z
zyx
zyxwv
Volume 3 Numbers 2/3
Financing Global Environmental Protection
z
Additional Funds,
Incremental Costs and
the Global Environment
Andrew Jordan and Jacob Werksman
II UNCED
and the Debate on
Finance
One of the most contentious issues raised at the June
1992 United Nations Conference on Environment and
Development (UNCED) was whether and to what
extent the developed countries would meet the
additional cost of measures undertaken by the
developing countries to protect the global climate
system and preserve biodiversity. It was generally
recognized that sufficient financial incentives would
need to be built into the agreements then under negotiation to encourage greater developing country s u p
port, but little discussion took place as to how these
incentives would function in practice. After protracted negotiations, a compromise of sorts was reached.
Developing countries pledged to implement certain
measures to address global environmental problems
in return for new and additional finance provided by
the industrialized states. The total amount of
‘additionality’ was not specified.’ However, the
additional money was earmarked for the incremental
costs incurred by developing countries in
implementing the terms of any agreements they
entered into.
Over the last five years, the terms ‘additionality’ and
‘incrementality’ have appeared with increasing regularity in international negotiations and agreements.
Broad conceptual agreement on additional financing
contributed to the successful renegotiation of the
Montreal Protocol in 1990’ and to the adoption of the
Conventions on Climate Change and Biodiver~ity.~
The successful use of financial bargains between
North and South in these areas appears to have set
an important precedent. An expectation has
developed that financial transfer packages or other
‘selective inducement^'^ will be needed to accelerate
and strengthen the process of negotiating inter-
national environmental regimes in other areas of g l e
bal concern such as desertification and deforestation.
In practice, however, the two concepts have proved
elusive and little agreement exists over how much
money should be transferred and how it should be
used. This is partly because additionality and
incrementality touch the heart of deeper political
debates over which countries should shoulder the
responsibility for human-induced global environmental change, and on how the costs of responding to
such change should be apportioned between countries. Historical grievances and the temptation to link
finance to other disputed issues in international politics, serve only to complicate the debate even further.
Some measure of agreement must be sought or the
implementation of agreements sighed at Rio may be
jeopardized.
This article reviews the emergence of the terms ‘new
and additional’ and ‘incremental cost’ in international
environmental politics. It focuses on the theoretical
and practical difficulties that have arisen during initial
stages of implementing the Climate Change Convention and in the operation of the Convention’s financing institution, the Global Environment Facility (GEF).
Additionality and Incrementality
Additionality describes the origins of the financial
resources needed to solve global environmental problems, while incrementality determines the total size
of those resources needed to address a particular
area of concern (e.g. biodiversity, marine pollution).
The concepts, thus, interlock: the greater the
incremental costs, the more additional resources will
be required; the more additionality that is provided,
the greater the ‘total’ incremental cost that can be
met.
zyxwvu
zyxw
0 Basil Blackwell Ltd. 1994. 108 Cowley Road, Oxford OX4 IJF. UK and 238 Maln Street, Cambridge, MA 02142. USA.
81
zy
z
zyxwvutsrqp
Financing Global Environmental Protection
zyxwv
The concepts have tended to take on different meanings in different contexts. The first context is that of
regime formation (i.e. international negotiations),
where bargains are struck between countries to produce international law and policy. Finance can help to
lubricate the process of international diplomacy. The
second context is the more drawn-out process of
operational decision-making (i.e. the implementation
of international agreements), where implementation
programmes are drawn up, individual projects are
identified and ranked, and finance begins to flow. The
rapid entry into force of both the Rio Conventions has
forced differences of opinion, which were subsumed
during the process of negotiation, to the surface.
