Public Disclosure Authorized
Public Disclosure Authorized
Public Disclosure Authorized
Public Disclosure Authorized
Finance
41792
for
All?
Policies and Pitfalls
in Expanding Access
FINANCE
FOR ALL?
A World Bank Policy Research Report
FINANCE
FOR ALL?
POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN
EXPANDING ACCESS
© 2008 The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank
1818 H Street NW
Washington DC 20433
Telephone: 202-473-1000
Internet: www.worldbank.org
E-mail: feedback@worldbank.org
All rights reserved
1 2 3 4 5 10 09 08 07
This volume is a product of the staff of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The
World Bank. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this volume do not necessarily
reflect the views of the Executive Directors of The World Bank or the governments they represent.
The World Bank does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this work. The boundaries,
colors, denominations, and other information shown on any map in this work do not imply any
judgement on the part of The World Bank concerning the legal status of any territory or the endorsement
or acceptance of such boundaries.
Rights and Permissions
The material in this publication is copyrighted. Copying and/or transmitting portions or all of this work
without permission may be a violation of applicable law. The International Bank for Reconstruction
and Development / The World Bank encourages dissemination of its work and will normally grant
permission to reproduce portions of the work promptly.
For permission to photocopy or reprint any part of this work, please send a request with complete
information to the Copyright Clearance Center Inc., 222 Rosewood Drive, Danvers, MA 01923, USA;
telephone: 978-750-8400; fax: 978-750-4470; Internet: www.copyright.com.
All other queries on rights and licenses, including subsidiary rights, should be addressed to the Office
of the Publisher, The World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433, USA; fax: 202-5222422; e-mail: pubrights@worldbank.org.
ISBN: 978-0-8213-7291-3
eISBN: 978-0-8213-7292-0
DOI: 10.1596/978-0-8213-7291-3
Cover photo: Comstock.
Cover design: Critical Stages.
Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data
Demirgüç-Kunt, Aslı, 1961–
Finance for all? : policies and pitfalls in expanding access / [by Aslı Demirgüç-Kunt, Thorsten
Beck, and Patrick Honohan].
p. cm.
Includes bibliographical references and index.
ISBN 978-0-8213-7291-3 -- ISBN 978-0-8213-7292-0 (electronic)
1. Financial services industry--Developing countries. 2. Banks and banking--Developing countries.
I. Beck, Thorsten. II. Honohan, Patrick. III. World Bank. IV. Title.
HG195.D46 2007
332.109172’4--dc22
2007033387
Contents
Foreword
ix
The Report Team
Abbreviations
xiii
xv
Overview and Summary
1.
1
Access to Finance and Development:
21
Theory and Measurement
Theory: The Crucial Role of Access to Finance
Measurement: Indicators of Access to Finance
Conclusions
51
Notes
52
2.
23
26
Firms’ Access to Finance: Entry, Growth,
and Productivity
55
Access to Finance: Determinants and Implications
57
The Channels of Impact: Micro and Macro Evidence
60
Transforming the Economy: Differences in Impact
66
What Aspects of Financial Sector Development Matter
for Access?
70
Conclusions
90
Notes
91
3.
Household Access to Finance: Poverty Alleviation
99
and Risk Mitigation
Finance, Inequality, and Poverty
100
Providing Financial Access to Households and Microentrepreneurs:
How and by Whom?
113
v
CONTENTS
4.
Reaching Out to the Poor or to the Excluded?
Conclusions
138
Notes
139
133
Government’s Role in Facilitating Access
143
Expanding Access: Importance of Long-Term Institution
Building
146
Specific Policies to Facilitate Financial Access
152
Policies to Promote Competition and Stability
156
Government Interventions in the Market
163
Political Economy of Access
176
Conclusions
179
Notes
180
Data Appendix
References
189
213
Boxes
Outline of this report
4
Main messages of this report
17
1.1 Access to finance vs. use: voluntary and involuntary exclusion
29
1.2 Access to finance: supply vs. demand constraints
31
1.3 Measuring access through household surveys
34
1.4 Households’ use of financial services: estimating the headline
indicator
36
1.5 Creating indicators of access barriers to deposit, payments, and loan
services
40
1.6 Small firms’ access to finance vs. use: firm-level surveys
48
2.1 Are cross-country regression results credible?
62
2.2 External vs. internal and formal vs. informal finance
66
2.3 When access can be too tempting: risks and use of foreign currency
borrowing by firms
85
3.1 Access to finance and the Millennium Development Goals
105
3.2 Financial depth and poverty reduction: how big is the effect?
109
3.3 Methodological challenges in analyzing the impact of financial
access
112
3.4 Testing impact with randomized control trials
119
3.5 Informal finance
122
3.6 Microfinance and gender
124
3.7 Why don’t migrants use the cheapest methods? Evidence from Tongan
migrants in New Zealand
132
4.1 Basel II and access
158
4.2 Sharia-compliant instruments for firm finance
161
4.3 Rural branching in India
164
4.4 Subsidy and access
175
vi
CONTENTS
Figures
1
2
3
4
1.1
1.2
1.3
1.4
1.5
1.6
1.7
1.8
1.9
1.10
1.11
1.12
2.1
2.2
2.3
2.4
2.5
Proportion of households with an account in a financial institution
5
Percent of firms reporting finance as a problem
6
Finance helps firms grow faster
8
Finance and income inequality
11
Fraction of households with an account in a financial institution
35
Economic development and use of financial services
38
Financial depth vs. use
39
Branch and ATM penetration by income quintile of countries
41
Number of documents required to open a checking account
42
Share of the population unable to afford checking account fees
44
Cost of transferring funds abroad as a percentage of $250
44
Financing and other constraints faced by small firms
46
Percentage of firms using external finance, by firm size
46
Sources of external finance for new investments
47
Time to process an SME loan application
50
Economic development and barriers to access
51
Response of beneficiaries under a credit scheme
59
Impact of self-reported obstacles on growth of firm sales
59
Italy vs. United Kingdom: firm size at entry and over time
61
Finance and growth across Chinese provinces
65
The effect of financing constraints on growth: small vs. large
firms
67
2.6 Credit information sharing and loan losses
75
2.7 Credit information sharing and firms’ financing constraints
76
2.8 Credit loss distribution for portfolios of large and small loans
77
2.9 Foreign bank participation and financing obstacles
79
2.10 Bank ownership and borrower characteristics in Pakistan
82
2.11 Stock price synchronicity with disclosure and governance
87
2.12 Returns to shareholders in acquiring and target firms around the date
of FDI announcement
89
3.1 Financial depth and poverty alleviation
108
3.2 Branch deregulation across U.S. states and income inequality
110
3.3 Testing for credit constraints in South Africa
116
3.4 Use of microcredit for consumption purposes
125
3.5 Remittance flows across countries
130
3.6 Financial self-sufficiency and subsidy dependence
134
3.7 Microfinance penetration across countries
135
3.8 Distribution of MFIs by size of outreach
135
4.1 Supervisory approaches and corruption in lending
159
4.2 Size of loans by Pakistani banks
165
4.3 Estimated annual subsidy cost of selected credit guarantee
schemes
171
vii
Foreword
ACCESS TO FINANCIAL SERVICES VARIES SHARPLY AROUND THE WORLD.
In many developing countries, less than half the population has an
account with a financial institution, and in most of Africa less than
one in five households do. Recent development theory sees the lack of
access to finance as a critical mechanism for generating persistent income
inequality, as well as slower growth. Without inclusive financial systems,
poor individuals and small enterprises need to rely on their own limited
savings and earnings to invest in their education, become entrepreneurs,
or take advantage of promising growth opportunities. Financial sector
policies that encourage competition, provide the right incentives to
individuals, and help overcome access barriers are thus central not only
to stability but also to growth, poverty reduction, and more equitable
distribution of resources and capacities.
The World Bank Group has long recognized that well-functioning
financial systems are essential for economic development. The work of
its financial sector has, over the years, emphasized the importance of
financial stability and efficiency. Promoting broader access to financial
services, however, has received much less attention despite the emphasis it
has received in theory. The access dimension of financial development has
often been overlooked, mostly because of serious data gaps in this area.
Empirical evidence that links access to financial services to development
outcomes has been quite limited, providing at best tentative guidance
for public policy initiatives. The increasing emphasis by policy circles in
recent years on building more inclusive financial systems thus highlights
the need for better data and analysis.
Measuring access to finance, its determinants, and its impact has
been the focus of a major research effort at the Bank in recent years.
ix
FOREWORD
This research has included case-study analyses of specific policies and
interventions, as well as systematic analyses of extensive cross-country
and micro data sets. Finance for All? presents first efforts at developing
indicators illustrating that financial access is quite limited around the
world and identifies barriers that may be preventing small firms and
poor households from using financial services. Based on this research,
the report derives principles for effective government policy on broadening access.
The report’s conclusions confirm some traditional views and challenge others. For example, recent research provides additional evidence
to support the widely-held belief that financial development promotes
growth and illustrates the role of access in this process. Improved
access to finance creates an environment conducive to new firm entry,
innovation, and growth. However, research also shows that small firms
benefit the most from financial development and greater access—both
in terms of entry and seeing their growth constraints relaxed. Hence,
inclusive financial systems also have consequences for the composition
and competition in the enterprise sector.
The evidence also suggests that besides the direct benefits of access
to financial services, small firms and poor households can also benefit
indirectly from the effects of financial development. For example, the
poor may benefit from having jobs and higher wages, as better developed
financial systems improve overall efficiency and promote growth and
employment. Similarly, small firms may see their business opportunities expand with financial development, even if the financial sector still
mostly serves the large firms. Hence, pro-poor financial sector policy
requires a broader focus of attention than access for the poor: improving
access by the excluded nonpoor micro and small entrepreneurs can have
a strongly favorable indirect effect on the poor.
Expanding access to financial services remains an important policy
challenge in many countries, with much for governments to do. However,
not all government action is equally effective, and some policies can
be counterproductive. Policy makers need to have realistic goals. For
instance, while access to formal payment and savings services can
approach universality as economies develop, not everyone will or should
qualify for credit. There are instances where national welfare has been
reduced by overly relaxed credit policies.
Government policies in the financial sector should focus on reforming
institutions, developing infrastructures to take advantage of technologix
FOREWORD
cal advances, encouraging competition, and providing the right incentives through prudential regulations. The report discusses experience and
evidence of different government interventions—such as those through
taxes, subsidies, and direct ownership of institutions—illustrating how
they sometimes tend to be politicized, poorly structured, and beneficial
mainly those who do not need the subsidy. In the absence of thorough
economic evaluations of most schemes, their net effect in cost-benefit
terms also remains unclear.
Despite best efforts, it seems likely that provision of some financial
services to the very poor may require subsidies. Generally speaking, the
use of subsidies in microcredit can dull the incentive for innovative new
technologies in expanding access, with counterproductive long-term
repercussions for the poor. Besides, evidence suggests that for poor households credit is not the only—or in many cases, the principal—financial
service they need. For example, in order to participate in the modern
market economy even the poor need—but often cannot access—reliable,
inexpensive, and suitable savings and payments products. Subsidies may
sometimes be better spent on establishing savings and payment products
appropriate to the poor.
This report reviews and synthesizes a large body of research, and
provides the basis for sound policy advice in the area of financial access.
We hope that it will contribute to the policy debate on how to achieve
financial inclusion. While much work has been done, much more
remains to be learned. The findings in this report also underline the
importance of investing in data collection: continued work on measuring
and evaluating the impact of access requires detailed micro data both at
the household and enterprise level.
The World Bank Group is committed to continuing work in the area
of building inclusive financial systems, helping member countries design
financial system policies that are firmly based on empirical evidence.
François Bourguignon
Senior Vice President and Chief Economist
World Bank
Michael Klein
Vice President, Financial and
Private Sector Development, World Bank
Chief Economist, IFC
xi
The Report Team
THIS POLICY RESEARCH REPORT WAS WRITTEN BY ASLI DEMIRGÜÇ-KUNT,
Thorsten Beck (both with the Development Research Group), and
Patrick Honohan (Development Research Group and Trinity College
Dublin), under the general supervision of L. Alan Winters (Development
Research Group). It draws heavily on the results of the on-going research
program in the Finance and Private Sector Team of the Development
Research Group at the World Bank. Original research as background
for this report includes work by the authors and by Meghana Ayyagari
(George Washington University), Robert Cull, Xavier Gine, Leora
Klapper, Luc Laeven (now at the IMF), Ross Levine (Brown University),
Inessa Love, Vojislav Maksimovic (University of Maryland), Maria
Soledad Martinez Peria, David McKenzie, Sergio Schmukler, Colin
Xu, and Bilal Zia.
The peer reviewers for the report were Franklin Allen (Wharton
School), Stijn Claessens (IMF), Augusto de la Torre, Michael Fuchs,
Richard Rosenberg (CGAP), and Guillermo Perry. The authors also
benefited from conversations with and comments from Finance and
Private Sector Board members, members of the UN Advisors Group
for Building Inclusive Financial Systems, participants of the 2007 IMFWorld Bank Dutch Constituency meeting in Moldova, and the 2007
WBER-DECRG conference on Access to Finance in Washington, DC.
While the analysis in this report needs to satisfy scientific standards and
hence is mainly based on academic research, the study has also benefited
from extensive discussions with policy makers and advisers in the course
of operational support for World Bank diagnostic and policy development work in the financial sector.
xiii
THE REPORT TEAM
The authors are also grateful to Priya Basu, Gerard Caprio (Williams
College), Shawn Cole (Harvard Business School), Gerrardo Corrochano,
Carlos Cuevas, Uri Dadush, Enrica Detragiache (IMF), Quy-Toan Do,
Samir El Daher, Aurora Ferrari, Francisco Ferreira, Inderbir Dhingra,
Matthew Gamser, Alan Gelb, Michael Goldberg, Arvind Gupta, Santiago
Herrera, Alain Ize, Eduardo Levy-Yeyati, Omer Karasapan, Shigeo Katsu,
Aart Kraay, Anjali Kumar, Rodney Lester, Latifah Osman Merican, Pradeep
Mitra, Ashish Narain, Tatiana Nenova, David Porteous, Roberto Rocha,
Luis Serven, Patrick Stuart, and Willem van Eeghen for comments.
The authors would like to acknowledge the editorial assistance of Mark
Feige. Edward Al-Hussainy and Subika Farazi provided excellent research
assistance and Agnes Yaptenco superb administrative support. Polly Means
contributed to cover design and graphics. Report design, production, and
dissemination were coordinated by the World Bank Publications team.
We are grateful to Stephen McGroarty and Santiago Pombo Bejarano in
the Office of the Publisher, and to Arvind Gupta, Merrell Tuck-Primdahl,
and Kavita Watsa for assistance in dissemination.
Financial support from the Knowledge for Change Program is gratefully acknowledged.
The findings, interpretations, and conclusions of this policy research
report are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of
the World Bank, its executive directors, or the countries they represent.
xiv
Abbreviations
ATM
DFI
FDI
GDP
MFI
ROSCAs
SBA
SME
automated teller machine
development finance institution
foreign direct investment
gross domestic product
microfinance institution
rotating savings and credit associations
Small Business Administration (United States)
small and medium enterprise
xv
Overview and Summary
FINANCIAL MARKETS AND INSTITUTIONS EXIST TO MITIGATE THE
effects of information asymmetries and transaction costs that prevent
the direct pooling and investment of society’s savings. Financial institutions help mobilize savings and provide payments services that facilitate
the exchange of goods and services. In addition, they produce and
process information about investors and investment projects to enable
efficient allocation of funds; to monitor investments and exert corporate governance after those funds are allocated; and to help diversify,
transform, and manage risk. When they work well, financial institutions
and markets provide opportunities for all market participants to take
advantage of the best investments by channeling funds to their most
productive uses, hence boosting growth, improving income distribution,
and reducing poverty. When they do not work well, opportunities for
growth are missed, inequalities persist, and in the extreme cases, costly
crises follow.
Much attention has focused on the depth and efficiency of financial
systems—and for good reason: well-functioning financial systems are
by definition efficient, allocating funds to their most productive uses.
Well-functioning financial systems serve other vital purposes as well,
including offering savings, payments, and risk-management products to
as large a set of participants as possible, and seeking out and financing
good growth opportunities wherever they may be. Without inclusive
financial systems, poor individuals and small enterprises need to rely on
their personal wealth or internal resources to invest in their education,
become entrepreneurs, or take advantage of promising growth opportunities. Modern development theories increasingly emphasize the key role of
Finance is an essential part of
the development process—
—and a well-functioning
system needs broad access,
as well as depth
1
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Thus, access to finance helps
to equalize opportunities and
reduce inequalities—
—but the access dimension
of financial development has
often been overlooked
2
access to finance: lack of finance is often the critical element underlying
persistent income inequality, as well as slower growth.
Earlier theories of development postulated that a rise in short-term
inequality was an inevitable consequence of the early stages of development. However, it is increasingly recognized that inequality can adversely
affect growth prospects—which implies that wealth redistribution can
spur development. Despite the emphasis that financial market imperfections now receive in theory, development economists have tended
to advocate the adoption of redistributive public policies to improve
wealth distribution and to foster growth. However, since financial
market imperfections that limit access to finance play an important
role in perpetuating inequalities, financial sector reforms that promote
broader access to financial services need to be at the core of the development agenda. Indeed, if financial market frictions are not addressed,
redistribution may have to be endlessly repeated, which could result in
damaging disincentives to work and save. In contrast, building inclusive
financial systems focuses on equalizing opportunities. Hence, addressing
financial market imperfections that expand individual opportunities
creates positive, not negative, incentive effects. While theory highlights
the risk that selectively increased access could worsen inequality, both
cross-country data and evidence from specific policy experiments suggest
that more-developed financial systems are associated with lower inequality. Hence, though still far from conclusive, the bulk of the evidence
suggests that developing the financial sector and improving access to
finance are likely not only to accelerate economic growth, but also to
reduce income inequality and poverty.
Access to financial services—financial inclusion—implies an absence
of obstacles to the use of these services, whether the obstacles are price
or nonprice barriers to finance. It is important to distinguish between
access to—the possibility to use—and actual use of financial services.
Exclusion can be voluntary, where a person or business has access to
services but no need to use them, or involuntary, where price barriers or
discrimination, for example, bar access. Failure to make this distinction
can complicate efforts to define and measure access. Financial market
imperfections, such as information asymmetries and transaction costs,
are likely to be especially binding on the talented poor and on micro- and
small enterprises that lack collateral, credit histories, and connections.
Without inclusive financial systems, these individuals and enterprises
with promising opportunities are limited to their own savings and
OVERVIEW AND SUMMARY
earnings. This access dimension of financial development has often
been overlooked, mostly because of serious data gaps on who has access
to which financial services and a lack of systematic information on the
barriers to broader access.
This report is a broad-ranging review of research work, completed or
in progress, focusing on access to finance. The report presents indicators
to measure financial access, analyzes its determinants, and evaluates the
impact of access on growth, equity, and poverty reduction, drawing on
research that uses data both at the firm and household level. The report
also discusses the role of government in advancing financial inclusion,
and these policy recommendations are stressed throughout the report.
Although much remains to be learned, a significant amount of empirical
analysis has been conducted on these issues over the past years. As with
any review, taking stock of all this research also allows us to identify the
many gaps in our knowledge and helps chart the way for a new generation of research in this area.
The report pays particular attention to the following themes:
This report presents access
indicators, evaluates impact,
and provides policy advice
• Measuring access. How well does the financial system in different
countries directly serve poor households and small enterprises?
Just how limited is financial access? Who has access to which
financial services (such as deposit, credit, payments, insurance)?
What are the chief obstacles and policy barriers to broader access?
• Evaluating the impact of access. How important is access to
finance as a constraint to the growth of firms? What are the
channels through which improved access affects firm growth?
What is the impact of access to finance on households and
microenterprises? What aspects of financial sector development
matter for broadening access to different types of financial services? What techniques are most effective in ensuring sustainable
provision of credit and other financial services on a small scale?
• Adopting policies to broaden access. What is the government’s role
in building inclusive financial systems? Given that financial
systems in many developing countries serve only a small part of
the population, expanding access remains an important challenge across the world, leaving much for governments to do. Not
all government actions are equally effective, however, and some
policies can be counterproductive. The report sets out principles
for effective government policy on broadening access, drawing
on the available evidence and illustrating with examples.
3
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Outline of this report
THIS OVERVIEW INTRODUCES THE MAIN MESSAGES
of the report, pulling together theory, data, and
analysis. It then presents the key policy implications
of this material and highlights some of the challenges
in the implementation of these recommendations. It
concludes with directions for future research.
Chapter 1 starts with analyses of the theoretical models that illustrate the crucial role access to
finance plays in the development process, particularly its influence on both growth and income distribution. Then the chapter examines various data
sets to assess the ability of both firms and households
to access financial services, to identify barriers to
access, and to provide an empirical foundation to
better understand the welfare impacts of broader
financial access.
Chapter 2 focuses on the ability of firms, particularly small firms, to access financial services. It
investigates not only the implications for growth and
productivity for individual firms, and the economy
at large, but also the impact that restrictive financial
access can have on the structure of the economy. The
chapter also explores which aspects of financial sector
development matter for access to external finance—
looking at banks, markets, and nonbank finance, and
focusing especially on the role of foreign banks.
The first step to improving
access is measuring it—
—but the paucity of data
presents methodological
challenges
4
Attention turns to households and microentrepreneurs in chapter 3, which examines whether
an emphasis on financial sector development as a
driver of economic growth is consistent with a propoor approach to development. After reviewing the
theory, empirical evidence at both the micro and
macro levels is presented. The chapter then analyzes
the barriers to access and how they can be overcome,
with particular consideration given to the promise
and limitations of microfinance.
An analysis of the government’s role in facilitating
access to financial services is presented in chapter 4.
The chapter starts with a discussion of the important
role that institution-building must play in improving
access in particular and financial development in
general. It then turns to measures to boost market
capacity, improve competition and efficiency, and
regulate against exploitative and imprudent practices. This is followed by a discussion of the impact
that governments can have by owning or subsidizing
financial service providers; as an example, the case
of government-backed credit guarantee schemes is
looked at in some depth. Before concluding, the
chapter considers key issues in the political economy
of access.
While data on the financial sector are often considered to be readily
available, systematic indicators of access to different financial services
are not. Indeed, access is not easy to measure, and empirical evidence
linking access to development outcomes has been quite limited because of
lack of data. Existing evidence on the causal relations between financial
development, growth, and poverty is consistent with theory. However,
most of the evidence comes either from highly aggregated indicators that
use financial depth measures instead of access or from micro studies that
use financial or real wealth to proxy for credit constraints.
One of the key problems in assessing financial inclusion is that—
unlike indicators of financial depth—an analysis of aggregated data sets
OVERVIEW AND SUMMARY
has limited value. Simply knowing how many deposit accounts there
are, for example, does not reveal much. Some individuals or firms may
have multiple accounts, while others have none; moreover, regulatory
authorities generally do not collect data on individual account holders.
Therefore the best data would be generated by census or survey, which
would allow researchers to measure financial access across subgroups.
Few such surveys exist for households, however, and the data sets that
are available are often not compatible from one country to the next.
In the absence of comprehensive micro data, researchers have sought
to create synthetic headline indicators, combining more readily available
macro data with the results of existing surveys. These headline indicators indicate that households around the world have limited access to
and use of financial services: in most developing countries less than half
the population has an account with a financial institution, and in many
countries less than one in five households does (figure 1).
Survey data on the access of firms to finance are more plentiful—
although there are concerns about the representativeness of the surveys,
particularly with regard to the inclusion of the informal sector (which is
larger than the formal sector in many countries). Survey data indicate that
less than 20 percent of small firms use external finance, about half the rate
of large firms. And in three regions, at least 40 percent of firms report that
access to and cost of finance is an obstacle to their growth (figure 2).
Figure 1
Proportion of households with an account in a financial institution
Percent
100
80
High
60
75th percentile
40
Median
20
0
Low
Sub-Saharan East Asia
Africa
25th
percentile
South Asia
Europe Latin America Middle
East and
and the
and
Central Asia Caribbean North Africa
Source: Honohan (2006).
Note: Figure shows the highest and lowest national percentages, as well as the median and
quartiles, for the countries in each region.
5
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Figure 2
Percentage of firms reporting finance as a problem
High income
East Asia
and Pacific
Access to finance
Cost of finance
Europe and
Central Asia
Latin America
and the Caribbean
Middle East
and North Africa
South Asia
Sub-Saharan Africa
0
10
20
30
40
Percent
50
60
70
Source: Investment Climate Survey (ICS) responses by enterprises in 76 countries, grouped
by region.
Note: Figure shows the percentage of firms reporting access to finance or cost of finance as a
severe or major obstacle to firm growth.
Identifying barriers to access:
physical access, eligibility,
and affordability
6
Why do large proportions of the populations in many developing countries not use financial services? Identifying the barriers that prevent small
firms and poor households in developing countries from using financial
services not only helps researchers understand the reasons for financial
exclusion but also provides hints as to which policies could be helpful
in removing these barriers and broadening access. One major constraint
is geography, or physical access. While some financial institutions allow
clients to access services over the phone or via the Internet, some require
clients to visit a branch or use an automated teller machine (ATM). While
an ideal measure would indicate the average distance from household to
branch (or ATM), the density of branches per square kilometer, or per
capita, provides an initial, albeit crude, indicator. For example, Spain has
96 branches per 100,000 people and 790 branches per 10,000 square
kilometers, while Ethiopia has less than 1 branch per 100,000 people
and Botswana has 1 branch per 10,000 square kilometers.
Another barrier is the lack of proper documentation. Financial institutions usually require one or more documents for identification purposes,
but in many low-income countries, most people—especially those not
employed in the formal sector (who are usually poor)—lack such papers.
OVERVIEW AND SUMMARY
Finally, many institutions have minimum account-balance requirements
or fees that are out of the reach of many potential users. For example, it
is not unusual for banks to require a person opening a checking account
to make a minimum deposit equivalent to 50 percent of that country’s
per capita gross domestic product (GDP).
While barriers to access vary significantly across countries, lower
barriers tend to be associated with more open and competitive banking
systems. Such systems are characterized by private ownership of banks,
including foreign ownership; strong legal, information, and physical
infrastructures (such as telecommunication and road networks); regulatory and supervisory approaches that rely heavily on market discipline;
and substantial transparency and media freedom.
However, access indicators are just that—indicators. While they are
linked to policy, they are not policy variables. Thus, creating indicators
is only the beginning of the effort. Analytical work collecting and using
in-depth household and enterprise information on access to and use
of financial services is necessary to understand the impact of financial
access and to design better policy interventions. Better data and analysis
will help researchers assess which financial services—savings, credit,
payments, insurance—are most important in achieving development
outcomes for both households and firms, and will inform efforts to narrow down which cross-country indicators to track over time.
Barriers to access vary
significantly across countries
Evaluating the impact of access to finance for firms
One of the important channels through which finance promotes growth
is the provision of credit to the most promising firms (figure 3). Many
firms, particularly small ones, often complain about lack of access to
finance. Recent research using detailed firm-level data and survey information provides direct evidence suggesting that such complaints are valid
in that limited access stunts firms’ growth. This finding is supported by
studies based on census data and individual case studies using detailed
loan information.
Access to finance, and the institutional underpinnings associated with
better financial access, favorably affects firm performance along a number
of different channels. Improvements in the functioning of the formal
financial sector can reduce financing constraints for small firms and others who have difficulty in self-financing or in finding private or informal
sources of funding. Research indicates that access to finance promotes
Access to finance can
promote new-firm entry,
growth, innovation, optimum
size, and risk reduction—
7
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Figure 3
Finance helps firms grow faster
Proportion of
firms that grow
at rates requiring
external finance
60
50
40
30
20
0
0.5
1
Private credit as a share of GDP
1.5
Source: Demirgüç-Kunt and Maksimovic (1998).
Note: The graph plots the proportion of firms that are able to grow faster than they would
if they had no access to external finance against financial development as measured by private
credit/GDP.
—to the benefit of the
economy in general
8
more start-ups: it is smaller firms that are often the most dynamic and
innovative. Countries that strangle this potential with financial barriers not only lose the growth potential of these enterprises but also risk
missing opportunities to diversify into new areas of hitherto unrevealed
comparative advantage. Financial inclusion also enables incumbent firms
to reach a larger equilibrium size by enabling them to exploit growth
and investment opportunities. Furthermore, greater financial inclusion
allows firms the choice of more efficient asset portfolios as well as more
efficient organizational forms, such as incorporation.
If stronger financial systems can promote entry of new firms, enterprise
growth, innovation, larger equilibrium size, and risk reduction, then it is
almost inescapable that stronger financial systems will improve aggregate
economic performance. Improved finance does not raise aggregate firm
OVERVIEW AND SUMMARY
performance uniformly, however, but rather transforms the structure of
the economy by affecting different types of firms in different ways. At any
given level of financial development, smaller firms have more difficulty
accessing external finance than do larger companies. But with financial
development and greater availability of external finance, firms that were
formerly excluded are given opportunities. Research shows that small
firms benefit the most from financial development—both in terms of
being able to enter the marketplace and of seeing their growth constraints
relaxed. Hence, inclusive financial sectors also have consequences for the
composition of and competition in the enterprise sector.
Firms finance their investments and operations in many different
ways, depending on a wide range of factors both internal and external to
the individual firm. The availability of external financing depends not
only on a firm’s own situation, but on the wider policy and institutional
environment supporting the enforceability and liquidity of the contracts
that are involved in financing firms. And it also depends on the existence
and effectiveness of a variety of intermediaries and ancillary financial
firms that help bring providers and users of funds together in the market.
Bank finance is typically the major source of external finance for firms of
all sizes. Modern trends in transactional lending suggest that improvements in information availability (for example, through development of
credit registries) and technological advances in analysis of this improved
data (for example, through use of automated credit appraisal) are likely
to improve access of small and medium enterprises (SMEs) to finance.
Provided that the relevant laws are in place, asset-based lending such as
factoring, fixed-asset lending, and leasing are other technologies that can
release sizable financing flows even for small and nontransparent firms.
However, relationship lending (which relies on personal interaction
between borrower and lender and is based on an understanding of the
borrower’s business and not just on collateral or mechanical credit scoring systems) will remain important in environments with weak financial
infrastructures and strong informal economic activity. Because relationship lending is costly for the lender, it requires either high spreads or
large volumes to be viable. If the customer’s creditworthiness is hard
to evaluate, then there may be no alternative to relationship lending.
Indeed, limited access to credit in some difficult environments may be
attributable to the reluctance of existing intermediaries to do relationship lending on a small scale.
Use of modern transactional
lending by banks helps reach
more firms
—but relationship lending will
remain important for informal
economic activity
9
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Foreign banks are likely to
increase access for SMEs—
—and the role of nonbank
finance is likely to increase
The role of foreign banks in improving access has always been
controversial, partly for political reasons. The growing market share of
foreign-owned banks in developing and transition economies has resulted
from a number of forces, including the privatization of long-established
state-owned banks and the sale of distressed banks in the aftermath of
banking crises (often after being financially restructured at the expense
of the host country government). Foreign owners bring capital, technology, know-how, and independence from the local business and political
elites, but debate continues over whether they have improved access.
Most foreign banks are relatively large and do not concentrate on SME
lending, sticking mostly to the banking needs of large firms and highnet-worth individuals. However, the increased competition for large
customers can drive local banks to focus more on providing profitable
services to segments they had once neglected. The balance of a large
body of evidence suggests that a country that allows foreign banks to
operate within its borders is likely, over time, to improve financial access
for SMEs, even if the foreign banks confine their lending to large firms
and government. In contrast, the performance of state-owned banks in
this dimension has tended to be poor.
Nonbank finance remains much less important than bank finance
in most developing countries, but it can play an important role in
improving the price and availability of longer-term finance to smaller
borrowers. Bond finance, for example, can provide a useful alternative
to bank finance. The emergence of a large market in external equity
requires strong investor rights; where these are present, opening to foreign
capital inflows can greatly improve access and lower the cost of capital,
with spillover effects for smaller firms. This is true for portfolio equity
investments, foreign direct investment (FDI), and private equity, all of
which are likely to become increasingly important in the future.
Evaluating impact of access to finance for households
Over the long term, economic growth helps reduce poverty and can be
expected to lift the welfare of most households. Evidence suggests not
only that finance is pro-growth but that it reduces income inequality
(figure 4) and is pro-poor. How important in this process is the direct
provision of financial services to poor households and individuals?
Existing evidence suggests that indirect, second-round effects through
10
OVERVIEW AND SUMMARY
Figure 4
Finance and income inequality
Change in Gini
coefficient
0.03
0.02
0.01
0
–0.01
–0.02
–0.03
–3
–2
–1
0
Private credit / GDP
1
2
Source: Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Levine (2007).
Note: The figure is a partial scatterplot of growth of Gini coefficient vs. private credit/GDP,
controlling for initial levels of Gini.
more efficient product and labor markets might have a greater impact
on the poor than direct access to finance. First, aggregate regressions
yield more robust results of a dampening effect of finance on inequality and poverty, while micro studies, which do not consider spillover
effects, provide a more tenuous picture. Similarly, calibrated general
equilibrium models that take into account labor market effects suggest
that the main impact of finance on income inequality comes through
inclusion of a larger share of the population in the formal economy and
higher wages. Hence, the evidence so far seems to suggest that direct
provision of financial services to the poor may not be the most important
channel through which finance reduces poverty and income inequality.
Therefore, fostering more efficient capital allocation through competitive
and open financial markets should remain an important policy goal,
11
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Financial exclusion extends
beyond the poor in many
countries—
—but there are barriers to
increasing access
Joint lending and dynamic
incentives may increase
inclusion—
12
and it is as relevant for reduction of poverty and inequality as it is for
overall economic growth.
In many countries, however, access to financial services is limited to only
20–50 percent of the population, excluding many nonpoor individuals and
SMEs. That being the case, improving the quality of the services provided
and the efficiency with which they are provided without broadening access
is not enough: it would leave large segments of the population and their
talents and innovative capacity untapped. The provision of better financial
access to these excluded nonpoor micro- and small entrepreneurs can have
an especially favorable indirect effect on the poor. Hence, to promote propoor growth, it is important to improve access not only to the poor but to
all who are currently excluded. That is not to say that improvements in
direct access for the poor should be neglected. The benefits here may be
more modest in the long run, but they can be immediate.
There are many reasons for the limited access to financial services,
especially in the case of the poor. The poor may not have anybody in
their social network who understands the various services that are available to them. Lack of education may make it difficult for them to fill out
loan applications, and the small number of transactions they are likely
to undertake may make loan officers think it is not worthwhile to help
them. As financial institutions are likely to be located in rich neighborhoods, physical distance may also matter—banks simply may not be
near the poor. Even if financial service providers are nearby, some poor
clients may encounter prejudice—being refused admission to banking
offices, for example. The poor face two significant problems in obtaining access to credit services. First, they typically have no collateral and
cannot borrow against their future income because they tend not to have
steady jobs or income streams that creditors can track. Second, dealing
with small transactions is costly for the financial institutions.
The new wave of specialized microfinance institutions serving the poor
has tried to overcome these problems in innovative ways. Loan officers
come from similar backgrounds and go to the poor, instead of waiting
for the poor to come to them. Group-lending schemes improve repayment incentives and monitoring through peer pressure, and they also
build support networks and educate borrowers. Increasing loan sizes as
customers demonstrate their ability to borrow and repay reduces default
rates. The effectiveness of these innovations in different settings is still
being debated, but over the past few decades, microfinance institutions
have managed to reach millions of clients and have achieved impressive
OVERVIEW AND SUMMARY
repayment rates. Even though subsidies are often involved, researchers
are reconsidering whether it might be possible to make profits while
providing financial services to some of the world’s poorest. Indeed,
mainstream banks have begun to adopt some of the techniques used by
the microfinance institutions and to enter some of the same markets.
For many, however, the most exciting promise of microfinance is that it
could reduce poverty without requiring continuous subsidies.
Has microfinance been able to meet its promise? While many heartening case studies are cited—from contexts as diverse as the slums of
Dhaka to villages of Thailand to rural Peru—it is still unclear how big
an impact microfinance has had on poverty overall. Methodological
difficulties in evaluating impact, such as selection bias, make it difficult
to reach any solid conclusion. So far, the evidence from microeconomic
studies, taken together, does not unambiguously show a reduction in
poverty. Additional research—ideally using more field experiments—is
needed to convince the skeptics.
One of the most controversial questions about microfinance is the
extent of subsidy required to provide access. Although group lending
and other techniques are employed to overcome the obstacles involved in
delivering services to the poor, these mechanisms are nevertheless costly,
and the high repayment rates have not always translated into profits.
Overall, much of the microfinance sector—especially the segment that
serves the very poor—still remains heavily dependent on grants and
subsidies. Recent research confirms that there is a trade-off between
profitability and serving the very poor.
Microfinance has traditionally focused on the provision of credit
for very poor entrepreneurs, and enthusiasts often emphasize how
microfinance will unleash the productive potential of these borrowers,
leading to productivity increases and growth. Yet much of microcredit
is not used for investment. Instead, a sizable fraction of it goes to meet
important consumption needs. These are not a secondary concern. For
poor households, credit is not the only, or in many cases the priority,
financial service they need: good savings and payments (domestic as well
as international) services and insurance may rank higher. For example,
one reason why the poor may not put any savings in financial assets may
be the lack of appropriate savings products.
The question, then, has two parts: Should finance for the very poor
be subsidized, and if so, is microfinance the best way to provide those
subsidies? The answer requires comparing costs and benefits of subsidies
—but the welfare impact of
microfinance is not clear—
—and much of the
microfinance sector relies on
grants and subsidies
The poor need other services
in addition to credit—
—and the very poor will require
subsidies to access financial
services
13
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
in the financial sector with those in other areas, such as education and
infrastructure. The clear need for the latter set a high threshold if scarce
public funds are to be diverted to subsidizing access. Within the financial
sector, the case for subsidizing savings and payments services, which can
be seen as basic services necessary for participation in a modern market
economy, seems stronger than that for credit. In the case of credit, interest rate subsidies in particular do not seem to be the way to go, given
their negative incentive effects on repayment, the likelihood that much
of the subsidy will in practice be diverted away from the target group,
and the chilling effect on unsubsidized service providers just starting
to provide small-scale credit. Instead, policies that encourage entry in
general are more promising, as are policies that promote the adoption
of novel techniques (such as those that take advantage of the already
wide and increasing availability of mobile phones). Once in place, such
techniques lower the unit cost of service delivery to the poor.
Policies to broaden access
It is important to have
realistic goals
14
Perhaps more important, improving financial access in a way that benefits
the poor to the greatest extent requires a strategy for inclusion that goes
well beyond credit for poor households. Since expanding access remains
an important challenge even in developed economies, it is not enough to
say that the market will provide. Market failures related to information
gaps, the need for coordination on collective action, and concentrations
of power mean that governments everywhere have an important role to
play in building inclusive financial systems. Not all government action
is equally effective, however, and some policies can be counterproductive. Direct government interventions to support access require careful
evaluation, something that is often missing. Our discussion is selective,
setting out principles for effective government policy, drawing on and
generalizing lessons from specific examples that illustrate how other
issues can be approached.
Even the most efficient financial system supported by a strong contractual and information infrastructure faces limitations. Not all would-be borrowers are creditworthy, and there are numerous examples where national
welfare has been reduced by overly relaxed credit policies. Access to formal
payment and savings services can approach universality as economies
develop. However, not everyone will—or should—qualify for credit.
OVERVIEW AND SUMMARY
Deep institutional reform ensuring, above all, security of property rights against expropriation by the state is an underlying, albeit
often long-term, prerequisite for well-functioning financial systems.
Prioritizing some institutional reforms over others, however, would help
focus reform efforts and have a positive impact on access in the short to
medium term. Recent evidence suggests that information infrastructures
matter most in low-income countries, while enforcement of creditor
rights is more important in high-income countries. Another finding is
that in relatively underdeveloped institutional environments, procedures
that enable individual lenders to recover on debt contracts (for example,
those related to collateral) are more important in boosting bank lending compared with those procedures mainly concerned with resolving
conflicts between multiple claimants (for example, bankruptcy codes).
Given that it is potentially easier to build credit registries and reform
procedures related to collateral compared with making lasting improvements in the enforcement of creditor rights and bankruptcy codes, these
are important findings for prioritizing reform efforts.
Encouraging the development of specific infrastructures (particularly
in information and debt recovery) and of financial market activities that
can use technology to bring down transaction costs will produce results
sooner than long-term institution building. Specific activities include
establishing credit registries or issuing individual identification numbers
to help establish and track credit histories; reducing costs of registering
or repossessing collateral; and introducing specific legislation to underpin
modern financial technology—including leasing and factoring, electronic
finance, and mobile finance.
Encouraging openness and competition is also an essential part of
broadening access, because they spur incumbent institutions to seek
profitable ways of providing services to previously excluded segments
of the population and increase the speed with which access-improving
new technologies are adopted. Foreign banks have an important role to
play in expanding access, as discussed above.
In this process, providing the private sector with the right incentives
is key; hence good prudential regulations are a necessity. Competition
that helps foster access can also result in reckless or improper expansion
if not accompanied by the proper regulatory and supervisory framework.
As increasingly complex international regulations—such as those envisaged in the advanced versions of the Basel II system—are imposed on
banks to help minimize the risk of costly bank failures, it is important
Reforming institutions—
—developing financial
infrastructures to take
advantage of technological
advances—
—encouraging competition—
—and providing the right
incentives
15
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
The role for direct government
intervention is limited
Political economy concerns
are key in implementing
policies to expand access
16
to ensure that these arrangements do not inadvertently penalize small
borrowers. That can happen if banks are not able to make full allowance
for the potential risk-pooling advantages of including SME loans in their
overall loan portfolio. Research suggests that while banks making small
loans have to set aside larger provisions against the higher expected loan
losses from small loans—and therefore they need to charge higher rates of
interest to cover these provisions—they should need relatively less capital
to cover the risk that they will lose more than they have anticipated.
A variety of other regulatory measures is needed to support wider
access. Sometimes the most effective measure is not the most obvious one.
For example, interest ceilings fail to provide adequate consumer protection against abusive lending. Increased transparency and formalization
and enforced lender responsibility are more coherent approaches, along
with support for the overborrowed (such as assistance in finding a viable
workout plan or formalized personal bankruptcy schemes). However,
delivering all of this is can be administratively demanding.
The scope for direct government interventions in improving access is
more limited than often believed. A large body of evidence suggests that
efforts by government-owned subsidiaries to provide credit have generally
not been successful. Direct intervention through taxes and subsidies can
be effective in certain circumstances, but experience suggests that they
are more likely to have large unintended consequences in finance than
in other sectors. For example, with direct and directed lending programs
discredited in recent years, partial credit guarantees have been the direct
intervention mechanism of choice pushed by SME credit activists.
However, these are often poorly structured, embody hidden subsidies,
and benefit mainly those who do not need the subsidy. In the absence
of thorough economic evaluations of most of these guarantee schemes,
their net effect in cost-benefit terms also remains unclear.
In nonlending services, the experience has been mixed. A few government financial institutions have moved away from providing credit
and evolved into providers of more complex financial services, entering
into public-private partnerships to help overcome coordination failures,
first-mover disincentives, and obstacles to risk sharing and distribution
that impede outreach to SMEs by banks. Ultimately, these successful
initiatives could have been undertaken by private capital, but the state
had a useful role in jump-starting these services.
A comprehensive approach to financial sector reform aiming at better
access must take political realities into account. If the interest of powerful incumbents is threatened by the emergence of new entrants financed
OVERVIEW AND SUMMARY
Main messages of this report
FINANCIAL MARKET IMPERFECTIONS THAT LIMIT
access to finance are key in most development theories.
Lack of access to finance is often the critical mechanism behind both persistent income inequality and
slow economic growth. Hence financial sector reforms
that promote broader access to financial services should
be at the core of the development agenda.
Access is not easy to measure, and empirical evidence linking access to development outcomes has
been quite scarce due to lack of data. Initial efforts
indicate that financial access is quite limited around
the world and that barriers to access are common.
Further research to assess the impact of access on
outcomes such as growth and poverty reduction will
require better micro data, particularly data derived
from household and enterprise surveys.
Empirical evidence suggests that improved access
to finance is not only pro-growth but also pro-poor,
reducing income inequality and poverty. Hence
financial development that includes small firms and
the poor disproportionately benefits those groups.
Providing better financial access to the nonpoor
micro- and small entrepreneurs can have a strongly
favorable indirect effect on the poor. Spillover effects
of financial development are likely to be significant.
Hence, to promote pro-poor growth, it is important
to broaden the focus of attention from finance for the
poor to improving access for all who are excluded.
Provision of financial services to the very poor
will require subsidies. If subsidies for credit damage the ability and incentives of the microfinance
industry and the financial sector more generally to
make use of innovative new technologies in providing access for the nonpoor, their effect on the poor
could be counterproductive.
However, for poor households, credit is not the
only—or in many cases, the principal—financial
service they need. Subsidies may be better spent on
savings and payment systems because those services
are necessary for participation in a modern market
economy.
Government policies should focus on building
sound financial institutions, encouraging competition (including foreign entry), and establishing
sound prudential regulation to provide the private
sector with appropriate incentive structures and
broaden access. Governments can facilitate the
development of an enabling financial infrastructure
and encourage adoption of new technologies, but
attempts at direct intervention (through subsidies,
for example, or ownership of financial institutions)
are more likely than not to be counterproductive.
by a system that has improved access and outreach, lobbying by those
incumbents can block the needed reforms. Given that challenges of financial inclusion and benefits from broader access go well beyond ensuring
financial services for the poor, defining the access agenda more broadly to
expand access for all, would include the middle classes and help mobilize
greater political support for advancing the agenda around the world.
Directions for future research
While this report reviews and highlights a large body of research, it
also identifies many gaps in our knowledge. Much more research is
17
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
More theory work—
—and more comprehensive
and consistent data
A better understanding of the
impact of finance
18
needed to measure and track access to financial services, to evaluate its
impact on development outcomes, and to design and evaluate policy
interventions.
New development models link the dynamics of income distribution
and aggregate growth in unified models. There are good conceptual
reasons for believing that financial market frictions play an important
role in the persistence of income inequalities, but there is too little theory
that examines how reducing these frictions may affect the opportunities
faced by individuals and the evolution of relative income levels. Future
theoretical work could usefully study the impact of financial sector
policies on growth and income distribution within the context of these
models and provide new insights.
Lack of systematic information on access is one of the reasons why
empirical research on access has been limited. The efforts described
above in developing cross-country indicators of access are only first steps
in this direction. This work should be continued and expanded, both
in terms of country coverage and coverage of institutions and different
services available. Building data sets that benchmark countries annually
would help focus policymaker attention and allow better tracking and
evaluation of reform efforts to broaden access.
Furthermore, while cross-country indicators of access are useful for
benchmarking, any assessment of the impact of access on outcomes
such as growth and poverty reduction requires data at the household
and enterprise level. Few household surveys focus on financial services.
Efforts to collect this data systematically around the world are important
in improving the understanding of access. Indeed, household surveys
are often the only way to get detailed information on who uses which
financial services from which types of institutions, including informal
ones.
Emerging evidence suggests that financial development reduces income
inequality and poverty, yet researchers are still far from understanding
the channels through which this effect operates. The finance-growth
channel is better understood: firms’ access to finance has been shown to
have significant payoffs in many areas, from promoting entrepreneurship
and innovation to better asset allocation and firm growth. But how does
finance influence income distribution? How important is direct provision of finance for the poor? Which is more important: improving the
functioning of the financial system so that it expands access to existing
OVERVIEW AND SUMMARY
customers, or broadening access to the underserved (including the nonpoor who are often excluded in many developing countries)?
Results of general equilibrium models and evidence at the aggregate
level hint that a narrow focus on giving just the poor better direct access
is not the best policy. Instead, the poor will benefit most by policies that
broaden access in general; moreover, spillover effects of financial development are likely to be important for the poor by improving employment
opportunities and wages. However, simply improving competition and
the available services for those already served by the financial system is
not likely to be enough either. In many countries improving efficiency
will require that access be broadened beyond concentrated incumbents,
since a large proportion of the nonpoor as well as the poor are currently
excluded. Hence the efficiency and access dimensions of finance are
likely to be closely linked, but more research is needed to sort out the
relative importance of these effects on growth and poverty.
In evaluating impact, randomized field experiments are promising.
These experiments operate by varying the treatments of randomly
selected subsamples of the surveyed households or microentrepreneurs.
For instance, they could be offered different financial products, or different terms and conditions, or different amounts of training in financial
literacy. Such random variation allows the researchers to make reliable
inferences about how removing barriers and improving access will affect
growth and household welfare. While this report discusses some of this
research, more experiments need to be conducted in different country
contexts, focusing on different dimensions of access. Ultimately, it is this
welfare impact that should determine which access indicators should be
tracked and how policy should be designed.
Policies to broaden access can take many forms, from improvements
in the functioning of mainstream financial products to innovations in
microfinance. Lack of careful evaluation of different interventions makes
it difficult to assess their impact and draw broader lessons. Careful
research in this area would also help improve design of policy interventions to build more inclusive financial systems.
Randomized field experiments
may provide insights on
welfare impact
19
CHAPTER ONE
Access to Finance and Development:
Theory and Measurement
FINANCE IS AT THE CORE OF THE DEVELOPMENT PROCESS. BACKED
by solid empirical evidence, development practitioners are becoming
increasingly convinced that efficient, well-functioning financial systems
are crucial in channeling funds to the most productive uses and in allocating risks to those who can best bear them, thus boosting economic
growth, improving opportunities and income distribution, and reducing
poverty.1 Conversely, to the extent that access to finance and the available range of services are limited, the benefit of financial development
is likely to elude many individuals and enterprises, leaving much of
the population in absolute poverty. This access dimension of financial
development is the focus of this report.
Improving access and building inclusive financial systems is a goal
that is relevant to economies at all levels of development. The challenge
of better access means making financial services available to all, thereby
spreading equality of opportunity and tapping the full potential in an
economy. The challenge is greater than ensuring that as many people
as possible have access to basic financial services. It is just as much
about enhancing the quality and reach of credit, savings, payments,
insurance, and other risk management products in order to facilitate
sustained growth and productivity, especially for small and mediumscale enterprises. Although the formal financial sector in a few countries
has achieved essentially universal coverage of the population, at least for
basic services, some financial exclusion persists even in many high-income
countries (and, because they find it difficult to participate fully in those
sophisticated economies, financial exclusion can be an even more serious
handicap for those affected).
Well-functioning financial
systems can boost growth and
reduce poverty
21
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Financial market frictions can
generate poverty traps
Measuring access
can be difficult
This chapter reviews the
theoretical models—
22
Theoreticians have long reasoned that financial market frictions can
be the critical mechanism for generating persistent income inequality
or poverty traps. Without inclusive financial systems, poor individuals
and small enterprises need to rely on their personal wealth or internal
resources to invest in their education, become entrepreneurs, or take
advantage of promising growth opportunities. Financial market imperfections, such as information asymmetries and transactions costs, are
likely to be especially binding on the talented poor and the micro- and
small enterprises that lack collateral, credit histories, and connections,
thus limiting their opportunities and leading to persistent inequality and
slower growth. However, this access dimension of financial development
has often been overlooked, mostly because of serious gaps in the data
about who has access to which financial services and about the barriers
to broader access.
Despite the emphasis financial access has received in theory, empirical
evidence that links broader access to development outcomes has been very
limited, providing at best tentative guidance for public policy initiatives
in this area. Financial inclusion, or broad access to financial services,
implies an absence of price and nonprice barriers in the use of financial
services; it is difficult to define and measure because access has many
dimensions. Services need to be available when and where desired, and
products need to be tailored to specific needs. Services need to be affordable, taking into account the indirect costs incurred by the user, such
as having to travel a long distance to a bank branch. Efforts to improve
inclusion should also make business sense, translate into profits for the
providers of these services, and therefore have a lasting effect.
The purpose of this chapter is twofold. First, it briefly reviews the
theoretical models that incorporate capital market imperfections to illustrate how improved access to finance is likely to reduce inequality as well
as promote growth and, through both channels, lead to a reduction in
poverty. Many types of policy measures aimed at reducing poverty and
inequality through redistributive measures such as land reform can have
adverse side-effects on incentives. If the underlying causes of inequality are not removed, the effect of such redistributive measures may be
only temporary and require repetition. A complementary development
strategy would directly address the underlying causes, including capital
market imperfections (in addition to redistributive policies). Financial
sector reforms to achieve this goal can represent a first-best policy to
promote growth and poverty reduction and would also make redistribution more effective and sustainable.
ACCESS TO FINANCE AND DEVELOPMENT: THEORY AND MEASUREMENT
Second, the chapter presents indicators of access to and use of financial
services that households and small firms are likely to need. Developing
better indicators of access to finance is essential to strengthen the link
between theory and empirical evidence and to investigate the channels
through which a more developed financial system promotes development, both in terms of growth and poverty reduction. Indeed, the
extent of direct access to financial services by households and small
enterprises varies sharply around the world, with very limited access in
many countries.
—and presents access
indicators for households
and small firms
Theory: The Crucial Role of Access to Finance
Modern development theory studies the evolution of growth, relative
income inequalities, and their persistence in unified models. In many of
these models, financial market imperfections play a central role, influencing key decisions regarding human and physical capital accumulation and
occupational choices. For example, in theories stressing capital accumulation, financial market imperfections determine the extent to which the
poor can borrow to invest in schooling or physical capital. In theories
stressing entrepreneurship, financial market imperfections determine the
extent to which talented but poor individuals can raise external funds to
initiate projects. Thus, the evolution of financial development, growth,
and intergenerational income dynamics are closely intertwined. Finance
influences not only the efficiency of resource allocation throughout the
economy but also the comparative economic opportunities of individuals
from relatively rich or poor households.
This crucial focus on the financial sector in economic modeling has
been strengthened with the historical development of views on the links
between economic growth and income inequality. It was long believed
that the early stages of economic development would inevitably be
accompanied by inequality and concentrations of wealth. Pointing to the
fact that rich people’s marginal propensity to save is higher than that of
the poor, theoreticians argued that the need to finance large, indivisible
investment projects in the process of development implied that rapid
growth would need wealth concentration, leading to a fundamental
trade-off between growth and social justice. More generally, Kuznets
(1955, 1963) reasoned that this trade-off meant that inequality would
increase in the early stages of development until the benefits of growth
spread throughout the economy. Some of the earlier empirical evidence
Empirical evidence suggests
that the link between growth
and inequality is ambiguous
23
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Modern development theory
highlights the role of finance
Wealth redistribution and
financial development
24
from the United States and other developed countries supported the
Kuznets hypothesis. But evidence from developing countries was not
so supportive.2
The importance of providing incentives to reward the productive
efficiency of enterprise and investment might seem to imply that growth
and inequality must be positively linked, but empirical studies suggest
that this is not always so. In particular, while very low inequality is indeed
empirically associated with rapid subsequent growth, the highest rates
of growth are associated with moderate inequality. Furthermore, high
levels of inequality seem to reduce subsequent growth.3
Helping to explain these findings, more subtle theories have explored
precise mechanisms whereby inequality might adversely affect growth.
Financial market imperfections are often at the core of this line of
thought because inequalities persist because of these imperfections.4
For example, in the model of Galor and Zeira (1993), it is because
of financial market frictions that poor people cannot invest in their
education despite their high marginal productivity of investment. In
Banerjee and Newman’s model (1993), individuals’ occupational choices
are limited by their initial endowments. The structure of occupational
choices—whether people can become entrepreneurs or have to remain
wage earners—in turn determines how much they can save and what
risks they can bear, with long-run implications for growth and income
distribution.5 Hence, these models show that lack of access to finance
can be the critical mechanism for generating persistent income inequality
or poverty traps, as well as lower growth.
One implication of these modern development theories is that redistribution of wealth can foster growth. Indeed, this has been the main
policy conclusion drawn by many readers of these theories. This thinking rationalizes a focus on redistributive public policies such as land or
education reform. However, if it is the capital market imperfections that
lead to these relationships and necessitate redistribution, why neglect
policies that might remove capital market imperfections? Nevertheless,
some theories take credit constraints or other frictions as exogenous.
In others, static information and transaction costs endogenously yield
adverse selection and moral hazard frictions that impede the operation
of financial markets. In either case, researchers take capital market
imperfections as given and suggest different redistributive policies to
promote growth, focusing on schooling, saving, or fertility changes.
This is true even though the literature also notes that if financial market
ACCESS TO FINANCE AND DEVELOPMENT: THEORY AND MEASUREMENT
imperfections continue to exist, absence of a virtuous circle a la Kuznets
may also necessitate permanent redistribution policies.6
A more effective and sustainable development approach would directly
address financial market imperfections, without causing adverse incentive effects. Most redistributive policies create disincentives to work and
save, although the economic magnitudes of these disincentive effects are
a subject of intense debate (Aghion and Bolton 1997). As DemirgüçKunt and Levine (2007) argue, these tensions vanish when focusing on
financial sector reforms. Reducing financial market imperfections to
expand individual opportunities creates positive, not negative, incentive effects. Hence these arguments are very consistent with modern
development theories yet emphasize putting financial sector reforms
that promote financial inclusion at the core of the development agenda.
Addressing financial sector imperfections can also appeal to a wider range
of philosophical perspectives than can redistributive policies inasmuch
as the latter are directly linked with equalizing outcomes, whereas better
functioning financial systems serve to equalize opportunities.
Extensive empirical evidence suggests a significant and robust relationship between financial depth and growth. More recent micro evidence
using firm-level data sets suggests that better-developed financial systems
ease financial constraints facing firms. This finding illuminates one
mechanism through which financial development influences economic
growth. Furthermore, researchers recently have shown that financial
depth reduces income inequality and poverty and is thus particularly
beneficial for the poor.7 This evidence is reviewed in detail in the coming chapters. Although these results are encouraging, the link between
theoretical models and empirical evidence has not been very close because
of a lack of data on access to financial services. While theory focuses
on the importance of broader access and greater opportunities (that is,
financial inclusion), relatively little empirical evidence links access to
finance to development outcomes, and there is little guidance for policies
on how best to promote access.
Financial depth, or development more generally, can have direct and
indirect effects on small firms and poor households. Greater depth is
likely to be associated with greater access for both firms and households,
which will make them better able to take advantage of investment opportunities, smooth their consumption, and insure themselves. However,
even if financial development does not improve direct access for small
firms or poor households, its indirect effects may also be significant.
Financial sector reforms can
improve incentive structures
Empirical evidence on
financial access is limited
25
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Before access can be
improved, it has to be
measured
For example, the poor may benefit from having jobs and higher wages,
as better-developed financial systems improve the efficiency of product
and labor markets and promote growth. Similarly, small firms may see
their business opportunities expand with financial development, even
if the financial sector still mostly serves the large firms.
Only now are many questions about access beginning to be answered.
Just how limited is financial access around the world? What are the chief
obstacles and policy barriers to broader access? How important is access
to finance as a constraint to growth or poverty alleviation? Which matters
more: access by households, or access by firms? Is it more important to
improve the quality and range of services available to those firms and
households who might already have access (intensive margin), or to
provide basic services to those who are completely excluded (extensive
margin)? How important is direct access to finance for the poor and small
firms compared with economywide spillover effects of greater financial
development through more efficient product and labor markets? The
development of indicators of access to financial services is the first step
in answering all these questions. Before we can improve access, or decide
whether and how to do it, we need to measure it.
Measurement: Indicators of Access to Finance
The financial sector is often thought of as being particularly well
documented by statistical data. In advanced securities markets, data on
transactions and prices are often available on a minute-by-minute basis.
Across countries, indicators of the depth of banking systems, capital
markets, and insurance sectors are widely available. Indicators such as
the total value of bank claims on an economy’s private sector expressed
relative to gross domestic product, the turnover of shares (relative to total
stock market capitalization), and the spread between lending and deposit
interest rates have become standard measures of financial sector development. These indicators are also the basis for a large literature assessing
the impact of financial depth and efficiency on outcomes in the real
sector, such as per capita GDP growth, and exploring the determinants
of financial sector development.
Much less is known about how inclusive financial systems are and who
has access to which financial services. How many borrowers are behind
the total value of outstanding loans of a country’s banking system? How
26
ACCESS TO FINANCE AND DEVELOPMENT: THEORY AND MEASUREMENT
many depositors are represented by the statistic on total deposits? Or
taking the perspective from the demand side, what share of the population uses deposit accounts? What share of the population has taken out
a loan? Unlike data on financial depth, these statistics are not readily
available. Until recently, there has been little systematic information
on who is served by the financial sector in developing countries, which
financial institutions or services are the most effective at supporting
access for poor households and small enterprises, or what practical and
policy barriers there may be to the expansion of access. Better data are
needed to advance research on financial inclusion, and significant efforts
have recently been made in this direction.
Unlike measures of financial depth—where data from individual
institutions (or trades in the case of the capital market) can be aggregated
relatively simply to obtain consolidated figures8 — data on financial use
cannot easily be constructed in this way. For instance, the total number of
all bank accounts far exceeds the number of customers served, as households and enterprises may have business with several banks (or multiple
accounts with a single bank). Further, regulatory entities traditionally do
not collect data on individual accounts or account holders (unless they
are large ones), because this information has not been considered useful
for macroeconomic stability analysis. Researchers have therefore used a
variety of different data sources and methodologies to infer the actual
share of households or enterprises that use financial services. Many of
these data collection efforts are recent, and researchers have just started
to relate them to real sector outcomes. As more data become available
and more systematic data collection efforts get under way, one can expect
more and better analysis.
Financial inclusion, or broad access to financial services, is defined here
as an absence of price or nonprice barriers in the use of financial services. Of
course this does not mean that all households and firms should be able to
borrow unlimited amounts at prime lending rates or transmit funds across
the world instantaneously for a fraction of 1 percent of the amount. Even
if service providers are keenly competitive and employ the best financial
technology, prices and interest rates charged and the size of loans and
insurance coverage on offer in a market economy will necessarily depend
on the creditworthiness of the customer. As discussed in later chapters of
this report, subsidies and regulation can influence this outcome to some
extent. But the application of modern techniques in information and
communications technology is more important in improving the prices,
Aggregate data can
be misleading
What does access mean?
27
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Distinguishing between
voluntary and involuntary
exclusion
28
terms, and conditions on which financial services are available—regardless
of whether services are provided at home or abroad.
Improving access, then, means improving the degree to which financial services are available to all at a fair price. It is easier to measure the
use of financial services since use can be observed, but use is not always
the same as access. Access essentially refers to the supply of services,
whereas use is determined by demand as well as supply.
To illustrate the differences between access and use, remember that
even wealthy customers in advanced financial systems will choose not
to use some financial services. Some moderately prosperous customers,
especially older individuals or households, may not have any wish to
borrow money, even if offered a loan at a favorable interest rate. Still,
almost all households need to use some financial services, such as payments services, to participate in a modern market economy, and in a
few of the most advanced economies, use of at least some basic services
from the formal financial sector is essentially universal.
Moreover, some specific financial products are not attractive to
some customers on ethical or religious grounds; nonusage in this case
cannot be attributed to lack of access—although access might be an
issue here if acceptable alternatives are not being offered. The case of
Sharia-compliant financial products can be relevant here, a topic that
is discussed in chapter 4.
For specific classes of financial services, the distinction between access
and use can be significant (box 1.1). The challenge is to distinguish
between voluntary and involuntary exclusion and, among those that
are excluded involuntarily, between those that are rejected due to high
risk or poor project quality and those that are rejected because of discrimination or high prices, which makes financial services or products
unaffordable. While rejection due to high risk and poor project quality
is not necessarily worrisome, rejection due to discrimination and high
prices is, particularly if equilibrium prices are too high, excluding large
portions of the population. In addition, even if the underlying cost
structures are the same in different countries, a given price would lead
to greater exclusion in poorer countries.
Poor people could be involuntarily excluded due to lack of appropriate products or services; they may need simple transaction accounts
rather than checking accounts that entail the risk of incurring severe
overdraft charges when the timing of payments and receipts goes wrong.
Microentrepreneurs might be reluctant to take out loans that require
ACCESS TO FINANCE AND DEVELOPMENT: THEORY AND MEASUREMENT
Box 1.1
Access to finance vs. use: voluntary and involuntary exclusion
WHAT DISTINGUISHES USE OF FINANCIAL SERVICES
from access to financial services? To what extent is
lack of use a problem? The figure below illustrates the
difference between access to and use of financial services.a Users of financial services can be distinguished
from nonusers, and there are important distinctions
among nonusers. On the one hand are those who
do not use financial services for cultural or religious
reasons or because they do not see any need. These
nonusers include households who prefer to deal in
cash and enterprises without any promising investment projects. These nonusers have access, but they
choose not to use financial services. From a policy
maker’s viewpoint, nonusers do not really constitute
a problem because their lack of demand drives their
nonuse of financial services. On the other hand are
the involuntarily excluded who, despite demanding
financial services, do not have access to them. There
are several different groups among the involuntarily
excluded. First, there is a group of households and
enterprises that are considered unbankable by commercial financial institutions and markets because
they do not have enough income or present too high
a lending risk. Second, there might be discrimination
against certain population groups based on social,
religious, or ethnic grounds (red-lining). Third, the
contractual and informational framework might
prevent financial institutions from reaching out to
certain population groups because the outreach is too
costly to be commercially viable. Finally, the price of
financial services may be too high or the product features might not be appropriate for certain population
groups. While the first group of involuntarily excluded
cannot be a target of financial sector policy, the other
three groups demand different responses from policy
makers—a topic that is discussed in chapter 4.
Distinguishing between access to finance and use
Users of formal
financial services
No need
Voluntary
self-exclusion
Population
Cultural / religious reasons
not to use / indirect access
Insufficient income /
high risk
Non-users of formal
financial services
Discrimination
Involuntary
exclusion
Access to financial services
No access to financial services
Contractual / informational
framework
Price / product features
a. For alternative classifications of the reasons for exclusion, see Claessens (2006) and Kempson and others (2000).
29
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Measuring access to, and use
of, financial services
Research is hampered by
limited survey data—
30
them to pledge their personal assets as collateral, a common practice
in most developing countries. In contrast, voluntary exclusion could
result from lack of awareness of products if financial institutions do
not target their marketing toward certain groups. Also, individuals can
access services indirectly, for example, by using an account that belongs
to somebody else in the household. And finally voluntary exclusion
could also result from lack of financial literacy. Defining the “access
problem” is challenging (box 1.2). It also requires a wealth of different
data sources that researchers are just starting to collect. In the remainder of this chapter, we discuss some of these initial efforts and point to
ongoing and future work.
