Community based ecotourism as a
panacea for protected areas: the use of
common property theory in its analysis
and development
Conference or Workshop Item
Accepted Version
Edwards, V. M. (2004) Community based ecotourism as a
panacea for protected areas: the use of common property
theory in its analysis and development. In: The Commons in
an Age of Global Transition: challenges, risks and
opportunities, 9-13 August 2004, Mexico. Available at
http://centaur.reading.ac.uk/26016/
It is advisable to refer to the publisher’s version if you intend to cite from the
work. See Guidance on citing .
Published version at: http://www.iasc-commons.org/conferences/global/iasc-2004
All outputs in CentAUR are protected by Intellectual Property Rights law,
including copyright law. Copyright and IPR is retained by the creators or other
copyright holders. Terms and conditions for use of this material are defined in
the End User Agreement .
www.reading.ac.uk/centaur
CentAUR
Central Archive at the University of Reading
Reading’s research outputs online
The Commons in an Age of Global Transition: challenges, risks and
opportunities.
The 10th Bienniel Meeting of the IASCP
Oaxaca, Mexico, August 9-13 2004
Dr. Victoria M. Edwards
School of Environmental Design & Management
University of Portsmouth
Portland Building, Portland Street
Portsmouth
Hampshire PO1 3AH
United Kingdom
Tel: +44(0)2392 842918
Fax: +44(0)2392 842913
Email: Victoria.Edwards@port.ac.uk
ABSTRACT: Community Based Ecotourism as a Panacea for Protected Areas:
the use of common property theory in its analysis and development
Tourism is the world’s largest employer, accounting for 10% of jobs worldwide
(WTO, 1999). There are over 30,000 protected areas around the world, covering
about 10% of the land surface (IUCN, 2002). Protected area management is moving
towards a more integrated form of management, which recognises the social and
economic needs of the world’s finest areas and seeks to provide long term income
streams and support social cohesion through active but sustainable use of
resources. Ecotourism - ‘responsible travel to natural areas that conserves the
environment and improves the well-being of local people’ – (The Ecotourism Society,
1991) is often cited as a panacea for incorporating the principles of sustainable
development in protected area management. However, few examples exist
worldwide to substantiate this claim. In reality, ecotourism struggles to provide social
and economic empowerment locally and fails to secure proper protection of the local
and global environment. Current analysis of ecotourism provides a useful checklist
of interconnected principles for more successful initiatives, but no overall framework
of analysis or theory. This paper argues that applying common property theory to the
application of ecotourism can help to establish more rigorous, multi-layered analysis
that identifies the institutional demands of community based ecotourism (CBE). The
paper draws on existing literature on ecotourism and several new case studies from
developed and developing countries around the world. It focuses on the governance
of CBE initiatives, particularly the interaction between local stakeholders and
government and the role that third party non-governmental organisations can play in
brokering appropriate institutional arrangements. The paper concludes by offering
future research directions.
1
1.0
INTRODUCTION
Since 2000, tourism has been the world’s largest employer, with more people in the
world employed in the tourist industry than in any other, including agriculture. With
nearly 200 million jobs in total, tourism accounts for some 10% of jobs worldwide
(WTO, 1999) and 11.75% of the world’s GDP.
There are over 30,000 protected areas around the world, covering about 10% of the
land surface (IUCN, 2002). Protected area management is moving towards a more
integrated form of management, which recognises the social and economic needs of
the world’s finest areas and seeks to provide long term income streams and support
social cohesion through active but sustainable use of resources.
Ecotourism - ‘responsible travel to natural areas that conserves the environment
and improves the well-being of local people’ – (The Ecotourism Society) is often
cited as a panacea for incorporating the principles of sustainable development in
protected area management. However, few examples exist worldwide to substantiate
this claim. In reality, ecotourism struggles to provide social and economic
empowerment locally and fails to secure proper protection of the local and global
environment.
Current analysis of ecotourism provides a useful checklist of interconnected
principles for more successful initiatives, but no overall framework of analysis or
theory. Community based ecotourism management refers to ecotourism programs
which take place under the control and with the active participation of the local
people who inhabit or own a natural attraction (Drumm, 1998:198). This paper
argues that applying common property theory to the application of ecotourism can
help to establish more rigorous, multi-layered analysis that identifies the institutional
demands of community based ecotourism (CBE).
The paper draws on existing literature on ecotourism and several new case studies
from developed and developing countries around the world. It focuses on the
governance of CBE initiatives, particularly the interaction between local stakeholders
and government and the role that third party non-governmental organisations can
play in brokering appropriate institutional arrangements. The paper concludes by
offering future research directions.
2.0
THE DEVELOPMENT OF TOURISM MARKETS
2.1
The Growth of Tourism
World tourism grew steadily from the late 1940s with the expansion of a tourist class
in passenger aircraft. The use of the jet engine from 1957 further fuelled mass travel
and the development of wide-bodied, high-speed aeroplanes in the 1970s allowed
for expansion of that market to the developing world. The growth of a more
prosperous society, with greater amounts of leisure time, furthered the development
of tourism as a leading industry. Between 1992 and 1997, international tourist
arrivals grew from 463 million to 594 million: an increase of 30% (WTO, 1999).
Current predications are that international tourism is growing at around 7-8% p.a.
and that international arrivals will be over 1 billion by 2010 (Lindberg et al, 1998).
Figure 1 illustrates the steady growth of tourism arrivals since 1950.
2
Figure 1: Global Tourist Arrivals
800
Arrivals (millions)
700
600
500
400
300
200
100
0
1950
1960
1970
1980
1990
2000
Year
Source: WTO, 1999
In the latter part of the 20th century, the growth in tourism in developing countries
was particularly pronounced. Whilst global tourist arrivals grew by 62% from 1985 to
1994, tourist arrivals to Central America grew by 91%, Africa by 89%, South America
by 86%, and the Caribbean by 71%. Only South Asia, where tourism arrivals grew by
48%, was below the world average. In contrast, East Asia and the Pacific
encountered growth of 142% (WTO, 1995). In addition, there has been a sharp
increase in the amount of domestic tourism taking place around the world, especially
in South East Asia, where growing amounts middle-income earners are keen to
participate in this essential ingredient of professional life.
2.2
The Costs of Tourism
Around the world, governments keen to earn foreign exchange and to see economic
development have encouraged the growth of tourism through policies that include
infrastructure development, subsidies and incentive packages. Resort development
supplies a market that is essentially still geared to pre-paid package experiences.
Such mass tourism became synonymous with the four S’s – sun, sea, sand and sex
– and mass tourists with the stereotypes that accompanied such an image.
Although countries originally embraced mass tourism as a ‘clean’ industry, many
soon realised that there were external costs associated with that industry. These
came in the form of environmental degradation, cultural conflict and social impacts.