‘New and Additional’ Financial Resources
At the core of the concept of additionality is a general
understandlng that resources should be provided by
the industrialized world over and above existing flows
of international finance for measures taken by
developing countries to address global environmental
challenges5 Additionality is either the price the South
demands for its participation in international
attempts to resolve global environmental problems or
the debt the North owes towards the solution of problems primarily of its making. The word ‘new’ is generally understood to describe either the sources of
funding or the financial mechanisms used to provide
them.6 The term ‘additional’ suggests that the assistance supplements, rather than diminishes, existing
flows of finance.’
The Additionality Debate
The principle of additionality could now be said to
form one of the central planks of the Group of 77
(G77) developing countries’ negotiating strategy in
international discussions on environment and development.8 On a very general level, the industrialized
states have been sympathetic to the South’s plea for
extra financial assistance but they have carefully avoided making specific commitments. Some donor
states have sought to put promises into action, and
have pledged their support for the new and additional
.funding mechanisms of the Montreal Protocol Multilateral Fund (MPMF) and the recently restructured
Global Environment Facility (GEFJ9 Neither fund,
however, has sought to clarify or define the
additionality of its contributions.
The Rationale for Additionality
The concept of additionality has an intellectual coherence and is politically attractive to both North and
South. The developing countries’ calls for
additionality are symptomatic of a number of underlying concerns, some essentially practical, others with
a moral and ethical dimension. First, developing countries claim that their attempts to industrialize should
not be hindered by the costs of measures designed
to ameliorate problems not of their making.
0 Basil Blackwell Ltd. 1994.
82
Volume 3 Numbers 2/3
Additionality would provide them with the inducement to leapfrog the polluting and wasteful stages of
industrialization. Second, capital constraints and an
overwhelming need to address domestic concerns
such as poverty and food security do not allow them
to tackle environmental problems with the same vigour as the industrialized world. During the 1980s,
flows of finance from the North (aid, private flows and
export credits) declined sharply (largely as a result
of reductions in private flows) and even reversed as
the debt problem reached its peak in the mid to late
1980s.lo Calls for additionality are thus one attempt
to address much deeper inequalities and economic
imbalances in the world economy. During international negotiations for the Conventions and the
GEF, the developing countries insisted that contributions be additional and disbursements concessional (i.e. in the form of grants or very low interest loans). They were particularly concerned that
contributions to the GEF would not diminish the
funds available for development assistance.”
The notion of providing an extra quantum of finance
specifically for the global environment holds a certain
appeal for the North as well. First, allocating a certain
amount of money for sustainable development or the
global environment makes for good and publicly visible ‘gesture politics’. Second, separating out a distinct portion of money for global warming or ozone
depletion raises the hope that it will be used more
‘efficiently’(in the sense that it specifically funds global environmental projects rather than developmentrelated activities), while also helping to parry criticism that existing flows of aid fail to reflect global
environmental concerns.
Additionality Baselines
Additionality is a relative term, which predicates the
need for some form of bench mark or baseline, above
which an ‘additional’increment can be measured. The
most common interpretation of additionality sets this
baseline empirically by measuring the existing level
of development assistance. Total net resource flows
to the South in 1991 amounted to $131bn (at 1990
prices) (World Resources Institute, 1994),12of which
$3bn (56%) was in the form of Official Development
Assistance (ODA).I3 Although global aid volume has
grown markedly in gross terms in the last 20 years,
as a percentage of OECD GNP it has hardly changed
and remains lodged at around 0.33%.Additionality, so
measured, would thus constitute any increase in ODA
over and above 0.33%.
zyxw
zyxwvz
Developing countries have pressed for a higher, aspirational baseline of 0.7% of GNP, which has been the
UN’s official target for ODA since 1970.14At present
only five developed countries could be said to be
meeting or exceeding this target.15 Not surprisingly,
individual OECD donors support definitions of
zyxwvutsrqpo
z
Volume 3 Numbers 2/3
Financing Global Environmental Aptection
additionality that place their practice in the best light.