Recent data compilation efforts have made progress toward better
measurement of both access to and use of financial services. Consider first
the measurement of the use of financial services. Ideally, one would like
to have census data on the number and characteristics of households that
have a bank account or an account with a bank-like financial institution.
In the absence of census data, one would at least like to have survey-based
measures that are representative of the whole population and of important
subgroups, again collecting information about the types of financial
services they are consuming, in what quantities, and at what price, as
well as complementary data on other characteristics of the household
that might affect or be affected by their financial service use.
To date, however, survey-based data are quite limited both in terms
of the number of countries that are covered and the amount of information collected about the respondents. The data are often not comparable
across countries because the surveys use different definitions. Only a
handful of the large and long-established Living Standard Measurement
Surveys (LSMS) surveys sponsored by the World Bank cover financial
services, and even these provide limited financial information. However,
a number of specialized household surveys designed to assess financial
access have been conducted in developing countries. Among these are
surveys prepared by or for the World Bank in India, Brazil, Colombia,
and Mexico (box 1.3), though even these are not always representative
of the whole country and are not consistent across different countries.
An ambitious multicountry effort to measure access of individuals to a
wide range of financial services was launched by Finmark Trust in South
Africa and four neighboring countries in 2002 and has since been rolled
out to several other African countries. Some data come as incidental byproducts of surveys designed for other purposes; this is the case for the
ACCESS TO FINANCE AND DEVELOPMENT: THEORY AND MEASUREMENT
Access to finance: supply vs. demand constraints
WHY DOES ONE OFTEN HEAR ABOUT AN ACCESS
problem in credit markets but not about an access
problem, say, for toothpaste? One of the basic rules
of economics is that prices adjust so that at market
equilibrium, supply equals demand. Hence, if
demand for toothpaste exceeds the supply for it,
the price of toothpaste will rise until demand and
supply are equated at the new equilibrium price.
If this price is too high for some, they will not use
toothpaste. But all who are willing to pay the price
will be able to use it. So if prices do their job, there
should be no access problem.
In a famous paper, Stiglitz and Weiss (1981) provide a compelling explanation for why credit markets
are different.a They show that information problems
can lead to credit rationing even in equilibrium.
That is because banks making loans are concerned
not only about the interest rate they charge on the
loan but also about the riskiness of the loan. And
the interest rate a bank charges may itself affect the
riskiness of the pool of loans, either by attracting
high-risk borrowers (adverse selection effect) or by
adversely affecting the actions and incentives of
borrowers (moral hazard effect). Both effects exist
because even after evaluating loan applications, the
banks do not have complete information on their
borrowers. When the interest rate (price) affects the
nature of transaction, market equilibrium may not
occur where demand equals supply.
The adverse selection aspect of interest rates is a
consequence of different borrowers having different
probabilities of repaying their loan. The expected
return to the bank obviously depends on the probability of repayment, so the bank would like to be able
to identify borrowers who are more likely to repay. It
is difficult to identify good borrowers, which is why
a bank uses a variety of screening devices, including
the interest rate. Those who are willing to pay high
interest rates may, on average, be worse risks; they are
willing to take higher risks to gain higher returns if
successful, but such high returns are generally associated with a higher probability of failure, making it
less likely that the loans will be repaid. As the interest
rate rises, the average “riskiness” of those who borrow
increases, possibly reducing the bank’s profits.
Similarly, as the interest rate and other terms of
the contract, such as collateral requirements, change,
the behavior of the borrower is likely to change.
Stiglitz and Weiss show that higher interest rates
lead to moral hazard, that is, they induce firms to
undertake riskier projects with lower probability of
success but higher payoffs when successful.
In a world with imperfect and costly information
that leads to adverse selection and moral hazard
problems, the expected rate of return to the bank
will increase less rapidly than the interest rate and,
beyond a point, may actually decrease, as shown in
figure A. The interest rate at which the expected
return to the bank is maximized, r*, is the “bankoptimal” rate. The bank will not want to raise the
interest rate above this rate, even though demand
may still exceed the funds available for lending.
This also suggests that the supply of loans will be
backward-bending, at interest rates above r*.
Figure A
Expected Return to the Bank
Box 1.2
r*
Interest rate charged
Note: D = demand, S = supply; r = interest rate.
(continued)
31
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Box 1.2 (continued)
Clearly, it is conceivable that at r*, the demand
for funds (D*) exceeds the supply of funds (S*)
as shown in figure B. In the absence of rationing,
with excess demand for loans, unsatisfied borrowers
would offer to pay a higher interest rate to the bank,
bidding up the interest rate until demand equals supply at rM. Although supply does not equal demand
at rate r*, it is the equilibrium interest rate. Since it
is not profitable to raise the interest rate when the
bank faces excess demand for credit, the bank will
deny loans to borrowers who are observationally
indistinguishable from those who receive loans. The
rejected applicants would not receive a loan even if
they offered to pay a higher rate. Hence they are
denied access. Determining empirically whether an
individual or firm has access to finance but chose
not to use it or was rationed out is complex, and the
effects of adverse selection and moral hazard are
difficult to separate (see chapter 3).
What about other financial services, such as
deposit or payment services, which do not suffer
from information problems? Why do these areas
of finance suffer from access problems? For those
types of financial services, nonprice barriers become
important. For example, some individuals will have
no access to financial services because there are no
financial institutions in their area, as is the case in
many remote rural areas. Or the small transactions
the poor demand may involve high fixed transaction
costs, which makes them too costly to be offered: it
costs as much for the bank to accept a $1 deposit as
it does to accept a $1,000 deposit. Poorly designed
regulatory requirements may also exclude those who
do not meet the documentation requirements of opening an account, such as not having a formal address or
formal sector employment. Some would-be customers
may be discriminated against for some reason. For all
those individuals the supply curve is vertical at the
origin, and the supply and demand for services do
not intersect, again leading to an access problem (as
shown by S 0 in figure C). Of course, credit markets
can also suffer from these nonprice barriers in addition
to the type of rationing discussed above.
Price can also be a barrier. Even when nonprice
barriers are overcome and the supply (S´) and
demand do intersect, the equilibrium price for these
services (including the fees, minimum requirements,
and so forth) may be very high, making them unaffordable for a large proportion of the population.
This is an access problem of a different nature
Figure C
S0
Figure B
S′
r
S′′
rM
r′
r*
D
r′′
S
S*
D*
Note: D = demand, S = supply; r = interest rate.
32
L
Note: D = demand, S = supply; r = interest rate.
ACCESS TO FINANCE AND DEVELOPMENT: THEORY AND MEASUREMENT
Box 1.2 (continued)
since there is no rationing, but it still represents a
policy problem because the high price often reflects
lack of competition or underdeveloped physical or
institutional infrastructures, leading to financial
exclusion. These are matters that may call for
public policy interventions to increase competition
among providers and build relevant institutional and
physical infrastructures, hence shifting the supply
curve to the right (S˝), reducing prices, and making
financial services affordable for a larger part of the
population. These government policies are discussed
in chapter 4.
a. For other explanations, see, for example, Keeton (1979) and Williamson (1987).
European Commission’s Eurobarometer, which covers all member states
of the European Union (European Commission 2005).9 Different surveys
have different primary objectives: the questions in the South African
survey reflect the original motivation for doing the survey, which was
to assess the political and commercial climate for expanding access to
finance, rather than to underpin research designed to build a comprehensive picture of economic and financial decision making. Findings
based on surveys of individuals cannot easily be compared directly with
those from surveys of households.10 Different survey methodologies and
their impact on the quality of information gathered are the subjects of
an ongoing research effort at the World Bank.
Thus, despite some interesting insights from individual household
surveys that focus on financial services, lack of cross-country comparability between survey instruments still prevents documentation of crosscountry differences and thus analyses of supply and demand constraints.
Altogether, household or individual survey data providing substantial
financial services information currently exist for fewer than 40 developing countries and are inconsistent across countries in representativeness,
measurement, and definition of financial services and products.11
Lack of consistent cross-country, micro data on use of financial services
has led researchers to consider the information contained in more easily
collected indicators such as the number of loan or deposit accounts in a
country. Of course the total number of accounts is not the total number of
users: people might have several accounts with one institution or accounts
with several institutions. Further, a number of accounts might be dormant,
a particularly common occurrence in many postal savings banks with
—and a lack of cross-country
consistency
33
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Box 1.3 Measuring access through household surveys
EXISTING HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS FOCUSING ON
fi nancial services in India, Brazil, Colombia, and
Mexico give some insights into the information
that can be obtained from such survey instruments beyond simple measures of use of fi nancial
services. Indeed, household surveys are necessary
to obtain detailed information on who uses which
financial services from which types of institutions,
including informal ones. These surveys include
questions on why people do not use fi nancial services, which help researchers distinguish between
use and access issues and between demand and
supply factors.
For example, in the United States, 87 percent of
the adult population has a bank account, compared
with 48 percent in rural Upper Pradesh and Andhra
Pradesh, India; 43 percent in 11 urban areas in Brazil;
41 percent in Bogota, Colombia; and 25 percent in
Mexico City (48 percent when compulsory savings
for borrowers are included). A comparison of U.S. and
Mexican households reveals interesting differences
about why some do not have bank accounts:
Main reasons for not having a bank account
Reason
Do not need account/no savings
Want to keep records private
Not comfortable with banks/don’t trust
Fees and minimum balance too high
Inconvenience-location and hours
Lack of documentation
Although these figures are not strictly comparable
because multiple reasons were allowed in the U.S.
survey but not in the Mexican one, voluntary exclusion reasons—such as no need or an unwillingness
to use banks—appear to be much higher in the
United States compared with Mexico City. Survey
United States (%)
Mexico (%)
53
22
18
45
10
10
7
2
16
70
2
3
responses also suggest that involuntary exclusion
because of affordability is a more important deterrent
in Mexico, with 70 percent of those without accounts
citing high fees and minimum balances. These figures also indicate that supply factors in Mexico play
a more important role in limiting access.
Sources: Caskey, Ruiz Duran, and Solo (2006); Kumar (2005); World Bank (2004).
free pass-book savings accounts and inefficient documentation systems.
Nevertheless, Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Martinez Peria (2007b) and
Honohan (2006) show that nonlinear combinations of such aggregate
indicators of loan and deposit accounts are sufficiently highly correlated
with the actual proportion of households using financial services in countries for which this information is available from household surveys.
34
ACCESS TO FINANCE AND DEVELOPMENT: THEORY AND MEASUREMENT
Indeed, in the absence of micro data that are more accurate but costly
to collect, combining these indicators allows estimates to be made of the
share of the population with accounts at formal or semiformal financial
intermediaries for most countries (box 1.4). Figure 1.1 maps the main
cross-country variations in this synthetic “headline” indicator. More
than 80 percent of households in most of Western Europe and North
America have an account with a financial institution, while the share is
below 20 percent in many countries in Sub-Saharan Africa. The Russian
Federation and many other countries of the former Soviet Union show
usage ratios between 60 and 80 percent, a legacy of the state-run savings
bank from communist time. Latin America exhibits a high variation in
usage, ranging from less than 20 percent in Nicaragua to more than 60
percent in Chile. Usage across Asian countries varies much less and is
mostly in the 40 to 60 percent range.
These headline indicators show that access to fi nance or, more
precisely, use of financial services is positively, but not very closely, correlated with economic development and financial depth. Take first the
correlation with economic development. The proportion of households
with an account in a financial institution is higher in more developed
Figure 1.1
Creating synthetic headline
indicators from surveys and
aggregate data
Fraction of households with an account in a financial institution
Fraction of
Households
< 20
20–40
40–60
60–80
> 80
Sources: Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Martinez Peria (2007b); Christen, Jayadeva, and Rosenberg (2004); Peachey and Roe (2006); and
Honohan (2006). See also box 1.4.
35
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Box 1.4 Households’ use of financial services: estimating the headline indicator
households that use formal financial services can
be inferred only from household surveys. However,
only around 34 countries have household surveys
containing this information, and researchers have
therefore turned to proxy indicators to estimate the
share of the population using financial services (For
estimates by country, see appendix table A.1).
Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Martinez Peria
(2007b) compile loan and deposit account data
through surveys of bank regulators for a cross-section of countries and document the large variation in
these indicators across countries (see appendix table
A.2). In Austria there are three deposit accounts for
every inhabitant; in Madagascar, there are only 14
for every 1,000 inhabitants. In Greece there is almost
one loan account for every inhabitant; in Albania,
there are just four for every 1,000 inhabitants.
The ratio of deposit and loan accounts per capita
increases with income, although the average deposit
or loan account balance relative to income per capita
decreases with income, indicating that poor people
and smaller enterprises are better able to make use of
these services in more developed countries (figures A
and B). Still there is great variation among developing countries. For example in Bolivia, the average
loan amount is 28 times GDP per capita, while
it is only a third of GDP per capita in Poland. In
Madagascar, the average deposit account balance is
nine times GDP per capita, while it is only 4 percent
of GDP per capita in Iran.
These aggregate indicators are not only interesting measures in their own right, but when no
household surveys are available, they also can be used
to predict the proportion of households using bank
accounts. Regressing the share of households with
deposit accounts obtained from household surveys
on their aggregate indicators of deposit accounts
and branch penetration, Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt,
and Martinez Peria (2007b) show that the predicted
share of households with deposit accounts resulting
from this regression provides a reasonably accurate
estimate of the actual share of households with
deposit accounts obtained from household surveys
Figure A. Number of loans and deposits per
capita, by income quintile of countries
Figure B. Loan and deposit size/GDP per capita,
by income quintile of countries
Average loans or deposits as
a fraction of GDP per capita
Number of loans or deposits
per 1,000 people
A N E X AC T S TAT IS T IC ON T H E N U M BE R OF
2,000
1,500
1,000
500
0
1
2
3
4
5
Median number of deposits
Median number of loans
36
8
6
4
2
0
1
2
3
4
Median deposits/GDP
Median loans/GDP
5
ACCESS TO FINANCE AND DEVELOPMENT: THEORY AND MEASUREMENT
Box 1.4 (continued)
(figure C). Hence it is also possible to obtain from
aggregate indicators out-of-sample estimates of the
proportion of households using a bank account,
although the fit is likely to be poorer.
In parallel efforts, Christen, Jayadeva, and
Rosenberg (2004) collected information on individual institutions that are considered socially
oriented or alternative financial institutions, that is,
institutions that target low-income clients and are not
profit maximizers, such as microfinance institutions,
postal savings banks, credit unions, and state-owned
agricultural and development banks, while Peachey
and Roe (2006) collected information on the member
institutions of the World Savings Bank Association.
These different efforts give a first indication of
financial services provided by different providers.
Honohan (2006) combines data from all three sources
to estimate a headline indicator of access. Using data
on number of accounts in financial institutions as a
proportion of population and an average account size
as a proportion of GDP per capita (or estimated values
where they do not exist) as regressors, he estimates a
nonlinear regression relationship between these variables and the actual share of households with a financial account obtained from survey data. Where there
is no survey data, a “predicted” share of households
is obtained using the regressors and regression coefficients. Hence, the headline indicator pieces together
the values of households using financial accounts from
surveys when available, and this predicted value when
survey data are not available. This indicator can then
be used to map the share of the adult population with
use of financial accounts for most of the world, as
illustrated by the map in figure 1.1.
Actual vs. fitted values of share of households with deposit accounts
Figure C.
100
France
Denmark
Belgium
Spain
Actual household share
80
Austria
Greece
Italy
60
Brazil
40
Namibia
20
0
Colombia
Mexico
Ecuador
Guyana
Kenya
Pakistan Guatemala
Armenia
Nicaragua
0
20
Bulgaria
40
60
Predicted household share
80
100
37
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
The correlation between
financial access and
economic development is
weak, albeit positive
countries, approaching 100 percent for some of the richest (figure 1.2).
Use of financial services increases steeply as per capita GDP approaches
$10,000, and converges to near universal use at income levels above
$20,000. However, countries show significant differences at similar levels
of economic development. On the one hand, countries in Western Europe
have typically higher rates of usage than does the United Kingdom or
the United States, despite similar levels of GDP per capita. On the other
hand, a higher proportion of households holds accounts in financial
institutions in low-income countries in South Asia than in low-income
countries in Sub-Saharan Africa.
Similarly, indicators of financial use show a positive but imperfect
correlation with indicators of financial depth, such as credit to the private
sector divided by GDP (figure 1.3). This correlation shows that access
really is a distinct dimension: financial systems can become deep without delivering access to all. Take Colombia and Lithuania as examples.
Both countries have similar levels of private credit to GDP at around
20 percent, but 70 percent of households in Lithuania have accounts,
compared with 40 percent in Colombia. Similarly, over 85 percent of
Figure 1.2
Economic development and use of financial services
% of households using financial services
100
80
60
40
20
0
0
10,000
20,000
30,000
GDP per capita (2000 $)
40,000
50,000
Sources: Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Martinez Peria (2007b); Christen, Jayadeva, and Rosenberg
(2004); Peachey and Roe (2006); Honohan (2006); World Bank (2002, World Development
Indicators).
38
ACCESS TO FINANCE AND DEVELOPMENT: THEORY AND MEASUREMENT
Figure 1.3
Financial depth vs. use
United
States
200
180
Private credit/GDP
160
Switzerland
140
120
100
80
60
40
Estonia
Colombia
20
Lithuania
0
0
20
40
60
80
% of households using financial services
100
Sources: Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Martinez Peria (2007b); Christen, Jayadeva, and Rosenberg
(2004); Peachey and Roe (2006); Honohan (2006); and updated version of Beck, DemirgüçKunt, and Levine (2000).
households have accounts in Estonia and Switzerland, but while Estonia’s
financial depth is around 20 percent, Switzerland’s is over 160 percent.
The positive but imperfect correlations of financial services usage with
economic development and financial depth raise questions regarding
the drivers of cross-country differences in financial use and access. The
correlations also suggest that there might be room for policy reforms
to increase the level of financial inclusion—an issue that is addressed
throughout this report.
It is important to understand not only the actual use of financial
services, but also access across its different dimensions. Collecting indicators of and barriers to access and comparing them to usage and other
country characteristics will enable researchers and policy makers to better
understand the reasons for low access and to design policies to close the
gaps (box 1.5). It is also important to assess the quality of access as well as
quantity. For example, services may be available but may not be customized to different needs, or points of delivery may be too few, or delivery
may take a very long time. The following discusses several dimensions of
access and the indicators that have been collected to proxy for them.
Identifying barriers to access
39
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Box 1.5 Creating indicators of access barriers to deposit, payments,
and loan services
FINA NCI A L SERV ICES A R E PROV IDED IN THE
informal and the formal sector by banks, postal
savings banks, credit unions, finance companies,
microfi nance institutions, and a whole range of
other formal and quasi-formal nonbank institutions.
Given the dearth of data on access, however, the
initial data collection effort has focused on commercial banks, which are the dominant institutions
in the formal financial sector. (Furthermore, policy
implications regarding improving access are also
more relevant for the formal financial sector given
that the ability of informal finance to scale up and
meet the financing needs of a growing economy is
not clear; see box 3.5 in chapter 3). Conducting a
survey of up to five large banks in each of more than
80 countries, Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Martinez
Peria (2007a) developed indicators of access for
three types of banking services—deposits, loans,
and payments—across three dimensions—physical
access, affordability, and eligibility (for breakdowns
by country, see appendix tables A.4–A.7).
Physical access barriers can
be overcome by technology
40
Barriers such as availability of locations, minimum
account and loan balances, account fees, fees associated with payments, documentation requirements,
and processing times are found to vary significantly
both across banks and across countries. Indicators of
access barriers are also found to be negatively correlated with actual use of financial services, confirming
that these barriers can exclude individuals from using
bank services. The correlations of these indicators
with country characteristics also have important
policy implications for broadening access.
This is a first effort in documenting access barriers around the world. Next steps include broadening
the study’s coverage of both countries and banks
and documenting the barriers imposed by nonbank
financial intermediaries. Finally, urban-rural differences, as well as the role of customer characteristics,
such as differences in gender and age, are important
areas where further work will focus. The World Bank
Group plans to expand and update these indicators
within the context of its Getting Finance indicators.
Consider first geographic access. Branches have been the traditional
bank outlet. Hence geographic distance to the nearest branch, or the
density of branches relative to the population, can provide a first crude
indication of geographic access or lack of physical barriers to access
(Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Martinez Peria 2007b). As in the case of
usage, geographic access varies greatly across countries. Low-income
Ethiopia has fewer than one branch per 100,000 people, while Spain
has nearly one for every 1,000 people. Similarly, Spain has 79 branches
for every 1,000 square kilometers, while sparsely populated Botswana
has one branch for every 10,000 square kilometers. ATM penetration,
rather than branch penetration, shows an even wider dispersion in
geographic access (figure 1.4). These indicators are only crude proxies
for geographic access, however, since branches and ATMs are never
distributed equally across a country but are clustered in cities and some
large towns. A better measure would be the average distance from the
ACCESS TO FINANCE AND DEVELOPMENT: THEORY AND MEASUREMENT
Branch and ATM penetration by income quintile of countries
ATMs and bank branches
per 100,000 people
Figure 1.4
60
40
20
0
1
2
3
4
5
Median number of bank branches
Median number of ATMs
Source: Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Martinez Peria (2007b).
household to the branch or ATM, but these data are available for very
few countries. Nevertheless, the branch and ATM density figures are
highly correlated with aggregate loan and deposit accounts per population and the synthetic headline indicator introduced above, suggesting
that they do contain access-relevant information (for branch and ATM
penetration by country, see appendix table A.3).
A focus on branches and ATMs ignores other delivery channels that
have gained importance over the past decades. Among these are nonbranch outlets, such as correspondent banking agreements, where bank
services are sold by nonfinancial corporations on behalf of the banks,
and mobile branches, where trucks drive through remote areas providing
financial services at a scheduled frequency. Phone finance allows clients
to do financial transactions such as payments or even loan applications
over the phone. Electronic finance (e-finance) allows clients to access
services through the Internet. While correspondent bank agreements and
mobile branches have helped extend geographic outreach of financial
institutions in many countries, phone and e-finance have been introduced
primarily to reduce transaction costs for already existing customers and
to make service delivery more effective for financial institutions. Any
of these delivery channels, however, can reduce the costs of access and
thus potentially increase the use of financial services.
While no cross-country data are available on the importance of these
different alternative delivery channels, a recent bank-level survey, discussed in box 1.5, sheds some light on their use. Asking banks whether
they accept loan applications in nonbranch bank outlets, over the phone,
41
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Lack of documentation can
create eligibility barriers
or over the Internet, Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Martinez Peria (2007a)
find a large variation across countries. According to this survey, bank
customers in Australia, Chile, Denmark, Greece, South Africa, and Spain
can submit their loan applications in nonbranch outlets, over the phone,
or over the Internet. At the other extreme, loan applicants in Armenia,
Ethiopia, Nepal, Sierra Leone, Thailand, Uganda, and Zambia have to
travel to bank headquarters or a branch to submit their loan application.
While this measure is of course not the only or even the most important
determinant of access, it is notable that Chile, for example, has 418 loan
accounts per 1,000 people, while Thailand has only 248.
Limited geographic or physical access to a bank is only one type of barrier that potential customers face. By limiting eligibility, documentation
requirements can be another important barrier to access. For example,
banks in Albania, the Czech Republic, Mozambique, Spain, and Sweden
demand on average only one document to open a bank account, whereas
banks in Bangladesh, Cameroon, Chile, Nepal, Sierra Leone, Trinidad
and Tobago, Uganda, and Zambia require at least four documents,
including an identity card or passport, recommendation letter, wage slip,
and proof of domicile (figure 1.5). Given the high degree of informality
in many developing countries, only a small proportion of the population can produce these documents. Sixty percent of the population in
Cameroon works in the informal sector and is thus unable to produce
a wage slip. People in rural areas in Sub-Saharan Africa—61 percent
of the overall population—are often unable to provide a formal proof
of domicile. Limiting banking services to customers within the formal
Figure 1.5
Number of documents required to open a checking account
11%
9%
27%
24%
1
1–2
2–3
3–4
>4
29%
Source: Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Martinez Peria (2007a).
42
ACCESS TO FINANCE AND DEVELOPMENT: THEORY AND MEASUREMENT
economy or formal society thus automatically excludes a large share, if
not the majority, of people in many low-income countries. Improvements
on this dimension would not require great sophistication or cost.
Perhaps even more important than barriers of physical access and
documentation are barriers of affordability. Standard bank account charges
seem absurdly high when related to average national per capita GDP. To
open a checking (transactions) account in Cameroon, a person needs more
than $700, an amount higher than the per capita GDP of the country. On
average, in 10 percent of the countries sampled, an amount equal to at least
50 percent of per capita GDP is necessary to open a checking account.
Likewise, the cost to the customer of maintaining these accounts
varies widely as a percentage of average per capita GDP. In Uganda the
figure is 30 percent, whereas customers in Bangladesh pay no annual fees.
Perhaps not surprisingly, there are 229 deposit accounts for every 1,000
people in Bangladesh, but only 47 for every 1,000 people in Uganda.
Obviously, much of the cross-country variation here reflects the fact
that bank charges do not vary as much across countries as income does,
imposing a much greater burden on individuals in poor countries and
making access more difficult. High minimum balances to open and
maintain bank accounts and high annual fees can constitute high barriers for large parts of the population in the developing world. Checking
accounts also often come as expensive packages with costly overdraft
facilities that can easily be incurred accidentally by those with low and
volatile incomes, resulting in great risks.
Assuming, somewhat arbitrarily, that poor people cannot afford to
spend more than 2 percent of their annual income on financial services,
just the fees on checking accounts can exclude more than 50 percent of
the population in some African countries such as Kenya, Malawi, and
Uganda from having a bank account (figure 1.6).12
Payments services—for paying bills and sending domestic or international money transfers—are an important service for many low-income
households, but again these services are too costly in many countries. For
example, the cost of transferring $250 internationally—a typical amount
of remittance—is 5–10 percent of this amount for half of the sampled
countries and varies from 30 cents in Belgium to $50 in the Dominican
Republic (figure 1.7). The fees associated with ATM transactions (for a
relatively small transaction of $100) are also above 40 cents in Pakistan
and Nigeria, and average 10 cents across countries, while the use of
ATMs is free in 50 percent of the sample countries.
Affordability barriers: fees and
minimum balances
43
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Figure 1.6
Share of the population unable to afford checking account fees
Malawi
Uganda
Sierra Leone
Kenya
Swaziland
Nepal
Cameroon
Chile
Madagascar
Ghana
South Africa
0
20
40 60
Percent
80 100
Source: Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Martinez Peria (2007a).
Figure 1.7
Cost of transferring funds abroad as a percentage of $250
11%
11%
27%
<2%
2–5%
5–10%
>10%
51%
Source: Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Martinez Peria (2007a)
A lack of appropriate
products and services
44
Lack of appropriate products and services for low-income households
and microenterprises is another important barrier to access financial services. Availability and affordability of consumer and mortgage loans vary
quite a bit around the world. Banks in Nepal reported that the minimum
amount a consumer can borrow is 12 times per capita GDP, whereas in
richer countries it is possible to borrow amounts smaller than 10 percent
of per capita GDP. Mortgage loans, where they exist, can also be subject
to high fees and high minimums. Furthermore, it can take more than 10
days to process a credit card application in the Philippines, more than 20
ACCESS TO FINANCE AND DEVELOPMENT: THEORY AND MEASUREMENT
days to process a consumer loan application in Pakistan, and more than
two months to process a mortgage loan application in Chile.
Surveys of firms over the past 10 years have greatly expanded the
information available about financing patterns of and access constraints
on small firms and even microenterprises across countries. These sources
include the Regional Program on Enterprise Development (RPED)
studies for Sub-Saharan Africa in the 1990s; Business Environment and
Enterprise Performance Surveys (BEEPS) for the transition economies;
the World Business Environment Survey (WBES), conducted across 80
countries in 1999–2000; and the Investment Climate Surveys (ICS),
conducted since 2002 and available for almost 100 countries. These
surveys include micro-, small, and medium enterprises that are not captured in data sets based on published financial statements. In addition
to specific firm information, these surveys contain an array of questions
on the business environment in which the firm operates, information
that allows in-depth analysis of the relationships between firm investment, productivity, growth, and financial and institutional obstacles.
Doubts have been raised about how well these surveys actually represent
the population of firms for a specific country, a concern that could be
fully allayed only by using census data, which are unavailable for most
developing countries. Even census data that are available mostly cover
only formal sector firms, representing, in many developing countries, a
small fraction of the total number of firms, formal and informal.13
These surveys ask firm managers to what extent access to and cost of
external finance constitute obstacles to their operation and growth, with
higher numbers indicating higher obstacles. In general, small firms in both
the WBES and ICS report financing constraints to be among the most
important business constraints they face (figure 1.8). The geographic variation is large. Firms in East Asian and European countries rate financing as
a minor constraint on average, while in the Middle East and Sub-Saharan
Africa, financing constraints are much more severe. Variation is also wide
within regions, particularly in Latin America, the Middle East, and South
Asia. For example, the average Chilean firm reports that neither access
to finance nor its cost are important constraints to growth, whereas the
average Brazilian firm reports both as important growth constraints.
These surveys show that more than 40 percent of large firms, but just
over 20 percent of small firms, use external finance for new investment
(figure 1.9). While large firms finance about 30 percent of their new investment by external finance, small firms only finance 15 percent externally.
Looking at firms’ use of and
access to finance—
—managers’ perceptions of
financial exclusion vary widely
45
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Business Constraint
3
Financing and other constraints faced by small firms
WBES
ICS
2
Business Constraint
Figure 1.8
2.5
2
1.5
1.5
1
.5
0
ac
ro
ec Co T
on st ax
tic Eco
om of ra
om no
pe mi Acc ic fin tes
tit c p es ins an
ive o s ta ce
/i licy to bil
nf u fin ity
o
Ta rma nce anc
x a l r ta e
dm pra int
Cr
in cti y
im
c
e, C istra es
Sk
th or tio
ill
ef ru n
so
t, pt
C
fa
d
Lic ust
va E iso ion
en om
i
r
l
l
a
sin s a
b ec de
g nd L le w tric r
an t eg o ity
d rad al rk
op e s er
er re yst s
at gu em
A ing la
La cce pe tors
bo ss rm
r r to its
Te
eg la
le
ul n
co
a d
m Tra tio
m n ns
un sp
ica or
tio t
ns
An
M
Ta
xe
Fi
sa
na
n
n
Po d R In cin
lit e fla g
ica gu tio
l I lat n
ns io
Co tab ns
An
tic
S r ili
om E tre rupt ty
pe xch et C ion
tit an ri
Fu
Or ive ge me
nc
ga Pr Ra
tio
ni ac te
ni
ng In zed tice
of fras Cri s
th tru me
e c
Ju tu
di re
cia
ry
1
Source: WBES and ICS.
Note: WBES covers small firms in 80 countries; ICS covers those in 71 countries. The figures show the mean response of firms rating obstacles
on a scale from 1–4 in WBES (1 = no obstacle; 4 = major obstacle) and 0–4 in ICS. In WBES, a firm is defined to be small if it has 5–50
employees; in ICS, small firms are those with 1–20 employees.
Figure 1.9
Percentage of firms using external finance, by firm size
40
30
20
10
0
Small
Medium
Large
Source: ICS.
Note: ICS covers 71 developing countries. Small firms are those with 20 or fewer employees;
medium firms are those with 20–99 employees; and large firms are those with 100 or more
employees.
46
ACCESS TO FINANCE AND DEVELOPMENT: THEORY AND MEASUREMENT
Looking across regions, use of external finance by firms varies considerably. For example, some firms in East Asia finance almost 60 percent
of their new investments with external finance. Within regions, there
are big differences here too—while the average firm in the Philippines
finances less than 8 percent of its new investment externally, this figure is
77 percent for the average Thai firm. Out of all financing sources, bank
finance is the most common, for firms of all sizes (figure 1.10).
Firm-level surveys suggest that the share of small firms with bank
credit varies from less than 1 percent in Pakistan to almost 50 percent
in Thailand. Analyzing WBES data on fi nancing patterns, Beck,
Demirgüç-Kunt, and Maksimovic (2008) find that small firms and firms
in countries with poor institutions use less external finance, especially
bank finance. Small firms do not use disproportionately more leasing
or trade finance compared with larger firms, so these financing sources
do not compensate for lower access to bank financing by small firms.
Consistent with these findings, financial sector assessments conducted
by the World Bank also often point to the limited availability of leasing
and factoring, two important financing products for small and medium
enterprises.
If firms do not use bank finance, why don’t they? Of the ones that
have applied and have been rejected, what are the reasons? Box 1.6
provides some highlights from three of the largest countries for which
% of financing for new investments
Figure 1.10
Banks are the most common
source of finance
Sources of external finance for new investments
20
Small (<20)
Medium (20–99)
Large (>100)
15
10
5
0
Banks
Equity
Leasing
Trade
credit
Development Informal
financing
sources
Source: ICS, covering 71 countries.
Note: Values in parentheses represent number of employees.
47
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Box 1.6 Small firms’ access to finance vs. use: firm-level surveys
ALTHOUGH BANK FINANCE IS THE MOST COMMON
type of external finance, a large proportion of small
firms do not have a bank loan. For example, enterprise
surveys of small firms suggest that only 20 percent in
China, 30 percent in Russia, and 55 percent in India
have a bank loan.
Of those who do not have a loan, 85 percent in
China, 95 percent in Russia, and 96 percent in India
have not applied for one. So the rejection rates are
15, 5, and 4 percent, respectively.
Do these numbers reflect barriers to access or lack
of need? Some of the firm surveys include questions
that help shed light on this issue.
The survey results suggest that a large proportion
of small firms that do not use bank loans actually
do not need external finance or have been refused
a loan for basic business reasons. However, in poor
contractual and informational environments, the
need to rely on collateral, rather than an assessment
of the quality or feasibility of the project and credit
history of the firm, is an important barrier for many
firms. High interest rates may reflect lack of competition and infrastructure problems, in addition
to other macroeconomic issues. Bank corruption is
also a potential barrier deterring firms from applying
for bank loans.
Why did the firm not apply for a loan?a
Does not need a loan
Does not think it would be approved
Application procedures are too burdensome
Collateral requirements are too strict
Interest rates are too high
It is necessary to make informal payments
Other
China (%)
India (%)
Russia (%)
69
22
27
26
17
11
N/A
80
N/A
16
18
17
N/A
7
60
2
23
25
35
6
3
18
69
24
N/A
N/A
32
N/A
N/A
16
37
11
56
11
11
N/A
What was main reason the loan application was rejected?*
Perceived lack of profitability
Lack of acceptable collateral
Inadequate credit history of the firm
Incomplete application
Other
Source: ICS.
a. Multiple answers are allowed, and hence the percentages do not sum to 100.
surveys have offered answers to these questions. Surveys of small firms
suggest that while some firms are excluded from bank finance because
of high interest rates, collateral requirements, corruption in banking,
cumbersome paperwork, and the like, a large proportion simply have
no demand for or good projects to finance.
48
ACCESS TO FINANCE AND DEVELOPMENT: THEORY AND MEASUREMENT
Smaller firms tend to face greater access barriers than do larger firms.
For example, the responses to the surveys discussed in box 1.5 suggest
that in Georgia, Nepal, and Uganda, the minimum SME loan amount
is 20 times GDP per capita, casting doubt on whether banks in those
countries can meet the borrowing needs of smaller firms. Similarly, fees
on SME loans and the time it takes to process an SME loan application
may represent barriers. For example, while it takes more than a month
to process an application in Bangladesh, Pakistan, the Philippines, and
Uruguay, the wait is less than two days in Denmark (figure 1.11). These
issues are explored in much greater detail in chapter 2.
Two aggregate indicators can be created by summarizing different
barriers that impede firms’ and households’ access to financial services.
These indicators, one for access barriers for deposit services and the
other for loan services, suggest an overall impression of the country
characteristics that are associated with high barriers.14
Based on simple correlations, access barriers decline as per capita
GDP rises (figure 1.12). The quality of physical infrastructure is also
negatively associated with access barriers. Such relationships are not
necessarily causal ones; both barriers and the country characteristics
shown have common underlying structural causes. Nevertheless it is
striking that indicators of competition, openness, and market orientation in the overall financial sector and economic policy are also strongly
negatively correlated with access barriers at the bank level. Examples
include the Heritage Foundation index of banking freedoms15 and an
index of media freedom developed by Djankov and others (2003). (Each
of these has also been found to be correlated with financial depth and
economic growth.)
As far as contractual and informational infrastructures are concerned,
better credit registries are associated with lower access barriers, but there
is no evident correlation with creditor rights, suggesting that a deficient
information infrastructure may be a greater barrier to access than a deficient contractual framework. Countries that encourage market discipline
by empowering market participants (through enforcement of accurate and
timely information disclosure and by not distorting risk-taking incentives)
also tend to have lower barriers to accessing loan services. Government
ownership of banks is associated with lower barriers on the deposit side (as
is foreign ownership of banks) but with higher barriers on the loan side.
Not too much should be read into these simple partial correlations.
They do, however, foreshadow the characteristics that emerge again and
Smaller firms tend to face
greater financial exclusion
What determines access
barriers for households and
enterprises?
49
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Figure 1.11
Time to process an SME loan application
Pakistan
Philippines
Uruguay
Ghana
Mozambique
Thailand
Lebanon
Madagascar
Ethiopia
Albania
Egypt, Arab Rep.
Chile
Bulgaria
Dominican Republic
Nepal
Czech Republic
India
Sri Lanka
France
Mexico
Bolivia
Indonesia
Sierra Leone
Cameroon
Bosnia and Herzegovina
Lithuania
Zambia
Colombia
Jordan
Hungary
Armenia
Trinidad and Tobago
Australia
Belarus
Malta
Kenya
Georgia
Croatia
Turkey
Moldova
South Africa
Zimbabwe
Slovenia
Peru
Brazil
Belgium
Slovak Republic
Switzerland
Korea, Rep.
Greece
Spain
Israel
Denmark
0
50
10
20
30
Number of days
Source: Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Martinez Peria (2007a).
40
50
ACCESS TO FINANCE AND DEVELOPMENT: THEORY AND MEASUREMENT
Figure 1.12
Economic development and barriers to access
6
4
2
0
–2
0
10,000 20,000 30,000 40,000
GDP per capita (2000 $)
0
10,000 20,000 30,000 40,000
GDP per capita (2000 $)
6
4
2
0
–2
Source: Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Martinez Peria (2007a).
Note: The two panels show the first principal component of the indicators of barriers to (a)
loan and (b) deposit services, respectively, as discussed in box 1.5.
again in the discussions in later chapters that take a more in-depth look
at access and policies to broaden it.
Conclusions
Data from financial institutions and their regulators can contribute
greatly to a better understanding of the many barriers to access and
usage. Ultimately, however, researchers are interested not only in measuring access to financial services and the barriers that prevent access
but also in understanding the welfare impact of removing these barriers
and broadening access. For this, household and firm-level surveys are
necessary to distinguish between supply constraints and demand-side
constraints and to determine how the removal of these different barriers
would affect household welfare.
Access, and its welfare
implications, can best be
measured through surveys—
51
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
—and randomized field
experiments have potential in
evaluating impact of access
In evaluating the impact of broadening access, randomized field experiments hold promise. These experiments, which use surveys of microenterprises and households, introduce a random component to the assignment of
financial products, such as subsidized fees for opening accounts or random
variation in the terms of loan contracts. Continuing research in this area
will shed more light on how reduced barriers and improved access affect
growth and household welfare. These findings, in turn, will inform the
design of policy interventions to build more inclusive financial systems,
and the efforts to narrow the access indicators to track over time. We
discuss these issues in more detail in the remainder of the report.
Notes
1. Conceptually, when discussing the impact of finance on growth, it is
important to distinguish between two different effects (Mankiw, Romer, and
Weil 1992) the impact of finance on raising income levels of developing countries and on helping countries converge in income toward advanced economies;
and the impact on steady state growth rate. The second effect could result from
the role of financial development in promoting innovation and accelerating
the outward movement of the frontier. Empirically, there is very little evidence
to distinguish between these two effects. However, see Aghion, Howitt, and
Mayer-Foulkes (2005), discussed below.
2. A return to rising inequality in several advanced economies in the past
couple of decades shows further shortcomings of the Kuznet’s model.
3. Key contributors to this literature are Alesina and Rodrik (1994); Perotti
(1992, 1993, 1996); Persson and Tabellini (1994); for a contrary view, see Forbes
(2000). World Bank (2006a) and Birdsall (2007) also discuss the implications
of this literature and provide further references. An interesting case study is
that of the Republic of Korea and the Philippines, which looked quite similar
with regard to their development in the early 1960s, except in the degree of
income inequality. Over the following 30-year period, income per capita in the
Philippines (the more unequal country) barely doubled, whereas fast growth
in Korea resulted in a fivefold increase.
4. There are other possible channels through which higher inequality could
slow growth: for example, if inequality results in less-accountable governments
or if it undermines civic and social life (compare Birdsall 2007).
5. Also see the discussion in Demirgüç-Kunt and Levine (2007) and many
references therein.
6. See for example, Aghion and Bolton (1997); Aghion, Caroli, and GarciaPenalosa (1999).
52
ACCESS TO FINANCE AND DEVELOPMENT: THEORY AND MEASUREMENT
7. See Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Levine (2007); Honohan (2004).
8. Of course, some netting of interinstitutional accounts is still needed.
9. For a general review of issues around data collection in this area, see
Honohan (2005b).
10. The focus on individuals rather than households raises issues of comparability with other surveys: use of financial services can differ considerably
between different household members, and it would be a mistake to assume
that one household member’s use is representative of the access of the other
members. Surveys that randomly question individuals in a household are a
less-promising basis for welfare analysis, which requires good-quality data at
the household level.
11. In the context of the Year of Microcredit 2005, a coordinated effort was
also started by World Bank, UN Capital Development Fund (UNCDF) and
the U.K. Department for International Development to implement a consistent, stand-alone household survey instrument across developing countries
to measure access to and use of financial services. Currently, the Research
Department of the World Bank and UNCDF are planning to move forward
with this effort, which should allow consistent cross-country comparison of
finance-related questions and derivation of the share of households that use
different financial services from different providers.
12. Genesis (2005a) examines the costs of using bank accounts in seven
countries: Brazil, India, Kenya, Malaysia, Mexico, Nigeria, and South Africa.
According to Genesis (2005b), the 2 percent limit is based on unpublished
research by the South African Universal Services Agency in the context of a
mandated rolling-out of telecommunications service to lower-income families.
As both financial transaction accounts and telecom service can be considered
network products, similar assumptions on affordability for both services seem
reasonable.
13. Surveys are now being designed to reach informal firms also; see http://
www.enterprisesurveys.org.
14. The aggregate indicators are the principal component indicator of
the underlying indicators for deposit and loan services, respectively. Beck,
Demirgüç-Kunt, and Martinez Peria (2007a) use a data set of 209 banks in
62 countries and regress these aggregate indicators of barriers on bank-level
controls and one country-level variable at a time, such as the quality of physical
and information infrastructures, protection of creditor rights, bank and media
freedoms, and government ownership of banks.
15. This index takes into account government involvement and ownership,
existence of directed lending and controls, quality of regulation and supervision, and the ability of foreign institutions to operate freely.
53
CHAPTER TWO
Firms’ Access to Finance:
Entry, Growth, and Productivity
IT IS BY PROVIDING FINANCIAL SERVICES TO ANY AND ALL FIRMS WITH
good growth opportunities that the financial sector helps developing economies to grow and to converge on the high-income levels of
advanced economies. This is not just a matter of the overall volume of
lending: it matters crucially which firms get finance and on what terms,
that is, on whether creditworthy firms of all sizes, both incumbent ones
and those that seek entry, have broad access to finance at reasonable
costs. Improving access to external sources of funding is undoubtedly
the main challenge for firm finance in developing countries, and that
fact alone justifies the attention it receives. Naturally, it is also the area
of finance that has received the most econometric research attention.
Other dimensions of finance also matter, such as cash management and
payments services, risk management, and insurance, and they deserve
further research attention.
This chapter looks at how firms finance themselves in developing
countries and explores the barriers to improved contracting between
firms and the providers of funds. It discusses the channels through which
finance affects firm performance and the relative importance of financing
obstacles as a constraint to firm growth compared with other obstacles in
the business environment. Firms finance their operations and growth in
many different ways, reflecting both the preferences of management and
the options that are available to them. Availability of external financing
for firms depends on the wider institutional environment, and lack of
availability is one of the more important business obstacles firms have to
overcome. Better access to finance can help new firm entry and growth,
which in turn promotes growth at the aggregate level.
This chapter examines the
impact of financial barriers
on firms—
55
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
—and on economic structures
in general—
—identifies firms’ sources
of finance—
—and considers the role of
foreign banks—
56
The chapter documents how improvements in the functioning of the
formal financial sector can be expected to reduce financing constraints
more for small firms and others who have difficulty in self-financing or
in finding private or informal sources of funding. As a result, the effectiveness of finance has a significant impact on the ownership structure,
the dynamism, and the resilience of the economy at large. Finance does
not just raise aggregate firm performance uniformly but also transforms
the structure of the economy by affecting different types of firms in different ways. The removal of financial barriers appears to be especially
beneficial for small firms—which embody much of an economy’s latent
dynamism. Removal or reduction of financial barriers can thus broaden
the sectoral range of the economy and reduce its vulnerability to sectorspecific shocks. The institutional environment can also influence patterns of ownership—for example, well-functioning financial and legal
systems can lead more firms to incorporate and result in more diffuse
patterns of firm ownership.
Finally, the chapter examines the ability of firms, especially small
firms, to access finance from different sources, including banks and
other intermediaries, securities markets, and foreign investment. Special
attention within this section is given to the much discussed issue of
foreign-owned banks and their contribution to improving access. The
debate about whether banks or markets do a better job no longer excites
much interest: each has its place in ensuring that finance reaches a wide
clientele. Creating the infrastructures that let both markets and institutions reach their optimal level is likely to be the best policy. Relationship
lending, which relies on personal interaction between borrower and
lender and is based on an understanding of the borrower’s business and
not just on collateral or on mechanical credit scoring systems, is costly
for the lender and thus requires either high spreads or large volumes to
be viable. However, if the customer’s creditworthiness is hard to evaluate,
then there may be no alternative to relationship lending—although this
may lead to discrimination against certain groups. The modern trend
to transactional lending—whether based on assets or, for example, on
automated credit appraisal using improved data—is clearly the way of
the future. Credit registries are an important tool for the expansion of
transactions-based lending technologies.
Foreign banks bring with them capital, technology, know-how, and a
degree of independence from the local business elite. However, the role of
foreign banks in improving access has always been controversial, partly
FIRMS’ ACCESS TO FINANCE: ENTRY, GROWTH, AND PRODUCTIVITY
for political reasons. Foreign banks have a comparative advantage in
transactional lending, which raises concerns about their contribution to
credit access for countries where relationship lending is still needed. The
entry of foreign banks has directly benefited larger firms, and in many
countries this improved credit access has extended directly or indirectly
to smaller firms. Nevertheless there are also some indications that the
arrival of foreign banks has not always been good for small firm access
to credit, at least at first.
Nonbank finance remains much less important than bank finance
in most developing countries, but this can be expected to change. The
corporate bond market and organized securities markets are chiefly of
relevance to larger firms, although by broadening the range of firms that
have access to long-term funding, these markets do make a contribution to access. Foreign direct investment offers a partial substitute for
local finance and is an alternative that has proved important in some
countries. FDI appears to have eased financing constraints—although
again the benefits are most apparent for larger firms.
—and the growth of
nonbank finance
Access to Finance: Determinants and Implications
Firms finance their operations and growth in many different ways.
Their financing choices are influenced by the preferences of each firm’s
entrepreneurs and, more important, by the options that are available to
them. In what form, from whom, how successfully, and at what cost
firms are financed thus depends on a wide range of factors both internal
and external to the firm. The internal financial resources available to
the firm’s entrepreneurs and other insiders are of course important. Not
only are these the basis for most start-ups, but they can help leverage
external finance, that is, finance from outsiders. But given information
and agency problems (discussed in chapter 1, box 1.2), external financing
also depends on the firm entrepreneurs’ own ability to project a credible
financing proposal, their willingness to share control, the nature of their
business plan, and the uncertainties and risks involved in implementing
it. The credibility of the proposal depends not only on the substance of
the business plan, but on how the firm is governed and on the transparency of its operations and financial condition.
Circumstances external to the firm are also important. Availability of
external financing depends not only on the firm’s situation, but on the
57
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Barriers to finance are a
constraint to firm growth—
—indeed, the major constraint
to firm growth, according to
surveys of managers
58
wider policy and institutional environment supporting the enforceability
and liquidity of the contracts that are involved in financing firms. And it
depends on the existence and effectiveness of a variety of intermediaries
and ancillary financial firms that help bring providers and users of funds
together in the market, not least by helping overcome information and
agency problems (Tirole 2006).
As countries differ in their financial contracting environments, so
too the extent and pattern of firm financing tend to differ. Most important, these background conditions affect the extent to which firms as a
whole face financing constraints in different countries (and even within
countries across different states or provinces; see Laeven and Woodruff
2007). As noted in chapter 1, access to finance is among the aspects of
the business environment most frequently cited by surveyed enterprises
in the developing world as an important obstacle to their growth.1
Moreover, investigations of the impact of financing obstacles on
firm growth reveal that firms’ complaints are valid—their growth is
significantly constrained by lack of access. One nice piece of evidence
on this comes—somewhat ironically, given the policy recommendations of this report—from a study of a directed credit program in India.
Banerjee and Duflo (2004) studied detailed loan information on 253
small and medium-size borrowers from a bank in India both before and
after they became newly eligible for the program. Specifically, the size
definition of the program was changed in 1998, which enabled a new
group of medium-size firms to obtain loans at subsidized interest rates.
Naturally these firms began to borrow under this favored program, but
instead of simply substituting subsidized credit for more costly financing, they expanded their sales proportionally to the additional loan
resources, which suggests that these firms must have previously been
credit constrained.
Moreover, as shown in figure 2.1, the new beneficiaries experienced
significantly higher costs and profits, while there was no significant
effect for other firms.2 The reader should not, of course, jump to the
conclusion that directed credit is the best—or even a good—solution
to the existence of credit constraints. As discussed in chapter 4, not
all such programs even reach their intended target groups or result in
increased output for the eligible firms, let alone their impact on the rest
of the economy.
More extensive cross-country evidence comes from the responses of
some 10,000 firms in 80 countries to the World Business Environment
FIRMS’ ACCESS TO FINANCE: ENTRY, GROWTH, AND PRODUCTIVITY
Figure 2.1
Response of beneficiaries under a credit scheme
Increases resulting from credit scheme (log)
1.5
Beneficiaries
Others
1
0.5
0
–0.5
–1
Sales
Sales/loans ratio
Costs
Profits
Source: Based on Banerjee and Duflo (2004).
Note: This figure shows estimated logarithmic increase in sales, costs, and profits for beneficiaries and nonbeneficiaries of the credit scheme. Error bars indicate 95 percent confidence
intervals.
Survey of 1999–2000. It turns out that respondents who identify finance
as a constraint are more likely to experience slow output growth (Beck,
Demirgüç-Kunt, and Maksimovic 2005).3 Among the three constraints
these authors focus on—corruption, legal, and finance—financing
constraints lead to the greatest reduction in firm growth (figure 2.2).
While other business environment obstacles are also important, they are
Figure 2.2
Impact of self-reported obstacles on growth of firm sales
Corruption obstacle
Legal obstacle
Financing obstacle
–0.1
–0.08
–0.06
–0.04
–0.02
0
% change in firm sales
Source: Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Maksimovic (2005).
Note: The figure shows the estimated reduction in the rate of firm sales growth for a firm
reporting the given obstacle (calculated at the average value of the obstacle).
59
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
often related to finance, and even when these interactions are controlled
for as well as they can be in a cross-section, access to finance seems to
emerge consistently as one of the most important and robust underlying factors that constrain firm growth (Ayyagari, Demirgüç-Kunt, and
Maksimovic 2006a).
Both cross-country and case-study evidence thus points to the existence of financing constraints and shows how access to and use of credit
can alleviate these constraints.
The Channels of Impact: Micro and Macro Evidence
The next issue is to identify the channels through which easier access to
external finance increases firm growth and ultimately economic growth.
There are numerous potential channels, and recent research shows that
finance is associated with all of them.
• The availability of external finance is positively associated with
the number of start-ups—an important indicator of entrepreneurship—as well as with firm dynamism and innovation.
• Finance is also needed if existing firms are to be able to exploit
growth and investment opportunities and to achieve a larger
equilibrium size.
• Firms can safely acquire a more efficient productive asset portfolio where the infrastructures of finance are in place,4 and they
are also able to choose more efficient organizational forms such
as incorporation.
Better access to finance
can promote new firm
entry and growth
60
To get a flavor of the nature of the empirical evidence researchers use
in detecting these effects, look, for example, at the evidence on startups and their subsequent growth. Klapper, Laeven, and Rajan (2006)
extracted data on more than 3 million firms from the Amadeus database
(which assembles information mainly from national company registries
in advanced and transition economies in Europe). From inspection of
the reported age of each company, Klapper and her colleagues were able
to compute the entry rate for each of eleven two-digit sector groups and
thus assess the effect of entry and other regulations on the degree of
new firm entry and firm growth. Figure 2.3 shows striking differences,
even between two developed economies such as Italy and the United
Kingdom, in such dimensions as the rate of firm entry (higher in the
FIRMS’ ACCESS TO FINANCE: ENTRY, GROWTH, AND PRODUCTIVITY
Italy vs. U.K.: firm size at entry and over time
Figure 2.3
Value added ($ millions)
1.6
1.2
United Kingdom
0.8
0.4
Italy
0
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18
Age of firm (years)
Source: Klapper, Laeven, and Rajan (2006).
United Kingdom), initial firm size at start-up (higher in Italy), and more
rapid growth (higher in the United Kingdom).
The econometrics shows that such differences are in part related to
firm registration costs (more than six times as high in Italy as in the
United Kingdom), as well as to easier access to external finance in the
United Kingdom. The authors also dig deeper and test the conjecture
that, within countries, entry regulations would have the greatest effect
in industries that—in a lightly regulated economy like that of the United
States—would be most likely to have a high entry rate. Indeed, this
proves to be so, providing a more convincing case for the importance
of avoiding unnecessarily burdensome regulation. But not all types of
regulations hinder: it turns out that the kinds of regulation needed for
well-functioning finance (such as accounting standards and property
rights) have a positive effect on entry.5
The wealth of information generated on a cross-country basis by the
Investment Climate Surveys can be used to examine the role of finance in
influencing a range of enterprise characteristics. For example, Ayyagari,
Demirgüç-Kunt, and Maksimovic (2007a) exploited the responses
of some 17,000 firms in 47 countries to the questions on enterprise
innovation.6 Taking an average of each firm’s responses to the innovation-related questions, these authors assembled a range of country- and
firm-level variables likely to be associated with firm innovation, including
Use of external finance
is associated with more
innovation by firms
61
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Box 2.1 Are cross-country regression results credible?
ECONOMETRIC STUDIES PURPORTING TO EXPLAIN
cross-country differences in economic growth rates
and other country characteristics have proliferated
in recent years. Not all of these studies have been
equally convincing. Numerous published papers did
not take adequate account of the formidable problems of making valid inferences from such data. The
most widespread problems include heterogeneity of
effects across countries, measurement errors, omission of relevant explanatory variables, and endogeneity, all of which tend to bias the estimated effect
of the included variables. These problems are not
limited to cross-country regressions, but they seem
especially prominent in this area. Of these, endogeneity is the most intractable. It arises when the
common effect of an omitted factor or disturbance
on two variables is misinterpreted as a causal link
between them. Econometric theory offers a number
of possible solutions, but most of them call (in one
way or another) for what are known as instrumental
variables. These are not always available or credible,
given that their validity and effectiveness depends on
the instrument being correlated with the explanatory
variables, but (crucially) not otherwise correlated
with the dependent variable. The second criterion
for validity—the so-called exclusion restriction—is
difficult to verify.
The cross-country studies cited in this report
have all made plausible efforts to deal with these
problems, sometimes by painstaking collection of
data on ingeniously chosen instrumental variables;
indeed, the literature has relied heavily on just a
handful of such instruments (compare Pande and
Udry 2006). Since they cannot logically have satis-
fied the exclusion restrictions required to ensure their
validity for all of the applications, in at least some
applications they must have been invalid.
Sometimes, a more direct approach can be taken
using micro data and making use of sectoral or firmlevel differences. For example, instead of just looking
at country aggregates, it may be plausible to assume
that the effect being measured, if present at all, is
stronger in some sectors, or for some types of firms,
than others; in other words, some sectors or firms are
more susceptible to the causal factor being examined
(for example, financial sector development). Even
if the causal factor varies only across countries, its
impact can then be more precisely measured if data
is available at the firm or sector level.a
The additional information obtained by working
with cross-country firm- or sector-level data may
not be as great as at first appears, however; the different firms in any given country are likely affected
by common disturbances, which, if neglected, can
result in overestimating the precision of coefficient
estimates. Dropping the cross-country dimension
often allows researchers to take explicit account of
special circumstances and to exploit more detailed
data, such as data across different states or regions of
a country. The quality of the data is more likely to
be uniform for observations within a single country.
But omitting cross-country variation comes at the
cost of narrowing the range of variation in the phenomena being studied—indeed, some causal factors
of interest may not vary at all within a country. All in
all, it is through an accumulation of evidence using
different methodologies that the complete picture
can be progressively filled in.
a. Several of the papers discussed in this chapter employ this assumption, using the product of the causal variable and the supposed
sectoral or firm-level susceptibility as the explanatory variable. This approach was first applied in the financial access literature by
Demirgüç-Kunt and Maksimovic (1998) and by Rajan and Zingales (1998). Using firm-level data from 8,500 large companies in
30 countries, the former used a financial planning model to calculate how fast those firms could be expected to grow if they had no
access to external finance. The extent to which firms were able to grow faster than this internally financed growth rate represented
the firm’s growth susceptibility to good finance. In countries with greater financial depth, stock market development, and legal
enforcement, a higher proportion of firms were able to grow at rates that are possible only with access to external finance. Rajan
and Zingales worked with data on 36 sectors in 41 countries and assumed that each sector’s susceptibility to financial development
would be correlated across countries with the degree to which large firms in the same sector in the United States relied on external
financing. This statistical technique is also referred to as a form of “difference-in-differences” estimation.
FIRMS’ ACCESS TO FINANCE: ENTRY, GROWTH, AND PRODUCTIVITY
information about the structure of each firm’s financing. Despite the
inclusion of the other control variables and even after controlling for
reverse causality by using instrumental variable techniques, they found
that firms’ use of external finance was associated with more innovation.
This finding was even more strongly evident when access to finance was
from foreign banks.
The results of this firm-level, cross-country evidence are pretty
unambiguous. Access to and use of fi nance, and the institutional
underpinnings that are associated with better financial access, favorably
affect firm performance along a number of different channels. If entry,
growth, innovation, equilibrium size, and risk reduction are all helped
by access to and use of finance, it is almost inescapable that aggregate
economic performance will also be improved by having stronger financial systems.
Indeed, this result is likely a glimpse of the main underlying mechanism behind the now relatively long-established finding that a significant
fraction of the differences across countries in economic growth in the
latter half of the 20th century can be explained by variations in their
level of financial development (Levine 2005; World Bank 2001). The
finance and growth literature typically measures financial development
by the ratio of bank credit to the private sector to GDP, an inevitably
crude measure that captures only two aspects of financial development,
namely, the ability of banks to mobilize resources, and the degree to
which they channel these resources to the private sector. Indeed, researchers’ extensive use of this banking-depth variable to summarize financial
development occurs primarily because—unlike other measures—it is
available for many countries over a long period of time. Among the
dimensions not explicitly captured by this measure are the ability and
success of banks in making good credit appraisal and monitoring decisions and in maintaining operational efficiency; the measure also does
not capture the operation of nonbank aspects of the financial sector,
including the market for equities. Given the imperfections of this measure, it is all the more striking that such a strong statistical cross-country
correlation between financial development and growth was detected
and proved robust to the application of instrumental variables to take
account of endogeneity. Indeed, when the adjustment for endogeneity
is made, it increases the estimated impact of finance on growth, which
underscores that credit depth is only a proxy for the true degree of
financial development.7
Broader access to finance
also promotes growth at the
aggregate level
63
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Rapid growth of the banking
sector can be potentially
destabilizing
64
Overall banking depth (not just private credit) is also correlated
across countries with overall economic growth, but less robustly: it does
seem that restricting attention to private credit, as opposed to all bank
intermediation, is correct. Look, for example, at China (a country that
is excluded from most econometric studies, not least because of the difficulty of reliably measuring private credit, due to the ambiguity of firm
ownership in the process of China’s transition from the planned economy
system). Interprovincial differences in growth rates in China are highly
correlated with banking depth—but negatively (Boyreau-Debray 2003;
Boyreau-Debray and Wei 2005). Mobilizing huge amounts of funds to
pour into the declining parts of the Chinese state enterprise system, as
the main Chinese banks were doing during the last decades of the 20th
century, does not appear, on this evidence, an effective way of employing the financial system in the interests of economic growth. China
has continued to grow rapidly, as more workers shift from subsistence
agriculture and other low-productivity activities into the modern sector.
But the Chinese banking system, despite being one of the deepest in the
world, has not been a major contributor to this growth (figure 2.4).8
The finance and growth link is thus better seen as one that operates by
enabling privately owned firms to reach their potential.9 Likewise, the
aggregate evidence on long-term growth shows that finance has its influence through productivity gains rather than simply through an increase
in the volume of investment (Beck, Levine, and Loayza 2000; Love
2003); finance also plays an important role in reallocating investments
across sectors as demand shifts (Wurgler 2000).10
Banking systems can grow too quickly—with the boom inevitably
followed by a bust—and in some countries the huge size of the banking system reflects policy distortions that are inhibiting the emergence
and growth of complementary segments of finance. Perhaps therefore
it is not so surprising that the econometric link between banking depth
and aggregate economic growth has weakened in recent years, in particular when the data set includes the 1997–98 East Asia financial crisis
(Rousseau and Wachtel 2005).
There also seems to be a threshold effect at the other end of the scale:
below a certain level of financial development, small differences do not
seem to help growth.11 In these countries, financial development may
boost income but not the long-run growth rate. Indeed, Aghion, Howitt,
and Mayer-Foulkes (2005) suggest that it is lack of access to finance
that prevents entrepreneurs in poor countries with undeveloped financial
FIRMS’ ACCESS TO FINANCE: ENTRY, GROWTH, AND PRODUCTIVITY
Finance and growth across Chinese provinces
Figure 2.4
% GDP per capita growth
14
Zhejiang
Fujian
Jiangsu
Shandong
12
Hebei
Anhui
10
Henan
Guangdong
Guangxi
Hainan
Hubei
Jiangxi
Sichuan
Chongqing Liaoning
8
Xinjiang Shaanxi
Nei Mongolia Shanxi Gansu
Yunnan
Heilongjiang
6
40
Jilin
Guizhou
Ningxia
Qinghai
60
80
100
120
State-owned bank credit/provincial GDP (percent)
Source: Boyreau-Debray (2003).
Note: This figure plots credit by state-owned banks relative to provincial GDP against GDP
per capita growth.
systems from catching up. Without access to finance at a reasonable
cost, and lacking sufficient personal wealth, these entrepreneurs cannot
afford to make the needed investments in innovation. The theoretical
access-based model of Aghion, Howitt, and Mayer-Foulkes implies that
low-income countries with low financial development will continue to
fall behind the rest, whereas those reaching the financial development
threshold will converge and, up to a certain point, will do so faster the
higher the level of financial development. Comparing average long-term
economic growth rates for a cross-section of about 70 countries, they
find—consistent with their theory—that financial development helps
an economy converge faster but that there is no effect on steady-state
growth.
Summarizing, access to credit supports firm growth and ultimately
national growth through a variety of different channels. Providing
access to credit to the most efficient and innovative enterprises is behind
the well-documented causal relationship between financial depth and
national growth. But who benefits the most from financial deepening
65
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Box 2.2 External vs. internal and formal vs. informal finance
TWO ASSUMPTIONS, EXPLICIT OR IMPLICIT, IN
much of the literature on financial access are that
availability of external finance and greater formality
in finance are both improvements over internal and
informal finance.
The idea that availability of external finance represents an improvement comes from two rather different perspectives. First is the idea that a latent pool
of enterprise and innovation exists in an economy
that, absent external finance, can be made effective
only if the entrepreneurs happen to begin with sufficient wealth either themselves or through associates
(Rajan and Zingales 2003). Second (and in a sense
the opposite problem) is the question of agency: a
firm that generates too much free cash may find its
insiders making poor investments and relaxing cost
control efforts (Jensen 1988; Stulz 1990). If that
happens in enough firms in a rapidly growing and
profitable enterprise sector, excess free cash could
actually weaken the growth process compared with
a situation where the enterprise sector has to rely
more on external finance provided by an efficient
and competitive financial system. The contemporary
case of profitable state-owned companies in China
provides an interesting case for this last point, as
discussed by Kuijs (2005).
The argument that informal financial systems
may substitute for formal financial systems has been
canvassed for the case of China by Allen, Qian, and
Qian (2005, 2008). But their story takes as given
obstacles to formal financial development such as
restrictions on entry and pervasive state ownership of banks. Even if informal finance works in
such conditions, it is just a second-best solution.
Besides, informal sources of finance vary widely in
their effectiveness. Ayyagari, Demirgüç-Kunt, and
Maksimovic (2007b) provide evidence from China
that, on average for the firms in their sample, access
to formal finance was associated with faster firm
growth. More generally, informality and relationship lending survive where the institutions needed
to support modern technologies of credit appraisal
and monitoring are not present.
and better access? What impact does financial deepening and broadening
have on the economy’s structure? We turn to these questions next.
Transforming the Economy: Differences in Impact
Finance does not just raise aggregate firm performance uniformly; it
also transforms the structure of the economy by affecting different
types of firms in different ways. As already discussed, some categories
of firms—the small and the new, for example—have more difficulty
obtaining external finance than others. But as financial access conditions improve in an economy, those that were formerly shut out have an
66
FIRMS’ ACCESS TO FINANCE: ENTRY, GROWTH, AND PRODUCTIVITY
opportunity to expand. In this way, financial sector development has
consequences for the composition and performance of the enterprise
sector in terms both of size and of ownership.
The size distribution of firms can be affected by the availability of
external finance: financial development aids entry of small firms much
more than that of large ones, but small firms usually struggle more to get
finance when the environment is weak.12 The size and success of sectors in
which small firms have a natural advantage, or those in which firms generally rely more on external finance (including export-oriented firms),13
are also particularly dependent on financial sector development.
