This article was downloaded by: [Loyola University]
On: 4 September 2009
Access details: Access Details: [subscription number 907142404]
Publisher Routledge
Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office: Mortimer House,
37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK
Journal of Poverty
Publication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information:
http://www.informaworld.com/smpp/title~content=t792306947
Poverty and Social Programs in Chile
Mauricio Olavarria-Gambi a
a
Institute of Public Affairs, University of Chile, Santiago Centro, Chile
Online Publication Date: 01 April 2009
To cite this Article Olavarria-Gambi, Mauricio(2009)'Poverty and Social Programs in Chile',Journal of Poverty,13:2,99 — 129
To link to this Article: DOI: 10.1080/10875540902841606
URL: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/10875540902841606
PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE
Full terms and conditions of use: http://www.informaworld.com/terms-and-conditions-of-access.pdf
This article may be used for research, teaching and private study purposes. Any substantial or
systematic reproduction, re-distribution, re-selling, loan or sub-licensing, systematic supply or
distribution in any form to anyone is expressly forbidden.
The publisher does not give any warranty express or implied or make any representation that the contents
will be complete or accurate or up to date. The accuracy of any instructions, formulae and drug doses
should be independently verified with primary sources. The publisher shall not be liable for any loss,
actions, claims, proceedings, demand or costs or damages whatsoever or howsoever caused arising directly
or indirectly in connection with or arising out of the use of this material.
Journa l of Poverty, 13:99–129, 2009
Copyright © Taylor & Francis Group, LLC
ISSN: 1087-5549 print/1540-7608 online
DOI: 10.1080/10875540902841606
1540-7608
1087-5549
WPOV
Journal
of Poverty,
Poverty Vol. 13, No. 2, March 2009: pp. 1–56
Pover ty an d Social Pr ogr ams in Ch ile
Poverty
M.
Olavarria-Gambi
and Social Programs in Chile
MAURICIO OLAVARRIA-GAMBI
Downloaded By: [Loyola University] At: 18:30 4 September 2009
Institute of Public Affa irs, University of Chile, Sa ntia go Centro, Chile
This a rticle presents a n empirica l cha ra cteriza tion of poverty in
Chile during the period 1987–2006. This cha ra cteriza tion refers to
both persona l cha ra cteristics a nd a ccess to ma in socia l services.
Such cha ra cteriza tion will help schola rs a nd policyma kers to
understa nd the strengths of the Chilea n poverty reduction process
a s well a s the ma in cha llenges it fa ces from now to the future.
KEYWORDS chile, poverty, socia l policy
OVERVIEW
Chile is often cited as a successful case of poverty reduction and a country
with social development compared to that of industrialized nations (World
Bank 2006). Data from an income measure show that poverty incidence was
reduced from 45.1 percent in 1987 to 13.7 percent in 2006, as shown in
Table 1. Other poverty measurements such as the Foster-Greer-Thorbecke
family of indexes about unsatisfied basic needs reported a sharp fall in poverty
as well (Carrasco, et al., 1997; Contreras & Larrañaga, 1998; Ferreira & Lichfield,
1998; Torche 1999). Poverty was reduced in terms of both an average economic
growth record of seven percent from 1984 to 1998 and a long tradition of public policy interventions on social affairs (Olavarrìa-Gambi, 2005).
Most studies attribute this reduction to economic growth almost exclusively (CEPAL, 2000; Contreras, 2000; Contreras & Larrañaga, 1998; Giovagnoli,
et al., 2005; Larrañaga, 1994; World Bank 2001) or mainly (Meller, 2000).
Olavarria-Gambi (2005) has challenged this conclusion arguing that economic growth has provided an opportunity, but those who have been able
to take that opportunity have been the ones who have access to education,
health care services, and social protection programs; in other words, those
Address correspondence to Mauricio Olavarria-Gambi, Instituto de Asuntos Publicos,
Universidad de Chile, Santa Lucía 240, Santiago Centro, Chile. E-mail: molavarr@uchile.cl
99
M. Ola va rria -Ga mbi
100
TABLE 1 Chile’s Poverty Trends, 1987–2003
Indigents
Poor Non Indigent
Total Poor
1987
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
2003
2006
17.4
27.7
45.1
12.9
25.7
38.6
8.8
23.8
32.6
7.6
20.0
27.5
5.7
17.5
23.2
5.6
16.1
21.7
5.7
14.9
20.6
4.7
14.1
18.8
3.2
10.5
13.7
Downloaded By: [Loyola University] At: 18:30 4 September 2009
Source: CASEN.
reached by social programs. In this context, this article is an analysis of the
Chilean experience of the effect of social policy interventions on the likelihood of leaving poverty. This is an area where the government needs to
focus and stress efforts. This article will analyze what type of programs have
been designed to address those deficits and what the early evidence is telling about the effectiveness of those efforts and will illustrate what is
behind—in terms of social policy interventions—an impressive record of
poverty reduction. This type of analysis also provides lessons, in terms of
both strengths and difficulties, which may be useful for those who are
involved in poverty alleviating efforts.
Chile’s tradition of social policy implementation rose in the first half of
the 19 th century with the first efforts for establishing the educational system.
It improved by early 20th century with the government’s involvement in the
delivery of health care services and the creation of the social security system in
1924. As a consequence of this long social policy tradition, by 2006 Chile
exhibited an average schooling of 10.14 years among people 15 years of age
and older, while the Latin American average by the early 2000s was 5.8 years
among people 25 years of age and older (De Ferranti & Ody, 2006), and has
one of the best indexes in Latin America on infant and child mortality and literacy rate. Chile jumped from the eighth to the second position in Latin America
between 1950 and 1998 on life expectancy (OPS, 1994; PAHO, 1998).
The main data source used in this study is the National Socio-Economic
Characterization Survey (CASEN). Taking nine of those surveys available,
this article analyzes how personal characteristics relate to the probability of
being poor, and how the likelihood of being poor varies according to different schooling levels as well as the likelihood of people from different socioeconomic levels to access social services. Analyses control for background
characteristics such as gender, age, marital status, and area of residence.
Similarly, the analysis of some of the main social programs focuses on the
likelihood of the poor and non-poor to be covered for the pension system
and health care programs—either public or private ones. In addition, the
work presents those probabilities from 1987 to 2006.
Following this overview, a policy backdrop is presented, and then the
article turns to the presentation of the main results of the quantitative analysis. Finally, relevant conclusions are discussed. Data and methodology used
in the empirical analysis are briefly explained in Appendix 1.
Poverty a nd Socia l Progra ms in Chile
101
Downloaded By: [Loyola University] At: 18:30 4 September 2009
POLICY BACKDROP
Olavarría-Gambi (2005) has argued that Chile’s long tradition of social policy
interventions has allowed the country to exhibit a relatively healthy and
educated population, which, in turn, make it possible for extended segments of people to take the opportunities created by the decade and a half
(1984–1998) of fast economic growth and exit poverty. At the opposite side,
those not reached by social policy stayed relatively unhealthy, less educated
and remained in poverty, even during the fast-growth era. Following a long
tradition of government intervention in social affairs starting in the 19th century, major social programs have been designed and implemented, and
since 1990 have been oriented to make the poverty-overcoming process a
sustainable one.
As a result of that long social policy tradition, available data show that
by the 1980s, Chile already exhibited one of the best records in this field in
Latin America (CEPAL, 1986). Chile’s life expectancy was the fourth highest
in the region (70.7 years), after Costa Rica’s (73.8 years), Uruguay’s (71
years) and Panama’s (70.8 years). Chile’s infant mortality was the second
lowest in the region (23.7 per thousand) after that of Costa Rica (19.2 per
thousand); Chile and Costa Rica were the two countries showing the lowest
mortality among children under five years old, registering average annual
rates of 20.2 and 27.9 per thousand, respectively. Similarly, by 1980, Chile
had attained complete coverage of primary education and its coverage of
secondary education was the second highest in Latin America. By 1960,
Chile already exhibited the highest percentage of economically active population in the region completing between 10 and 12 years of education. By
the decade beginning in 2000 those social indicators were even better.
Considering that investments in human capital take a long time to mature,
there is undoubtedly an effect of those investments on the comparatively
good social development indicators shown by Chile relative to those of the
Latin American region.
In addition, available evidence suggests that poverty should have
increased by the early 1980s as a consequence of recessions caused by the
debt crisis of the early 1980s. GDP fell 14.1 and 0.7 percent in 1982 and
1983, respectively, unemployment skyrocketed to 20 percent in 1982 and
real wages fell almost 11 percent on average in 1983. By 1987, when 45.1
percent of the population was poor, Chile had been growing at an average
rate of 5.25 percent for four consecutive years, and unemployment had
fallen to 9.6 percent. Poverty fell to 21.7 percent in 1998, after a period of
fast growth, decreased again to 20.6 percent in 2000 in a context of a GDP
fall of 1.1 percent in 1999, and it continued reducing to 13.7 percent in 2006,
in the context of a slowdown economy (1998–2006). The unemployment rate
that was 6.5 percent by mid 1998, increased to 11.5 percent by mid 1999, and
kept between 8 and 10 percent from 1999 to the end of 2005 (INE 2008).
Downloaded By: [Loyola University] At: 18:30 4 September 2009
102
M. Ola va rria -Ga mbi
Despite an economic slowdown and an unemployment increase, poverty
did not rise because of social programs implemented by social programs
oriented to counteract the effects of the economic crisis of the late 1990s
and its slow recovery in the 2000s.
The analysis of Chile’s poverty trends and social indicators suggest that
Chile’s long tradition of social policy has played a highly important role in
the reduction of poverty, not only providing the basis (in terms of human
capital expansion in education and health prior to fast growth era) from
which growth could act, but also continuing the poverty reduction pattern
despite the economic difficulties faced by the country.
But this analysis also suggests that those unable to overcome poverty
were those that these social policy interventions could not reach. Major
social programs have been implemented since the 1990s seeking to reach
them. Whether those social programs have been effective in reaching them,
as well as whether the results of these programs are positive may shed light
on the main challenges that the Chilean-poverty-overcoming process faces
from now to the future. The following sections deal with that.
POVERTY TRENDS BETWEEN 1987–2006
As explained before, this work tries to focus on the personal characteristics
of the poor. Thus, the analysis of housing is beyond its scope. Similarly, the
analysis of the relation between unemployment and poverty is not undertaken because it has been already well established (Anriquez, et al.,1998;
Castro, 1994; Contreras & Larrañaga, 1998; Torche, 1999). Consequently, this
section concentrates on the analysis of education levels; health status of different socio-economic strata; types of employment; personal characteristics
such as age, gender, and marital status; and whether residence is in urban
or rural areas. These characteristics have been selected because data on
them have been consistently included in the eight CASEN surveys available.
The poor have been divided in two categories: the indigents, being the
poorest, and the poor non-indigents. To complete the panorama about lowincome people, an additional category has been created, namely the almost
poor. The indigent are those whose income is lower than a basic basket of
food (BBF), the income of the poor non-indigent lies between one and two
BBF, that of the poor is lower than two BBF, and the almost poor are those
whose income is equal or higher than two BBF but lower than three BBF.
A basic basket of food is a measure that identifies the minimum income
needed by a person to satisfy his or her nutritional needs. It is constructed
using the minimum-required consumption of calories and proteins according
to the World Health Organization standards, the population consumption
habits, and market prices. An explanation about the data and methodology
of the empirical analysis has been included in Appendix 1.
Downloaded By: [Loyola University] At: 18:30 4 September 2009
Poverty a nd Socia l Progra ms in Chile
103
Statistical analysis shows that the poor–indigents and poor non-indigents
appear mainly to be women, urban residents, and people younger than
40 years of age with less than eight years of schooling (see Tables 2 and 3).