Environmental degradation can include direct loss of habitat and wildlife through
development and tourist intervention (Budowski, 1976; Crittendon, 1975; Cohen,
1978), but also breakdown of local water and sewage supplies, air and water
3
pollution (Young, 1973; Goldsmith, 1974), and changes in local farming practices,
and hence landscapes, to supply the tourist market.
Cultural conflicts have involved the introduction of drugs & alcohol to cultures
previously not dependent on such substances, and the social and cultural
breakdown of communities associated with excessive use and trade in them. Simple
cultural disturbances, such as conflict over introduced language, mannerisms,
expressions, beliefs and dress, are also cited by host populations as significant
consequences of tourism (Mathieson & Wall, 1982). More serious consequences,
however, include prostitution (Shaw & Williams, 1997) and the packaging of arts and
crafts for the souvenir trade and music and dance for tourism amusement. Such and
‘commodification’ of culture can ultimately erode the value and authenticity of
products and services (Britton, 1977). Social Impacts include (i) the displacement of
local people from tourism destinations to the periphery of new development; (ii)
increased pressures on infrastructure, particularly water supplies, resulting in
increased costs of provision; and (iii) the realisation that employment benefits of
tourism were often seasonal and involved low paid, manual work (see, for example,
Britton, 1982; Krippendorf, 1987; Altman, 1989; Lea, 1988; Truong, 1991; Butler,
1991; Ryan, 1991).
As if unexpected ‘external’ costs weren’t enough to disappoint countries that had
raced to develop their tourism markets, most also came to realise that the expected
benefits of tourism were less widely dispersed than anticipated. Tourism ‘leakage’
soon became a recognised problem, whereby as much as 80% of the tourism spend
in a particular location soon ‘leaked’ out of the host country, often back to the
tourists’ own country (Getz, 1990; Goodwin, 1995). This happens as a result of
many of the products and services being provided by companies based outside the
host nation and purchasing only minimal products and services from providers in the
host nation. Leakage tends to be highest in less developed countries and island
economies, because of the need to buy in more products and services and also
because management control of the industry lies in the hands of external, multinational interests. In such cases, even if businesses such as car hire and restaurants
spend some of their revenue locally when paying staff and buying basic food
products, etc., profits will disappear outside the host country (Pattullo, 1996).
Dissatisfaction with tourism, and disappointment in its ability to deliver, led to the
Manila Declaration on World Tourism in 1980:
“Tourism does more harm than good to people and to societies in the Third
World.” (Nicholson-Lord, 1997:12).
Both tourism leaders and increasingly sophisticated tourists soon looked for
alternatives to mass tourism.
2.3
Tourism Planning
Realisation of the unintended costs of tourism development led to calls for tighter
planning of tourism and control over its destiny (Inskeep, 1991 Dowling, 1993; Elliot,
1994; Gunn, 1994). Table 1 shows the application of post-Fordisti consumption
patterns to tourism (Lash & Urry, 1994:274) and in particular, points to the demand
for independent holidays and to the use of environmental planning and control of
tourism in providing ‘alternatives’ to mass tourism.
4
Table 1
Post-Fordism and Tourism
Consumers increasingly dominant and
producers have to be much more
consumer-orientated
Rejection of certain forms of mass tourism (holiday
camp & cheaper packaged holidays) and increased
diversity of preferences
Greater volatility of consumer preference
Fewer repeat visits and the proliferation of alternative
sites and attractions
Increased market segmentation
multiplication of types of holiday and visitor
attractions based on lifestyle research
Growth of consumers’ movement
Much more information provided about alternative
holidays and attractions through the media
Development of many new products,
each of which has a shorter life
Rapid turnover of tourist sites and experiences
because of fashion changes
Increased preferences expressed for
non-mass forms of
production/consumption
Growth of ‘green tourism’ and of forms of refreshment
and accommodation which are individually tailored to
the consumer (such as country house hotels)
Consumption less and less ‘functional’
and increasingly aestheticised
De-differentiation of tourism from leisure, culture,
retailing education, sport, hobbies
Source: Lash & Urry, 1994:274, cited in Mowforth & Munt, 1998:27
Nevertheless, such approaches have not been without criticism. Burns (2004:25)
argues that planning often overlooks the distribution of benefits amongst the local
community in much the same way as they are overlooked by market-lead
development:
“To be quite blunt, the one-shot, big-bang masterplan alluded to above, is
driven not so much by the economic and social needs of the destination as by
the structure of technical assistance. The unintentional result has been the
marginalization of those who most aid agencies claim are their target
beneficiaries (the poor, female-headed households, demobilizing combatants
following civil or war strife, women, children, and other rural dwellers).”
Perhaps what was needed was as a smaller scale approach to tourism, one that
focused at the local level and approached tourism development in an ‘alternative
form’?
3.0
ECOTOURISM AS A PANACEA
Governments aspiring to improve the economic, social and cultural conditions of a
community have looked to new forms of ‘alternative’ tourism to further such
conditions. ‘Ecotourism’ is one such alternative form of tourism. Fennell provides
evidence that ecotourism was viable long before the 1980s “in practice, if not in
name.” (Fennell, 1999:32). Nevertheless, it was the 1980s that saw ecotourism
emerge as a panacea to mass tourism problems.
There is a plethora of definitions and interpretations of ecotourism. Proponents of
ecotourism have failed to reach a consensus on the principles and frameworks that
should underpin this concept. Often cited is the International Ecotourism Society’s
5
definition of "responsible travel to natural areas, which conserves the environment
and sustains the well-being of local people."
Much as there is little consensus over the definition of ecotourism, there is little
conformity of statistical estimates as to its size. In the late 1980s, the Americanbased Speciality Travel Index suggested that ecotourism accounted for between
1.5% and 2.5% of al tourism (Whelan, 1991). However, according to the World
Tourism Organisation (WTO, 1996), ecotourism is the fastest growing niche market
in the tourism industry, with an annual growth rate of 5%. Whereas, The World
Resources Institute (1993) found that while tourism overall has been growing at an
annual rate of 4%, nature travel is increasing at an annual rate between 10% and
30% (Reingold, 1993). Some estimates suggest that 20% of all international tourists
are in some way involved in ‘ecotourism’ (Dowling & Charters, 2000) and The
Ecotourism Society (1998) cited sources suggesting 20-40% of all international
tourists travel for wildlife-related purposes. There is agreement, however, that
growth has been fuelled by the increasing number of people interested in wildlife
watching and the increasing demand for more experiential vacations. For example,
the Travel Data Centre reported that 43 million US adults took a nature-based
related visit between 1992 and 1994 (cited in Honey, 1999).
3.1
Ecotourism in Protected Areas
There are over 33,000 protected areas around the world, covering about 10% of the
land surface (Eagles, 2002). Protected area management is moving towards a more
integrated form of management, which recognises the social and economic needs of
the world’s finest areas and seeks to provide long term income streams and support
social cohesion through active but sustainable use of resources. National Parks are
often seen as the top tier of protected area designation and, consequently, act as a
tourism magnet. National Parks have traditionally held a close relationship with
tourism and it is generally recognised that that relationship is now being tested to the
limit (Boyd & Butler, 2000).