Not only do small firms report higher financing obstacles than do
large firms; they are also more severely affected when they encounter
these obstacles. Survey findings suggest that financing obstacles loom
much more for small firms than for large firms (figure 2.5). Specifically,
Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Maksimovic (2005) find that financing
constraints reduce firm growth by 6 percentage points, on average, for
large firms but by 10 percentage firms in the case of small firms. This
difference between small and large firms is as big or even bigger for
some of the specific financing obstacles reported in the World Business
Environment Survey, such as collateral requirements, bank paperwork,
Lowering financial barriers
is especially beneficial
for small firms—
Figure 2.5 The effect of financing constraints on growth:
small vs. large firms
Financing obstacle
Collateral requirements
Bank paperwork or bureaucracy
High interest rates
Need special connections with banks
Banks lack money to lend
Small firms
Large firms
Access to foreign banks
Access to financing for leasing equipment
Access to long-term loans
–12
–8
–4
0
4
% change in firm growth
Source: Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Maksimovic (2005).
Note: This graph shows the effect of different financing obstacles on firm growth for small
and large firms, measured at the average constraint for the two size groups.
67
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
—which in turn can widen
an economy’s sectoral
range and dynamism
Financial development
influences ownership patterns
68
interest rate payments, the need for special connections, and banks’ lack
of lending resources. In addition, the lack of access to specific forms
of financing such as export, leasing, and long-term finance is significantly more constraining for small firms (Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and
Maksimovic 2005).
To the extent that small firms embody much of an economy’s latent
dynamism, a weaker financial system, by constraining such firms, may
condemn a country to a much slower growth path. More generally, the
economy as a whole may lose out on the potential for wealth creation
in sectors that might give the economy a comparative advantage were
it not for the sector’s difficulty in accessing needed financial services.14
With a narrower range of healthy sectors, the economy’s resilience to
sector-specific shocks is also likely to be weakened.
While lack of financial access tends to hurt small firms the most in
countries with underlying weaknesses in their institutional environment,
empirical evidence also suggests that small firms benefit disproportionately—in terms of seeing their constraints relaxed—as financial systems
develop (Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Maksimovic 2005; Beck and others
2005). Hence it is those who were previously constrained—not those
who were already getting finance—that benefit most from financial
development. This effect also shows up when studying episodes of
financial liberalization. Laeven (2003) shows that small firms’ financing
constraints decrease following financial liberalization (including interest rate liberalization, elimination of credit controls, privatization, and
foreign bank entry), while large firms’ financing constraints actually
increase (perhaps reflecting the loss of preferential access to finance by
large and politically well-connected firms).
Perhaps even more important, ownership patterns depend on financial
sector development, both because firm entrepreneurs choose ownership
structures in large part to ensure adequate financing, and because finance
tends to go to firms with conducive ownership structures—the selection
effect. Specifically, background conditions in the financial sector influence the degree to which the producing firms choose to incorporate or
remain controlled by a closed group of family members.
For example, Demirgüç-Kunt, Love, and Maksimovic (2006) use
survey data from 52 developed and developing countries to investigate
the drivers of the decision to incorporate and the gains for the enterprise
from incorporation They find that firms are more likely to incorporate
FIRMS’ ACCESS TO FINANCE: ENTRY, GROWTH, AND PRODUCTIVITY
in countries with better-developed financial and legal systems, strong
creditor and shareholder rights, and effective bankruptcy processes.
While incorporated firms do not necessarily report lower financial
barriers to their operation and growth in an average country, financial
and institutional development does seem to lower obstacles more for
incorporated than unincorporated firms. Similarly, incorporated firms
grow faster than unincorporated firms only in countries with higher
levels of institutional development. These results suggest that the
costs and benefits of the legal form of enterprises is endogenous to a
country’s institutions: incorporated firms have a comparative advantage
in countries with institutions that support formal contracting, while
unincorporated firms are more adapted to operate in countries with
less-developed formal institutions where firms have to rely on informal
institutions and reputation.
The institutional environment can also affect other dimensions of
ownership. Family firms, even large ones, are still remarkably common,
as are interrelated multifirm business groups. Ownership concentration
is prevalent in countries with weak minority shareholder rights, suggesting that the inability to share control and profits with nonmanagement
shareholders might very well result in limiting the opportunities for
raising external equity (La Porta, Lopez-Silanes, and Shleifer 1999). The
prevalence of interrelated business groups in many developing countries
is similarly attributed to the lack of functioning financial markets, forcing firms to look for alternatives in the form of internal capital markets
of large business groups.
Financial development and easier access to external finance thus allows
incorporated, self-standing, and independent enterprises with widely
spread ownership to flourish. This has a range of broader implications
for the identity and concentration of ownership in the economy at large.
For one thing, a developed financial sector also tends to be associated
with a greater degree of competition in the nonfinancial enterprise sector.
More broadly, ownership structures in the enterprise sector can influence
political economy performance (Rajan and Zingales 2003).
Summarizing, financial development that improves access to external
finance by firms has a deep impact on the sectoral and industrial structure
of an economy. What institutions and markets matter most for broader
access to external finance, particularly for small firms? We address this
question in the next section.
Increased shareholder
rights can broaden the
ownership base
69
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
What Aspects of Financial Sector Development
Matter for Access?
We now examine different sources of access to finance. This section looks
first at the old “banks versus markets” debate, before turning to a more
detailed look at the role of banks (especially foreign banks), nonbank
debt markets, and equities. Other dimensions of finance, such as cash
management, payments, and insurance, are not specifically discussed,
reflecting the state of the literature. In particular, the role of domestic
and foreign financial intermediaries (including insurance firms) in helping to manage risk for firms in developing countries is an area deserving
much more formal econometric research to add to a sizable practitioner
literature.
The main message of these subsections can be briefly summarized.
On the debate between banks and markets, the suggestion that one type
of system is clearly better than the other no longer has much support
in the literature, whether for access or for financial sector development.
Instead, creating the infrastructures that let both markets and institutions reach their optimal level is likely to be the best policy.
Making credit from banks and other intermediaries that provide debt
finance more widely accessible calls for two complementary approaches.
On the one hand, the modern trend to transactional lending, whether
based on assets or on automated credit appraisal such as credit registries,
for example, is clearly the way of the future. On the other hand, neglect
of relationship lending can mean that large parts of the market are
underserved where infrastructures are weak and economic activity more
informal. The role of foreign banks in improving access has always been
controversial, partly for political reasons. We look in some detail at the
evidence here, and conclude on balance that opening to foreign banks
is likely over time to improve access for small and medium enterprises,
even if the foreign banks confine their own lending primarily to large
firms and governments.
The corporate bond market and organized securities markets are
chiefly of relevance to larger firms, though by broadening the range of
firms that have access to long-term funding, they do make a contribution
to access. Indeed, the spillover effects of greater access for large firms may
be significant for smaller firms because they often rely on trade credit,
another area that deserves more research. Opening up the equity market
to foreign investors improves access for the larger firms. The market for
70
FIRMS’ ACCESS TO FINANCE: ENTRY, GROWTH, AND PRODUCTIVITY
private equity (including through inward foreign direct investment) can
also reach medium-size firms, and its development depends on adequate
shareholder protections and accounting and other information.
Banks versus Markets
As mentioned, much of the early econometric evidence on cross-country differences used broad measures of financial development such as
banking depth. That was largely a matter of convenient availability of
data, and it certainly does not imply that nonbank finance is of lesser
concern. Even a deep banking sector can hinder access if it lacks competition, mainly serves incumbents at high cost (something that has often
been observed with state-owned banking systems), or operates without
regard to prudential standards. In contrast, a liquid securities market can
contribute an additional valuable dimension to financial access (albeit
mainly for larger firms).
Following a vigorous debate about the relative merits of bank-dominated systems and those oriented to the securities market, the proponents
of each seem to have fought themselves to a standstill. There are good
reasons for thinking that each has its sphere of comparative advantage
(Allen and Gale 2000). For instance, banks can be effective in financing ventures and firms active in sectors where there is little dispute over
the sector’s prospects and where firms can be relied upon to pay back
loans provided they maintain cost control and productive efficiency.
Even though just a few banks may control most of the loanable funds,
that need not result in exclusion of creditworthy borrowers. In contrast,
where an entrepreneur seeks external financing for a venture about whose
prospects there is considerable disagreement, the securities markets can
help: even if majority opinion is against the scheme, the entrepreneur
can find financing if a sufficiently well-financed minority of investors
likes the project.
But when it comes to aggregate economic growth, the research
evidence shows that it does not matter for long-term economic growth
whether a financial system is primarily bank-based or market-based.
What does matter is the level of overall financial development of banks
and markets (Demirgüç-Kunt and Levine 2001; Levine 2002).
The same is true at the sectoral level: there seems to be no tendency
for sectors especially reliant on external finance to grow more (or less)
quickly in a bank-dominated system than in a market-based system
Both banks and markets
have a role to play—
—although markets may
be better at providing
long-term finance
71
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
(Beck and Levine 2002). The growth in the number of firms in the sector, or in the average size of firms, is likewise insensitive to the relative
size of the banking and securities sectors.15 There is a hint, however, in
the results obtained by Demirgüç-Kunt and Maksimovic (2002), that
firms’ ability to obtain financing may be affected in different ways by
the two systems, especially at lower levels of financial development.16
While development of both banks and markets improves access to external finance, a relatively larger securities market may be associated with
relatively better access of firms to long-term financing, with banking
development more associated with availability of short-term financing.
Hence differences in the contracting environments and their impact
on relative development of banks versus markets may have important
implications for which firms and projects have access to finance, despite
our inability to observe an impact on growth using aggregate data. More
recent analysis helps shed light on some of the underlying aspects of
financial sector development in broadening access.17
Access to Debt Finance
Debt finance is the major
source of external funding
for firms of all sizes
72
Debt finance is typically the major source of external funding for firms
of all sizes, no matter how small.18 Diverse lending technologies are
employed for reaching different types of client in contrasting environments, especially where clients do not have conventional collateral or
where collection of collateral is not secure.19 Conventional practice
distinguishes between transactions lending, based primarily on “hard”
quantitative data (such as a credible set of borrower financial accounts)
or secured on assets, and relationship lending, based significantly on
“soft” qualitative information. In practice, however, the menu is much
broader (as Berger and Udell 2006 emphasize).
Because of the time and effort involved in understanding the borrower’s business and financial needs, relationship lending is costly for
the lender and therefore requires either high spreads or large volumes
to be viable. If the customer’s creditworthiness is hard to evaluate, then
there may be no alternative to relationship lending. In a broad sense,
relationship lending is at the core of the banking business, continuing to give banks a comparative advantage over markets and nonbank
financial institutions, even in developed countries (Boot and Schmeits
2005). Indeed, limited access to credit in some difficult environments
may be attributable to the reluctance of existing intermediaries to engage
FIRMS’ ACCESS TO FINANCE: ENTRY, GROWTH, AND PRODUCTIVITY
in relationship lending on a small scale (Honohan and Beck 2007).20
For lenders willing to put in the effort, however, relationship lending
can be profitable.
Credit networks that employ and sustain a form of social capital
through relationship lending have long been observed in different parts
of the world. These networks are often characterized by a common
ethnicity of the participants, although ethnic group membership does
not automatically convey membership in the credit network.21 Biggs
and Shah (2006) describe credit networks observed in the responses to
enterprise surveys in a sample of African countries in the 1990s.22 They
show that a common ethnicity greatly increases the likelihood of a trade
credit relationship between any two firms, and that a lengthy specific
relationship history between the two firms involved in the credit transaction is not required: network membership itself seems to be sufficient.
Credit between firms from different networks is much less likely and
does require a lengthy trading relationship. As a result, firms that are not
in the dominant networks are effectively shut out of credit, resulting in
ethnically biased financial access. For example, enterprises that form part
of a network of European-owned or Asian-owned firms enter at a larger
size, show higher productivity, and grow faster compared with other
African enterprises.23 To overcome the de facto exclusion of the latter
from these networks based on relationship lending, it would be desirable to build the infrastructures that allow a move towards the greater
formality and anonymity of modern transaction-based lending.
Corruption in India and the strong pro-state orientation of formal
finance in China mean that relationship lending has had to assume an
important role in supporting the recent fast growth of firms in those
countries, as documented by Allen, Qian, and Qian (2005, 2008) and
by Allen and others (2006). For the firms that responded to their survey in India, informal governance mechanisms, such as those based on
reputation, trust, and relationships, are more important than formal
mechanisms, such as courts, in resolving disputes, overcoming corruption, and supporting growth. Apparently, the pervasiveness of petty
corruption more than offsets the advantages of inheriting the common
law legal origin in India, inhibiting the growth of transactional lending.
Despite the need to rely on relationship lending, however, the Indian
economy has managed to grow at a rapid rate, showing the potential for
these mechanisms to substitute at least partially for more formal finance
in a very poor country. Likewise in China, the fast growth of private
Informal relationship lending
discriminates against firms
outside the credit networks—
—though informal finance has
filled some of the gaps left by
constrained formal systems
73
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Other forms of lending can
provide financial access
Credit registries and credit
scoring can expand access
for small firms—
74
firms in some coastal provinces seems to depend a lot on relationship
lending (facilitated by Confucian ethics), including from unlicensed
private financial intermediaries, as well as on relationships built on social
capital and shared interests with local government officials. (See box 2.2,
however, for a somewhat different perspective).
But even where standard types of transactional lending based on
transparent financial accounts are not available, other forms of transaction lending may be possible, as Berger and Udell (2006) stress. Provided
the relevant laws are in place, asset-based lending such as factoring,
fixed-asset lending, trade finance, and leasing are technologies that can
release sizable financing flows even for small and nontransparent firms
to finance the relevant assets. To be sure, factoring does require a degree
of creditworthiness but not necessarily of the “borrower,” but rather its
customers. That may often be the case, as where a major exporter buys
on credit from smaller suppliers. As a result, factoring is found to be more
prevalent where credit information is good, though it does not seem to
require a high degree of property rights protection (Klapper 2006).
It is striking that some of these techniques have not been more widely
used in developing countries. Leasing, for example, constitutes only a few
percentage points of fixed investment in the typical developing country,
while it reaches up to 20 percent in many developed countries. Similarly,
factoring in the United Kingdom reaches 7 percent of GDP, whereas
it constitutes less than 1 percent of GDP in most developing countries
(Klapper 2006). The limited role of leasing and other nonstandard debt
financing is also illustrated by the financing patterns reported in chapter 1 and potentially reflects the shortcomings of the underlying legal,
informational, and institutional environment, as is discussed later.
Credit registries are important tools for the expansion of transactions-based lending technologies (Miller 2003; Love and Mylenko
2003; Brown, Jappelli, and Pagano 2006; Powell and others 2004).
Credit registries ease for the lender the routine task of verifying aspects
of the repayment record (and sometimes the outstanding indebtedness)
of the applicant borrower and increase the cost of delinquency, thereby
reducing moral hazard. They also help build a database that the lender
can use to generate credit scores predicting repayment on the basis of
borrower characteristics. This technology is quite mature in the United
States, where, as shown by Berger, Frame, and Miller (2005), the use of
credit-scoring technology for small business loans has led to an expansion in the availability of loans to small and riskier firms, even by larger
FIRMS’ ACCESS TO FINANCE: ENTRY, GROWTH, AND PRODUCTIVITY
banks that would hitherto have shied away from this segment. The use
of credit scoring for small business lending, often based on data collected for credit registry purposes, is growing in developing countries
as well (De la Torre, Martinez Peria, and Schmukler 2007), although
it has yet to reach many countries: this is banking at what is currently
a very active frontier.
The more information is stored in the credit registry, the more useful
it is in selecting out the risky borrowers without reducing overall access to
credit. For instance, Powell and others (2004) use the actual data in the
public Argentine credit registry to show that availability of systemwide registry information can substantially improve the precision of credit decisions
even for a large bank (figure 2.6). In addition, they show that availability of
positive information (for example, history of borrowings, not just defaults)
could enable a lender to lower the default rate from 3.8 percent to 2.9 percent
while still lending to 60 percent of the sample borrowers.
It is not just the lenders who benefit from better credit information
sharing. Using firm-level survey data across 24 transition economies,
Brown, Jappelli, and Pagano (2006) find a positive association between
the quality of the credit registry and the ease of external financing (figure
2.7). This relationship was confirmed using panel data over time for a
limited set of countries.
Figure 2.6
—by helping to identify
risky loans
Credit information sharing and loan losses
Default rates on loan applications (percent)
5
Without credit registry
With credit registry
4
3
2
1
0
Large banks
Small banks
Source: Based on an experiment using actual data in the Argentine credit registry, as processed
by Powell and others (2004).
Note: Default rate is computed for banks that are targeting a 60 percent acceptance rate of
loan applications and optimizing use of a credit registry where available.
75
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Figure 2.7
Credit information sharing and firms’ financing constraints
Information sharing index
5
Lithuania
4
Estonia
Kazakhstan
Hungary
3
Slovenia
2
Macedonia
Slovak Republic
1
0
–1
0.5
Bulgaria
Romania
Poland
Moldova
1
Albania
Ukraine Armenia
Croatia
Azerbaijan
Bosnia Czech Republic Russia
Serbia Georgia
Belarus
Kyrgyzstan
1.5
Latvia
2
2.5
Ease of financing
Source: Brown, Jappelli, and Pagano (2006).
Note: This figure plots the quality of credit information sharing against the across 24 transition countries. Ease of financing ranges from 0 to 3, with higher values meaning lower obstacles
to financing.
While public credit registries may have some potential advantages,
such as the power to compel lenders to share positive information, the
experience has been that most public registries do not make as much
of the information at their disposal as they might. Increasingly public
credit registries are being complemented, where they exist, by private
credit bureaus.
With more countries considering the move to Basel II, which can
make use of private credit rating agencies, the credit information industry
is likely to see considerable expansion in the years ahead.24 And the more
sophisticated the statistical analyses of loan loss probabilities, the more
small borrowers can benefit through cheaper access to bank loans. For
instance, using data from the Chilean public credit registry, Adasme,
Majnoni, and Uribe (2006) have shown that the distribution of loan
losses from small loans (equivalent to less than $20,000) is much less
skewed than that for large loans (figure 2.8).25
The implication is that, while banks making small loans do have to
set aside larger provisions against the higher expected losses from small
loans—and therefore they need to charge higher rates of interest to cover
76
FIRMS’ ACCESS TO FINANCE: ENTRY, GROWTH, AND PRODUCTIVITY
Figure 2.8
Credit loss distribution for portfolios of large and small loans
Median % loss on loan
8
Large loans
6
4
Small loans
2
0
0.016
0.025
0.034
0.043
0.053
0.062
0.071
0.080
% likelihood of loss
Source: Adasme, Majnoni, and Uribe (2006).
Note: This figure shows the loan loss distribution for portfolios of large and small loans based on data from
Chile. Although the probability of loss on small loans is higher, the median percent loss on large loans is much
higher and there are far more very high losses for large loans.
these provisions—they need relatively less capital to cover the upper tail
of the distribution, that is, to support the risk that losses will exceed
their expected value (such losses are sometimes known as “unexpected”
loan losses). It is important that in making regulatory arrangements,
such as those of Basel II, policy makers do not neglect such findings and
unnecessarily penalize small borrowers.
The Role of Foreign Banks
The growing market share of foreign-owned banks in developing and
transition economies has resulted from a number of forces, including the
privatization of long-established state-owned banks (in response to their
disappointing financial and economic performance) and the aftermath
of banking crises, when distressed banks were put up for sale, often after
being financially restructured at the expense of the host country government. Foreign banks were often the successful acquirers, transforming
the ownership structure, especially in many parts of Latin America,
Eastern Europe, and Africa. Foreign banks have also entered de novo,
although typically remaining relatively small in that case. In addition
77
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
A growing market share
for foreign-owned banks
excites controversy
The evidence suggest foreign
banks benefit firms of all
sizes—
78
to the big international banks, foreign entry has come from regionally
specialized banks or those from a neighboring country often exploiting
close business or cultural ties (Claessens and van Horen 2007).
Foreign owners bring capital, technology, know-how, and a degree of
independence from the local business elite. It has been suggested that they
can help stabilize the banking system and the macroeconomy, and they
have tended to be more efficient and profitable than incumbent banks
in developing countries. But have they improved access? This is a highly
contested issue. Most foreign banks are relatively large (at least in their
global operations) and may struggle to understand aspects of the local
business culture. It is a commonplace observation in advanced countries
that large banks have a comparative advantage in transactions banking
based on “hard” information, whereas the comparative advantage for
relationship lending to small or otherwise opaque firms lies with small,
thus local, banks. The progressive extension of credit information will
tend to erode these differences over time, but there is no doubt that the
credit environment in developing countries tends to be considerably
more opaque than in advanced economies. Could it therefore be that in
countries relying heavily on foreign banks, the SME sector will experience more limited access to credit? Indeed, many foreign banks do not
concentrate on SME lending but stick mainly to the banking needs of
larger firms and high-net-worth individuals.26 Foreign banks are more
efficient and can undercut the local banks in their targeted segments.
But that does not imply that foreign entry will result in lower systemwide availability of credit for SMEs. Instead, the increased competition
for large customers can drive other banks to focus more on providing
profitable services to segments they had formerly neglected.27
Ultimately this is an empirical issue, and one on which much recent
evidence from developing countries has accumulated, although with
somewhat contrasting results across different regions. Overall, foreign
bank entry has been a welcome improvement for larger firms, and this
improved credit access has in many countries extended to smaller firms.
Nevertheless there are also some indications that the arrival of foreign
banks has not always been good for small firm access to credit, at least
at first.28
The evidence on the impact of foreign banks comes from a myriad
of different types of analysis on different types of data sources; some
international, some (more fine-grained) at the national or subnational
level.
FIRMS’ ACCESS TO FINANCE: ENTRY, GROWTH, AND PRODUCTIVITY
The benchmark research finding on the relation between financial
access and foreign bank presence comes from a reanalysis of the responses
to access questions in the WBES surveys. In a very direct approach that
yielded striking results, Clarke, Cull, and Martinez Peria (2006) found
that respondent firms were less likely to rate high interest rates and access
to long-term loans as major obstacles in countries with sizable foreign
bank shares. The effect was stronger for larger firms but was present
even for small firms (figure 2.9).29
Figure 2.9
Foreign bank participation and financing obstacles
20th percentile
50th percentile
80th percentile
Proportion of firms ranking
high interest rate as an obstacle
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
Proportion of firms ranking
access to long-term loans as an obstacle
0
Small
Medium
Large
20th percentile
50th percentile
80th percentile
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
Small
Medium
Large
Source: Clarke, Cull, and Martinez Peria (2006), table 3.
Note: This figure shows the likelihood that small, medium, and large enterprises rank high
interest rates and lack of access to long-term loans as the major obstacles in developing countries
at the 20th, 50th, and 80th percentile of foreign bank ownership, holding other firm and country
characteristics constant. Small firms are defined as those with 5–50 employees, medium firms as
those with 51–500 employees, and large firms as those with 500 or more employees.
79
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
—although the impact
of foreign banks has not
always been positive—
—especially for smaller firms
in the short term
80
One contrary suggestion that a larger share of foreign bank ownership
might not always be so good for financial development or access comes
from broad-brush aggregate cross-country data. Confining themselves
to low-income countries (the poorest 60 or so) Detragiache, Gupta, and
Tressel (2006) found that a higher share of foreign-owned banks is significantly and negatively correlated with private credit growth, even after
controlling for some other national variables. This somewhat surprising
result does not hold for middle- and upper-income countries and may
reflect the more cautious approach that foreign banks take in countries
with deficient legal and information infrastructures.
Greater richness of evidence is obtained if bank-by-bank data for
locally owned and foreign-owned banks is available for comparing
behavior between the two groups and also to see whether more entry by
foreign banks affects the behavior of local banks. Among recent studies taking this approach, Clarke and others (2005) collected data from
bank supervisory entities in Argentina, Chile, Colombia, and Peru for
the late 1990s, a period in which there was substantial foreign entry
in that region. The data included each bank’s origin (and, if foreign,
its mode of entry; distinguishing between de novo, by acquisition, or
long-established), and the share of its lending portfolio going to SMEs.
Controlling for the bank’s size, age, and financial performance, they
find that, as expected, foreign banks lend less to SMEs, but that the differential is largely associated with small banks. There is little difference
between the share of small business lending in the portfolio of medium
and large foreign-owned and domestic banks—with foreign banks even
nudging ahead in Chile and Colombia.30
This bank-level evidence is partly confirmed by firm-level evidence
from transition economies, which have also seen rapid foreign bank
entry over the past 15 years, with foreign-owned banks accounting
for over 90 percent of total credit in several countries. Examination
of firm-level data (from the Amadeus database) on medium and large
firms in that region shows that the process of foreign bank entry has
been associated with more rapid sales growth and total assets of large
firms, and an increase in both firm entry and exit rates. Using 60,000
firm-year observations covering the period 1993–2002,31 Giannetti and
Ongena (2005) also found that these effects were stronger for firms in
sectors that are more bank-susceptible (in the sense explained above).
However, they also found that foreign bank entry was negatively associated with the growth of the smaller firms in their sample. It remains
FIRMS’ ACCESS TO FINANCE: ENTRY, GROWTH, AND PRODUCTIVITY
to be seen to what extent this experience proves to be a transitional
one, both in the sense of being specific to the rapid structural changes
that were happening in Eastern Europe in those years—indications
are that firms established from 1989 through 2003 did not benefit
so much from foreign bank entry—and in the sense of evolving over
time as the foreign banks’ behavior matures. Foreign bank managers in
Eastern Europe themselves report an evolution in their strategy toward
a focus on smaller firms as the lending environment becomes both more
competitive and more transparent.
The arrival or expansion of foreign banks, however, can also be
disruptive, generating extensive changes in economic behavior. A study
in India by Gormley (2004) is highly instructive in this regard. He
shows that the state-owned development banks reduced the volume of
long-term lending in districts where foreign banks had entered. The
newcomers took up only some of the slack. While they gave some firms
more credit than these firms had before—in effect skimming the cream
of the best clients—they did not take on all of the clients dropped by
the state-owned development banks, regardless of profitability. Many of
those firms that thus lost access to long-term bank finance were able to
make up the deficiency, however, because they were part of an industrial
group. Gormley was unable to detect any adverse consequences of the
refocusing of bank lending in sales or bankruptcies.32
Gormley notes that in the years following entry the foreign banks
seem to have expanded the clientele to whom they would lend, but even
though the liberalization that triggered entry started in 1994, he suggests
that it is still too early to determine the scale of long-term effects. Also,
as observers of the Indian scene will be aware, foreign entry was not the
only source of heightened competition in India; bank privatization also
contributed to increased competition.
Mian’s (2006) study of 80,000 bank loans in Pakistan during the
period 1996–2002 throws light on the possible limitations of many
international banks when it comes to lending in developing countries.
He finds that foreign-owned banks were more conservative, shying away
from soft-information loans; this was true even for foreign banks that had
been present in Pakistan for a very long time. Specifically, they were less
likely to lend to small firms, domestically owned firms, firms that were
not part of a business group (that is, groups of firms with overlapping
directorships), or those without other banking relationships (figure 2.10).
Mian also compares foreign banks of different nationalities and finds
Foreign banks can generate
extensive changes in
economic behavior
Foreign banks tend to avoid
relationship lending
81
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Figure 2.10
Bank ownership and borrower characteristics in Pakistan
60
40
20
0
Borrower city size
Domestic bank
Foreign bank
80
0–50 50–75
% of borrowers
% of borrowers
Borrower size
75–95
95–99 99–100
100
80
60
40
20
0
Small
80
60
40
20
0
Domestic
firms
Foreign
firms
80
60
40
20
0
Single
% of borrowers
% of borrowers
80
60
40
0
2
3
Medium
Large
Loan typea
Number of creditors
20
0
Large
Borrower group size
% of borrowers
% of borrowers
Borrower type
Medium
4 or more
60
40
20
0
Fixed
loansa
Working
capital
Letter
of
credit
Guarantees
Other
nonfunding
loans
Source: Mian (2006).
a. All loan types are short-term loans except fi xed loans, which have a maturity of more than two years.
that non-Asian foreign banks were less likely than Asian banks to lend to
Pakistani firms. Second, despite being such conservative lenders, foreign
banks did not have lower default rates in Pakistan and were less likely
to renegotiate and recover after default. It is not as if all the good borrowers were being served by existing locally owned banks: Mian found
that during the period under review, private domestic banks established
new branches from which they served new, soft-information costumers
rather than existing customers from other banks.33
Foreign bank entry can also influence the degree of concentration in
a country’s banking system (although it is only one contributory factor;
82
FIRMS’ ACCESS TO FINANCE: ENTRY, GROWTH, AND PRODUCTIVITY
large state-owned banks, for example are another contributing factor).
On the one hand, the arrival of foreign banks injects a degree of competition for the rest; on the other hand, the foreign banks tend to be large
and their entry might displace others (Claessens, Demirgüç-Kunt, and
Huizinga 2001; Bonin, Hasan, and Wachtel 2004).34 The competitive
structure of banking can also affect the degree to which firms have access,
but the effect seems to be highly dependent on other characteristics of
the business environment for banking. Greater concentration is often
equated with greater monopoly power, but this may not be the case in
banking if the various market segments are vulnerable to new entrants
(Berger and others 2004). Other indicators of monopoly power are
also needed.35 Nevertheless, big banks almost inevitably enjoy a degree
of monopoly power; indeed the logic of modern banking increasingly
entails exploiting economies of scale and diversification.36
Some scholars have suggested that a degree of monopoly power for
banks might even be good for small borrowers’ access to credit. They
argue that the investment in relationship banking required to determine
whether a small borrower is creditworthy is likely to be rewarded by a
stream of profits only in an uncompetitive market.37 If so, only banks
with monopoly power will make the effort to build the relationship.
However the responses of firms to the WBES survey provide little evidence to support the idea that a more concentrated banking system is
good for access. Adverse effects of concentration can be found only in
low-income countries or in those countries with weak credit information
or tight restrictions on the scope of banking (Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt,
and Maksimovic 2004). Although small, low-income countries may
stand to benefit most from greater banking competition, it is precisely in
these that achieving a sufficient number of well-capitalized and qualified
bankers is problematic.
A balanced overall statement of the available empirical evidence is
that opening to foreign banks has the potential to convey net benefits
by introducing competition and increasing efficiency and independence
of local political processes and that these benefits are likely to be greater
as time goes on and the entrants learn more about local conditions. The
benefits are also likely to be greater in host countries that have the necessary information and contractual frameworks and incentive structures
in place that facilitate foreign banks doing what they are best at, namely,
automated transactions lending. While foreign entry generally generates
more competition for the incumbents, the end result may not always be
Foreign banks may
increase banking
concentration—and
competition
The benefits of foreign banks
are more apparent in the
longer term
83
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
an increase in competition if entry happens through acquisition, especially in a small market. Given the little empirical support for the theory
that increased monopoly power improves the access of small borrowers,
such entry may not necessarily lead to greater access. There are indications that foreign entry tends to make domestic financial institutions seek
out nontraditional businesses, including services for previously excluded
segments of the population, as these institutions find their traditional
businesses coming under competition. Hence, locally managed banks
with a business model focused on addressing opportunities in the local
business community have the potential to survive foreign entry, adding
value by broadening access, especially to the SME sector.
Access to Nonbank Debt Finance
A poor business environment
can inhibit long-term bank
financing
84
Where long-term finance is available, the evidence is that it makes a
positive contribution to firm growth (Demirgüç-Kunt and Maksimovic
1999). But there are numerous barriers to availability of long-term
finance. It is not just that banks need to maintain liquidity, an aspect
that is often stressed. In reality, well-run banks with a stable deposit
base can and do lend at maturities well beyond the nominal maturity
of their deposits. Indeed this maturity transformation is one of the key
contributions of banking to the wider economic system. Other factors
at both the national and firm-level also impose barriers to long-term
finance. At the aggregate level, macroeconomic risks loom large in the
decision to make a long-term loan, as do weaknesses in the credit information environment and contract enforcement.38 In dealing with riskier
and more opaque borrowers (for example, small or new firms, or those
with an adverse credit history), banks prefer to use shorter-term loans,
which can be renewed or renegotiated, so that they can maintain control
over the lending relationship and retain the possibility to influence firm
management during the course of the relationship.39
For long-term lending, the role for bond financing is potentially larger,
can provide competition for banks, and can serve as a spare tire to be
employed in the event of a banking crisis. The potential here should
not be exaggerated, however, as Gormley, Johnson, and Rhee (2006),
for example, point out in their study of the Korean financial crisis of
1997–98. When that crisis triggered a freeze in bank lending, a private
bond market easily sprang to life, capturing households’ savings and
channeling them to corporations. But it was the largest corporations,
FIRMS’ ACCESS TO FINANCE: ENTRY, GROWTH, AND PRODUCTIVITY
the chaebols, that received the financing, and the public was willing to
invest in bonds because it perceived them as a safe investment, assuming
that the chaebols would be regarded by the authorities as too big to fail.
This public perception was proved correct by the bailout of bond investors after the 1999 collapse of the large chaebol Daewoo. Smaller firms,
despite their often better corporate governance structures, were unable
to access the bond market even after banks stopped lending.
Private bonds can provide a competitive alternative to banks, but
banks can also use bonds to exploit their credit appraisal capacity while
economizing on capital and liquidity by packaging residential mortgages
and other small or medium-size loans into larger units that then can
be sold to pension funds and other institutional investors. Mortgagebacked bonds issued by banks perform a similar function and can
work in less sophisticated financial systems. The legal, accounting, and
other requirements to make this kind of financial engineering effective,
Bond financing can provide
competition for banks
Box 2.3 When access can be too tempting: risks and use of foreign currency
borrowing by firms
ONE MAJOR RISK THAT CAN ARISE FROM FINANCIAL
globalization is the assumption by financial, and
especially nonfinancial, firms of much greater foreign
exchange risk than is prudent. The temptation to do
so often arises when macroeconomic and exchange
rate policy results in high and volatile nominal interest rates for borrowings in local currency, whereas
creditworthy borrowers may access foreign currency
borrowing either from locally based or foreign banks
at much lower nominal interest rates, but accepting
the exchange risk.a The combination of availability
of foreign capital and high domestic interest rates
has often been associated with a policy of fi xing the
exchange rate at what seems an undervalued rate:
promoting an export and profit boom as well as
capital inflows caused by expectations of a nominal
currency appreciation. The combination greatly
heightens the risks, and a reversal of investor sentiment can mean very large currency movements and
an economic crisis, as has been seen in such disparate
cases as Chile in 1982–83 and Indonesia in 1997–98.
It is not a simple task to calculate even approximately
what a prudent foreign exchange exposure would
be for a firm whose nonfinancial business has an
international component. (South African Airlines
recently incurred heavy losses as a result of treasury
policies that could be characterized as overhedging
of foreign exchange.) The scale of onshore dollarization of bank deposits and international fixed-interest
lending has surged several times in the past couple
of decades (De Nicoló, Honohan, and Ize 2005;
Goldstein and Turner 2004), making currency
exchange risk a problem that is likely to recur.
a. See Allayannis, Brown, and Klapper (2003) for a study of firms’ strategies to hedge foreign exchange rate exposure in East
Asia before and after the crisis.
85
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
including the role of independent credit-rating firms to help investors
price these bonds, are considerable and beyond the reach of smaller or
less advanced markets, but the details need not concern us here. Where
bond financing is possible, it can improve the price and availability of
longer-term credit to smaller borrowers.
Access to External Equity
Stock market development
requires a sound regulatory
environment
86
Even start-up firms need equity to finance working capital; entrepreneurs
everywhere have recourse to relatives and friends for initial equity to
supplement their own resources. The quantitative importance of internal
financing from retained earnings to help support the growth process has
already been discussed. As firms grow, so too does the importance of
having access to sources of external equity. Bank loans cannot perform
this function. In most countries there are individuals and firms who, in
one way or another, arrange private equity for some of the most promising growth firms, but a wider investor clientele can be tapped through
a listing on an organized stock exchange.
The development of shareholder capitalism depends on strong investor rights and on adequately enforced public disclosure of the financial
condition of public companies (Morck and Steier 2005). Reliance on
disclosure and private enforcement mechanisms seems more effective
than public enforcement policies and restrictions imposed by authorities
(La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, and Shleifer 2006). In many countries,
information and investor protection are not adequate to allow the stock
market to fulfill its full potential in establishing the full price of each
equity stock. As Morck, Yeung, and Yu (2000) and Jin and Myers
(2006) show, stock prices of different firms move closely together in
the stock exchanges of many countries and especially in countries with
weak shareholder rights and lack of firm transparency (figure 2.11).40
This contrasts to the situation in advanced economies, where the correlation of individual stock prices with the average of the market tends
to be rather low. The strong co-movement of stock prices may mean that
little firm-specific information comes into the public arena. As a result,
individual firm equity is not, on average, fully priced, and the discount
is likely to be greater, the greater the firm’s growth prospects. It is not
surprising, then, that most of the largest firms in the corporate sector of
such countries tend to be controlled by a small elite group of families,
as outsiders doubt they will benefit from holding shares—with reason,
FIRMS’ ACCESS TO FINANCE: ENTRY, GROWTH, AND PRODUCTIVITY
Figure 2.11
Stock price synchronicity with disclosure and governance
Value-weighted R2
0.4
0.3
0.3
0.3
0.2
3
4
5
6
Disclosure index
7
10
15
20
Good governance index
25
Value-weighted R2
0.4
0.3
0.3
0.3
0.2
Source: Jin and Myers (2006).
Note: This figure compares the degree to which stock prices tend to move together in each of
40 stock exchanges with indicators of disclosure and governance.
as Desai and Moel (2007) document in several spectacular cases. The
consequences can be lower investment than optimal.41
Investor rights and transparency might not be enough to foster liquid
equity markets. Rather, a critical mass of issues, issuers, and investors
seems to be necessary (De la Torre and Schmukler 2007). The recent
merger wave among the stock exchanges of developed countries and
the deepening of a rather limited set of emerging stock exchanges raise
questions about the extent to which smaller emerging countries will have
the critical mass to support national stock exchanges or will need to rely
on regional or foreign exchanges for firms’ funding needs.
These findings confirm the importance of shareholder protection and
information for ensuring that the stock market makes external capital
available to firms with growth prospects. However, making reforms is
not an easy matter. Controlling families often do not seem interested
in increasing the transparency of the market or in boosting the rights
of minorities (even though such actions could make cheaper capital
available). Indeed, they seem to be effective in blocking, through their
Small economies may benefit
from regional exchanges
87
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
External listing by larger firms
might not be good for equity
access of smaller firms
FDI may ease financing
constraints—
—and improve firm
management and use of
technology
88
rent-seeking activities, a strengthening of the financial system for fear
that a stronger system would allow the emergence of challengers to their
incumbency.42 Venture capital is also more effective when underlying
legal protections are present (Cumming, Schmidt, and Walz 2006).
Opening up equity markets to the outside world has made a big contribution to improving access and cost of equity finance for larger local
firms.43 A listing (or ADR44) in a foreign market by such firms improves
their access to equity by increasing the share price and making them
more attractive for institutional investors, thus generating an incentive
for firms to expand (Aggarwal, Klapper, and Wysocki 2005; Levine
and Schmukler 2007a). Such listings can import corporate governance
(Coffee 2002), although this finding is not reflected in any sustained
increase in the market value of the firm (Levine and Schmukler 2007a).
These gains, however, might be partly offset by loss of liquidity in local
markets, potentially limiting access to outside equity for smaller firms
(Levine and Schmukler 2007b). The net overall impact on the access
of small firms is not clear; after all, improved access by large firms may
spill over to small ones through trade credit. Furthermore, as larger
firms have greater access to, and substitute, these alternative sources of
funding for bank finance, banks are likely to become more interested
in serving smaller clients.
Foreign direct investment offers a partial substitute for local finance,
a fact that has proved important in some countries, where it appears to
have eased financing constraints, at least for large, publicly listed firms.45
To be sure, foreign investors likely choose some of the best-performing
local firms in which to invest, so this selection bias needs to be taken
into account (Weiss and Nikitin 2004). However, FDI transactions
in which firms in advanced economies have acquired listed firms in
developing countries have been associated with sizable stock market
gains for both acquirer and target. That finding implies consequential
gains in profitability over time, according to a study by Chari, Ouimet,
and Tesar (2005) of 1,629 acquisitions in Argentina, Brazil, Chile,
Indonesia, Republic of Korea, Malaysia, Mexico, the Philippines, and
Thailand (figure 2.12).
The mode of entry can be influential in determining how productive
the investment will be. A particular issue is whether insisting on joint
ventures rather than allowing foreign control of the enterprise is better
for the host country overall. Moran (2005) has observed that target
companies that have been integrated into the foreign acquirer’s worldwide
FIRMS’ ACCESS TO FINANCE: ENTRY, GROWTH, AND PRODUCTIVITY
Figure 2.12 Returns to shareholders in acquiring and target firms around the
date of FDI announcement
Buyer
Target
% return around announcement
12
10
8
6
4
2
0
Full sample
East Asia
Latin America
Majority
control
acquired
Source: Chari, Ouimet, and Teas (2005).
operations tend to be larger, better managed, and more technologically
advanced than those whose purpose is to serve protected domestic markets in the host country. Many of the most effective FDI transactions,
therefore, go well beyond providing financial access to the target firms,
which instead are swallowed up.
With the emergence of large private equity firms in the advanced
economies temporarily taking majority stakes in firms in the developing world (such as banks in Korea, following the crisis of 1997–98),
the dividing line between FDI and other equity investment has become
somewhat blurred. At the same time, locally controlled private equity
funds, often affiliated with banks or other financial service providers,
have also been created in numerous countries. One way or another,
venture capital and private equity (including venture capital for near
start-ups) have been an increasingly important source of finance for
certain categories of firms in developing countries, although such
investment has been subject to waves of enthusiasm (the mid-1990s,
for example) followed by valley periods. These transactions are not very
fully documented in available data, so they have not been subjected to
the same kinds of econometric analysis discussed in this chapter.46 A
half-dozen large emerging economies currently receive most of the flow
of FDI—Brazil, China (including Taiwan), India, Korea, Russia, and
South Africa. This geographic concentration is likely to persist, because
89
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
of the size of these economies, the availability (in some of them) of large,
capital-hungry, natural resource–based projects for foreigners to invest
in, and the perceived quality of the overall investment environment,
including the availability of local currency debt financing to complete
the package and a market on which the equity stake can be floated in due
course (Rubenstein 2006). Nevertheless, private equity firms have been
looking at most countries with increasing interest since 2003, and, while
there may be interruptions, private equity may become an increasingly
important source of financing for larger firms with growth potential.
Conclusions
Barriers to finance are a major
obstacle, especially for new
and small firms
Foreign banks improve access
to finance, especially in the
longer term
Nonbank finance has a
growing role to play
90
Availability of external financing for firms depends on the wider institutional environment; lack of availability does constrain firm growth,
and it is one of the more important business obstacles firms have to
overcome. Access to finance contributes to firm entry, growth, and
innovation, among other things. Small and new firms are affected the
most by financing constraints. Yet they also benefit the most as financial
systems develop and financing constraints consequently ease. Empirical
evidence suggests that it is through improving access for enterprises
that financial sector development makes an important contribution to
economic growth.
While relationship lending remains important in many parts of the
world, the modern trend is increasingly toward transactional lending.
In this regard, good credit registries can be a powerful force for expanding the reach of lenders. Not least because international banks have a
comparative advantage in transactional lending, their arrival or expansion in a country can cause natural apprehension about their possible
effect on broad access to credit. However, the balance of a large body
of evidence is that even where foreign entrants are highly selective in
their target credit market, access to credit from the system as a whole
usually improves. And it is increasingly likely to do so as time goes on.
In contrast, the performance of state-owned banks in this dimension
has tended to be poor.
Nonbank finance remains much less important in most developing
countries, but that too can be expected to change. Bond finance is an
increasingly important alternative to bank finance, mainly for large firms.
Access to external equity requires strong investor rights; where these are
FIRMS’ ACCESS TO FINANCE: ENTRY, GROWTH, AND PRODUCTIVITY
present, opening to capital inflows can greatly improve access and lower
the cost of capital. That is true both for portfolio equity investments
and for foreign direct investment and private equity, which are likely
to become increasingly important. While bond and equity markets are
most directly relevant for improving access to finance for larger firms,
these markets are also likely to have an indirect effect on access for small
firms, as trade credit represents an important source of external finance
for many small firms.
Notes
1. There is a large empirical literature on financing constraints that arise
because of information asymmetries and on the resulting agency problems
between lenders and borrowers (see surveys by Schiantarelli 1995; Blundell,
Bond, and Meghir 1996; Hubbard 1998; and Bond and Van Reenen 1999).
While most of this literature has tried to infer financing constraints indirectly
from investment–cash flow correlations or deviations from optimal investment
patterns, studies highlighted in this chapter use more direct measures. Also
see Beck and others (2006), who use the WBES survey data discussed in the
text and show that self-reported financing constraints are robustly correlated
with firm size, age, and ownership (domestic or foreign).
2. The increase in sales was proportional to the increase in bank credit,
another piece of evidence to support the authors’ hypothesis that credit constraints were at work. While the increase in profits might be partly explained
by the subsidized interest on directed lending, the magnitude seems too large
to be the sole factor.
3. Surveyed businesses in the WBES were asked (among other things) to
rate financing, legal, and corruption obstacles, as well as others, on a scale
from 1 (no obstacle) to 4 (major obstacle), to reflect the extent to which these
obstacles affected the growth of their business. Regressing firm sales growth
on financing, corruption, and legal obstacles, while controlling for firm and
country characteristics, shows that all three obstacles significantly constrain
firm growth. If all three obstacles are entered in the regression, financing
and legal obstacles still remain negative and significant, while the corruption
obstacle loses its significance.
4. This is evidenced for example by the increased willingness of firms to
diversify by acquiring intangible assets in countries where property rights are
secure (Claessens and Laeven 2003).
5. Using household survey data from Bosnia and Herzegovina, DemirgüçKunt, Klapper, and Panos (2007) study determinants of self-employment for
91
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
individuals. They find that personal wealth predicts the choice of becoming
an entrepreneur, as does receiving remittances (although negatively). However,
access to bank finance predicts survival as an entrepreneur beyond the first
year.
6. Specifically, respondents were asked whether they had (i) developed a
major new product line; (ii) upgraded an existing product line; (iii) introduced
new technology that has substantially changed the way that the main product
is produced; (iv) discontinued at least one product (not production) line; (v)
opened a new plant; (vi) closed at least one existing plant or outlet; (vii) agreed
to a new joint venture with a foreign partner; (viii) obtained a new licensing
agreement; (ix) outsourced a major production activity that was previously
conducted in-house; or (x) brought in-house a major production activity that
was previously outsourced.
7. Measurement error in a causal variable tends to bias the OLS (ordinary
least squares) estimates downward, whereas reverse causality or an unobserved
common causal factor would tend to bias the OLS estimates upward. This
downward bias has been noted in econometric studies of other supposed causes
of growth as well (Pande and Udry 2006). Note however that this interpretation depends on the use of valid instruments in the attempt to adjust for
endogeneity. Using an invalid instrument (for example, one that should really
be included in the equation as an explanatory variable) will bias the adjusted
(instrumental variables) estimate.
8. The supposed inefficiency of Chinese bank lending should not be overstated, though, especially for recent years. Using firm-level survey data, Cull and
Xu (2000, 2003) find that bank finance was associated with higher subsequent
firm productivity in the 1980s, while government transfers were not. This
relationship, however, weakened in the 1990s. Drawing on a sample of mostly
small and medium Chinese firms, which account for the most dynamic part
of the Chinese economy, Ayyagari, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Maksimovic (2007b)
show that those receiving bank credit around 2002 did tend to grow more
quickly than the average firm, whereas those receiving funds from informal
sources did not. This suggests that even if the bulk of Chinese bank credit has
not been directed to financing the most productive firms, credit decisions of
Chinese banks regarding smaller enterprises have been associated with faster
firm growth, and the formal financial system is still better than the informal
one in picking the best performers.
9. That Vietnam has also seen perverse flows of credit is argued by Malesky
and Taussig (2005), who find that despite rapid increases in both bank deposits
and credit in recent years, suggestive of financial development, this additional
credit does not seem to have found its way into the provinces where it is most
needed, that is, provinces with the highest share of private entrepreneurs.
Private entrepreneurs seem to be crowded out systematically by state-owned
enterprises. Connection to the government and the party, in contrast, seem to
92
FIRMS’ ACCESS TO FINANCE: ENTRY, GROWTH, AND PRODUCTIVITY
help private entrepreneurs gain access to credit. These authors also find a negative relationship between access to credit and investment growth. Simply put,
firms receiving bank finance in Vietnam are not the engines of growth. At the
same time, expanding private firms seem to rely mostly on retained earnings
and personal savings to finance investment. There is one positive exception
to this disappointing picture: in more competitive provinces, that is, in those
where there are more private entrepreneurs per capita competing for credit,
easier access to credit is positively related to investment growth. Overall, these
results point to a misallocation of banking credit to connected firms in less
competitive regions of the country.
10. Also, Rajan and Zingales (1998) find the growth effect of finance only
on industries that need it most, and not on all industries, suggesting that it
is the efficiency of financial intermediation that matters, not simply capital
accumulation.
11. See, for example, Rioja and Valev (2004a, b).
12. Noting that most enterprises need some initial wealth, Aghion, Fally,
and Scarpetta (2006) see the financial system as allowing entrepreneurs to leverage this initial wealth—the better developed the financial system, the higher
the leverage, a phenomenon that allows efficient newcomers to displace even
well-financed but inefficient incumbents. Working with data on more than
10,000 firms drawn mainly from national business registries and administrative records in 16 countries, including 7 developing or transition economies
(and using the susceptibility measure of Rajan and Zingales, mentioned in
box 2.1), they find that national policies that restrict credit availability tend
to limit entry and growth of small firms to a much larger extent than do labor
market regulations. On the other hand, large firm entry is not affected by
financial development.
13. Given that exporting firms face fi xed costs and might therefore depend
more on external finance than other firms, Becker and Greenberg (2005)
conjectured that countries with higher levels of financial development should
have higher exports. And indeed—using bilateral trade data and controlling
for other variables in a gravity regression—they find that countries with higher
levels of financial development export more. This effect is stronger in industries
in which exporters potentially face higher fi xed costs, as proxied by the lack of
standardization, or for exports to nonneighboring countries or countries with
a different language.
14. Using the Rajan and Zingales methodology, Beck (2003) shows countries with better-developed financial systems have a comparative advantage in
industries relying more on external finance.
15. These results are reported by Beck and Levine (2002), who used the
same sectoral data source for 42 countries as Rajan and Zingales (1998) (see
93
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
box 2.1), but added measures of the relative size or activity of the securities
markets and the banking system.
16. Specifically, Demirgüç-Kunt and Maksimovic (2002) found no additional explanatory power when they added a variable indicating the relative
size of securities markets and banks to their analysis of the proportion of each
county’s firms that were growing faster than could be achieved solely with
internal resources. But the equations, containing both banking depth and stock
market turnover as independent explanatory variables in quadratic form, did
suggest that stock market development might be more important than bank
development in allowing firm growth that required long-term financing. (For
their dependent variable, they counted the number of firms—out of a total of
more than 10,000 from 32 countries—that were expanding sales faster than
would seem supportable from internal resources or short-term borrowing, as
modeled by a standard financial planning model. (This study built on a paper
they published in 1998; see box 2.1).
17. Of course the dichotomy between banks and markets is also too simplistic. Many nonbank institutions, including nondepository mortgage lenders,
leasing, and factoring companies, are involved in specialized forms of asset-based
finance. And important channels of equity finance—venture capital, business
angel finance, and other forms of private equity—can operate without much
use of organized securities exchanges. Institutional investors too are important
providers of several forms of financing. The bank-market distinction is nevertheless a useful handle: much of what can be said about bank finance applies
to nonbank lenders; much of what is important for securities markets is also
relevant for private equity.
18. There are good theoretical reasons for debt finance to be the major
source of external finance, not least because, relative to other forms of sharing
the returns on a project, the debt contract economizes on precise monitoring
of project performance (Diamond 1984).
19. De la Torre, Martinez Peria, and Schmukler (2007) show that banks in
two very different institutional environments (Argentina and Chile) adapt to
lend to SMEs and overcome institutional weaknesses. Banks do so by lending
short term, collateralizing their loans, or securing their loans in some other
forms.
20. It is perhaps worth emphasizing the difference between relationship lending and related-party lending, which is a form of self-dealing. Although banks
often resort to related-party lending where information about other borrowers
or contract enforcement is lacking, such lending can ultimately impose social
costs, as is well illustrated in the discussion by Maurer and Haber (2004) of
Mexico’s experience in the early 1900s and by La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, and
Zamarripa (2003) of the more recent experiences in East Asia in the 1990s.
94
FIRMS’ ACCESS TO FINANCE: ENTRY, GROWTH, AND PRODUCTIVITY
21. A classic account of the Jewish Maghribi traders’ network in the late
Middle Ages is in Greif (1993).
22. These Regional Program on Enterprise Development surveys were carried out in five African countries during the 1990s. For a book-length discussion
of the findings, see Fafchamps (2004).
23. Fisman (2003) controls more carefully for unobserved firm quality and
still finds that firms are more than twice as likely to receive trade credit from
within their ethnic community than from outside. However, he also finds that
these ethnic ties account for only 15 percent of the overall preferential credit
access enjoyed by entrepreneurs of non-African descent.
24. Ensuring that the growth of this industry is based on trustworthy rating
agency firms is a nonnegligible challenge (Honohan 2001).
25. Bebczuk (2007) undertook a similar exercise using Argentine data and
reported similar findings.
26. In some countries foreign banks have entered the SME lending market
themselves (De la Torre, Martinez Peria, and Schmukler 2007). This does not
only imply relying on the transaction-lending techniques mentioned above,
but it does imply a learning process for foreign banks. Similarly, bank-survey
evidence from transition economies has shown that many foreign banks are
taking advantage of the improving contractual and information frameworks
in these countries and are applying business models from their mostly West
European home countries and (de Haas and Naaborg 2005). Some banks in
transition countries also have been expanding intraregionally and moving
beyond a traditional focus on large corporations to provide more financial services geared to SMEs in host countries. In Sub-Saharan Africa, where foreign
banks have long been criticized for neglecting all but the large, international
borrowers, a more differentiated picture has been emerging in recent years
(Honohan and Beck 2007).
27. In most cases, an important market segment typically remains to be
served by locally owned and smaller banks. Indeed, cross-country evidence
(Berger, Hassan, and Klapper 2004) suggests that where smaller non-stateowned local banks have a higher market share, economic growth is stronger,
although it has not proved possible to establish that this growth is attributable
to more SME lending.
28. The Mexican case, where foreign banks spent $30 billion between 1997
and 2004 and increased the foreign ownership of the Mexican banking system from 11 to 83 percent, provides an interesting illustration of the fact that
large-scale foreign entry is not a panacea even for a highly distressed banking
system. Tracking each bank in Mexico, Schulz (2006) shows that, over the
period 1997–2004, bank capital strengthened, the quality of the loan portfolio
95
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
improved, and there appears to have been a modest increase in productivity (the
latter always hard to measure in banking because of its multiple joint outputs).
During this period, bank lending to the private sector continued the slump
that had begun with the crisis of 1994; there has since been a recovery. But
Haber and Musachio (2005) find it impossible to detect any indication in the
data that foreign acquisition slowed credit granting by a bank, although the
foreign banks did effectively screen out problem borrowers and were ahead of
the others in achieving reduced loan losses.
29. Of course one might get such results if foreign banks tend to be attracted
to countries where the financial market works well anyway. To control for this,
Clarke, Cull, and Martinez Peria (2006) also looked at firms’ opinions about
access to nonbank finance. It turns out that the presence of foreign banks has
no significant impact on the responses to the control question.
30. It is not so easy to draw conclusions about the interest rates charged. For
example, using the same basic data sources, Martinez Peria and Mody (2004)
found that whether bank entry was by merger, acquisition, or de novo, foreignowned banks charge narrower margins, by 50 basis points on average, than
domestic banks; and the difference is even larger for de novo foreign banks.
Of course, with interest rates differing widely between customer types, it is
difficult to be sure that the control variables are adequate to reveal a true price
differential, rather than a reflection, for example, of foreign banks lending to
low-risk, low-spread borrowers, and funding on wholesale terms.
31. And using instruments that predict foreign bank entry, but not firm
growth, in a convincing attempt to ensure that the measured effects were not
attributable to a common hidden cause.
32. Even firms outside a formal group structure can indirectly access bank
credit if they are granted increased trade credit from firms with growing bank
borrowings. Trade credit in effect offers credit access to an additional layer
of firms, exploiting information and other bilateral relationships (Fisman and
Love, 2003; Love, Preve, and Sarria-Allende 2007; Burkart, Ellingsen, and
Gianetti; 2004; Omiccioli 2005).
33. But the same database from Pakistan has also thrown light on the potential deficiencies of state-owned banks and specifically on the nexus between
politicians and state-owned banks (see chapter 4).
34. Levy Yeyati and Micco (2007) argue that the extensive foreign bank
entry in Latin America in the 1990s resulted in a less competitive banking
system overall, although this contention is not undisputed. Their evidence
comes from showing that bank revenues became less sensitive to variations in
input costs, as happens with a monopolist charging “what the market will bear,”
in contrast to a competitive system that effectively fully passes on changes in
input prices to the customer.
96
FIRMS’ ACCESS TO FINANCE: ENTRY, GROWTH, AND PRODUCTIVITY
35. For example Demirgüç-Kunt, Laeven, and Levine (2004) show that
restrictions on bank entry, measured by the fraction of entry applications
rejected by the regulatory agency, are more closely correlated with interest
margins than with concentration. Using data on net interest margins of some
1,165 banks from 47 countries, they find that countries that restrict foreign
bank entry end up with higher bank margins.
36. It seems that transactions costs, including those of acquiring information, are strongly related to distance, resulting in a degree of monopoly power
for local banks. Very convincing evidence on this point comes from a market as
developed as Belgium, for which Degryse and Ongena (2005) document how
the lending rates charged by one bank vary according to the physical distance
between the customer and the nearest competitor bank.
37. Studies of this proposition for the United States and other advanced
economies show that its applicability is context specific, with few simple lessons directly applicable to all developing countries. For instance, Cetorelli and
Strahan (2004) show that new entrants found it more difficult to get finance
in U.S. states with less competitive banking markets, but Zarutskie (2005),
using data based on corporation tax returns, finds less investment (as indicated
by higher rates of return) and less external financing for small firms following
increases in competition resulting from the liberalization of U.S. interstate
banking. Using data from different Italian regions, Bonaccorsi di Patti and
Dell’Ariccia (2004) find that bank concentration can have a positive effect
on firm entry where information is opaque. Bertrand, Schoar, and Thesmar
(2007) show that the far-reaching French banking liberalization of the 1980s
did not uniformly increase credit availability but made it more sensitive to
borrowers’ business prospects.
38. Using data on 27,000 publicly listed firms in 27 developed economies
and 18 developing economies, Sorge and Zhang (2006) find that countries with
better quality of credit information (broader coverage of public and especially
private credit registries as well as better accounting standards) are characterized
by a higher share of long-term debt as a proportion of total corporate debt.
39. Based on an extensive U.S. survey of small business finance, OrtizMolina and Penas (2006) provide evidence that loan maturity is positively
correlated with firm size and age and with the amount of collateral posted—
though personal guarantees do not have this effect. Firms that have had a loan
delinquency in the previous three years had shorter maturities.
40. The Jin and Myers (2006) results are based on data from 40 stock
exchanges and use a variety of measures of opacity, including the diversity of
analysts’ forecasts, accounting completeness, and auditing activity.
41. Himmelberg, Hubbard, and Love (2002) examine the return on capital
for a panel of more than 6,000 listed firms on 38 stock exchanges and detect
97
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
a strong and sizable positive relationship between the share of stock held by
insiders and the accounting return on capital, suggesting underinvestment in the
most closely held firms. With such a high return, they “should” have invested
more. The degree of ownership concentration is also strongly correlated with
an index of shareholder protection (measuring, for example, whether voting
is proportional to shareholding, use of proxy voting, and the right of minority shareholders to challenge oppressive majority decisions in court). See also
Burkart, Panunzi, and Shleifer (2003) and Nenova (2003).
42. For a review of these and other issues related to family control, see
Morck and Yeung (2003).
43. See overviews by Bekaert, Harvey, and Lundblad (2005) and Gupta
and Yuan (2005).
44. An American Depository Receipt (ADR) is, in effect, a repackaging of
a non-U.S. equity into a convenient form for U.S. investors to trade in U.S.
stock markets. Depository receipts are also traded in the securities markets of
some other advanced economies.
45. This, at least, was the finding of Harrison, Love, and McMillan (2004),
who took data for 7,000 firms from 40 countries and estimated the sensitivity of
each firm’s investment decisions to its available cash. The authors were exploiting the idea that if a firm has easy access to finance, it should be able to finance
profitable investment opportunities regardless of the immediate availability of
cash balances. In practice, firms’ investments do tend to be sensitive to their cash
holdings. But this sensitivity proves to be lower for firms in countries with high
inward FDI. Contrary, then, to the fears of some that inward FDI would tap
local capital markets, diverting funds from incumbent firms, it seems that FDI
does brings its own funding with it. In specific cases, though, borrowing from
banks by foreign-owned firms could crowd out local firm financing. Another
paper by Harrison and McMillan (2003) finds this crowding-out effect for
Cote d’Ivoire, which the authors conjecture may result from the existence of
interest ceilings and the links between many of the foreign-owned fi rms with
the French parents of the local banks.
46. An interesting study by Da Rin, Nicodano, and Sembenelli (2004)
shows the way. It uses information on the size of private equity investments
in 14 European countries. The authors track the impact of policy and other
variables on the division of these funds between early stage (seed and venture
capital) and late stage, and between high-tech and other sectors.
98
CHAPTER THREE
Household Access to Finance:
Poverty Alleviation and
Risk Mitigation
OVER THE LONG TERM, ECONOMIC GROWTH HELPS REDUCE POVERTY
and can be expected to lift the welfare of most households. This chapter returns to the questions first raised in chapter 1: Well-functioning
financial systems contribute to growth, but do poor households benefit
proportionately from financial reforms that strengthen the economy
generally? To what extent is an emphasis on financial sector development
as a driver of growth consistent with a pro-poor approach to development? Or could the deepening of financial systems lead to a widening
of income inequalities? Must poor households and microentrepreneurs
have direct access to financial services for there to be meaningful poverty
reduction? What techniques are most effective in ensuring sustainable
provision of credit and other financial services on a small scale?
This chapter reviews the findings of recent research on these questions.
Although several theoretical models have highlighted the risk that selectively increased access to credit could worsen inequality, the empirical
evidence does not seem to bear out this risk. Instead, available evidence
suggests that a more developed financial system tends to reduce inequality in the long run. That is not simply because microfinance could help
the poor directly—indeed the evidence from microstudies of favorable
impacts from direct access of the poor to credit is not especially strong.
The conclusions of studies using calibrated general equilibrium models,
specific policy experiments, and econometric analysis of cross-country
data tend to be more positive than are those of the microstudies.
These studies alert us to the likely importance of indirect effects in
explaining the relationship between financial development and income
inequality. These effects are well tracked in the general equilibrium
models discussed below, which show that better financial access for
The empirical evidence
suggests that financial sector
development is consistent
with a pro-poor approach to
development—
—but some of the most
important links may be indirect
99
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Access can be provided by a
range of institutions
nonpoor entrepreneurial households has a strongly favorable, indirect
effect on the poor. These findings imply that for financial development
to have maximum impact on pro-poor growth, the focus should be
broadened from improving finance for the poor to improving finance for
all. That is particularly true in many developing countries, where large
segments of the middle class are still among the financially excluded, as
was discussed in chapter 1.
Delivering broader access is the task of a growing array of financial
institutions, including specialized microfinance institutions (MFIs),
cooperatives, and savings banks. The techniques they use to reach a
wider clientele, while controlling both risks and operating costs, are
evolving, as is their use of information and communication technology.
This chapter reports on recent research that has thrown much light on
the relative importance of different obstacles to improved access at the
micro level and on the techniques that work well, particularly given the
recent trends of globalization and technological advances.
Finance, Inequality, and Poverty
Theory suggests that
greater financial access
could raise income inequality
in the short term—
100
At the outset, it is not immediately obvious that expanding access
to financial services will reduce inequality. After all, the successful
microentrepreneur who manages to get financing for her ideas will
experience an increase in income that her neighbor does not. Indeed,
the more successful she becomes, the wider the income gap would be.
This increase in income inequality is what is predicted by some of the
theories discussed in chapter 1. At the same time, giving people a wider
set of growth opportunities through increased access to finance should
eliminate inequities caused by barriers to such access. At the end of the
day, the net result of greater financial access on measured inequality
will be an empirical issue, and it is one on which there is a considerable
body of recent research.
Theoreticians have developed simple, stylized models to analyze these
questions. Imagine a world in which individuals, differing in their wealth
and entrepreneurial skills, must choose between subsistence farming,
wage work, or entrepreneurial endeavor. Without access to external
finance, the amount of investment an entrepreneur has to start is limited
to her wealth. Start-up costs will often be too large to allow poorer or
less-skilled individuals to become entrepreneurs, so they will remain
HOUSEHOLD ACCESS TO FINANCE: POVERTY ALLEVIATION AND RISK MITIGATION
subsistence farmers or work for a wage if it is high enough. Introducing
a banking sector into such a world allows skilled entrepreneurs to borrow
to finance setup costs. Although such a stylized world is far from the
complex reality of even the very poor in developing countries, it offers
a glimpse of the range of possible impacts on growth, inequality, and
welfare that can come from increasing access to finance. But the size
and even the nature of these impacts depend on the magnitude of, for
example, the behavioral responses, the distribution of skills and wealth,
and the productivity of labor and capital. Is it possible to derive realistic
estimates of the size of these various parameters from what is known
about the economic decisions of actual individuals and households? A
paper by Giné and Townsend (2004) attempts to do just that. Drawing
on data from a collection of surveys of Thai households, stretching
from 1976 to 1996, the authors use information about wealth, wage
rates, financial transactions, and occupational choices to estimate some
of the model’s parameters; they calibrate other parameters to help the
model fit the evolution of Thai growth and savings rates. The authors
then use this model to simulate how increasing the share of households
with access to credit affects entrepreneurship, employment, wages, and
ultimately growth and income distribution.