Correspondingly, females and people younger than 40 years of age are less
likely to belong to a medium or high income stratum, but the opposite happens with rural residents and people who are single, separated, divorced, or
widowed. Furthermore, people who completed secondary education or
higher are more likely to belong to the medium or high-income stratum.
The multinomial logit model shows that the likelihood of being poor falls
along the period 1987–2006 for each controlled background characteristic,
which is consistent with the diminishing poverty trend. Controlling for gender,
area of residence, age, schooling level, and marital status, the likelihood of
a woman to be poor is between one or two percent higher than that of men
during the period, all else equal, but both face practically the same probability to be almost poor (Table 2). Furthermore, urban residents are more
likely to be either poor or almost poor than rural inhabitants (Table 2).
However, Table 2 also shows that the likelihood of being poor rose
slightly in 2000, fell again in 2003 and 2006, and the likelihood of being
almost poor rose by the year 2000 and 2003 but fell by 2006. This is coincident with the period of an economic slowdown affecting Chile and it would
TABLE 2 Predicted Probability of Being Either Poor or Almost Poor Sorted by Gender and
Area of Residence, 1987–2006
Male
Female
Urban
Rural
Almost Male
Poor Female
Urban
Rural
Poor
1987
1990
1992
1994
0.4159
0.4253
0.4401
0.3728
0.1852
0.1790
0.1782
0.1874
0.3454
0.3631
0.3902
0.2688
0.1904
0.1900
0.1958
0.1695
0.3060
0.3274
0.3464
0.2645
0.1909
0.1917
0.1992
0.1731
0.2951
0.3155
0.3303
0.2679
0.1900
0.1946
0.1960
0.1841
1996
1998
0.2386 0.2101
0.2545 0.2295
0.2625 0.2427
0.2093 0. 1747
0.1773 0.1703
0.1817 0.1756
0.1867 0.1849
0.1591 0.1453
2000
2003
2006
0.2500
0.2643
0.2738
0.2343
0.1812
0.1848
0.1933
0.1683
0.2236
0.2414
0.2577
0.1948
0.2195
0.2283
0.1964
0.2666
0.1460
0.1629
0.1763
0.1221
0.1928
0.2049
0.1843
0.2207
Source: Author’s calculation based on CASEN surveys.
Note: See appendix 2 for results of the multinomial logit regression.
TABLE 3 Predicted Probability of Being Poor According to Selected Levels of Schooling,
Chile 1987–2003
Schooling Levels
4
8
12
17
years
years
years
years
1987
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
2003
2006
0.5013
0.3058
0.1499
0.0491
0.4335
0.2858
0.1641
0.0702
0.3812
0.2463
0.1400
0.0603
0.3576
0.2253
0.1256
0.0533
0.3171
0.1859
0.0953
0.0364
0.2929
0.1756
0.0939
0.0385
0.3179
0.2040
0.1179
0.0532
0.3209
0.1989
0.1094
0.0459
0.3210
0.2100
0.1252
0.0596
Source: Author’s calculation based on CASEN surveys.
Note: See appendix 3 for results of the multinomial logit regression.
Downloaded By: [Loyola University] At: 18:30 4 September 2009
104
M. Ola va rria -Ga mbi
suggest that the main negative effect of the period would have been concentrated in the lower-middle class people.
Education is negatively associated with poverty. Even though the likelihood of being poor decreased for all educational levels during the period
due to the poverty reduction trend, those with lower education consistently
exhibit a higher probability of being poor. For instance, among people
24 years of age and older and controlling for gender, area of residence, age,
and marital status, somebody having four years of schooling in 1987 faced a
50 percent probability of being poor, while that probability for those who
had achieved 8 or 12 years of completed education was 30 and 15 percent
respectively (see Table 2). In 1998, the probability of being poor for the
same schooling levels had changed to 29, 17, and 9 percent respectively
and by 2006 that likelihood was 32, 20, and 12 respectively (Table 3).
In this general diminishing poverty trend, the fastest path is that of
those who accumulated higher human capitalthrough education. The analysis
shows that the percentage change in the probability of being poor due to
one more year of schooling relates to the stage of the educational process
where that additional year is achieved. For instance, in 1987, when poverty
incidence was 45.1 percent, the percentage change in the probability of
being poor for increasing educational achievements from 3 to 4 years was 0.085, 7 to 8 years was -0.135 and 11 to 12 years was -0.18. In 1998, when
poverty incidence was 21.7 percent, that percentage change for the same
schooling levels was -0.10, -0.13 and -0.15 respectively. Those changes
were respectively -0.08, -0.108 and -0.127 in 2003, when poverty incidence
was 13.7 percent in 2006.
Results of the predicted probability analysis shows a slight decrease in
2006 respect to those of the year 2000, except for the category of four years
of schooling. That might suggest that the recuperation process—after an
economic crisis—is much harder for those with the lowest human capital.
These findings additionally open questions that later research should
address. Why do people who have higher education fall into or remain in
poverty?, Why are people with low schooling, or even no education, not
poor?, Is there anything else besides education that significantly prevents
people from overcoming poverty? Analyses are made on characteristics registered on surveys but there could be other factors on which we lack data,
such as propensity for effort and work, social relation networks, fortuitous
events, all of which can influence someone’s probability of being poor. Since
there is not much evidence available in Chile on the effect of these unobserved variables, that could be an important contribution of later researches.
Controlling for the same variables already mentioned, statistical analysis
also shows that people younger than 40 years of age are more likely to be
poor. This result is consistent with Torche’s (1999) as well as Contreras’s
and Larrañaga’s (1998) findings. Torche explains this in terms of the value of
experience. Contreras and Larrañaga argue that ages 20 to 39 are associated
Downloaded By: [Loyola University] At: 18:30 4 September 2009
Poverty a nd Socia l Progra ms in Chile
105
to transient poverty due to the fact that those ages correspond to the early
stages of a household.
On the other hand, reported findings contradict a common view that
poverty is more extended in rural areas. A reason for this finding would be
that the lack of a better future and the seeking of better economic opportunities would stimulate the migration to cities, which would result in a concentration of the poor in urban areas. An alternative explanation would suggest
that in rural areas there would be a greater number of working people per
household—oriented either to earning income or self consumption—which
would result in a lower likelihood of poverty in the country side.
So far the analysis has concentrated on whether some personal characteristics are associated to poverty. Now the focus turns to the analysis of the
likelihood of low-income people to be healthy, or the likelihood of the sick to
receive medical help, and to be self employed or low qualification worker.
The analysis of the health conditions faced by low-income people
reveals that they are likely to be healthy. 1 However, when sick they are less
likely to receive medical help. This finding suggests, on the one hand, that
the low quality health care service that the poor receive, along with the long
waiting list they have to go through, discourage them from seeking medical
help when sick or injured. On the other hand, it would also suggests that,
since they have a higher probability of lacking social security coverage, the
opportunity cost of getting such services, and eventually taking a sick leave,
is too high for the poor who cannot afford to stop working.
Labor is the most important way in which people get income and exit
poverty (Larrañaga, 1997) and in order to get into the labor market people
need to be healthy enough. That is why being healthy is positively correlated to income (Akin et al, 1985). These findings suggest that keeping
healthy is the only asset the poor can exhibit, but that asset is in jeopardy
because they do not get the same opportunities to receive medical help
when sick as people from higher economic strata do.
Statistical analysis also reveals that people younger than 40 years of age
are likely to be healthy too but the opposite occurs with women and people
older than 65 years of age. Rural residents and people older than 65 years of
age are less likely to get medical care when sick. Children from low income
families are more likely to be undernourished.
The fact of being a low-income person—indigent, poor, non-indigent,
or almost poor—does not seem to be associated with the fact of being a self
employed worker. However, from the educational attainment point of view,
those who have between one and seven years of schooling are more likely
to become self-employed workers.
1
Variables controlled for are: socioeconomic stratum (indigent, poor, non-indigent, and almost poor),
gender, area of residence, age, schooling and marital status.
106
M. Ola va rria -Ga mbi
Downloaded By: [Loyola University] At: 18:30 4 September 2009
Being a self employed worker is not associated with poverty or low
income because being self employed is a reality among the poor, and they
are not the only ones belonging to this category, which includes several
types of labor activities such as various types of commerce, salesmen, professional consulting, craftsmen, gardeners, and also blue collar workers who
work occasionally.
“Unskilled worker” seems to be a better category to describe the working
poor. The poor—indigents and poor non-indigents—are likely to belong to
this category. Correspondingly, low educational attainments exhibit a positive association with being an unskilled worker. Similarly, people younger
than 40 years of age, women, and rural inhabitants are more likely to get
non-specialized jobs.
SOCIAL POLICY AND THE INCIDENCE OF POVERTY
Although social programs themselves are not intended to reduce poverty
directly, they have an impact on that since, on the one hand, poverty is
measured through income and, on the other, an important part of those
programs are the government money subsidies going to people. Thus, an
interesting question is how many people are left to be counted as poor
because of these subsidies. A simple methodology to address that question
is to compare the incidence of poverty with and without those subsidies.
Table 4 reports the results.
Government money subsidies considered are the following: the unique
family subsidy (SUF), 2 the Assistance Pension (PASIS), 3 the family subsidy4
and the subsidy for unemployed workers. 5 These subsidies directly transfer
money to people. All four subsidies are targeted to low-income people.
However, the family subsidy, though progressive, does not exclusively
focus on the poor, since workers having children and a monthly salary
lower than 734 US dollars—as of December 2006—are entitled to this subsidy.
Results from Table 1 show that on average, 1.5 percent of the population
left to be deemed poor due to money subsidies in each of the year in which
2
The unique family subsidy (subsidio único familiar—SUF) is a subsidy delivered to parents of
children, pregnant women, and mentally disabled people lacking protection within the social security
system. To qualify for this subsidy, people have to fulfill several requirements showing that they are in
a state of poverty.
3
People entitled to the minimum old age and disability pension (pensiones asistenciales—PASIS)
are those older than 65 years of age and the handicapped over than 18 years of age without protection
within the social security system.
4
The family subsidy (asignación familiar) is a subsidy entitled to every worker with dependants
earning less than the equivalent to US 574 dollars monthly. The subsidy is progressive, so workers
earning the lowest salaries are entitled to a higher subsidy.
5
Workers who have been unemployed for at least three months are entitled to this subsidy. It is paid
every four months, its amount is decreasing and it can not be received for more than 360 continued days.
Poverty a nd Socia l Progra ms in Chile
107
TABLE 4 Variation in Percentage of Poor People Due to Money Subsidies, 1987–2006
Indigents
Poor
non-indigents
Total
poverty
Almost
poor
Medium-high
income
Total
non-poor
-2.39%
-1.32%
-1.23%
-1.14%
-1.44%
-1.50%
-1.09%
-1.52%
-1.31%
+0.73%
+0.25%
+0.003%
-0.12%
-0.33%
-0.44%
-0.65%
-0.46%
-0.81%
-1.66%
-1.07%
-1.22%
-1.26%
-1.77%
-1.94%
-1.74%
-1.99%
-2.12%
+0.97%
+0.52%
+0.55%
+0.53%
+0.35%
+0.69%
+0.25%
+0.49%
-1.40%
+0.69%
+0.55%
+0.68%
+0.74%
+1.43%
+1.25%
+1.49%
+1.50%
+3.52%
+1.66%
+1.07%
+1.22%
+1.26%
+1.77%
+1.94%
+1.74%
+1.99%
+5.11%
1987
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
2003
2006
Downloaded By: [Loyola University] At: 18:30 4 September 2009
Source: Author’s calculations based on CASEN 1987 to 2006.
the CASEN survey was administered. The greatest impact of these subsidies
on the incidence of indigence is in 1987, but the greatest impact on total
poverty is in 2006. This year the percentage of almost poor also fell and the
category of medium-high income shows the highest increase thanks to
these money subsidies. This may be attributed to a greater efficiency of the
targeting system but also to the increase in the amount of the subsidies and
the people covered.