Many developing countries are embracing ecotourism because of its apparent
environment-conscious parameters, as well as achieving above average economic
performance. In addition, the World Conservation Monitoring Centre (1992) has
pointed out that “species richness increases with decreasing latitude and over half of
the species of animals in the entire world are in the rainforests of developing
countries.” The World Wildlife Fund for Nature says that 20% of revenue generated
from tourism in developing countries is due to ecotourism.
It has been widely recognised that ecotourism can help nature conservation of
natural resources and generate income and employment for the local residents of an
ecotourism destination (Wallace & Pierce, 1986; Ceballos-Lascurain, 1996; Honey,
1999, TIES, 2004). Whereas tourism research acknowledges the negative social,
economic and environmental effects of tourism development, ecotourism is praised
for its positive effects, with many arguing that it is the only true form of sustainable
tourism and that it provides an economic rationale to promote natural resource
conservation and wildlife protection policies. For example, in Kenya, the ‘visitor
attraction’ value of a single lion has been estimated at US$27,000 annually, with a
herd of elephants valued at US$610,000 (Lindberg, 1991). The Kenyan Wildlife
Service estimates that more than 90% of tourists visit a game park, and eight out of
6
ten visitors cite ‘nature and wildlife’ as their major reason for visiting Kenya. By
1990, wildlife based tourism was earning $480 million annually, or 43% of Kenya’s
total foreign exchange (Honey, 1999). Similarly, ecotourism has been used to justify
the protection of entire ecosystems. For example, the economic benefits of
rainforest ecotourism are often used as arguments to limit the extraction of timber
from the forest: as case of where the forest is worth more than the trees.
Forms of revenue from ecotourism might include: entrance, licence and permit fees
(‘user’ fees); admission to specific facilities (such as lavatories or camp sites); user
fees associated with goods and services (such as tent hire); sales and concessions
(including the profit from direct sales of souvenirs, lodgings, food sales, etc.); fees
from concessionaries selling such goods and services; and revenues from logos and
trademarks (Page & Dowling, 2002:167-8). However, critics of ecotourism have
provided evidence that whilst ecotourism has the potential to generate considerable
economic benefits, a large proportion of the money tends to be spent on travel to the
destination, with relatively little spent on site (Wall, 1994; Honey, 1999). Lindberg
(1998) suggests that a common priority in ecotourism is to increase local economic
benefits and questions the extent to which this has been achieved. Burns (2004:25)
comments that cries to leave only footprints “carry an ironic and unintentional truth.”
“The eco-centric, ultra-cautious approach of ecotourism will protect the
environment but fail to produce economic benefit to all but a handful.” (Burns,
2004:24).
Others are even more critical of the eco-tourists themselves, and their egoenhancing needs (Wheeller, 1993, Munt, 1994). Gordon (1990) refers to them as
“an emergent, urban-based, alienated petit bourgeoisie.”
Further research on tourism in protected areas has focused on the nature and
experiences of the tourist (Obua & Harding, 1996; Deng et al, 2002); the economic,
social and environmental impacts of tourism (Lindberg et al, 1996; Lindberg &
McKercher, 1997; Ross & Wall, 1999: Adams & Infield, 2003; Mbaiwa, 2003); and
the need for planning for tourism in protected areas (Agardy, 1993). Edwards (1997)
stresses the importance of regarding ecotourism as a process rather than a product
and provides a prescriptive definition that incorporates five essential elements of any
ecotourism project, making up the acronym ‘MECCA’: monitoring; education;
conservation; community involvement; and advocacy (of environmental
conservation).
3.2
Community Based Ecotourism (CBE)
Ecotourism that contributes to environmental and cultural conservation, is managed
and owned by local communities, and where the profits go back to the community is
now sought. Coined as ‘ Community based ecotourism (CBE)’, this type of
ecotourism is seen as a development resource, bringing wider benefits to the
community and their environment, and fostering empowerment.
According to Tourism Concernii, community tourism should:1. be run with the involvement and consent of local communities;
2. give a fair share of profits back to the local community;
3. involve communities rather than individuals;
4. be environmentally sustainable;
5. respect traditional culture and social structures;
7
6. have mechanisms to help communities cope with the impacts of Western
tourists;
7. keep groups small to minimise cultural/environmental impact;
8. brief tourists before the trip on appropriate behaviour;
9. not make local people perform inappropriate ceremonies;
10. leave communities alone if they do not want tourism (Page & Dowling,
2002:245).
Communities have been encouraged to establish their own ecotourism projects.
Drumm (1998) provides a spectrum of community based tourism opportunities,
summarised in Table 2, of which true CBE is seen as the ultimate state of “operating
fully independent community tourism programmes.”
Table 2: Spectrum of Community Tourism Opportunities
Renting land to an operator to develop while simply monitoring progress
Working as occasional, part or full-time staff for outside operators
Providing selected services such as food preparation, guiding, transport or accommodation (or a
combination of several or all of these) to operators
Forming joint ventures with outside operators with a division of labour, which allows the
community to provide most services, while the operator takes care of marketing
Operating fully independent community tourism programmes
Source: Drumm, 1998:201
Duperly-Pinks (2002:151) defines empowerment as:
“not something that is bestowed on an individual, it is a psychological
construct that is developed through a process of being……..it is enabling
progress, for an individual or collective, towards the perception of control over
one’s life and issues relating to it.”
Scheyvens (2002) identifies four types of empowerment that ecotourism can bring to
communities: economic, psychological, social and political.iii The need to involve
local communities in all stages of tourism development is widely accepted. CBE is
thought to
“empower local communities by giving them a sense of pride in and
awareness of the importance of their natural resources and control over their
own development.” (Wearing & Larsen, 1996:13).
3.3
Problems with CBE
In theory, CBE can transform the quality of life of communities, by bringing sources
of income and a renewed pride in the natural and cultural heritage of an area. In 50
case studies written up by the World Tourism Organisation (WTO, 2000:11), four
major factors were identified as having contributed to the success of the
8
sustainability of the projects. ‘Local Community involvement in the planning,
development and management of the projects’ was seen as the most critical factor,
with 40% of case studies citing it as specifically relevant in determining successiv.
In reality, however, many schemes are conceived as a top-down initiative, with
benefits concentrated on few community members, with little concept of community
ownership (MacKinnon, 1995). The key is to achieve full integration of the CBE
within the community, with widespread participation from the start. However,
participation in CBE projects is highly varied, particularly in developing countries.