Giné and Townsend compare the evolution of growth and inequality in the model with the actual development in the Thai economy and
show that financial liberalization and the consequent increase in access
to credit services can explain the fast GDP per capita growth in the
Thai economy during the period, but they also initially increase income
inequality. Underlying these developments are occupational shifts from
the subsistence sector into the intermediated sector, that is, the sector
with access to credit and accompanying changes in wages. Net welfare
benefits of increased access are found to be substantial. Although they are
concentrated disproportionately on a small group of talented, low-wealth
individuals, who without credit could not become entrepreneurs, a wider
class of workers also benefits because eventually wage rates increase as
the new entrepreneurs use their newfound access to credit to build their
companies. Savers also benefit in the form of higher interest paid on their
savings. But there are also losers; these are former entrepreneurs who lose
because they have to pay the much higher postliberalization wage rates.1
When calibrated to fit Thai data on finance, growth, and inequality,
the general equilibrium model analyzed by Giné and Townsend implies
that the greatest quantitative impact of financial deepening and financial
—which was evident in a study
of the Thai economy—
—although the biggest impact
was due to higher wages,
which led to lower inequality
in the longer run
101
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Finance and poverty—
the micro evidence
The benefits of microfinance
may reflect selection bias—
102
access on income inequality comes through indirect labor market
effects. Depending on initial conditions and the choice of parameters,
these effects also result in a long-term decrease in income inequality
that off-sets short-term increases coming from wealth gains of new
entrepreneurs.
Although calibrated theoretical models illuminate important aspects
of the financial development process and provide illustrative quantification of these processes, their findings must be interpreted with care,
because they do exclude other potentially important influences on
growth and inequality.2 A more direct approach to assessing the impact
of access to finance is to zoom in on specific schemes or experiments
in which some, but not all, households are eligible, and try to uncover
the consequences both for beneficiaries and for those excluded. Unlike
general equilibrium models and the aggregate regression methodology,
discussed later, the microanalyses often focus on the direct effect of access
to finance on the well-being of households with access, not always taking
into account possible spillover and indirect effects that are highlighted
in the general equilibrium analyses.
The success stories of microfinance are well documented. But to be
convinced of the overall benefit of microfinance, skeptics require careful
differentiation between those changes that can be clearly attributed to
financial access and those that might have happened anyway or result
from other changes in the environment in which microfinance clients
operate. In other words, is measurement of the true effect biased by a
selection effect? For example, was it the more talented or otherwise wellendowed households that actually got the loans and might have prospered
even in their absence? Or did the MFI target the village because it was
particularly deprived and hence may have benefited even if its condition
remains behind that of unserved villages? How specific is the impact
to the village; can the same MFI scheme have the same effect in other
villages? Numerous studies have attempted to find ways of answering
these questions on the basis of particular features of the MFI design.
Debate surrounding even the most famous MFI, Bangladesh’s
Grameen Bank, illustrates how difficult this task has been. In a celebrated and very careful study of Grameen Bank and two other MFIs in
Bangladesh, Pitt and Khandker (1998) exploited an exogenous eligibility
criterion: to be eligible for credit from these three MFIs, households
could not own more than one-half acre of land. All other things being
equal, the difference in the fortunes of two households with just under
HOUSEHOLD ACCESS TO FINANCE: POVERTY ALLEVIATION AND RISK MITIGATION
and just over half an acre could be attributed to the program. The sharp
cutoff of the eligibility criterion seemed to allow the researchers to avoid a
selection-effect bias. Using appropriate econometric techniques to correct
in this way for selection, Pitt and Khandker found small but significant
and positive effects of the use of credit on household expenditures,
household assets, labor supply, and the likelihood that children attend
schools.3 This effect was stronger for female program participants than
for male participants. The study also found that labor supply response
was surprisingly low compared with the response of assets and expenditures, suggesting that the effect of finance goes through productivity
of labor, rather than the amount.
However, even this research has not gone unchallenged. For example,
there is doubt that the half-acre rule was systematically and rigorously
applied. If it was not, then its use to correct for selection bias is weakened. Khandker (2003), using panel data from a follow-up survey on
the same group of borrowers, was able to obtain more precise estimates
by controlling for unobserved, but time-invariant borrower characteristics. His results suggest a substantially lower impact of credit than the
original Pitt and Khandker study found.
Another opportunity to assess the impact of access to credit while avoiding selection bias was seized by Coleman (1999), who studied microcredit
borrowers in northeast Thailand. He exploited the fact that six communities had been identified as future locations for village banks, and that
there was a list of self-selected villagers who wanted to apply for loans once
the banks were established. By comparing these borrowers-in-waiting
with actual borrowers of existing banks in other villages, Coleman could
reasonably hope to have corrected for the selection bias that would have
resulted from simply surveying a random group in the not-yet-served villages.4 He found no significant impact of credit on physical assets, savings,
production sales, productive expenses, labor, or expenditures on health care
or education. In a similar study, Cotler and Woodruff (2007) compared
small-scale retailers receiving loans from a Mexican microfinance lender
with a similar group of retailers that had been selected to receive such
loans in the future. They found a positive and significant effect of the
microlending program on sales and profits only for the smallest retailers,
but a negative effect on larger retailers’ sales and profits.
A more direct way to avoid selection bias is to construct a genuine
experiment in which the subjects and the control group are chosen
randomly and thus create the necessary exogenous variation needed to
—and the empirical evidence
is mixed
A field experiment using
random selection criteria
highlights the benefits of
microcredit—
103
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
—but more research is
needed in this area
104
identify impact. Recently, Karlan and Zinman (2006a) persuaded a South
African consumer lender to relax its risk assessment criteria for a randomly
chosen group of barely rejected loan applicants. The random nature of
the assignment of credit helps the authors to get around the problem of
selection bias.5 Comparing the group of randomly chosen borrowers with
the control group of marginally rejected applicants, Karlan and Zinman
found that six to twelve months after the loan application, borrowers were
significantly more likely to retain wage employment, less likely to experience hunger in their household, and less likely to be impoverished.
Further research, ideally using real experiments, is needed to convince
the skeptics that access to microcredit really is good for the neighborhoods
where it becomes established, as most well-informed observers and practitioners believe.6 It has to be said that the current systematic statistical
research evidence on the benefits of microcredit is not yet overwhelming.
The studies reviewed here were undertaken in very different institutional
settings and with different credit products. Individual or household welfare
is notoriously difficult to measure, which biases microanalysis against finding a positive effect of access to credit. More research is needed to assert
whether there is a robust and positive relationship between the use of credit
and household welfare, including moving out of poverty.
Several other studies have used cross-sectional household data to assess
the impact of access to finance on households’ consumption patterns,
income prospects, and the decision to send children to school rather than
using them as laborers in the household. Most of these studies, however,
use proxy measures of access to finance such as durable assets, which can
be used as collateral, rather than the direct measures used by the studies
mentioned above. Survey data of this type for Peru suggest that lack of
access to credit reduces the likelihood that poor households send their
children to school, while studies for Guatemala, India, and Tanzania
point to households without financial access as being more likely than
households with more assets to reduce their children’s school attendance
and increase their labor if they suffer transitory income shocks. Survey
data for Guatemalan microentrepreneurs show a positive effect of credit
use on upward class mobility, allowing them to expand their businesses.
Finally, consumption patterns of Indonesian households that live closer
to the nearest BRI branch, the largest MFI lender in the country, show
smaller or no effects from health shocks compared with households living farther away.7 Box 3.1 discusses the links between access to financial
services and some of the Millennium Development Goals.
HOUSEHOLD ACCESS TO FINANCE: POVERTY ALLEVIATION AND RISK MITIGATION
Box 3.1
Access to finance and the Millennium Development Goals
IN 2000, 189 NATIONS ADOPTED THE MILLENNIUM
Decla ration, specif ying eight Millennium
Development Goals, including eradicating extreme
poverty by 2015. The other goals concern education
(universal primary education), gender equality, health
(reductions in child and maternal mortality and
reversing the spread of AIDS, malaria, and other diseases), environment, and global partnerships. While
access to financial services is not explicitly mentioned
among these goals, both theory and numerous empirical studies, including many mentioned in this text,
suggest that access to financial services is an important
direct or indirect contributor to the achievement
of most of the goals (Claessens and Feijen 2006;
Littlefield, Morduch, and Hashemi 2003).
In the case of education and health, one important effect of access to financial services is through
the income effect: better access to financial services
improves incomes and therefore the possibility of
obtaining health and education services, and at the
same time it reduces the need to rely on children
as laborers in the household. Allowing women
direct access to financial services might improve
their possibilities to become entrepreneurs, thus
increasing their individual incomes, their chances
to become more independent, and their participation in family and community decision making.
There is also an important insurance effect: better access to credit, savings, or insurance services
reduces the need to use child labor as a buffer in the
case of seasonal income fluctuations and transitory
income shocks and allows consumption smoothing
in the case of transitory income reductions resulting
from health shocks. It also allows faster attention
to health problems. Finally, there is an aggregate
infrastructure effect, with more efficient financial
institutions and markets allowing more private and
public investment in the construction of schools
and health facilities.
The links between access to finance and the goals
of environmental stability and global partnerships
might be less obvious and have not been researched
very thoroughly. However, arguments can be made
for such relationships, at least at the aggregate level.
Ensuring environmental stability will require large
investments in new technologies, and financial depth
has shown to be conducive for capital reallocation
across sectors. Finally, the goal of global cooperation
will be hard to achieve without better functioning
global financial markets.
To evaluate the effect of increasing financial access for households
and microentrepreneurs, one has to look beyond the direct impact on
the household or enterprise and assess the impact on the whole economy.
That cannot be done through micro studies. In particular, even if the
very poor do not themselves gain access to financial services, they may
benefit substantially from increased employment and other opportunities
resulting from the activities of less-poor microentrepreneurs whose access
has improved. With large numbers of the nonpoor still excluded from
access to credit, these systemic effects could include trickle-down effects
for the poor from improved access for the nonpoor. However, they could
also include perverse trickle-down effects: if only a subset of households
in a village has access to credit or insurance to smooth consumption,
Finance, inequality and
poverty—the aggregate
evidence
105
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Financial development
reduces poverty through its
effect on overall growth—
—increases the income share
of the poorest quintile—
106
that subset will bid up the price of nontraded goods when a negative
shock hits the village, so excluded households will be worse off than if
nobody had access to credit or insurance (Morduch 2006).
Chapter 2 has already discussed the evidence for a strong causal link
between financial development, as measured by financial depth, and
overall national economic growth. That chapter also identified improved
access to finance by firms as an important channel through which this
effect works. If income growth rates of the poor remain broadly in line
with those of the rest of the population, aggregate economic growth
will mean a reduction in absolute poverty as more households graduate
beyond the poverty threshold (Ravallion 2001). Only a sizable fall in
the income share of the poor could prevent aggregate economic growth
from lowering absolute poverty.8 If growth reduces the absolute poverty
count, it is said to be pro-poor in the absolute sense. Growth that reduces
poverty by narrowing income differentials is said to be pro-poor in the
relative sense. Recent research suggests that financial development generates pro-poor growth in both senses.
For example, Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Levine (2007) look at
cross-country data for varying periods during 1960–2005 to assess
the relationship between financial depth and changes in both income
distribution and absolute poverty. They work with a simple decomposition of the income growth of the poorest income quintile into mean per
capita national income growth and the change in the share of the poorest
quintile. A large body of literature has established that finance has a positive impact on GDP per capita growth; but what about the relationship
between finance and changes in the income share of the lowest income
quintile? The authors find a positive relationship between financial depth
(as measured by the ratio of private sector credit to GDP) and the change
in the share of the lowest quintile in total national personal income.
Not only does a deeper financial system accelerate national growth, but
it is associated with a faster increase in the income share of the poorest
group. Indeed, almost half of the beneficial effect of financial deepening
on average income of the poorest quintile comes from this improvement
in the (relative) distribution of income.
They also obtain similar results when they look at the changes in the
Gini measure of income inequality. The relationship between financial
development and the growth rate of the Gini coefficient is negative,
suggesting that finance reduces income inequality. Not only are these
findings robust to controlling for other country characteristics associated
HOUSEHOLD ACCESS TO FINANCE: POVERTY ALLEVIATION AND RISK MITIGATION
with economic growth and changes in income inequality, but the authors
also make an attempt to control for potential reverse causality, using
historic variables such as national origin of the legal system to extract
an exogenous component of financial development, as well as panel
techniques that control for omitted variable and endogeneity bias.
Although cross-country studies are subject to the caveats discussed in
box 2.1, these findings are also consistent with the findings of general
equilibrium models discussed earlier, in that financial development
is associated with reductions in income inequality over the long run.
Further evidence is provided by cross-country studies looking at the
relationship between financial development and the level of income
inequality. Li, Squire, and Zou (1998) and Li, Xu, and Zou (2000) find
a negative relationship between finance and the level of income inequality as measured by the Gini coefficient, a finding confirmed by Clarke,
Xu, and Zhou (2006), using both cross-sectional and panel regressions
and instrumental variable methods.
In some countries, far more than the bottom 20 percent are poor when
measured against the international standard poverty lines of $1 or $2 a day;
in other countries almost nobody is poor by these demanding standards.
To look more directly at the impact of financial development on absolute
poverty, Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Levine (2007) also estimate the change
in the share of each country’s population below the international poverty
line that results from financial deepening. Again, they find a robust effect
of finance on poverty alleviation—countries with higher levels of financial
development experienced faster reductions in the share of population living
on less than $1 a day over the 1980s and 1990s (figure 3.1).
The economic impact is strong as well, as discussed in box 3.2. The
relative importance of economic growth and the distributional impact
of finance vary according to initial conditions: not surprisingly, the
distributional impact is strongest for countries with relatively high per
capita income and a very unequal income distribution, while the growth
impact is strongest in relatively poor countries with a relatively equal
income distribution.
This finance-poverty evidence is consistent with the findings of
Honohan (2004), who showed that even among societies with the same
average income, those with deeper financial systems have lower absolute
poverty. These findings all point in the same direction: policies fostering
financial sector development are not only pro-growth, but also pro-poor
in both relative and absolute senses.9
—and lowers poverty
107
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Figure 3.1
Financial depth and poverty alleviation
Growth in poverty headcount / GDP
0.2
0
–0.2
–0.4
–2
–1
0
Private credit / GDP
1
2
Source: Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Levine (2007).
Note: This figure is a partial scatter plot of growth of poverty headcount vs. private credit to
GDP, controlling for the initial level of poverty headcount, with data averaged over the period
1980–2005.
A natural experiment
from Indian regulations
shows the impact of
improved access—
108
The cross-country evidence has the merit of broad coverage, but the
quality of the data is uneven from country to country. Gini coefficients,
quintile shares, and poverty headcounts are all subject to substantial measurement problems.10 The shortcomings of financial depth as a measure
of financial development, let alone financial access, have already been
pointed out. That the results obtained with aggregate data are stronger
than the results of the micro studies cited earlier may point to the potentially greater importance of spillover effects, which are not captured by
micro studies. But the stronger results may also reflect the difficulty of
controlling for reverse causality in cross-country regressions. It is therefore important to seek additional types of evidence for systemic effects
of improved financial access. Two policy changes that can be thought
of as akin to natural experiments point in the same direction.
One experiment involved the Indian government’s policy on bank
branching, imposed between 1977 and 1990. In those years a commercial bank in India was allowed to open one new branch in a district
that already had a bank presence only after it opened four branches in
areas without a bank presence. This policy led to the opening of 30,000
HOUSEHOLD ACCESS TO FINANCE: POVERTY ALLEVIATION AND RISK MITIGATION
Box 3.2 Financial depth and poverty reduction: how big is the effect?
JUDGING FROM THE REGRESSIONS ESTIMATED BY
Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Levine (2007), the relation between financial depth and poverty is not only
causal and statistically significant but sizable. Even
after account is taken of the effect of other control
variables, almost 30 percent of the cross-country
variation in changing poverty rates can be attributed
to cross-country variation in financial development.
Consider, for example, the fact that the share of the
population in deep poverty (less than $1 a day) fell
by 14 percent a year in Chile between 1987 and
2000, whereas it rose at a similar rate in neighboring Peru. Chile has a much deeper financial sector
(private credit is 47 percent of GDP) than Peru
(private credit is 17 percent of GDP). The estimated
regression implies that had Peru started with the
same financial depth as Chile, its poverty headcount
would have grown a full 5 percentage points more
slowly, so that by 2002, just 5 percent of Peru’s
population would have been living on less than $1
a day instead of the actual share of 10 percent.
Such comparisons have to be interpreted with caution, though, for several reasons. The regression coefficients indicate marginal, not large, discrete changes;
the variable measuring financial depth is only a proxy;
omission from the equation of other unmeasured
causal variables may be exaggerating the measured
impact of financial depth. However, even if one is
convinced that private credit is associated with faster
poverty reduction, that is not an invitation to policy
makers to expand credit freely: attempts to force the
rate of financial deepening through lax monetary
policy, for example, will not generate true financial
development and will prove to be unsustainable.
new rural branches over the period, as well as to an increase in deposit
and credit volume in states with initially low levels of financial development. Burgess and Pande (2005) find that as a result of this branching
regulation, nonagricultural output grew faster, and poverty declined
faster, in states that started the period with a lower level of financial
development, while the opposite was true before and after this period
of regulation. Further, wages of agricultural workers grew faster during
this period, while the wages of urban factory workers do not show such
a time pattern. This seems to suggest that financial development—triggered by the branching regulation—led to faster reductions in poverty.
The cost-benefit calculation of this policy, though, is a different matter
(see box 4.3 in chapter 4) and suggests that the macroeconomic costs
might have been significant.
Another natural experiment is offered by the branching deregulation
implemented by different U.S. states over a 20-year period from the
mid-1970s to the mid-1990s. Following Jayaratne and Strahan (1996),
a large literature has evaluated the effect that easing restrictions on
intra- and interstate branching had on income growth, banking sector
structure, and entrepreneurial activity. The variation in timing of the
—as does one from the U.S.
experience with liberalization
109
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
deregulation over a 20-year period and the fact that the deregulation was
not driven by expectations of higher growth or higher entrepreneurial
activity allow researchers to perform difference-in-differences estimates,
thus holding constant unobserved state-level and year effects. Beck,
Levine, and Levkov (2007) exploit the same quasi-natural experiment
to assess the effect of branching deregulation on income inequality; they
find that states see their Gini coefficient decrease by a small but statistically significant amount in the years after deregulation relative to other
states and relative to their own level before the deregulation (figure 3.2).
This effect eliminated about one-sixth of the overall increase in income
inequality that the United States experienced over this time period. Over
three-quarters of the inequality reduction after deregulation comes from
changes in the distribution of income among wage and salary earners, with
less than a fifth coming from distributional changes among self-employed
proprietors, suggesting that the main effect of branch deregulation on
income inequality in this case is not enhanced entrepreneurship, but rather
the indirect effects of higher labor demand and higher wages.
Figure 3.2
Branch deregulation across U.S. states and income inequality
Percentage change in Gini
1
0
95th percentile
–1
–2
5th percentile
–3
–10
–8
–6
–4
2
4
–2
0
Years since deregulation
6
8
10
Source: Beck, Levine, and Levkov (2007).
Note: This graph illustrates a regression of the log of the Gini coefficient across U.S. states and
over the years 1977 to 2003 on state and year dummies, other time-variant state characteristics
and dummy variables indicating t + x years, where t is the year of branch deregulation and x goes
from -10 to +10. Gray lines indicate 95 percent and 5 percent confidence intervals.
110
HOUSEHOLD ACCESS TO FINANCE: POVERTY ALLEVIATION AND RISK MITIGATION
Of course care must be taken in extrapolating findings from a system
as developed as that of the United States, where most households have
at least some access to formal financial services, in contrast to the situation in low- and middle-income countries. Nevertheless, these results
are consistent with the results obtained by Giné and Townsend (2004)
for the effects of financial liberalization in Thailand.
Despite the theoretical possibility that a selective expansion of access
to finance could initially worsen income inequality, and methodological
challenges notwithstanding (see box 3.3 for a summary), the balance of
evidence from specific quasi-experimental events, estimation of general
equilibrium models, and broad cross-country regressions is that financial
development and improved access to credit tends not only to accelerate
economic growth but to lower household poverty and inequality.
Much remains to be learned about the channels through which financial development affects income inequality and poverty alleviation. Is it
through providing access to credit to a larger proportion of the population
or through fostering more efficient capital allocation, that is, through
fostering more competitive and open markets? Is it through depth or
through broader access that finance helps reduce income inequality and
poverty? Given the wide differences that exist in financial inclusion across
countries, to what extent do these effects depend on the initial level of
financial access and economic development?
Since the strongest evidence for a favorable finance-inequality relationship points to important labor market effects of financial deepening
and broadening, one must consider whether direct provision of financial
services to the very poor is the best way to use finance to help the poor.
Indeed, improving access for small firms and for nonpoor entrepreneurial
households can be a powerful mechanism for helping reduce poverty. It
is easy to see that financing opportunities for the nonpoor in particular regions or among particular ethnic groups could help improve the
functioning of labor and product markets and the efficiency of investment, leading to better employment opportunities for the poor in those
regions as well.
The discussion so far has focused exclusively on the use of credit services, since that is the financial service the literature has focused on most
extensively. However, credit is rarely the first financial service priority
for very poor households. Access to savings and insurance services helps
cushion income shocks and smooth consumption, while access to formal
In summary, improved access
to finance reduces inequality
and poverty—
—but the nature of the
transmission mechanisms
is unclear—
—with evidence suggesting that
the indirect effects on poverty
may be more important
Poor households need other
financial services, not just
access to credit
111
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Box 3.3 Methodological challenges in analyzing the impact of financial access
BOTH THE TECHNICAL ADVANCES IN COMPUTING
power and the availability of subnational and even
household data have helped researchers move beyond
cross-country regression analysis to assess the relationship between finance, growth, and inequality
and thus overcome problems of endogeneity, heterogeneity of the relationship between dependent and
independent variables across countries, and nonlinear
effects. Some of these strategies use innovative historical instruments and panel data. However, even
employing firm- or household-level data, be it within
or across countries, does not by itself solve the identification problem of endogeneity and spurious correlations, as the debate between Pitt and Khandker
(1998) and Morduch (1998) has shown. Identifying
an exogenous policy change, preferably at different
times across subnational units, overcomes selection
problems by utilizing a difference-in-differences estimator that holds constant other confounding effects.
Two such examples, the social banking experiment in
India, and the branching deregulation in the United
States, are discussed in the text.
However, such quasi-natural experiments are rare,
and researchers have therefore also exploited general
equilibrium models and household-level micro data
to calibrate them. This technique has the advantage
of being thoroughly based in theory and controlling for dynamic effects, unlike regression analysis.
At the same time, its application is limited by the
variables included in the theoretical models and
by the availability of household data. While these
structural models are promising in improving the
understanding of the micro foundations of growth
and inequality, it is not always clear how much the
insights from these stylized models rely on specific
details of how the imperfections were modeled and
whether the results are robust to these choices.
Another valuable approach is the use of controlled
or natural experiments in specific countries or in
specific locations, such as the one undertaken by
Karlan and Zinman (2006a) in South Africa and
others discussed here in the context of evaluating the
impact of microfinance. Of course, natural experiments are scarce, and controlled experiments can
be costly to implement and their results specific to
their context. In addition, they necessarily measure
partial equilibrium effects and, unlike aggregate
studies, do not pick up spillover and indirect effects.
Furthermore, many important policy issues with
implications for financial access, such as regulation
and supervision of financial institutions, involve
country-level variation and do not lend themselves
to randomization.
Finally, laboratory experiments work with
potential clients or people with similar profiles and
mimic different fi nancial contract mechanisms.
Experimental games have the advantage of allowing
researchers to have even more control of events, but
they also have the shortcoming of being a staged
setting that might or might not be consistent with
real life behavior.
Given that each methodological approach has
its advantages and shortcomings, a robust research
philosophy would try to identify the most important
policy questions and to employ appropriate and
feasible methods for addressing them.
payment services is increasingly important in market-based economies.
This is an area that requires future research.
Having established the importance of access to finance, the next
task is to consider what is the best way of reaching out to low-income
households and microentrepreneurs to foster access to and use of
credit, savings, and payment services. The following section discusses
112
HOUSEHOLD ACCESS TO FINANCE: POVERTY ALLEVIATION AND RISK MITIGATION
institutional and product innovations to reach out to these customers
traditionally excluded by the banking system.
Providing Financial Access to Households and
Microentrepreneurs: How and by Whom?
The considerable success of the microfinance movement, both technically
and in its ability to mobilize financial and political support, has focused
attention on direct access to credit for poor people and especially for
poor women. In what has been an accelerating revolution over the past
few decades (Robinson 2001), specialized microfinance institutions have
reached millions of clients, and many of them have achieved impressive repayment rates, especially when compared with the disappointing
record of an earlier generation of development banks. Attention has also
broadened to other types of financial institutions, such as savings banks,
including postal savings banks, and financial cooperatives and credit
unions that have also been catering to the financial needs of low-income
households and microenterprises.
Now mainstream financial institutions are becoming interested in
the market at the “bottom of the pyramid,” to use the term popularized
by Prahalad (2004). At the same time, some of the stronger MFIs have
secured banking licenses and offer a wider range of services to a broader
clientele. Many have graduated beyond the need for sizable subsidies to
ensure their financial viability, whereas others still seek subsidies to help
keep the costs to the borrower to a minimum. There has been much
experimentation in lending technologies as practitioners find the various
formulas with which they began unduly constraining. These techniques
included the use of various forms of mutual guarantee in small or large
borrower groups (joint liability), and programs of progressively larger
loan sizes as loans were repaid and new loans given (dynamic incentives).
To attract savings, financial institutions of all sorts are using new methodologies, such as mobile branches, deposit collectors, and cell phone
technology, and developing new products, such as commitment savings
products and micro-insurance policies.
Against this background, a growing number of researchers has been
using formal econometric techniques to assess quantitatively some of the
key operational issues that face MFIs and other providers of financial
services to small-scale users. The findings—several of them striking in
The growth of microcredit has
attracted new players—
113
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
—despite obstacles to
delivering credit to the poor
114
their precision—have used replicable statistical evidence that has either
confirmed or questioned practitioner intuition. This section reviews some
of the main findings in five areas of interest: the relative importance of
transaction costs and two key information barriers, moral hazard and
adverse selection, for outreach to low-income borrowers; the sensitivity of
the demand for microcredit to the level of the interest rate charged; the
relative effectiveness of group and individual lending; the complementary role of access to noncredit services; and the link between subsidies
and outreach to the poor. While most emphasis is placed on credit, the
discussion also highlights the importance of depository, insurance, and
especially payments services. Throughout, the discussion emphasizes the
potential effects of globalization and technological advances on access
to financial services. It concludes with some observations on the likely
welfare implications of targeting efforts to expand household access
to the very poor, noting again that access for nonpoor entrepreneurial
households can have a sizable antipoverty impact.
As already discussed, the main problems in delivering credit are
linked to risk management and the high transaction costs of processing,
monitoring, and enforcing small loans, which increase break-even interest
rates for these loans. The risks include those arising out of information
asymmetries. These asymmetries can result from adverse selection, that
is, the inability of the lender to distinguish between high- and low-risk
borrowers, or from moral hazard, that is, the tendency for some borrowers
to divert resources to projects that reduce their likelihood of being able
to repay the loan and the inability of the lender to detect and prevent
such behavior. Depending on the specific information asymmetry and
the ability of potential borrowers to pledge collateral, lenders may try to
use the interest rate or a combination of the interest rate and collateral
as a screening and sorting mechanism (Bester 1985). If collateral is not
available, lenders are forced to rely only on the interest rate, but in doing
so, they risk excluding, or crowding out, safe borrowers. Indeed, under
some circumstances lenders will prefer to keep the lending rate below
the market-clearing level for fear of worsening adverse selection; that
behavior in effect rations credit by nonprice means (Stiglitz and Weiss
1981). Even more borrowers will be rationed out if the high transaction
costs of lending to them lead to break-even interest rates that are too
high to make lending safe (Williamson 1987).
How relevant and important are these three factors—adverse selection, moral hazard, and high transaction costs—for credit rationing
HOUSEHOLD ACCESS TO FINANCE: POVERTY ALLEVIATION AND RISK MITIGATION
of poor households and microentrepreneurs? The existing evidence
points to moral hazard as the driving factor, with a less significant role
for adverse selection. Although high transaction costs can also result in
high repayment burdens, there is evidence of very high rates of return to
investment by microentrepreneurs, which explains why some borrowers
are prepared to pay very high interest rates.
Are the interest rates on microloans too high? Much of the microfinance revolution has been built on the premise that its clients can afford
to pay high interest rates given very high marginal returns on capital.
But measuring these returns is challenging. Using field experiments, de
Mel, McKenzie, and Woodruff (2006) and McKenzie and Woodruff
(2007) estimate capital returns to investment in microenterprises in light
manufacturing and commerce in Sri Lanka and Mexico, respectively.
The enterprises are given cash or equipment, depending on the outcome
of a lottery, and this exogenous shock is used to compute the return to
capital. They find returns of 5–7 percent per month in Sri Lanka and 20
percent or more in Mexico! While these returns might seem high—even
unrealistically high in the case of Mexico—they are based on grants, not
loans; are measured only over the short term; and increased capital by
25 percent on average. Thus, these returns might not be replicable over
the long term. Nor does it follow that the microentrepreneurs would
have pursued the same strategies if they had had loans instead of cash or
equipment. Nevertheless, these estimates suggest that some microentrepreneurs are indeed able to pay the high interest charged by microfinance
institutions, at least where these loan resources are being invested.
That is not to deny that high interest rates are costly for borrowers,
especially poor ones. In their eagerness to emphasize the importance for
the development of sustainable microfinance by removing constraining
interest rate ceilings, some advocates may have overstated the insensitivity
of borrowers to high interest rates. In contrast, Dehejia, Montgomery,
and Morduch (2005), using data from a credit cooperative in Dhaka, and
Karlan and Zinman (2007), using data from a South African consumer
lender, both find rather high elasticities of loan demand with respect to
interest rates, that is, loan demand decreases as interest rates increase.
Emran, Morshed, and Stiglitz (2006) provide a theory to reconcile
these empirical findings with practitioners’ oft-repeated assertions that
borrowers are insensitive to interest rates. They point to imperfections
in the labor market, especially for women, and suggest that it is only
for as long as these imperfections prevent women from entering the
High returns allow some
microentrepreneurs to pay
high interest rates—
—but the demand for
microcredit is interest-elastic
115
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Moral hazard may be more
important for default rates
than repayment burden
labor market that their demand for credit will be so interest inelastic.
Curiously, the Bangladesh data suggest that the elasticity decreased (in
absolute value) with the borrower’s income, whereas the South African
data suggest the opposite. While MFIs in Bangladesh demanding higher
interest rates to compensate for higher costs and risks may face problems
reaching out to poorer clients, the South African lender does not seem to
face these problems. These contrasting results might reflect differences
between consumer and production credit or different institutional settings. Ongoing research is trying to shed more light on the interest rate
elasticity of microcredit borrowers.
One recent experiment in which interest rates were varied among a
homogenous group of borrowers suggests that the repayment burden is
the least of the obstacles the borrowers faced. This experiment points
to moral hazard, including the inability of the lender to enforce repayment from willful defaulters, as the driving factor limiting outreach
to the poor. Karlan and Zinman (2006b) used a randomized direct
mail offer by a South African consumer lender to distinguish between
adverse selection, moral hazard, and repayment burden, as illustrated
in figure 3.3. Specifically, customers were sent credit offers with either
Figure 3.3
Testing for credit constraints in South Africa
Mo
High offer rate
Low offer rate
ral
n.a.
ha
zar
d
Mo
ral
ha
Adverse selection
Low rate tive
t
ate
n
ct r
trac nce
con amic i contra namic
High contract rate
y
yn
Low no d tive
hd
h
wit
wit incen
Repayment burden
zar
d
Source: Karlan and Zinman (2006b).
Note: This figure illustrates the setup of the consumer credit experiment that Karlan and
Zinman ran in South Africa to distinguish between repayment burden, adverse selection, and
moral hazard.
116
HOUSEHOLD ACCESS TO FINANCE: POVERTY ALLEVIATION AND RISK MITIGATION
a high or a low interest rate, and the response of customers to this offer
helps to identify adverse selection, that is, the difference between ex
ante high-risk and low-risk customers (difference between points 3 and
5 in figure 3.3). Some of the customers with the initial high offer rate
then received a lower rate when they responded favorably to the offer,
and the difference between customers with the same high initial offer
rate (and thus the same ex ante risk profile) but different final contract
rate helps identify default due to repayment burden of high interest
rates (difference between points 1 and 2 in figure 3.3). Finally, some
borrowers were offered the prospect of a repeat loan if they repaid their
loan in time; the comparison between borrowers with and without this
dynamic incentive allows identification of moral hazard, that is, incentives to repay (difference between points 2 and 3 and between points 4
and 5 in figure 3.3). Karlan and Zinman find strong evidence for moral
hazard but evidence for adverse selection only for female borrowers and
borrowers who had not borrowed from this lender before. The evidence
for default due to repayment burden is weak. Quantifying the effect of
moral hazard, they find that between 10 and 15 percent of default is
due to moral hazard, with the remainder due to observable differences
in risk across borrowers.11
The entry of a Guatemalan MFI into a credit bureau offers another
innovative experimental setup to distinguish between adverse selection
and moral hazard and yields similar results to those in South Africa (de
Janvry, McIntosh, and Sadoulet 2006). While this entry was initially not
announced to borrowers, the subsequent staggered education of borrowers, who were organized in joint-liability groups, allowed the researchers to distinguish between moral hazard and adverse selection effects.
Specifically, the initial effect on repayment of the announcement of the
existence of the credit bureau helps isolate and identify moral hazard,
that is, repayment incentives, as group composition is constant in the
short run. Subsequent changes in group composition and the effect of
those changes on repayment, on the other hand, can be attributed to
adverse selection, that is, selection of lower-risk group members. The
authors find that delinquency attributable to moral hazard declined 18
percent. Reductions in delinquency resulting from changes in adverse
selection, that is, replacement of high-risk with low-risk group members,
as measured over several loan cycles where groups can adjust their composition, are weaker, but still present. The most significant change in
group composition was a large exit of women and corresponding large
Adverse selection problems
might be more pronounced
among female borrowers
117
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
entry of men, suggesting again that adverse selection problems might
be more pronounced among female borrowers.
Summarizing, many microentrepreneurs are able to pay high interest
rates given high returns on capital. Therefore, the high transaction costs
associated with small loans, the resulting high interest rates, and thus the
higher repayment burden do not seem to be obstacles to reaching poor
households. Rather, outreach to these groups is impeded by the inability
of poor borrowers to commit the use of loan resources to projects with
a risk acceptable to the lender and by the inability of lenders to enforce
repayment. The inability of lenders to distinguish between good and
bad credit risks before making the loan is also an obstacle, but less so.
The research reviewed so far, however, points to two techniques that can
be used to overcome these barriers—joint-liability lending and dynamic
incentives through repeat lending.
Joint-Liability Lending and Dynamic Incentives
Overcoming obstacles—
joint-liability lending and
dynamic incentives
118
The use of joint-liability groups is a traditional tool to overcome the
hurdles of adverse selection, moral hazard, and monitoring and enforcement costs. Joint liability can reduce all three of these barriers to lending, but there are trade-offs (see Ghatak and Guinnane 1999 for an
overview). By pooling borrowers that know each other well and making
them jointly liable for each others’ loan repayment, the lender effectively
outsources the screening and monitoring function. Through assortative
matching—safe (risky) borrowers will join with other safe (risky) borrowers—the lender can screen borrowers by the company they keep.
Joint-liability lending reduces monitoring and enforcement costs and
thus allows lower interest rates. These lower rates reduce the repayment
burden and result in less credit rationing. Most important, lower monitoring costs and strong enforcement through social sanctions can reduce
moral hazard problems in joint-liability credit contracts if borrowers
decide cooperatively on project choices. However, joint-liability lending
can also induce strategic default; if good borrowers see the prospect of
future loans wane because other group members are not repaying their
loans, they have fewer incentives to repay (Besley and Coate 1995).
Further, joint-liability lending is not suitable where different members
of the group have different borrowing needs.
Joint-liability lending was already being applied by German cooperatives in the 19th century. Introduced into the microfinance movement
HOUSEHOLD ACCESS TO FINANCE: POVERTY ALLEVIATION AND RISK MITIGATION
Box 3.4 Testing impact with randomized control trials
MEASURING THE IMPACT OF NEW MICROFINANCE
programs or products requires careful design
because standard assessments comparing customers
before and after introduction of a new program or
product or a comparison between participants and
nonparticipants suffer from two serious shortcomings (Goldberg and Karlan 2005). First, selection
bias can occur if there is a correlation between the
take-up decision of customers and other individual
characteristics that explain the outcome variable.
Further, dropouts can bias the comparison between
program participants and nonparticipants. Second,
such assessments suffer from a lack of a proper
counterfactual, that is, how the same group of clients would have behaved without the new program
or product.
To overcome these methodological challenges,
researchers are increasingly using randomized experiments to assess new microfinance programs and
products. The characteristics of these experiments
can be summarized as follows. First, the evaluation
has to be prospective; in other words, it has to start
before the new product is introduced so that the
changes induced by the product can be properly
assessed. Second, to have a proper counterfactual,
the evaluation should be based on comparison of a
treatment and a control group, where only the first
has access to the new program or product. Third,
assignment to either group has to be random to
ensure that clients in both groups have the same
characteristics; only then can the effects of the new
program or product be isolated. Fourth, the researchers have to take into account two potential spillover
effects: experiment spillover, where members of
treatment and control groups find out about each
other; and impact spillover, where the effects of the
new program or product spread to people and areas
beyond the treatment group.
Although they have limitations, carefully planned
and executed impact evaluations are a powerful
instrument both for individual financial institutions
that want to assess the profitability and impact of
new products and programs and for policy makers
who want to assess which interventions are the most
promising in reducing poverty. A significant shortcoming is the high costs of such evaluations, which
prevent many MFIs from using them (Armendáriz
de Aghion and Morduch 2005). In addition, the
question of external validity—whether the results
of the evaluation are applicable in different socioeconomic and institutional contexts—cannot be
addressed with such experiments.
A final word of caution concerns the use of these
impact evaluations for public policy or public resources.
Because no counterfactual or alternative intervention
is being evaluated, either in the financial sector or for
nonfinancial interventions, one has to keep in mind the
partial equilibrium aspect of these assessments.
in the 1980s by the Grameen Bank in Bangladesh, joint-liability lending
quickly became popular with pioneer microcredit institutions. Given its
limitations, however, many MFIs, including Grameen itself, have moved
away from a pure joint-liability lending model and now also offer individual loans. The limitations of relying on just one lending model are also
reflected in the results of recent field research, especially some studies that
have made very effective use of randomized control trials (box 3.4).
How important are reductions in adverse selection, moral hazard,
or monitoring and enforcement costs for the success of joint-liability
119
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Joint liability can help reduce
moral hazard when social
connections are strong—
—but group-based lending
may not always be better than
lending to individuals
120
lending? Giné and others (2006) find in the setting of laboratory experiments in Peru that both the screening of group members before the loan
is made and the monitoring of borrowers afterward have an important
role in the success of joint-liability lending.12 However, they also find
that joint liability helps reduce moral hazard only when the group forms
voluntarily. Using household data across members of more than 262 Thai
joint-liability groups, Ahlin and Townsend (2007) find that informal
sanctioning, thus ex post reductions in moral hazard, fits the data best
in poor rural areas, while ex ante screening, thus reducing the risk of
adverse selection, fits the data best in more affluent areas.
The importance of moral hazard reductions through joint-liability
lending is confirmed with evidence from poor rural Peru, where Karlan
(2007) exploited a natural quasi-random group-building process, where
members were randomly assigned to groups rather than selecting their
peer group members themselves. He finds that stronger social connections between group members (as measured by geographic proximity
and common ethnicity) lead to better repayment and higher savings than
for groups where social connections are weaker. Given the absence of
peer selection in this group-building process, Karlan concludes that the
better repayment behavior is attributable to reductions in moral hazard;
in other words, joint-liability groups that were more socially connected
were better able to prevent their members from diverting loan funds to
risky projects or other purposes.13 He finds direct evidence that members
of groups with better social connections have better knowledge of each
other and are more likely to punish defaulters by cutting relationships;
however, they are also more likely to forgive debt, suggesting that peers in
these groups know how to distinguish between culpable or blameworthy
default on the one hand, and bad luck on the other.
However, some evidence suggests that social ties can be too strong, leading to collusion and lower repayment. Ahlin and Townsend (2007) find
evidence in their Thai data that stronger social ties, measured by more sharing between unrelated members of the groups and clustering of relatives, are
associated with lower repayment performance. Similarly, Giné and others
(2006) find in their laboratory experiment that communication between
group members leads to higher default due to riskier investments.
Existing evidence thus clearly shows that group-based joint-liability
lending can, but does not necessarily, lead to better repayment performance.
Yet recent evidence has also shed doubt on the superiority of group-based
lending vis-à-vis individual lending. In an experiment in the Philippines,
HOUSEHOLD ACCESS TO FINANCE: POVERTY ALLEVIATION AND RISK MITIGATION
some of the borrower groups were randomly converted from group liability
to individual liability. Giné and Karlan (2006) found that conversion to
individual liability groups does not change the repayment rate for preexisting borrowers but does attract more borrowers. Perhaps surprisingly, the
new members have closer links to the other individual liability borrowers,
suggesting that fear of peer pressure might have been limiting growth of
existing joint-liability groups. It could also be that the joint-liability nature
of the program was keeping the good-risk borrowers out of the program.
Ongoing research is trying to distinguish between new microcredit clients
that are randomly assigned to either individual or joint-liability lending.
Some observers have criticized MFIs for making larger loans to individuals, complaining that the MFIs are drifting from their focus on the
poor. Cull, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Morduch (2007) examined data from
124 MFIs in 49 countries and find that both group- and individual-based
lending institutions are able to earn profits while serving the poor, but
a trade-off between profitability and outreach emerges when serving
the very poor.14 Individual-based lenders have the highest average profit
levels but perform less well on measures of outreach.
To summarize, joint-liability lending can help overcome barriers to
reaching poor households and microentrepreneurs and has shown its
usefulness in many different settings, but it also has its limitations. As
members’ borrowing needs diverge over time, conversion to individual
lending might be necessary. Further, diverging borrowing needs might
also destroy screening and monitoring incentives and may create tension
among borrowers, as those borrowing little are still liable for the larger
amounts of their peers. Finally, joint liability can result in collusion and
increased, rather than reduced, risk taking.
Dynamic incentives, such as the promise of repeat lending, have
been another mechanism to overcome moral hazard in lending relationships with risky and high transaction cost borrowers, as shown by
Karlan and Zinman (2006b) in the context of their work with a South
African consumer lender. Similarly, Giné and others (2006) find that
giving borrowers the prospect of repeat loans reduces both the riskiness
of investment and improves repayment performance. The introduction of progressive lending, that is, increasing loan amounts over time,
can further increase the opportunity costs of default for borrowers,
thus reducing loan delinquency (Armendáriz de Aghion and Morduch
2005).15 The interaction of joint liability and repeat lending, however,
can also backfire; if borrowers see the prospect of future loans wane
Overcoming moral hazard
through the promise of
repeat lending—
121
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Box 3.5 Informal finance
INFORMAL FINANCE IS NOT THE SUBJECT OF THIS
report, which deals essentially with formal finance.
To be sure, informal financial services still do represent a significant part of the financial dealings of
poor people, especially but not only in developing
countries, although reliable quantification on this
point is not readily available. An extensive literature
discusses this area (see Rutherford 1998).
The reason for focusing on formal finance is the
underlying premise that formal, modern finance can
potentially provide most of the financial services
needed by poor people with greater efficiency and
security than informal finance (see box 2.2). Formal
finance has not yet superseded informal finance
largely because the current working practices of formal financial intermediaries are not adapted to providing services in small packets at a cost that makes
them affordable to the poor. Technology—financial
and physical—as well as an improved overall infrastructure, can help bring costs down to realistic levels,
but only if the management of formal institutions
chooses to focus on the potential for doing profitable
business with what C. K. Prahalad has termed the
“bottom of the pyramid.” Prahalad’s image conveys
the potential volume of small-scale business, which
can make it attractive even if the setup costs (required
to achieve low unit costs) are high.
At the same time, many features of informal
finance convey lessons that can and have been successfully adopted and adapted by formal and semiformal intermediaries. Scholars have in particular
been fascinated by the durability of rotating savings
and credit associations (ROSCAs), one of the most
striking forms of informal financial intermediary
(see, for example, Ghatak and Guinnane 1999).
Regular payments by each member and assignment
of the collected resources to one member help overcome savings and credit constraints, reduce problems
122
of cash management and storage, and allow members
to realize large investments, be they for consumption or business purposes. The use of social capital
and peer pressure that holds ROSCAs together and
reduces the threat of default by individual members
has important parallels to the use of joint-liability
lending by many MFIs. But ROSCAs cannot hope
to match the scale of resources of the formal financial
system, with its ability to pool risks and intermediate
over extended periods and across geographic areas.
Hawala and other ethnically based international
money transfer businesses have achieved astonishing
efficiencies for payments along certain migration
corridors. Corresponding small payments made
through the banking system’s procedures have generally been more costly and slower, though of course
the banking system’s procedures are scalable and the
network of correspondents is essentially universal, as
are the networks of the major formal international
money transmission companies. Funeral insurance
arrangements are a common product of communitybased informal insurance associations, especially in
AIDS-plagued Africa.
The high cost of credit from informal moneylenders is often cited as a main reason why the
microfinance revolution can bring benefits to the
poor (Robinson 2001). The possibility of providing
alternative formal financial solutions for those who
might otherwise fall into the trap of debt bondage
is for many a sufficient reason to emphasize the
need for improving the reach of the formal financial sector. Yet unregistered (and therefore usually)
illegal moneylenders continue to operate in deprived
neighborhoods of even the richest economies (as is
discussed in chapter 4). The shortcomings of informal finance mean that it will fade in importance
as economies and fi nancial systems mature and
improve in their outreach.
HOUSEHOLD ACCESS TO FINANCE: POVERTY ALLEVIATION AND RISK MITIGATION
as other members fail to repay, their incentives to repay decrease. The
Ecuadorian microlender Childreach is an example: as rumors of its
impending failure spread, the microlender faced a rapid increase in loan
delinquency (Bond and Rai 2002).
Other mechanisms linked to the microcredit movement have not been
thoroughly assessed yet. Specifically, frequent (weekly, for example) and
regular repayments are said to impose discipline on borrowers. On the
one hand, repayment schedules that are too frequent might limit the
investment opportunities of borrowers and are useful only for borrowers
with several diversified income sources. Some observers even claim that
frequent repayment schedules are paid out of savings rather than from
returns on investment (Rutherford 1998). In those cases, providing credit
services is only a second-best solution, and the first-best would be the
provision of savings services for the poor. On the other hand, frequent
repayment might also be a tool of MFIs to use better informed informal
lenders, inasmuch as some borrowers have to rely on these moneylenders
to help them make weekly payments (Jain and Mansuri 2003).
Some other microlending techniques include repayment in public,
forced savings, notional collateral, and targeting of women. Public repayment is said to increase social pressure and the threat of stigma, while
at the same time reducing transaction costs for lenders (Armendáriz de
Aghion and Morduch 2005). The requirement to keep a certain fraction of the credit as savings with the microfinance institution has often
been cited as a success factor, although the practice has not yet been
thoroughly evaluated. The use of assets with “notional” rather than
resale or salvage value, such as refrigerators and televisions, has often
been quoted as increasing the leverage of the lender over the borrower
and augmenting payment discipline. Finally, the targeting of women by
microlenders has been indicated as a factor for commercial success as
well as enhanced social benefit (box 3.6).
Most of the microcredit movement and literature has focused on
production credit for household enterprises or microenterprises. But even
if lack of financing is fundamentally the only constraint for poor microentrepreneurs, as is asserted by Muhamed Yunus, founder of Grameen
Bank and winner of the 2006 Nobel Peace Prize, they do also face
numerous practical challenges. Hence some MFIs have decided to offer
complementary extension services, such as training or health services.
Are they wise to do so? There could be economies of scope in providing
these different services, but there might also be benefits of specialization.
—frequent repayment
schedules—
—and public repayment
Looking beyond microcredit—
123
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Box 3.6 Microfinance and gender
THE MICROCREDIT MOVEMENT HAS FOCUSED
on women, with some programs providing services
exclusively for women and others having a majority
of female borrowers. Why this focus on women?
First, women traditionally face greater access
barriers to formal banking services and are thus
also credit-constrained to a greater extent than men.
In some countries, women are legally barred from
opening accounts or applying for credit. In most of
the developing world, women would not be deemed
creditworthy since they do not hold formal sector
jobs or the titles to their houses. Many restrictions
faced by the poor in the developing world are thus
even more exacerbated for women. As discussed
by Emran, Moshed, and Stiglitz (2006), women
also have lower opportunity costs if they do not
hold formal sector jobs and are thus more likely to
pay the high interest rates required for sustainable
microfinance.
Second, experience has shown that repayment is
higher among female borrowers, mostly due to more
conservative investments and lower moral hazard
risk. The lower moral hazard risk might stem from
lower mobility and higher risk aversion. Given that
moral hazard seems to be the constraining factor in
outreach to low-income households, women might
therefore be the more attractive clients. While
adverse selection might be more problematic among
women, the joint-liability technique can control for
this risk.
Third, some practitioners stress social objectives as women seem to be more concerned about
children’s health and education than their husbands.
As already discussed, Pitt and Khandker (1998) and
Khandker (2003) find a stronger effect of Grameen
Bank in Bangladesh on female than on male borrowers. For example, Khandker (2003) shows that the
impact of credit on nonfood expenditures is higher
among female compared to male borrowers.
Finally, focusing on women might empower
them in the intrafamily decision process, as shown
by Ashraf, Karlan, and Yin (2006b); use of a commitment savings product increased expenditures on
female durable goods. Similarly, access to credit and
the subsequent establishment of a microenterprise
might give women more say in intrahousehold decisions, as Johnson and Morduch (2007) illustrates
with some anecdotes from Bangladesh, Sierra Leone,
and Zambia. Providing access to financial services
for female savers and borrowers might thus directly
contribute to the Millennium Development Goal of
gender equality (box 3.1). For a detailed discussion
of gender and credit, see Armendáriz de Aghion and
Morduch (2005, chapter 7).
Karlan and Valdivia (2006), and Ashraf, Giné and, Karlan (2007) find
that MFIs that offer extension services have higher client retention and
better repayment performance than MFIs that do not offer such services.
Their clients also have better business outcomes.
Even the limited focus on production credit might be mistaken.
Recent analysis of survey data from Indonesia suggests MFI clients use
credit as much for consumption as for investment purposes (Johnston
and Morduch 2007). This finding applies not only to households that
do not run microenterprises but even to a quarter of microentrepreneur
households (figure 3.4). As discussed earlier, consumer credit is also the
124
HOUSEHOLD ACCESS TO FINANCE: POVERTY ALLEVIATION AND RISK MITIGATION
Figure 3.4
Use of microcredit for consumption purposes
50
Percentage
40
30
20
10
0
Loan use by
household
Loan use by
household
enterprise
Below poverty line
Per capita income is 1–3
times the poverty line
Per capita income is more
than 3 times the poverty line
Source: Johnston and Morduch (2007).
Note: This figure shows the percentage of surveyed Bank Rakyat Indonesia customers at different income levels in Indonesia that indicated they used the credit for consumption purposes.
only credit type shown to be robustly linked with higher household welfare (Karlan and Zinman 2006b). This is not a negative outcome, but it
does suggest a very different vision of microfinance from the original.
In addition to the reluctance of traditional lenders to reach out to
low-income households and microentrepreneurs, risk-averse producers
might be reluctant to take up loans. While credit-financed microenterprise might increase the level of income, it might also increase its variation. Indeed, in their survey Johnston and Morduch (2007) find a large
group of households that do not want credit although they are deemed
creditworthy by officials of a microcredit institution.
While research on a randomly chosen sample of entrepreneurs in
Sri Lanka finds credit constraints are the main reason for the lack of
expanding business, not missing insurance markets (de Mel, McKenzie,
and Woodruff 2006), take-up of credit might be increased if coupled
with a proper insurance mechanism. This might be especially true for
agricultural producers who are subject to high price and yield volatility.
—to microinsurance—
125
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Insurance products with or without credit might thus help these farmers expand without taking on too much additional risk. Traditional
insurance to farmers to protect them against climatic and other shocks
has proved costly and unmarketable because of high moral hazard risk
from misreporting. As an alternative, insurers have developed weather
index insurance, which compensates farmers according to objectively
verifiable benchmarks likely to be correlated with the actual damage
the farmer has suffered.
How successful are such insurance schemes? Giné, Townsend, and
Vickery (2007) assess the introduction of a rainfall insurance product,
first designed by a large insurance company in southern India in 2004
and marketed by a microfinance institution. In villages where policies
were sold, the authors find that less than 5 percent of the targeted population buys the insurance product and less than 3 percent of the purchasers
change their production patterns. Why such low uptake of the product?
The most common reason given for not buying the insurance, according to Giné, Townsend, and Vickery (2007), is lack of understanding
of the product. The cost of insurance combined with credit constraints
constitute another powerful factor explaining the lack of take-up. Lack of
trust that the insurer would pay claims promptly or at all if the insurable
event occurs is likely also a factor—not unwarranted given the experience with many financial innovations in low-income environments in
the past. Overall, it seems the insurance product did not reach the most
vulnerable households that would benefit most from it.
In a similar experiment in Malawi, farmers were randomly offered
the choice between a simple credit contract or one that combined
credit with insurance (Giné and Yang 2007). The latter is effectively a
contingent credit contract, that is, a loan that has to be repaid only in
good times. Surprisingly, the take-up of the credit-insurance contract
was significantly lower than the take-up of the credit contract, and
the difference cannot be explained by the cost of including insurance.
Unlike microcredit, microinsurance products are still in their infancy,
so it is too early to draw definite conclusions. But this research shows
the substantial barriers that providers have to overcome to market the
product effectively to the target population.
Rainfall insurance is only one of the microinsurance products that
have been developed over the past years. Life and health insurance policies are increasingly offered by both commercial and nongovernmental
organization (NGO) insurance institutions. For such policies to be viable
126
HOUSEHOLD ACCESS TO FINANCE: POVERTY ALLEVIATION AND RISK MITIGATION
for a commercial insurer, there needs to be a delivery channel with which
potential clients are familiar, such as an MFI or an NGO (as in the two
cases discussed). While a large practitioners’ literature discusses these
different products and delivery mechanisms, rigorous research assessing
their impact is still to be conducted.16
To what extent do poor households really need credit? In the absence
of credit, the poor might simply accumulate savings over time before
investing and thus overcome credit constraints. If they are too poor
to accumulate savings, access to credit can improve their incomes,
although poor households might run the risk of overindebtedness. Dale
Adams and others argue that better savings vehicles, not what they call
“microdebt,” are the financial service most needed by most of the poor:
rotating savings and credit associations (ROSCAs) and microcredit
are thus seen as imperfect tools to address savings constraints (Adams
and von Pischke 1992; Rutherford 1998). This school also argues that
despite popular beliefs to the contrary, the fact that the poor are capable
of weekly repayments shows that the poor are capable of saving, even if
it is only in small amounts (Rutherford 1998).
Why are poor households less likely to save in monetary forms, that
is, through the banking system, than other households? One constraint
is certainly the geographic distance to bank outlets. A large share of
the poor population in many developing countries is still concentrated
in rural areas, and banking systems in developing countries typically
concentrate their branch network in urban areas. That geographic access
can matter for monetary savings is shown by the analysis of a pseudonatural experiment in Mexico. Specifically, Aportela (1999) analyzed
the results of the expansion of a government-owned Mexican savings
institute in the early 1990s. This expansion happened only in some states,
and there seems to be no significant correlation of state characteristics
with the expansion programs. Computing savings rates of low-income
households from survey responses before and after the expansion started,
Aportela shows that the expansion increased the savings rate of lowincome households—the ones targeted by the expansion in the first
place—but had no effect on high-income households. In addition, the
increased financial savings did not seem to crowd out other informal
ways of savings: there was a positive net effect on the overall savings of
the typical household.
The importance of geographic proximity points to local savings
banks and post office networks as important tools for attracting savings
—and microsavings
Geographic distance is an
important barrier to savings
for many households
127
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Commitment devices may
encourage savings
128
by low-income households. In 19th century Germany, municipalities
established local savings banks to do just that. The fact that almost all
adults in most countries in continental western Europe have checking
or savings accounts is often attributed to the dense networks of savings
and cooperative banks. Similarly, postal savings banks have traditionally
played an important role in the rural and more remote areas of many
developed and developing countries, despite their often weak financial
structure and suboptimal service provision.
Lack of geographic access is not the only impediment to saving in monetary form, however. Time inconsistency problems—short-run impatience
(high discount factors in the near future) and long-run patience (low discount factors in the far future)—could explain why many individuals often
regret how little they have saved. Conflicts within households over savings
can also result in undersaving. In developing countries as in developed, a
variety of commitment devices are used to help overcome such problems.
Indeed, some of the practices of the informal ROSCAs can be rationalized
in this way. Microfinance institutions around the world offer a wide variety
of savings commitment devices for their clients (Ashraf, Karlan, and Yin
2003). But do these commitment devices work in increasing savings? Do
they influence intrahousehold decision processes and consumption-savings
patterns? Several recent papers assess these questions.
Ashraf, Karlan, and Yin (2006b, c) assess the effect of a commitment
product where savers commit to forgo their access to savings accounts
until a specific date or until they have reached a precommitted balance.
Specifically, the authors conducted an experiment by randomly giving
half of 1,800 existing or former clients of a rural Philippine bank the
option to save through a commitment savings account (a locked box)
that allowed them access to the funds only after they reached a self-set
date or a self-set amount of savings. Only 28 percent of clients decided to
take up this product, but Ashraf, Karlan, and Yin find an increase of 81
percent in average savings balances of account holders who participated
in the scheme over a 12-month period. This effect was not sustained,
however; after 30 months the average balance was only 33 percent higher
than the average balance of nonparticipants and the difference was no
longer significant; many clients stopped saving with the commitment
product after an initial period. At the same time, this commitment device
led to a shift in the power of decision making by women, which was seen
in higher investment in durable goods associated with women, such as
washing and sewing machines and kitchen appliances.
HOUSEHOLD ACCESS TO FINANCE: POVERTY ALLEVIATION AND RISK MITIGATION
Ashraf, Karlan, and Yin (2006a) assess the effect of another technique
to attract savings, designed to overcome both the problem of geographic
distance and the lack of commitment, namely, door-to-door collection
of savings. Among those who did take up this service, savings increased
by 25 percent over a 15-month period, while borrowing went down; it
is possible that savings, rather than borrowing, were thus used for consumption smoothing. Households accepting this service lived farther
away from the nearest bank branch, thus indicating the importance of
travel costs; and they were more likely to be married, again showing the
importance of intrahousehold conflicts in the savings decision. The fact
that the offer of a convenient savings instrument reduced borrowing is
yet more evidence for those who interpret microcredit take-up as a surrogate solution in the absence of savings opportunities.
Geographic impediments and intrahousehold conflicts are only some
of the barriers poor people face in accessing savings services offered by
financial institutions, as discussed in chapter 1. Continuing research
in Indonesia is exploring other dimensions such as barriers related to
affordability and financial literacy.
While access to financial services, such as credit or savings services,
has received a great deal of attention in recent years, access to payments
services has generated even more attention. Increased globalization has
heightened demand for these services. International remittances, funds
earned by migrants abroad and sent to their families in developing countries, have grown so dramatically in recent years that they have become
the second largest source of external finance for developing countries
after foreign direct investment (figure 3.5).17 Moreover, a large share of
the population in developing countries receives remittances. Relative to
private capital flows, remittance flows tend to be relatively stable and
countercyclical, that is, they increase in times of crisis. Technological
advances have also become important for remittance flows, as the increasing trend to send remittances through ATMs and cell phones shows.
Remittances sent through formal channels are commonly subject to
high costs. These high costs drive many remittance senders to informal
remittance agencies. Furthermore, the costs of sending remittances have
important implications for the amount of remittances sent. Yang (2007)
shows that Philippine migrants sent lower remittances in foreign currency when the Philippine peso depreciated, suggesting that they want
their families to receive a fixed amount in pesos. Gibson, McKenzie,
and Rohorua (2006) show a negative cost elasticity for Tonga of 0.22;
Demand for payments
services has increased
129
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Figure 3.5
Remittance flows across countries
Moldova
Tonga
Guyana
Haiti
Lesotho
Lebanon
Honduras
Tajikistan
Jordan
Armenia
Jamaica
Bosnia and Herzegovina
Serbia and Montenegro
El Salvador
Nepal
Albania
Cape Verde
Philippines
Kyrgyz Republic
Gambia
0
5
10
15
20
25
Proportion of GDP (%)
30
35
Source: World Bank (2005, World Development Indicators).
Note: This figure shows remittance flows through official channels as a proportion of GDP for
20 countries with the largest remittance inflows, based on national balance of payments data.
The high costs of sending
formal remittances—
130
if the cost of sending the remittances were reduced to levels in more
competitive markets around the world, they compute an increase of 28
percent in remittances—an amount that would constitute 4 percent of
Tonga’s GDP.
A lack of bank competition and financial underdevelopment seem to
explain the high costs of formal remittances. The typical remittance fee
is priced as a two-part tariff, consisting of a fixed fee regardless of the
amount sent, and a variable fee arising from the exchange rate commission. As a result, the average fee for sending remittances decreases as the
remittance amount increases, so the small amounts that are typically sent
are subject to high costs. But remittance costs vary significantly across
corridors. The decrease in fees in the U.S.-Mexico corridor, for example,
has been attributed to a higher degree of competition in the remittance
market (Hernandez-Coss 2005). In the Tonga-New Zealand corridor,
where competition is minimal and migrants lack information about
available options, the fees are three times as high as in the U.S.-Mexico
HOUSEHOLD ACCESS TO FINANCE: POVERTY ALLEVIATION AND RISK MITIGATION
corridor (box 3.7). The example of Tonga also illustrates an important
factor explaining high remittance costs: lack of bank penetration not only
reduces competition but also makes remittances more expensive if the
alternative money transfer operators have only indirect access (through
banks) to the payment system.
Tonga provides just one example of how expanded access to modern
technologies can help. Technology can make business processes more
efficient for financial institutions as well as increase access possibilities
for customers. Technological advances can reduce the costs of banking, effectively enabling outreach further down the income pyramid to
customers with demand for smaller transaction amounts.18 For example,
payment systems based on electronic fund transfers rather than checks
can substantially reduce the costs of payment transfers. Cell-phone-based
financial transactions (also referred to as m-banking or m-finance, with
the m standing for mobile phone) have gained prominence in recent years.
There are more cell-phone users in Sub-Saharan Africa than holders
of bank accounts, and the use of cell phones for financial transactions
has increased rapidly in recent years. How far this technology can go
in pushing out the access frontier is still subject to debate, however.
Porteous (2006) finds that use of m-banking services in South Africa is
predominantly concentrated among existing bank customers, with only
a few providers targeting those without accounts.
Technology can also affect customers directly. The introduction
of ATMs has not only increased accessibility of accounts to 24 hours
a day, thus improving convenience, but has also expanded the range
of customers. Financial institutions in several Sub-Saharan African
countries have introduced transaction accounts that are purely ATM
based; customers do not have to enter banking halls, a cultural barrier
for many Africans without bank accounts. Providing financial services
through ATMs is also cheaper for the financial institution. And by
encouraging channeling of payments such as remittances through
the formal banking system, technological advances may broaden the
deposit base of banks, allowing them to intermediate more funds to the
private sector. If the banks can learn over time about their clients and
their creditworthiness, including remittance recipients in the formal
banking system as depositors, at least some of those customers may
become borrowers. Receiving remittances through the formal banking
system thus might enable recipients to gain access to other financial
services as well. Two recent studies show that remittance flows pull new
—can be overcome with
technology
Technology can also expand
the customer base
131
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Box 3.7 Why don’t migrants use the cheapest methods? Evidence from Tongan
migrants in New Zealand
R E M I T TA NC E S A R E E X T R AOR DI N A R I LY
important in Tonga, where they constitute more than
30 percent of GDP and account for 20 percent of
monetary household income (Gibson, McKenzie,
and Rohorua 2006) Despite their importance, the
transaction costs of sending remittances to Tonga
by the most widely used methods are high. Typical
transactions costs average 15–20 percent of the
remittance amount for bank drafts, telegraphic
transfers through banks, transactions through
Western Union, and transactions through Melie mei
Langi, a church-based money transfer operation. In
contrast, transferring money through an ATM card
linked to a New Zealand bank account set up by the
sender costs less than 5 percent, but this method is
not widely used. The cost spread between the more
popular methods and ATMs means a potential loss
for Tonga equivalent to 4 percent of GDP.
What accounts for the underuse of ATMs? Gibson
and others (2006) use a survey among Tongan
immigrants in New Zealand to explore this puzzle.
First, the immigrants seem to lack knowledge: only
2 percent of those surveyed knew how to use an
ATM to send money, and few knew of the hidden
exchange rate premiums that increase the cost of
other methods. Second, distance of recipients from an
ATM in Tonga outside the capital city of Nuku’alofa
limits access to this method. The figure below shows
the coverage areas of ATM machines and Western
Union outlets on the main island of Tongatapu.
Although there are more ATMs than Western Union
outlets, the ATMs are concentrated in Nuku’alofa,
and cover only 77 percent of the population within a
10 kilometer radius, whereas Western Union reaches
97 percent of that population. Finally, three-quarters
of respondents indicated they would not use ATMs
as a method of remitting because they did not trust
them, fearing unauthorized withdrawals and card
skimming among other things.
This analysis suggests several ways for financial
sector policy to improve both the demand for and
supply of newer and cheaper remittance technologies. In particular, more attention needs to be given
to improving the financial literacy of migrants and
customers into the formal banking system. Combining municipalitylevel and household survey data for Mexico, Demirgüç-Kunt and others
(2007) find a positive relationship between the share of households in
a municipality that receives remittances and total deposits to GDP,
deposit accounts per capita, and branches per capita, but no significant
relationship with total credit to GDP. Using household survey data for
El Salvador, Demirgüç-Kunt and Martinez Peria (2007) find evidence
that channeling remittances through the banking system increases
banking outreach; the likelihood that the recipient has a bank account
is twice as high if the remittances are received through the banking
system than if they are received through informal channels, although
there is no effect on the credit side.19
132
HOUSEHOLD ACCESS TO FINANCE: POVERTY ALLEVIATION AND RISK MITIGATION
Box 3.7 (continued)
providing them with clear and accurate information about the alternatives available for remitting.