The government has shown that the aggregate spending on money
subsidies has been targeted on the poor. According to the government, the
40 percent lowest income people appropriated between 55.9 and 73.5 percent
of that spending from 1987 to 2006 (see Table 5).
Both SUF and PASIS have been the money subsidy showing the best
capacity to reach low income people during the period 1987–2006. Statistical
analysis shows that they are the ones most likely to receive these subsidies.
On the other hand, the family subsidy has not been so effective in reaching
the poorest: indigent people are unlikely to get it and the almost poor are
generally more likely to receive it. And there is no consistent evidence
about the subsidy for unemployed workers since statistical analysis generally
delivers insignificant coefficients.
TABLE 5 Distribution of Money Subsidies Among Households Classified by Quintiles of
Income, 1987–2006 (%)
Quintile
of income
1987
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
2003
2006
I
II
III
IV
V
Total
33.6
22.3
17.9
14.9
11.3
100.0
33.7
23.9
18.4
13.9
10.1
100.0
36.4
26.2
17.9
12.0
7.4
100.0
38.7
26.2
17.3
12.1
5.6
100.0
36.1
27.8
20.6
11.5
4.0
100.0
46.3
26.4
16.0
8.4
2.9
100.0
45.4
27.7
15.8
8.3
2.8
100.0
46.7
25.6
15.8
8.8
3.1
100.0
47.9
25.6
14.8
8.6
3.1
100.0
Source: MIDEPLAN 1999; p. 82; MIDEPLAN 2005; MIDEPLAN 2008.
M. Ola va rria -Ga mbi
108
SOCIAL POLICY: REACHING THE POOR?
Previous sections have dealt with the characterization of the poor and specific subsidies targeted to low income people. This section addresses the
topic of whether massive social programs are reaching the poor. Some of
them are universal, such as those of education, health care, and pensions,
while others are targeted ones, such as the School Feeding Program and the
Children Feeding Program.
Downloaded By: [Loyola University] At: 18:30 4 September 2009
Education Programs
The school system in Chile is universal. Primary school is mandatory, reaching
practically all children, and secondary education coverage rose from 81.5 percent in 1987 to 92.7 percent of the population younger than 25 years of age in
2003 (see Table 6). The long tradition of education policies, emerging shortly
after the independence, has led the country to have an increasing educational
coverage and comparatively good standards in the Latin American context. As of
2006, Chileans showed a illiteracy rate of 2.9 percent (CEPAL, 2007) and 10.14
years of schooling on average. The Latin American schooling average of people
age 25 and older was 5.8 years by the early 2000s (De Ferranti & Ody, 2006).
Currently the school system is structured on the basis of municipal
schools, the school voucher system, and entirely private schools. Municipals
are public schools managed by Municipal Educational Corporations. The
school voucher system corresponds to private schools receiving subsidies
TABLE 6 Educational Coverage (%) and Average Schooling Years, Age 15 and Older
Educational coverage
Year
Circa 1958
1962 – 1964
1970
1980
1987
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
2003
2006
Primary
96,4
96,8
97,4
97,6
98,2
98,3
98,6
99,1
99,0
Secundary
Average
schooling years
81,5
80,5
84,2
84,2
85,9
86,9
90,0
92,7
92,0
3,3 (1)
4,2 (2)
4,3
7,6
8,3
8,9
9,0
9,1
9,5
9,7
9,8
10,12
10,14
Source: Data series 1987–2006 are based on CASEN. Data 1958–1980 has beed taken from
Ahumada (1958), Aylwin et al (1990), Libertad y Desarrollo (2000).
Note: Ahumada (1) and Aylwin et al (2) report these numbers, but they do not specify the
range of age considered.
Downloaded By: [Loyola University] At: 18:30 4 September 2009
Poverty a nd Socia l Progra ms in Chile
109
from the government for each student attending them. The entirely private
schools are the ones that do not receive such subsidies and, consequently,
families completely pay tuition and fees charged. Municipal schools show
the highest coverage among the lowest income people, the school voucher
system increases educational participation among middle income people, and
the richest 20 percent of children mostly attend private schools (MIDEPLAN,
1999, p. 44; MIDEPLAN, 2005).
An important complementary program to the educational system is the
School Feeding Program. This is a program that delivers breakfasts, lunches,
and snacks to poor students, from ages six to fourteen, attending schools
belonging to the municipal and voucher systems. This program was created
in 1964 and it is managed by an agency of the Ministry of Education called
“Junta Nacional de Auxilio Escolar y Becas” (National Council of Scholastic
Aid and Grants).
Beyond the analysis of the attendance by type of school and economic
stratum, an analysis on the likelihood of school attendance among the lowincome people has been performed. It is important to realize whether the
poor have real possibilities to access the school system. Results show that
the poor are likely to attend school. This finding is consistent with the analysis
of the School Feeding Program, which shows that poor children are more
likely to participate in the program. In turn, the government reports successful
targeting of this program to the poorest attending schools from the voucher
system (MIDEPLAN, 1999, p. 41; MIDEPLAN, 2005). This leads to the conclusion that the reason that a poor child is more inclined to attend the
school would be that the feeding program works as an extra incentive other
than the attraction of learning itself.
The analysis on education programs from the point of view of either
the coverage, attendance, or the likelihood of a poor child to get education
shows that the school system is reaching the poor. By the same token, considering that poor families face an increasing opportunity cost of sending
their children to school, the School Feeding Program seems to be a good
complementary mechanism to keep poor children in school and improve
their future possibilities in life.
Health Programs
Chile’s tradition of efforts in health issues began to develop in 1887 with the
creation of the General Council of Sanitation (Junta General de Salubridad),
an agency in charge of public hygiene and sanitation. Later, by the mid
1920s, health care programs were organized around the recently created
social security funds but mainly oriented to formal workers. Since then the
system expanded constantly and several reforms were undertaken. In 1952,
the health care system was reformed, creating the National Health Service
(SNS), which expanded health care to the population at large regardless of
Downloaded By: [Loyola University] At: 18:30 4 September 2009
110
M. Ola va rria -Ga mbi
their ability to pay. In 1968, the system was complemented with the rise of
the National Service for Employees (SERMENA), a program delivering health
care for white collar workers. In 1980 both SNS and SERMENA were merged
into the National Fund of Health (FONASA). Private participation in organizing
health care protection plans was introduced in 1980 with the creation of the
ISAPREs—a close equivalent of the U.S. HMOs.
Chile’s current public health care system, organized around FONASA, is
universal. However, workers have the freedom to choose to be covered by
a private one, namely ISAPREs. Workers have an automatic legal deduction
of seven percent from their salaries to have health care coverage, for them
and their families, from either an ISAPRE or FONASA. People lacking health
care protection still can get medical help from the public system but under
the indigent modality, which is a mean-tested benefit.
ISAPRE contributors can choose their physician, hospital, or other
health care supplier and face a copay for every service received. FONASA
contributors can get medical care under two modalities: free choice or institutional modality. Under the latter, people must get the service in public
hospitals or community health centers. There is no copay requirement for
people lacking financial capacity. This is called the indigent modality of
health care services. For other people there is a copay of 25 or 50 percent of
the cost of the service rendered, depending on their level of income. Under
the free choice modality, people can get the service from private suppliers
registered in FONASA but the copay is usually higher because it depends on
the price charged by the supplier.
Public hospitals and community health centers often have been
criticized as having long waiting lists, inadequate facilities and equipment, and a lack of enough medicines and resources to deliver proper
medical care.
The poorest mostly get health care assistance under the indigent
modality; among low to middle-income people FONASA is the main mean
to get health care coverage while ISAPREs concentrate in the highest
income people. Between 1987 and 2006 the indigent modality increased its
relative importance among the poorest 20 percent of the population but
decreased in the other quintiles; FONASA decreased in every segment until
the year 2000; and the ISAPRE system raised its participation among the low
to middle-income people and consolidated among the richest 20 percent of
people. Despite that, as of the year 2000, FONASA was the main mean to
get health care protection, covering 41.7 percent of the population, followed by the indigent modality, which covered 24.8 percent, and ISAPREs
covered 23.1 percent (MIDEPLAN, 1999, pp. 49–50; MIDEPLAN 2003). As of
2006, the public system (FONASA plus the indigent modality) covered 69.5
percent of the population, 16.3 were covered by ISAPREs, and the remaining 14.2 percent were covered by the Armed Forces Health Care System and
other coverages (FONASA 2007).
Downloaded By: [Loyola University] At: 18:30 4 September 2009
Poverty a nd Socia l Progra ms in Chile
111
Statistical analysis shows, as expected, that low income people—indigents,
poor non–indigents and almost-poor people—are more likely to receive
medical service under the indigent modality. In addition, the predicted
probability of getting medical services under this modality increased along
the period 1987–2006 not only for indigents and poor non-indigent individuals but also for almost-poor people, whom are considered to be non-poor
by official estimations (Table 7).
Although it is expected that the poor receive health care services under
the indigent modality, it is somewhat surprising that the likelihood of the
almost poor of getting health care attention under this modality increased
despite the diminishing poverty trend of the period. This suggests either a
lack of social security protection mechanisms for health care or insufficient
benefits in the heath care plans of this population segment. This should be
related to the already mentioned fact that low income people—indigents,
poor non-indigents and almost-poor people—are less likely to receive medical help when sick. Then, though the almost poor are more likely to have
health care protection from FONASA—or could eventually get it from an
ISAPRE as well—the FONASA’s high copays or the low levels of benefits of
the ISAPRE’s health care plans they can afford would lead them to seek service
under the indigent modality when sick or injured.
An important and successful health program is the “Children Complementary Nutrition Program” (PNAC). Created in 1954 and managed by the
Ministry of Health, this program delivers milk and other nutritional products
to children under six years of age, pregnant women, and wet-nurses to prevent or remedy situations of under-nourishment. To get the benefits, mothers
must take children to periodical medical exams to control their health status.
Although formally universal, the program is in fact a self-targeted one for
two reasons. First, because it addresses undernourishment, the program
focuses on children from low income families since they are the ones with
the highest risk of undernourishment. Second, because higher income
mothers face an increasing opportunity cost, which lead them to drop
the program, those mothers take their children to private physicians in a
more convenient time for them and buy milk and feeding products through
the market. Statistical analysis shows that children under five from lowincome families are more likely to access PNAC.
Chile exhibits a long tradition of concern for the health status of the
population, a high coverage of the system and comparatively good health
standards. For instance, life expectancy in Chile is 78.4 years as of 2006
(PAHO, 2008), the second highest in Latin America, the under-nutrition rate
fell from 15.5 in 1970 to 3.8 6 percent in 2004 (MINSAL, 2005) and infant
6
This index is composed as follows: children in risk of undernourishment: 3.2 percent; children
undernourished: 0.5 percent and children with secondary undernourishment: 0.1 percent.
Downloaded By: [Loyola University] At: 18:30 4 September 2009
TABLE 7 Predicted Probability of Receiving Medical Services Either as Indigent or Through FONASA (the Public Health Care Plan) Sorted by
Poverty and Almost Poverty, 1987–1998.