Tourism involves processes that are constructed out of complex and varied social
realities and relations, which are often hierarchical and unequal. Mitchell (2001)
states that ideally, a community involved in ecotourism would have a broad based
and open democratic structure, an equitable and efficient decision making process
and a high amount of local ownership. However, to assume that all members of a
community will have equitable access to involvement in tourism development and
the benefits it can bring may be a simplistic and idealistic notion (Taylor, 1995). In
reality, the economic benefits and political power in a community are likely to be
influenced by a complex interplay of age, class, ethnic affiliation and gender, and
certain individuals or families are likely to have more privileges than others because
of their apparent status. Research suggests that local elites become wealthier as
they have more power and confidence to deal with outsiders and ensure that
development opportunities offer specific benefits for themselves and their families.
Local elitism might be gender based. For example, Hitchcock & Brandenburgh
(1990) demonstrate how adult, multi-lingual males making up part of an indigenous
group in the Kalahari are more likely to benefit financially from tourism enterprises
than other members of the community. Stonich et al (1995) report how tourism
development has enhanced existing social inequalities in the Bay of Islands,
Honduras. Mowforth & Munt (1998) show how local elitism not only secures greater
financial benefits of tourism, but also political influence.
Tosun (2000:618) asserts that one of the major obstacles for participation in
developing countries is the centralisation of public administration in tourism
development.
Formulation and implementation of any kind of community
participation requires decentralisation of the political, administrative and financial
powers of the central government.
4.0
THE RELEVANCE OF COMMON PROPERTY RESOURCE (CPR) THEORY
4.1
The need for theory
Explanatory models of tourism development can largely be grouped into three
categories: “those which explain the tourist’s motivation, those which explain the role
of the tourist industry, and those which explain the development of the destination
community.” (Mowforth & Munt, 1998:85).
Some models attempt to explain the relationship between the industry and the
destination, such as Butler’s Product Life Cycle Model (Butler, 1980), and others,
such as Murphy’s identification of three crucial growth factors (motivation, ability and
9
mobility) explain the evolution of tourism (Murphy, 1995). In summarising the major
features of studies in tourism, Mowforth and Munt (1998:88) comment that:
“it is striking how few concepts there actually are in the tourism debate and
the hold that these ideas have retained in directing subsequent research. Many of
them are endlessly repeated or contested in case study material.”
They identify only four main areas of analysis:• Structure of the tourism industry (e.g. Wall, 1982; Shaw & Williams, 1994; and
Burns & Holden, 1995)
• Impacts of tourism development (e.g. Lea, 1988; Pearce, 1995)
• Models of tourism development (e.g. Doxey, 1976; Butler, 1980), including
blueprints for more ‘appropriate’ development (e.g. Whelan, 1991, Lindberg &
Hawkins, 1993)
• Tourist typologies and motivational characteristics (e.g. Cohen, 1979; Smith,
1989).
It is generally accepted that new policy approaches are needed in tourism, but there
has been little work on role models or operational frameworks to provide evidence of
how this might manifest itself at ground level. In particular, few address the
institutional arrangements governing tourism, with their related power structures.
Burns (2004) criticises the dichotomy of “left versus right” approaches to tourism
planning characterized by the free market on the one hand and “central master
planning” on the other. He suggests a ‘third way’, based on Gidden’s proposal of
transcending “both old-style social democracy and neoliberalism” (Giddens, 1998:26).
In the past, similar criticism has been voiced in the natural resource management
world, where polarized policy analysis often ignored the importance of institutions.
Just as some authors assumed that government provision offers a panacea to the
problem of supply of collective goods, so others, offering market solutions, ignored the
problems of establishing and maintaining a well-functioning market.
4.2
Common Property Resource (CPR) Theory
CPR theory has traditionally recognised the importance of analysing institutional
arrangements governing natural resource decisions (Bromley, 1985; Ostrom, 1990;
Feeny, 1988). Whilst current analysis of CBE provides a useful checklist of
interconnected principles for more successful initiatives, there is no overall
framework of analysis or theory. Applying CPR theory to the application of
ecotourism can help to establish more rigorous, multi-layered analysis that identifies
the institutional demands of community based ecotourism (CBE).
Ecosystems that support nature based tourism initiatives can be likened to a common
pool resource, where several resource ‘users’ might draw from the resource (Healy,
1994). Common pool resources are characterized by being ‘non-exclusive’ (where it
is impossible, or at least very costly, to exclude additional users) and ‘rival’,
(consumption by one user reduces the quantity or quality available for other users).
Common reliance on the ecosystem does not necessarily result in cooperation
between the users in conserving the resource. Indeed, Hardin's 'Tragedy of the
commons' (1968) has become a strong symbol of the problems of common pool
resources. Implicit in Hardin's theory is an assumption that when a natural resource is
physically and legally accessible to multiple users, the result will be a ‘free for all’, with
10
users competing with one another for a greater share of the resource to the eventual
depletion in the quality and/or quantity available of the resource. There is plenty of
evidence from the tourism literature of such environmental degradation, from all
corners of the globe (see, for example, Edington & Edington, 1986; Mathieon & Wall,
1982; Hunter & Green, 1995; Mieczkowski, 1995; Monbiot, 1994; Pattullo, 1996;
Holden, 2000; Honey 1999).
However, absent from Hardin's theory is the recognition that individuals can, and
indeed do, design and enforce rules which govern their individual and collective
choices and can minimise such degradation. Whilst it is recognized in natural
resource management that it is exactly these decision-making arrangements that are
crucial for the sustainable management of common pool resources, little attention has
been paid to them in the tourism literature.
In ‘pure’ common property situations, the rights to the resource will be shared coequally and are exclusive to a well-defined set of people (Singh, 1994)v. However, the
ecosystem that supports a tourism destination may be used variously in common,
without comprising pure common property, but comprise a mixture of rights, including
public and/or private property rights, and where ‘open access’ may be assumed by
some usersvi. Even where complex property rights exist over common pool
resources, and a number of competing users are present, decision making
arrangements (or institutions) can be devised that prevent depletion or degradation of
the resource.
Institutions are defined as
“sets of working rules that are used to determine who is eligible to make
decisions in some area, what actions are allowed or constrained, what
aggregation rules will be used, what procedures must be followed, what
information must or must not be provided, and what payoffs will be assigned to
individuals dependent on their action” (Ostrom, 1986:4).
Thus, the institutions, or decision-making arrangements are usually a constellation of
rights, rules, conventions (informal codes and agreements) and contracts, supported
by an authority structure, which is often vital to their operation and enforcement
(Swallow and Bromley, 1995). Empirical research has shown that the institutions
associated with common property are as diverse as the social, cultural and ecological
context in which they are practiced. However, the prevailing management practices
tend to share the characteristics of respect, responsibility, stewardship and user
participation.
Recognising that factions within a community need to cooperate well in providing a
high quality CBE product and safeguarding the natural environment, Williams (1992,
cited in Fennell, 1999), advocates the development of an institutional structures
approach which encompasses:1. development of a grassroots planning process, driven by local interests and
including aboriginal involvement;
2. understanding and appreciation of ecotourism market requirements;
3. an inventory of the region’s resources to determine areas that are suitable for
ecotourism and ones that are not;
11
4. the establishment of goals and objectives in line with concerns related to the
cultural and natural impacts of ecotourism, with the creation of a vision
statement to act as a control mechanism for the future; and
5. the establishment of a formal Tourism Management Board, to work with both
the operators and the public, with the responsibility of monitoring.