Sweden, a country which nets its contributions to the
GEF and the Montreal Protocol Multilateral Fund
(MPMF) from a general multilateral aid budget
(thereby failing the aforementioned test for
additionality)Ifi that is around 0.92% of its domestic
GNP, would clearly have a strong incentive to push
for the acceptance of a 0.7% baseline and indeed has
made representations to that effect.17
flows of development assistance continues to
increase and finance becomes more closely linked
with the future prospects for global environmental
governance, greater scrutiny may need to be applied
to the measurement and enforcement of additionality.
Arguably, this may help to engender trust between
Parties and may improve the quality of the overall cooperative effort.
zyxwvu
The US government, in the context of ozone protection, describes additionality as ‘the allocation of more
funds specifically to ozone protection, but not necessarily the allocation of funds in addition to overall
resource flows’ (emphasis added).18 On this interpretation, any extra money which is diverted to environmental protection is judged to be additional regardless of its origins.’’ In the context of the GEF’s pilot
phase the US announced that it was not prepared to
contribute ‘additional’ funds to the GEF‘s core fund.
Instead, the US negotiated a co-financing agreement
with the GEF, contributions to which a r e redirected
from the regular US Agency for International Development (USAID) budget.
Finally, some countries have argued that additionality
should be measured over and above the level of total
net resource flows, including resources in the form
of private flows of money.zo In this respect, the US
government has argued that more should be done to
exploit private sources of funding ‘in which case
much additionality would ensue’.z1 If net financial
transfers are taken as the unit of account (i.e. total
flows minus interest and dividends on loans) the
bench mark in 1990 would have been just $34bn. The
concept of additionality could then be stretched to
include such things a s debt forgiveness or ‘debt-fornature’ swaps. The adequacy of money allotted to the
GEF and MPMF could be judged to be either very large
or relatively small, depending on the baseline adopted.
Incremental Cost Financing
The term incremental cost is important because it
quantifies the size of the payment that developing
countries will receive from developed countries as
compensationzz for acceding to, and implementing the
terms of, international environmental agreements.
Just as with the term ‘additionality’, recipient Parties
clearly have an incentive to try and maximize the size
and scope of the total side payment; providers, the
converse.
Incrementality can be traced to the text of the revised
(1990) Montreal Protocol. During the negotiations,
countries of the South expressed concern that measures to address ozone depletion, a problem they
repeatedly stressed was not of their making, would
‘add new burdens to their economies and adversely
affect their standard of living’.z3 What were termed
‘incremental burdens’ by negotiators were eventually
incorporated into the text of the revised Protocol as
‘incremental costs’.
zyxwvu
Additionality Post-Rio
The texts of the Climate Change and Biodiversity Conventions d o not clarify the meaning of additionality,
and merely commit industrialized countries to provide ‘new and additional’ finance, If ‘existing flows’ are
t o provide the baseline, then what is ‘additional’ can
only be calculated on the counterfactual of what a
donor would have done had they not entered into an
international agreement or pledged to support an
international fund. The absence of a definition opens
up an enormous opportunity for conflicting interpretations and expectations.
In the Montreal Protocol the sources and technical
solutions for ozone depletion are relatively easy to
identify. Defining and implementing the term
‘incremental cost’ has proved comparatively straightforward and Parties have agreed on a broad list (an
‘indicative list’) of costs judged to be eligible for
‘incremental’ cost financing.z4 In terms of climate
change, a problem more complex and uncertain to
predict and alleviate, the task will be far more challenging.
Much of the controversy surrounding the concept of
incrementality has arisen because of expectations
attached t o the concept when it was expressed as a
broad principle. Thus far, the work of developing a
specific definition for incrementality in the Climate
Change Convention has been carried forward by two
separate but related institutions: the Intergovernmental Negotiating Committee (INC) for a Framework
Convention on Climate Change, which is carrying out
preparatory work for the first meeting of the Convention’s Conference of Parties (COP), and the GEF,
which is to serve as t h e interimz5‘operating entity’ of
the Convention’s financial mechanism. The INC has
only considered the issue in the period since the signing of the Convention (June 1992), whereas the GEF
has made much greater headway during its pilot
zyxwv
zyxwvutsrqponmlkji
An accurate calculation o r indeed enforcement of
additionality will be difficult to achieve not least
because it would transform a general commitment to
a specific obligation. But, as the demand for regular
0 Basil Blackwell Ltd 1994
83
zy
z
zyxwvutsr
Financing Global Environmental Protection
phase (1991-1994). The future of the incremental
financing issue will probably be determined by the
continuing interplay between these two institutions.