112
Health Care as
Indigent
Health Care
through FONASA
Poor
Almost Poor
Poor
Almost Poor
1987
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
2003
2006
0.4446
0.3828
0.5360
0.5750
0.4477
0.3874
0.4909
0.5270
0.4604
0.3988
0.4511
0.4769
0.5635
0.4837
0.3518
0.4022
0.5146
0.4209
0.4083
0.4536
0.5640
0.4539
0.3792
0.4404
0.6691
0.5299
0.3081
0.4230
0.6896
0.5520
0.2949
0.4141
0.7057
0.5506
0.2770
0.4252
Source: Author’s calculation based on CASEN surveys.
Notes: (1) See appendix 4 for results of the multinomial logit regression; (2) Variables controlled for: socioeconomic stratum, gender, area of residence, age, schooling
level and marital status.
Poverty a nd Socia l Progra ms in Chile
113
mortality diminished from 153.2 in 1950 to 7.2 per thousand born alive in
2005–2010 (CEPAL, 2007). However, in practice, not only the poor but also
the almost poor in this study have serious restrictions to satisfy their needs
on health care services. Their only choice is to get medical help from deteriorated and insolvent hospitals and community health centers, which can
barely deliver a quality and opportune service. Coincidentally, the poor and
almost-poor people are less likely to have medical help when sick. Then,
the health care system would be inadequately reaching the poor: they
would be formally but not effectively covered.
Downloaded By: [Loyola University] At: 18:30 4 September 2009
Social Security
The first social security initiatives arose in Chile in 1832 with the Funds protecting destitute people, the pension program for death of the military in
1855, the Saving Fund of the civil servants in 1858 and the Pension Funds for
the Railroad Workers in 1918. By the mid 1920s an extensive social security
system was created. The system was mainly oriented to formal workers,
structured on a pay-as-you-go basis and managed by semiautonomous
agencies—the social security funds. Chile’s social security system was
reformed in 1980 after a deep crisis characterized by a financial insolvency,
inequality in the distribution of benefits and administrative inefficiency
(SAFP, 1998). Funds were merged into the Institute of Social Security
Normalization (INP), a public agency whose mission is to administer contributions and pensions of the old pay-as-you-go system. In addition, a new
system was created on the following basis: privately managed by Pension
Fund Administrators (AFPs) but supervised by the government, workers
contribute to a personal account, AFPs invest pension funds seeking profits
and security, worker’s pensions are a direct consequence of contributions
and profits earned, and the workers are free to choose the AFP that manage
their individual pension funds (Olavarria-Gambi, 2000). Both systems have
coexisted since the enactment of the private one but the INP system is in
extinction: workers contributing to the pay-as-you-go scheme can remain in
it until they retire while new workers must enroll in the private system.
The Chilean social security system expanded rapidly since its inception,
making Chile stand out for the broad coverage of the system (Raczynski,
1994); however, neither the pay-as-you-go scheme nor the private pension
system have gotten a complete coverage of the labor force. The pay-as-you-go
scheme reached a pick coverage of 79 percent in 1973. By 1980, when it was
reformed, it covered 64 percent of the labor force. As of 2005, the Chilean
pension system covered 70.12 percent of the labor force, being 67.75 percent
contributors of the private pension system and the remaining 2.37 percent
still contributed to the old pay-as-you-go plan (SAFP, 2007).
It has been difficult for the poor to get effective protection from the
social security system. Under the pay-as-you-go scheme social security
Downloaded By: [Loyola University] At: 18:30 4 September 2009
114
M. Ola va rria -Ga mbi
protection was restricted to workers but the poor—non-salaried people,
occasional laborers, seasonal workers, craftsmen, people working in the
peasant economy and so on—could barely have that protection since they
could rarely get formal jobs. In addition, benefits received by different sectors of workers corresponded to their political influence, resulting in poorer
workers having the hardest condition to retire. For instance, blue-collar
workers, which contributed to the Social Security Fund (SSS), could retire at
the age of 65for men, and women at the age of 55, while white collar workers
contributing to the Civil Servant Security Fund could retire having worked a
minimum of 20 years.7 Thus, somebody who started to work at the age of
18 and contributed to these funds, could retire at the age of 38. Blue-collar
workers never got that possibility. By 1980, 65 percent of workers contributed
to the Social Security Fund, 18 percent to the Private Employees Security
Fund, 12 percent to the Civil Servant Security Fund and the remaining five
percent to other minor funds (Cheyre, 1991; SAFP, 1998).
Some methods of minimum protection have been created during
the last decades for workers contributing to social security and even for
those lacking such coverage. According to the law, people contributing to
private pension plans have at least a minimum pension assured no matter
the amount of the individual fund accumulated. This is particularly important for low-income workers whose accumulated fund could be lower than
needed to get a higher pension. In addition, the “Assistance Pension”
(PASIS, as it called in Spanish), created in 1975, delivers a small pension to
old age and disabled people who do not get any other pension and whose
total income is not greater than 50 percent of the minimum pension.
As reported, low income people are generally more likely to get PASIS.
Nevertheless, beyond this small emergency help, coverage of the social security
system looks problematic among the low-income people, who are more likely
to lack coverage from the pension system—either the private or the public one.
Low income people show a high probability to lack social security plan
coverage (see Table 8). Although the almost-poor are more likely to be enrolled
in a social security plan than the poor, such coverage is still low among them.
Similarly, females are more likely to lack social security protection.
The Presidential Advisory Commission for the Pension Reform has concluded that the private pension system is not in crisis and proposed reforms
due to the demographic and labor market changes that occurred since the
inception of this system in 1980. According to the Counsel (Consejo
7
Before the enactment of the Decree Law 2448 in 1979, in cases of firing, the minimum requirement
for a public employee to retire was 15 years of contributions. In that situation, pension was around a
half (15/30)of the normal pension. That Decree Law increases that minimum requirement to 20 years of
contributions. Before the Decree Law 2448, the standard requirement to retire was 30 years of contributions.
The Decree Law added the requirement of 65 years of age for men and 60 for women. See: Republic of
Chile, Decree Law 2448, 1979.
Poverty a nd Socia l Progra ms in Chile
115
TABLE 8 Predicted Probability of not Having Social Security Plan Coverage Sorted by
Poverty and Almost Poverty, 1987–2006.
1987
1992
1994
1996
1998
2003
2006
Lacking Social
Poor
0.6378 0.5278 0.6447 0.6357 0.6553 0.4865 0.7096
Security Coverage Almost Poor 0.6113 0.4846 0.5982 0.5838 0.5953 0.4485 0.6232
Downloaded By: [Loyola University] At: 18:30 4 September 2009
Source: Author’s calculation based on CASEN surveys.
Notes: (1) See appendix 5 for results of the multinomial logit regression; (2) Variables controlled for:
socioeconomic stratum, gender, area of residence, age, schooling level and marital status.
Presidencial para la Reforma Previsional, 2006), the workers who have had
stable employment and a record of regular contributions to the system will get
a pension close to the salary they had before retiring; however, many workers—those who are self-employed, the informal ones, those earning around
the minimum salary and an important proportion of the females—will not
be able to fulfill the basic requirement of having contributed at least 240
months to be able to get the minimum pension guaranteed by the government. Thus, according to the Counsel, within the next 20 years, around a 50
percent of the current workers will get a pension higher than the minimum
one, less than a five percent will be able to obtain the minimum pension,
and the rest will get a pension lower than the minimum pension only, an
Assistance Pension (PASIS, as it is called in Spanish), or no pension at all.
To address these issues the Counsel has proposed a reform based on the
creation of a pillar of solidarity, the establishment of tax incentives for self
employed workers to contribute to the pension system as well as access to the
same benefits of the dependent workers, the introduction of criteria of gender
equity, increasing competency within the pension system, and improving regulatory institutions so that investments may be kept profitable and secure. On
December 19, 2006 the President sent to the Congress the bill reforming the
pension system and on March 2008 it was enacted as the law 20,255.
Seen in perspective, although the social security system coverage has
been in expansion since its creation, reaching 70.12 percent of the labor
force by 2005 (SAFP, 2007), and complementary mechanisms have been
created during the last decades, the true fact is that social security protection—as old age and disability pensions—is still precarious for low income
people and women. Thus the reform may be seen as a serious effort oriented to expand worker protection for the time when their capacities to
work had been extinguished.
EXPANDING SOCIAL PROTECTION
Given the fact that indigence did not fall between 1996 and 2000, and thatas
shown in this articlethe very poor have difficulties in accessing to social
Downloaded By: [Loyola University] At: 18:30 4 September 2009
116
M. Ola va rria -Ga mbi
services, the government created a Social Protection Program called “Chile
Solidario” with the purpose of addressing the vulnerability of extremely
poor people. The program was designed between 2000 and 2002, implemented by FOSIS8 as a Pilot Program from 2002—under the name of
Programa Puente (Bridge Program)—and enacted as the law 19,949 in
2004. Similarly, due to the difficulties of low income people in accessing
opportune and affordable health care services the government implemented
the so-called Plan AUGE, later renamed as GES.9 AUGE-GES is a health care
protection system that guarantees coverage for a set of illnesses included in
the Plan.
Chile Solidario is a mean tested program targeting extremely poor people.
The ficha CAS (CAS Card)before 2006and the Ficha Familia (Family Card)
since then have been the instruments used to determine whether a given
household can qualify to the program. According to MIDEPLAN (2006), as
of the year 2005, 209,398 households and 15,675 people older than 65 years
of age living alone qualified to Chile Solidario. Target population has been
invited to participate, since the rejection rate is very small—around five
percent—and full coverage (invitation) was achieved by March 2006.
The Program has three areas of intervention,called componentes,
which are as follows: (i) personalized psychosocial support and a protection
voucher; (ii) guaranteed money subsidies; and (iii) preferred access to social
promotion programs. The psychosocial support is an intervention conducted
by a Social Worker—called Apoyo Familiar (Family Support)—seeking to
help the extremely poor households in the process of achieving an acceptable
standard of living. This expression refers to 53 minimum conditions that the
households receiving the psychosocial support are expected to achieve in the
following dimensions: identification, health care, education, family living,
housing, work, and income. This intervention lasts two years, during which
the household is entitled to receive the protection voucher, consisting of an
amount of money given to the mother, which decreases every six month
and extinguishes by the end of the psychosocial support. The second area
of intervention seeks to guarantee to those qualifying households access to
SUF, PASIS, Subsidy of Drinking Water (SAP), Subsidy for School Retention,
and the Graduation Voucher, a subsidy equivalent to SUF that households
receive after finishing its participation in the Bridge Program (personalized
psychosocial support and a protection voucher). During the intervention
seeking to guarantee preferred access to programs on social promotion,
MIDEPLAN set agreements with public organizations delivering social
programs for Chile Solidario’s participants to get preferred access to the
programs they manage.
8
FOSIS is the Chilean Social Investment Fund.
Plan AUGE means Plan for Universal Access with Explicit Guarantees. And GES means Explicit
Guarantees on Health Care.
9
Downloaded By: [Loyola University] At: 18:30 4 September 2009
Poverty a nd Socia l Progra ms in Chile
117
All households participating in the Chile Solidario Program must go
through the process just one time. The program has been designed for participants going from one stage to the next—starting in the Bridge Program
and ending in the access to social promotion programs. If a household does
not meet the 53 minimum conditions by the end of the psychosocial support or its achievement on the minimum fall later, that particular household
cannot receive the intervention again.
After the two-year-period of the Bridge Program, Chile Solidario’s participants spend three years in a follow up process during which they receive
the Graduation (of Bridge Program) Voucher. It is expected that after the
five-year-intervention, households participating in Chile Solidario overcome
extreme poverty and may autonomously access services delivered by government organizations.