Community newspapers and associations could play
an important role in disseminating this information.
Second, expansion of access to modern technologies in the remittance-receiving country is needed
to match the convenience and service offered by
traditional money transfer operators.
Service areas of ATMs and Western Union on Tongatapu, Tonga
Nuku’alofa
ATMs
Village centers
2km service area
5km service area
10km service area
Nuku’alofa
airport
N
0
Western Unions
Village centers
2km service area
5km service area
10km service area
airport
Kilometers
5
10
Source: Gibson and others (2006).
Reaching Out to the Poor or to the Excluded?
Thirty years after the establishment of Grameen Bank, the microfinance
movement has attained a certain maturity. Microfinance increases
access to financial services for those participating in the program, and,
because of lower staff salaries and lack of posh banking halls, it does so
at lower operating costs than commercial banks can. Nonetheless, most
microfinance programs still incur high unit costs because of the small
size of loans. As a result, a large proportion of the institutions—albeit
mostly the smaller ones—are dependent on subsidies (Robinson 2001;
Armendáriz de Aghion and Morduch 2005), and there is a continuing
discussion about the financial sustainability of microcredit, regarding
both its feasibility and desirability. Cull, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Morduch
Many microfinance institutions
require subsidies—
133
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
—raising questions
about sustainability
(2007) looked at a sample of 124 MFIs in 49 countries representing
around 50 percent of all microfinance clients around the globe, most
likely, the more profitable and cost-efficient institutions. The authors
find that even in this select group, only half of the institutions were
profitable and financially self-sustainable, generating sufficient revenue
to cover their costs (figure 3.6).
One of the reasons for this lack of self-sustainability might be the lack
of scale; only in eight countries do microfinance borrowers account for
more than 2 percent of the population (Honohan 2004, figure 3.7), and
most individual MFIs seem to be too small to reap the necessary scale
economies to become financially sustainable (figure 3.8). At the same
time, as MFIs grow and mature, they seem to focus less on the poor (Cull,
Demirgüç-Kunt, and Morduch 2007), which could be interpreted either
as a success story for their borrowers or as mission drift.
Microfinance also suffers from another important limitation: for many
MFIs, scaling up to nonpoor customers will be difficult, as will be the
ability of MFIs to accompany their customers as they grow richer. Jointliability lending relies on groups of borrowers with similar borrowing
needs, and the profitability of the approach relies on large numbers of
Figure 3.6
Financial self-sufficiency and subsidy dependence
2.5
Financial self-sufficiency
2.0
1.5
MFIs in the top quartile of subsidy
dependence
1.0
0.5
0.0
Source: Cull, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Morduch (2007).
Note: This figure shows the financial self-sustainability (ability to generate sufficient revenue
to cover costs) of 124 MFIs across 49 countries, with the blue bars indicating MFIs in the top
25th percentiles in subsidy dependence (given by share of subsidies as a proportion of total
liabilities plus equity).
134
HOUSEHOLD ACCESS TO FINANCE: POVERTY ALLEVIATION AND RISK MITIGATION
Microfinance penetration across countries
Figure 3.7
Ethiopia
Bolivia
India
Nicaragua
El Salvador
Honduras
Niger
Mali
Nepal
Senegal
Benin
Gambia
Togo
Malawi
Cambodia
Vietnam
Sri Lanka
Thailand
Indonesia
Bangladesh
0
2
4
6
8
10
% of population borrowing from MFIs
12
14
Source: Honohan (2004).
Note: This figure shows the ratio of borrowing clients to total population for the 20 countries
with the highest microfinance penetration.
Figure 3.8
Distribution of MFIs by size of outreach
Remaining 3,000
Next 100
Next 10
Top 10
Source: Updated from Honohan (2004).
Note: This figure shows that the top 10 MFIs reporting to the Microcredit Summit (DaleyHarris, 2006) accounted for 66 percent of the total number of MFI customers in the world. At the
other extreme, nearly 3,000 of the 3,133 reporting MFIs had fewer than 15,000 clients each.
135
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
MFIs often are unable to
meet the needs of the
excluded nonpoor
A narrow focus on the poor
may be counterproductive—
136
borrowers and groups. The higher borrowers are on the income ladder
and the larger the size of the enterprise, however, the more divergent are
borrower characteristics and borrowing needs. Not surprisingly, loans
made by individual-based microlending institutions are larger on average than loans made by MFIs using joint-liability lending. Furthermore,
larger average loan sizes also imply lower costs (Cull, Demirgüç-Kunt,
and Morduch 2007).
MFIs in most cases do not have sufficient resources to fulfill the borrowing needs of larger microenterprises. And microenterprises might
no longer be willing and able to pay the higher MFI interest rates as
they expand. MFIs are constrained by the lack of savings mobilization
and their reliance on donor resources. Especially in developing countries, only the formal banking system has sufficient resources to fulfill
the borrowing needs of their economies’ private sectors. The obvious
solution—linking the microcredit sector with the banking sector—has
therefore become an increasingly popular solution. In several countries,
such as Bolivia and Uganda, MFIs have been given the opportunity to
convert into microbanks and collect deposits from the general public.
Some of the leading microfinance institutions have received equity funding from institutional investors, and links between banks and MFIs in
numerous countries have provided MFIs with the necessary funding
from banks, while maintaining their business and credit model to target
low-income clients.20
Many MFIs, even with subsidies, have had trouble reaching the very
poor. And, as mentioned, some MFIs have been moving upscale with
their successful clients. Should policymakers worry about an apparent
drift in the emphasis of many MFIs, and of the MFI industry as a whole,
away from focusing on credit access for the very poor? Considering
the indications that improving access for not-so-poor entrepreneurial
households can have powerfully favorable indirect implications for the
poor, such worries may be overstated.
Focusing on finance for the very poor shifts the attention to subsidies
and charity, which can hurt the quality of services. There are also good
political economy reasons why the focus should not be on the poor or on
how microfinance can be made more viable, but instead on how financial
services can be made available for all.21 The poor lack the political clout
to demand better services, and subsidies may spoil the credit culture,
that is, the willingness to repay loans since they are perceived as grants.
Defining the issue more broadly to include the middle class, who often
HOUSEHOLD ACCESS TO FINANCE: POVERTY ALLEVIATION AND RISK MITIGATION
also lack access, would make it more likely that policy makers would
make financial access a priority. Hence shifting the focus to building
inclusive financial systems and improving access for all underserved
groups is likely to have greater impact on development outcomes.
As a result, the development community has shifted its attention to
building inclusive financial systems focusing not only on specialized
microcredit institutions, but on an array of other financial institutions,
such as postal savings banks, consumer credit institutions, and, most
important, the banking system. This broader approach can lead to overall
financial system efficiency and outreach to the whole population.
The recent expansion in banking services across Latin America, for
example, has been driven by consumer credit, provided mostly by utility and other nonfinancial companies, such as large department stores.
Although no firm data exist, anecdotal evidence suggests that this credit
expansion is based on credit scoring and risk diversification through the
law of large numbers. Postal networks have come to play an increasingly
important role, such as in Brazil, where the postal service linked with a
private commercial bank through an agency agreement, thus effectively
increasing geographic access to banking services to all municipalities.
Private commercial banks have taken the lead in reaching out to lowincome households and microenterprises with new techniques and products, often driven by a combination of profit and social objectives.
The broader focus on an inclusive financial system raises again the
question of how to ensure that financial institutions will expand outreach.
How can governments and donors best help reduce transaction costs
and risk that often impede commercially oriented financial institutions
from reaching out to the poor and near poor? Should donors subsidize
microfinance institutions so they can reach out to the very poor? Should
the government subsidize financial institutions so they reach out to rural
and remote areas? Several ideas and questions arise in this context.22
First, subsidies in the financial sector have to be assessed in a rigorous manner to compare costs and benefits with subsidies in other areas,
such as education or infrastructure. Any subsidy has the opportunity
costs of forgone government intervention in other sectors and areas.
Second, a distinction has to be made between credit services, on the
one hand, and savings and payments services, on the other hand. More
of a case might be made for subsidies in payment services, because such
services are considered necessary for participation in a modern market
economy. Further, payment services can be seen as a network good whose
—highlighting the need
to foster the development
of a range of financial
institutions—
—and carefully assess
whether subsidies could
more effectively be used in
other areas
137
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
benefits increase as a larger proportion of the population has access to
and uses them (Claessens and others 2003). Third, subsidies should
focus on overcoming the barriers to access rather than distorting prices,
such as interest rates. Finally, technological advances have the potential
to revolutionize access for the poor, shifting attention from subsidies to
establishing an environment conducive to technological innovations that
may help overcome many of the restrictions. However, these technological
advances, such as m-finance, also pose important regulatory questions.
To what extent should electronic and m-finance providers be considered
financial institutions and thus be subject to the heavier regulatory and
supervisory framework? This issue is discussed further in chapter 4.
The simple point is that access to finance is lacking not only for
the poor but for vast portions of the population in many low-income
economies. If attempts to ensure that the poor do get credit result in
distorting subsidies that damage the incentives for the microfinance
industry, and the financial sector more generally, to innovate in providing access for the nonpoor, then their net effect on the poor could be
counterproductive.
Conclusions
The direct provision of credit
to the poor may not be the
most important channel
More than just the poor face
financial exclusion
138
While still far from conclusive, the bulk of the evidence suggests financial
development and improved access to finance is likely not only to accelerate economic growth but also to reduce income inequality and poverty.
The channels through which finance works to produce this impact are
less clear, but the evidence from cross-country research, natural experiments, and general equilibrium models suggests that direct provision
of credit to the poor may not be the most important channel. Hence
fostering more efficient capital allocation through competitive and open
markets has always been and still remains an important policy goal.
In most countries around the world, however, fewer than half the
households have even basic financial access; many nonpoor and small and
medium enterprises are effectively excluded from the financial system.
For the most part, then, improving efficiency without broadening access
is likely to be insufficient because it is likely to leave untapped the talents
and innovative capacity of large segments of the population. Improving
access for all of the excluded, not just the very poor, is therefore also likely
to be an important policy goal for most developing countries.
HOUSEHOLD ACCESS TO FINANCE: POVERTY ALLEVIATION AND RISK MITIGATION
Reaching out to low-income households and microentrepreneurs is
quite challenging however, since issues of risk management, monitoring, and transaction costs tend to increase break-even interest rates and
often lead to credit rationing. Here, innovative techniques and products
developed by MFIs have helped overcome these information barriers.
Nevertheless, microfinance services are costly to deliver, and they typically require extensive subsidies. While a focus on improving access to
the excluded does not need to involve subsidies, reaching out to the
very poor does. Should such access be subsidized? Encouraging and
taking advantage of technological advances, which are becoming more
widespread and fast-paced due to globalization, may be more promising
in broadening access for the poor than providing subsidies, as well as
shifting the focus of policy to establishing an environment conducive to
the adaptation of the new technologies and to the entry of providers that
bring them in. These issues are discussed more fully in the next chapter,
which concerns governments’ role in broadening access.
Innovative techniques
and products can improve
financial access
Notes
1. Introducing fi xed transaction costs into a general equilibrium model and
thus endogenizing the size of the intermediated sector, Townsend and Ueda
(2006) conclude that restrictive financial sector policies in Thailand might have
slowed the growth of financial intermediation below the endogenous growth
rate that would have resulted from increasing per capita income, as predicted
by Greenwood and Jovanovic (1990).
2. General equilibrium models have limited power to mimic the real world,
as shown by Jeong and Townsend (2003). They compare the fit of the two
models with exogenous and endogenous financial intermediation, the two
models later used by Giné and Townsend (2004) and Townsend and Ueda
(2006), respectively, and find that while both models fit the data well, they
both exaggerate the movement between low- and high-income groups and
underestimate the movements within different income groups. While general
equilibrium models fit the long-term trends in the data reasonably well, Jeong
and Townsend conclude that they cannot account for business cycle effects.
3. Reanalyzing the same data with a different econometric technique,
Morduch (1998) failed to find any significant impact of microcredit on borrowers’ income, though he did find an effect on consumption smoothing.
4. This technique was later named “pipeline matching” (Goldberg and
Karlan 2005)
139
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
5. It is worth noting that such a design picks up the effect of credit for the
marginal borrower. Assuming heterogeneity across agents, the effect might be
lower or zero for those borrowers who easily got credit, since they may have
plenty of close substitutes, while the effect could be even bigger for those who
were denied credit by a bigger margin.
6. In particular, it is not only the sceptics who find much of the less rigorous
literature unconvincing. Coleman (1999) notes: “Most existing impact studies
are nonacademic project evaluations that are of a descriptive nature or suffer
from the selection bias problem.” In a useful survey of microfinance impact
studies confined to those that tried “to select control groups whose observed
characteristics were comparable except for their participation in microfinance,”
Littlefield, Morduch, and Hashemi (2003, p. 2) conclude that while “the general
pattern of results sheds valid light on the question of impact, . . . few studies
include fully rigorous controls for selection biases.” Armendáriz de Aghion and
Morduch (2005, p. 199–200) write that the differences between anecdotes
and statistical evidence “should not be surprising: the anecdotes are culled to
show the potential of microfinance, while the statistical analyses are designed
to show typical impact across the board.”
7. For evidence on the relation between durable-asset holding, education, and
child labor, see Jacoby (1994); Guarcello, Mealli, and Rosati (2003); Jacoby and
Skoufias (1997); and Beegle, Dehejia, and Gatti (2007). Several cross-country
studies also assess the relationship between financial development, education,
and incidence of child labor; see Flug, Spilimbergo, and Wachtenheim (1998)
and Beegle, Dehejia, and Gatti (2007). For evidence on access to credit and
upward mobility, see Wydick (1999). For evidence on geographic proximity to
bank branches and health, see Gertler, Levine, and Moretti (2003).
8. For a detailed discussion, see Ravallion (2004).
9. Cross-country regressions using other poverty-related measures also
point to a favorable impact. For example, Claessens and Feijen (2007) find a
significant impact of financial sector development on the incidence of undernourishment. One of the channels through which this relationship works seems
to be financial development enhancing the level and growth rate of agricultural
productivity, which in turn leads to higher output and lower prices, which helps
reduce the incidence of undernourishment. However, as is the case with many
cross-country studies, identification issues remain.
10. The distribution data are notoriously difficult to compare across countries for several reasons, including the fact that they are based on different
welfare measures (consumption versus income), different measures of income
(gross versus net), and different units of observation (households versus individuals), and adjustments for these differences are imperfect (Dollar and Kraay
2002; Deaton 2005). While these differences in measurement introduce an
error into the regressions run by Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Levine (2007),
this error should bias their estimations against finding a significant relationship
140
HOUSEHOLD ACCESS TO FINANCE: POVERTY ALLEVIATION AND RISK MITIGATION
between finance and changes in income distribution. Further, the regressions
of changes in headcount on finance are less subject to this concern as the
headcount measures are based on a set of consistent household surveys (Chen
and Ravallion 2004).
11. Using Thai data and testing a structural model with moral hazard
and limited liability due to high enforcement costs, Paulson, Townsend, and
Karaivanov (2006) confirm that moral hazard is the dominant source of financing constraints. In the case of poorer households, however, they cannot reject
the hypothesis that limited liability also plays a role. Giné (2005) distinguishes
between transaction costs incurred by borrowers and enforcement costs incurred
by lenders and shows that enforcement costs limit outreach more than transaction costs do in the context of rural finance in Thailand.
12. To tease out the trade-off in group-based lending in comparison with
individual lending, Giné and others (2006) created an experimental economics
laboratory in a large, urban market in Lima, Peru, and conducted difference
games with microentrepreneurs and potential microfinance clients.
13. Undertaking experimental games with a group of microfinance clients
in Peru, Karlan (2005) finds that cultural similarity and geographic proximity
predict trust and trustworthiness.
14. This could also reflect that a disproportionate number of those MFIs
that concentrate on the very poor are charitable concerns willing to channel
subsidies to the poor rather than aiming at profitability.
15. However, because of imperfections in the labor market, the poor women
borrowers in the model of Emran, Morshed, and Stiglitz (2006) will not be
interested in expanding their operation beyond a certain scale.
16. See Roth, McCord, and Liber (2007) for an overview of microinsurance
products and delivery mechanisms.
17. Official data on remittance flows—mostly from balance-of-payment
statistics—underestimate their true extent because a large proportion of
remittances is sent through informal channels. In addition, in many cases,
remittances sent through money transfer providers that do not settle through
banks are not recorded in official data either (de Luna Martinez 2005). A
large share of remittances is thus misclassified as net errors and omission in
balance-of-payment statistics. Using cost data on sending remittances through
formal channels and assuming that use of these channels, but not the amount
of remittances, is elastic to the cost of sending the remittances. Freund and
Spatafora (2005) estimate that informal remittance flows equal 35–75 percent
of formal remittance flows.
18. See Firpo (2005) for a discussion on the role of technology in reducing
costs in microfinance.
141
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
19. Recent research also shows that remittance flows can affect financial
development in the recipient countries, increasing access indirectly. For
example, Aggarwal, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Martinez Peria (2006) find that
formal remittance flows, as captured by balance-of-payments statistics, have a
positive impact on financial intermediary development.
20. Microfinance institutions face another challenge as the industry
matures—competition. During the initial stages of microfinance, most institutions compete only against informal moneylenders; their monopoly position
allows them to use dynamic incentives such as repeat and progressive lending,
as borrowers do not have any alternatives. However, as MFI sectors mature, as
in Bangladesh, Bolivia, and Uganda, MFIs start competing directly against
each other in certain regions of the country, with negative implications for
borrowers, who may become overindebted and receive less favorable loan terms,
but also for lenders who encounter worse repayment performance. Effective
information sharing among lenders is one way of overcoming these difficulties.
For example, in the already-discussed Guatemalan case, Luoto, McIntosh, and
Wydick (2007) calculated that the introduction of a credit information system
allowed MFIs to improve their loan appraisal to the extent of lowering their
break-even interest rate by more than 2.5 percentage points.
21. Rajan (2006b) argues “let’s not kill the microfinance movement with
kindness. If we want it to become more than a fad . . . it has to follow the clear
and unsentimental path of adding value and making money. On that path lies
the possibility of a true and large-scale escape from poverty.”
22. See also the discussion in Armendáriz de Aghion and Morduch (2005,
chapter 9), focusing on subsidies for MFIs.
142
CHAPTER FOUR
Government’s Role
in Facilitating Access
GIVEN THE EVIDENCE THAT FINANCIAL ACCESS VARIES WIDELY
around the world, and that expanding access remains an important
challenge even in advanced economies, it is clear that there is much
for policy to do. It is not enough to say that the market will provide.
Market failures related to information gaps, the need for coordination
on collective action, and concentrations of power mean that governments everywhere have an extensive role in supporting, regulating, and
sometimes directly intervening in the provision of financial services.
Not all government action is equally effective, however, and some
policies can be counterproductive. Complex system responses can make
well-intentioned policies misfire, so successful policy design must be
context specific. Governance issues are important: policy success can
depend on institutional quality. Measures that are effective in environments that already enjoy strong institutions may fail elsewhere. At the
same time, a well-functioning financial system itself is likely to contribute
to strengthening national governance.
Previous chapters have already mentioned some individual policy
issues. This chapter takes a broad view of the role of policy in improving
access. It draws as much as possible on findings from formal quantitative
research to throw light on a few of the more difficult choices that arise.
Implementation of policy requires complementing the results of research
analysis with practitioner experience, which this study does not attempt
to summarize. Nontheless, the analysis presented in this chapter provides
a base for sound policy advice. The treatment is necessarily selective but
illustrates how other issues can be approached.
Government action is
necessary to correct market
failures, but some policies
can be ineffective or
counterproductive
143
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Policies to improve financial
access and financial
development are not always
the same
It is important to set
realistic goals
144
Many of the policies often recommended to enhance overall development of the financial sector—including the legal and information
underpinnings needed to lower the cost of services for large enterprises,
governmental entities, and wealthy individuals, and to improve the innovative capacity of the financial sector—will also help increase access to
those now excluded from, or poorly served by, the financial sector. That
reduces the number of difficult trade-offs that have to be made. But the
overlap and alignment of the goals are not perfect. A policy reform package for the financial sector that does not explicitly prioritize access will
tend to make different choices from one that does. For example, certain
regulatory prudential measures aimed at financial stability can restrict
the degree to which banks can serve small borrowers. Concentrating
institution-building efforts on developing an offshore financial center
to export efficient wholesale financial services could result in the neglect
of the infrastructures needed to help onshore financial intermediaries
reach small, local producers. A reform approach to financial sector policy
that explicitly recognizes the importance of access can help ensure that
financial development also makes financial systems more inclusive.
In prioritizing access policy, it is important to recognize the limitations of even a very efficient financial system supported by a strong
contractual and information infrastructure. Not all would-be borrowers
are creditworthy, and there are numerous examples of overly relaxed
credit policies that have reduced national welfare. Indeed, prudential
regulation of banks in developing countries is largely concerned with
ensuring that loss-making credit decisions are, on average, avoided. It is
also important not to undermine market discipline by adopting rules or
regulations (such as mispriced deposit insurance) that may distort the
risk-taking or monitoring incentives of market participants. Access to
other formal financial services can approach universality as economies
develop—indeed the presumption that everyone should be entitled to
some form of account at a financial intermediary has gained ground
in advanced economies and is essentially a reality in several European
countries. The fixed costs of service provision, however, have made it
very difficult for traditional financial service providers to reach customers whose need is only for tiny payment and savings transactions or who
are located in small and remote markets. Over time, technological and
organizational innovations should begin to overcome these barriers,
and entry and other regulatory policies should be designed so that such
innovation is not inadvertently blocked. More generally, the challenge
GOVERNMENT’S ROLE IN FACILITATING ACCESS
for policy is to help build the necessary infrastructures and to ensure that
the financial system is one in which service providers are delivering as
widely as is possible, given existing infrastructures, and are not hampered
by inappropriate regulatory or other policies or by coordination failures
(Beck and de la Torre 2007).
This chapter begins by discussing some overall market development
issues concerning general measures for improving the contractual, information, and other infrastructures needed to support an effective financial
system with good outreach. It highlights recent findings that address
the question of which institutional reforms should be prioritized. For
example, in low-income countries, improving information infrastructures
seems to yield more immediate access benefits than undertaking legal
reforms. But legal reforms are also important, and among those, there
is evidence that other aspects of contract enforcement may be more
important for access than protection of property rights against the state.
It also notes that intermediaries can be helped to work around hard-toremedy institutional deficiencies.
The chapter then turns to specific enabling policy actions to boost
the capacity of market intermediaries to deliver financial access. It
reviews the many supportive measures that need to be addressed.
These range from specific legislation to underpin payments technologies that use the Internet and mobile phones, to ensuring that
anti-money-laundering regulations do not choke household access, to
securities markets regulation that is not so costly as to prevent listings
by medium-size firms.
The chapter then moves to a discussion of regulatory structure. Much
of the needed regulatory structure for finance is designed to improve
competition and efficiency while restraining excesses, including imprudent or exploitative behavior. The chapter focuses in particular on the
potential for positive policy action to mandate access-enhancing product
development, contrasting this with the usually counterproductive effect
of unrealistic usury ceilings. It also describes recent evidence showing
that market discipline can complement official prudential regulation but
needs an appropriate policy environment to be effective.
Next the chapter addresses the controversial question of whether government should enter directly into the access business through ownership
or subsidy of financial service providers. Here it looks in some detail at
state-sponsored credit guarantee schemes (showing how some of these
appear to be as costly as many old-fashioned state-lending programs,
This chapter starts with an
examination of institutions
and infrastructure—
—and then turns to
intermediaries—
—and the tricky issues of
government ownership—
145
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
—and political economy
with little clear benefit, while potential improvements in scheme design
have often been ignored).
Before concluding, the chapter turns to the links between politics
and access. Financial sector reform delivering outreach is not politically
unproblematic. Elites in closed-access societies may lose in the short run
by policies that open access to finance and thereby to wider economic
opportunities.
Expanding Access: Importance of Long-Term
Institution Building
Macroeconomic stability
can foster financial sector
development—
—as can a positive business
environment—
—supported by well
functioning institutions
146
There is little disagreement that the ability of financial service providers to reach a broad clientele is highly dependent on macroeconomic
environment and on the overall state of the contractual and information
infrastructure.
Theoretical and empirical research has confirmed that macroeconomic
instability is an important obstacle to effective intertemporal contracting.1 Fiscal imbalances in particular generate high and variable inflation,
often making the future value of money so uncertain (and difficult
to hedge) for both suppliers and demanders that long-term financial
contracts simply do not exist. Households will not give up control over
their savings for longer time-periods in unstable macroeconomic environments, and financial institutions will not commit beyond short-term
contracts given funding uncertainties. Unsustainable macroeconomic
and fiscal policies have often been the prelude to financial instability and
crises; the fear of macroeconomic and financial instability also inhibits
financial innovation that can promote access. In addition, the scale of
borrowing by free-spending governments tends to crowd out other borrowers, including (perhaps especially) small firms.
There is thus clear scope for positive government action in the areas of
macroeconomic stability and general institution building that supports
greater financial access. Policies not specifically addressed to financial
sector needs but designed to improve the general business environment
(communication, transportation, and energy infrastructure) in which
financial institutions operate, as well as the general security situation,
are also of evident importance.
The emphasis in recent literature on the importance of institutions—
the “rules of the game”—for economic development, and on the parallel
GOVERNMENT’S ROLE IN FACILITATING ACCESS
role these institutions are thought to play in financial development,
suggests that the mechanisms of finance are at the heart of the complex
processes that lead to accelerated economic growth in a way that is still
far from being fully understood (Beinhocker 2006). As such, adjusting
institutions in directions that clearly help improve the functioning of
finance is likely to be a highly effective pro-growth strategy. Even if
the claims that finance plays the chief causal role in economic growth
were to be proved false, and instead all of the causality came from the
underlying institutional framework, emphasis on ensuring financial
performance is likely to select growth-effective institutions.
Building these institutions is typically a long-term and diffuse
endeavor, and it necessarily involves a key role for government.
Government is the natural—in many cases the only—provider of some
of the key organizations that support good institutions, such as efficient,
speedy, and fair courts. Government may also need to provide some or
all of the needed registries of credit information, liens, and property
ownership. Legislation that defines the rights and responsibilities of
companies, financial entities, and other financial market participants,
avoiding uncertainty or ambiguity in contracts, is also a valuable part of
the financial infrastructure provided by government. First and foremost,
then, governments can broaden access by making and encouraging
infrastructure improvements needed for market development.2
For the policy maker, or the adviser on policy matters, the range of
institutional reforms demanded can seem overwhelming, as can the
difficulty of implementing even a subset of them. What then are the
priorities and how best can the obstacles to implementation be overcome? These are questions to which researchers are only beginning to
find solutions.
This is not the place for a handbook of good practice in institution
building. For one thing, much of what is held to be good practice in this
regard still amounts to a transplant of models that have been successful
in advanced economies and otherwise lacks systematic evidential foundations from across the world.3 Yet, there are some interesting lessons from
recent research findings that speak to the priorities and likely successes
in institutional reform.
The first wave of cross-country empirical literature on law and finance
(La Porta and others 1997, 1998) established the strong role of institutions in boosting financial market depth and economic growth, including
financial access.4 To take one dimension of this, although most will agree
Institution building requires a
long-term commitment
Evidence that legal institutions
matter
147
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
The risk of expropriation can
be a major threat to financial
sector development
148
that enforcement of investor and creditor rights is important for access,
there has been less agreement on the nature of the legal systems that are
best adapted to financial development. As with financial depth and other
aggregate measures of financial development, there appear to be fewer
barriers to financial access in countries with a common law legal tradition
than in those whose legal origins spring from civil codes.5 But perhaps it
is not so much legal origin per se, but rather a degree of adaptability in
legal institutions that is essential to ensure that contract enforcement can
keep pace with changing financial technologies. In analyzing the World
Business Environment Survey data, Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Levine
(2005) also use measures of judicial independence and adaptability to
look more closely at whether the style of law in effect has an impact on
access as reported in these surveys. Their regressions suggest that firms
in civil code countries face larger obstacles to accessing external finance
than do firms in common law countries, especially in the dimensions
of collateral requirements, long-term loans, and paperwork and bureaucracy. Based on the performance of the other legal variables in the study,
the authors suggest that these obstacles are more likely to result from the
lack of adaptability in many civil code legal systems rather than from a
lack of judicial independence from political pressures.6
Arguably the most important institutions to put into place to achieve
economic growth are those that reliably constrain the state from compromising private property rights. North, Wallis, and Weingast (2006)
argue persuasively—in their ambitious, albeit not fully elaborated or
proved, thesis—that the most fundamental distinction between types
of organized societies is that between open access societies and those
that limit access to economic resources. The course of history suggests
that the former have proved to be far and away the more successful,
especially in recent times. According to the authors, social order in an
open access society is maintained by competition, not rent creation, and
competition requires a political system that does not depend on creating
and capturing rents for a limited elite.
This proposition finds some confirmation in econometric analysis of
the cross-country data that is available on various aspects of national
institutions relevant to financial sector performance. In particular,
Acemoglu and Johnson (2005) have looked carefully at the different
types of institutional variables found in cross-country studies to influence
financial sector development and economic growth. They distinguish
between those legal and political institutions that mainly underpin the
GOVERNMENT’S ROLE IN FACILITATING ACCESS
security of contracting between economic agents on the one hand and
those that ensure the security of private property rights vis-à-vis the
state on the other. Security of contracting includes measures of legal
complexity and formalism in debt recovery; security of property rights
includes measures of the constitutional constraints on the political
executive and the degree of protection against risk of expropriation. All
of these variables are strongly correlated with financial development and
economic growth (and with each other).
To eliminate the likely feedback or reverse causality from growth to
institutional performance, Acemoglu and Johnson employ as instruments not only legal origin, but also the mortality of colonial settlers,7
with the interesting twist that legal origin proves to be a predictor only
of the contracting institutions and settler mortality to be a predictor of
the institutions related to private property rights. Indeed, they show that
legal origin is also strongly correlated with enterprise survey responses
on the quality of the courts and the functioning of the judicial system,
but not with survey responses on official corruption and predictability
of regulation, whereas exactly the opposite is true of settler mortality.
Using these instruments, it is the private property rights institutions,
rather than the contracting institutions, that prove to be most strongly
associated with banking depth and GDP per capita.8
If the econometric findings of Acemoglu and Johnson are to be taken
at face value, they have some clear implications: a “grabbing state” is
a major threat to financial sector development (and thus to economic
growth); without institutions that restrain the state from preying on
private property, the financial route to economic prosperity is severely
constrained.
A conjectural synthesis of these results with those of Beck, DemirgüçKunt, and Levine (2005) on judicial adaptability would say that protection of private property against the state is key for the depth of financial
sector development, but that more specific protections of contracts
between private agents are important for determining access.9
The nature of the 19th century European colonial engagement is of
course not the only determinant of modern institutions in countries that
were formerly colonized, but the long-lasting influence of that engagement has far-reaching implications for the needed institutional reforms
along this dimension. Whether a country has been a settler colony
(with the settlers ensuring that they would be relatively free of arbitrary
exactions by the state) or an extractive colony (seen by the colonizing
A potentially difficult
transition to open societies
149
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
What should the institutional
priorities be?
Information infrastructure
appears to be especially
important for poorer countries
150
country as merely a source of rent through primary production) seems
to have had an enduring effect. As North, Wallis, and Weingast (2006)
have stressed, only a few countries have successfully made the transition
from a rent-creating, limited-access society to an open society where
private property accumulation is relatively secure against expropriation
by government. And researchers are a long way from understanding how,
when, and why countries are transformed from closed to open access.
Yet this transformation is what is called for.
Pending success in reforming these most important—but intractable—institutions, it may be easier, and less politically contentious, to
make progress on other dimensions. For example, within the category
of legal institutions that support private contracting, Haselmann, Pistor,
and Vig (2006) have distinguished between those that chiefly enable the
individual lender to recover on a debt (for example, institutions relating
to collateral) and those that are mainly concerned with resolving conflicts
between different claimants (for example, bankruptcy codes). Basing
their analysis on evidence from the transition economies of Central and
Eastern Europe—which adopted relevant legal reforms at different times
after the collapse of the planned economy system—these authors are
able to show that bank lending is more sensitive to the institutions that
govern individual claims than to those that resolve conflicts between
multiple claimants.10 Given the relative complexity of bankruptcy codes
compared with laws and procedures related to collateral, this finding—
which matches practitioner experience—is good news for governments
overwhelmed with institutional reform challenges.11
While it is well accepted that, in addition to legal infrastructures,
information infrastructures are also key for both financial depth and
access, it is not so clear which of the two classes of infrastructure matter
most for developing countries.
A recent contribution by Djankov, McLiesh, and Shleifer (2007) in this
area has uncovered systematic differences in the relative importance of
these two dimensions of financial infrastructure to the growth of private
credit. Based on a panel of aggregate data for 129 countries over 25 years,
they confirm that creditor rights and the existence of credit registries,
whether public or private, are both associated with a higher ratio of private
credit depth to GDP, whether measured in levels or in terms of change.
Interestingly, creditor rights (especially strong in countries that inherited
the common law system) prove to be particularly important for private
credit in the richer countries, whereas the information infrastructure (in
GOVERNMENT’S ROLE IN FACILITATING ACCESS
the form of credit registries) seems to matter more in the poorer countries.
Given that it is arguably easier to build credit registries and other elements
of the credit information infrastructure in low-income countries than to
make lasting improvements in the enforcement of creditor rights, this is
a finding of considerable importance and practical value.
The private sector does, of course, have a number of ways of working
around dysfunctional institutions. De la Torre and Schmukler (2004)
discuss how U.S. dollar contracts (rather than local currency contracts),
short maturities with rollover clauses, and contracting under foreign
jurisdiction are mechanisms that cope with systemic risk arising from
institutional deficiencies in developing countries. Using a remarkably
detailed data set on the interest rate, collateral, and maturity of some
60,000 large bank loans in 21 countries, Qian and Strahan (2007) show
how banks adapt to an environment of official corruption and defective property rights by shortening maturities and increasing collateral
(thereby facilitating timely action to intervene and recover on debts that
begin to look doubtful). These findings reinforce the point that even if
protection of property rights is the key institution to get right, the collateral regime does act as a kind of substitute. If so, an improvement in
the security of contracts can help the financial system work around the
other deficiencies. Qian and Strahan note two other interesting points.
Where the procedural costs of enforcing collateral are high, local banks
hold a higher share of lending to unrated firms (including SMEs); foreign
banks, which have to rely more on collateral, stay away. In addition, only
the interest rate on secured loans to rated firms varies with the cost of
enforcement—lenders have little intention of pursuing their claims on
unrated firms through the courts.
Differences in the efficiency of legal systems can also affect the sectoral
structure of lending. Haselmann and Wachtel (2006) show that banks
in transition economies whose managers have more trust in the country’s
legal system also provide more SME and mortgage lending and less lending to consumers, large enterprises, and government. In Brazil banks
provided payroll loans—loans whose repayment is deducted directly from
the borrower’s payroll check—at significantly lower rates than regular
consumer loans, which were subject to the slow and inefficient recovery
procedures of the Brazilian legal system (Costa and de Mello 2006).
These findings well illustrate the ability of financial intermediaries
to adapt and work around some of the constraints and environmental
deficiencies that they face.12 This may explain why some reforms have
The private sector can adapt
to weak institutions
Some reforms may require
others to affect access
significantly
151
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
disappointing results. For example, especially since the work of Hernando
de Soto, it is commonly observed in the literature that, given the importance of collateral, and the fact that secure land titles can often be the
best collateral available to a borrower, effective land titling programs
should be a good way of enhancing access to credit. Yet, when individual land titling experiments in specific countries are examined—as
reviewed, for example, in a recent paper by Pande and Udry (2006)—the
estimated impact on credit has often been negligible and statistically
insignificant. Evidently, in these cases lenders had already substantially
worked around the lack of land as collateral, or repossessing the land was
not possible despite the title, or the cumulative effect of other obstacles
to the functioning of the credit market remained severe. In any event,
the single reform of titling has in these documented cases not had the
impact anticipated in the literature. Sometimes a comprehensive set of
policy reforms is needed.13
One example of the kind of shortcut that governments can take
to improve the functioning of the credit market is illustrated by the
introduction in India in the 1990s of a new expedited mechanism for
loan contract enforcement. As Visaria (2006) has shown, this new
procedure bypassed dysfunctional court procedures and resulted in a
considerable increase in loan recoveries. Furthermore, interest rates on
new loans contracted after the introduction of the new mechanism were
1–2 percentage points lower because of compositional changes in banks’
portfolios. Visaria is able to establish this from an econometric study
exploiting the facts that only loan contracts above 1 million rupees fall
under this new procedure (thus generating cross-firm variation for the
analysis) and that political resistance and a court injunction had prevented simultaneous introduction of the new institution across all Indian
states (thus allowing cross-time and cross-state variation and the use of
the difference-in-differences estimator discussed in box 2.1).14
Specific Policies to Facilitate Financial Access
Policies to complement
the long-term process of
institution building
152
While indispensable for long-term sustainable broadening and deepening
of financial systems, broad institution building is a long-term process.
The government can achieve additional impact in the short to medium
term by taking action specifically directed at facilitating financial market
activity that helps access. Beyond the overall legal structure and its pro-
GOVERNMENT’S ROLE IN FACILITATING ACCESS
tections, an important practical question is the extent to which contract
enforcement in finance needs to be supplemented by specific laws restricting and clarifying, and thereby offering more reliable protection to,
certain types of financial contracts or financial business more generally.
The trend worldwide has been to expand greatly the degree to which the
law is tightly defined by statute rather than relying on judicial precedent
in areas such as accountancy, banking, securities markets, unit trusts,
leasing, payments, and so on. Indeed, the experience of practitioners in
developing countries has been that many financial contracts simply do
not happen without the presence of an adequate explicit law to clarify
that the contract will have the protection of the courts. But it is possible
that law and regulation can become too intrusive, to the point where they
are counterproductive for access; two such areas—prudential regulation
and anti-money-laundering—are touched on later.
Some of these measures for facilitating financial market activity are
generally unproblematic from a policy point of view, and their implementation is constrained only by government capacity. These measures
include putting in place the legislation, taxation, and other rules needed
for specific financing tools and institutions such as leasing and factoring
that are particularly suited to small and medium enterprises. So long as
the tax arrangements are not unduly generous, these improvements will
be uncontroversial.15 Improved financial literacy might also help if it can
be provided at a low cost. The capacity of individuals and entrepreneurs
to take advantage of available financial services (and to avoid pitfalls)
depends to some degree on adequate financial education. Other policies
can be more controversial, either because they involve trade-offs between
the goal of achieving enhanced access and other accepted goals of public
policy, or because the improvement in access is ambiguous.
As discussed in previous chapters, credit registries—through which
lenders share information about their clients’ repayment records—are
an established way of enhancing the ability of borrowers to signal a
good credit record. Such registries have emerged in the private sector
in numerous countries, but the public sector has also taken a leading
or complementary role in many others (Miller 2003). Even where the
operation and ownership of registries is left to the private sector, government action strongly influences the ability of registries to function. For
example, given that privacy laws may severely constrain information
sharing, the design of credit registries is highly relevant. Sharing of
credit information strengthens the competitive environment in the credit
Credit registries can increase
access by establishing a good
credit record for some—
153
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
—but also exclude high-risk
borrowers
Difficulties in repossessing
collateral may lead to higher
interest rates and
reduced access
154
market. Incumbent banks, however, might not be interested in sharing
positive information, as that increases competitive pressure from possible
entrants. So the government may have to consider making information
sharing mandatory, either through legislation or by regulation of licensed
intermediaries. At a more prosaic level, measures such as giving every
individual a national identification number can dramatically improve the
ease and effectiveness of the operation of the credit information industry
with regard to individual or microfinance borrowers.
Some have argued that credit registries have drawbacks. While better
credit information gives lenders the confidence to expand their customer
base, it also enables them to identify and screen out some high-risk borrowers who might have received credit in a low-information environment.
If so the improvement in access may not be uniform and may result in
some groups being left even further behind. Evidence for this kind of
effect comes from the so-called “home credit” market in the United
Kingdom, where more refined information and credit scoring systems
have resulted in the main mortgage lenders withdrawing from some
geographical segments.16 On balance, though, the indications are that
the number of losers is small compared with the number of winners, and
besides the losers are likely to be the least creditworthy and most prone
to overindebtedness (U.K. Competition Commission 2006).
Some observers have also questioned the degree to which compulsory
sharing of credit information undermines the profitability of relationship
lending, thereby discouraging lenders from investing in such relationships and possibly reducing access in some market conditions (Semenova
2006). Errors and abuses in the maintenance of credit records can be
damaging for individuals; regulations need to guard against such errors
and to ensure that the collection and sharing of credit information does
not in practice represent an unwarranted invasion of borrowers’ privacy.
Even the establishment of national identity numbers has been controversial from a civil liberties perspective in some countries.
Reducing costs and increasing the certainty of registering and repossessing collateral in the event of a default is also crucial. In Brazil, for
example, legal and enforcement obstacles facing lenders trying to repossess property have kept mortgage rates too high to be affordable for the
poor (Kumar 2005). Residential mortgage lending remains small in
scale and accessible mainly to upper-income groups, although there are
a growing number of experiments in microlending for housing. Some
specific legislation and other policy measures are typically called for to
GOVERNMENT’S ROLE IN FACILITATING ACCESS
support developments here. For example, practitioners discuss the question of special policies to promote a market in mortgage securities that
would help expand the supply and lengthen the maturity of housing loans
(Chiquier, Hassler, and Lea 2004). Of course policy efforts to improve
housing for a wider group go well beyond issues of housing finance.17
The rapidly evolving technologies based on the Internet (e-finance)
and cell phones (mobile phones, or m-finance) can be powerful engines
of access (Porteous 2006).18 But a lack of legal clarity may impede the
adaptation of these technologies. Government needs to keep legislation
up to date not only to ensure contracting parties that what they intend
will be unambiguously enforceable but also to prevent legislation from
blocking new innovations. Even though most of the technical problems
seem to have been readily soluble, and despite the huge potential market—probably more individuals have mobile phones than are connected
to the electricity power grid in many low-income countries—m-finance
has been slow to take off. A major early success was in the Philippines,
where two companies signed up a total of 4 million customers. South
Africa was also an early adopter of m-finance, and it has been followed
in Africa by the Democratic Republic of Congo, Kenya, and Zambia,
illustrating the potential for this technology (with its low marginal costs)
to overcome the problem of high unit costs that shut out low-income
customers in countries with relatively weak infrastructures.
But when it comes to policy design as it relates to m-finance, some
unresolved problems have emerged. Defining and updating the legislation that gives participants in the market (especially providers) full legal
protection for the diverse electronic transactions that are involved is a
costly and difficult undertaking for low-income countries. From this
point of view, providers have had to take a leap of faith to enter this
market. There is also the question of regulatory barriers to entry. From
a technical and financial point of view, telephone companies can provide
small-scale payments services without having to draw on the services of a
licensed bank. But regulation may insist that such services are provided
only by a bank (as is the case in South Africa), and if so the compliance
costs can be a major barrier to entry (Porteous 2006).19 A contrasting
example is Kenya, where the regulatory regime has been more open to
initiatives of the phone companies, and innovation is beginning to be
rewarded by relatively rapid consumer take-up.
Any payments system can entail risks of money laundering and terrorism financing, potentially justifying the imposition of AML-CFT
Legislation must adapt to new
technologies—
—including m-finance
155
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Balancing access against
formality of investor protection
in the regulation
of securities markets
(anti-money-laundering and combating of financial terrorism) regulations. This too can become a barrier to the establishment of m-finance
facilities, even though a risk-based approach would show that almost all
of the m-finance customers pose negligible risks of this type.20
Even more controversial is the design of regulation for securities markets. While general principles have been agreed under the auspices of
the International Organization of Securities Commissions, these can be
implemented with varying degrees of formality. More formality means
higher fixed costs of establishing and maintaining a stock market listing,
and the result can be a crowding out of smaller issuers. Low-formality
models, such as London’s innovative Alternative Investment Market, rely
heavily on the reputation of intermediaries known as “nominated advisers”
to ensure that the issuer complies with the relevant principles. Because
of its lower cost, this model has attracted a large number of issuers. This
system has been criticized for not doing enough to protect investors.
There is little systematic empirical evidence on this topic; however, some
practitioners argue that by lowering entry costs, this kind of approach
could yield substantial benefits of greater access for medium-sized issuers,
especially in low-income countries (Grose and Friedman 2006).21
Policies to Promote Competition and Stability
A limited range of effective
tools for competition policy—
156
The literature on the functioning of policies for financial intermediary
competition, prudential regulation and supervision, and protection of the
poor against abusive lending is vast; here we can only mention a small
selection of relevant research findings. The reader also should bear in
mind that the applicability to developing countries of lessons learned in
advanced economies is not always clear. For instance, numerous deposit
insurance schemes have been transplanted from advanced economy models and proved poorly adapted to the circumstances of their developing
country hosts, resulting in excessive risk taking by banks and subsequent widespread fragility and crisis (Demirgüç-Kunt and Kane 2002).
Regulatory institutions that have evolved in advanced country settings
should not be unthinkingly transplanted to the very different political
and institutional settings that prevail in most developing countries.22
The role of competition in enhancing access has already been
discussed in chapter 2. Policy makers who seek to stimulate greater
competition often have only a limited range of effective tools they can
GOVERNMENT’S ROLE IN FACILITATING ACCESS
use, especially in small, low-income markets. A liberal entry policy visà-vis reputable financial service providers can help, but it may not be
enough. Transparency of product pricing and the compulsory sharing
of credit information can also help, as can rules about network access
and interoperability of networks in the retail payments system, but these
may not be fully effective either.
Because of their traditionally high unit costs, the main banks in most
countries have been slow to provide products adapted to the needs of
low-income households, even though they could be in a better position
to do so than others because of the advantages of incumbency. More
and more advanced economies have been adopting affirmative regulatory policies that require financial intermediaries to make appropriate
products available to disadvantaged groups.23 The features needed in such
products can be deduced from the reasons given in surveys of those who
do not use banking services, including the cost of banking and the risk of
a costly loss of control of their finances. Among the products that could
help are basic bank accounts that allow low-cost, simple transactions of
modest size and that have mechanisms to protect low-income users from
inadvertently triggering unauthorized overdrafts.24 Where low-income
customers represent only a fraction of a profitable banking market, the
authorities can insist on such facilities being introduced without fear
that the banks will exit. This might not be the case in many developing countries. But recently in South Africa, financial service providers
introduced voluntarily (albeit under an implicit threat of legislation) a
financial sector charter that included a basic bank account scheme.
More generally, as discussed in chapter 2, policies to promote competition in the banking system can also help restrain the exercise of market
power that could be damaging to access. With their traditional lines of
business coming under competitive pressures, incumbent institutions
have an incentive to reach the underserved segments and increase the
speed with which access-improving technologies are adopted.25
The same competition that can help foster access to financial services
can also result in imprudent lending binges if it is not accompanied by a
proper regulatory and supervisory framework. The financial market rules
with the highest profile are the increasingly complex battery of prudential
regulations imposed on banks to help minimize the risk of disruptive
and costly bank failures. The contraction of credit often associated with
systemic banking crises hits the poor as well as the rich—sometimes more
so—and the poor are less able to bear losses (Honohan 2005a; Halac
—such as affirmative
regulatory policies
Prudential regulation and
supervision can reduce the
risks of banking crises—
157
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
—but too much discretionary
powers for bank regulators
can be harmful
and Schmukler 2004). The goal of financial stability is thus generally
aligned with that of access, although some stability-oriented measures
have the potential to restrict access (box 4.1).26
Indeed, an important current debate among scholars centers on what
style of prudential regulation works best, both in ensuring stability and
avoiding potential side effects such as hindering financial sector development and facilitating corruption.
Barth, Caprio, and Levine (2006) have addressed this issue with regard
to banking. They collected detailed information about the powers and
conduct of bank supervisors in over 150 countries in 1997 and in 2001,
searching for causal links between regulatory style and the performance
of banking systems across the world. Based on regression analysis linking
measures of national regulatory style to financial access and other economic outcomes at the individual firm level, the authors concluded that
Box 4.1 Basel II and access
FOLLOWING AGREEMENT AMONG THE REGULATORS
of the largest industrial countries on a revised framework establishing minimum capital requirements
for international trading banks and new supervisory
practices, bank regulators all over the world have
been taking steps to make comparable revisions in
their bank regulation. The new framework, known
as Basel II, is intended to avoid regulatory arbitrage
by sophisticated banks by making required capital
more sensitive to measurable differences in credit and
other risks faced by banks. Although it is recognized
as embodying technical compromises and could in
certain circumstances amplify risk, Basel II’s more
elaborate approach to capital requirements has triggered technological advances in risk measurement
by banks. There is much to be said for the drive to a
more scientific approach to risk management, which
has been encouraged by the Basel II process and which
has the potential to improve access for creditworthy
borrowers.
But Basel II also has the potential to limit firm
access to finance in developing countries. For one
158
thing, the risk weight attached to international bank
lending to some developing countries is likely to
increase, especially at times of economic difficulty,
and this could contribute to an onshore credit
crunch affecting firm borrowers (Ferri, Liu, and
Majnoni 2001).
Concerns have also been raised that foreignowned banks, reluctant to incur the costs of
multiple regulatory reporting, might pressure
regulatory authorities to adopt the new system even
in developing countries where the advanced risk
measurement techniques of Basel II are impractical or premature (Honohan 2001). If that occurs
and results in higher compliance costs for local
banks and inappropriate risk rating of borrowers,
access could be damaged. In addition, by failing
to make full allowance for the potential for a
portfolio of SME loans to achieve risk pooling,
the Basel II rules miss an opportunity for banks
to use improved information on the distribution
of risks to make SME loans at more competitive
rates (Adasme, Majnoni, and Uribe 2006).
GOVERNMENT’S ROLE IN FACILITATING ACCESS
Supervisory approaches and corruption in lending
Corruption in lending
Corruption in lending
Figure 4.1
3
3
2
2
1
–2
–1
0
1
Private monitoring
2
–3
–2
–1
0
Official supervisory power
1
3
3
2
2
1
Source: Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Levine (2006).
Note: This figure shows the correlation between the average financing obstacles due to corruption reported by firms and (a) the degree of private monitoring across countries and (b) the
degree of supervisory power.
relying too much on discretionary powers given to government officials
to keep the banking system safe, sound, and efficient may be misguided.
Using the same data, Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Levine (2006, figure 4.1)
found that firms in countries that grant the largest discretionary powers
to their bank supervisors tend to complain more that the corruption of
bank officials is an obstacle to their firm’s growth.27
Barth, Caprio, and Levine argue that for banks to promote social
welfare, a country needs political and other institutions that induce
its officials to develop policies that maximize social welfare, not the
private welfare of officials or bankers. From this analysis, it seems that
empowering and inducing large private market participants to conduct
their own due diligence or monitoring of banks (for example, ensuring
good disclosure of information) can be a powerful and often-neglected
way of strengthening the stability of banking while at the same time
improving the reach of the system. And this is not just a message for
159
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Policies restraining abusive
lending to the poor
Interest rate ceilings are rarely
effective—
160
advanced economies. On the contrary, the potential for market discipline
to be relatively effective even in low-income countries is often underestimated (Caprio and Honohan 2004). Similarly, ensuring that bank
supervisors are independent of the political sphere and of the supervised
entities themselves, while at the same time accountable to the general
public is important, though often difficult to achieve given political and
institutional traditions. In many countries, especially those whose law
is based on civil code, supervisors are still liable for their actions, even
if undertaken in good faith, making them subject to frivolous law suits.
Similarly, many countries seem reluctant to give the same degree of political independence cum accountability to bank regulatory entities as they
have given to central banks (Quintyn, Ramirez, and Taylor 2007).
Prudential policies, however, are important not only at the bank or
system level but also at the borrower level. As discussed in chapter 3,
when it comes to borrowing by the poor, more is not always better. Very
poor people, especially those hit by adverse shocks, such as ill health
or natural disaster, and those with chaotic lifestyles, can easily find
themselves in an overborrowed situation where their inability to service
accumulated debt has severe effects on their wellbeing. Most often this
occurs by accident, but in some cases it can be attributable to predatory
behavior by lenders deliberately exploiting the gullibility and ignorance
of the borrowers to trap them in spiraling charges.
The approach of caveat emptor, which assumes that borrowers have
a clear picture of the costs and benefits of entering a borrowing relationship and the capacity to make rational choices, is certainly not true
for marginal groups—and the margin can be quite large in developing
countries.28 These borrowers need to be protected against abusive,
deceptive, extortionate, or predatory behavior, but doing so is not easy.
Although protecting the vulnerable from unwise borrowing and dealing
with the overborrowed poor has long been considered an appropriate
matter for public policy, as yet no generally agreed policy approach has
emerged, even in the advanced economies. Policy measures to deal well
with these kinds of situation may be beyond the technical capacity of
many developing country governments.29
One traditional approach, a ceiling on interest rates (usury laws), is
still widely used, although it is increasingly considered rather ineffective as a measure, not least because opaque cost structures can result in
total costs of credit greatly exceeding stated interest rates. Using what
is known as “behavioral pricing,” unscrupulous lenders advertise low
GOVERNMENT’S ROLE IN FACILITATING ACCESS
interest rates knowing that they will attract naïve and disorganized borrowers who do not realize that their predictable behavior is sure to result
in a very high overall cost of credit when penalties for late payments
and other charges are factored in. At the same time, to the extent that
regulators can detect and limit these extra charges, low ceilings on interest rates are clearly counterproductive if they exclude many low-income
households that could be creditworthy even at the high rates needed
by lenders to cover the costs of processing the borrowings. As a result,
although most advanced countries still have usury ceilings, these have
been relaxed or qualified by exemptions (Policis 2004; Helms and Reille
2004; Goodwin-Groen 2007). Constraints on interest ceilings do exist
in numerous developing countries, and it is widely accepted that they
inhibit the expansion of credit by formal and semiformal intermediaries.
For some Muslims, prohibition of riba entails avoidance of all interestbased finance, although there are practical alternatives (box 4.2).
Allowing a category of licensed or supervised lenders to exceed the
basic usury level is one device that many advanced jurisdictions have used
to bring high-interest lending into the light of day, rather than consigning
it to the shadows in illegality.30 This licensing needs to be accompanied
by enforceable consumer protection rules to ensure that charges are
Box 4.2 Sharia-compliant instruments for firm finance
R EL IGIOUS SCRU PL E S C A N R E SU LT I N SOM E
self-exclusion. To meet the financing and investment needs of Muslims whose beliefs and ethical
frameworks may preclude them from using some
conventional financial instruments, a large industry of sharia-compliant financial instruments has
emerged in recent years and is being constantly
refined. These instruments are scrutinized and
authorized by legal scholars for their compliance
with Islamic precepts. Financial instruments are prohibited if they allow forbidden forms of exploitation
by charging riskless interest (riba); entail radically
uncertain financial transactions (gharar) or zerosum games of pure chance (maysir), especially those
that involve actual or potential deception; or finance
forbidden (haram) activities. Experts have found
ways of meeting the core financing requirements of
modern economies (including insurance through
takaful) without violating these precepts. Indeed,
innovation in sharia-compliant financial engineering
continues with the goal—shared with conventional
finance—of providing for the needs of enterprise
while pooling risk and assigning risk to where it can
best be borne (Jaumdally 1999; Obaidullah 2005).
For example, the global demand for sukuk, a type
of Islamic bond that Malaysia helped popularize,
has been growing very rapidly. In addition, many
Muslims advance charitable funds (qard al-hasan)
at a zero rate of return to help meet the financing
needs of poor people.
161
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
—and may even be
counterproductive
Bankruptcy laws should take
moral hazard into account
162
transparent and that lenders do not make loans to those who cannot bear
the service charges.31 This approach is also used in South Africa, and it
could be applied more widely in developing countries, though its effectiveness depends on the capacity of the licensing authority to enforce the
accompanying rules of good lender practice. But even advanced countries
have had difficulty enforcing the transparency requirements, and in an
environment of widespread illiteracy, establishing what information has
been provided to the borrower is not obvious. As a result, this approach
is not practicable in many low-income countries.
A recent comparison of consumer credit in the three largest EU
economies displays the wide variation in regulatory philosophy and
suggests the very considerable consequences that this variation may have
for the scale and nature of the consumer credit market for middle- and
low-income people. Although thorough econometric analysis is still lacking, the tighter interest ceilings (and other rules for lenders) in France
and Germany may have had quite significant effects on restricting the
range and availability of legally provided credit, compared with credit
in the United Kingdom, and seem to have been associated with a higher
incidence of overborrowing (Policis 2006). The fraction of borrowers
who have defaulted on high-cost, subprime credit cards is much higher
in U.S. states with binding usury laws than in states without such laws,
pointing to the lack of other more suitable sources of credit for lowincome borrowers (Policis 2004).
Even in the United Kingdom, which no longer has usury laws, a
small minority of individuals in difficult circumstances has no access
to legally provided credit. But when these individuals have recourse to
illegal lenders, they pay on average about three times the prevailing cost
of legal credit and are typically subjected to aggressive debt collection and
predatory lending abuses. Usury laws in France and Germany are likely
at the root of the finding that more of the destitute in those countries
borrow in the illegal market than do the poor in the United Kingdom;
if so, the usury ceilings effectively remove protection from them rather
than giving it (Policis 2006).
Overborrowing can result from misfortune as much as from abusive
behavior of lenders. In that case, the primary need may be for assistance
to the overborrower in finding a viable workout plan with the creditors.
Some countries have formalized personal bankruptcy or administration
schemes. The likely impact on credit market functioning should be borne
in mind in designing public policy regarding overborrowing, respecting
GOVERNMENT’S ROLE IN FACILITATING ACCESS
the danger of moral hazard behavior, the limited capacity of courts or
bankruptcy tribunals, and the impracticality of having costly procedures
to deal with debts of poor people that are small in absolute terms.
Public policy around the supply of credit for low-income households
thus needs to ensure contract and pricing transparency, lender responsibility, and measures to facilitate workouts for the overborrowed. Many
administrative resources must be used to implement and enforce these
policies, and those costs must be factored into the policy design.
Government Interventions in the Market
If access to financial services is a powerful tool for reducing poverty, as many
economists and policy makers argue, an a priori case might be made for
subsidization. Subsidization of these fixed costs, however, would have to
be justified in relation to competing demands for public funds. As chapter
3 discussed, the case for subsidization of financial services in this context
is hotly contested in discussions of microfinance. The deadweight cost of
diverting subsidies to intramarginal clients, especially when the target group
cannot be well defined, and the risk of undercutting market innovation that
could enhance access on a sustainable basis are but two of the problems
cited. The fiscal costs of de facto credit subsidies can be high—often much
higher than predicted ex ante (see, for example, Adams, Graham, and von
Pischke 1984; and Micco, Panizza, and Yañez 200732).
The effectiveness of numerous official attempts to improve the reach
of SME lending and the maturity structure of SME loans is doubtful
(Caprio and Demirgüç-Kunt 1997; Beck and Demirgüç-Kunt 2006).
Political subversion of directed credit programs has been a significant
problem. Sometimes such schemes have ended up channeling sizable
loans to political cronies, but politicization of small-scale lending has
also been observed. It is easy to see why: extending small loans is an ideal
political lever, with evident benefits and opaque costs. That is especially
evident when the lenders are state-owned banks, as discussed below. Even
where politicization is not a problem, attempts to redirect credit toward
disadvantaged groups often seem to be ineffective.33
Perhaps the most widely discussed policy intervention of this type
was the restrictive branching law adopted in India in 1977; under this
law banks wishing to open additional urban branches were first obliged
to open additional rural branches. The rural locations benefited from
Interventions through taxes
and subsidies—
—can be politicized
163
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Interventions through
government-owned
intermediaries have
a poor record—
additional banking services, although the process was not costless (box
4.3). This intriguing scheme can be considered an implicit self-financing
combination of tax and subsidy, but it would be hard to judge whether
the tax fell more heavily on the banks or the urban dwellers.
Ease of raising revenue from the sector has resulted in numerous other
forms of tax or quasi-tax being imposed on the financial sector in most
countries; not least are large and underremunerated reserve requirements
and—a recent fashion—financial transactions taxes. The distortions
created by these taxes have sometimes been very severe, especially when
inflation is high. The potential negative impact on the outreach of the
financial system from the introduction of such taxes needs to be borne
carefully in mind (Honohan 2003).
Despite a few success stories, substituting government provision of
financial services for that of the market is generally considered problematic. The poor record of government development banks in delivering
broad access or lowering poverty weakens the case for using this tool
Box 4.3 Rural branching in India
Between 1977 and 1990, the Reserve Bank of
India mandated that a commercial bank could open
a new branch in a location that already had bank
branches only if it opened four in locations with no
branches. This regulation was part of a social banking program that tried to expand access to financial
services in rural areas. An ex post evaluation of this
policy (Burgess and Pande 2005) shows that it had
sizable effects. The 1:4 rule was a binding constraint
on banks and together with a regulated branch-level
loan-deposit ratio of 60 percent led to an increase
in bank branches and in rural credit in less densely
banked states, even after controlling for other state
characteristics that might have driven branch and
credit expansion. One interesting finding: whereas
the presence of more bank branches in a state was
associated with more rapid poverty reduction in
that state in the period before and after the policy
was in effect, this correlation was absent between
1977 and 1990. This finding, which is robust to
164
other policies introduced over the period and to
controlling for endogeneity, suggests that availability of a bank branch is poverty reducing, even
where the branch has been opened only as a result
of the policy. The regression results imply that rural
branch expansion during the policy period may have
accounted for 60 percent of all rural poverty reduction during the period, largely through an increase
in nonagricultural activities, which experienced
higher returns than in agriculture, and especially
through an increase in unregistered or informal
manufacturing activities. But there was a significant downside: commercial banks incurred large
losses attributable to subsidized interest rates and
high loan losses—suggesting potential longer-term
damage to the credit culture. Furthermore, many
governments do not have the carrot of licensing
branches in markets as dynamic as those of some of
the largest Indian cities to compensate for the stick
of compulsory rural branches.
GOVERNMENT’S ROLE IN FACILITATING ACCESS
on the credit side. Instead the evidence is that state-owned banks tend
to lend to cronies, especially around the time of elections, as vividly
displayed by recent detailed analysis of statistics on bank credit by Cole
(2004), Dinç (2005), and Khwaja and Mian (2005), whose findings
confirm numerous anecdotes.
For example, Cole has shown that government-owned banks in Indian
states ramped up agricultural lending in tightly contested districts in
election years. Given a history in which state governments cancelled
banking debts in the past, borrowers might not only have been glad of
the loan, but likely assumed that it might not have to be repaid if times
became hard.34 Dinç showed that increased lending by governmentowned banks right before elections is not specific to India but can be
observed in data from 22 developing countries.35
Drilling down to the individual loan level, Khwaja and Mian found
evidence from Pakistan that politically active borrowers were able to
secure larger and cheaper loans from state-owned banks and defaulted
on these loans much more than other business borrowers (figure 4.2).36
Even though not all state-owned banks performed poorly (Levy Yeyati,
Micco, and Panizza 2006), this and a large body of other evidence make
Figure 4.2
—including the use of political
criteria to grant loans
Size of loans by Pakistani banks
Defaulted political loans from
government banks
Defaulted nonpolitical loans from
government banks
Performing political loans from
government banks
Performing nonpolitical loans from
government banks
Loans from nongovernment banks
0
50
100
150
200
250
Index
Source: Based on Khwaja and Mian (2005).
Note: Larger, politically connected loans default more than nonpolitical loans and are more
likely to be from government-owned banks. There was no significant correlation between political
connections and size of loan from nongovernment banks.
165
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
The record is better for
state-supported savings and
payment services
DFIs could become more
effective as providers of knowhow than of credit
166
it easy to see why many countries have preferred to sell large state-owned
banks, even to foreign-owned entities.37
In the case of depository services, experience has been more mixed.
The postal banking service and state-supported savings banks have traditionally been seen as the providers of depository services to low-income
groups. The wide geographic network of post offices and agencies makes
it the tool of choice for offering basic payment and savings products in
more remote areas. Japan Post Bank and the Russian Sberbank (formerly
a savings bank) are among the largest retail financial institutions in the
world. Indeed, in France, the right to a banking account is essentially
ensured through the postal savings system. Given the sunk cost nature
of the post office infrastructure, banking services can be offered at
marginal costs, a fact that implies significantly lower costs in the case
of low-income clients with the need for small transactions (World Bank
2006b). At the same time, examples abound of postal banks with weak
financial structures because they lack a clear legal and accounting separation from the post office. Preliminary cross-country evidence on access
barriers suggests that, despite explicit mandates for government banks
to expand outreach, in banking systems dominated by state banks, there
are fewer bank branches and automated teller machines. Customers in
such systems do face lower fees, but they also experience poorer service
quality (Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Martinez Peria, 2007a, b).
Some state-owned banks, designated as development finance institutions (DFIs) or development banks, have a specific public policy mandate
to make long-term credit available to promote economic development in
particular regions or sectors. While these banks have typically been urged
to operate in as commercial a manner as is consistent with fulfilling their
mandate, the difficulty of doing that has led many to reconsider their
business model. A handful of more sophisticated government-owned DFIs
have moved away from credit and evolved into providers of more complex
financial services. Their know-how, willingness, and capacity to take
initiatives that are consistent with their social remit—even at the cost of
a lengthy initial period of loss-making—has allowed them to introduce
into developing countries financial products and markets that have been
proven elsewhere but that entail heavy setup costs without certainty of
high financial return. Involving few if any credit risks, these services are
less subject to political subversion. Moreover, employing public-private
partnerships, the DFIs can help overcome coordination failures, firstmover disincentives, and obstacles to risk sharing and distribution.
GOVERNMENT’S ROLE IN FACILITATING ACCESS
Three examples from Mexico illustrate. One is the electronic brokerage of reverse factoring, developed by Nafin, a government development
bank, which allows many small suppliers to use their receivables from
large creditworthy buyers to obtain working capital financing (Klapper
2006). Another example is the electronic platform implemented by
BANSEFI, another government-owned institution, to help semiformal
and informal fi nancial intermediaries reduce their operating costs
by centralizing back-office operations. Finally, a government-owned
DFI, turned investment bank, FIRA, has brokered quite complicated
structured financial products to realign credit risks with the pattern of
information between financial intermediaries and the different participants in the supply chains for several industries, including shrimp
and other agrifish products (De la Torre, Gozzi, and Schmukler 2007).
Given patient capital, the private sector could have undertaken each of
these successful initiatives. Indeed, the Mexican government explicitly
envisages privatization of at least some of these initiatives. But they
have had a useful catalytic function in “kick-starting” certain financial
services in Mexico.