zyxwvu
Incremental Costs and the Climate Convention
All Parties to the Convention, developed and
developing countries alike, have committed themselves to undertake a wide range of measures to
address the threat of climate change. These ‘general
commitments’ are designed to develop, collect and
disseminate information on climate change and possible responses, to implement programmes containing
measures to reduce net emissions of greenhouse
gases and to facilitate adequate adaptation to climate
change. Developed country Parties further commit
themselves to provide new and additional resources
to meet the agreed full incremental costs of
developing country Parties. The term ‘agreed full
incremental cost’ was, in itself, a compromise.
Throughout negotiations, developed countries had
advocated the use of the single qualification ‘agreed’,
whereas developing countries preferred the term
‘full’.z6 As a last minute compromise, the two qualifiers, ‘full’ and ‘agreed’, were combined to produce
the seemingly contradictory term ‘agreed full
incremental
Volume 3 Numbers 2/3
GEF on parallel tracks. The INC, a large and looselystructured intergovernmental body with limited
administrative and research capacity but a wide-ranging agenda, has thus far failed to resolve the issue
beyond renewing its requests to its Secretariat for
further clarification of the issues. As this vacuum
developed, the GEF administration launched its own
multi-million dollar research Programme for Measuring Incremental Costs for the Environment
(PRINCEJZ8
Certain commentators expressed surprise over PRINCE’S approach to measuring incrementality because
it appeared both to significantly erode the level of financial resources that would be available under the
Convention and prejudge the outcome of discussions
which are scheduled to begin at the first meeting of
the Convention’s Conference of the Parties (COP) in
1995.29The Convention provides specifically that the
COP (and not the GEF) will ‘decide on. . .policies, programme priorities and eligibility criteria’ for the financial mechanism.
zy
zyxwvutsr
Incremental Costs and the GEF
During the GEF‘s pilot phase (which began almost a
year before the Convention was signed at Rio), donor
country Participants defined incremental cost as that
segment of an eligible project’s total cost which
directly benefits the global environment, but which
would not normally be in the interest of a host nation
to finance itself. Only those projects which generated
global benefits, but which required extra concessional financing to be viable to the host nation (i.e.
where national costs exceeded national benefits),
were judged to be eligible for GEF support in the pilot
phase. ‘Domestically beneficial’ projects were to be
excluded.
In the context of the GEF, then, incremental cost is
the difference between the national costs and national
benefits of a project designed to generate global
environmental benefits. So, for example, the GEF
could meet the incremental cost of redesigning a proposed coal-fired power station project to utilize a
local supply of natural gas, thereby realizing the global benefit of reduced CO, emissions. In this example,
the GEF would pay for the incremental cost of the conversion; the ‘baseline’ cost of the coal-fired station
would have been financed by the host nation (either
from its own resources, or from international lending
or the private sector).