No households have completed the all stages of Chile Solidario yet so
there is not an impact or a result evaluation on the whole intervention available. However, available indicators show some outcomes of the program at
this stage. According to Serrano (2005) qualitative evaluations have shown
achievements and limitations of the intervention. Among one of the most
important achievements of Chile Solidario is that the psychosocial support
has led extremely poor people to access public social services as well as to
generate among them a will to improve their living condition. Among the
limitations is the fact that an over-expectation has been generated that Chile
Solidario may solve such concrete and difficult problems faced by extremely
poor households such as housing and the generation of sustainable income,
which may lead to deception. On the other hand, based on the Bridge
Program Data Base, Santibáñez (2006) reports that 64% of the households
completing the psychosocial support achieved the 53 minimum conditions
established by the Bridge Program but just 37.1 percent was able to maintain that achievement short time later, when the final card with data on the
graduated from the Bridge Program was collected. The criteria of success
set to this program was that 70 percent of the participants graduated with
the 53 minimum conditions achieved. By the same token, evaluating the
effect of the first two years of the program, Galasso (2006) found that participants households tend to improve their outcomes on education and health
care, increase their access to money subsidies, housing and employment
programs but no evidence was found that that had translated into an
improvement in employment or income outcomes in the short term.
These very preliminary results are opening question on the effectiveness
of Chile Solidario in overcoming extreme poverty. Given that households
receive the treatment just one time, that 36% of the participants did not
achieve all the 53 minimum conditions, that 26.9% of the intervened households were not able to keep the minimum conditions they had achieved and
that there was no evidence on the improvement of employment or income
outcomes of participants, the question about whether Chile Solidario is an
Downloaded By: [Loyola University] At: 18:30 4 September 2009
118
M. Ola va rria -Ga mbi
effective intervention to overcome extreme poverty is raising. At this stage,
most positive results of the program are in its qualitative side. Coincidently
with Serrano (2005), Galasso (2006) found that the role of the psychosocial
support has been fundamental in participants achieving a better awareness
of social services and orientation to the future.
Although these are very preliminary results, from the earliest stages of
the program, and more definitive outcomes and impacts will be captured in
future evaluations, they may suggest the need to stress the role of the psychosocial support and reform the areas of the programs related to outcomes
on employment and income.
AUGE-GES is part of a reform seeking to guarantee universal access to
health care. To reach that end, apart from the system of health care guaranteed, the reform addresses issues about hospital management, health care
financing, rights and protection of ISAPREs’s enrollees as well as rights and
duties of patients. It started on July 1, 2005 covering 25 illnesses, later
expanded to 40 types of illnesses and from 2007 expanded again to 56
illnesses. The financing for those enrolled in FONASA or the indigent lacking
a health care plan is provided by the public coffer while ISAPREs’s enrollees
have a copay of 20% of the respective tariff of reference and the rest has to
be covered by the ISAPRE.
The Chilean Medical Association10 (Colegio Médico de Chile, 2007) has
critically stated that the Plan AUGE-GES “is not a health care plan for a
health care system” but a health care insurance to be managed by both public
and private organizations. The Medical Association has also criticized
AUGE-GES for not being a plan with real universal access to health care but
a segmented plan of services with a guaranteed component and another
component not guaranteed. Thus, the Medical Association has called
AUGE-GES an “eventually Basic Plan” of health care.
Evaluations on the implementation of AUGE-GES performed by the
“Superintendencia de Salud”11 (2007) have found that FONASA enrollees
have used AUGE-GES five times more than ISAPREs enrollees, that AUGE-GES
is used by all socioeconomic strata, that there are important differences in
the use of coverage for the different heath problems, and that in its first year
of implementation–based on data available on 83% of services provided—
AUGE-GES has not been able to reach the level of use that the health care
system had prior to the reform.
Seen in perspective, AUGE-GES can be seen as a serious effort to
expand the social protection coverage on health care, specially oriented to
the protection of low-income people. Although it started covering a very
limited number of illnesses, it has shown a trend of increasing expansion to
10
Its name in Spanish is “Colegio Médico de Chile.”
The “Superintendencia de Salud” is the public organization in charge of the regulation of the provision
of health care services.
11
Poverty a nd Socia l Progra ms in Chile
119
cover other illnesses that seriously or frequently affect the Chilean population.
Evaluations on the implementation, however, are calling for an extra effort
since the access to a health care services for those in need does not seem to
have improved.
Downloaded By: [Loyola University] At: 18:30 4 September 2009
CONCLUDING REMARKS
The analysis presented in this work has shown that the poor are mainly
women, people younger than 40 years of age, urban residents, individuals
with less than eight years of schooling, and people likely to be healthy but
less likely to receive health care services when sick or injured. The analysis
also shows that there is a persistent association between low education and
poverty either by analyzing the likelihood of a poor to get different levels of
education or that of an individual with low education to be poor.
Furthermore, statistical analysis results show, as expected, that people
who have achieved college education are highly likely to belong to the
medium-high income stratum and, correspondingly, unlikely to be poor.
This finding, however, opens a question that later research should address:
Why are there people with higher education who are poor?
On the other hand, even though almost-poor people could be covered
by either FONASA or a ISAPRE, they exhibit a high likelihood to get medical
help under the indigent modality of health services. Similarly, the likelihood
to lack social security protection is high for low income people and the
poorer the person the higher that likelihood. All of this is showing a precarious
social protection system for the poor in episodes of sickness, old age and
disability. While the middle class and high-income people have effective
mechanisms to face those events, the poor are alone during those difficult
times. The pension reform under the parliamentary discussion seek to
address this issue bringing more equity to the system.
To strengthen social protection for the extreme poor government has
created the Chile Solidario Program with the purpose of making accessible
to the extreme poor public social services, improving the poor’s living
standards and, finally, making the process of overcoming extreme poverty
self-sustainable. Although the extreme poor have increased their access to
public social services, the limited evidence available so far would suggest
that the program may need a second thought to get intervened households
out of extreme poverty once they have completed the program. Similarly,
although AUGE-GES is a serious effort to expand the social protection
coverage on health care for the disadvantaged, access to medical services
when needed is still not better than before the reform.
Chile exhibits good social indicators. The long tradition of social policies
has played a fundamental role on it. Education expanded to a point that
today practically all children attend primary school and 92.7 percent of the
Downloaded By: [Loyola University] At: 18:30 4 September 2009
120
M. Ola va rria -Ga mbi
young population access secondary school (MIDEPLAN, 2005). What is
considered low education in Chile, or less than eight years of schooling, is
substantially higher than the Latin American average of 5.2 years. The health
care system expanded during the 20 th century, which contributed to
increased life expectancy, and to a lower the infant mortality rate—which is
comparable to those of the developed countries—and to the fact that even the
poorest present an increasing marginal likelihood to be healthy. By the same
token, although oriented to formal workers, the social security system greatly
expanded since the 1920s, reaching 70.12 percent of the labor force by 2005.
These attainments have been the result of a long process, taking
decades, of country’s concerns, government efforts and social progress.
However, the ones left behind have been always the same: the poor.
Notwithstanding Chile’s impressive social development, social protection for
the poor is still precarious. The fact that the poor areless likely to get medical
help when sick and are unlikely to get social security protection is a situation
that not only affects the poor but those lying on or just above the poverty
line, namely the almost-poor. As shown, one of the few valuable assets of
the poor is to keep healthy. Then the lack of access to such medical help
for the poor means to cut a way to exit poverty and for the almost-poor
means to increase greatly their likelihood to either fall or return to poverty.
Lack of social security protection in the old age or disability for these people
means that the only possible future for them is poverty.
Consequently, the policy lesson today is the need to strengthen the
effectiveness of social protection for the poor. Although coverage of major
social programs have greatly expanded, health care and social security still are
not completely accessible to the poor. To make social protection effectively
available to the disadvantaged is one of the most important contributions
that social policy can make in order to make the process of overcoming
poverty a sustainable one. Otherwise, the poor will be condemned to continue
seeing how progress goes by in front of them.
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
This article is part of the research project “Inequality,” which has received
financial support from the University of Chile’s Vice-Presidency of Research
and Development.
REFERENCES
Ahumada, J. (1958). En Vez de la Miseria . Santiago, Chile: Editorial Del Pacífico
Akin, J., Griffin, C., Guilkey, D., and Popkin, B. (1985). The Dema nd for Prima ry
Hea lth Services in the Third World . Totowa, NJ: Rowman and Allanheld.
Downloaded By: [Loyola University] At: 18:30 4 September 2009
Poverty a nd Socia l Progra ms in Chile
121
Anriquez, G., Cowan, K., & De Gregorio, J. (1998). Poverty and Macroeconomic
Policies: Chile 1987–1994. Serie Economía , Working Paper No. 27, Centro de
Economía Aplicada. Santiago, Chile: CEA, Universidad de Chile.
Carrasco, S., Martinez, J., & Vial, C. (1997). Pobla ción y necesida des bá sica s en Chile: Un
a cerca miento sociodemográ fico a l período 1982–1994 . Santiago, Chile: MIDEPLAN.
Castro, R. (1994). Pobreza en el Gran Santiago: un estudio de flujos a partir de la
encuesta panel de hogares 1990–1993, in Economía y Tra ba jo en Chile , 4
Informe Anual 1993–1994. Santiago, Chile: PET.
CEPAL (1986). Anua rio Esta dístico de América La tina y el Ca ribe, Edición 1985 .
Santiago, Chile: Author.
CEPAL (2000). La brecha de la equida d. Una segunda eva lua ción . Santiago, Chile:
CEPAL, Naciones Unidas.
CEPAL (2007). Anua rio Esta dístico de América La tina y el Ca ribe 2007 . Santiago,
Chile: Author.
Cheyre, H. (1991). La Previsión en Chile . Santiago, Chile: Centro de Estudios Públicos.
Colegio Médico de Chile (2007). Análisis General y Descriptivo del ‘Plan de Acceso
Universal con Garantías Explicitas–AUGE, Serie Publicación Técnica N°21.
Retrieved January 2008 from www.colegiomedico.cl
Contreras, D. (2000). Links between poverty, inequa lity a nd welfa re. Evidence from a
ra pid growth economy:Chile 1990–1996. Documento de Trabajo, Departamento
de Economía, Universidad de Chile.
Contreras, D., & Larrañaga, O. (1998). Los a ctivos y recursos de la pobla ción pobre
en América La tina : El ca so de Chile . Santiago, Chile: Mimeo.
Chile, Republica de (1979). Decree Law 2448,” published in the Diario Oficial on
February 9, 1979.
Consejo Asesor Provisional para la Reforma Previsional (2006). Informe Fina l, 1.
Santiago, Chile: Presidency of the Republic.
De Ferranti, D., & Ody, A. J. (2006). Key economic a nd socia l cha llenges for La tin
America : Perspectives from recent studies. Working Paper, World Fund.
Ferreira, F. & Litchfield, J. (1998). Ca lm a fter the storms. Income distribution in Chile,
1987–1994. Policy Research Working Paper 1960. Washington, DC: The World Bank.
FONASA. (2007). Protección Socia l en Sa lud en Chile . Santiago, Chile: FONASA.
Galasso, E. (2006). With their effort a nd one opportunity: Allevia ting extreme poverty in
Chile . Development Research Group Working Paper. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Giovagnoli, P., Pizzolito, G., & Trias, J. (2005). Monitoring the socioeconomic
conditions in Argentina, Chile, Paraguay and Uruguay: CHILE. CEDLAS
Paper. Washington, DC: The World Bank.