Evaluation of interventions
It is increasingly recognized that direct interventions to support access
need careful evaluation. There are at least three potentially important
dimensions to the needed evaluations.
• First, a management audit is necessary to try to ensure that
delivery is cost effective and that decision and control structures
are optimized against best practice, with, for example, clear and
effective procedures for measuring intended outputs and desired
outcomes.38
• Second, the impact of the scheme on the intended beneficiaries
must be assessed. Comparing beneficiaries before and after the
intervention is not sufficient, as a recent example of a government-sponsored scheme of poverty reduction loans in China
shows (Chen, Mu, and Ravallion 2006). Once the researchers controlled for the selection bias of the program targeted to
poor households and for potential spillover effects to villages
that were not in the program, they did not find any long-term
effect on incomes, except for the poor who were relatively well
educated.
167
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
The best methodology is often randomized evaluation, as
discussed in chapter 3.39 This methodology requires recording
the experience both of program beneficiaries and of a control
group; the latter must be selected with care to ensure that they
were not excluded from the program as a result of the program’s
design. Unfortunately, most control groups are not selected until
after the program has been started, complicating the subsequent
evaluation.
• Third, general equilibrium, or “system,” effects, especially of largescale programs, must be taken into account. These are especially
difficult to assess, given that they affect nonparticipants as well
as participants and may be subtle. Thus, for example, it is often
argued that direct provision of services below cost can undermine
the capacity or motivation of private service providers to incur
setup costs for competing services. This is especially important
in cases where there is no clear provision that the government
intervention or subsidy will end after a certain time period. Not
only can governance problems undermine the effectiveness of the
program but they also can have negative spillover effects on the
economy at large. This is where it is important to have a good
conceptual understanding of the potential processes at work and
the honest and skilled use of econometric techniques to deal with
endogeneity, selection bias, and errors in variables.
Overall, whereas better nutrition or education for the poor may be
uncontroversial as overarching goals, the immediate goals of policy
interventions to improve financial access need careful definition. Direct
policy intervention has a chance of working only if attention is paid to
getting four things right:
• Clarity and logical coherence of the objectives of intervention
• Governance structures that inhibit subversion of these objectives
• Control over agency costs, especially credit risk related to
adverse selection and moral hazard
• Adequate technical and administrative arrangements.
A canonical example of direct intervention: the credit guarantee scheme
In the following pages we take a close look at one type of direct intervention—government-backed credit guarantees. Most of the issues that
168
GOVERNMENT’S ROLE IN FACILITATING ACCESS
arise in designing credit guarantee schemes have their counterparts in
other types of direct intervention. The details described here for credit
guarantees thus carry lessons for a wide range of policy initiatives.40
With direct and directed lending programs somewhat in eclipse in
recent years, the direct intervention mechanism of choice for SME credit
activists in recent years has been the government-backed partial credit
guarantee. According to Green (2003), well over 2,000 such schemes
exist in almost 100 countries.41 Thus more than half of all countries—
and all but a handful of the developed countries—have some form of
credit guarantee scheme, usually targeted at some sector or category of
firm that is thought to be underserved by the private financial sector.
Typically, these guarantee programs seek to expand availability of credit
to SMEs and are sometimes focused on specific sectors, regions, or ownership groups, or on young or new technology firms (or even on firms
that have been hit by an adverse shock and risk failure). Often there is a
subsidiary employment, innovation, or productivity growth objective.
But these trends reflect more the disappointing experience of other
forms of intervention than any substantial body of evidence that publicly
funded credit guarantee schemes work well. Indeed, while new guarantee
schemes are contemplated in several countries, some of the countries
with the largest and longest-established guarantee schemes have been
downsizing or drastically redesigning their programs.
Of course, credit guarantees are observed in private financial markets
without explicit government support. They emerge typically for one of
three main reasons: first, because of differential information, as where the
borrower’s creditworthiness is better known by a well-capitalized guarantor
than by the lender; second, as a means of spreading and diversifying risk;
and third, as a regulatory arbitrage, as when an unregulated firm provides
a guarantee allowing the lender to bring an otherwise insufficiently secured
loan into compliance with regulatory requirements or other government
programs or financial industry risk-rating practices and conventions.
Government involvement in creating a credit guarantee company is
often rationalized by the observation that SMEs commonly do not have
the kinds of collateral that bankers require. Given that financial markets
are not perfectly efficient, a decision by the government to step in where
private financiers have not found it profitable to do so need not necessarily involve subsidy and fiscal outlay—although typically it does.42 With
many competing pressures for public funds, an economically coherent
argument in favor of a subsidized credit guarantee system needs to go
Weighing the welfare benefits
against the costs of subsidies
169
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
a lot further than the observation that such a scheme would increase
the availability of credit. The government needs to be sure that such a
scheme will increase overall welfare by enough to justify the subsidy
cost, and not simply result in a costly distortion. A welfare economics
perspective suggests three possible sources from which a net welfare
improvement could come:
• Market failure related to adverse selection. Lending may be
rationed and undersupplied relative to the social optimum (see
box 1.2); in such circumstances a credit subsidy might improve
overall welfare.43
• Correcting for unequally distributed endowments. Lack of collateral is most acute for low-wealth individuals and groups of
people and for poorer geographical areas. However, it is far from
clear that credit allocation is the best or even a good instrument
to correct for unequal initial endowments.
• Kick-starting SME lending. SME lending is not well developed in
part because lenders have not accumulated the needed practical
experience and the stock of credit information, and therefore
face a lengthy loss-making startup period. Credit appraisal and
management can build on experience, including systemwide
credit history data and credit scoring.
It can be difficult to evaluate
the total costs of a scheme at
its inception—
170
Reading between the lines of the diverse and often rather vaguely stated
goals of publicly sponsored credit guarantee schemes, one can usually detect
hints of one or more of these economists’ arguments, perhaps most often
the last one mentioned.44 Whether these goals are fully achieved and at
what cost is something that has never been evaluated in a fully satisfactory way even after the event, much less in advance. The evaluations that
have been carried out focus on operational aspects such as ensuring that
sufficient take-up or keeping the cost of the scheme within bounds.
The cost issue sometimes attracts less attention in the early days of the
scheme. After all, one obvious but superficial attraction for promoters
of credit guarantee schemes is that the upfront cash commitment by the
government is small in relation to the total volume of credit supported
by such schemes. The liabilities are contingent and in the future, while
operating costs can be covered by fees and premiums paid by beneficiaries. The endowment of capital may be a small fraction—often 5
percent—of the allowed total sum guaranteed and need not be paid
in cash. In due course, loan losses do emerge, and the adequacy of the
GOVERNMENT’S ROLE IN FACILITATING ACCESS
fees and premiums becomes evident only over time as the contingent
liabilities inherent in this soft budget constraint crystallize.
Estimating likely future underwriting losses is not as easy as it might
seem, especially at start-up.45 If the target group has not been borrowing,
there is little experience on which to project defaults and the consequent
losses. Furthermore, default experience is highly dependent on the
state of the business cycle, so that it is unwise to extrapolate from the
experience of a few years. If there is a major economic downturn, then
default rates and resulting losses can soar, as was seen in several East
Asian countries in recent years.
In practice the range of experience regarding cost has been enormous
(figure 4.3).46 While numerous schemes have experienced much higherthan-expected losses, heavy and unanticipated underwriting costs are by
no means a universal experience of credit guarantee schemes (Doran and
Levitsky 1997; Bennett, Doran, and Billington 2005). This finding is
consistent with the belief of many bankers that loan losses can be held to
acceptable levels through good credit appraisal and monitoring practices,
but that it is the cost per loan of appraisal and monitoring that underFigure 4.3
schemes
Estimated annual subsidy cost of selected credit guarantee
16
Percentage of loan amount
14
12
10
8
6
4
2
0
Chile
United
States
Italy
Mexico
Koerea
United
Kingdom
Source: Approximate figures based on data in Benavente, Galetovic, and Sanhueza 2006;
Bennett, Doran, and Billington 2005; Benavides and Huidobro 2005; Zechinni and Ventura
2006; Shim 2006; and Graham 2004. The U.S. figure assumes average maturity of 13 years
(U.S. General Accounting Office 1996). The U.K. figure is the 2003–4 outlay divided by that
year’s flow of new guarantees (Graham 2004, para 1.12); using the average of the previous 10
years’ new guarantees would give a much higher figure.
171
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
—and even harder to calculate
the benefits
Operational design is
important
172
mines the profitability of SME lending. If so, a well-run credit guarantee
scheme may not need to be very expensive, but it may also not be enough
to attract bankers into the market for loans to the target group.
If it is difficult to estimate the likely future cost of a credit guarantee scheme, it is even more difficult to evaluate the social benefit that
results. Evidently the volume of loans guaranteed is a wholly inadequate
measure of social benefit. On one hand, there might be no additionality
involved—the loans might have been forthcoming anyway even in the
absence of the guarantee. On the other hand, additionality might be
greater than the loan amount guaranteed, as receipt of the guarantee
might leverage a much more substantial, unguaranteed financing package. Most evaluations of guarantee schemes rely on the qualitative assessment of bankers and SME insiders to determine whether availability of
credit to SMEs has eased. Depending on the design of the scheme and in
particular on the nature of eligibility rules, formal econometric methods
can sometimes be used to throw light on this question, but only a few
systematic attempts to do so have been made.47 A specific policy change
in Pakistan allowed Zia (2007) to uncover credible evidence of very
substantial deadweight (lack of additionality) in the subsidized export
credit scheme in Pakistan.48 By distinguishing between the experience
of Chilean firms whose main bank began using the FOGAPE scheme
at different times, Larraín and Quiroz (2006) estimated that microfirms whose bank used the FOGAPE scheme had a 14 percent higher
probability of getting a loan. At the same time, Benavente, Galetovic
and Sanhueza (2006) note evidence of sizable displacement in the
scheme—for example, a large and growing share of successive guarantees
being granted to the same firms.
Second, even if there is additionality, it might involve such heavy
loan losses or transaction costs as to result in net welfare losses for the
economy as a whole. And even if fiscal costs are low, the economic costs
of misallocated resources can be high. In the Pakistan case, Zia calculated
that diversion of unneeded credit to beneficiary firms could have held
GDP below its potential by 0.75 percent.
The operating expenses and underwriting experience of a credit
guarantee scheme depend on the design of the scheme (as well as on
the effectiveness of its administration). These will also clearly affect the
success of the scheme in improving the availability of credit and achieving any other goals of the scheme. The first issue is pricing: systematic
underpricing clearly adds to the fiscal cost of any such scheme. Three
other design dimensions are worth noting.
GOVERNMENT’S ROLE IN FACILITATING ACCESS
• First is the question of whether the guarantee scheme should
carry out its own credit appraisal of each final borrower who is
being guaranteed. Some of the best-regarded schemes do not conduct such retail assessments but instead rely on an assessment of
the intermediary whose portfolio of loans is being guaranteed.49
• Second is the rate of guarantee, that is, the proportion of the
total loan that is guaranteed (along with related aspects, such as
whether the losses are shared proportionately between lender and
guarantor, or if the guarantor covers the first or last portions).
Many practitioners argue that the lender should retain a significant part of the risk (at least 20 percent and preferably 30–40
percent, according to Levitzky 1997 and Green 2003), so that
there will be an incentive to conduct credit appraisal. In practice,
most schemes offer slightly higher rates of guarantee—70 to 80
percent being about the norm—and up to 85 percent in the case
of the U.S. Small Business Administration and 100 percent in
some other cases (for example, Japan). Guarantee rates significantly under 50 percent fail to attract lenders. Scaling guarantee
rates according to the claims experience from each lender can
improve lender incentives without the adverse distributional
impact that would result from requiring final borrower guarantees. Chile’s FOGAPE has started to auction available guarantee
amounts, with the lenders bidding on the rate of guarantee.50
Bankers who bid for lower guarantee rates than the maximum
allowable have their requests filled; others are rationed. In practice, the auctions have resulted in the primary lender retaining
between 20 and 30 percent of the risk (Benavente, Galetovic, and
Sanhueza 2006; Bennett, Doran, and Billington 2005).
• Third is the nature of the lending criteria, such as the categories of eligible borrowers and the terms of the lending. Some
schemes have relatively broad eligibility rules (for example, a
ceiling on borrower size as measured by turnover, and a ceiling on the guarantee fund’s overall exposure to the borrower).
The more complex the criteria, the more likely opaque political
interference with the granting of guarantees. At the same time,
a broad set of criteria leaves the door open to deadweight in
the allocation of subsidy to borrowers that have no need of it.
Restrictions on the lending terms, such as interest ceilings, seek
to limit the degree to which the lenders in an uncompetitive
173
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
market capture rent from the scheme, but if these restrictions
are set at unrealistic levels, they can open the door to corrupt
side-payments. In practice the trend has been to move toward
less complicated eligibility criteria over time.
Subsidies are not an
ingredient for success
174
Although Japan and Korea have had very extensive credit guarantee
schemes, with the stock of guarantees exceeding 7 percent of GDP in
2001, and still in excess of 5 percent of GDP at the time of writing,51
guarantee schemes in most countries have typically covered only a small
fraction of total SME lending, and guarantees amount to a fraction of
1 percent of GDP. Sometimes this is due to capacity constraints (as in
the well-regarded Chilean scheme, which covers only about one-sixth
of micro-, small-, and medium-enterprise lending). In other cases it is
attributable to lack of demand, which in turn can be traced to such
features as excessive procedural costs, lack of lender confidence, delays
in claims payments, or narrow eligibility criteria.
Systematic economic evaluations do not yet offer enough evidence
to form an impression of which schemes, if any, truly represent value
for money. But as this brief review suggests, the lessons of operational
experience are that government-sponsored credit guarantee schemes have
the most to show for their efforts where they have effectively and credibly delivered an attractive package of services to lenders, with a view
to enhancing their capacity to lend to the underserved sector, thereby
propelling them to a sustainably higher level of lending. Innovative
pricing can induce improved results (for example, better loan appraisal
by lenders); even without subsidy, demand from lenders may be high
where the scheme operator can add value, for example, by disseminating industry information on SME loan performance. More and more
guarantee schemes are likely to move to broad eligibility and other criteria, reduced subsidies, and more use of the portfolio and wholesaling
approach in preference to case-by-case evaluation by the guarantor of
retail loans.
Government-sponsored credit guarantee schemes will never substitute
for reform of the underlying institutional requirements of an effective
credit system. The best of them can probably survive and add value even
without ongoing government subsidies.
Given the checkered record of such schemes in the advanced economies, and this is true of many other types of direct government intervention in the financial market, the question is not just one of avoiding
GOVERNMENT’S ROLE IN FACILITATING ACCESS
unthinking transplantation of success stories; it is more a matter of pausing to consider whether, if success is unlikely in a favorable governance
and general institutional environment, an adaptation can work in the
more difficult environment of the developing world?
Box 4.4 Subsidy and access
THE NET FISCAL COST INCURRED BY PUBLICLY
funded credit guarantee schemes is just one example
of a variety of access-related subsidies. As in other
areas of development, the use of public funds is easy
to justify in the interest of improving access and
thereby promoting pro-poor growth. Such subsidies
of course need to be evaluated against the many
alternative uses of the donor or scarce public funds
involved, not least of which are alternative subsidies
to meet education, health, and other priority needs
for the poor themselves. In practice, such a costbenefit calculation is rarely made. Indeed, the scale
of subsidy is often unmeasured.
Furthermore, as with financial sector taxation,
subsidies in finance can be more liable to deadweight costs than is the case for many other sectors
(Honohan 2003). It is often especially hard to ensure
that finance-related subsidies reach the target group
or that they have the hoped-for effect.
But an even more serious problem is the possible
chilling effect of subsidies on the commercial provision of competing and potentially better services to
the poor. Subsidizing finance is likely to undermine
the motivation and incentive for market-driven
financial firms to innovate and deliver. It is this
danger—that subsidies will inhibit the viability of
sustainable financial innovation—that can be the
decisive argument against some forms of subsidy.
Note that it is not subsidization of the poor that
should be questioned: the poor need help and subsidies in many dimensions. Subsidies to cover fi xed
costs (for example, in payments systems, especially
when these generate network externalities) may be
less subject to this chilling effect than those that
operate to subsidize marginal costs. But every case
must be assessed on its own merits.
Microfinance is the area of financial access
where subsidies have been most debated. Many
well-intentioned people have sought by means of
subsidy to make credit affordable for the poor. As a
result, a majority of microfinance institutions (MFIs)
today—though fewer of the largest ones—operate on a subsidized basis (Cull, Demirgüç-Kunt,
and Morduch 2007). Some of these subsidies are
for overhead, and the MFIs do not think of them
as subsidizing the interest rates. Many currently
subsidized MFIs aspire to reach a break-even point
and ultimately become fully profitable. Others,
including the famous Grameen Bank, consciously
apply subsidies to keep interest rates down. MFIs
that operate group-lending schemes and that in
practice are more focused on the poor rely on the
highest subsidies.
While many borrowers are able and willing to
service interest rates at levels that allow efficient
MFIs to be fully profitable, there is no doubt that
demand and borrower surplus would be even higher
if interest rates were lower. Many would agree with
Morduch (1999) that the prospects of reaching many
of the very poor with unsubsidized credit are low.
But even with a subsidy, credit will rarely be the
first financial service need of the very poor. Also,
apart from ensuring that the subsidy does reach its
target group, the question, as always, is whether
introduction of subsidy undermines the emergence
of a sustainable industry with extensive—albeit
incomplete—outreach.
175
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Political Economy of Access
Existing elites may benefit
from restricted access—
176
Politics and finance are the keys to economic access. If North, Wallis,
and Weingast (2006) are correct in their view that the decisive transition
in economic history is that between limited and open-access societies, to
understand this transition is, as they point out, to understand modern
development.
It is one thing to identify a policy measure that will achieve a net
improvement in financial access at reasonable cost and limited overall
side-effects. It is quite another to suppose that such a policy will automatically be implemented by an enthusiastic government.52 Governments
are, after all, operating in a political environment, and the package of
policies that is implemented often owes more to the balance of political
influence than to the state of knowledge about policy effectiveness.53
Why should governments introduce reforms that might be at the expense
of incumbent elites?
When the political and social structure of the state is predicated
on limited access and the resulting rents, existing elites have limited
enthusiasm for policies that would increase access to financial services
(Rajan and Zingales 2003). It may well be, as Rajan (2006a) argues,
that in unequal societies the desire of each subgroup to preserve its
economic rents against all others tends to reinforce the status quo. The
policy reform agenda is therefore not a simple matter of adjusting a
flawed policy stance or adapting existing laws to changing market and
technological realities. Instead the reforms must be far-reaching if the
gain in economic performance is to be large enough to be attractive to
existing elites, who will have a smaller share of the larger postreform
cake. Vested interests must be convinced of the merits of transition.
Making that argument is a more effective way of inducing change than
direct attacks on privileges. And prioritizing financial access generates
a detailed policy agenda for converting the aspiration for transition into
concrete measures. For, despite the far-reaching nature of the institutional
changes involved in the transition to an open-access society, it seems
clear that reforms that really do improve financial access should also
help drive the societal transformation. The financial access agenda thus
points back to the nature of the institutional changes that are needed in
society and as such provides a touchstone for reform.
The reforms needed to improve financial access as the decisive change
mechanism in the economy are not only necessary but almost sufficient
GOVERNMENT’S ROLE IN FACILITATING ACCESS
to define that wider policy agenda. This agenda ranges from matters of
great generality down to questions of operational implementation and
design. Delivering on this agenda calls on many different agencies of
government and also typically needs support from external development
partners. Engagement of civil society is essential to create the political
environment within which governments will be induced to act.
Numerous examples can be cited from research on policy adoption
to illustrate the pressures that are involved. When and how do financial
sector reforms occur? What is the relative importance of private and
public interest and ideology? In a classic paper, Kroszner and Strahan
(1999) argued that the sequence in which U.S. states liberalized banking
was consistent with the view that resistance to such policy changes was
driven by the well-organized private special interest of the bankers and
not by an objective or ideologically driven view of the public interest.54
Eventually, technological progress and a competitive political system
overcame the special interests of small bankers who benefited from the
constraints. In contrast, Haber (2005) argues that a less competitive
political system in Mexico meant that the government limited entry
into the banking sector in return for favors and for financing for much
longer than did the United States; as a result, by the early 20th century,
Mexico was left with a much smaller, more concentrated, and more
inefficient banking system.
The example of branch deregulation in the United States also shows
the potential for exogenous events, such as technological innovation,
to overcome political resistance to competition-enhancing reforms.
As the introduction of ATMs, money market checking accounts, and
improvements in communication technology have reduced the banks’
need to be physically close to their clients, the monopoly power of
small local banks declined and with it political resistance to change.
The prospect of accession to the European Union helped many governments in transition economies to overcome political resistance against
institutional reform (Beck and Laeven 2006). It is worth looking for
such windows of opportunity when political resistance to reform may
be weaker.
Once started, there seems to be an internal dynamic to the process
of financial sector reforms, though timing can be also be influenced by
macroeconomic conditions. Based on the timing of financial liberalization in 35 countries over the period 1973–96, Abiad and Mody (2005)
found that countries with highly repressed financial sectors are unlikely
—but vested interests can be
overcome in a competitive
political system—
—and through technological
innovation
177
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
The middle classes can be
powerful allies for the poor
178
to reform.55 Once reforms, even small ones, take place, however, the
process builds momentum and further reforms become more likely. A
balance-of-payments crisis typically triggers financial sector reforms,
but a banking crisis is often associated with an interruption or reversal
of liberalization.
Many other examples of political influence on financial sector policy
are reported in the literature. For example, seeking to explain the frequency with which underpriced privatizations are observed, Biais and
Perotti (2002) discuss how a strategic privatization program allocating
left-leaning voters enough underpriced shares can induce a voting shift
away from left-wing parties whose policy would reduce the values of
shareholdings. Perotti and Volpin (2004) argue, with some supporting
evidence, that in countries with low political accountability, incumbent
firms succeed in persuading politicians not to strengthen effective investor protection in order to prevent potential entrants from raising capital.56
Along similar lines, Feijen and Perotti (2005) suggest that, following
financial liberalization (which typically results in improved access to
finance by new entrants), elites successfully lobby politicians to ensure
weak contract enforcement with the result that their highly leveraged
recent entrant competitors are unable to refinance in downturns, and
have to exit the market. And lobbying can be effective even at the micro
level. Claessens, Feijen, and Laeven (2007) discovered, using data on
every political donation made by Brazilian firms in the runup to the
1998 elections, that political contributions are somehow rewarded by
subsequent excess returns in the stock market.
How to help align reform-making process with public interest? This
is another area where much more research is needed. Greater public
awareness of the potential benefits of policies to broaden access will
also be important to shift the political equilibrium in the direction of
reforms that promote the public good. In this context, the challenges of
financial access and financial inclusion clearly go well beyond ensuring
financial services for the poor. The middle classes too have insufficient
access to finance. Advertising the access agenda as a broad one that
includes the middle class helps mobilize a powerful supporter in the
struggle to broaden access (Rajan 2006b). The same mechanisms that
expand access for middle-class households and SME entrepreneurs will
often help expand the access for the very poor as well. This process will
also help strengthen the links between formal and informal financial
systems and allow the poor to migrate upward.
GOVERNMENT’S ROLE IN FACILITATING ACCESS
Conclusions
This chapter has highlighted the complexity of the policy challenge in
improving access. The discussion has been necessarily selective, setting
out principles for effective government policy by drawing on and generalizing lessons from specific examples.
Deep institutional reform that above all ensures security of property rights against expropriation by the state is an underlying, albeit
often long-term, goal. Meanwhile legal and especially informational
infrastructures can be strengthened to help financial institutions work
around a difficult environment, thereby making the provision of wider
access privately profitable.
Ensuring competition is an essential part of broadening access as competition encourages incumbent institutions to seek out profitable ways
of providing services to previously excluded segments of the population
and increases the speed with which new, access-improving technologies
are adopted. In this process, providing the private sector with the right
incentives is key, hence the importance of good prudential regulations. A
variety of regulatory measures is needed to support wider access. Taking
consumer protection against abusive lending as an example, we have
shown that interest ceilings fail to address the problem adequately and
can even be counterproductive; increased transparency and formalization
and enforcement of lender responsibility are a more coherent approach,
along with support for the overborrowed. However, delivering all of this
is administratively demanding.
The scope for direct government interventions in improving access
is more limited than often believed. Here, we have used credit guarantee schemes as an example of direct government intervention aimed at
increasing access for SMEs. These programs can be more costly in budgetary terms than anticipated, and their performance can be improved
by careful scheme design. In the absence of thorough economic evaluations of most schemes, their net effect in cost-benefit terms remains
unclear.
If the interest of powerful incumbents is threatened by the potential
emergence of new entrants financed by a system that has improved
access and outreach, lobbying by those incumbents can block the needed
reforms. A comprehensive approach to financial sector reform aiming at
better access must take these political realities into account. Given that
the challenges of financial inclusion and benefits from broader access go
Institutional reform and
building infrastructure are key
long-term priorities
Ensure competition and
provide the private sector with
the right incentives
A limited role for direct
government interventions
The middle class may have the
power to overcome the vested
interests of the elites
179
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
well beyond ensuring financial services for the poor, defining the access
agenda more broadly to include the middle class will help mobilize greater
political support for advancing the access agenda around the world.
Notes
1. For a theoretical analysis, see Huybens and Smith (1998, 1999), among
others, and for empirical analysis of the cross-country relationship between
finance and inf lation, see Boyd, Levine, and Smith (2001); Honohan
(2003).
2. This infrastructure can also be seen as a public good that private providers are not willing to provide.
3. Recently more country-specific evidence has been accumulated through
two programs conducted by the World Bank, in the latter case jointly with
the International Monetary Fund. The Reports on Observance of Standards
and Codes on insolvency and creditor rights, corporate governance, auditing
and accounting standards, and other areas are detailed assessments of the
contractual, information, and regulatory frameworks of countries and provide
detailed reform suggestions. The Financial Sector Assessment Program provides
a detailed assessment of the stability and development of countries’ financial
systems as well as road maps to short-, medium- and long-term deepening
and broadening.
4. LaPorta and others (1997, 1998) (and the literature that ensued) showed
that, compared with French legal origin countries, the English common law
countries have deeper banking systems and securities markets, more initial
public offerings, more diffuse ownership of public equity, a higher ratio of
market to book value of shares (Tobin’s Q), and higher dividend payouts that
are more closely tied to profits. The interpretation of these findings remains
quite controversial. LaPorta and others relate these outcomes to cross-legal
system variation in the protection of minority shareholders and creditors and
enforcement of law. Thus, to oversimplify, the common law system tends to
offer stronger legal protection of shareholders and creditors, together with more
efficient courts and judicial systems.
5. While most scholars believe that efficient protection of creditor and
investor rights is an important determinant of financial development, there
has been considerable debate as to whether the legal origin variable proposed
by La Porta and others (1997, 1998) is at the root of international differences
in these rights, let alone their enforcement. This variable is correlated across
countries with other predetermined variables such as geographical endowments,
political structures, and ethnic diversity (Beck and Levine 2005; Ayyagari,
Demirgüç-Kunt, and Maksimovic 2006b, 2007c).
180
GOVERNMENT’S ROLE IN FACILITATING ACCESS
6. However, related work shows that the distinction between legal systems
according to adaptability is not completely aligned with the difference between
civil and common law (Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Levine 2003). German
civil code legal systems are found to be as adaptable as common law systems,
suggesting reform possibilities to policy makers within the civil code legal
tradition.
7. A proxy indicator for the quality of institutions that colonizers established
during the 18th and 19th centuries, introduced by Acemoglu, Johnson, and
Robinson (2001, 2002).
8. That is not to say that contracting institutions are of no importance.
Far from it, as is shown, for example, in Cull and Xu’s (2005) analysis of the
contrasting experience on both of these dimensions in Chinese provinces. They
find that both property rights protection and contract enforcement matter for
firms’ reinvestment decisions.
9. This conjecture is not inconsistent with Acemoglu and Johnson’s (2005)
finding that it is the private contracting institutions that remain significant in
explaining stock market capitalization.
10. Given their heavier reliance on secured lending, it is not surprising that
foreign bank lending increases by even more.
11. This is not to say that reform of bankruptcy code cannot have an important impact, as Gine and Love (2006) show for the case of Colombia. Once
it was reformed, the country’s insolvency system managed to separate viable
from nonviable enterprises, allowing the former to restructure and liquidating
the latter. Further, systems with effective collateral systems and ineffective
insolvency systems can result in severe imbalances in the long term. In practice,
designing the needed reforms requires great attention to detail if they are to
work effectively. For example, practitioners may have to scrutinize such aspects
as the relative priority of secured and unsecured creditors in an insolvency, the
availability of corporate workout solutions, the remuneration of insolvency
professionals, personal liability for officers and directors, discrimination
between local and foreign creditors, stays on the premature dismemberment
of a debtor’s assets, and so on.
12. It is not only intermediaries that can perform the work-around. Fisman
and Love (2003) found evidence that trade credit partly offsets national
weaknesses in financial sector deficiencies; industries with higher dependence
on trade credit financing (measured by the ratio of accounts payable to total
assets) exhibit higher rates of growth in countries with relatively weak financial
institutions.
13. Field and Torero (2006) and Galiani and Schargrodsky (2005) find
similar results for land titling in the cases of Peru and Argentina, respectively.
181
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
In both cases the effect of land titling programs on access to finance was low
or zero. In Peru, Field and Torero explain their finding with the political
economy observation that freshly titled landowners feared less expropriation
from lenders than before.
14. The Brazilian authorities have introduced several shortcuts to allow contracting parties to work around the painfully slow process of enforcing contracts
through the court system, which can take several years. Apart from allowing
payroll deduction of consumer loans, certain contract forms allow for expedited
court procedures or even out-of-court enforcement (Kumar 2005).
15. Tax concessions to boost specific financial markets risk misfiring, because
of the considerable potential for arbitrage. For a discussion and some overall
principles, see Honohan (2003).
16. In this market, licensed lenders visit the borrowers in their homes on a
weekly basis to collect the repayments, typically 3 percent of the initial amount
borrowed over 55 weeks. (Ellison, Collard, and Forster 2006).
17. Pensions represent another area where details of legislative and regulatory design can be crucial. Practitioners have been studying the performance
of innovative regimes such as the one in Chile, and much research still needs
to be done on ensuring that pensioners get value for money and a reasonable
risk-return balance (both in the accumulation and the payout phases) and that
pension funds contribute to the availability of long-term and risk finance to the
private sector (Rocha and Impavido 2006; Rocha and Thorburn 2007).
18. Regulatory design should ensure sufficient certainty around electronic
contracting, protecting customers adequately against fraud and abuse and
aiming for interoperability between the technical platforms of different suppliers. In addition, Porteous (2006) proposes three principles of good regulatory
design if m-finance is to transform the payments environment for low-income
customers in developing countries. First, customer due diligence procedures
for account opening should be risk based and should not unduly prejudice
remote account openings by small customers. Second, customers should be
able at least to make deposits and withdraw cash through agents and remote
points outside of bank branches. Third, adequate provision must be made for
the issuance of e-money by appropriately capitalized and supervised entities,
which are not necessarily banks.
19. A regulatory decision in Brazil to allow limited banking services to be
operated on an agency basis by lottery offices and other bank correspondents
raised similar issues, but in practice this initiative has worked effectively and
has greatly improved access. By 2004 all municipalities in Brazil had some
form of banking service, whereas only 29 percent had access to these services
in 2000; half of the increase was exclusively attributable to correspondents
(Kumar 2005).
182
GOVERNMENT’S ROLE IN FACILITATING ACCESS
20. More generally, the need to make AML-CFT regulations as accessfriendly as possible is recognized by specialists in the field (Hernández-Coss
and others 2005). To do so requires ensuring that these requirements are risk
based and that they therefore do not impose documentation and verification
requirements for low-income customers accessing services that have limited
scope for abuse. Regulatory authorities need to engage with financial service
providers to design services needed by the poor, such as basic bank accounts,
in such a way that they can be safely offered without triggering AML-CFT
concerns.
21. Early evidence with these separate boards suggests a higher entry and
exit rate of listed companies (potentially reflecting the dynamism of the SME
sector), but also lower liquidity, as most of the trading is done by institutional
investors (Yoo 2007).
22. This is the case not least where regulation is in flux in the advanced
economies, as with recent rules on corporate financial information. Low-income
countries in particular should not be made guinea pigs for novel and untested
regulatory ideas that could impose costs. Assessments being carried out by
the World Bank—often in the context of the already mentioned joint World
Bank-IMF Financial Sector Assessment Program, and the wider Reports on
the Observance of Standards and Codes—of the compliance of individual
financial systems with international financial regulations have sought to bear
this potential problem in mind.
23. In the United States, there are no such requirements, but the U.S.
Treasury has negotiated with a wide range of deposit-taking institutions for
the establishment of limited service, low-cost accounts known as electronic
transfer accounts (ETAs), into which federal payments such as Social Security
can be electronically deposited, even for beneficiaries with poor credit histories
(Caskey, Ruiz Duran, and Solo 2006; Claessens 2006). So far, however, only
a tiny fraction of the unbanked beneficiaries of federal payments have opened
such accounts.
24. For example, arranging for money entering the account to trigger automated, direct debit, bill-payment instructions so that payments cannot be made
without money to cover them, a feature still lacking in the basic bank accounts
recently introduced in several countries (Collard and Kempson 2005).
25. Competition policy for payments systems is an especially complex issue:
new technology for retail payments requires novel theoretical analysis of the
resulting two-sided markets involving both merchants and consumers (for an
accessible survey, see Evans and Schmalensee 2005). There can be a tension
between the desirability of achieving scale and network economies (through
cooperation) and keen pricing (through competition). Specialists are still debating optimal competition policy for advanced economies, with practitioners only
beginning to look at the issues for developing countries (Guadamillas 2007).
183
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
26. While protection of small depositors is important, the design of the
financial safety net should minimize moral hazard, thereby reducing risk-shifting behavior from bankers to society at large.
27. Once again these are the responses to the WBES survey. Numerous
firm- and country-level controls were included in the regressions, which used a
sample of about 2,500 firms in 37 countries, and the likely correlation of errors
across firms within countries was carefully taken into account using a clustering technique. The authors also control for each firm’s response to financing
obstacles generally to ensure that what is being measured as corruption is not
just a generalized complaint about lack of access.
28. Indeed, the notion that consumer borrowing decisions are rationally
made is undermined by clear evidence from an interesting experiment conducted recently in South Africa by a large consumer lender. Loan offers with
randomized interest rates were mailed to some 50,000 customers, along with
numerous variants of advertising material. The researchers (Bertrand and
others 2005) found that loan demand was sensitive not only to the quoted
interest rates but to several of the advertising devices. For example, including a
photograph of a woman in the accompanying literature (as opposed to a man)
was, in terms of its influence on loan take-up, equivalent to lowering the rate
of interest by over 4 percentage points a month.
29. Extortionate or predatory behavior is particularly hard to define. In more
than 30 years of operation, the U.K. legislation against “extortionate lending”
led to only 10 successful claims by borrowers. New legislation enacted in 2006
broadens the criteria by which lending may be found “unfair” and thus illegal
(U.K. Department of Trade and Industry 2003).
30. This could happen either by removing the ceiling altogether or by retaining it at a fairly high rate for licensed lenders. In Ireland the annual percentage
rate of 200 percent still applies to licensed money lenders (compared with the
traditional ceiling of 23 percent for unlicensed lenders). The 200 percent ceiling appears to be constraining at very short maturities for the main lenders in
the high-risk market but not for maturities of several months or more (U.K.
Competition Commission 2006). Of course much higher interest rates (in the
millions of percent per year) have been documented all over the world in illegal
or unregulated lending to unfortunate individuals.
31. Such requirements should not be too draconian, as where unfavorable
registration on the national credit registry is enough to exclude a borrower
from future loans.
32. Using an eight-year bank-level dataset for over 100 countries Micco,
Panizza, and Yañez (2007) confirm that state-owned banks in developing countries are less profitable than privately owned banks because of lower margins and
higher overhead costs, even after controlling for the dynamics of ownership over
time, most notably regarding privatization. The relationship is much weaker in
184
GOVERNMENT’S ROLE IN FACILITATING ACCESS
developed countries. Of special interest is the finding that state-owned banks
report higher profits in years of economic expansion compared to privatelyowned banks, but they are much less profitable in election years, a result which,
because it is driven by differences in net interest margins rather than overhead
costs, points to loan losses (or debt forgiveness) in those years.
33. Even the U.S. Community Reinvestment Act may have had little effect,
at least in its early years. Introduced in 1977, this law is sometimes pointed to
as an example of a well-functioning directed credit program. Banks are rated
on their “efforts in determining community credit needs, marketing credit,
participating in community development, maintaining branch offices and
avoiding discriminatory credit policies” in low-income neighborhoods. But,
at least before 1997–98, they were not assessed on whether they actually lent
more to target groups. Indeed, Dahl, Evanoff, and Spivey (2000) found that
banks whose performance under the law was downgraded did not respond by
increasing the share of their lending to target groups.
34. Cole analyzed the allocation of agricultural credit from governmentowned banks in India and found a strong suggestion of political influence.
Across a sample of 412 districts in 19 Indian states in each year 1992–99 , and
including 32 elections, he finds that not only did credit increase in election
years but the election-year credit surge was greatest in the districts most closely
contested. Given that it is state-level governments that appoint members of the
coordinating committee for lending practices and policies, political pressure
can be coming from different parties in different states even in the same year,
a feature of the data that helped pinpoint likely political effects.
35. Using a sample of 22 developing countries with 10 banks from each
country over the period 1993–2000, Dinç found that in the months before
elections, government-owned banks increase their lending—and the amount
of loans restructured or overdue—relative to privately owned banks. This suggests not only politically motivated lending at government-owned banks but
also loan forgiveness before elections.
36. Khwaja and Mian analyzed all 112,685 business loan accounts at banks
in Pakistan during 1996–2002 and uncovered strong circumstantial evidence
of corruption at state-owned banks. The loan files contained the names of the
borrowing companies’ directors, which allowed the authors to link them with
the names of all of the candidates in the 1993 and 1997 general elections.
Fully one-quarter of the candidates were directors of borrowing firms. More
important, their firms borrowed more, paid lower interest rates, and defaulted
more often (a 24 percent default rate, compared with a 6 percent for others,
even after inclusion of firm-level control variables). These effects proved to be
entirely attributable to borrowing from state-owned banks—implying sizable
fiscal costs as well as the costs from misallocation of investable funds—and
they were larger, the more electorally successful the politician. The effects are
smaller in districts with a healthier democratic process, as measured by voter
turnout.
185
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
37. See World Bank (2001) and Hanson (2004) for other reviews of the
experience with state-owned banks.
38. For some examples related to financial access, see http://www.ifc.org/
ifcext/sme.nsf/Content/Publications.
39. Also see Duflo and Kremer (2005) for a discussion of the relative merits
of randomized evaluation and competitors such as propensity score testing and
the difference-in-difference methods for estimating the partial equilibrium
effects on beneficiaries of direct policy interventions.
40. The analysis of credit guarantee schemes displays some similarities
and some contrasts with that of deposit insurance schemes (Demirgüç-Kunt
and Kane 2002). In both types of schemes, the benefits of expanding access
have to be balanced with the moral hazard risk. Perhaps the main difference
is that coverage of a credit guarantee scheme can be credibly limited, whereas
deposit insurance guarantees tend to be extended to all depositors, especially
in a crisis. In addition, pricing and other features of credit guarantees can
more easily be made realistically risk-related. For example a sizable degree of
coinsurance is the norm with credit guarantees, and coverage can vary. But,
as is argued in the text, just as with deposit insurance, success is less likely in
poor institutional environments.
41. Curiously, the large, publicly funded SHG-bank linkage program in
India, which provides subsidized refinancing (by NABARD) of bank loans
to self-help groups, directly benefiting about 14 million households, offers no
loan-loss guarantee to the bank.
42. For example, government interventions in every one of the 25 EU
member states involve subsidies or fiscal outlays, according to Dorn (2005);
47 EU schemes are reviewed by Gracey (2001).
43. Note, however, that this line of reasoning is more specific than is often
portrayed. Depending on the exact nature of project risks and of the information asymmetries between lenders and borrowers, there might even be more
lending than is socially optimal (DeMeza and Webb 1987; Besley 1994). The
successful operation of MFIs that charge high interest rates shows that this
problem is not decisive in all markets.
44. Even in the United Kingdom, the stated purpose of the government’s
Small Firms’ Loan Guarantee (SFLG) scheme has been simply the limited,
instrumental one of assisting “SMEs who have a viable business plan but lack
the collateral necessary to secure the loan that they seek.”
45. Even the U.S. Small Business Administration’s (SBA) long-established SME
guarantee scheme (the so-called section 7a scheme) has been criticized for poor
underwriting loss estimates (U.S. General Accounting Office 2001). Curiously,
186
GOVERNMENT’S ROLE IN FACILITATING ACCESS
though, the SBA erred on the conservative side in this matter; its actual underwriting losses turned out to be considerably lower than had been budgeted.
46. The highly regarded Chilean FOGAPE scheme has increased its
annual charge to between 1 and 2 percent of the loan amount depending
on the claims performance of participating banks; to date, the charges have
been sufficient to cover the administrative expenses of the scheme as well as
claims (Benavente, Galetovic, and Sanhueza 2006; De la Torre, Gozzi, and
Schmukler 2007). Schemes in Malaysia and Thailand have also required very
little subsidy over the years. The long-running SBA section 7a program in the
United States entails a one-time subsidy of only about 1.3 percent of the value
of the guaranteed loans, including provision for calls on the guarantee and
operating expenses. The annual subsidy for the Italian SGS system grew to
about 1 percent by 2004. Other programs have had higher costs. The charges
of between 0.5 and 4 percent of the sum guaranteed by Mexican schemes cover
only about half of the operating costs and underwriting losses (Benavides and
Huidobro 2005). The very large Korean KCGF charges between 0.5 percent
and 2 percent depending on the borrower’s credit rating, with an average of
just over 1 percent, but this revenue covers only a fifth of the scheme’s outlays.
Indeed the two major Korean schemes operated at a loss of almost 4 percent
a year of the stock of outstanding guarantees in 2001–5 (Shim 2006). Over
the years, the (much smaller) U.K. SFLG scheme—which charges an annual
2 percent fee—had experienced defaults on more than one in three of its guaranteed loans, requiring a subsidy amounting in a recent year to 15 percent of
gross new guarantees in that year (Graham 2004).
47. One recent attempt to use quantitative information to estimate additionality is Zecchini and Ventura (2006), who compare data on some 4,000
Italian firms eligible for the SGS guarantee scheme and 6,000 controls—firms
that were not eligible because of their sector. Estimating a regression equation
explaining the level of bank borrowing by firm in terms of the firm’s number of
employees, sales, tangible and intangible assets, nonbank debt, net worth, and
net earnings, they find that, even after taking account of eligibility (using an
instrumental variables technique), a firm’s use of SGS guarantees is associated
with a modestly higher level of bank borrowing (about 10–13 percent). Another
econometric effort was made by KPMG Management Consulting (1999), but
it looked only at assisted borrowers and did not include a control group.
48. The key natural experiment allowing identification of the effect of subsidized export credit was the removal of one important sector, cotton yarn, from
eligibility for subsidy. Apparently the authorities wanted to concentrate available
funds on export sectors with higher value added. The cotton yarn sector, which
had accounted for over half of the 100,000 individual loans made in the scheme
between 1998 and 2003, survived this removal with output and exports almost
unaffected. While some smaller, unlisted firms without multiple banking relationships were hit by the change, the larger firms just saw a reduction in their
profits. An estimated one-half of the subsidized funds had gone to financially
187
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
unconstrained firms that did not need it. Interestingly, it was not systematically
the less-productive firms that were hit by the removal of the subsidy.
49. A third form is the wholesale guarantee of, for example, a bond issue by
a specialized SME lender, a securitization of the underlying loans, or a block
loan to a specialized lender by another intermediary. The Italian SGS provides
counterguarantees on a wholesale basis to mutual guarantee associations for
bank loans of their members. Accion International has had many years of experience on a cross-country basis in wholesale guarantees of facilities provided
to its local affiliates.
50. This can be seen as an application of the increasingly fashionable idea of
auctioning a block of subsidy funds to the highest bidder. In finance, the risk
that the beneficiary will ultimately default, thereby eventually paying much
less than she promised, makes auctioning of rather limited application. It can
work in the case at hand, where the block of funds and the subsidy involved is
only a small part of the bidder’s business.
51. Chinese guarantee funds, some of which are publicly backed but result
from regulatory arbitrage, were estimated to cover loans amounting to 2.6
percent of GDP in 2005 (Shim 2006).
52. Sometimes such measures can also be undermined by judicial decisions,
as is illustrated by the case of payroll loans in Brazil, which were declared
unconstitutional by a court, leading to higher borrowing costs (Costa and de
Mello 2006).
53. The study of Braun and Raddatz (2007) provides an excellent example
of this. Distinguishing between economic sectors that are more or less likely
to favor financial liberalization, the authors were able to show that in countries
in which the economic power of the former grew (as a result of trade liberalization), subsequent financial deepening was faster.
54. Specifically, Kroszner and Strahan (1999) examined the removal of
restrictions on branch banking. They trace the origin of these restrictions to
the interest that 19th century state governments had in creating local banking
monopolies that could be taxed. Resistance in the 20th century to deregulation
came from the incumbent small banks, and indeed it was the states with many
small banks that deregulated last.
55. They constructed an indicator of financial liberalization encompassing
credit and interest rate controls, entry barriers, restrictive regulations, government ownership, and restrictions on international financial transactions.
56. From cross-country evidence from 38 countries they find that greater
political accountability is associated with higher entry in sectors that are more
dependent on external capital and have greater growth opportunities.
188
Data Appendix
TABLES A.1 TO A.7 PRESENT DATA COLLECTED FOR AND USED IN THIS
book and its background papers on indicators of use of, access to, and
bariers to financial services. The data are also available at http://econ
.worldbank.org/programs/finance.
189
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Table A.1 Composite measure of access to financial services
Percent
with access
Albania
Algeria
Angola
Antigua and Barbuda
Argentina
Armenia
Austria
Azerbaijan
Bahamas, The
Bangladesh
Barbados
Belarus
Belgium
Belize
Benin
Bermuda
Bhutan
Bolivia
Bosnia and Herzegovina
Botswana
Brazil
Bulgaria
Burkina Faso
Burundi
Cambodia
Cameroon
Canada
Cape Verde
190
s
s
s
s
s
s
s
34
31
25
48
28
9
96
17
53
32
56
16
97
46
32
48
16
30
17
47
43
56
26
17
20
24
96
40
Percent
with access
Gambia, The
Georgia
Germany
Ghana
Greece
Grenada
Guatemala
Guinea
Guyana
Haiti
Honduras
Hungary
India
Indonesia
Iran, Islamic Rep. of
Iraq
Ireland
Italy
Jamaica
Jordan
Kazakhstan
Kenya
Korea, Rep. of
Kyrgyz Republic
Latvia
Lesotho
Liberia
Libya
s
s
s
s
s
s
s
s
s
s
21
15
97
16
83
37
32
20
20
15
25
66
48
40
31
17
88
75
59
37
48
10
63
14
64
17
11
27
Percent
with access
Panama
Papua New Guinea
Paraguay
Peru
Philippines
Poland
Portugal
Romania
Russian Federation
Rwanda
Samoa
Saudi Arabia
São Tomé and Principe
Senegal
Seychelles
Sierra Leone
Singapore
Slovak Republic
Slovenia
Solomon Islands
South Africa
Spain
Sri Lanka
St. Kitts and Nevis
St. Lucia
St. Vincent
Sudan
Suriname
s
s
s
s
s
s
s
46
8
30
26
26
66
84
23
69
23
19
62
15
27
41
13
98
83
97
15
46
95
59
49
40
45
15
32
APPENDIX
Table A.1 Composite measure of access to financial services (continued)
Central African Republic
Chile
China
Colombia
Comoros
Congo, Rep. Of
Costa Rica
Cote d’Ivoire
Croatia
Cuba
Cyprus
Czech Republic
Denmark
Dominica
Dominican Republic
Ecuador
Egypt, Arab. Rep. of
El Salvador
Eritrea
Estonia
Ethiopia
Fiji
Finland
France
Gabon
s
s
s
s
s
s
s
s
s
s
19
60
42
41
20
27
29
25
42
45
85
85
99
66
29
35
41
26
12
86
14
39
99
96
39
Lithuania
Luxembourg
Macedonia, FYR
Madagascar
Malawi
Malaysia
Mali
Malta
Mauritius
Mexico
Moldova
Mongolia
Morocco
Mozambique
Myanmar
Namibia
Nepal
Netherlands
Nicaragua
Niger
Nigeria
Norway
Oman
Pakistan
s
s
s
s
s
s
s
70
99
20
21
21
60
22
90
54
25
13
25
28
12
19
28
20
100
5
31
15
84
33
12
Swaziland
Sweden
Switzerland
Syrian Arab Rep.
Tajikistan
Tanzania
Thailand
Togo
Trinidad andTobago
Tunisia
Turkey
Uganda
Ukraine
United Kingdom
United States
Uruguay
Uzbekistan
Venezuela, R. B. de
Vietnam
West Bank and Gaza
Yemen, Republic of
Yugoslavia, former
Zambia
Zimbabwe
s
s
s
s
s
35
99
88
17
16
5
59
28
53
42
49
20
24
91
91
42
16
28
29
14
14
21
15
34
Note: The composite indicator measures the percentage of the adult population with access to an account with a financial intermediary.
The indicator is constructed as follows: for any country with data on access from a household survey, the surveyed percentage is given
and designated by an s. For other countries, the percentage is constructed as a function of the estimated number and average size of bank
accounts, as discussed in box 1.4 and Honohan (2007). These numbers are subject to estimation error. This is a “live” data set, and figures
will be replaced as survey data become available for each country. See http://econ.worldbank.org/programs/finance for updates.
191
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Table A.2
Use of loan and deposit services across economies
Albania
Argentina
Armenia
Austria
Bangladesh
Belgium
Bolivia
Bosnia and
Herzegovina
Brazil
Bulgaria
Chile
Colombia
Czech Republic
Denmark
Dominican
Republic
Ecuador
El Salvador
Fiji
France
Greece
Guatemala
Guyana
Honduras
Iran, Islamic Rep. of
Israel
Italy
Jordan
Kenya
Lebanon
Lithuania
Madagascar
Malaysia
Malta
192
Loan
accounts
per capita
(number)
Depositincome ratio
Ratio of
private credit
to GDP
(average 1999
to 2003)
GDP per
capita,
2003 ($)
161.25
368.73
111.38
3,119.95
228.75
3,080.31
40.63
429.40
2.75
0.58
1.00
0.26
1.60
0.38
5.81
1.87
—
0.205
0.076
1.025
0.245
0.773
0.558
—
1,933
3,381
915
31,202
376
29,205
894
1,682
6.18
4.24
1.6
—
—
2.09
6.71
630.86
1,351.37
1,044.82
612.21
1,922.83
2,706.07
719.52
0.40
0.26
0.46
0.42
0.42
0.22
0.10
0.346
0.149
0.694
0.262
0.424
1.100
0.335
2,788
2,538
4,591
1,747
8,375
39,429
1,821
2.63
0.39
4.75
—
0.83
3.19
—
6.13
2.91
1.58
2.35
8.2
—
9.13
3.65
18.35
2.95
6.24
419.54
456.69
444.42
1,800.84
2,417.64
403.54
571.03
287.27
2,249.28
—
975.64
465.48
69.98
382.53
1,166.45
14.46
1,250.10
2,495.81
0.63
0.12
1.13
0.40
0.29
0.55
1.37
0.74
0.04
—
0.47
1.41
6.26
6.65
0.21
9.31
0.92
1.22
0.353
0.047
0.322
0.857
0.546
0.189
—
0.388
0.281
0.859
0.750
0.721
0.258
—
0.128
0.081
1.352
1.083
2,066
2,204
2,696
29,267
16,203
2,009
965
1,001
2,061
16,686
25,429
1,858
434
4,224
5,273
323
4,164
9,699
Loanincome ratio
Deposit
accounts
per capita
(number)
4.42
154.19
41.23
647.64
54.73
59.47
9.53
114.09
15.41
1.77
1.93
1.84
5.22
21.09
27.89
3.19
49.59
73.85
417.74
—
—
450.99
50.10
77.09
126.89
67.09
—
776.48
45.79
—
67.27
48.19
709.90
328.15
80.39
—
93.42
58.86
4.38
328.97
407.21
APPENDIX
Table A.2
Use of loan and deposit services across economies (continued)
Mauritius
Mexico
Namibia
Nicaragua
Norway
Pakistan
Panama
Papua New Guinea
Peru
Philippines
Poland
Romania
Russian Federation
Saudi Arabia
Singapore
Spain
Switzerland
Thailand
Trinidad and
Tobago
Turkey
Uganda
Venezuela, R. B. de
West Bank and Gaza
Zimbabwe
Loan
accounts
per capita
(number)
Depositincome ratio
Ratio of
private credit
to GDP
(average 1999
to 2003)
GDP per
capita,
2003 ($)
1,585.99
309.57
422.96
96.12
1,610.78
191.84
—
119.77
316.19
302.05
—
1,207.88
1,892.28
214.13
1,670.88
2,075.96
1,985.84
1,423.12
1,073.48
0.53
0.46
1.27
4.70
0.23
2.63
—
2.48
0.74
1.77
—
0.25
0.07
2.28
1.62
0.44
0.29
0.83
0.35
0.559
0.181
0.438
0.424
0.870
0.260
0.922
0.147
0.248
0.405
0.265
0.073
—
0.554
1.159
0.992
1.589
1.044
0.404
4,265
6,121
2,312
748
48,592
464
4,328
617
2,247
989
5,487
2,719
3,022
8,366
21,492
20,343
42,138
2,309
7,769
1,114.23
46.64
486.74
253.99
173.56
0.68
3.93
0.48
4.91
7.98
0.171
0.051
0.110
—
0.235
3,365
245
3,319
1,026
634
Loanincome ratio
Deposit
accounts
per capita
(number)
207.13
—
80.74
95.61
—
21.93
297.84
—
77.92
—
773.87
—
54.11
47.45
513.23
556.48
—
247.87
—
2.75
—
5.16
2.49
—
14.26
5.32
—
2.45
—
0.33
—
4.23
7.73
3.84
1.91
—
4.56
—
264.51
5.79
93.04
50.15
—
0.65
10.74
1.02
8.25
—
Note: Reported indicators are based on data collected through a survey of bank regulators, as discussed in box 1.4 and Beck, DemirgüçKunt, and Martinez Peria (2007b). Loan (deposit) accounts per capita refer to the number of loans (deposits) per 1,000 people. Loan
(deposit)-income ratio refers to the average size of loans (deposits) per GDP per capita. The survey questions asked are: “How many loans
are there in your country right now that have been issued by deposit money banks? (Please include loans from deposit money banks to
individuals, businesses and others, including home mortgages, consumer loans, business loans, trade loans, student loans, emergency
loans, agricultural loans, etc.),” “What is the total value of these loans? (Please specify currency and units.),” “How many deposit accounts
are there at deposit money banks in your country right now? (Please include all current (checking) accounts, savings accounts, and time
deposits for businesses, individuals, and others.),” and “What is the total value of these deposits? (Please specify currency and units.).”
Private credit to GDP is the ratio of claims of financial institutions on the private sector to GDP and is obtained from the World Bank
Financial Structure and Economic Development Database. GDP per capita is in US$ and is taken from World Development Indicators.
Data are available at http://econ.worldbank.org/programs/finance. — = data not available.
193
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Table A.3 Branch and ATM penetration across economies
Albania
Argentina
Armenia
Australia
Austria
Azerbaijan
Bahrain
Bangladesh
Belarus
Belgium
Belize
Bolivia
Bosnia and
Herzegovina
Botswana
Brazil
Bulgaria
Canada
Chile
China
Colombia
Costa Rica
Croatia
Czech Republic
Denmark
Dominican Republic
Ecuador
Egypt, Arab Rep. of
El Salvador
Estonia
Ethiopia
Fiji
Finland
France
Georgia
Germany
Ghana
Greece
Guatemala
Guyana
194
Demographic Ratio of private
credit to GDP GDP per
ATM
(average 1999
capita,
penetration
2003 ($)
to 2003)
(number)
Geographic
branch
penetration
(number)
Demographic
branch
penetration
(number)
Geographic
ATM
penetration
(number)
2.45
1.40
8.23
0.77
52.47
3.90
135.21
47.46
2.28
181.65
1.67
0.13
3.15
2.11
10.01
7.59
29.86
53.87
4.11
13.48
4.47
4.79
53.15
14.67
1.53
3.86
2.74
2.09
1.49
1.66
84.95
—
269.01
0.61
2.41
229.28
—
0.40
4.38
2.37
14.91
1.37
64.18
87.21
—
26.83
0.06
5.06
67.09
—
4.80
5.36
—
0.205
0.076
0.879
1.025
—
0.576
0.245
0.070
0.773
0.543
0.558
—
1,933
3,381
915
26,062
31,202
865
10,791
376
1,770
29,205
3,583
894
1,682
0.11
3.05
9.81
1.56
1.98
1.83
3.74
7.52
18.62
14.73
47.77
10.83
4.38
2.45
14.58
4.85
0.28
2.52
3.26
46.94
2.32
116.90
1.43
25.53
11.49
0.12
3.77
14.59
13.87
45.60
9.39
1.33
8.74
9.59
23.36
11.15
37.63
6.00
9.30
3.62
4.62
15.19
0.41
5.51
19.06
43.23
3.14
49.41
1.60
30.81
10.12
3.12
0.27
3.72
21.09
4.64
5.06
5.25
4.10
10.07
31.96
25.84
66.51
27.24
2.97
1.21
34.89
18.43
—
5.69
13.55
76.33
0.86
144.68
—
39.39
22.93
0.25
9.00
17.82
29.79
135.23
24.03
3.80
9.60
12.83
40.10
19.57
52.39
15.08
6.32
1.78
11.07
57.7
—
12.46
79.21
70.30
1.17
61.16
—
47.55
20.20
6.50
0.163
0.346
0.149
0.967
0.694
1.236
0.262
0.240
0.416
0.424
1.100
0.335
0.353
0.579
0.047
0.248
0.294
0.322
0.558
0.857
—
1.178
—
0.546
0.189
—
4,290
2,788
2,538
26,380
4,591
1,094
1,747
4,365
6,356
8,375
39,429
1,821
2,066
1,220
2,204
6,210
97
2,696
31,007
29,267
768
29,081
375
16,203
2,009
965
APPENDIX
Table A.3 Branch and ATM penetration across economies (continued)
Honduras
Hungary
India
Indonesia
Iran, Islamic Rep. of
Ireland
Israel
Italy
Japan
Jordan
Kazakhstan
Korea, Rep. of
Kuwait
Kyrgyz Republic
Lebanon
Lithuania
Madagascar
Malaysia
Malta
Mauritius
Mexico
Namibia
Nepal
Netherlands
New Zealand
Nicaragua
Nigeria
Norway
Pakistan
Panama
Papua New Guinea
Peru
Philippines
Poland
Portugal
Romania
Russian Federation
Saudi Arabia
Singapore
Slovak Republic
Geographic
branch
penetration
(number)
Demographic
branch
penetration
(number)
0.46
31.04
22.57
10.00
3.40
13.41
47.82
102.05
34.82
5.98
0.14
65.02
11.05
0.82
79.18
1.81
0.19
7.39
375.00
71.92
4.09
0.11
2.96
163.81
4.19
1.29
2.41
3.41
9.10
5.16
0.20
0.89
21.40
10.25
57.45
13.26
0.19
0.56
636.07
11.33
0.73
28.25
6.30
8.44
8.39
23.41
14.74
52.07
9.98
10.02
2.47
13.40
8.27
3.11
18.01
3.39
0.66
9.80
30.08
11.92
7.63
4.47
1.72
34.23
28.04
2.85
1.62
22.92
4.73
12.87
1.64
4.17
7.83
8.17
51.58
13.76
2.24
5.36
9.13
10.28
Geographic
ATM
penetration
(number)
2.22
32.30
—
5.73
0.51
27.78
61.01
131.71
396.98
5.60
0.39
436.88
26.32
—
73.90
15.34
0.07
12.40
462.50
133.00
8.91
0.30
0.15
223.02
7.53
1.18
—
—
1.02
6.49
—
1.24
14.52
21.72
121.50
12.02
0.53
1.54
2,642.62
32.21
Demographic Ratio of private
credit to GDP GDP per
ATM
(average 1999
capita,
penetration
2003 ($)
to 2003)
(number)
3.56
29.40
—
4.84
1.25
48.49
18.81
67.20
113.75
9.38
7.01
90.03
19.69
—
16.81
28.78
0.22
16.44
37.09
22.04
16.63
12.11
0.09
46.60
50.36
2.61
—
—
0.53
16.19
—
5.85
5.31
17.31
109.09
12.47
6.28
14.70
37.93
29.21
0.388
0.309
0.277
0.236
0.281
1.020
0.859
0.750
1.115
0.721
0.125
1.197
0.644
0.041
—
0.128
0.081
1.352
1.083
0.559
0.181
0.438
0.272
1.407
1.101
0.424
0.136
0.870
0.260
0.922
0.147
0.248
0.405
0.265
1.318
0.073
—
0.554
1.159
0.441
1,001
8,182
563
971
2,061
37,637
16,686
25,429
34,010
1,858
1,995
12,634
14,848
344
4,224
5,273
323
4,164
9,699
4,265
6,121
2,312
237
31,548
19,021
748
370
48,592
464
4,328
617
2,247
989
5,487
14,665
2,719
3,022
8,366
21,492
5,922
(continued)
195
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Table A.3 Branch and ATM penetration across economies (continued)
Slovenia
South Africa
Spain
Sri Lanka
Sweden
Switzerland
Tanzania
Thailand
Trinidad and Tobago
Turkey
Uganda
Ukraine
United Kingdom
United States
Uruguay
Venezuela, R. B. de
West Bank and Gaza
Zambia
Zimbabwe
Geographic
branch
penetration
(number)
Demographic
branch
penetration
(number)
Geographic
ATM
penetration
(number)
2.14
2.22
78.90
20.41
4.74
70.54
0.23
8.71
23.59
7.81
0.67
—
45.16
9.81
1.23
1.28
18.33
0.21
1.11
2.19
5.99
95.87
6.87
21.80
37.99
0.57
7.18
9.22
8.50
0.53
—
18.35
30.86
6.39
4.41
3.27
1.52
3.27
64.56
6.49
104.18
10.91
6.43
131.10
0.07
20.69
52.44
16.54
0.90
0.78
104.46
38.43
—
4.81
18.17
0.09
1.15
Demographic Ratio of private
credit to GDP GDP per
ATM
(average 1999
capita,
penetration
2003 ($)
to 2003)
(number)
66.14
17.50
126.60
3.67
29.56
70.60
0.17
17.05
20.49
18.00
0.70
0.93
42.45
120.94
—
16.60
3.24
0.65
3.38
0.352
0.689
0.992
0.274
0.830
1.589
—
1.044
0.404
0.171
0.051
—
1.301
1.628
0.517
0.110
—
—
0.235
13,383
3,530
20,343
965
33,586
42,138
275
2,309
7,769
3,365
245
1,024
30,278
37,388
3,308
3,319
1,026
413
634
Note: Reported indicators are based on data collected through a survey of bank regulators, as discussed in box 1.4 and Beck, DemirgüçKunt, and Martinez Peria (2007b). Geographic branch (ATM) penetration refers to the number of branches (ATMs) per 1,000 square
kilometers. Demographic branch (ATM) penetration refers to the number of branches (ATMs) per 100,000 people. The questions
asked were: “How many bank branches do deposit money banks have (combined for all banks) in your country?” “How many ATMs
(automated cash withdrawal machines) are there in your country?” Private credit to GDP is the ratio of claims of financial institutions
on the private sector to GDP and is obtained from the World Bank Financial Structure and Economic Development Database. GDP per
capita is in US$ and is taken from World Development Indicators. Data are available at http://econ.worldbank.org/programs/finance.
— = data not available.