Since Rio, discussions on developing an operational
definition for incremental costs in the climate change
context has been proceeding within the INC and the
0 Basil Blackwell Ltd. 1994.
84
It is easy to imagine that the bulk of the measures
to be undertaken by developing countries under the
Convention will have national as well as global benefits. Because of this, CEF conceded early on that ‘only
a limited number of projects are likely to be. . .eligible
for full funding from GEF‘. The GEF suggests that the
rest of the increment, to cover that portion of the
costs seen to have ‘national’ benefits, should come
from ‘other sources of domestic and foreign funding
sources’.31In a later statement the GEF claimed that
‘in typical cases, the incremental cost will be a relatively small proportion of the total cost of the redesigned or alternate activity.. .’.31
‘Cross’ and ‘Net’ Incremental Costs
As policy makers begin to struggle with the impli-
cations of these early attempts to apply incremental
cost principles, two competing interpretations can be
said to have emerged: gross and net incremental
costs.32Gross incremental costs can be defined as the
difference between the total costs of implementing a
proposed project and that course of action which the
developing country would have pursued had it not
undertaken commitments under the Convention. S u p
porters of this interpretation rely on a direct reading
of the text of the Convention and tend to lay stress
upon the word ‘full’ in ‘agreed full incremental
Net incremental costs, on the other hand, can be
viewed as the additional cost of complying with the
Convention minus the value of any domestic benefits
thereby generated. Generally, this has been the
approach taken by the GEF, and justified on the
grounds that it is more ‘cost effective’ than funding
the full cost of projects (i.e. by funding only those
aspects of a project that specifically yield global
environmental benefits, more funds will be available
zyxwv
zyxwvutsrqpo
z
Volume 3 Numbers 2/3
Financing Global Environmental Protection
zyxwvuts
zyxwvu
to fund the globally beneficial aspects of further
projects). The significant difference between the two
approaches is that on the gross cost interpretation,
developing countries are left better off than they
would have been without Convention funding,
whereas on the net cost interpretation developing
countries are left no better off (except for their share
of the global environmental benefit) than had the Convention not been adopted.34
The G77 coalition and China have signalled that they
expect the costs of all the commitments mentioned
in the Climate Convention to be met including those
measures with primarily domestic benefits such as
adaptation, research, training.35They have expressed
concern that some developed countries are
attempting to reduce the scale of transfers by disallowing projects which are domestically beneficial
from being eligible for funding (i.e. the net cost
appr~ach).~~
If the net approach is followed, developing countries
may be asked to look outside the GEF for funding. To
implement the Convention, developing countries may
be forced to fend for themselves in financial channels
ungoverned by the principles of the Convention. This
may, in turn, lead to an unsystematic and uneven distribution of resources. No system would be in place
to ensure funding from other sources is new and
additional, and at the same on the concessional terms
agreed to under the Convention. Ironically, the net
approach, if adopted, would render those countries
least capable of fulfilling their obligations (and thus
most likely to benefit nationally from enhanced
capacity) least’ eligible for extra funding. Least
developed countries would be saddled with an inequitable share of the global burden of climate change (for
which they have relatively less responsibility) under a
Convention in which developed country Parties have
committed themselves to ‘take full account of the
specific needs and special situations of the least
developed countries in their actions with regard to
funding and transfer of technology’.
Negotiated Incremental Costs
On closer analysis, the line dividing the two interpretations is more blurred than the simple ‘net’ and
‘gross’ typology suggests. There are, for example,
measures which could be taken to reduce global
warming at a negligible incremental cost (correcting
subsidies for example) or even a negative incremental
cost (e.g. energy efficiency measures). Meanwhile, it
is likely that for certain types of projects (e.g. game
parks to protect biodiversity and institutional
strengthening) the incremental cost might approach
100% (i.e. because nothing would have been done in
the absence of the respective Convention). Indeed,
the GEF suggests that ‘there are cases when the
incremental cost will be equal to the full cost of the
a~tivity’.~~
In practice, a balance between the gross and net
interpretations will probably emerge out of a process
of n e g ~ t i a t i o na, ~view
~ now reflected in statements
from the GEF.39 Negotiations could proceed on two
levels: at a sectoral level to determine the eligibility
of certain classes of activity, through the preparation
of indicative lists; and at the project level to determine the scale of assistance to individual interventions. What remains to be agreed on are a set of
guidelines to structure and inform these negotiations.
These should be agreed by the COPS and may draw
upon the research emerging from the PRINCE programme.