INE, National Institute of Statistics (2008). Merca do del Tra ba jo-Empleo . Retrieved
October 2008 from www.ine.cl
INE, National Institute of Statistics (1999, November). Esta dística s de Chile en el
Siglo XX. Santiago, Chile: Author
Larrañaga, Osvaldo (1997). Educación y superación de la pobreza en América
Latina, en J. V. Zevallos, (Ed.), Estra tegia s pa ra reducir la pobreza en América
La tina (pp. 321–383). Quito, Ecuador: PNUD.
Larrañaga, O., & Sanhueza, G. (1994). Descomposición de la pobreza en Chile con
ba se en la función lognorma l despla za da , Working Paper, ILADES/Georgetown
University. Santiago, Chile: ILADES.
Downloaded By: [Loyola University] At: 18:30 4 September 2009
122
M. Ola va rria -Ga mbi
Meller, P. (2000). Pobreza y distribución del ingreso en Chile (Déca da del 90).
Working Paper No. 69, Departamento de Ingeniería Industrial, Universidad de
Chile. Santiago, Chile: DII, Universidad de Chile.
MIDEPLAN. (1999). Módulo Serie 1987–1998.” Sa ntia go de Chile: Serie CASEN 98 .
Santiago de Chile: MIDEPLAN, Departamento de Información Social.
MIDEPLAN. (2003). CASEN 2003: Principa les Resulta dos del Módulo de Sa lud . Santiago, Chile: MIDEPLAN.
MIDEPLAN. (2005). CASEN 2003 . Santiago de Chile: MIDEPLAN, Departamento de
Información Social.
MIDEPLAN. (2008). CASEN 2006: Distribución del ingreso e impa cto distributivo del
ga sto socia l. Santiago de Chile: MIDEPLAN, Departamento de Información Social.
MINSAL. (2005). Indica dores de Sa lud . Santiago, Chile: Author.
Olavarria-Gambi, M. (2000). Social security in perspective: A parallel between Chile
and the United States. Georgetown Public Policy Review , 5(2), 165–182.
Olavarria-Gambi, M. (2005). Pobreza , crecimiento económico y politica s socia les.
Santiago, Chile: Editorial Universitaria.
PAHO, Pan-American Health Organization, (1998). Hea lth in the America s. Scientific
Publication No. 569. Washington, DC: PAHO.
PAHO, Pan-American Health Organization, (2008). Ba se de da tos de indica dores
bá sicos. Retrieved March 2008 from www.paho.org
Raczynski, D. (1994). Social policies in Chile: Origin, transformation and perspective.
University of Notre Dame’s Kellog Institute, Democracy and Social Policy Series,
Working Paper No. 4. Notre Dame, Indiana, Kellog Institute.
Santibáñez, C. (2006). Pobreza y desigualdad en Chile: Antecedentes para la
construcción de un sistema de protección social. Banco Interamericano de
Desarrollo, Serie de Estudios Económicos y Sociales.
Serrano, C. (2005). Claves de la política social para la pobreza. Working Paper.
Santiago, Chile: Asesorías para el Desarrollo.
SAFP, Superintendencia de Administradoras de Fondos de Pensiones. (1998). El sistema
chileno de pensiones. Santiago, Chile: Author.
SAFP, Superintendencia de Administradoras de Fondos de Pensiones. (2007). El sistema
chileno de pensiones, Sexta Edición . Santiago, Chile: Author.
Superintendencia de Salud. (2007). Eva lua ción de la reforma de sa lud y situa ción
del sistema de ISAPREs. Diseño metodológico y definición de línea s ba sa les.
Santiago, Chile: Author.
Torche, A. (1999). Pobreza y distribución del ingreso en Chile: Logros y desa fíos.
Unpublished Draft. Santiago, Chile.
UNESCO. (1998). Informe Mundia l sobre la Educa ción 1998 . Madrid, Spain: Author.
World Bank. (2001). Chile. Poverty and Income Distribution in a High Growth
Economy. The case of Chile 1987–1998. Report No. 22037–CH. Washington,
DC: World Bank.
World Bank. (2006). World developm ent report 2006: Equity & developm ent.
Washington, DC: World Bank, Oxford University Press.
World B ank. (2007). Reseña sobre Chile. Retrieved January 2008 from
www.bancomundial.org/alc
Poverty a nd Socia l Progra ms in Chile
123
APPENDIX 1
Downloaded By: [Loyola University] At: 18:30 4 September 2009
Data and Methodology
The analysis presented in this work has been performed on data from the nine
available CASEN surveys. This is a national representative based on a probabilistic sampling survey taken by the University of Chile’s Department of Economics on behalf of the Chile’s Ministry of Planning and Cooperation. CASEN has
been processed in the Santiago headquarters of the United Nation’s Economic
Commission for Latin American and the Caribbean. The main purpose of the
survey is to provide valid information to analyze socio-economic characteristics
of the Chilean population and to monitor the performance of social programs.
A multinomial logit model has been applied to estimate the likelihood
of being poor (Equation 1), having health care coverage (Equation 2) and
being covered by a pension plan (Equation 3) given background characteristics. In addition, a probit model has been employed to determine the
marginal likelihood of being poor or non-poor having different background
characteristics (Equation 4), the marginal likelihood of access to social service for people from different socio-economic strata (Equation 5), and the
marginal likelihood of being healthy and receiving or not receiving medical
help in case of sickness (Equation 6). Dummy variables have been constructed for socio-economic stratum, education levels, health status, social
programs, and background characteristics such as gender, age, residence in
urban or rural areas, and marital status. The unit of analysis is the individual
and multinomial logit and MLE probit models have been estimated at that
level.
Equation 1 : poorsta tti = b1 + b2 Fem ti + b3 Rurti + b4 AGEti + b5 SLti
+ b6 MStti + e ti
Where:
poorstat is an unordered dependent variable including the following categories:
poorstat = 0 if poor (income less than 2 basic basket of food)
poorstat = 1 if almost poor (income between 2 and 3 basic baskets of food)
poorstat = 2 if medium high income (income higher than 3 basic baskets of
food)
Comparison group : medium high income
Equation 2:
hea lsta tti = b1 + b2 SECSti + b3 Fem ti + b4 Rurti + b5 AGEti
+ b6 MSti + e ti
Where:
healstat is an unordered dependent variable including the following categories:
healstat = 0 if lacking a health plan
124
M. Ola va rria -Ga mbi
healstat = 1 if having the public health plan (salupub)
healstat = 2 if having the private health (isapre)
Comparison group : having the private health plan
Equation 3: penssta tti = b1 + b2 SECSti + b3 Fem ti + b4 Rurti + b5 AGEti
+ b6 MSti + e ti
Where:
Downloaded By: [Loyola University] At: 18:30 4 September 2009
pensstat is an unordered dependent variable including the following categories:
pensstat = 0 if lacking a pension plan
pensstat = 1 if having the public pension plan (inp)
pensstat = 2 if having the private pension plan (afp)
Comparison group : having the private pension plan
Equation 4: SECSti = b1 + b2 Fem ti + b3 Rurti + b4 AGEti + b5 SLti + b6 MSti + e ti
Equation 5: PPti = b1 + b2 SECSti + b3 Fem ti + b4 Rurti + b5 AGEti + b6 SLti
+ b7 MSti + e ti
Equation 6 : HSti = b1 + b2 SECSti + b3 Fem ti + b4 Rurti + b5 AGEti + b6 SLti
+ b7 MSti + e t
Where: PP represents participation in the program, Fem stands for female,
Rur represents population living in rural areas, SECS stand for socio-economic
stratums, AGE represents a vector of age dummies, SL means schooling levels and MS stands for marital status. Variants of these models also include
controls for either whether the person is self-employed or a low qualification worker.
Dummy variables have been created to represent different socio-economic
strata, age, schooling, and marital status categories as follows. Socioeconomic stratums considered are: indigent, poor, almost-poor, and
medium-high income. The criteria to distinguish among them is whether
income falls below one, two, or three values of a basic basket of food. 1 If
so, they are indigent, poor, or almost-poor. If their income is above the
value of three basic baskets of food, then they are classified as mediumhigh income. These values correspond to population living in urban areas.
For the rural population the values are 0.75, 1.5 and 2.5 values of the basic
basket of food. In the case of people’s age the categories considered are: 0
1
A basic basket of food is a measure that identify the minimum income needed by a person to satisfy
his or her nutritional needs. It is constructed considering the minimum required consumption of calories
and proteins according to the World Health Organization standards, the population consumption habits,
and market prices.
Poverty a nd Socia l Progra ms in Chile
125
Downloaded By: [Loyola University] At: 18:30 4 September 2009
to 4 years, 5 to 14 years, 15 to 19 years, 20 to 39 years, 40 to 65 years and 66
years and over. The category of 40 to 65 years of age has been identified as
the reference group. The categories considered for schooling level are: no
education at all, 1 to 4 years of schooling, 5 to 7, 8 years of schooling, 9 to
11, 12, and more than 12 years of schooling. Eight years of schooling has
been taken as the reference group. Categories for marital status are: couples
(either married or living together), living alone (either single, separated, or
divorced), and widow(er)s. Couples are the reference group for marital status.
Appendices present results of the multinomial logit models. Tables presenting results of the marginal probability probit model have been omitted
due to their excessive length. However, they are available upon request.