196
Table A.4 Barriers to deposit services
DEPOSITS
Physical access
Eligibility
Locations
to open
deposit
account
(out of 3)
Minimum
amount
to open
checking
account
(% of
GDPPC)
Minimum
amount
to open
savings
account
(% of
GDPPC)
91.42
17.90
59.63
32.59
56.98
74.58
72.56
58.04
64.04
2.73
1.59
1.81
2.59
2.00
2.71
2.00
2.00
2.60
0.85
4.85
10.97
0.00
2.28
0.00
0.00
17.40
0.04
6.08
2.85
15.25
0.00
0.89
0.04
0.00
0.81
0.04
0.85
0.00
10.56
0.00
2.28
0.00
0.00
25.44
0.19
6.08
0.00
15.25
0.00
0.79
0.00
0.00
3.93
0.15
0.19
2.06
0.35
0.16
0.00
0.00
0.09
0.83
0.34
0.39
1.13
0.00
0.10
0.00
0.00
0.00
1.78
0.35
1.00
3.41
2.85
3.00
4.57
1.44
1.80
2.53
1.74
1.00
2.00
2.19
3.00
4.57
1.00
1.80
2.33
1.34
4
3
5
2
2
5
4
2
64.35
34.87
83.83
35.50
23.33
50.48
63.42
43.00
2.44
2.02
1.88
2.42
3.00
1.93
2.63
2.00
0.00
0.59
116.39
4.33
0.00
8.78
0.00
0.23
0.10
0.88
68.26
0.00
0.01
1.22
1.19
1.41
0.00
0.59
55.88
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.91
64.75
0.00
0.00
0.18
0.00
1.24
0.81
0.14
7.87
3.38
0.00
0.78
0.07
0.26
0.03
0.00
1.22
0.42
0.00
0.56
0.00
0.00
2.67
1.72
4.00
4.42
1.00
3.08
2.16
1.00
2.16
1.72
3.11
1.58
1.00
2.25
2.00
1.00
2
2
72.71
39.27
2.32
2.67
0.00
2.94
0.00
0.70
0.00
0.58
0.00
0.41
0.09
0.66
0.00
0.00
1.32
2.66
1.32
1.99
2
32.05
2.00
0.35
0.00
0.18
0.18
0.40
0.07
2.00
1.00
4
2
3
93.73
26.23
—
1.92
1.46
1.83
55.41
0.00
141.84
5.50
0.03
70.92
6.04
0.00
6.96
5.11
0.03
8.70
0.00
0.00
3.39
0.00
0.00
0.00
3.77
2.00
4.00
2.14
2.00
3.83
Number
of banks
responding
Deposit
market share
(respondents
share out of
total system)
2004
5
2
4
2
5
3
3
4
4
Minimum
amount
to be
maintained
in savings
account
(% of
GDPPC)
Annual
Annual
fees
fees
checking savings
account
account
(% of
(% of
GDPPC) GDPPC)
Number
Number
of
of
documents documents
to open
to open
checking
savings
account
account
(out of 5) (out of 5)
(continued)
197
APPENDIX
Albania
Argentina
Armenia
Australia
Bangladesh
Belarus
Belgium
Bolivia
Bosnia and
Herzegovina
Brazil
Bulgaria
Cameroon
Chile
China
Colombia
Croatia
Czech
Republic
Denmark
Dominican
Republic
Egypt, Arab
Rep. of
Ethiopia
France
Gabon
Affordability
Minimum
amount
to be
maintained
in checking
account
(% of
GDPPC)
DEPOSITS
Physical access
Georgia
Germany
Ghana
Greece
Hungary
India
Indonesia
Iran, Islamic
Rep. of
Israel
Italy
Japan
Jordan
Kenya
Korea, Rep. of
Lebanon
Lithuania
Madagascar
Malawi
Malta
Mexico
Moldova
Mozambique
Nepal
Nigeria
Pakistan
Affordability
Locations
to open
deposit
account
(out of 3)
Minimum
amount
to open
checking
account
(% of
GDPPC)
Minimum
amount
to open
savings
account
(% of
GDPPC)
85.71
31.91
69.49
56.92
53.09
36.87
44.73
29.86
2.56
2.65
2.15
1.21
2.53
2.00
2.53
2.06
0.00
0.00
22.69
0.64
0.14
8.85
9.54
0.03
33.18
0.01
21.89
1.27
2.04
5.02
3.03
0.59
0.00
0.00
0.09
0.64
0.00
5.83
6.14
0.03
8.09
0.00
11.99
1.27
0.82
5.02
0.65
0.30
0.33
0.26
5.90
0.02
0.17
0.00
2.80
0.00
0.33
0.00
0.58
0.02
0.00
0.17
0.66
0.00
1.66
1.74
3.62
2.53
1.55
2.69
3.18
3.53
1.78
1.74
3.24
2.26
1.00
2.55
2.66
3.53
36.17
22.79
29.63
83.61
43.82
68.95
38.00
88.87
72.44
82.36
44.56
48.95
40.16
48.78
37.86
32.22
47.50
2.00
2.14
1.75
1.93
2.78
2.11
1.58
2.71
1.95
2.00
2.00
2.18
3.00
2.00
2.34
2.44
2.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
16.55
11.71
3.32
4.22
0.00
38.86
0.00
0.22
1.11
0.00
29.61
90.66
106.42
1.59
0.00
0.00
0.00
5.34
44.30
0.01
23.98
1.45
19.35
17.89
0.71
0.62
13.13
15.71
63.39
22.07
1.59
0.00
0.17
0.66
1.73
0.00
0.00
4.22
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.90
0.00
14.19
123.77
0.00
0.33
0.00
0.17
0.00
0.87
41.82
0.01
23.98
1.55
17.59
17.89
0.68
0.67
8.26
7.20
73.83
1.96
0.71
0.04
0.40
0.02
0.00
12.82
0.06
1.96
0.01
5.15
21.98
0.00
0.43
0.53
11.56
8.28
0.05
0.00
0.00
0.21
0.00
0.00
2.07
0.00
1.90
0.00
0.00
3.63
0.00
0.18
0.00
0.30
4.97
0.00
0.00
1.22
1.67
2.03
2.04
3.78
1.94
2.54
1.59
2.94
3.65
3.17
2.80
2.31
1.00
4.11
3.66
2.64
1.00
1.67
1.24
2.04
2.86
1.20
2.36
1.00
2.71
2.84
3.07
2.18
2.06
1.00
3.92
1.99
2.43
Number
of banks
responding
Deposit
market share
(respondents
share out of
total system)
2004
5
3
4
3
3
4
4
2
2
4
4
3
3
6
3
5
5
3
4
3
3
2
5
3
3
Minimum
amount
to be
maintained
in savings
account
(% of
GDPPC)
Eligibility
Minimum
amount
to be
maintained
in checking
account
(% of
GDPPC)
Number
Number
Annual
Annual
of
of
fees
fees
documents documents
checking savings
to open
to open
account
account
checking
savings
(% of
(% of
account
account
GDPPC) GDPPC) (out of 5) (out of 5)
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
198
Table A.4 Barriers to deposit services (continued)
Table A.4 Barriers to deposit services (continued)
DEPOSITS
Physical access
Peru
Philippines
Poland
Romania
Sierra Leone
Slovak
Republic
Slovenia
South Africa
Spain
Sri Lanka
Sweden
Switzerland
Thailand
Trinidad and
Tobago
Tunisia
Turkey
Uganda
United
Kingdom
Uruguay
Venezuela,
R. B. de
Zambia
Zimbabwe
Affordability
Eligibility
Locations
to open
deposit
account
(out of 3)
Minimum
amount
to open
checking
account
(% of
GDPPC)
Minimum
amount
to open
savings
account
(% of
GDPPC)
Minimum
amount
to be
maintained
in checking
account
(% of
GDPPC)
81.88
41.84
28.65
35.01
100.00
58.12
2.00
2.00
2.53
2.30
1.42
2.08
1.66
14.54
0.00
0.03
51.63
0.12
0.53
11.88
0.00
0.71
44.89
0.79
0.00
14.54
0.00
0.02
8.81
0.10
0.00
11.88
—
0.18
43.56
0.79
1.44
0.00
0.24
0.40
26.63
0.18
0.50
0.00
0.00
0.23
0.00
0.01
2.42
3.17
1.00
1.28
4.02
1.47
1.87
2.20
2.00
1.00
3.88
1.51
5
3
4
3
2
2
3
3
67.48
70.09
63.75
52.19
39.47
79.57
38.36
40.15
1.50
2.27
1.53
1.80
1.66
2.00
2.48
2.00
0.01
0.00
0.00
15.76
0.00
0.00
6.74
1.37
0.03
1.06
0.00
3.54
0.01
0.00
0.41
0.42
0.01
0.00
0.00
4.77
0.00
0.00
0.31
1.28
0.02
0.28
0.00
0.84
0.00
0.00
0.31
0.49
0.17
2.13
0.19
0.73
0.00
0.08
1.29
0.35
0.00
0.91
0.04
0.00
0.00
0.00
1.29
0.00
1.88
3.45
1.00
2.62
1.00
1.14
1.23
4.29
1.88
3.07
1.00
1.00
1.00
1.14
1.23
3.07
2
3
3
2
29.65
50.14
59.27
17.46
2.49
2.20
2.00
3.00
7.96
0.00
51.12
0.22
0.23
0.00
48.62
0.002
0.00
0.00
1.73
0.002
0.23
0.00
29.52
0.002
0.59
0.30
24.88
0.23
0.12
0.14
3.37
0.00
2.02
3.20
4.00
2.00
1.51
2.40
3.00
2.00
4
2
48.52
27.47
1.75
1.51
1.77
6.38
1.48
0.86
0.00
4.04
2.28
0.00
2.05
0.52
1.13
0.00
3.28
3.02
2.91
3.02
3
4
46.28
28.24
1.80
2.00
0.00
3.64
7.87
2.06
0.00
0.00
7.87
0.69
9.07
10.70
7.79
6.55
4.28
4.13
4.00
4.72
Number
of banks
responding
Deposit
market share
(respondents
share out of
total system)
2004
4
4
2
4
4
3
Minimum
amount
to be
maintained
in savings
account
(% of
GDPPC)
Number
Number
Annual
Annual
of
of
fees
fees
documents documents
checking savings
to open
to open
account
account
checking
savings
(% of
(% of
account
account
GDPPC) GDPPC) (out of 5) (out of 5)
199
APPENDIX
(continued)
DEPOSITS
Physical access
Minimum
5th percentile
Median
Average
Maximum
95th percentile
Affordability
Number
of banks
responding
Deposit
market share
(respondents
share out of
total system)
2004
Locations
to open
deposit
account
(out of 3)
Minimum
amount
to open
checking
account
(% of
GDPPC)
1
1
3
3
6
5
4.63
13.68
44.56
48.25
100.00
89.08
1.00
1.50
2.00
2.14
3.00
3.00
0.00
0.00
0.62
11.09
141.84
57.17
Minimum
amount
to open
savings
account
(% of
GDPPC)
Minimum
amount
to be
maintained
in checking
account
(% of
GDPPC)
Minimum
amount
to be
maintained
in savings
account
(% of
GDPPC)
0.00
0.00
0.88
7.79
70.92
45.26
0.00
0.00
0.00
3.85
123.77
14.23
0.00
0.00
0.45
5.65
73.83
31.36
Eligibility
Number
Number
Annual
Annual
of
of
fees
fees
documents documents
checking savings
to open
to open
account
account
checking
savings
(% of
(% of
account
account
GDPPC) GDPPC) (out of 5) (out of 5)
0.00
0.00
0.30
2.36
26.63
11.69
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.55
7.79
3.38
1.00
1.00
2.53
2.49
4.57
4.15
1.00
1.00
2.00
2.13
4.72
3.92
Note: Indicators are obtained from a bank-level survey, as discussed in box 1.5 and Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Martinez Peria (2007a), and are weighted country-level averages. The first column gives the number of banks that responded to the survey from each country. Deposit market share is the total deposits of all the
banks in the sample divided by total deposits of the banking system of a country. The data on bank deposits is taken from Bankscope. Locations to open deposit
account take the value 1 if an account can be opened at headquarters only; 2 if at headquarters or a branch; and 3 if at headquarters, branches, or a nonbranch outlet. Minimum amount to open (be maintained in) a checking (savings) account is the minimum balance required to open (maintain) a checking (savings) account.
Annual fees checking (savings) account are the fees associated with maintaining a checking (savings) account. The affordability indicators are expressed as a share
of GDP per capita (GDPPC). Documents needed to open a checking (savings) account consist of identification, payment slip, letter of reference, proof of domicile,
and any “other” document a bank requires. This indicator varies from 1 to 5 depending on the number of documents required. Data for countries in which only one
bank responded are not shown but are included in the descriptive statistics at the end of the table. Data are available at http://econ.worldbank.org/programs/finance.
— = data not available.
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
200
Table A.4 Barriers to deposit services (continued)
Table A.5 Barriers to loan services: consumer and mortgage loans
LOANS
Physical access
Eligibility
Number
of banks
responding
Loan market
share
(respondents
share out of
total system)
2004
Locations
to submit
loan
applications
(out of 5)
Minimum
amount
consumer
loan (% of
GDPPC)
Fees
consumer
loan
(% of
GDPPC)
Minimum
amount
mortgage
loan (% of
GDPPC)
5
2
4
2
5
3
3
4
4
64.24
19.89
47.28
33.59
56.51
71.63
68.57
58.87
58.96
2.03
5.00
2.00
5.00
2.12
2.00
2.45
2.74
2.73
214.29
7.64
14.74
7.31
25.70
3.28
5.34
109.00
18.54
7.17
3.44
1.98
0.52
0.23
0.89
0.00
3.45
1.47
535.19
97.55
234.16
41.12
1412.52
0.00
86.18
1124.84
484.92
7.36
0.75
9.19
0.80
0.18
1.43
0.95
3.48
1.49
9.64
2.00
4.83
1.00
9.44
8.06
2.70
5.36
5.36
11.69
4.82
10.95
2.59
33.48
8.74
5.24
15.03
16.65
4
3
5
2
2
5
4
2
2
2
48.61
31.65
81.36
36.05
23.63
45.65
63.69
43.00
48.81
42.61
4.85
3.42
2.14
5.00
2.00
3.47
3.43
3.13
5.00
4.67
1.96
14.24
78.53
8.29
54.94
16.40
3.90
10.22
0.00
13.02
3.44
1.45
6.21
0.88
0.00
0.97
1.76
0.70
2.00
0.82
151.08
213.32
1544.77
213.20
—
150.48
183.04
84.65
0.00
176.10
9.06
1.49
5.84
1.09
0.00
1.39
1.17
0.60
1.59
6.27
1.00
4.88
4.87
3.84
20.00
2.51
2.42
1.00
0.73
1.84
13.62
6.84
16.97
70.63
20.00
5.14
4.53
6.66
4.56
17.55
2
32.08
2.81
5.84
0.01
0.00
0.01
5.38
38.72
4
2
85.37
30.08
2.00
4.00
178.16
3.22
0.00
1.00
712.65
6.36
0.68
1.00
5.41
4.87
15.00
24.67
Days to
Fees
process
mortgage
consumer
loan
loan
(% of
GDPPC) applications
Days to
process
mortgage
loan
applications
201
(continued)
APPENDIX
Albania
Argentina
Armenia
Australia
Bangladesh
Belarus
Belgium
Bolivia
Bosnia and
Herzegovina
Brazil
Bulgaria
Cameroon
Chile
China
Colombia
Croatia
Czech Republic
Denmark
Dominican
Republic
Egypt, Arab
Rep. of
Ethiopia
France
Affordability
LOANS
Physical access
Gabon
Georgia
Germany
Ghana
Greece
Hungary
India
Indonesia
Iran, Islamic
Rep. of
Israel
Italy
Japan
Jordan
Kenya
Korea
Lebanon
Lithuania
Madagascar
Malawi
Malaysia
Malta
Mexico
Moldova
Mozambique
Nepal
Affordability
Eligibility
Number
of banks
responding
Loan market
share
(respondents
share out of
total system)
2004
Locations
to submit
loan
applications
(out of 5)
Minimum
amount
consumer
loan (% of
GDPPC)
3
5
3
4
3
3
4
4
2
—
80.26
23.72
68.72
58.36
42.43
37.75
40.38
28.51
4.76
2.46
3.42
2.63
5.00
3.29
2.44
3.10
2.67
0.00
34.53
0.43
111.94
11.99
4.77
28.79
31.68
11.24
109.24
1.40
2.23
2.04
2.30
3.71
1.19
1.67
15.00
0.00
290.71
107.10
1320.35
80.86
29.00
145.17
225.90
11.24
109.24
0.73
1.00
2.01
6.70
1.59
0.74
1.46
16.00
7.00
3.31
1.00
9.50
1.00
5.66
4.17
4.94
4.33
15.00
4.56
5.02
10.00
5.43
19.94
9.45
6.07
15.62
2
4
4
3
3
6
3
5
5
3
1
4
3
3
2
5
34.75
19.04
24.52
80.36
47.61
73.54
38.00
86.77
74.59
59.73
10.22
58.34
45.74
48.32
40.34
42.40
4.58
2.69
3.42
2.05
3.27
3.78
4.60
4.25
2.16
2.12
3.00
4.20
4.20
2.54
2.15
2.00
0.03
8.47
3.81
147.67
186.42
4.19
32.95
6.31
24.06
222.36
31.42
19.26
7.54
31.11
30.71
1153.17
—
0.38
0.00
1.00
1.84
0.37
1.05
0.71
2.62
1.00
0.63
0.45
1.81
2.05
1.00
0.94
16.65
33.89
11.65
362.27
4206.32
4.19
409.00
65.83
290.98
1738.08
125.69
275.38
298.56
428.58
71.53
2147.93
0.40
1.03
0.56
0.95
1.00
0.37
1.95
0.67
4.69
17.37
0.00
0.27
1.40
1.09
1.00
1.00
1.00
2.01
1.95
2.68
2.52
1.88
1.58
2.41
8.55
1.72
14.00
1.34
5.01
1.36
8.66
3.71
12.08
22.44
1.95
7.24
7.00
2.36
9.26
8.48
15.00
14.16
14.00
2.74
28.25
3.90
34.21
9.5
Fees
consumer
loan
(% of
GDPPC)
Minimum
amount
mortgage
loan (% of
GDPPC)
Days to
Fees
process
mortgage
consumer
loan
loan
(% of
GDPPC) applications
Days to
process
mortgage
loan
applications
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
202
Table A.5 Barriers to loan services: consumer and mortgage loans (continued)
Table A.5 Barriers to loan services: consumer and mortgage loans (continued)
LOANS
Physical access
Eligibility
Number
of banks
responding
Loan market
share
(respondents
share out of
total system)
2004
Locations
to submit
loan
applications
(out of 5)
Minimum
amount
consumer
loan (% of
GDPPC)
Fees
consumer
loan
(% of
GDPPC)
Minimum
amount
mortgage
loan (% of
GDPPC)
3
3
4
4
2
4
4
3
5
3
4
3
2
2
3
3
29.31
44.02
76.40
43.17
28.77
24.66
100.00
51.93
70.68
69.39
66.73
51.10
22.43
59.19
36.16
50.27
2.78
3.09
3.21
2.36
3.43
2.00
1.77
3.64
2.13
5.00
5.00
2.90
4.28
3.12
2.00
4.62
81.79
146.71
21.08
330.55
3.66
6.10
143.55
10.26
1.13
7.27
9.95
36.10
1.14
0.11
265.43
7.71
3.83
0.14
1.83
1.46
6.15
5.51
2.07
0.60
1.22
0.48
1.85
0.34
0.21
0.00
1.43
1.33
408.96
954.59
410.39
763.35
32.50
197.64
5157.40
71.15
94.90
142.37
100.19
51.64
11.49
22.57
42.74
93.03
3.67
0.08
6.50
4.37
2.27
1.07
1.00
0.85
1.30
0.47
0.89
1.83
0.11
0.00
0.60
1.02
3.59
20.71
1.94
10.13
3.00
2.53
1.73
1.75
1.13
1.46
1.00
7.34
1.72
1.44
15.49
1.33
14.75
28.44
3.81
12.21
9.35
14.35
4.66
4.67
7.60
5.55
3.22
20.61
1.72
1.56
24.59
7.50
2
3
3
2
4
2
29.08
38.33
46.87
18.46
59.16
29.26
2.00
4.15
2.00
5.00
2.26
2.00
18.41
11.83
205.75
6.05
32.62
0.00
0.80
0.95
2.68
1.11
0.00
0.00
18.41
165.37
—
59.56
355.97
0.00
1.40
2.16
—
1.66
1.57
0.00
9.00
2.94
1.38
1.00
8.51
9.15
45.00
5.00
—
14.32
14.42
19.65
3
4
34.41
43.45
2.00
2.85
—
24.08
2.41
3.05
—
—
—
—
—
1.46
—
—
Days to
Fees
process
mortgage
consumer
loan
loan
(% of
GDPPC) applications
Days to
process
mortgage
loan
applications
203
(continued)
APPENDIX
Nigeria
Pakistan
Peru
Philippines
Poland
Romania
Sierra Leone
Slovak Republic
Slovenia
South Africa
Spain
Sri Lanka
Sweden
Switzerland
Thailand
Trinidad and
Tobago
Tunisia
Turkey
Uganda
United Kingdom
Uruguay
Venezuela,
R. B. de
Zambia
Zimbabwe
Affordability
LOANS
Physical access
Minimum
5th percentile
Median
Average
Maximum
95th percentile
Affordability
Number
of banks
responding
Loan market
share
(respondents
share out of
total system)
2004
Locations
to submit
loan
applications
(out of 5)
Minimum
amount
consumer
loan (% of
GDPPC)
Fees
consumer
loan
(% of
GDPPC)
1
1
3
3
6
5
5.61
14.43
43.17
45.19
100.00
80.46
1.77
2.00
3.05
3.23
5.00
5.00
0.00
0.03
13.63
56.79
1153.17
215.50
0.00
0.00
1.08
3.07
109.24
6.16
Minimum
amount
mortgage
loan (% of
GDPPC)
0.00
0.00
143.77
428.58
5157.40
1631.76
Eligibility
Days to
Fees
process
mortgage
consumer
loan
loan
(% of
GDPPC) applications
0.00
0.01
1.09
3.70
109.24
9.11
0.73
1.00
2.94
4.58
20.71
14.10
Days to
process
mortgage
loan
applications
1.00
1.67
9.45
12.68
70.63
33.70
Note: Indicators are obtained from a bank-level survey as discussed in box 1.5 and Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Martinez Peria (2007a), and are weighted countrylevel averages. The first column gives the number of banks that responded to the survey from each country. Loan market share is the total loans of all the banks in the
sample divided by total loans of the banking system of a country. The data on bank loans is taken from Bankscope. Locations to submit loan applications take the
value 1 if application can be submitted at headquarters only; 2 if at headquarters or a branch; 3 if at headquarters, branches, or a nonbranch outlet; 4 if at headquarters,
branches, nonbranch outlets, or electronically; and 5 if at headquarters, branches, nonbranch outlets, electronically, or over the phone. Minimum amount consumer
(mortgage) loan is the smallest amount of loan banks make, and fees consumer (mortgage) loan are the fees associated with consumer (mortgage) loans. Minimum
loan amount and fees are expressed as a share of gross domestic product per capita (GDPPC). The last two columns show the number of days banks take to process a
typical consumer (mortgage) loan application. Data for countries in which only one bank responded are not shown but are included in the descriptive statistics at the
end of the table. Data are available at http://econ.worldbank.org/programs/finance. — = data are unavailable.
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
204
Table A.5 Barriers to loan services: consumer and mortgage loans (continued)
Table A.6 Barriers to loan services: business and SME loans
LOANS
Physical access
Affordability
Loan market
Locations Minimum
share
amount
(respondents to submit
business
loan
Number share out of
of banks total system) applications loan (% of
GDPPC)
(out of 5)
2004
responding
Albania
Argentina
Armenia
Australia
Bangladesh
Belarus
Belgium
Bolivia
Bosnia and
Herzegovina
Brazil
Bulgaria
Cameroon
Chile
China
Colombia
Croatia
Czech Republic
Denmark
Dominican Republic
Egypt, Arab Rep. of
Ethiopia
France
Gabon
Eligibility
Fees
business
loan
(% of
GDPPC)
Minimum
amount
SME loan
(% of
GDPPC)
Fees SME
loan
(% of
GDPPC)
Days to
Days to
process
process
business
SME loan
loan
applications applications
5
2
4
2
5
3
3
4
4
64.24
19.89
47.28
33.59
56.51
71.63
68.57
58.87
58.96
2.03
5.00
2.00
5.00
2.12
2.00
2.45
2.74
2.73
2263.77
971.72
1042.28
10.06
55.28
7.12
28.29
759.35
573.97
7.33
1.56
0.19
3.03
6.46
1.15
2.30
3.48
1.20
1358.23
151.87
860.58
10.06
174.4
0.00
28.29
795.48
711.11
7.33
1.56
0.00
1.29
2.62
1.15
2.30
3.61
1.10
16.05
7.82
9.94
7.19
34.55
7.34
3.60
23.26
14.70
14.50
5.26
7.62
7.19
43.26
6.20
3.60
9.70
8.86
4
3
5
2
2
5
4
2
2
2
2
4
2
3
48.61
31.65
81.36
36.05
23.63
45.65
63.69
43.00
48.81
42.61
32.08
85.37
30.08
—
4.85
3.42
2.14
5.00
2.00
3.47
3.43
3.13
5.00
4.67
2.81
2.00
4.00
4.76
19.19
130.35
16393.68
178.74
—
2131.83
146.24
4.96
0.00
89.32
14.61
981.67
6.36
0.00
2.10
2.05
81.39
3.57
0.00
0.23
0.94
0.70
1.73
1.25
0.35
0.64
1.00
100.35
8.08
95.79
947.92
121.70
—
242.96
22.58
4.96
0.00
43.52
0.00
878.77
6.36
0.00
2.10
2.27
81.39
1.09
0.00
0.09
1.30
0.70
2.00
1.32
0.00
0.64
1.00
100.35
10.32
21.38
12.91
10.00
50.00
11.00
11.89
8.05
1.00
6.67
19.29
14.55
18.22
15.08
3.63
13.38
9.31
13.87
40.00
8.22
4.65
10.84
1.00
13.04
14.43
14.55
10.00
15.08
205
APPENDIX
(continued)
LOANS
Physical access
Affordability
Loan market
Locations Minimum
share
amount
(respondents to submit
business
loan
Number share out of
of banks total system) applications loan (% of
GDPPC)
(out of 5)
2004
responding
Georgia
Germany
Ghana
Greece
Hungary
India
Indonesia
Iran, Islamic Rep. of
Israel
Italy
Japan
Jordan
Kenya
Korea, Rep. of
Lebanon
Lithuania
Madagascar
Malawi
Malta
Mexico
Moldova
Mozambique
Nepal
5
3
4
3
3
4
4
2
2
4
4
3
3
6
3
5
5
3
4
3
3
2
5
80.26
23.72
68.72
58.36
42.43
37.75
40.38
28.51
34.75
19.04
24.52
80.36
47.61
73.54
38.00
86.77
74.59
59.73
58.34
45.74
48.32
40.34
42.40
2.46
3.42
2.63
5.00
3.29
2.44
3.10
2.67
4.58
2.69
3.42
2.05
3.27
3.78
4.60
4.25
2.16
2.12
4.20
4.20
2.54
2.15
2.00
2345.59
0.00
1044.39
13.98
58.00
57.77
0.00
11.24
1.67
4.49
30.98
354.70
193.78
16.99
4470.83
17.54
17.27
306.05
529.00
101.93
64216.77
28.61
19407.57
Eligibility
Fees
business
loan
(% of
GDPPC)
Minimum
amount
SME loan
(% of
GDPPC)
Fees SME
loan
(% of
GDPPC)
1.01
0.62
1.31
2.43
3.31
0.93
0.90
15.00
45.80
4.74
0.00
1.03
1.57
0.29
5.40
0.88
3.56
1.32
0.28
1.27
1.34
0.75
18.57
2480.08
0.00
1448.07
33.96
58.00
145.17
1853.19
11.24
1.67
7.24
11.75
445.26
166.44
16.99
1154.76
17.54
17.27
1929.34
355.91
87.80
71.78
28.61
2970.18
1.10
0.62
1.54
2.43
1.51
0.84
1.46
16.00
45.80
4.74
0.00
1.03
2.10
0.29
4.95
0.67
3.56
1.00
0.28
1.61
1.43
1.00
16.86
Days to
Days to
process
process
business
SME loan
loan
applications applications
5.03
3.87
19.07
4.77
10.04
19.98
16.59
10.64
1.79
19.26
11.39
8.16
5.66
2.73
15.61
9.83
18.60
15.39
5.64
15.70
7.31
25.84
9.53
5.62
4.25
29.20
2.23
7.66
10.75
9.68
10.64
1.79
18.12
10.14
7.91
5.66
2.73
15.61
8.62
15.46
3.71
5.69
9.86
4.31
25.84
10.94
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
206
Table A.6 Barriers to loan services: business and SME loans (continued)
Table A.6 Barriers to loan services: business and SME loans (continued)
LOANS
Physical access
Affordability
Loan market
Locations Minimum
share
amount
(respondents to submit
business
loan
Number share out of
of banks total system) applications loan (% of
GDPPC)
(out of 5)
2004
responding
Nigeria
Pakistan
Peru
Philippines
Poland
Romania
Sierra Leone
Slovak Republic
Slovenia
South Africa
Spain
Sri Lanka
Sweden
Switzerland
Thailand
Trinidad and Tobago
Tunisia
Turkey
Uganda
United Kingdom
Uruguay
Venezuela, R. B. de
Zambia
Zimbabwe
3
3
4
4
2
4
4
3
5
3
4
3
2
2
3
3
2
3
3
2
4
2
3
4
29.31
44.02
76.40
43.17
28.77
24.66
100.00
51.93
70.68
69.39
66.73
51.10
22.43
59.19
36.16
50.27
29.08
38.33
46.87
18.46
59.16
29.26
34.41
43.45
2.78
3.09
3.21
2.36
3.43
2.00
1.77
3.64
2.13
5.00
5.00
2.90
4.28
3.12
2.00
4.62
2.00
4.15
2.00
5.00
2.26
2.00
2.00
2.85
0.00
1526.04
429.43
920.23
0.00
124.83
218.23
50.91
5.21
15.98
19.35
20.56
0.00
11.28
0.00
8.30
92.07
74.26
7039.03
26.12
32.62
0.00
—
263.49
Eligibility
Fees
business
loan
(% of
GDPPC)
Minimum
amount
SME loan
(% of
GDPPC)
Fees SME
loan
(% of
GDPPC)
1.35
0.12
0.16
1.41
2.35
1.03
1.76
1.13
0.38
0.65
1.06
2.29
0.21
0.00
0.55
1.24
1.50
1.94
1.51
1.32
0.00
0.00
2.23
2.54
81.79
234.25
54.35
916.66
0.54
124.83
243.89
57.89
5.21
15.98
19.35
20.56
0.00
11.28
3.21
8.30
92.07
18.57
3141.17
6.05
32.62
0.00
—
240.12
4.14
0.19
0.16
1.41
2.31
1.06
2.07
1.13
0.95
0.65
1.10
2.09
0.22
0.00
0.94
1.14
1.50
1.41
2.25
1.32
0.00
0.00
2.43
2.54
Days to
Days to
process
process
business
SME loan
loan
applications applications
8.24
31.98
10.63
44.13
12.00
12.45
11.53
3.06
4.19
2.73
1.83
15.57
2.28
3.24
22.46
10.41
20.60
13.75
5.15
12.32
31.52
11.40
10.67
7.91
11.49
33.63
3.71
33.29
12.43
12.45
9.52
3.54
3.89
4.13
1.83
10.04
2.28
3.24
23.74
7.32
22.60
4.61
4.47
10.47
31.45
11.40
8.33
3.91
207
APPENDIX
(continued)
LOANS
Physical access
Affordability
Loan market
Locations Minimum
share
amount
(respondents to submit
business
loan
Number share out of
of banks total system) applications loan (% of
GDPPC)
(out of 5)
2004
responding
Minimum
5th percentile
Median
Average
Maximum
95th percentile
1
1
3
3
6
5
5.61
14.43
43.17
45.19
100.00
80.46
1.77
2.00
3.05
3.23
5.00
5.00
0.00
0.00
55.28
2259.06
64216.77
9845.42
Fees
business
loan
(% of
GDPPC)
0.00
0.00
1.26
4.73
100.35
15.54
Minimum
amount
SME loan
(% of
GDPPC)
0.00
0.00
39.86
337.58
3141.17
1876.04
Eligibility
Fees SME
loan
(% of
GDPPC)
0.00
0.00
1.28
4.67
100.35
16.13
Days to
Days to
process
process
business
SME loan
loan
applications applications
1.00
1.99
10.64
12.68
50.00
31.54
1.00
1.99
9.09
11.03
43.26
31.54
Note: Indicators are obtained from a bank-level survey, as discussed in box 1.5 and Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Martinez Peria (2007a), and are weighted country-level
averages. The first column gives the number of banks that responded to the survey from each country. Loan market share is the total loans of all the banks in the sample
divided by total loans of the banking system of a country. The data on bank loans is taken from Bankscope. Locations to submit loan applications take the value 1 if the
application can be submitted at headquarters only; 2 if at headquarters or a branch; 3 if at headquarters, branches, or nonbranch outlets; 4 if at headquarters, branches,
nonbranch outlets, or electronically; and 5 if at headquarters, branches, nonbranch outlets, electronically, or over the phone. Minimum amount business (SME) loan
is the smallest amount of loan banks make to businesses (SMEs), and Fees business (SME) loan are the fees associated with business (SME) loans. Minimum loan
amount and fees are expressed as a share of gross domestic product per capita (GDPPC). The last two columns show the number of days banks take to process a typical
business loan and a typical SME loan application. Data for countries in which only one bank responded are not shown but are included in the descriptive statistics at
the end of the table. Data are available at http://econ.worldbank.org/programs/finance. — = data are not available.
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
208
Table A.6 Barriers to loan services: business and SME loans (continued)
APPENDIX
Table A.7 Barriers to payment services
Country
Albania
Algeria
Argentina
Armenia
Australia
Austria
Bangladesh
Belarus
Belgium
Bolivia
Bosnia and Herzegovina
Brazil
Bulgaria
Cameroon
Chile
China
Colombia
Croatia
Czech Republic
Denmark
Dominican Republic
Egypt, Arab Rep. of
El Salvador
Estonia
Ethiopia
France
Gabon
Georgia
Germany
Ghana
Greece
Hungary
India
Indonesia
Iran, Islamic Rep. of
Israel
Italy
Japan
Number of
banks that have
responded
Deposit market
share (respondents
share out of total
system) 2004
Cost to
transfer funds
internationally
(% of $250)
Amount of fee for
using ATM cards (%
of $100)
5
1
2
4
2
1
5
3
3
4
4
4
3
5
2
2
5
4
2
2
2
2
1
1
4
2
3
5
3
4
3
3
4
4
2
2
4
4
91.42
91.00
17.90
59.63
32.59
11.46
56.98
74.58
72.56
58.04
64.04
64.35
34.87
83.83
35.50
23.33
50.48
63.42
43.00
72.71
39.27
32.05
24.74
6.51
93.73
26.23
—
85.71
31.91
69.49
56.92
53.09
36.87
44.73
29.86
36.17
22.79
29.63
7.70
—
0.75
6.14
8.05
3.45
1.93
1.27
0.12
13.47
3.79
14.85
5.24
9.15
20.00
2.67
11.67
3.57
3.99
4.09
20.00
0.76
1.23
11.26
1.87
5.12
4.85
7.03
1.12
14.70
7.42
3.60
6.49
2.83
—
8.15
7.39
13.24
0.0003
0.21
0.00
0.07
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.26
0.01
0.11
0.13
0.00
0.00
0.12
0.19
0.00
0.19
0.00
5.70
0.00
0.06
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.13
0.00
0.19
0.00
—
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.23
0.00
0.00
(continued)
209
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Table A.7 Barriers to payment services (continued)
Country
Jordan
Kenya
Korea
Lebanon
Lithuania
Madagascar
Malawi
Malaysia
Malta
Mauritius
Mexico
Moldova
Mozambique
Nepal
New Zealand
Nigeria
Norway
Pakistan
Peru
Philippines
Poland
Portugal
Romania
Sierra Leone
Slovak Republic
Slovenia
South Africa
Spain
Sri Lanka
Swaziland
Sweden
Switzerland
Thailand
Trinidad and Tobago
Tunisia
Turkey
Uganda
United Kingdom
210
Number of
banks that have
responded
Deposit market
share (respondents
share out of total
system) 2004
Cost to
transfer funds
internationally
(% of $250)
3
3
6
3
5
5
3
1
4
1
3
3
2
5
1
3
1
3
4
4
2
1
4
4
3
5
3
4
3
1
2
2
3
3
2
3
3
2
83.61
43.82
68.95
38.00
88.87
72.44
82.36
10.38
44.56
4.63
48.95
40.16
48.78
37.86
16.75
32.22
19.30
47.50
81.88
41.84
28.65
13.93
35.01
100.00
58.12
67.48
70.09
63.75
52.19
43.40
39.47
79.57
38.36
40.15
29.65
50.14
59.27
17.46
5.37
8.43
7.05
9.76
8.72
4.30
6.42
—
5.59
—
8.66
11.19
4.25
7.10
6.63
6.17
3.56
2.10
6.68
2.27
7.10
—
17.43
6.86
4.38
2.88
9.53
6.39
7.14
14.40
8.16
3.17
4.97
3.74
5.19
6.34
0.55
9.56
Amount of fee for
using ATM cards (%
of $100)
0.00
0.15
0.22
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.08
0.13
0.03
—
0.40
0.00
0.22
0.00
0.33
0.50
0.00
0.60
0.24
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.19
0.00
0.34
0.00
0.03
.
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.05
0.00
0.00
0.19
0.00
APPENDIX
Table A.7 Barriers to payment services (continued)
Number of
banks that have
responded
Deposit market
share (respondents
share out of total
system) 2004
Cost to
transfer funds
internationally
(% of $250)
Uruguay
Venezuela, R. B. de
Zambia
Zimbabwe
4
2
3
4
48.52
27.47
46.28
28.24
7.18
12.00
3.24
3.77
0.14
0.10
0.13
1.04
Minimum
5th percentile
Median
Average
Maximum
95th percentile
1
1
3
3
6
5
4.63
13.68
44.56
48.25
100.00
89.08
0.12
1.01
6.34
6.63
20.00
14.75
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.17
5.70
0.42
Country
Amount of fee for
using ATM cards (%
of $100)
Note: Indicators are obtained from a bank-level survey, as discussed in box 1.5 and Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Martinez Peria
(2007a), and are weighted country-level averages. The first column gives the number of banks from each country that responded to
the survey. Deposit market share is the total deposits of all the banks in the sample divided by total deposits of the banking system
of a country. The data on bank deposits is taken from Bankscope. Cost to transfer funds internationally is the amount of fees banks
charge to transfer funds internationally. The fee is expressed as percentage of $250. Amount of fee for using ATM cards is the fee banks
charge consumers for using an ATM card. The fee is expressed as percentage of $100. Data are available at http://econ.worldbank
.org/programs/finance. — = data are not available.
211
References
Abiad, Abdul, and Ashoka Mody. 2005. “Financial
Reform: What Shakes It? What Shapes It?”
American Economic Review 95 (11): 66–88.
Acemoglu, Daron, and Simon Johnson. 2005.
“Unbundling Institutions.” Journal of Political
Economy 113 (5): 949–95.
Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson, and James
Robinson. 2001. “The Colonial Origins of
Comparative Development: An Empirical
Investigation.” American Economic Review 91
(5): 1369–1401.
———. 2002. “Reversal of Fortunes: Geography
and Institutions in the Making of the Modern
World Income Distribution.” Quarterly Journal
of Economics 117 (4): 1231–94.
Adams, Dale, Douglas Graham, and J. D. von Pischke.
1984. Undermining Rural Development with
Cheap Credit. Boulder, CO: Westview Press.
Adams, Dale, and J. D. von Pischke. 1992.
“Microenterprise Credit Programs: Déja Vu.”
World Development 20 (10): 1463–70.
Adasme, Osvaldo, Giovanni Majnoni, and Myriam
Uribe. 2006. “Access and Risk: Friends or Foes?
Lessons from Chile.” Policy Research Working
Paper 4003, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Aggarwal, Reena, Aslı Demirgüç-Kunt, and
Maria Soledad Martinez Peria. 2006. “Do
Workers’ Remittances Promote Financial
Development?” Policy Research Working
Paper 3957, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Aggarwal, Reena, Leora Klapper and Peter Wysocki.
2005. “Portfolio Preferences of Foreign
Institutional Investors.” Journal of Banking
and Finance 29 (12): 2919–46.
Aghion, Philippe, and Patrick Bolton. 1997. “A Theory
of Trickle-Down Growth and Development.”
Review of Economic Studies 64 (2): 151–72.
Aghion, Philippe, Eve Caroli, and Cecilia GarciaPenalosa. 1999. “Inequality and Economic
Growth: The Perspective of New Growth
Theories.” Journal of Economic Literature 37
(4): 1615–60.
Aghion, Philippe, Thibault Fally, and Stefano
Scarpetta. 2006. “Credit Constraints as a
Barrier to the Entry and Post-Entry Growth
of Firms: Lessons from Firm-Level Cross
213
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Country Panel Data.” Working paper, Harvard
University, Economics Department, Boston,
MA.
Economic Transformation, ed. Thomas Rawski
and Loren Brandt, New York: Cambridge
University Press, forthcoming.
Aghion, Philippe, Peter Howitt, and David MayerFoulkes. 2005. “The Effect of Financial
Development on Convergence: Theory and
Evidence.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 120
(1): 173–222.
Aportela, Francisco. 1999. “Effects of Financial Access
on Savings by Low-Income People.” Working
paper, MIT, Cambridge, MA.
Ahlin, Christian, and Robert M. Townsend. 2007.
“Using Repayment Data to Test across Models
of Joint Liability Lending.” Economic Journal
117 (517): F11-F51.
Alesina, Alberto, and Dani Rodrik. 1994. “Distributive
Politics and Economic Growth.” Quarterly
Journal of Economics 109 (2): 465–90.
Allayannis, George, Greg Brown, and Leora Klapper.
2003. “Capital Structure, Foreign Debt and
Financial Risk: Evidence from East Asia.”
Journal of Finance 58 (6): 2667–2710.
Allen, Franklin, Rajesh Chakrabarti, Sankar De, Jun
Qian, and Meijun Qian. 2006. “Financing
Firms in India.” Policy Research Working
Paper 3975, World Bank, Washington,
DC. Wharton Financial Institutions
Center Working Paper 06-08, University of
Pennsylvania, Philadelphia.
Allen, Franklin, and Douglas Gale. 2000. Comparing
Financial Systems. Cambridge, MA: MIT
Press.
Allen, Franklin, Jun Qian, and Meijun Qian. 2005.
“Law, Finance, and Economic Growth in
China.” Journal of Financial Economics 77
(1): 57–116.
———. 2008. “China’s Financial System: Past,
Present, and Future.” In China’s Great
214
Armendáriz de Aghion, Beatriz, and Jonathan
Morduch. 2005. The Economics of Mirofinance.
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Ashraf, Nava, Xavier Giné, and Dean Karlan. 2007.
“Finding Missing Markets: An Evaluation of
a Horticultural Export and Credit Program
in Kenya.” Working paper, World Bank,
Washington, DC.
Ashraf, Nava, Dean Karlan, and Wesley Yin. 2003.
“A Review of Commitment Savings Products
in Developing Countries.” Asian Development
Bank, Manila, Philippines.
———. 2006a. “Deposit Collectors.” Advances in
Economic Analysis and Policy 6 (2): 1483–83.
———. 2006b. “Female Empowerment: Further
Evidence from a Commitment Savings
Product in the Philippines.” Working paper,
Yale University, Economics Department, New
Haven, CT.
———. 2006c. “Tying Odysseus to the Mast:
Evidence from a Savings Commitment
Product in the Philippines.” Quarterly Journal
of Economics 121 (2): 635–72.
Ayyagari, Meghana, Aslı Demirgüç-Kunt, and
Vojislav Maksimovic. 2006a. “How Important
Are Financing Constraints? The Role of
Finance in the Business Environment.” Policy
Research Working Paper 3820, World Bank,
Washington, DC.
REFERENCES
———. 2006b. “What Determines Protection of
Property Rights: An Analysis of Direct and
Indirect Effects.” Policy Research Working
Paper 3940, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Bebczuk, Ricardo. 2007. “Loan Size and Loss
Predictability in Argentina.” Working paper,
Universidad Nacional de la Plata, La Plata,
Argentina.
———. 2007a. “Firm Innovation in Emerging
Markets: Role of Governance and Finance.”
Policy Research Working Paper 4157, World
Bank, Washington, DC.
Beck, Thorsten. 2003. “Financial Dependence and
International Trade.” Review of International
Economics 11 (2): 296–316.
———. 2007b. “Formal versus Informal Finance:
Evidence from China.” Working paper,
Development Research Group, World Bank,
Washington, DC.
———. 2007c. “How Well Do Institutional
Theories Explain Firms’ Perceptions of
Property Rights?” Review of Financial Studies,
forthcoming.
Banerjee, Abhijit V., and Esther Duflo. 2004. “Do
Firms Want to Borrow More? Testing Credit
Constraints Using a Directed Lending
Program.” CEPR Discussion Paper 4681. Centre
for Economic Policy Research, London.
———. 2005. “Growth Theory through the Lens
of Development Economics.” In Handbook of
Economic Growth, vol. 1, part A, ed. Philippe
Aghion and Steven Durlauf, 473–552.
Amsterdam: Elsevier.
Banerjee, Abhijit V., and Andrew F. Newman. 1993.
“Occupational Choice and the Process of
Development.” Journal of Political Economy
101 (2, April): 274–98.
Barth, James R., Gerard Caprio, Jr., and Ross Levine.
2006. Rethinking Bank Regulation: Till Angels
Govern. New York: Cambridge University
Press.
Beck, Thorsten, and Augusto de la Torre. 2007.
“The Basic Analytics of Access to Financial
Services.” Financial Markets, Institutions, and
Instruments 16 (2): 79–117.
Beck, Thorsten, and Aslı Demirgüç-Kunt. 2006.
“Small and Medium-Size Enterprises: Access
to Finance as a Growth Constraint.” Journal
of Banking and Finance 30 (11): 2931–43.
Beck, Thorsten, Aslı Demirgüç-Kunt, Luc Laeven,
and Ross Levine. 2005. “Finance, Firm Size
and Growth.” Policy Research Working Paper
3485, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Beck, Thorsten, Aslı Demirgüç-Kunt, Luc Laeven,
and Vojislav Maksimovic. 2006. “The
Determinants of Financing Obstacles.”
Journal of International Money and Finance
25 (6): 932–52.
Beck, Thorsten, Aslı Demirgüç-Kunt, and Ross
Levine. 2000. “A New Database on the
Structure and Development of the Financial
Sector.” World Bank Economic Review 14 (3):
597–605. Updated version available at econ.
worldbank.org/programs/finance.
———. 2003. “Finance, Law and Endowments.”
Journal of Financial Economics 70 (2):
137–81.
215
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
———. 2005. “Law and Firms’ Access to Finance.”
American Law and Economics Review 7 (1):
211–52.
———. 2006. “Bank Supervision and Corruption
in Lending.” Journal of Monetary Economics
53 (8): 2131–63.
———. 2007. “Finance, Inequality, and the Poor.”
Journal of Economic Growth 12 (1): 27–49.
Beck, Thorsten, Aslı Demirgüç-Kunt, and Vojislav
Maksimovic. 2004. “Bank Competition and
Access to Finance: International Evidence.”
Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 36 (3,
part 2): 627–48.
———. 2005. “Financial and Legal Constraints
to Firm Growth: Does Firm Size Matter?”
Journal of Finance 60 (1): 137–77.
———. 2006. “The Influence of Financial and Legal
Institutions on Firm Size.” Journal of Banking
and Finance 30 (11): 2995–3015.
———. Forthcoming. “Financing Patterns Around
the World: Are Small Firms Different?”
Journal of Financial Economics.
Beck, Thorsten, Aslı Demirgüç-Kunt, and Maria
Soledad Martinez Peria. 2007a. “Banking
Services for Everyone? Barriers to Bank
Access and Use around the World.” Policy
Research Working Paper 4079, World Bank,
Washington, DC.
———. 2007b. “Reaching Out: Access to and Use of
Banking Services across Countries.” Journal of
Financial Economics 85 (1): 234–66.
Beck, Thorsten, and Luc Laeven. 2006. “Institution
Building and Growth in Transition Economies.”
Journal of Economic Growth 11 (2): 157–86.
216
Beck, Thorsten, and Ross Levine. 2002. “Industry
Growth and Capital Allocation: Does
Having a Market- or Bank-Based System
Matter? Journal of Financial Economics 64
(2): 147–80.
———. 2005. “Legal Institutions and Financial
Development.” In Handbook of New
Institutional Economics, ed. Claude Menard
and Mary M. Shirley. Norwell MA: Kluwer
Academic Publishers.
Beck, Thorsten, Ross Levine, and Alex Levkov. 2007.
“Big Bad Banks? The Impact of U.S. Branch
Deregulation in Income Distribution.” Policy
Research Working Paper 4330, World Bank,
Washington, DC.
Beck, Thorsten, Ross Levine, and Norman Loayza. 2000.
“Finance and the Sources of Growth.” Journal of
Financial Economics 58 (1): 261–300.
Becker, Bo, and David Greenberg. 2005. “Financial
Development and International Trade.”
Working Paper, University of Illinois, UrbanaChampaign, College of Business.
Beegle, Kathleen, Rajeev Dehejia, and Roberta
Gatti. 2007. “Child Labor and Agricultural
Shocks.” Journal of Development Economics
81 (1): 80–96.
Beinhocker, Eric D. 2006. The Origin of Wealth:
Evolution, Complexity, and the Radical
Remaking of Economics. Cambridge, MA:
Harvard Business School Press.
Bekaert, Geert, Campbell R. Harvey, and
Christian Lundblad. 2005. “Does Financial
Liberalization Spur Growth?” Journal of
Financial Economics 77 (1): 3–55.
REFERENCES
Benavente, José Miguel, Alexander Galetovic, and
Ricardo Sanhueza. 2006. “FOGAPE: An
Economic Analysis.” Working paper 222,
University of Chile, Economics Department,
Santiago.
Benavides, Guillermo, and Alberto Huidobro. 2005.
“Are Loan Guarantees Effective? The Case
of Mexican Government Banks.” http://ssrn
.com/abstract=637385.
Bennett, Fred, Alan Doran, and Harriett Billington.
2005. “Do Credit Guarantees Lead to
Improved Access to Financial Services? Recent
Evidence from Chile, Egypt, India, and
Poland.” Policy Division Working Paper, U.K.
Department for International Development,
Financial Sector Team, London.
Berger, Allen N., Aslı Demirgüç-Kunt, Ross Levine,
and Joseph G. Haubrich. 2004. “Bank
Concentration and Competition: An Evolution
in the Making.” Journal of Money, Credit, and
Banking 36 (3): 433–654.
Berger, Allen N., W. Scott Frame, and Nathan
H. Miller. 2005. “Credit Scoring and the
Availability, Price, and Risk of Small Business
Credit.” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking
37 (2): 191–222.
Berger, Allen N., Iftekhar Hasan, and Leora F. Klapper.
2004. “Further Evidence on the Link between
Finance and Growth: An International
Analysis of Community Banking and
Economic Performance.” Journal of Financial
Services Research 25 (2/3): 169–202.
Berger, Allen N., and Gregory F. Udell. 1998. “The
Economics of Small Business Finance: The
Roles of Private Equity and Debt Markets
in the Financial Growth Cycle.” Journal of
Banking and Finance 22 (6-8): 613–73.
———. 2006. “A More Complete Conceptual
Framework for SME Financing.” Journal of
Banking and Finance 30 (11): 2945–66.
Bertrand, Marianne, Dean S. Karlan, Sendhil
Mullainathan, Eldar Shafir, and Jonathan
Zinman. 2005. “What’s Psychology Worth?
A Field Experiment in the Consumer Credit
Market.” Discussion Paper 918, Yale University
Economic Growth Center, New Haven, CT.
Bertrand, Marianne, Antoinette Schoar, and David
Thesmar. 2007. “Banking Deregulation and
Industry Structure: Evidence from the French
Banking Reforms of 1985.” Journal of Finance
62 (2): 597–628.
Besley, Tim J. 1994. “How Do Market Failures Justify
Interventions in Rural Credit Markets?” World
Bank Research Observer 9 (1): 27–47.
Besley, Tim J., and S. Coate (1995). “Group Lending,
Repayment Incentives, and Social Collateral.”
Journal of Development Economics 46 (1):
1–18.
Bester, Helmut. 1985. “Screening versus Rationing in
Credit Markets with Imperfect Information.”
American Economic Review 75 (4): 850–55.
Biais, Bruno, and Enrico Perotti. 2002. “Machiavellian
Privatization.” American Economic Review 92
(1): 240–58.
Biggs, Tyler, and Manju Kedia Shah. 2006. “African
SMEs, Networks, and Manufacturing
Performance.” Journal of Banking and Finance
30 (11): 3040–66.
217
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Birdsall, Nancy. 2007. “Income Distribution: Effects
on Growth and Development.” In International
Handbook of Development Economics, ed.
Amitava K. Dutt and Jaime Ros. Aldershot:
Edward Elgar, forthcoming.
Blundell, Richard, Stephen R. Bond, and Costas Meghir.
1996. “Econometric Models of Company
Investment.” In The Econometrics of Panel Data:
A Handbook of the Theory with Applications, ed.
László Matyas and Patrick Sevestre. Boston:
Kluwer Academic Publishers.
Bonaccorsi di Patti, Emilia, and Giovanni Dell’Ariccia.
2004. “Bank Competition and Firm Creation.”
Journal of Money, Banking, and Credit 36 (2):
225–51.
Bond, Philip, and Ashok Rai. 2002. “Collateral
Substitute in Microfinance.” Working
paper, Northwestern University, Institute for
Advanced Study, Evanston, IL.
Bond, Stephen R., and John Van Reenen. 1999.
“Microeconomic Models of Investment and
Employment.” In Handbook of Econometrics,
vol. 5, ed. James J. Heckman and Edward
E. Leamer. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science,
North-Holland.
Bonin, John P., Iftekhar Hasan, and Paul Wachtel.
2005. “Bank Privatization and Performance:
Evidence from Transition Countries.” Journal
of Banking and Finance 29 (1): 31–53.
Boot, Arnoud, and Anjolein Schmeits. 2005. “The
Competitive Challenge in Banking.” Working
paper 2005-08, Amsterdam Center for Law
and Economics, Amsterdam.
Bourguignon, François. 2001. “Pareto-Superiority of
Unegalitarian Equilibria in Stiglitz’s Model
218
of Wealth Distribution with Convex Savings
Function.” Econometrica 49 (6): 1469–75.
———. 2003. “The Growth Elasticity of Poverty
Reduction: Explaining Heterogeneity across
Countries and Time Periods.” In Inequality
and Growth: Theory and Policy Implications,
ed. Theo Eicher and Stephen Turnovsky.
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
———. 2004. “The Poverty-Growth-Inequality
Triangle.” Working paper, World Bank,
Washington, DC.
Boyd, John, Ross Levine, and Bruce Smith. 2001.
“The Impact of Inflation on Financial Sector
Performance.” Journal of Monetary Economics
47 (2): 221–48.
Boyreau-Debray, Genevieve. 2003. “Financial
Intermediation and Growth—Chinese Style.”
Policy Research Working Paper 3027, World
Bank, Washington, DC.
Boyreau-Debray, Genevieve, and Shang-Jin Wei.
2005. “Pitfalls of a State-Dominated Financial
System: The Case of China.” NBER Working
Paper 11214, National Bureau of Economic
Research, Cambridge, MA.
Braun, Matias, and Claudio Raddatz. 2007. “The
Politics of Financial Development: Evidence
from Trade Liberalization.” Journal of Financial
Economics, forthcoming.
Brown, Michael, Tulio Jappelli, and Marco Pagano.
2006. “Information Sharing and Credit: FirmLevel Evidence from Transition Countries.”
Swiss National Bank, Zurich.
Burgess, Robin, and Rohinde Pande. 2005. “Can
Rural Banks Reduce Poverty? Evidence from
REFERENCES
the Indian Social Banking Experiment.”
American Economic Review 95 (3): 780–95.
Burkart, Mike, Tore Ellingsen, and Mariassunta
Giannetti. 2004. “What You Sell Is What You
Lend? Explaining Trade Credit Contracts.”
Stockholm School of Economics, Stockholm.
Burkart, Mike, Fausto Panunzi, and Andrei Shleifer.
2003. “Family Firms.” Journal of Finance 58
(5): 2167–202.
Calvo, Guillermo. 1998. “Capital Flows and CapitalMarket Crises: The Simple Economics of
Sudden Stops.” Journal of Applied Economics
1 (November): 35–54.
Caprio, Gerard, and Aslı Demirgüç-Kunt. 1997.
“The Role of Long-Term Finance: Theory
and Evidence.” World Bank Economic Review
10 (2): 291–321.
Caprio, Gerard, Jonathan Fiechter, Robert Litan,
and Michael Pomerleano, eds. 2004. The
Future of State-Owned Financial Institutions.
Washington, DC: Brookings Institute.
Caprio, Gerard, and Patrick Honohan. 2004. “Can the
Unsophisticated Market Provide Discipline.”
In Market Discipline across Countries and
Industries, ed. William C. Hunter, George
G. Kaufman, Claudio Borio, and Kostas
Tsatsaronis, 349–62. Cambridge, MA: MIT
Press.
Caskey, John, Clemente Ruiz Duran, and Tova
Maria Solo. 2006. “The Urban Unbanked
in Mexico and the United States.” Policy
Research Working Paper 3835, World Bank,
Washington, DC.
Cetorelli, Nicola, and Philip E. Strahan. 2004.
“Finance as a Barrier to Entry: Bank
Competition and Industry Structure in Local
U.S. Markets.” Working paper 2004-04
(January), Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago,
Chicago, IL.
Chari, Anusha, Paige Ouimet, and Linda Tesar. 2005.
“The Stock Market Valuation of Corporate
Control: Evidence from Cross-Border Mergers
and Acquisitions in Emerging Markets.”
University of Michigan, Department of
Economics, Ann Arbor, MI.
Chen, Shaohua, Ren Mu, and Martin Ravallion.
2006. “Are There Lasting Impacts of a
Poor-Area Development Program?” Policy
Research Working Paper 4084, World Bank,
Washington, DC.
Chen, Shaohua, and Martin Ravallion. 2004. “How
Have the World’s Poorest Fared since the Early
1980s?” World Bank Research Observer 19 (2):
141–69.
Chiquier, Loic, Olivier Hassler, and Michael Lea.
2004. “Mortgage Securities in Emerging
Markets.” Policy Research Working Paper
3370, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Christen, Robert Peck, Veena Jayadeva, and Richard
Rosenberg. 2004. “Financial Institutions with
a Double Bottom Line: Implications for the
Future of Microfinance.” CGAP Occasional
Paper 8, Consultative Group to Assist the
Poorest, Washington DC.
Claessens, Stijn. 2006. “Access to Financial Services:
A Review of the Issues and Public Policy
Objectives.” World Bank Research Observer
21 (2): 207–40.
Claessens, Stijn, Aslı Demirgüç-Kunt, and Harry
Huizinga. 2001. “How Does Foreign Entry
219
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Affect the Domestic Banking Market?” Journal
of Banking and Finance 25 (5): 891–911.
Claessens, Stijn, Gergely Dobos, Daniela Klingebiel,
and Luc Laeven. 2003. “The Growing
Importance of Networks in Finance and
its Effects on Competition.” In Innovations
in Financial and Economic Networks, ed. A.
Nagurney, 110–35. Northampton, MA:
Edward Elgar Publishers.
Claessens, Stijn, and Eric Feijen. 2006. “Financial
Sector Development and the Millennium
Development Goals.” World Bank Working
Paper 89, Washington, DC.
———. 2007. “Finance and Hunger: Empirical
Evidence of the Agricultural Productivity
Channel.” Policy Research Working Paper
4080, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Claessens, Stijn, Erik Feijen, and Luc Laeven. 2007.
“Political Connections and Preferential
Access to Finance: The Role of Campaign
Contributions.” Journal of Financial Economics,
forthcoming.
Claessens, Stijn, and Luc Laeven. 2003. “Financial
Development, Property Rights, and Growth.”
Journal of Finance 58 (6): 2401–36.
Bank Participation and Access to Credit across
Firms in Developing Countries.” Journal of
Comparative Economics 34 (4): 774–95.
Clarke, George R. G., Robert Cull, Maria Soledad
Martinez Peria, and Susana M. Sanchez. 2005.
“Bank Lending to Small Businesses in Latin
America: Does Bank Origin Matter?” Journal of
Money, Credit, and Banking 37 (1): 83–118.
Clarke, George, L. Colin Xu, and Heng-fu Zou.
2006. “Finance and Income Inequality: What
Do the Data Tell Us?” Southern Economic
Journal 72 (3): 578–96.
Coffee, John C. 2002. “Racing towards the Top? The
Impact of Cross-Listings and Stock Market
Competition on International Corporate
Governance.” Columbia Law and Economics
Working Paper 205, Columbia University,
New York (May 30).
Cole, Shawn. 2004. “Fixing Market Failures or Fixing
Elections? Agricultural Credit in India.”
Harvard Business School, Cambridge, MA.
Coleman, B. 1999. “The Impact of Group Lending in
Northeast Thailand.” Journal of Development
Economics 60 (1): 105-42.
———. 2004. “What Drives Bank Competition?
Some International Evidence.” Journal of
Money, Credit, and Banking 36 (3): 563–83.
Collard, Sharon, and Elaine Kempson. 2005.
Affordable Credit: The Way Forward. Bristol,
U.K.: Policy Press and Joseph Rowntree
Foundation.
Claessens, Stijn, and Neeltje van Horen. 2007.
“Location Decision of Foreign Banks and
Competitive Advantage.” Policy Research
Working Paper 4113, World Bank,
Washington, DC.
Costa, Ana Carla, and Joao de Mello. 2006. “Judicial
Risk and Credit Market Performance: Micro
Evidence from Brazilian Payroll Loans.” NBER
Working Paper 12252, National Bureau of
Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
Clarke, George R. G., Robert Cull, and Maria
Soledad Martinez Peria. 2006. “Foreign
Cotler, Pablo, and Chris Woodruff. 2007. “The Impact
of Short-Term Credit on Microenterprises:
220
REFERENCES
Evidence from the Bimbo Program in Mexico.”
Working Paper, University of California at San
Diego, School of International Relations and
Pacific Studies.
Cull, Robert, Aslı Demirgüç-Kunt, and Jonathan
Morduch. 2007. “Financial Performance
and Outreach: A Global Analysis of Leading
Microbanks.” Economic Journal 117 (517):
F107–F133.
Cull, Robert, and L. Colin Xu. 2000. “Bureaucrats,
State Banks, and the Efficiency of Credit
Allocation: The Experience of Chinese StateOwned Enterprises.” Journal of Comparative
Economics 28 (1): 1–31.
———. 2003. “Who Gets Credit? The Behavior of
Bureaucrats and State Banks in Allocating
Credit to Chinese SOEs.” Journal of
Development Economics 71 (2): 533–59.
———. 2005. “Institutions, Ownership, and Finance:
The Determinants of Profit Reinvestment
among Chinese Firms.” Journal of Financial
Economics 77 (1): 117–46.
Cumming, Douglas, Daniel Schmidt, and Uwe Walz.
2006. “Legality and Venture Governance
around the World,” Working paper, University
of Frankfurt, Department of Economics.
Dahl, Drew, Douglas Evanoff, and Michael F. Spivey.
2000. “Does the Community Reinvestment
Act Influence Lending? An Analysis of
Changes in Bank Low-Income Mortgage
Activity.” Working Paper 2000–06, Federal
Reserve Board of Chicago.
Daley-Harris, Sam. 2006. “State of the Microcredit
Summit Campaign Report 2006.” http://
www.microcreditsummit.org/pubs/reports/
socr/2006.htm.
Da Rin, Marco, Giovanna Nicodano, and Alessandro
Sembenelli. 2004. “Public Policy and the
Creation of Active Venture Capital Markets.”
Innocenzo Gasparini Institute for Economic
Research Working Paper 270, Milan, Italy.
Deaton, Angus. 2005. “Measuring Poverty in a
Growing World (or Measuring Growth in
a Poor World).” Review of Economics and
Statistics 87 (1): 1–19.
Degryse, Hans, and Steven Ongena. 2005. “Distance,
Lending Relationships, and Competition.”
Journal of Finance 60 (1): 231–66.
De Haas, Ralph, and Ilko Naaborg. 2005. “Does
Foreign Bank Entry Reduce Small Firms’
Access to Credit? Evidence from European
Transition Economies.” Working Paper 50,
De Nederlandsche Bank, Amsterdam.
Dehejia, Rajeev, Heather Montgomery, and Jonathan
Morduch. 2005. “Do Interest Rates Matter?
Credit Demand in the Dhaka Slums.” Working
paper, New York University, Department of
Economics, New York.
De Janvry, Alain, Craig McIntosh, and Elisabeth
Sadoulet. 2006. “The Supply and Demand
Side Impacts of Credit Market Information.”
Working paper, University of California,
Berkeley, Agricultural and Resource
Economics, Berkeley, CA.
De la Torre, Augusto, Juan Carlos Gozzi, and Sergio
Schmukler. 2007. “Innovative Experiences in
Access to Finance: Market Friendly Roles for
the Visible Hand?” Policy Research Working
Paper 4326, World Bank, Washington, DC.
De la Torre, Augusto, Maria Soledad Martinez Peria,
and Sergio Schmukler. 2007. “Bank Financing
to Small and Medium Enterprises: Survey
221
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Results from Argentina and Chile.” Working
paper, World Bank, Development Research
Group, Washington, DC.
———. 2007. “Finance and Economic Opportunity.”
Working paper, World Bank, Development
Research Group, Washington, DC.
De la Torre, Augusto, and Sergio Schmukler. 2004.
“Coping with Risks through Mismatches:
Domestic and International Financial
Contracts for Emerging Economies.”
International Finance 7 (3): 349–90.
Demirgüç-Kunt, Aslı, Luc Laeven, and Ross Levine.
2004. “Regulations, Market Structure,
Institutions, and the Cost of Financial
Intermediation.” Journal of Money, Credit,
and Banking 36 (3): 593–622.
De Luna Martinez, Jose. 2005. “Workers’ Remittances
to Developing Countries: A Survey with
Central Banks on Selected Public Policy
Issues.” Policy Research Working Paper 3638,
World Bank, Washington, DC.
Demirgüç-Kunt, Aslı, Ernesto Lopez-Cordova, Maria
Soledad Martinez Peria, and Christopher
Woodruff. 2007. “Remittances and Banking
Services. Evidence from Mexico.” Working
paper World Bank, Development Research
Group, Washington, DC.
De Mel, Suresh, David McKenzie, and Christopher
Woodruff. 2007. “Returns to Capital in
Microenterprises: Evidence from a Field
Experiment.” Policy Research Working Paper
4230, World Bank, Washington, DC.
De Meza, David, and David C. Webb. 1987. “Too
Much Investment: A Problem of Asymmetric
Information.” Quarterly Journal of Economics
102 (2): 281–92.
Demirgüç-Kunt, Aslı, and Edward Kane. 2002.
“Deposit Insurance around the Globe? Where
Does It Work?” Journal of Economic Perspectives
16 (2): 175–95.
Demirgüç-Kunt, Aslı, Leora Klapper, and Giorgios
Panos. 2007. “The Origins of Self-Employment.”
Working paper, World Bank, Development
Research Group, Washington, DC.
Demirgüç-Kunt, Aslı, and Ross Levine. 2001.
Financial Structure and Economic Growth: A
Cross-Country Comparison of Banks, Markets
and Development. Cambridge, MA: MIT
Press.
222
Demirgüç-Kunt, Aslı, Inessa Love, and Vojislav
Maksimovic. 2006. “Business Environment
and the Incorporation Decision.” Journal of
Banking and Finance 30 (11): 2967–93.
Demirgüç-Kunt, Aslı, and Vojislav Maksimovic.
1998. “Law, Finance, and Firm Growth.”
Journal of Finance 53 (6): 2107–37.
———. 1999. “Institutions, Financial Markets, and
Firm Debt Maturity.” Journal of Financial
Economics 54 (3): 295–336.
———. 2002. “Funding Growth in Bank-Based and
Market-Based Financial Systems: Evidence
from Firm-Level Data.” Journal of Financial
Economics 65 (3): 337–63.
Demirgüç-Kunt, Aslı, and Maria Soledad Martinez
Peria. 2007. “Remittances and the Use of
Banking Services. Evidence from El Salvador.”
