, Policy and Practice 3 (4, Winter), 73–97.
648
S.P. Heyneman / International Journal of Educational Development 24 (2004) 637–648
Heyneman, S.P., 2003a. Education, social cohesion and the
future role of international organizations. Peabody Journal
of Education 78 (3), 25–38.
Heyneman, S.P., 2003b. Education and social cohesion. In:
Guthrie, J. (Ed.), Encyclopedia of Education, Vol. 6. Macmillan Publishers, New York, pp. 2242–2250.
Kalnins, V., 2001. Latvia’s Anti-Corruption Policy: Problems
and Prospects. Soros Foundation, Riga, Latvia, (December).
Kigotho, W., 2002. Kenyan authorities arrest 21 accused of
running fake-diploma ring at Ministry of Education. The
Chronicle of Higher Education February 4.
Klitgaard, R., 1986. Elitism and Meritocracy in Developing
Countries. Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore.
Linden, G.M., Beck, W.M., 1981. White collar crime in the
Dallas public schools. Phi-Delta Kappan 62 (8), 574–577.
Pinera, S., Selowsky, M., 1981. The optimal ability—
education mix and the misallocation of resources within
education. Journal of Development Economics 8.
Plomp, T., Voogt, J., 1995. Curriculum standards and assessment in modern Russian education. In: Mertens, F.J.H.
(Ed.), Reflections on Education in Russia. Acco Publishers, Belgium, pp. 97–113.
Sadlak, J., 1994. The emergence of a diversified system: the
state/private predicament in transforming higher education
in Romania. European Journal of Education 29 (1), 13–23.
Segal, L., 1997. The pitfalls of political decentralization and
proposals for reform: the case of New York City public
schools. Public Administration Review 57 (2), 141–149.
Senter, R.J., 1996. Economic development and the university:
a case study of a failed program. Research in Higher Education 37 (4), 367–387.
Roche, G.C., 1994. The Fall of the Ivory Tower: Government
Funding, Corruption and the Bankrupting of American
Higher Education. National Book Network, Lanham,
MD.
Teferra, D., Altbach, P., 2003. African Higher Education: An
International Reference Handbook. Indiana University
Press, Bloomington.
World Bank. 1995. Russia: Education in the Transition.
World Bank, Washington DC.
Xuequin, J., 2001. Corrupt admissions alleged in China. The
Chronicle of Higher Education September 14.