Incrementality Baselines
As with additionality, incremental costs can only be
defined against some kind of hypothetical baseline
which measures what a host nation would have done
in the absence of an international agreement.
Incremental cost baselines are as difficult to establish
as additionality baselines, not least because if a proposed project is financed then the baseline situation
will never occur. The baseline is intrinsically hypothetical, since it can be premised upon a number of
very different scenarios and may adopt many different forms, and hence is open to manipulation. King
(1993)40 suggests that the baseline could be based on
a number of factors, including economic efficiency,
equity, and existing trends. In the case of the power
station example (above), the costs and benefits of a
hypothetical coal-fired power station project over the
next 10 to 20 years would need to be calculated. This
would not be easy. The interim Secretariat to the Climate Convention notes that rules of ‘economic,
environmental, technical, and financial reasonableness’ may need to be applied, but.these have yet to
be formulated and agreed upon.41
W Conclusions
As implementation of the Rio Convention proceeds,
the importance of measuring, verifying and perhaps
enforcing additionality and incrementality will
increase. Yet, both are relatively elastic terms and the
potential for conflict and confusion remains high. For
example, the foregoing underscores the importance
of having proper baselines, calculated according to
what a donor or recipient would have done had they
not entered into the respective global environmental
agreement. Clearly, there are enormous difficulties in
estimating. and, more importantly, verifying this
‘counterfactual’. Further, both donors and recipient
parties have an incentive, and the latitude allowed
them by the vagueness of international agreements,
to push the rules of assessment in their favour, leaving plenty of room for discord and conflict in the
future.
zyxwvutsr
zyxwvutsrqponm
D Basil Blackwell Ltd. 1994.
z
zyxwvutsrqpon
~
~~
~~
Financing Global Environmental Protection
zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONM
Volume 3 Numbers 2/3
A vital need has arisen for some form of mutually
4. P. Sand, Lessons Learned in Global Environmental
acceptable calculus or set of criteria for measuring
both terms. As the process of implementation begins
to roll forward, the policy debate may now turn to
fundamental questions about the types of institutions
and decision-making structures appropriate to
developing and applying these criteria. Issues such as
additionality and incrementality involve sophisticated
social, economic, moral, scientific and political judgments. Policy makers must decide if such complex
issues can be handled by open-ended debates in large
intergovernmental bodies such as the Conventions’
COPs or the UN’s Commission on Sustainable Development, or be delegated to more efficient but less
democratic processes such as the CEF‘s PRINCE.
Governance (Washington, World Resources Institute,
The foregoing discussion challenges the simple idea
that the Rio Summit resolved the issue of how to finance the transition to sustainable development. One
suspects that there are very profound discrepancies
in the manner that North and South perceive the need
for, probable role and scope of additional financial
transfers. The developed states tend towards a minimal interpretation; transfers being a price (to be minimized wherever possible) to be paid for enlisting the
support of the South in tackling common problems.
Meanwhile the developing states seek perpetually to
advance a maximal interpretation of additionality and
incrementality, arguing that ‘new’ environmentally
related transfers are a rightful and legitimate means
to address the inequities inherent in the operation of
the world economy. These very different standpoints
are not easily reconcilable. In the short term, the task
of balancing will be worked out between the COPs and
the CEF and the coming years will provide a fascinating test case of how well North and South can adapt
to the challenge of sustainable development.
1990).
5. UNEP, ‘Interpretations of Phrases “Adequate, New and
6.
7.
8.
9.
zyxwv
10.
11.
12.
13.
14.
15.
Notes
Basil Blackwell Ltd 1994
86
16.
zyxwvut
zyxwvu
The UNCED Secretariat calculated that the North would
need to provide the South with $125bn of additionality
each year between 1992 and 2000 t o implement Agenda
21, World Resources Institute, World Resources 1994-5:
A Guide to the Global Environment (Oxford, Oxford University Press, 1994), p. 226. A.J. Jordan discusses other
estimates made of the total amount of additionality
needed to implement sustainable development in A.J.