Working paper, World Bank, Development
Research Group, Washington, DC.
De Nicolo, Gianni, Patrick Honohan, and Alain Ize.
2005. “Dollarization of the Banking System:
REFERENCES
Good or Bad?” Journal of Banking and Finance
1647–1727.
Journal of the European Economic Association
3 (2–3): 587–97.
Desai, Mihir, and Alberto Moel. 2007. “Czech
Mate: Expropriation and Investor Protection
in a Converging World.” Review of Finance,
forthcoming.
Dollar, David, and Aart Kraay. 2002. “Growth
is Good for the Poor.” Journal of Economic
Growth 7 (3): 195–225.
Detragiache, Enrica, Poonam Gupta, and Thierry
Tressel. 2006. “Foreign Banks in Poor
Countries: Theory and Evidence.” Working
Paper 06/18, International Monetary Fund,
Washington, DC.
Diamond, Douglas. W. 1984. “Financial
Intermediation and Delegated Monitoring.”
Review of Economic Studies 51 (3): 393–414.
Dinç, Serdar. 2005. “Politicians and Banks: Political
Influences on Government-Owned Banks in
Emerging Countries.” Journal of Financial
Economics 77 (2): 453–79.
Djankov, Simeon, Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopezde-Silanes, and Andrei Shleifer. 2005. “The
Law and Economics of Self-Dealing.” NBER
Working Paper 11883. National Bureau of
Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
Djankov, Simeon, Caralee McLiesh, Tatiana Nenova,
and Andrei Shleifer. 2003. “Who Owns the
Media?” Journal of Law and Economics 46
(October): 341–82.
Djankov, Simeon, Caralee McLiesh, and Andrei
Shleifer. 2007. “Private Credit in 129
Countries.” Journal of Financial Economics
84 (2): 299–329.
Djankov, Simeon, Edward Miguel, Yingyi Qian,
Gerard Roland, and Ekaterina Zhuravskaya.
2005. “Who Are Russia’s Entrepreneurs?”
Doran, Alan, and Jacob Levitsky. 1997. “Credit
Guarantee Schemes for Small Business
Lending: A Global Perspective.” Graham
Bannock and Partners Ltd., London.
Dorn, Helmut. 2005. “Practices and Policies in
Credit Guarantee Programs in the EU.”
Powerpoint presentation at the EU Workshop
on SME Credit Guarantee Systems, October
26–28, 2005, Shanghai, China. http://info
.worldbank.org/etools/docs/library/202079/
Helmut%5FDorn%5FPractices%5Fand%
5FPolicies%5Fin%5FCredit%5FGuarantee%
5FPrograms%5Fin%5Fthe%5FEU.pdf.
Duflo, Esther, and Michael Kremer. 2005. “Use
of Randomization in the Evaluation of
Development Effectiveness.” In Evaluating
Development Effectiveness, ed. O. Feinstein, G.
K. Ingram, and G. K. Pitman, vol. 7, 205–32.
London, U.K.: Transaction Publishers.
Ellison, Anna, Sharon Collard, and Rob Forster.
2006. “Illegal Lending in the U.K.” Research
Report URN 06/1883, U.K. Department of
Trade and Industry, London.
Emran, M. Shahe, AKM Mahbub Morshed, and
Joseph Stiglitz. 2006. “Microfinance and
Missing Markets.” Working paper, Columbia
University, Department of Economics, New
York.
European Commission (2005). “Public Opinion
in Europe on Financial Services.” Special
223
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Eurobarometer 230. http://europa.eu.int/
comm/consumers/cons_int/fina_serv/cons_
experiences/background_en.htm.
Evans, David S., and Richard Schmalensee. 2005.
Paying with Plastic, 2d ed. Cambridge, MA:
MIT Press.
Fafchamps, Marcel. 2004. Market Institutions in
Sub-Saharan Africa: Theory and Evidence.
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Feijen, Eric, and Enrico C. Perotti. 2005. “The
Political Economy of Financial Fragility.”
CEPR Discussion Paper 5317, Centre for
Economic Policy Research, London.
Ferri, Giovanni, Li-Gang Liu, and Giovanni
Majnoni. 2001. “The Role of Rating Agencies
Assessments in Less Developed Countries:
Impact of the Proposed Basel Guidelines.”
Journal of Banking and Finance 25 (1):
115–48.
Field, Erica, and Maximo Torero. 2006. “Do Property
Titles Increase Access to Credit among the
Urban Poor? Evidence from a Nationwide
Titling Program.” Working paper, Harvard
University, Department of Economics,
Cambridge, MA.
Firpo, Janine. 2005. “Banking the Unbanked:
Technology’s Role in Delivering Accessible
Financial Services to the Poor.” In Electronic
Banking with the Poor, ed. Stuart Mathison.
Foundation for Development Cooperation.
https://securesites.golden-orb.com/websites
.golden-orb.com/fdc/100462.php.
Fisman, Raymond J. 2003. “Ethnic Ties and the
Provision of Credit: Relationship-Level
224
Evidence from African Firms.” Advances in
Economic Analysis and Policy 3 (1).
Fisman, Raymond J., and Inessa Love. 2003. “Trade
Credit, Financial Intermediary Development,
and Industry Growth.” Journal of Finance 58
(1): 353–74.
Flug, Karnit, Antonio Spilimbergo, and Erik
Wachtenheim. 1998. “Investment in
Education: Do Economic Volatility and Credit
Constraints Matter?” Journal of Development
Economics 55 (2): 465–81.
Forbes, Kristin. 2000. “A Reassessment of the
Relationship between Inequality and Growth.”
American Economic Review 90 (4): 869–87.
Freund, Caroline, and Nikola Spatafora. 2005.
“Remittances : Transaction Costs,
Determinants, and Informal Flows.” Policy
Research Working Paper 3704, World Bank,
Washington, DC.
Galiani, Sebastian, and Ernesto Schargrodsky.
2005. “Property Rights for the Poor: Effects
of Land Titling.” Working paper, Centro de
Investigacion en Finanzas, Buenos Aires.
Galor, Oded, and Joseph Zeira. 1993. “Income
Distribution and Macroeconomics.” Review
of Economic Studies 60 (1): 35–52.
Genesis. 2005a. “An Inter-Country Survey of
the Relative Costs of Bank Accounts.”
Johannesburg.
———. 2005b. “Measuring Access to Transaction
Banking Services in the Southern Customs
Union: An Index Approach.” Johannesburg.
Gertler, Paul, David Levine, and Enrico Moretti. 2003.
“Do Microfinance Programs Help Families
Insure Consumption against Illness?” Center
REFERENCES
for International and Development Economics
Research Working Paper, University of
California, Berkeley.
Ghatak, Maithreesh, and Timothy Guinnane. 1999.
“The Economics of Lending with Joint
Liability: Theory and Practice.” Journal of
Development Economics 60 (1): 195–228.
Giannetti, Mariassunta, and Steven Ongena. 2005.
“Financial Integration and Entrepreneurial
Activity: Evidence from Foreign Bank Entry
in Emerging Markets.” Working Paper
498, European Central Bank, Frankfurt,
Germany.
Gibson, John, Geua Boe-Gibson, Halahingano
Rohorua, and David McKenzie. 2006.
“Efficient Financial Services for Development
in the Pacific.” Working paper, World Bank,
Development Research Group, Washington,
DC.
Gibson, John, David McKenzie, and Halahingano
Rohorua. 2006.” How Cost-Elastic Are
Remittances? Estimates from Tongan
Migrants in New Zealand?” Working paper,
World Bank, Development Research Group,
Washington, DC.
Giné, Xavier. 2005. “Access to Capital in Rural
Thailand: An Estimated Model of Formal
vs. Informal Credit.” Policy Research Working
Paper 3502, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Giné, Xavier, Pamela Jakiela, Dean Karlan, and
Jonathan Morduch. 2006. “Microfinance
Games.” Policy Research Working Paper
3959, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Giné, Xavier, and Dean Karlan. 2006. “Group vs.
Individual Liability: A Field Experiment in the
Philippines.” Policy Research Working Paper
4008, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Giné, Xavier, and Inessa Love. 2006. “Do
Reorganization Costs Matter for Efficiency?
Evidence from a Bankruptcy Reform in
Colombia.” Policy Research Working Paper
3970, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Giné, Xavier, and Robert Townsend. 2004.
“Evaluation of Financial Liberalization: A
General Equilibrium Model with Constrained
Occupation Choice.” Journal of Development
Economics 74 (2): 269–307.
Giné, Xavier, Robert Townsend, and James Vickery.
2007. “Patterns of Rainfall Insurance
Participation in Rural India.” Working Paper,
World Bank, Development Research Group,
Washington, DC.
Giné, Xavier, and Dean Yang. 2007. “Insurance,
Credit and Technology Adoption: A Field
Experimental Approach.” Working Paper,
World Bank, Development Research Group,
Washington, DC.
Goldberg, Nathanael, and Dean Karlan. 2005.
“The Impact of Microfinance: A Review
of Methodological Issues.” Yale University,
Department of Economics, New Haven,
CT.
Goldstein, Morris, and Philip Turner. 2004.
Controlling Currency Mismatches in Emerging
Markets. Washington, DC: Institute for
International Economics.
Gonzalez-Vega, Claudio. 2003. “Deepening Rural
Financial Markets: Macroeconomic, Policy
and Political Dimensions.” Presented to
the USAID-WOCCU Conference: Paving
the Way Forward for Rural Finance: An
225
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
International Conference on Best Practices.
Washington DC, March 2003. http://www.
basis.wisc.edu/rfc/.
Goodwin-Groen, Ruth. 2007. The National Credit
Act and Its Regulations in the Context of Access
to Finance in South Africa. Johannesburg:
Finmark Trust.
Green, Richard K., and Susan M. Wachter. 2005.
“The American Mortgage in Historical and
International Context.” Journal of Economic
Perspectives 19 (4): 93–114.
Greenwood, Jeremy, and Boyan Jovanovic. 1990.
“Financial Development, Growth, and the
Distribution of Income.” Journal of Political
Economy 98 (5): 1076-1107.
Gormley, Todd A. 2004. “Banking Competition in
Developing Countries: Does Foreign Bank
Entry Improve Credit Access?” Working
paper, Washington University, John M. Olin
School of Business, St. Louis.
Greif, Avner. 1993. “Contract Enforceability and
Economic Institutions in Early Trade: The
Maghribi Traders’ Coalition.” American
Economic Review 83 (3): 525–48.
Gormley, Todd A., Simon H. Johnson, and
Changyong Rhee. 2006. “Corporate Bonds:
A Spare Tire in Emerging Markets?” Working
paper, Washington University, John M. Olin
School of Business, St. Louis.
Grose, Claire, and Felice B. Friedman. 2006.
“Promoting Access to Primary Equity
Markets: A Legal and Regulatory Approach.”
Policy Research Working Paper 3892, World
Bank, Washington, DC.
Gozzi, Juan Carlos, Ross E. Levine, and Sergio L.
Schmukler. 2007. “Internationalization and
the Evolution of Corporate Valuation.” Journal
of Financial Economics, forthcoming.
Guadamillas, Mario. 2007. “Balancing Competition
and Cooperation in Retail Payment Systems.”
Powerpoint presentation. http://info
.worldbank.org/etools/library/latestversion
.asp?240389.
Gracey, A. D. 2001. Guarantee Mechanisms for
Financing Innovative Technology: Survey
and Analysis. Luxembourg: European
Commission.
Graham, Teresa. 2004. Review of the UK Small Firms
Loan Guarantee Scheme. London: Her Majesty’s
Stationery Office. http://www.hm-treasury
.gov.uk/independent_reviews/graham.
Green, Anke. 2003. “Credit Guarantee Schemes for
Small Enterprises: An Effective Instrument
to Promote Private Sector-Led Growth?”
SME Technical Working Paper 10. Vienna:
United Nations Industrial Development
Organization.
226
Guarcello, Lorenzo, Fabrizia Mealli, and Furio
Rosati. 2003. “Household Vulnerability and
Child Labour: The Effects of Shocks, Credit
Rationing, and Insurance.” Working paper,
Understanding Children’s Work Research
Project, Washington DC. http://www
.ucw-project.org/pdf/publications/standard_
CL_and_Vulnerability.pdf.
Gupta, Nandini, and Kathy Yuan. 2003. “Financial
Dependence, Stock Market Liberalizations,
and Growth.” William Davidson Institute
Working Paper 562, University of Michigan,
Ann Arbor.
REFERENCES
Haber, Stephen. 2005. “Political Institutions and
Financial Development: Evidence from the
Economic Histories of Mexico and the United
States.” Stanford Center for International
Development Working Paper 268, Stanford
University, Palo Alto, CA.
Haber, Stephen, and Aldo Musacchio. 2005. “Contract
Rights and Risk Aversion: Foreign Banks and
the Mexican Economy, 1997–2000.” Stanford
University, Department of Economics, Palo
Alto, CA
Halac, Marina, and Sergio Schmukler. 2004.
“Distributional Effects of Crises: The Financial
Channel.” Economia 5 (1): 1–67.
Hanson, James A. 2004. “The Transformation
of State-Owned Banks.” In The Future of
State-Owned Financial Institutions, ed. Gerard
Caprio, Jonathan Fiechter, Robert Litan,
and Michael Pomerleano. Washington DC:
Brookings Institution Press.
Harrison, Ann, Inessa Love, and Margaret McMillan.
2004. “Global Capital Flows and Financing
Constraints.” Journal of Development Economics
75 (1): 269–301.
Harrison, Ann, and Margaret McMillan. 2003.
“Does Direct Foreign Investment Affect
Domestic Firm Credit Constraints?” Journal
of International Economics 61 (1): 73–100.
Haselmann, Rainer F. H., Katharina Pistor, and
Vikrant Vig. 2006. “How Law Affects
Lending.” Columbia Law and Economics
Working Paper 285. Columbia University,
New York.
Haselmann, R., and P. Wachtel. 2006. “Institutions
and Bank Behavior.” Stern Economics
Working Paper 06-16, New York University,
New York.
Helms, Brigit, and Xavier Reille. 2004. “Interest Rate
Ceilings and Microfinance: The Story So Far.”
CGAP Occasional Paper 9, Consultative Group
to Assist the Poorest, Washington, DC.
Hernández-Coss, Raúl. 2005. “The U.S.-Mexico
Remittance Corridor: Lessons on Shifting from
Informal to Formal Remittance Systems.” World
Bank, Financial Sector, Washington, DC.
Hernández-Coss, Raúl, Chinyere Egwuagu, Jennifer
Isern, and David Porteous. 2005. “AML/CFT
Regulation: Implications for Financial Service
Providers that Help Low-Income People.”
CGAP Focus Note 29, Consultative Group
to Assist the Poorest, Washington, DC.
Himmelberg, Charles P., R. Glenn Hubbard, and
Inessa Love. 2002. “Investor Protection,
Ownership, and the Cost of Capital.” Policy
Research Working Paper 2834, World Bank,
Washington, DC.
Honohan, Patrick. 2001. “Perverse Effects of an
External Ratings-Related Capital Adequacy
System.” Economic Notes 30 (3): 359–72.
———, ed. 2003. Taxation of Financial Intermediation:
Theory and Practice for Developing Countries.
New York: Oxford University Press.
———. 2004. “Financial Sector Policy and the Poor.”
Working Paper 43, World Bank, Washington,
DC.
———. 2005a. “Banking Sector Crises and
Inequality.” Policy Research Working Paper
3659, World Bank, Washington, DC.
———. 2005b. “Measuring Microfinance Access:
Building on Existing Cross-Country Data.”
227
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Policy Research Working Paper 3606, World
Bank, Washington, DC.
http://islamic-finance.net/journals/journal2/
art5.pdf.
———. 2006. “Household Financial Assets in the
Process of Development.” Policy Research
Working Paper 3965, World Bank, Washington
DC.
Jayaratne, Jith, and Phil Strahan. 1996. “The FinanceGrowth Nexus: Evidence from Bank Branch
Deregulation.” Quarterly Journal of Economics
111 (3): 639–70.
Honohan, Patrick, and Thorsten Beck. 2007. Making
Finance Work for Africa. Washington, DC:
World Bank.
Jensen, Michael. 1988. “Agency Costs of Free Cash
Flow, Corporate Finance, and the Market for
Takeovers.” American Economic Review 76 (2):
323–29.
Hubbard, Glenn. 1998. “Capital Market Imperfections
and Investment.” Journal of Economics
Literature 36 (1): 193–225.
Huybens, Elisabeth, and Bruce Smith. 1998.
“Financial Market Frictions, Monetary Policy,
and Capital Accumulation in a Small Open
Economy.” Journal of Economic Theory 81:
353–400.
———. 1999. “Inflation, Financial Markets, and
Long-Run Real Activity.” Journal of Monetary
Economics 43 (2): 283–315.
Jacoby, Hanan G. 1994. “Borrowing Constraints and
Progress through School: Evidence from Peru.”
Review of Economic Studies 76 (1): 151–60.
Jacoby, Hanan G., and Emmanuel Skoufias. 1997.
“Risk, Financial Markets, and Human Capital
in a Developing Country.” Review of Economic
Studies 64 (3): 311–35.
Jain, Sanjay, and Ghazala Mansuri. 2003. “A Little
at a Time: The Use of Regularly Scheduled
Repayments in Microfinance Programs.”
Journal of Development Economics 72 (1):
253–79.
Jaumdally, Adnan Ally Mamode. 1999. “Discussion:
Speculation and Gambling.” International
Journal of Islamic Financial Services 1 (2).
228
Jeong, Hyeok, and Robert Townsend. 2003. “Growth
and Inequality: Model Evaluation Based on
Estimation-Calibration Strategy.” Institute
of Economic Policy Research Paper 05.10,
University of Southern California, Los
Angeles.
Jin, Li, and Stewart C. Myers. 2006. “R 2 around the
World: New Theory and New Tests.” Journal
of Financial Economics 79 (2): 257–92.
Johnson, Susan. 2007. “Gender and Microfinance:
Guidelines for Good Practice.” http://www
.gdrc.org/icm/wind/gendersjonson.html.
Johnston, Don, and Jonathan Morduch. 2007.
“Microcredit vs. Microsaving: Evidence from
Indonesia.” http://siteresources.worldbank
.org/INTFR /Resources /Microcredit_
versus_ Microsaving _Evidence_from_
Indonesia.pdf.
Karlan, Dean. 2005. “Using Experimental Economics
to Measure Social Capital and Predict Financial
Decisions.” American Economic Review 95 (5):
1688–99.
———. 2007. “Social Connections and Group
Banking.” Economic Journal 117 (517):
F52–F84.
REFERENCES
Karlan, Dean, and Martin Valdivia. 2006. “Teaching
Entrepreneurship: Impact of Business Training
on Microfinance Clients and Institutions.”
Yale University, Department of Economics,
New Haven, CT.
Karlan, Dean, and Jonathan Zinman. 2006a.
“Expanding Credit Access: Using Randomized
Supply Decisions to Estimate the Impacts.”
Yale University, Department of Economics,
New Haven, CT.
———. 2006b. “Observing Unobservables:
Identifying Information Asymmetries with
a Consumer Credit Field Experiment.” Yale
University, Department of Economics, New
Haven, CT.
———. Forthcoming. “Credit Elasticities in Less
Developed Countries: Implications for
Microfinance.” American Economic Review.
Keeton, W. 1979. Equilibrium Credit Rationing. New
York: Garland Press.
Kempson, Elaine, Claire Whyley, John Caskey, and
Sharon Collard. 2000. “In or Out? Financial
Exclusion: A Literature and Research Review.”
Financial Services Authority, London.
Khandker, Shahidur R. 2003. “Microfinance and
Poverty: Evidence Using Panel Data from
Bangladesh.” Policy Research Working Paper
2945, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Khwaja, Asim Ijaz, and Atif Mian. 2005. “Do
Lenders Favor Politically Connected Firms?
Rent Provision in an Emerging Financial
Market.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 120
(4): 1371–411.
Klapper, Leora. 2006. “The Role of Reverse Factoring
in Supplier Financing of Small and Medium
Sized Enterprises.” Journal of Banking and
Finance 30 (11): 3111–30.
Klapper, Leora, Luc Laeven, and Raghuram Rajan.
2006. “Entry Regulation as a Barrier to
Entrepreneurship.” Journal of Financial
Economics 82 (3): 591–629.
KPMG Management Consulting. 1999. An Evaluation
of the Small Firms Loan Guarantee Scheme.
London: U.K. Department of Trade and
Industry.
Kroszner, Randall S., and Philip E. Strahan. 1999.
“What Drives Deregulation? Economics and
Politics of the Relaxation of Bank Branching
Restrictions.” Quarterly Journal of Economics
114 (4): 1437–67.
Kuijs, Louis. 2005. “Investment and Saving in
China.” Policy Research Working Paper 3633,
Washington, DC, World Bank.
Kumar, Anjali. 2005. Access to Financial Services in
Brazil. World Bank, Washington, DC.
Kuznets, Simon. 1955. “Economic Growth and
Income Inequality.” American Economic
Review 45 (1): 1–28.
———. 1963. “Quantitative Aspects of the Economic
Growth of Nations.” Economic Development
and Cultural Change 11 (2): 1–80.
Laeven, Luc. 2003. “Does Financial Liberalization
Reduce Financing Constraints?” Financial
Management 2003 (Spring): 5–34.
Laeven, Luc, and Christopher Woodruff. 2007. “The
Quality of the Legal System, Firm Ownership,
and Firm Size.” Review of Economics and
Statistics, forthcoming.
229
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
La Porta, Rafael, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, and
Andrei Shleifer. 1999. “Corporate Ownership
around the World.” Journal of Finance 54 (2):
471-517.
———. 2007b. “Migration, Spillovers, and Trade
Diversion: The Impact of Internationalization
on Domestic Market Liquidity.” Journal of
Banking and Finance 31 (6): 1595–1612.
———. 2006. “What Works in Securities Laws?’
Journal of Finance 61 (1): 1–32.
Levitsky, Jacob. 1997. “SME Guarantee Schemes: A
Summary.” The Financier 4 (1 and 2): 5–11.
http://www.the-financier.com.
La Porta, Rafael, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, Andrei
Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny. 1997. “Legal
Determinants of External Finance.” Journal
of Finance 52 (3): 1131–50.
———. 1998. “Law and Finance.” Journal of Political
Economy 106 (6): 1113–55.
La Porta, Rafael, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, and
Guillermo Zamarripa. 2003. “Related
Lending.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 118
(1): 231–68.
Larraín, C., and J. Quiroz. 2006. “Estudio para el
fondo de garantía de pequeños empresarios.”
Santiago: Banco Estado.
Leeds, Roger, and Julie Sunderland. 2003. “Private
Equity Investing In Emerging Markets.” Journal
of Applied Corporate Finance 15 (4): 8–16.
Levine, Ross E. 2002. “Bank-Based or Market-Based
Financial Systems: Which Is Better?” Journal
of Financial Intermediation 11 (1): 1–30.
———. 2005. “Finance and Growth: Theory
and Evidence.” In Handbook of Economic
Growth, ed. Philippe Aghion and Steven
Durlauf. Amsterdam: North-Holland Elsevier
Publishers.
Levine, Ross E., and Sergio L. Schmukler. 2007a.
“Internationalization and Stock Market
Liquidity.” Review of Finance 10 (1): 153–87.
230
Levy-Yeyati, Eduardo, and Alejandro Micco. 2007.
“Concentration and Foreign Penetration in
Latin American Banking Sectors: Impact on
Competition and Risk.” Journal of Banking
and Finance 31 (6): 1633–47.
Levy-Yeyati, Eduardo, Alejandro Micco, and Ugo
G. Panizza. 2006. “State-Owned Banks:
Do They Promote or Depress Financial
Development and Economic Growth?”
http://ssrn.com/abstract=629384.
Li, Hongyi, Lyn Squire, and Heng-fu Zou. 1998.
“Explaining International and Intertemporal
Variations in Income Inequality.” Economic
Journal 108 (446): 26–43.
Li, Hongyi, Lixin Colin Xu, and Heng-fu Zou.
2000. “Corruption, Income Distribution,
and Growth.” Economics and Politics 12 (2):
155–82.
Littlefield, Elizabeth, Jonathan Morduch, and
Syed Hashemi. 2003. “Is Microfinance an
Effective Strategy to Reach the Millennium
Development Goals.” CGAP Focus Note 24.
Consultative Group to Assist the Poorest,
Washington, DC.
Love, Inessa, 2003. “Financial Development and
Financing Constraints: International Evidence
from the Structural Investment Model.”
Review of Financial Studies 16 (3): 765–91.
REFERENCES
Love, Inessa, and Natalia Mylenko. 2003. “Credit
Reporting and Financing Constraints.” Policy
Research Working Paper 3142, World Bank,
Washington, DC.
Love, Inessa, Lorenzo A. Preve, and Virginia SarriaAllende. 2007. “Trade Credit and Bank Credit:
Evidence from Recent Financial Crises.” Journal
of Financial Economics 83 (2): 453–69.
Luoto, Jill, Craig McIntosh, and Bruce Wydick.
2007. “Credit Information Systems in LessDeveloped Countries: A Test with Microfinance
in Guatemala.” Economic Development and
Cultural Change 55 (2): 313–34.
Malesky, Edmund, and Markus Taussig. 2005. “Where
Is Credit Due? Companies, Banks, and Locally
Differentiated Investment Growth in Vietnam.”
http://homepage.mac.com/markustaussig/.
Public/MaleskyTaussig.pdf.
Working paper, World Bank, Development
Research Group, Washington, DC.
Mian, Atif. 2006. “Distance Constraints: The Limits
of Foreign Lending in Poor Economies.”
Journal of Finance 61 (3): 1465–1505.
Micco, Alejandro, Ugo Panizza, and Monica Yañez.
2007. “Bank Ownership and Performance:
Does Politics Matter?” Journal of Banking and
Finance 31 (1): 219–41.
Miller, Margaret, ed. 2003. Credit Reporting Systems
and the International Economy. Cambridge,
MA: MIT Press.
Mitton, Todd. 2006. “Why Have Debt Ratios
Increased for Firms in Emerging Markets?”
Working paper, Brigham Young University,
School of Management, Provo, Utah.
Mankin, N. Gregory, David Romer, and David N.
Weil. 1992. “A Contribution to the Empirics
of Economic Growth.” Quarterly Journal of
Economics 107 (2): 407–37.
Moran, Theodore H. 2005. “How Does FDI Affect
Host Country Development.” In Does Foreign
Direct Investment Promote Development?, ed.
Theodore H. Moran, Edward M. Graham, and
Magnus Blomström, 281–313. Washington
DC: International Institute of Economics.
Martinez Peria, Maria Soledad, and Ashoka Mody.
2004. “How Foreign Participation and Market
Concentration Impact Bank Spreads: Evidence
from Latin America.” Journal of Money, Credit,
and Banking 36 (3): 510–37.
Morck, Randall K., and Lloyd Steier. 2005. “The
Global History of Corporate Governance: An
Introduction.” NBER Working Paper 11062,
National Bureau of Economic Research,
Cambridge, MA.
Maurer, Noel, and Stephen Haber. 2004. “Related
Lending and Economic Performance: Evidence
from Mexico.” Working paper, Stanford
University, Department of Economics, Palo
Alto, CA.
Morck, Randall, and Bernard Yeung. 2003. “Family
Control and the Rent-Seeking Society.”
William Davidson Institute Working Paper
585, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor,
MI.
McKenzie, David J., and Christopher Woodruff.
2007. “Experimental Evidence on Returns to
Capital and Access to Finance in Mexico.”
Morck, Randall K., Bernard Yeung, and W. Yu.
2000. “The Information Content of Stock
Markets: Why Do Emerging Markets Have
231
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Synchronous Stock Movements?” Journal of
Financial Economics 58 (1-2): 215–60.
Morduch, Jonathan. 1998. “Does Microfinance
Really Help the Poor? New Evidence from
Flagship Programs in Bangladesh.” Princeton
University, Department of Economics,
Princeton, NJ.
———. 1999. “The Microfinance Promise.” Journal
of Economic Literature 37 (4): 1569–1614.
———. 2006 “Microinsurance: The Next
Revolution?” In Understanding Poverty,
ed. Abhijit V. Banerjee, Roland Benabou,
and Dilip Mookherjee. New York: Oxford
University Press.
Nenova, Tatiana. 2003. “The Value of Corporate
Voting Rights and Control: A Cross-Country
Analysis.” Journal of Financial Economics 68
(3): 325–51.
North, Douglass C., John Joseph Wallis, and Barry
R. Weingast. 2006. “A Conceptual Framework
for Interpreting Recorded Human History.”
NBER Working Paper 12795, National Bureau
of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
Obaidullah, Mohammed. 2005. Islamic Financial
Services. Jeddah: King Abdulazziz University.
Omiccioli, Massimo. 2005. “Trade Credit as
Collateral.” Temi di discussione (Economic
Working Papers) 553, Bank of Italy, Economic
Research Department, Rome.
Ortiz-Molina, Hernan, and Maria Fabiana Penas.
2006. “Lending to Small Businesses: The Role
of Loan Maturity in Addressing Information
Problems.” Working paper, University of
British Columbia, Sauder School of Business
Working Paper, Vancouver.
232
Pande, Rohini, and Christopher Udry. 2006.
“Institutions and Development: A View
from Below.” Working paper, Yale University,
Department of Economics, New Haven,
CT.
Paulson, Anna, Robert M. Townsend, and Alexander
Karaivanov. 2006. “Distinguishing Limited
Liability from Moral Hazard in a Model of
Entrepreneurship.” Journal of Political Economy
114 (1): 100–144.
Peachey, Stephen, and Alan Roe. 2006. “Access
to Finance: Measuring the Contribution
of Savings Banks.” World Savings Banks
Institute, Brussels, Belgium.
Perotti, Enrico C., and Paolo F. Volpin. 2004.
“Lobbying on Entry.” CEPR Working Paper
4519, Centre for Economic Policy Research,
London.
Perotti, Roberto. 1992. “Fiscal Policy, Income
Distribution, and Growth. “Working Paper
636, Columbia University, Department of
Economics, New York.
———. 1993. “Political Equilibrium, Income
Distribution, and Growth.” Review of Economic
Studies 60 (4): 755–76.
———. 1996. “Income Distribution and Growth.”
Journal of Economic Growth 1 (2): 149–87.
Persson, Torsten, and Guido Tabellini. 1994. “Is
Inequality Harmful for Growth?” American
Economic Review 84 (3): 600–21.
Pitt, M. M., and S. R. Khandker. 1998. “The Impact
of Group-Based Credit Programs on Poor
Households in Bangladesh: Does the Gender
of Participants Matter?” Journal of Political
Economy 106 (5): 958–96.
REFERENCES
Policis. 2004. “The Effect of Interest Rate Controls in
Other Countries.” U.K. Department of Trade
and Industry, London.
———. “Economic and Social Risks of Consumer
Credit Market Regulation: A Comparative
Analysis of the Regulatory and Consumer
Protection Frameworks for Consumer Credit
in France, Germany and the U.K.” London,
U.K. http://www.policis.com/Economic
%20and%20Social%20Risks%20of%20
Consumer%20Credit%20Market%20
Regulation.pdf.
Porteous, David. 2005. “The Access Frontier as an
Approach and Tool in Making Markets Work
for the Poor.” Finmark Trust, South Africa.
———. 2006. “The Enabling Environment for
Mobile Banking in Africa.” Bankable Frontier
Associates. http://www.bankablefrontier.com/
assets/ee.mobil.banking.report.v3.1.pdf.
Powell, Andrew P., Nataliya Mylenko, Margaret Miller,
and Giovanni Majnoni. 2004. “Improving
Credit Information, Bank Regulation, and
Supervision: On the Role and Design of Public
Credit Registries.” Policy Research Working
Paper 3443, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Paper 07/25, Inernational Monetary Fund,
Washington, DC.
Rajan, Raghuram. 2006a. “The Persistence of
Underdevelopment: Constituencies and
Competitive Rent Preservation.” Working
Paper, University of Chicago, Graduate School
of Business, Chicago.
———. 2006b. “Separate and Unequal.” Finance and
Development 43 (1): 56–57.
Rajan, Raghuram, and Luigi Zingales. 1998.
“Financial Dependence and Growth.”
American Economic Review 88 (3): 559–87.
———. 2003. Saving Capitalism from the Capitalists.
New York: Crown Business.
Ravallion, Martin. 2001. “Growth, Inequality, and
Poverty: Looking beyond Averages.” World
Development 29 (11): 23–49.
———. 2004. “Pro-Poor Growth: A Primer.”
World Bank, Development Research Group,
Washington, DC.
Rioja, Felix, and Neven Valev. 2004a. “Does One Size
Fit All? A Reexamination of the Finance and
Growth Relationship.” Journal of Development
Economics 74 (2): 429–47.
Prahalad, C. K. 2004. The Fortune at the Bottom of the
Pyramid: Eradicating Poverty through Profits.
Philadelphia: Wharton School Publishing.
———. 2004b. “Finance and the Sources of Growth
at Various Stages of Economic Development.”
Economic Inquiry 42 (1): 127–40.
Qian, Jun, and Philip E. Strahan. 2007. “How Law
and Institutions Shape Financial Contracts:
The Case of Bank Loans.” Journal of Finance,
forthcoming.
Robinson, Marguerite. 2001. The Microfinance
Revolution: Sustainable Banking for the Poor.
Washington, DC: World Bank.
Quintyn, Marc, Silvia Ramirez, and Michael Taylor.
2007. “The Fear of Freedom: Politicians and
the Independence and Accountability of
Financial Sector Supervisors.” IMF Working
Rocha, Roberto, and Gregorio Impavido. 2006.
“Competition and Performance in the
Hungarian Second Pillar.” Policy Research
Working Paper 3876, World Bank,
Washington, DC.
233
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Rocha, Roberto, and Craig Thorburn. 2007.
Developing Annuity Markets: The Experience
of Chile. Washington DC: World Bank.
Roth, Jim, Michael McCord, and Dominic Liber.
2007. “The Landscape of Microinsurance
in the World’s 100 Poorest Countries.”
Microinsurance Centre, Appleton, WI.
Rousseau, Peter, and Paul Wachtel. 2005. “Economic
Growth and Financial Depth: Is the
Relationship Extinct Already?” Stern School
of Business Working Paper 05-15, New York
University, New York.
Rubenstein, David M. 2006. “Have Emerging
Markets Finally Left Behind their Second
Class Citizenship for Private Equity Investors?”
Presentation to EMPEA Conference, May.
The Carlyle Group, Washington, DC
Rutherford, Stuart. 1998. “The Savings of the Poor:
Improving Financial Services in Bangladesh.”
Journal of International Development 10 (1):
1–15.
Sapienza, Paula. 2004. “The Effects of Government
Ownership on Bank Lending.” Journal of
Financial Economics 72 (2): 357–84.
Schiantarelli, Fabio. 1995. “Financial Constraints
and Investment: A Critical Review of
Methodological Issues and International
Evidence. In Is Bank Lending Important for the
Transmission of Monetary Policy?, ed. Joe Peek
and Eric Rosengren. Federal Reserve Bank of
Boston, Boston, MA.
Schulz, Heiner. 2006. “Foreign Banks in Mexico:
New Conquistadors or Agents of Change?”
Wharton Financial Institutions Center
Working Paper 06-11, Philadelphia.
234
Semenova, Maria. 2006. “Information Sharing in
Credit Markets: Incentives for Incorrect
Information Reporting.” Working paper,
Higher School of Economics, Moscow,
Russia.
Shim, Ilhyock. 2006. “Corporate Credit Guarantees
in Asia.” BIS Quarterly Review (December):
85–98.
Sorge, Marco, and Chendi Zhang. 2006. “Credit
Information Quality and Corporate Debt
Maturity: Theory and Evidence.” Policy
Research Working Paper 4239, World Bank,
Washington, DC.
Stiglitz, Joseph, and Andrew Weiss. 1981. “Credit
Rationing in Markets with Imperfect
Information.” American Economic Review 71
(3): 393–410.
Stulz, Rene. 1990. “Managerial Discretion and
Optimal Financing Policies.” Journal of
Financial Economics 26 (1): 3–27.
Tirole, Jean. 2006. The Theory of Corporate Finance.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Townsend, Robert, and Kenichi Ueda. 2006.
“Financial Deepening, Inequality and Growth:
A Model-Based Quantitative Evaluation.”
Review of Economic Studies 73 (1): 251–93.
U.K. Department of Trade and Industry. 2003. “Fair,
Clear and Competitive: The Consumer Credit
Market in the 21st Century.” White Paper
CM 6040, Her Majesty’s Stationery Office,
London.
U.K. Competition Commission. 2006. Home Credit
Market Investigation. London.
U.S. General Accounting Office. 1996. “A Comparison
of SBA’s 7(a) Loans and Borrowers with Other
REFERENCES
Loans and Borrowers.” Report to the U. S.
Senate Committee on Small Business, GAO/
RCED-96-222, Government Printing Office,
Washington, DC. (NB: Since 2004, this
agency has been known as the Government
Accountability Office.)
———. 2001. “Small Business Administration
Section 7(a) General Business Loans
Credit Subsidy Estimates.” Briefing
before the Staffs of the Senate and House
Committees on Small Business, July 31,
2001. GPO, Washington, DC. www.gao.
gov/cgi-bin/getrpt?GAO-01-1095R.
———. 2003. “Small Business Administration:
Progress Made but Improvements Needed
in Lender Oversight.” Testimony before
the Committee on Small Business and
Entrepreneurship, U.S. Senate, April 20, 2003.
GAO-03-720T. GPO, Washington DC.
Visaria, Sujata. 2006. “Legal Reform and Loan
Repayment: Microeconomic Impact of Debt
Recovery Tribunals in India.” Institute for
Economic Development Working Papers
DP157, Boston University, Boston, MA.
Weiss, Andrew, and Georgiy Nikitin. 2004. “Foreign
Portfolio Investment Improves Performance:
Evidence from the Czech Republic.” Topics in
Economic Analysis & Policy 4 (1): Art. 15.
Williamson, Steven D. 1987. “Costly Monitoring,
Loan Contracts and Equilibrium Credit
Rationing.” Quarterly Journal of Economics
102 (1): 135–46.
World Bank. 2001. Finance for Growth. Policy Choices
in a Volatile World. Washington, DC.
———. 2006a. Equity and Development: World
Development Report 2006. Washington, DC.
———. 2006b. The Role of Postal Networks in
Expanding Access to Financial Services.
Washington, DC.
———. Various years. World Development Indicators.
Washington, DC.
Wurgler, Jeffrey. 2000. “Financial Markets and the
Allocation of Capital.” Journal of Financial
Economics 58 (1–2):187–214.
Wydick, Bruce. 1999. “Credit Access, Human Capital,
and Class Structure Dynamics.” Journal of
Development Studies 35 (6): 131–52.
Yang, Dean. 2007. “International Migration,
Remittances, and Household Investment:
Evidence from Philippine Migrants’
Exchange Rate Shocks.” Economic Journal,
forthcoming.
Yoo, JaeHoon. 2007. Developing SME Exchanges.
Washington, DC: World Bank.
Zarutskie, Rebecca. 2005. “Evidence on the Effects
of Bank Competition on Firm Borrowing and
Investment.” Working paper, Duke University,
Fuqua School of Business, Durham, NC.
Zecchini, Salvatore, and Marco Ventura. 2006.
“Public Credit Guarantees and SME Finance.”
ISAE Working Paper 73, Instituto di Studi e
Analisi Economica, Rome.
Zia, Bilal. 2007. “Export Incentives, Financial
Constraints, and the (Mis)Allocation of
Credit: Micro-Level Evidence from Subsidized
Export Loans.” Journal of Financial Economics,
forthcoming.
———. 2004. India: Scaling Up Access to Finance for
India’s Rural Poor. Washington, DC.
235
Index
A
Access to finance
benefits for general economy, 8–9, 56, 63–66
current international composite measures,
190–191
current knowledge-base and data sources, 3, 4–5,
26–27
definition, 27, 30
development linkage, 25–26, 55
equilibrium modeling, 31–32
financial depth and, 1, 38–39, 71
foreign-owned bank presence and, 9, 10, 56–57, 70
global correlation with economic development,
35–39
limitations, 14, 27, 144
measurement of. See Measurement of access
Millennium Development Goals and, 104, 105
for non-poor, 11–12, 17, 25–26, 100, 105–106, 111,
114, 138
obstacles to. See Obstacles to access
poverty and inequality reduction and, 10–11, 17, 25,
99–102, 111, 138
rationale for improving, 1–3, 7–9, 17, 21
remittance payment effects, 142 n.19
research needs, 17, 18, 112
size of firm and, 5, 45
technology to improve, 131–132
theory development, 17–18
use of financial services and, 2, 28–30, 191–192
See also Firms, access to finance in; Policy
development to improve access to finance
Adverse selection effects
in joint liability lending, 119–120
in lending, 31
obstacles to credit access for poor households,
114–115, 116–117
Advertising effects, 184 n.28
Agency issues, 57, 66, 91 n.1
Albania, 36, 42
American Depository Receipt, 88, 98 n.44
AML-CFT regulations, 155–156, 183 n.20
Argentina, 75, 80, 88
Asset-based lending, 74
ATMs. See Branch/ATM distribution of financial
institutions
Australia, 42
Austria, 36
B
Bangladesh, 42, 49, 102–103, 115–116, 118–119
Bank account ownership and usage patterns, 5, 33–35,
36–37
cross-country comparison, 192–193
Bankruptcy codes, 150, 162–163, 181 n.11
Basel II system, 15, 76, 158
Bolivia, 36
Bond and securities markets, 10, 57, 70–72, 84–88,
90–91
bank-dominated vs. market-oriented systems, 70,
71–72, 94 n.16
regulation, 156
237
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Botswana, 6
Branch/ATM distribution of financial institutions, 6,
40–41, 127–128, 131, 163–164, 188 n.54
bank correspondents, 182 n.19
branching laws, 108–111, 163–164
cross-country comparison, 194–196
poverty reduction and, 108–111
Brazil, 30, 34, 88, 137, 154
C
Cameroon, 42, 43
Capital markets, 23, 24–25
Children
labor activities, 105
school attendance and household access to finance,
104
Chile, 42, 45, 80, 85, 88, 109, 172, 173, 187 n.46
China, 48, 64, 66, 73–74, 92 n.8, 188 n.51
Collateral
barriers to finance access, 28–30
ease of repossession, 154–155
notional, 123
obstacles to credit access for poor households, 114
private sector adaptation to weak regulation, 151
Colombia, 30, 34, 38, 80, 181 n.11
Community Reinvestment Act (U.S.), 185 n.33
Competition in financial sector
access and, 15, 97 n.37
bank monopolies, 83
bond financing, 85–86
credit registries and, 153–154
foreign bank presence and, 81, 82–83, 96 n.34
international remittance costs, 130–131
microfinancing and, 142 n.20
payment system policies, 183 n.25
policies to promote, 156–157, 179
regulation and, 15
sociopolitical environment, 148
Contract law, 182 n.14
expedited enforcement mechanism, 152
financial policy goals, 144, 145
financial sector development and, 148–149
government role, 147
Corruption
238
impact on firm growth, 59–60
lending from government-owned banks, 164–166,
185 n.36
relationship lending and, 73
Costs of financial services, as barrier to access, 28, 29,
43
cross-country comparison, 197–208
international remittances, 129–131, 132
technological advances and, 131
See also Interest rates
Credit cards, 44–45
Credit guarantees, government-subsidized
additionality in, 172, 187 n.47
credit appraisal process, 172–173
deposit insurance and, 186 n.40
eligibility rules, 173–174
fees and subsidies, 187 n.46
objectives, 169
operational design, 172–174
program costs, 170–171
rate of guarantee, 173
rationale, 169–170
shortcomings in implementation, 16, 145–146, 169,
174–175
significance of, for financial policy development,
168, 179
social benefits, 171
utilization, 168–169
wholesale guarantees, 188 n.49
Credit registries, 15, 49, 56, 74–76, 147, 150–151,
153–154
Cross-country comparisons, 30, 33, 53 n.11, 62, 140
n.10
barriers to access, 197–211
branch and ATM penetration, 194–196
current composite measures, 190–191
financial service usage, 191–192
Czech Republic, 42
D
Data sources
to assess access to finance, 4, 25
to assess impact of access, 112
cross-country comparison, 30, 33, 62
INDEX
current shortcomings, 4–5, 17, 26–27, 30–34, 53
n.10, 140 n.6
firms’ access to finance, 45
microfinance outcome evaluations, 102–104, 119
number of loan and deposit accounts, 33–34
rationale for improving, 7
remittances, 141 n.17
scope of financial institutions, 40
See also Measurement of access; Research needs
Debt finance mechanisms, 72–77, 94 n.18
Denmark, 42, 49
Deposit insurance, 186 n.40
Depth, financial
access and, 1, 38–39, 71
data on, 26, 27
development growth and, 25, 63, 64
income inequality and, 25, 106–108, 109
indirect benefits, 25–26
legal infrastructure and, 149
use of financial services and, 38–39
Developing countries
bank branch and ATM distribution, 6
current household access to finance, 5
financial service usage patterns, 36
foreign bank ownership in, 9
relevance of advanced country policies, 156
remittances to, 129
Development
banking depth as measure of, 63
financial sector reform rationale, 25
global correlation with access to finance, 35–39,
63–66
income inequality and, 2, 23–24, 106–107
policies to improve access and, 144
poverty reduction linkage, 111
rationale for improved access to finance, 2–3
role of financial institutions and markets, 1, 21, 23,
24, 55
threshold effects, 64–65
wealth redistribution strategies, 24–25
Development finance institutions, 166–167
Direct and directed lending, 16, 58, 168–169, 185
n.33
Documentation for financial transactions, 6–7, 42–43
Dominican Republic, 43
Dynamic incentives, 113, 121–123
E
Education, access to finance and, 12, 104
Electronic finance, 15, 41, 42, 131, 155, 182 n.18
Electronic transfer accounts, 183 n.23
Environmental issues, 105
Equilibrium modeling, 31–32, 101–102, 112, 139 n.2
Estonia, 39
Ethiopia, 5, 40
European Union, 33
Exchange rates, foreign currency borrowing and, 85
Export-oriented firms, 67, 93 n.13, 187 n.48
Expropriation risk, 148–149, 150
Extortionate lending, 184 n.29
F
Factoring, 9, 15, 74
Financial systems, generally
bank-dominated vs. market-oriented systems, 70,
71–72
characteristics of open and competitive systems, 7
in creation of poverty traps, 22
current data and knowledge base, 26
depth without broad access, 38–39
development rationale for reform, 25
development role, 1, 21, 23, 55
effects of foreign bank presence, 78
good qualities of, 1
legal system linkage, 147–148
overall growth effects on income inequality, 52 n.1,
106–108
policy goals, 144–145
policy reform effects on access, 144
political resistance to reform, 176–178
rapid growth of banking sector, 64–65
reform outcomes for households, 99–100
system-wide support for expanding credit, 9
Firms, access to finance for
bank market competition and, 97 n.37
bank monopolies and, 83
cross-country comparison, 205–208
current data, 5, 45–48, 91 nn.1–3
debt finance mechanisms, 72–77
determinants of, 55, 57–58
239
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
firm investment behavior and, 98 n.45
foreign bank lending and, 78–84
impact of, 3, 4, 7, 55, 58–60, 63, 68, 69, 90
innovation and, 7–8, 60, 61–63
linkages to growth, 60, 63–66
nonbank sources, 57, 84–86, 90–91
obstacles to, 47–48, 91 n.3
ownership patterns and, 68–69
sources, 56, 57
start-up enterprises, 60–61
See also Microlending; Small and medium
enterprises (SMEs)
Fixed-asset lending, 9, 74
Foreign currency borrowing, 85
Foreign direct investment, 10, 57, 88–90, 98 n.45
Foreign-owned banks
access outcomes, 9, 56–57, 70, 78–84, 90
advantage in transactional lending, 57
benefits for financial system, 78, 83–84, 95–96 n.28
effects on local economic behavior, 78, 80, 81, 84,
96 n.34
interest rates and, 79, 96 n.30, 97 n.35
lending to small and medium enterprises, 10, 79,
80–81, 95 n.26
as obstacle to access, 80
relationship lending and, 81–82
trends, 9, 77–78, 95 n.26
Foreign stock market listing, 88
France, 162, 166
G
Geographical obstacles to access, 6, 12, 40–41,
127–128, 129
Georgia, 49
Germany, 162
Gini coefficient, 106–107
Government intervention
credit registry regulation, 153–154
data sources, 180 n.3
evaluation of interventions, 167–168
institution building and support, 4, 17
nonlending financial services, 16
private–public partnerships, 16
240
public credit registries, 76, 147
rationale, 32–33, 143, 147
required provision of financial products for
disadvantaged groups, 157
scope of, to broaden access, 16, 145, 179
See also Credit guarantees, government-subsidized;
Policy development to improve access to finance;
Regulation; Subsidies
Government-owned financial institutions, 49, 145–
146, 164–167, 184–185 n.32, 185 nn.34–36
Grameen Bank, 102–103, 118–119, 175
Greece, 36, 42
Group-lending, 12, 13
Guatemala, 104, 117
H
Headline indicators, 5, 35, 36–37
Health care, 105, 126–127
Households
access to payment services, 129–131
with bank accounts, 33–35
child school attendance and access to finance, 104
current data sets, 33, 34, 53 n.10
financial sector development outcomes, 99–100
financial service usage patterns, 35–38
geographical access to bank services, 104
impact of access to finance, 3, 4, 10–11, 25–26
measurement of financial system access, 5, 53
nn.10–11
non-credit services, 13
obstacles to credit access, 114–118
research needs, 51–52
rotating savings and credit associations, 127, 128
strategies to increase savings, 127–129
See also Poverty and inequality reduction
I
Identification for financial transactions, 6–7, 42–43
Incorporation, financial development and, 68–69
India, 30, 34, 48, 58, 73, 81, 104, 108–109, 126,
163–164, 185 n.34
INDEX
Indonesia, 85, 88, 104
Inflation, 146
Information asymmetries
creditor rights and protections, 14–15
equilibrium modeling of access, 31
financial growth linkage, 150–151
financial policy goals, 145
inequitable distribution of effects, 2–3, 22
institutional functioning to improve access, 14
obstacles to credit access for poor households,
114–115
rationale for government role in finance, 14
role of financial institutions and markets, 1
Innovation, firm access to finance and, 7–8, 60,
61–63
Institutional functioning
effects of foreign bank presence, 83–84
financial sector self-regulation, 159–160
firm ownership patterns, 68–69
government role in institution building, 4, 17
investor rights and protection, 10
policies to complement institution-building to
improve financial access, 152–153
policy goals, 144–145
private sector adaptation to weak institutions,
151
relevance of advanced country practices in
developing countries, 156
requirements for improving financial system, 14
strategies for improving access to finance, 9, 14–15,
17, 56, 146–152
See also Regulation
Insurance, 105, 125–127
Interest rate
advertising effects on consumer behavior, 184 n.28
bank-optimal, 31
ceiling, 160–161, 162, 184 n.30
equilibrium modeling, 31–32
foreign-owned bank presence and, 79, 96 n.30, 97
n.35
joint liability lending, 118
microloans, 115–116
obstacles to credit access for poor households,
115–118
size of loan and, 76–77
subsidies, 14
Interest rates
adverse selection effect, 31
moral hazard effect, 31
Investor rights and protection
access barriers and, 49
access to finance and, 14–15, 49, 90–91, 179
firm ownership patterns and, 69, 86–88, 97–98 n.41
growth of nonbank finance and, 10
legal system characteristics and, 147–148, 180 n.4–5
in low-income countries, 150–151
securities market regulation, 156
stock market performance and, 86–88
Italy, 60–61, 187 n.46, 188 n.49
J
Japan, 166, 174
Joint liability loans, 113, 118–121, 134–136
K
Kenya, 43
Korea, Republic of, 52 n.3, 84–85, 88, 174, 187 n.46
L
Labor market effects
impact of access to finance and, 10–11, 101–102
microloan interest rate elasticity, 115
poverty reduction–financial development linkage,
111
Land titling, 151–152, 181–182 n.13
Leasing, 9, 15, 74
Legal environment
adaptability, 148
colonial experience and, 149–150
common law vs. civil law systems, 148, 180 n.4, 181
n.6
conflict resolution vs. property protection, 150, 151
constraints to firm growth, 59–60
emerging finance technologies, 155–156
financial policy goals, 145, 179
241
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Legal environment (continued)
financial system linkage, 147–148
private sector adaptation to weak institutions, 151
transition to open society, 150
usury laws, 160–161, 162
Licensing, lender, 161–162
Lithuania, 38
Living Standard Measurement Surveys, 30
Long-term financing, 94 n.16
development finance institutions for, 166
macroeconomic stability and, 146
nonbank sources, 72, 84–85
M
Macroeconomic stability, 146
Madagascar, 36
Malawi, 43, 126
Malaysia, 88, 187 n.46
Maturity transformation, 84, 97 n.39
M-banking, 131, 155–156, 182 n.18
Measurement of access, 3
bank account ownership, 5, 33–35
branch/ATM distribution, 6, 40–41
current data, 4–5, 17, 22, 30–34
headline indicators, 5, 35, 36–37
importance of, 26
indicators of access, 7, 23, 28, 40
measurement of use and, 30
quality of access, 40
strategies for improving, 5
use of financial services vs. access, 2, 28–30
Mexico, 30, 34, 88, 95–96 n.28, 115, 127, 167, 177
Microbanks, 136
Microlending
ancillary services in, 123–124
banking services and, 136
collateral requirements, 28–30
competition in, 142 n.20
dynamic incentives, 113, 121–123
household consumption uses, 124–125
with insurance, 125–127
interest rates, 115–116
joint liability loans, 118–121, 134–136
242
limitations, 133–136
loan sizes, 136
needs of nonpoor and, 136–137
non-credit services, 13
obstacles to credit access for poor households,
114–115, 117–118, 125
outcome evaluation, 3, 4, 102–104, 113, 119
outcomes, 12, 13, 113–114
public repayment, 123
repayment schedules, 123
return to capital, 115, 121
strategies to improve access, 12
subsidy requirements, 13, 113, 133, 175
targeting women for, 123, 124
trends, 12–13, 113, 136
utilization, 134
Middle class interests, 178
Millennium Development Goals and, 104, 105
Minimum account balance requirements, 7, 43
Minimum loan amounts, 44
Mobile finance, 15, 41
Monetary policy, 146
Money laundering, 155–156, 183 n.20
Monopoly power of banks, 83, 84
Moral hazard effects, 141 n.11
bankruptcy codes and, 162–163
dynamic incentives to overcome, 121
in joint liability lending, 118, 119–120
in lending, 31
obstacles to credit access for poor households,
114–115, 116–117
Mortgage loans, 44, 201–204
Mozambique, 42
N
Nepal, 42, 44, 49
New Zealand, 132–133
Nigeria, 43
Nonbank finance, 10, 57, 71–72, 84–86, 90–91, 94
n.17. See also Bond and securities markets
Non-poor individuals and SMEs
access to finance, 138
microfinance limitations, 136–137
INDEX
political aspects of finance policies, 136–137
spillover effects of improved access for, 11–12, 17,
25–26, 100, 105–106, 111, 114
Notional collateral, 123
Number of loan and deposit accounts, 33–34,
36–37
O
Obstacles to access
affordability, 28, 29, 43
associated country characteristics, 49–51
consumer and mortgage loans, 201–204
cross-country comparison, 197–211
deposit services, 197–200
effects of regulation, 15, 32
firm growth and, 58–60
for firms, 47–48, 49, 67–68, 205–208
foreign bank presence and, 79, 80
geographical, 6, 12, 40–42, 104, 127–128, 129
government intervention rationale, 32–33
identifying, 6, 39
inappropriate products and services, 44–45
indicators of, 40, 49
lack of documentation, 6–7, 42–43
lack of education, 12
long-term financing, 84
nonprice barriers, 32
payment services, 209–211
for poor households, 12, 115–118, 125–126
relationship lending, 9
repayment burden, 116
research needs, 51–52
subsidies to overcome, 138
supply and demand modeling, 31–32
usage patterns and, 40
voluntary and involuntary exclusion, 28–30, 34
Offshore financial centers, 144
Ownership structure
bank monopolies, 83
financial development and, 68–69
foreign bank presence and, 82–83
investor rights regime and, 69, 86–88, 97–98 n.41
return on capital and, 97–98 n.41
P
Pakistan, 43, 45, 47, 49, 81–82, 165, 172
Payment services, 129–131
barriers to service, 209–211
competition policy, 183 n.25
costs, 131
subsidy rationale, 13–14, 17, 137–138
Pension systems, 182 n.17
Peru, 80, 104, 109, 120
Philippines, 44, 47, 49, 52 n.3, 88, 120–121, 129
Physical access to financial services, 6, 12, 97 n.36,
104, 127–128, 129
cross-country comparison, 197–208
measurement, 40–42
Poland, 36
Policy development to improve access to finance, 3
bankruptcy codes, 162–163
competition-promoting policies, 156–157
to complement institution-building, 152–153
consideration of local conditions, 143
to create positive business environment, 146
development policies and, 144
to encourage financial system outreach, 137
general equilibrium effects, 168
goal setting, 144–145, 168
infrastructure concerns, 144–145, 146–152
macroeconomic stability, 146
political context, 16, 176–178, 179–180
potential negative effects, 143
principles for, 14, 168
rationale, 14
research analysis for, 143
scope of government intervention, 16, 145
strategies, 4, 17, 152–156
subsidy programs, 137–138
technology regulation, 138
See also Regulation
Political context
bank supervision, 160
financial sector reform, 146, 176–178, 179–180
lending from government-owned banks, 164–166,
185 nn.34–35
services for excluded nonpoor, 136–137
significance of, for financial reform, 16
243
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
Poor individuals and SMEs
appropriate bank products and services, 44, 157
barriers to access, 12, 115–118, 125–126
benefits of improved access for non-poor, 11–12, 17,
25–26, 100, 105–106, 111, 114
best use of subsidies for finance, 13–14, 17
effects of financial market imperfections, 2–3, 22
financial service usage patterns, 36
importance of finance system, 23
non-credit finance services, 13
political aspects of financial reform, 176–178
prevention of abusive lending to, 160–162
subsidies to improve access for, 13–14, 17
See also Poverty and inequality reduction
Portfolio equity investments, 10
Postal savings banks, 128, 137, 166
Poverty and inequality reduction
bank branching regulation effects, 108–111
financial development linkages, 111, 138
financial sector development outcomes, 99–100
impact of access to finance, 10–11, 17, 25, 99–102,
111, 138
microlending outcomes, 13
Millennium Development Goals, 105
negative short-term effects of increased access,
100–102
overall financial growth and, 106–108
political elite interests, 176
research needs, 18
side-effects of redistributive measures, 22
spillover effects of improved access for non-poor,
11–12, 17, 25–26, 100, 105–106, 111, 114
strategies to increase savings, 127–129
Prejudice and discrimination, 12, 28, 29, 73
Private equity, 10, 70, 86–88, 89, 90, 91
Privatization, 178
Property rights and protection
financial sector development and, 148–149
goals, 179
land titling, 151–152, 181–182 n.13
in open society, 148, 150
private sector adaptation to weak institutions, 151
Prudential regulations, 157–158
Public repayment, 123
244
R
Rainfall insurance, 126
Randomized field experiments, 19, 52, 103–104, 112,
119
Redistributive policies, 22, 24–25
Regulation
AML-CFT, 155–156, 183 n.20
bank branching laws, 108–111, 163–164
bank supervisor powers, 158–159
of finance technologies, 155, 182 n.18
financial sector self-regulation, 159–160
goals, 17
interest rate ceilings, 160–161, 162, 184 n.30
lender licensing, 161–162
lending, 76–77
as obstacle to access, 15, 144
to prevent abusive lending to poor, 160–162
prudential regulations, 157–158
securities market, 156
strategies to improve access, 16, 145
See also Government intervention; Policy
development to improve access to finance
Related-party lending, 94 n.20
Relationship lending, 9, 56, 70, 72–74, 81–82, 90,
153–154
Remittances, 129–131, 131–132, 141 n.17, 142 n.19
Repayment schedules, 123
Repeat lending, 121–123
Research needs
to assess impact of access, 112
barriers to access, 51–52
benchmarking data, 18
finance reform strategies, 18–19
household data, 18
measures of access, 7, 17, 26
microlending, 13, 104
obstacles to access, 40
for policy development, 17, 143
randomized field experiments, 19, 52, 103–104
surveys, 51
theory development, 17–18
Rotating savings and credit associations, 127, 128
Russia, 48, 166
INDEX
S
Savings
commitment devices, 128
door-to-door collection, 129
microfinance role, 13
microloan requirements, 123
obstacles for poor households, 127–128
rotating savings and credit associations, 127,
128
state-supported savings institutions, 166
subsidies to improve, 13–14, 17
Securities market. See Bond and securities markets
Self-employment, 91 n.5
Sharia, 28, 161
Sierra Leone, 42
Small and medium enterprises (SMEs)
bank regulation effects on access for, 15
benefits of improved access to finance, 7–9, 25–26,
56, 68
bond and securities markets and, 70
current access to finance, 5, 45–49
foreign bank lending to, 10, 79, 80–81, 95 n.26
government-subsidized credit guarantees,
168–174
implications of foreign bank lending, 57
obstacles to finance, 48, 49, 67–68, 205–208
political subversion of credit programs, 163
private equity markets and, 70–71
role in general economic growth, 68
sources of finance, 56
See also Firms; Microlending
SMEs. See Small and medium enterprises
Sources of finance, 56
external vs. internal, 66, 93 nn.13–14
formal vs. informal, 66
nonbank, 10, 57, 71–72, 84–86, 90–91, 94 n.17
South Africa, 30, 33, 42, 104, 115–116
Spain, 5, 40, 42
Sri Lanka, 115
Start-up enterprises, 60–61, 93 n.12
Stock markets, 86–88, 94 n.16, 156
Subsidies
auctioning of subsidy funds, 188 n.50
best use of, 13–14, 17
direct and directed lending, 16, 58
effectiveness, 163
export credit, 187 n.48
interest rate, 14
for microlending, 13, 113, 133, 175
to overcome obstacles to access, 138, 139
policy formulation, 137–138
possible negative effects, 175
rationale, 175
See also Credit guarantees, government-subsidized
Sweden, 42
Switzerland, 39
T
Tanzania, 104
Tax policy, 16, 153, 164
Technology, finance
debt finance mechanisms, 72–77
to expand customer base, 131–132
government regulation, 155–156, 182 n.18
international remittances, 129, 132
physical barriers to service and, 41–42
policy issues, 138
political resistance to financial reform and, 177
strategies and techniques to improve access, 9, 15,
100, 113, 131
for transactional lending, 56
Telecommunications technology, 41, 42, 131,
155–156
Terrorism financing, 155–156, 183 n.20
Thailand, 42, 47, 88, 101, 103, 139 n.1, 141 n.11, 187
n.46
Theory, development, 17–18, 23–26
Tobago, 42
Tonga, 129–131, 132–133
Trade credit, 96 n.32, 181 n.12
Trade finance, 74, 187 n.48
Transaction costs, 141 n.11
inequitable distribution of effects, 2–3, 22
obstacles to credit access for poor households,
114–115, 117–118
physical access and, 97 n.36
Trinidad, 42
245
FINANCE FOR ALL? POLICIES AND PITFALLS IN EXPANDING ACCESS
U
W
Uganda, 42, 43, 49
United Kingdom, 60–61, 74, 154, 162, 187 n.46
United States, 34, 60–61, 97 n.37, 109–111, 162, 183
n.23, 185 n.33, 186–187 n.45
Uruguay, 49
Usury laws, 160–161, 162
Weather insurance, 126
Women
microloan targeting, 123, 124
obstacles to credit access, 117
Z
V
Vietnam, 92–93 n.9
246
Zambia, 42
ECO-AUDIT
Environmental Benefits Statement
The World Bank is committed to preserving
endangered forests and natural resources. We
have chosen to print Finance for All? on 50pound New Life Opaque, a recycled paper with
30% post-consumer waste. The Office of the
Publisher has agreed to follow the recommended
standards for paper usage set by the Green Press
Initiative, a nonprofit program supporting publishers in using fiber that is not sourced from
endangered forests. For more information, visit
www.greenpressinitiative.org.
Saved:
• 13 trees
• 9 million BTUs of total energy
• 1,459 pounds of net greenhouse
gases
• 4,782 gallons of waste water
• 791 pounds of solid waste
Finance for All? is a much needed report on the state of access to finance around the world. It provides sensible
measures of access and offers sound policy advice, including the caution that access to finance is much
more than simply access to credit. It is a must-read for policy makers, activists, academics, and anyone interested
in development.
RAGHURAM G. RAJAN, Eric J. Gleacher Distinguished Service Professor of Finance,
University of Chicago, and former Economic Counselor and Director of Research, International
Monetary Fund
The revolution in financial access has been driven by bankers, activists, donors, and governments. Research has
lagged behind, but the next steps will require hard-headed analysis about what has worked and where to focus
innovation. Finance for All? gathers lessons from a growing body of new research and presents it sharply. The
arguments and evidence will inform and provoke readers, and will surely frame coming debates.
JONATHAN MORDUCH, Professor of Public Policy and Economics, New York University,
Director, The Financial Access Initiative, and Co-author of The Economics of Microfinance
Finance for All? represents a vigorous and broad review of the existing academic research and current practice
on the important subject of access to financial services. The report is a carefully crafted analysis that sets forth
the current status of empirical research, describes a variety of best practices, and identifies crucial issues that
must be addressed if poor and low income people and micro and small enterprises are to have access to a broad
range of financial services on a sustainable basis. This compelling report will surely provide a useful tool for
policy makers and other decision makers in designing financial systems that work for the poor.
RICHARD WEINGARTEN, Executive Secretary, United Nations Capital Development
Fund (UNCDF), and Chairman, United Nations Advisors Group on Inclusive Financial Sectors
This study will be a classic in its field. It makes a great contribution to the problem of making finance available
to all. Covering not only policy problems, but also the institutional side and the political economy of reform, this
study provides comprehensive data to back up the theory and analysis.
ANDREW SHENG, CHAIRMAN, Hong Kong Securities and Futures Commission, and
former Deputy Chief Executive, Hong Kong Monetary Authority
This excellent report documents how limited access to finance is in many poor countries and analyzes why this
occurs. Policies based on the insights developed provide a real chance of improving the situation. The report is a
major contribution to an important area that has not received the attention it deserves up to now.
FRANKLIN ALLEN, Nippon Life Professor of Finance and Economics,
The Wharton School of the University of Pennsylvania
978-0-8213-7291-3
THE WORLD BANK
SKU 17291