Downloaded By: [Loyola University] At: 18:30 4 September 2009
APPENDIX 2 Selected Multinomial Results for Poverty Sorting (Base Category: Medium and High Income People)
1987
Variable
Femaler
Poor
Almost
poor
126
0.0340 -0.0238
(.0174) (0.0213)
Rural
-0.3461 -0.1134
(0.0205) (0.0249)
Age 20to 39 1.2060
0.6468
(0.0246) (0.0298)
Age 66 and -0.4246 -0.0486
over
(0.0384) (0.0432)
Schooling 0 1.2234
0.7640
(0.0507) (0.0612)
Schoolingd
0.3773
0.2634
5 to 7
(0.0337) (0.0415)
Schooling 12 -1.0163 -0.4587
(0.0378) (0.0457)
-1.3375 -0.9552
Schooling
greater
(0.3558) (0.0441)
than 12
Single,
-0.4237 -0.0703
separated, (0.0224) (0.0268)
divorced
Constant
-0.3431 -0.9812
(0.0328) (0.0402)
Númber of
74,213
Observ
Prob>chi2
0.000
Pseudo R2
0.0549
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
2003
2006
Poor
Almost
poor
Poor
Almost
poor
Poor
Almost
poor
Poor
Almost
poor
Poor
Almost
poor
Poor
Almost
poor
Poor
Almost
poor
Poor
Almost
poor
0.1012
(0.0172)
-0.7831
(0.0202)
1.1403
(0.0233)
-0.6884
(0.0398)
0.6160
(0.0449)
0.2392
(0.0339)
-1.1563
(0.0352)
-2.2294
(0.0413)
0.0434
(0.0199)
-0.5132
(0.0234)
0.5852
(0.0262)
-0.2592
(0.0417)
0.3703
(0.0524)
0.1398
(0.0404)
-0.6388
(0.0407)
-1.3270
(0.0442)
0.1273
(0.0148)
-0.5531
(0.0165)
1.1719
(0.0201)
-0.6815
(0.0343)
0.8350
(0.0394)
0.2720
(0.0284)
-1.0288
(0.0298)
-2.1133
(0.0379)
0.0590
(0.0168)
-0.3998
(0.0188)
0.7326
(0.0223)
-0.2443
(0.0349)
0.5453
(0.0451)
0.1673
(0.0331)
-0.5789
(0.0335)
-1.4384
(0.0399)
0.1334
(0.0134)
-0.4086
(0.0145)
1.1942
(0.0185)
-0.8044
(0.0305)
0.6410
(0.0337)
0.2089
(0.0257)
-1.1600
(0.0282)
-2.3116
(0.0368)
0.0851
(0.0150)
-0.2442
(0.0162)
0.7285
(0.0203)
-0.3556
(0.0304)
0.4167
(0.0380)
0.1230
(0.0295)
-0.6304
(0.0309)
-1.6315
(0.0379)
0.1129
(0.0160)
-0.4145
(0.0187)
1.1284
(0.0219)
-0.8501
(0.0378)
0.8140
(0.0434)
0.1781
(0.0306)
-1.1768
(0.0321)
-2.1159
(0.0407)
0.0687
(0.0174)
-0.3318
(0.0206)
0.7646
(0.0232)
-0.4055
(0.0367)
0.6278
(0.0476)
0.1133
(0.0347)
-0.6802
(0.0345)
-1.5075
(0.0412)
0.1440
(0.0139)
-0.5651
(0.0158)
1.0431
(0.0188)
-0.8145
(0.0329)
0.7098
(0.0369)
0.2033
(0.0260)
-1.1199
(0.0271)
-2.3029
(0.0379)
0.0813
(0.0148)
-0.4580
(0.0169)
0.7428
(0.0196)
-0.3560
(0.0309)
0.4855
(0.0400)
0.2943
(0.0316)
-0.6425
(0.0285)
-1.6872
(0.0367)
0.0925
(0.0098)
-0.2878
(0.0103)
0.2140
(0.0130)
-1.5617
(0.0298)
0.2194
(0.0314)
0.0474
(0.0212)
-0.9418
(0.0222)
-0.5857
(0.0217)
0.0554
(0.0109)
-0.2646
(0.0115)
0.1565
(0.0144)
-0.9239
(0.0269)
0.1736
(0.0340)
0.0311
(0.0239)
-0.5213
(0.0239)
-0.5596
(0.0246)
0.1322
(0.0101)
-0.2720
(0.0109)
0.1784
(0.0134)
-1.1197
(0.0267)
0.3569
(0.0333)
0.2141
(0.0220)
-0.9220
(0.0220)
-0.8382
(0.0222)
0.0926
(0.0101)
0.3163
(0.0105)
0.1603
(0.0134)
-0.4694
(0.0223)
0.3150
(0.0314)
-0.0186
(0.0219)
-0.5565
(0.0214)
-0.7541
(0.0225)
0.1608
(0.011)
-0.4031
(0.012)
.01662
(0.015)
-1.0392
(0.028)
0.4437
(0.035)
0.1321
(0.024)
-0.7951
(0.024)
-0.7192
(0.024)
0.1101
(0.011)
0.1477
(0.012)
0.1371
(0.015)
-0.4101
(0.028)
0.3664
(0.035)
-0.0003
(0.024)
-0.5001
(0.024)
-0.6751
(0.024)
-0.4592 -0.1402 -0.5648 -0.2965 -0.5490 -0.2543 -0.4925 -0.2960 -0.3900 -0.3154
0.1215
0.0498
0.2327
0.1209
0.2960
(0.0223) (0.0249) (0.0192) (0.0212) (0.0175) (0.0190) (0.0210) (0.0220) (0.0181) (0.0189) (0.0131) (0.0144) (0.0135) (0.0134) (0.015)
0.1194
(0.015)
-0.2915 -0.7660 -0.2562 -0.9558 -0.6677 -0.9978 -0.9310 -1.1544 -1.0407 -1.1827 -0.6424 -0.9381 -0.7364 -0.9584 -1.3780 -1.221
(0.0329) (0.0384) (0.0392) (0.0321) (0.0259) (0.0293) (0.0300) (0.0331) (0.0254) (0.0273) (0.0200) (0.0223) (0.0197) (0.0198) (0.021)
(0.021)
79,715
109,011
136.077
102,814
145,232
252,748
257,019
268873
0.000
0.0708
0.000
0.0645
0.000
0.0693
0.000
0.0654
0.000
0.0648
0.000
0.0316
0.000
0.0317
0.000
0,0270
Note: Standard errors are given in parentheses. Other results not shown here refer to variables representing additional categories for age, schooling levels, and marital status. The constant refers to urban, married men
between 40 and 65 years of age, and having eight years of education completed.
Downloaded By: [Loyola University] At: 18:30 4 September 2009
APPENDIX 3 Multinomial Results for Poverty Sorting and Schooling of People 24 Years and Over (Base Category: Medium and High Income
People)
1987
Variable
Poor
Almost
poor
Female
−0.02597
−0.0359
Rural
Age 20 to 39
127
Age 66 and
over
Scholling
(people
age 24
and older)
Single,
separated
or
divorced
Widow (er)
Constant
Númber
Observations
Prob>chi2
Pseudo R2
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
2003
2006
Poor
Almost
poor
Poor
Almost
poor
Poor
Almost
poor
Poor
Almost
poor
Poor
Almost
poor
Poor
Almost
poor
Poor
Almost
poor
Poor
Almost
poor
(0.0226)
−0.6245
(0.0271)
1.3421
(0.0275)
−0.6135
(0.0399)
−0.2634
(0.0034)
(0.0268)
−0.3655
(0.0318)
0.7644
(0.0322)
−0.1720
(0.0442)
−0.1722
(0.0038)
0.0441
(0.0208)
−0.8725
(0.0247)
1.1992
(0.0243)
−0.8659
(0.0406)
−0.2107
(0.0028)
0.0147
(0.0239)
−0.6607
(0.0283)
0.6054
(0.0274)
−0.3841
(0.0421)
−0.1401
(0.0031)
0.0720
(0.0180)
−0.6545
(0.0202)
1.2596
(0.0210)
−0.8465
(0.0348)
−0.2032
(0.0025)
0.0367
(0.0202)
−0.5124
(0.0227)
0.7739
(0.0233)
−0.3698
(0.0352)
−0.1438
(0.0027)
0.0821
(0.0161)
−0.5030
(0.0175)
1.2811
(0.0191)
−0.9692
(0.0309)
−0.2025
(0.0023)
0.0426
(0.0178)
−0.3328
(0.0192)
0.7821
(0.0208)
−0.4804
(0.0306)
−0.1398
(0.0024)
0.0706
(0.0198)
−0.6046
(0.0235)
1.2328
(0.0233)
−1.0489
(0.0386)
−0.2189
(0.0028)
0.0417
(0.0210)
−0.4935
(0.0253)
0.8298
(0.0244)
−0.5560
(0.0373)
−0.1554
(0.0029)
0.0990
(0.0170)
−0.6906
(0.0197)
1.1030
(0.0197)
−0.9996
(0.0333)
−0.2036
(0.0024)
0.0593
(0.0176)
−0.5861
(0.0206)
0.7854
(0.0203)
−0.5003
(0.0311)
−0.1454
(0.0024)
0.0702
(0.0144)
−0.6845
(0.0158)
1.0090
(0.0165)
−1.5962
(0.0310)
−0.1884
(0.0021)
0.0441
(0.0151)
−0.6131
(0.0166)
0.7357
(0.0173)
−0.9672
(0.0278)
−0.1369
(0.0021)
0.1215
(0.0146)
−0.6715
(0.0161)
0.9381
(0.0167)
−1.1629
(0.0277)
−0.2028
(0.0021)
0.0875
(0.0137)
0.0039
(0.0146)
0.6995
(0.0159)
−0.5074
(0.0228)
−0.1460
(0.0019)
0.2071
(0.016)
−0.7003
(0.017)
0.7945
(0.018)
−1.088
(0.029)
−0.1751
(0.022)
0.1178
(0.013)
−0.0959
(0.014)
0.5974
(0.015)
−0.4533
(0.021)
−0.1309
(0.001)
−0.4981
−0.1037
−0.5928
−0.2355
−0.6794
−0.3896
−0.6673
−0.3049
−0.6271
−0.3824
−0.5319
−0.3735
−0.6205
−0.4711
−0.4726
−0.3676
−0.2403
−0.2779
(0.0281)
(0.0321)
(0.0261)
(0.0289)
(0.0222)
(0.0244)
(0.0203)
(0.0215)
(0.0247)
(0.0255)
(0.0210)
(0.0214)
(0.0177)
(0.0184)
(0.0175)
(0.0164)
(0.018)
(0.016)
−0.3758
(0.0348) (0.0303)
0.4903 −0.0402
(0.0215) (0.0212)
148,603
−0.3323
−0.2146
−0.0900
(0.0442) (0.0507)
1.5875
0.3264
(0.0327) (0.0385)
47,350
0.000
0.0868
−0.2715
−0.2748
(0.0455) (0.0505)
1.1071
0.2064
(0.0297) (0.0338)
55,945
0.000
0.0758
−0.2439
(0.0401) (0.0428)
0.7981
0.0631
(0.0259) (0.0291)
77,428
−0.2970
0.000
0.0707
−0.3005
−0.1596
(0.0362) (0.0374)
0.6504 −0.0738
(0.0227) (0.0252)
98,086
0.000
0.0697
−0.2742
−0.2542
(0.0452) (0.0463)
0.5097 −0.0852
(0.0282) (0.0304)
72,663
0.000
0.0748
−0.3493
−0.2372
(0.0399) (0.0388)
0.3107 −0.1978
(0.0242) (0.0256)
104,607
0.000
0.0661
−0.4262
−0.2224
(0.0366) (0.0345)
0.4091 −0.1054
(0.0214) (0.0227)
142,979
0.000
0.0675
−0.4541
0.000
0.0639
−0.3765
(0.037) (0.029)
−0.2909 −0.3813
(0.023) (0.020)
162496
0.000
0.0480
Note: Standard errors are given in parentheses. Other results not shown here refer to variables representing additional categories for age, schooling levels, and marital status. The constant refers to urban, married men, between 40 and 65 years
of age, and having eight years of education completed.