Whilst Williams’ recognition of the importance of institutions is helpful, it is typical of
such approaches that do not provide an insight into how such boards and
committees might be established, who might establish them, what their lines of
authority and accountability might comprise and how decisions might be reached.
Some work has been completed on the link between common property theory and
tourism. Healy (1994) addresses the “common pool problem” in tourism landscapes,
suggesting that, as common pool resources, landscapes that provide a ‘background
tourism element’ are characterized by (i) a susceptibility to overuse and (ii) resource
damage by a lack of incentive for productivity-enhancing investment because of the
potential for ‘free-riding’. He suggests that common property regimes, involving
community control or reciprocal actions among individuals, whilst appearing to be the
least common arrangement for managing such resources, clearly have potential for
addressing common pool tourism problems. However, he concludes that:
“Further research is needed to evaluate the effectiveness of alternative
mixtures of property rights regimes in different settings, including determining
which tourism resources are suitable to common property arrangements, in
comparison to those best managed privately or by government.”(Healy,
1994:609).
Sadly, such empirical work has not been followed up. Although, more recently,
Huybers and Bennett (2003) apply CPR theories of cooperation and literature on
regional cluster to suppose that inter-firm environmental cooperation at nature based
tourism destinations might be expected to materialize. Using empirical evidence from
Tropical north Queensland, they assert that;
“A self-regulatory governance regime, based on strong internal institutions
complemented by informal monitoring and enforcement, can be particularly
effective at nature-based tourism destinations.” (Huybers and Bennett,
2003:585).
In both cases, the authors use useful concepts that form part of CPR theory to help
analyse tourism scenarios and suggest future institutional arrangements. However,
neither applies the full range of CPR theory and neither focuses on community based
ecotourism. Below, I attempt to extract more use from CPR theory by explaining
explicitly why it might aid in the analysis of CBE.
4.3
Applying CPR Theory to CBE
When examining CBE, it is important to examine its success or failure from an
institutional perspective. It is suggested here that an analytical framework developed
for the study of complex, multiple-use common property resources systems can be
particularly useful in assisting such analysis. The framework is presented in Figure
2.
12
Figure 2: Analytical Framework for Applying CPR Theory to Community Based
Ecotourism
Source: Adapted from Edwards & Steins, 1998
Although all separate elements of the framework are important, it is ultimately their
relationship to the institutional arrangements that holds the key to analysing the
effective working of a CBE initiative. The institutional arrangements governing the
CBE initiative must be devised and revised in ways that take full account of the
characteristics of the other elements. Each element it explained in turn, below. In
each explanation, the relationship between the element examined and the governing
institutional arrangements is highlighted.
Physical Characteristics of the Environment
First, it is important to understand the characteristics of the environment (built and
natural) upon which the CBE is based and the nature in which it can be used to
support tourism. There might be specific elements of the ecosystem (in particular,
individual species), which are crucial to delivery of a tourism ‘product’. For example,
in the coastal town of Kaikoura, New Zealand, the presence of sperm whales is
essential to the marketing of the town as an ecotourism destination. Although other
marine mammals, such as grey seals, dolphins and other whales, help add to the
tourism attraction, it is the sperm whales’ profile that draws tourists from all corners
of the world (Edwards, 1996).
A sound understanding of the physical characteristics of individual species and the
environment as a whole is essential in being able to devise and maintain useful
13
institutional arrangements to ensure their long term sustainability. For example,
knowledge of the effects that human interactions can have on the wellbeing of the
marine mammals has enabled the Department of Conservation in New Zealand to
draw up a set of regulations governing such interaction and setting limits on, for
example, the nearness of approach of humans, direction of approach, noise limits,
etc. in order to minimise disturbance (see below).
The environment might be evaluated according to the extent to which (i) it is
attractive to nature-based tourists; (ii) it is accessible to tourists; (iii) it can meet the
infrastructure demands of tourists; (iv) the access and behaviour of tourists can be
controlled; and (v) one tourist’s enjoyment will impinge on another. These are
summarised in Table 3.
Additional information is needed about the environment as a whole and its
susceptibility to damage, by both tourists and other uses. In particular, the CBE
must be able, through full control or through cooperation and integration of governing
institutions, to secure compatibility between competing uses for the ecosystem. For
example, a CBE initiative in an area where hunting is permitted (fee hunting or local
hunting for food) must be able to integrate design of institutional arrangements
between the separate uses of the ecosystem, to ensure that the wildlife is hunted
within sustainable limits and to ensure tourists’ safety when visiting the area.
Similarly, where local farming practices might change water supplies (in quantity or
quality) in ways that will adversely affect the environment, the external costs must be
internalised into the institutional arrangements. Appreciation of the relationships
between different environmental uses is, therefore, an essential starting point for any
CBE initiative.
Table 3 Evaluation of the Environment for CBE
Attractiveness
Accessibility
Adaptability
Control
Subtractability
What can the environment offer nature-based tourists? For example:• High profile species
• Endemic species
• Aesthetic scenery
• Unique Cultural landscape
Is the environment easily accessible to tourists? Is appropriate transport
available? For example:• Restricted, mountainous region
• Fragile coastline
• Unstable strata (dunes, marshes)
Can infrastructure demands of the CBE be accommodated? For example:• Appropriate accommodation
• Food and water availability
Can the access and behaviour of tourists be controlled? For example:• physical restrictions & exclusion zones
• awareness raising
• guiding access
• visitor codes
Will one tourist’s enjoyment impinge on another? Is alleviation of impacts
possible through, for example:-• density of different uses
• changing physical conditions of ecosystem
• techniques to help reduce impact, such as habitat restoration
Source: Edwards, 1997
14
User Characteristics
The environment that supports a CBE initiative is likely to be used in multiple ways
by different types of users. Thus, a rainforest supporting a CBE might also be used
for logging, plant collection and hunting. It is important that there is a full
appreciation of the different stakeholders deriving benefit from the ecosystem and
their particular characteristics and dependency on it. In particular, we are interested
in the extent to which the community is likely to cooperate in furthering shared
benefits to be derived from tourism and the protection of the environment.
In a CPR scenario, collective action will typically occur if local stakeholders seek to
overcome the problems associated with the ‘the tragedy of open access’, and agree
on decision-making arrangements to control access to, allocation of and control over
the CPR, converting it into a common property regime. Consequently, the problem
facing its user groups is that of organizing in order to supply and maintain institutions
(Ostrom 1990). Huybers & Bennett (2003) identify seven factors that enhance the
success of environmental cooperation and self-regulation for tourism: (Table 4).