Jordan, ‘Financing the UNCED Agenda: The Controversy
Over Additionality’, Environment, vol. 36 no. 3 (1994),
pp. 16-20 and 26-34.
J.M. Patlis, ‘The Multilateral Fund of the Montreal Protocol’, Cornell International Law Report, vol. 25 no. 1
(1992), pp. 181-230.
D. Bodansky, ‘The United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change’, Yale Journal Of International
Law, vol. 18 no. 2 (Summer) (1993), p. 492.
(i’
Additional, New and Additional, and Adequate and
Additional”’, Intergovernmental Negotiating Committee
For A Convention On Biological Diversity, Fourth Session, 23 September-2 October, (UNEP/BIO.DIV/INC. 4/4,
16 August), (Nairobi, UNEP, 1991).
UNEP, ‘Interpretations of Phrases’, n. 5 above.
P. Kohona, ‘UNCED: The Transfer Of Financial
Resources T o Developing Countries’, RECIEL, vol. 1 no.
3 (1992), pp. 307-313.
A.J. Jordan, ‘Financing the UNCED Agenda: The Controversy Over Additionality’, Environment, vol. 36 no. 3
(1994), pp. 16-20 and 26-34.
A.J. Jordan and J. Werksman, ‘Power, Money and the
Global Environment: Restructuring and Replenishing
the Global Environment Facility’, EcoDecision (1994)
(forthcoming). Developed country Parties t o the Montreal Protocol recently agreed to provide between $300500m t o the Multilateral Ozone Fund in the period 19946, 1. Rowlands, The Fourth Meeting o f the Parties to the
Montreal Protocol, CSERGE Working Paper vol. GEC 9318 (London and Norwich, CSERCE, 1993).
OECD, Development Cooperation: I992 Report (Paris,
OECD, 1992), p. 79. Net North-South Financial Transfers
(US$) amounted t o 54bn in 1980 and 34bn in 1991; in
1985 and 1986 they were minus 13bn and minus 3bn
respectively (id., p. A-25).
UNEP, UNDP, World Bank, Report of the Independent
Evaluation of the Global Environment Facility
(Washington, GEF, 1993), p. viii.
World Resources Institute, World Resources 1994-5: A
Guide to the Global Environment (Oxford, Oxford University Press, 1994), p. 227.
OECD, Development Cooperation: I992 Report, p. 25, see
n. 10 above.
J. MacNeill et al., Beyond Interdependence (Oxford,
Oxford University Press, 1991), p. 104. Note also that
Switzerland and the US d o not accept this target.
Norway, Denmark, Sweden, Netherlands, Finland
(OECD, Development Cooporation: I992 Report, see n.
10 above).
0. Kjorven and A. Sydnes, Funding for the Global Environment: The Issue of Additionality, Working Paper 199214,
(Lysaker, Norway Fridjtof Nansen Institute, 1992), p. 12.
Government of Sweden, Proposition 1999/1: IOO, bilga 5,
Submission to the Swedish Parliament of Budget Proposals
for 1991-2 (Stockholm, Ministry for Foreign Affairs,
17.
1991).
18. R. Benedick, Ozone Diplomacy (Cambridge, Mass., Harvard University Press, 1991).
19. This was the interpretation of additionality pushed by
the US in negotiations t o revise the Montreal Protocol,
but pressure from the other states subsequently forced
it t o back down. (R. Benedick, Ozone Diplomacy, see n.
17 above.)
20. In 1991 private flows of money made up 42% of total
resource flows from North to South. (OECD, Develop
ment Cooperation: 1992 Report, 1992, see n. 10 above.)
21. Quoted in J. Holmberg, ‘Financing Sustainable Develop
ment’, in J. Holmberg (Ed.), Policies for a Small Planet
(London, Earthscan, 1992).