Downloaded By: [Loyola University] At: 18:30 4 September 2009
APPENDIX 4 Selected Multinomial Results for Health Plan Coverage (Base Category: ISAPRE)
1987
Variable
FONASA
Indigente
3.0420
2.0469
(0.0531) (0.0504)
1.4339
1.0874
(0.0520) (0.0474)
Female
0.0972
0.0153
(0.0352) (0.0322)
Rural
2.0635
1.7056
(0.0694) (0.0679)
Age 20 to 39
0.3523
−0.1126
(0.0493) (0.0444)
Age 66 and
0.7756
1.3330
over
(0.1254) (0.1194)
Schooling 5
0.6254
0.4790
to 7
(0.0876) (0.0839)
Schooling
−1.1604
−0.5992
12
(0.0755) (0.0818)
More than
−11–.4878 −00–.9482
12 years
(0.0761) (0.0696)
schooling
Single,
1.4474
0.6149
separated, (0.0474) (0.0440)
divorced
Constant
−00–.6317 1.1678
(0.0749) (0.0682)
Number
60,261
66,882
Observ
Prob>Chi2
0.000
0.000
Pseudo R2
0.1406
0.1446
2.3132
(0.0367)
1.3644
(0.0389)
0.1262
(0.0274)
1.4394
(0.0369)
0.2044
(0.0366)
0.7936
(0.0814)
0.4611
(0.0666)
−1.4049
(0.0607)
−22–.3802
(0.0654)
Poor
Almost Poor
Indigent
1990
1992
FONASA
128
1.4418
2.0774
(0.0337)
(0.0290)
1.0275
1.1639
(0.0344)
(0.0305)
0.0808
0.1822
(0.0242)
(0.0222)
0.7753
1.5796
(0.0348)
(0.0283)
−0.1558
0.2773
(0.0313)
(0.0298)
1.1359
0.6844
(0.0751)
(0.0609)
0.2373
0.4713
(0.0636)
(0.0491)
−0.7856
−1.3817
(0.0545)
(0.0462)
−11–.4370 −22–.5566
(0.0543)
(0.0588)
0.9821
(0.0355)
0.2761
(0.0315)
(0.0604)
90,363
0.000
0.1546
−00–.5767
Indigente
1994
FONASA
1.2857
2.0255
(0.0267)
(0.0256)
0.8384
1.1685
(0.0270)
(0.0265)
0.0896
0.1965
(0.0196)
(0.0191)
0.9673
1.6686
(0.0268)
(0.0240)
−0.1845
0.1218
(0.0254)
(0.0258)
1.0884
1.1160
(0.0533)
(0.0556)
0.2310
0.3916
(0.0467)
(0.0436)
−0.7131
−1.3240
(0.0408)
(0.0408)
−11–.3855 −22–.5298
(0.0422)
(0.0468)
0.8748
(0.0288)
0.2625
(0.0256)
0.9749
(0.0544)
120,186
(0.0460)
87,072
0.000
0.1599
0.000
0.1757
−00–.9037
Indigente
1996
FONASA
1.1203
2.3955
(0.0247)
(0.0337)
0.8265
1.3131
(0.0248)
(0.0317)
0.1338
0.3318
(0.0177)
(0.0227)
0.9773
1.8249
(0.0233)
(0.0320)
−0.2672
0.1928
(0.0231)
(0.0300)
1.2806
1.2342
(0.0529)
(0.0628)
0.2712
0.4157
(0.0427)
(0.0529)
−0.7078
−1.5099
(0.0382)
(0.0481)
−11–.4157 −22–.5528
(0.0392)
(0.0549)
1.0360
(0.0250)
0.2996
(0.0233)
0.5422
(0.0409)
123,391
(0.0405)
223,799
0.5399
(0.0380)
234,003
0.000
0.1756
0.000
0.1688
0.000
0.1638
−00–.5291
Indigente
0.6556
(0.0288)
−00–.6800
(0.0474)
249982
FONASA
1998
Indigente
1.3879
2.6829
(0.0319)
(0.0335)
0.8851
1.4499
(0.0285)
(0.0283)
0.1830
0.3701
(0.0197)
(0.0197)
0.8958
1.6100
(0.0308)
(0.0259)
−0.1740
0.3243
(0.0251)
(0.0258)
1.2699
0.9755
(0.0584)
(0.0540)
0.2143
0.4911
(0.0503)
(0.0469)
−0.8274
−1.4708
(0.0427)
(0.0411)
−11–.5466 −22–.8845
(0.0438)
(0.0488)
0.1203
(0.0248)
0.7430
(0.0423)
FONASA
Indigente
1.4468
3.2955
(0.0325)
(0.0295)
0.8464
1.9117
(0.0261)
(0.0247)
0.1833
0.3065
(0.0172)
(0.0160)
0.7960
1.9272
(0.0246)
(0.0194)
0.0406
−0.1604
(0.0217)
(0.0207)
1.1295
0.9297
(0.0501)
(0.0513)
0.3272
0.5565
(0.0448)
(0.0483)
−0.7513
−1.3890
(0.0371)
(0.0404)
−11–.6362 −22–.0974
(0.0380)
(0.0402)
0.7304
(0.0251)
0.1050
(0.0218)
(0.0406)
0.8753
(0.0366)
−00–.5692
2000
FONASA
2003
Indigente
1.8394
3.4023
(0.0291)
(0.0359)
1.3383
2.0736
(0.0235)
(0.0269)
0.1038
0.2562
(0.0147)
(0.0164)
0.9795
1.7023
(0.0186)
(0.0209)
−0.2059
−0.0268
(0.0184)
(0.0209)
0.9830
0.2502
(0.0492)
(0.0491)
0.3413
0.4791
(0.0469)
(0.0557)
−0.8012
−1.4549
(0.0375)
(0.0442)
−11–.6668 −22–.5882
(0.0373)
(0.0439)
FONASA
2006
Indigente
1.9759
2.906
(0.0357)
(0.398)
1.4659
2.142
(0.0263)
(0.0322)
0.1238
0.5398
(0.0152)
(0.015)
0.7498
1.4950
(0.0204)
(0.020)
−0.1543
−0.0856
(0.0189)
(0.020)
0.5087
0.4918
(0.0468)
(0.048)
0.2664
0.3114
(0.0547)
(0.058)
−0.8792
−1.537
(0.0424)
(0.045)
−11–.9568 −22–.754
(0.0418)
(0.045)
FONASA
1.4115
(0.0400)
1.4777
(0.031)
0.1369
(0.015)
0.7128
(0.019)
−0.0908
(0.019)
0.4805
(0.046)
0.0641
(0.057)
−0.9650
(0.044)
−22–.0339
(0.043)
1.1181
(0.0215)
0.3609
(0.0192)
1.1236
(0.0217)
0.3807
(0.0197)
0.2335
(0.065)
0.3469
(0.063)
(0.0393)
1.2592
(0.0368)
0.5245
(0.0426)
1.7341
(0.0410)
1.0666
(0.044)
2.1975
(0.043)
−00–.2035
0.000
0.1366
Note: The indigent plan refers to health care services received under the indigent modality, that is free of charge. FONASA refers to being covered by the public health care plan. ISAPRE refers to being covered by a private pre-paid health care plan. Standard errors
are given in parentheses. Other results not shown here refer to variables representing additional categories for age, schooling levels, and marital status. The constant refers to urban, married men,between 40 and 65 years of age, and having eight years of education
completed.
Downloaded By: [Loyola University] At: 18:30 4 September 2009
APPENDIX 5 Selected Multinomial Results for Pension Plan Coverage (Base Category: AFP)
1987
Variable
Poor
Almost Poor
Female
Rural
Age 40 to 65
129
Age 66 and
over
Schooling 5
to 7
Schooling 12
More thab 12
years of
schooling
Single,
separated,
divorced
Constant
Nunmber
Observ
Prob>chi2
Pseudo R2
No
pension
plan
1992
INP
No
pension
plan
0.4162
(0.0218)
0.1610
(0.0271)
1.4006
(0.0198)
0.2501
(0.0231)
−0.0651
(0.0272)
1.6373
(0.1006)
0.1651
(0.0393)
−0.6299
(0.0409)
−1.2981
(0.0364)
0.0868
(0.0334)
0.1323
(0.0396)
0.1337
(0.0307)
−0.0219
(0.0342)
1.5316
(0.0402)
4.3926
(0.1028)
0.3528
(0.0548)
−0.8594
(0.0780)
−1.3625
(0.0611)
0.5538
(0.0218)
0.2581
(0.0368)
−0.0282
−1.7497
(0.0387) (0.0603)
72.147
0.000
0.2006
1994
INP
No
pension
plan
0.7806
(0.0185)
0.3510
(0.0208)
2.3477
(0.0169)
0.2271
(0.0173)
−0.5039
(0.0198)
0.6953
(0.0413)
0.1569
(0.0299)
−0.2271
(0.0308)
−0.6220
(0.0344)
0.2603
(0.0382)
0.1668
(0.0402)
0.8954
(0.0323)
−0.3237
(0.0340)
2.3007
(0.0568)
5.0200
(0.0640)
0.2472
(0.0654)
−0.4159
(0.0761)
−0.7949
(0.0882)
0.7205
(0.0175)
0.6235
(0.0404)
−2.2583
−5.0666
(0.0316) (0.0807)
107.504
0.000
0.2967
1996
1998
INP
No
pension
plan
INP
No
pension
plan
0.4994
(0.0165)
0.1411
(0.0182)
1.3628
(0.0139)
0.4277
(0.0149)
0.0008
(0.0172)
1.2837
(0.0427)
0.2523
(0.0256)
−0.6324
(0.0262)
−0.9988
(0.0287)
0.0076
(0.0298)
−0.0132
(0.0309)
0.1987
(0.0243)
0.2039
(0.0250)
2.3501
(0.0381)
4.6447
(0.0537)
0.4203
(0.0502)
−0.4714
(0.0575)
−0.7647
(0.0622)
0.6499
(0.0186)
0.2679
(0.0199)
1.1775
(0.0151)
0.5318
(0.0180)
−0.0544
(0.0191)
1.1383
(0.0459)
0.2721
(0.0298)
−0.5019
(0.0290)
0.0060
(0.0286)
0.1334
(0.0356)
−0.0142
(0.0366)
0.1110
(0.0274)
−0.1001
( −0.0321)
2.6706
(0.0473)
4.9376
(0.0623)
0.3945
(0.0548)
−0.5467
(0.0613)
−0.6264
(0.0660)
0.7798
(0.0163)
0.3775
(0.0169)
1.1659
(0.0127)
0.5400
(0.0145)
−0.1311
(0.0159)
1.1030
(0.0377)
0.2595
(0.0248)
−0.4477
(0.0239)
0.0801
(0.0240)
0.7618
(0.0155)
0.5665
(0.0307)
1.0146
(0.0168)
0.7771
(0.0348)
1.1392
(0.0143)
−0.8464
−3.6584
(0.0259) (0.0578)
133.533
0.000
0.2104
−1.0970
−3.8790
(0.0285)
(0.0661)
100.838
0.000
0.1909
−1.2501
2003
INP
No
pension
plan
(0.0332)
−0.0710
(0.0323)
0.1381
(0.0237)
−0.0579
(0.0263)
3.0312
(0.0496)
5.4227
(0.0593)
0.4481
(0.0468)
−0.5703
(0.0540)
−0.6205
(0.0595)
0.4260
(0.0159)
0.1072
(0.0155)
1.3609
(0.0127)
0.3138
(0.0133)
−0.0175
(0.0152)
1.1989
(0.0369)
0.4102
(0.0237)
−0.5405
(0.0223)
−1.8015
(0.0237)
0.9099
(0.0304)
0.0076
(0.0146)
−0.0239
−4.5090
(0.0238) (0.0638)
142.553
0.000
0.2107
−0.7034
2006
INP
No
pension
plan
INP
(0.0585)
−0.2960
(0.0468)
0.1127
(0.0362)
−0.4258
(0.0393)
7.3146
(0.7079)
9.3704
(0.7092)
0.5512
(0.0676)
−0.4576
(0.0772)
−1.1004
(0.0886)
1.0775
(0.021)
0.5142
(0.016)
1.5651
(0.013)
0.4466
(0.013)
−0.1185
(0.015)
1.3546
(0.034)
0.4470
(0.023)
−0.6129
(0.022)
−0.5667
(0.024)
0.0512
(0.063)
−0.1978
(0.047)
0.2949
(0.033)
−0.2039
(0.034)
4.864
(0.025)
7.1974
(0.025)
0.5526
(0.062)
−0.4467
(0.071)
−0.6332
(0.055)
0.1492
(0.0461)
0.3560
(0.014)
0.2777
(0.042)
−0.4985
−9.4503
(0.0228) (0.7106)
214,463
0.000
0.4222
−1.2330
−7.498
(0.023)
(0.025)
155399
0.000
0.2610
Note: No pension plan refers to people who lack social security coverage. INP refers to people covered by the public pay-as-you-go pension scheme. AFP refers to the social security coverage under the private individual capitalization system. Standard errors are given in parentheses. Other results not shown here refer to variables representing additional categories for age,
schooling levels, and marital status. The constant refers to urban, married men, between 40 and 65 years of age, and having eight years of education completed.