Table 4
Conditions for Successful Tourism Collective Action
1
Size of the group (.i.e. the smaller the number of resource users);
2
Frequency of interactive relationships between group members
3
Durability of interactive relationships between group members;
4
Degree of homogeneity of group members;
5
Capacity of members to learn;
6
Extent to which the product ‘sold’ by group members is dependent on the
environmental resource shared;
8
Geographical size of the shared resource (smaller being more likely to enhance
cooperation.
Source: Huybers & Bennett (2003)
Institutional Arrangements
Institutional arrangements establish rules and provide incentives that influence the
decisions of individuals, organisations and public agencies. Rules can occur at
different levels of decision-making. Three levels of analysis can be distinguished
(Kiser & Ostrom, 1982):1. Policy Level – considers institutions external to the local community and may
include appropriate statutes and national policy on tourism and/or resource
management. They facilitate the development of an ecotourism policy for a
nation state and establish the framework in which collective choice decisions
will be made.
2. Collective-Choice Level – considers interactions between the collective
decision-makers. Rules at this level are derived from the policy level and may
15
include industry regulations and codes of practice. They form the framework
for ecotourism planning in a particular region or locality.
3. Operational Level – considers interactions between resource users. Rules at
this level are derived from the Collective-choice level and are designed to
ensure the proper use of the shared ecosystem. They form the basic codes
of practice for ecotourism operators.
The operational rules are made within the regulatory framework at the organizational
level, which in turn is determined by legislation at the policy level. In other words, the
decision-making arrangements at different levels are ‘nested’: change at one level is
the result of patterns of interactions at another level. At all three levels, authority
structures are present that “sanction rights, enforce rules, and define the contexts in
which conventions and contracts are negotiated” (Swallow and Bromley 1995: 109).
Decision making arenas at the different institutional levels are considered to be vital
to the operation of decision-making. Arenas involved in the management of the
commons are essentially ‘platforms’ for resource use negotiation. Platforms are
defined as;
a negotiating and/or decision-making body (voluntary or statutory),
comprising different stakeholders who perceive the same resource
management problem, realize their interdependence in solving it, and
come together to agree on action strategies for solving the problem
(Röling 1994; Maarleveld et al, 1996).
Whilst some authors criticise the frequent ‘top-down’ approach to tourism employed
through central government planning in many countries (Woods, 1996; Olindo, 1991;
Burns, 2002), others are critical of the piecemeal, ‘market’, fashion in which
ecotourism in many countries has developed, often in response to the need for
alternative sources of income in remote, rural communities.
Proper design of institutional arrangements, at the operational, collective-choice and
policy levels and, in particular, integration of the existing rules between different
stakeholders at each level and between levels is needed. Development of this
approach demands the cooperation of government (at central, regional and local
level), industry (both private sector organisations and individuals and the voluntary
sector) and local communities.
policy level
The establishment of CBEs depends on consistent and supportive policies at the
regional and national level. Partnerships are unlikely to be formed without the
construction of a shared ecotourism vision that establishes the extent to which a
country wants to develop tourism within sustainable limits. Second, policy makers
must devise appropriate institutional frameworks within which the tourism industry
can operate. However, the ultimate efficacy of CBE rests in its implementation and
hence complementary collective action at the collective choice and operational
levels. Many examples exist of well designed and laudable national tourism policies,
which fail to secure stated objectives due to poor implementation (see, for example a
commentary on Botswana in Edwards, 1997).
16
collective choice level
The collective choice level can help establish appropriate decision-making platforms
for the local community, to facilitate the development and management of
ecotourism markets. Such platforms should provide access for all members of the
community to participate in decision making over the resource base and tourism
development. They should be based on existing arenas and learn from the
successes and failures of traditional CPR platforms; particularly the failures.
Frequently, ecotourism is sought to diversify income sources in areas where a
reliance on primary based industries such as farming, forestry and fishing have
failed. In such cases, where the industry has been based on a common pool
resource, much can be learned to inform the future development of tourism. For
example, was failure the result of a breakdown in the institutions governing the
resource base or in a failure for the institutions to cope with external influences over
the resource base or the marketing of its products? For example, many whale
watching locations around the world have emerged in areas where the local fishery
has declined due to over fishing and lack of appropriate institutions to prevent
resource depletion. In such cases, the lessons to be learned from the management
of the fishery can be valuable in informing the newly evolving ecotourism industry on
how to collectively manage the whales as a common pool resource.
operational level
Individual ecotourism operators must act collectively to ensure the proper use of
shared resources at the operational level. This might involve the enforcement of
locally designed and self-determined rules. The establishment and operation of
reliable monitoring procedures might be one of the most valuable tasks to be
achieved by partnerships that integrate public and private sector interests. Much can
be achieved by self-regulation and enforcement (informal monitoring of ecotourism
operators by ecotourism operators), but such can approach can only work if it is
based on clearly publicised and widely accepted codes and regulations. The
acceptance of practice codes is more likely if they are devised at the collectivechoice level, where the ecotourism operators have an opportunity to participate in
their creation, rather than imposed by some higher authority.
The higher authority
might, however, play an important role in the enforcement of appropriate sanctions
on violations of the codes. One such code has been devised for marine mammal
watching in New Zealand. All marine mammals are fully protected under the Marine
Mammals Protection Act 1978. However, in 1990, the Department of Conservation
introduced regulations specifically for the control and management of marine
mammal watching.
The regulations are monitored and enforced by casual
observers, acting on behalf of the Department. In addition, there is an element of
self-regulation, with operators gently reinforcing the regulations amongst themselves
through observation of each other’s practices and subsequent peer pressure.
Part of the analysis of existing institutions at the operational level should focus on the
rights attached to individual species or parts of the ecosystem underpinning the CBE
initiative. In the case of the sperm whales in New Zealand, they were considered an
‘open access’ resource for many years and ‘supported’ an important hunting
economy. Nowadays, the whales are considered a common property resource, to
be enjoyed by the whole community and tourists alike. However, some exclusivity of
right has been assigned to them through the issuing of permits to view the whales.
17
Only one company (Whalewatch) holds the licence (issued by the Department of
Conservation) to take tourists by boat to view the whales.
While competition amongst ecotourism operators may improve standards and
ensure the delivery of a quality service, too much competition can lead to pricecutting that gradually erodes the gross margin of each trip. Inevitably, operators
forced into a price-cutting situation are persuaded to offer a lower quality service
and/or cut costs by some means in order to retain profitability. Such price-cutting
destabilises a small industry and is inconsistent with the long term objectives of
sustainable development, by encouraging cost reductions that might result in action
that is detrimental to the environment or the client’s safety. For example, some
swimming-with-dolphins operators in Kaikoura began to offer refunds when clients
did not enjoy a good experience. Such practice, while providing a competitive
advantage, might encourage operators to relentlessly pursue dolphin pods in
sometimes unsuitable situations (such as pods swimming with young dolphins or in
sleep patterns) in order to avoid the refund demands from customers.