Volume 3 Numbers 2/3
22. The term 'compensation' is used here to describe a payment in return for a service (i.e. the provision of global
environmental 'services'), and not a payment by way of
acknowledgement of liability for damage (i.e. a s
demanded by a strict legal interpretation of the term).
23. R. Benedick, Ozone Diplomacy, see n. 17 above.
24. A. Wood, Study Three: 'The Interim Multilateral Fund
for the Implementation of the Montreal Protocol', in D.
Reed, (Ed.), The GEF Volume 11 (Washington, WWF International, 1993).
25. More definite arrangements will be discussed at the first
meeting of the COP in 1995.
26. D. Bodansky, The United Nations Framework Convention
on Climate Change, at p. 524, see n. 3 above.
27. In the last draft (March, 1992) of the Convention prior
to it being signed, references t o the scope of funding
still appeared thus: '[full]/[ agreed] incremental costs'
(see A/AC/237/18 (Part I), 10 March 1992). A compromise (i.e. to include agreed and full) was only reached
at INC 5 (8 May 1992) when the final text was adopted.
This was only a month before the UNCED (see
A/AC.237/L. 14).
28. A.J. Jordan and J. Werksman, Power, Money and the Global Environment, see n. 9 above.
29. R. Sharma, 'Debate on PRINCE likely t o Delay Progress
on GEF', Climate Action Network - South Asia (CANSA)
Newsletter, vol. 2 no. 3, p. 8; and J. Werksman, Incremental Costs under the Climate Change Convention: The International Legal Context, FIELD Working Paper (London,
FIELD, 1993).
30. 1. Johnson, 'Incremental Costs and the GEF', Letter t o
workshop invited participants (GEF Letter); 'Attachment 1: PRINCE', 10 November 1992 (Washington, GEF,
1992), p. 2.
3 1. GEF, GEF Replenishment Paper (Washington, GEF, 1993),
p. 18.
32. 'Approaches 'To The Determination Of Agreed Full
Incremental Costs', Note by the Interim Secretariat t o
the Convention on Climate Change (A/AC.237/50/Add.l,
21 December 1993).
Financing Global Environmental Protection
z
33. J. Werksman, Incremental Costs under the Climate Change
convention: The International Legal Context, FIELD Working Paper, (London, FIELD, 1993).
34. D. Pearce and S. Barrett, Incremental Costs and Biodiversity Conservation, Paper prepared for a GEF seminar on
incremental costs and the global environment, Washington, September 21, 1993 (CSERGE, London and Norwich, 1993).
35. Group of 77 and China (draft decision), Matters Relating
t o Arrangements for the Financial Mechanism, INC 7,
15-20 March 1993 (A/AC.237/L.18).
36. S. Oberthur, 'Discussions on Joint Implementation and
the Financial Mechanism', Environmental Policy and
Law, vol. 23 no. 6 (1993), p. 248.
37. GEF, GEF Replenishment Paper, see n. 30 above.
38. D. Pearce and S. Barrett, Incremental Costs and Biodiversity Conservation, see n. 33 above.
39. GEF, The GEF and the Evaluation: Learning h-om Experience and Looking Forward (Washington, GEF, 1993),
p.18. '[Tlhe.. . incremental cost concept [provides] an
analytical framework for a structured dialogue between
a potential recipient country, o r institution, and an
Implementing Agency', GEF, id., p. 5).
40. K. King, Issues to be Addressed by the Program Measuring
Incremental Costs, Working Paper 8 (GEF, Washington,
1993).
41. A/AC.237/50/Add.l, p. 2.
zyx
zyx
zyxwvutsr
zyxwvutsrqp
0 Hasil Blackwell I.td
1991.
I
Andrew Jordan is a Research Associate at the
School of Environmental Sciences, University of
East Anglia. Jacob Werksman is a staff lawyer
and a Co-Director of the Climate Change and
Energy Programme at the Foundation for International Environmental Law and Development
(FIELD).
zyxwv
zyxwvutsrqponml
87