Market mechanisms have their place in the development of an economically
sustainable ecotourism industry. However, market expectations for the ecotourism
industry must be tempered with the reality of the need for regulations to protect
common interests and internalise external costs.
Individual Strategies and Patterns of Interaction
Given particular situational variables (physical and technological characteristics of the
resource and institutional arrangements), individuals make choices from sets of
different possible strategies in relation to the common pool resource and to one
another. Some pattern of interaction emerges from such choices, which then results
in a certain outcome of resource management. In determining the motivations,
values and norms of different user groups, the analyst must appreciate the effect that
local influences have made on individuals’ strategies, including, inter alia:
1. knowledge of the opportunity cost of selecting certain strategies. For example
the presence of 'better value' choices (see Galjart, 1992);
2. existing knowledge. For example, about the array of different decision-making
possibilities;
3. past experiences. For example, successful collective action in the past will
have a positive influence on collective decision-making (see Steins, 1995);
4. normative behavioural and cultural codes. For example, a community
characterized by multi-stranded relationships may perceive difficulties in
acting collectively (see Steins, 1995).
In addition to the interdependence of the actions at the collective management level
and the users' everyday environment, the behavior of individuals involved in the CBE
is interdependent: that is, observations and expectations of how others behave will
affect the strategies of individuals (Runge, 1981). In the evaluation of others'
behavior, users will use social experience gained from their involvement in the
common, as well as experience from everyday life.
Outcomes & Monitoring
The individual strategies of those involved in the CBE initiative will result in patterns of
interaction, eventually leading to outcomesvii. These might be measured in economic,
18
social and environmental terms. Several criteria can be employed to evaluate the
outcomes of collective behavior. Oakerson (1992) suggests the adoption of 'efficiency'
and 'equity' as appropriate. Ostrom et al. (1995: 36) suggest that the key question to
be addressed is ‘how do predicted outcomes conform to evaluative criteria?viii’
The presence of a well-established set of institutional arrangements is not enough to
guarantee sustained collective action in the long term. Empirical research into the
management of CPRs has identified a number of design principles underlying
collective action in such scenarios (Table 5). These might equally be applied to CBE
initiatives. Where undesirable or disappointing outcomes are encountered, the
governing institutions should be capable of redesigning rules
Table 5 Determinants of Collective Action in CPR Situations
Source
Principles
Wade, 1988
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
6.
Ostrom, 1990
1. clearly defined boundaries
2. congruence between allocation and access rules and local conditions
3. users’ ability to modify the operational rules through collective-choice
arrangements
4. monitoring of management systems
5. graduated sanctions
6. conflict resolution mechanisms; and
7. management rights of resource users are not challenged by external agents.
Pinkerton &
Weinstein,
1995
1.
2.
3.
4.
the nature of the resource
the costs of exclusion
the relationship between resources and user groups
the characteristics of the user group
noticeability of cheating; and
the relationship between users and the state.
accountability
effectiveness
representativeness; and
adaptability
Source: Steins & Edwards, 1999
4.4
Application of CPR Theory to CBE in the Dominican Republic
This section uses the illustration of two case studies in the Dominican Republic to
demonstrate how the institutional development of CBE projects can help determine
their success. The research was conducted by Rachel Clelland as part of a masters
thesis at the University of Portsmouth in 2003 and can be read in full (Clelland,
2003).
El Salto de Limon
El Salto de Limon (the waterfall of Limon) is one of few recognised and established
community tourism projects in the Dominican Republic.ix Before the initiation of the
project, the environmental condition of the waterfall and surrounding areas was
deteriorating due to erosion, indiscriminate fishing and deforestation. A local NGO,
CEBSE (the Centre for the Conservation and Eco-Development of Samana Bay and
its Surroundings) decided to intervene and, with the help of the German
19
development NGO, DED (Deutsche Entwicklungs Dienst), SECTUR (the Ministry of
Tourism) and several other government agencies, helped the surrounding
communities of Arroyo Surbido, El Rancho Espanol, Lona de la Cruz, and El Café
organise their own sustainable community tourism project.
A community
organisation and association of ecotourism providers, ASECAL (Asociacion
Comunitario de Ecotourismo del Salto del Limon) was founded and is now
recognised by the government.
The CBE comprises fourteen separate paradas (micro-enterprises), where tourists
can hire horses and guides, purchase refreshments, handicrafts and local produce.
Registers are maintained on tourism numbers and show that El Salto received
20,000 visitors in 1998 (CEBSE, 1999). The majority of these are day-trippers who
come to visit the waterfall with an organised tour operator, in groups ranging from 5
to 100. According to CEBSE (2000:5), the following are stakeholders in the CBE
project:Operational Level
• owners of paradas
• owners of horses and mules
• local (untrained/unofficial guides)
• handicraft workers
• touts (‘very’ informal guides)
• local hotel/hostel/pension owners
• tour operators and safari tour companies
Collective Choice Level
Centre for the Conservation and Eco-Development of Samana Bay and its
Surroundings (CEBSE)
Policy Level
Mimistry for Tourism (SECTUR)
The local communities of El Salto feel that they have benefited tremendously from
the CBE project. In the Arroyo Surbido area, of 64 individuals interviewed, 98.2%
interviewed believed the community had improved since ecotourism began and
78.7% agreed “tourism has helped the solidarity of the community” (Holmes, 2003,
cited in Clelland, 2003).
Similar results were obtained in the other local
communities, where 31 interviews revealed that no one identified significant
disadvantages or negative impacts of the CBE project. Respondents believed that
their living conditions had improved as a result of the project, and it had enabled
them to buy modern conveniences, such as washing machines, refrigerators and
televisions.
In terms of non-material benefits, respondents believed that the project had brought
considerable educational benefits to the area, both directly and indirectly.
Environmental awareness locally had been raised and, as a consequence,
deterioration of the waterfall and surrounding area had halted and users of the
waterfall and surrounding neighbours had assumed responsibility for its
conservation. People also believed that they had benefited from learning foreign
languages and that the increased income from the CBE project might enable them to
20
send their children to university. In addition, the local communities were educated,
mostly through the training provision of CEBSE, in the importance of conserving the
environment and using natural resources sustainably and were given advice on
book-keeping, hygiene, and horse husbandry.
Although there is a real sense of empowerment in the community, it is evident that
there was established social cohesion before inception of the CBE project with clear
evidence of social capacity: as one community member said, “Todos ayudan todos”
(everyone helps everyone). The sense of social cohesion is certainly helped by the
presence of the tourism ‘platform’ ASECAL, where everyone has the regular
opportunity for communication and discuss problems and collective strategies.
The distribution of benefits amongst stakeholders is equitable, according to individual
effort and ability, and benefits tend to be widely dispersed amongst all stakeholders.
Perhaps the greatest beneficiaries of the project were the women, who had not
enjoyed such financial independence before and many of whom are now directly
involved in tourism, working as co-owners of paradas, as guides, and as cooks.
Both men and women participate equally in the ASECAL community meeting and
are equally involved in the decision making process, through a democratic voting
procedure of all 230 members. Members ASECAL who are seen to be exploiting the
CBE for their own gain beyond acceptable boundaries are soon pulled into line by
other community members. Although not every community member directly benefits
from tourism, no social or environmental costs of tourism were identified amongst
non-participatory members:
“When questioned ‘but aren’t there tourists who are rude?’, an interviewee
indignantly replied ‘yes, but there are many rude Dominicans too!’ One community
member declared ‘there are no victims here!’ (Clelland, 2003:54)
Parque Nacional Armando Bermudez
The case of Parque Nacional Armando Bermudez is a stark contrast to the El Salto
de Limon CBE project. The national park houses the highest mountain in the
Caribbean, Pico Duarte, at 3,087m above sea level. The park, which was
established in 1956 is attractive to birdwatchers (with populations of Hispaniolan
parrots, woodpeckers and trogons) and attracts visitors from all over the world.
Tourism in the national park began in the 1960s, but did not really take off until the
1980s. The majority of visitors come in tour groups, many of whom are students on
field trips. Although the majority of foreign visitors tend to come as independent
travellers, a minority come in tour groups. A park fee of RD$50 (about US$1) is paid
for the 3 to 7 day stay in the park. Visitors stay in cabanas between daily hikes.
The closest village to the mountain in La Cienega de Manabao, a small community
of 320 families situated just on the outskirts of the park. The residents of La Cienega
live in considerable poverty, with no electricity, little running water and wood fires for
cooking. Although there are two local schools offering primary education, most
community members are only semi-literate. The economy is based on subsistence
agriculture. The majority of the men work in agriculture or for the Ministry of the
Environment in the national park, as guides (around 80), wardens (40-45) or
supervisors (4). The women work at home or in the fields; no women have paid
employment.
21
In terms of benefiting from tourism, interviews revealed that few benefits accrue to
the community of La Cienega. One respondent said that the children benefit,
because tourists take pity on them and give them pens and sweets. The only
opportunities for gaining income from tourism are from paid employment in the
national park service (at minimum wage rates of around RD$2000, or US$40 a
month), renting out mules to tourists (around RD$100, or US$2 per day), or guiding
(RD$200 or US$4 per day). Guides normally only achieve 1 to 20 trips a year, and
so guiding merely supplements agricultural income. Tourism employees were
noticeably better off than their neighbours, with gas cookers and running water,
although no residents had proper bathroom facilities.
The distribution of benefits from tourism were clearly unequal, even amongst those
who were employed as guides: there was no fair rotation of guides, with those who
live nearer the centre of the village or those who had earned favour of the national
park officers tending to be allocated more trips. The community had no tourist
shops, cafes or hostels and was gaining no revenue from tourists passing through
the village to the national park.
The residents of La Cienega felt completely dis-empowered in terms of any
involvement with tourism. All interviewees stated that the government made all of
the decisions related to tourism. At one time the local community had shown interest
in building a managing a community-run hostel for visitors to the national park. They
approached the government for assistance, who promptly built a government-run
hostel just outside the village, within the national park boundary. A local NGO,
Esperanza La Cienega (The New Hope of La Cienega) was established to try to
initiate a CBE project involving a community-run restaurant in the village, but faltered
though lack of resources and knowledge.
The two case studies demonstrate the vital role of collective choice institutions in
engaging community members in CBE projects. The community that was able to
establish credible collective choice platform demonstrated sound social cohesion
before inception of the CBE. However, the ‘successful’ CBE community also
benefited from third party assistance from a local NGO. Similar results were found in
CBE projects in Mexico, where existing social cohesion and the presence of an
NGO, helped to establish a credible CBE co-operative (Foucat, 2002).
5.0
CONCLUSION
An awareness of environmental issues, an urgency to experience the natural
wonders of the world and a need to ‘get back to nature’ are all contributing to growth
in one of the newest forms of tourism travel: ecotourism. In particular, protected
area management is moving towards a more integrated form of management, which
recognises the social and economic needs of the world’s finest areas and seeks to
provide long term income streams and support social cohesion through active but
sustainable use of resources. Ecotourism can provide much needed foreign
exchange and economic rewards to local communities for the conservation of
ecosystems and wildlife. However, ecotourism also threatens to destroy the very
resources on which it depends. Concurrently, communities might find that the ‘trickle
down’ effect of piecemeal ecotourism development disappoints their expectations of
22
increased prosperity while the social and cultural externalities associated with an
influx of tourists might exceed their fears.
Proponents of community-based ecotourism (CBE) claim that it holds the key to
incorporating the principles of sustainable development in protected area
management. So far, this paper has argued that applying common property theory to
the application of ecotourism can help to establish more rigorous, multi-layered
analysis that identifies the institutional demands of community based ecotourism
(CBE). The following sections address the appropriateness of CPR theory and the
extent to which it can be applied to help analyse CBE. The final section concludes
the paper by offering future research directions.
5.1
Advantages of the CPR Approach
There are several distinct advantages of applying CPR theory to CBE analysis. First,
whereas community based tourism research is relatively new, CPR research has
been well established for several decades. As such, CPR theory can provide a
substantial amount of empirical evidence of analysis of CPRs, some of which
comprise active role models in community based resource management with a long
history of success.
Second, CPR focuses on the sustainability of the resource and the resource system:
a concept that is axiomatic to CBE in protected areas, where the goose that lays the
golden egg must be conserved, not just for economic, but also for biodiversity
objectives. Understanding of and knowledge of the resource system must be built
into the governance mechanisms associated with CBE.
Third, CPR analysis focuses on institutions. It has long been recognised in tourism
research that there is a dearth of multi-level analysis of the institutions governing
tourism (Mowforth & Munt, 1998). Finding participatory civil institutions that can be
developed for CBE initiatives is vital. CPR theory provides us with useful information
about social democracy in action and the role of resource management platforms in
negotiation. CPR based systems are highly participatory and build on established
platforms and social institutions. Most analyses criticising CBE initiatives focus on
the lack of social institutions underpinning the programme, but offer little advice on
the establishment of such institutions; other than that establishment is needed! In
developing countries, in particular, CPR institutions might provide the best ‘fit’ for
building ecotourism institutions.
Platforms for resource use negotiation emerge when stakeholders experience the
negative impacts of their own and others’ use of a natural resource and become aware
that these problems require “building human institutions and a capacity for collective
learning and decision-making about the ecosystem perceived to be under threat”
(Röling and Jiggins, 1998). In this light, Ostrom (1995) refers to the creation of
social capital or the arrangement of human resources to improve flows of future
benefits.
A key notion in the literature on platforms is the idea of ‘social learning’ in order to
achieve solutions to natural resource management problems. Social learning is a
form of learning that has emerged from the realization that environmental policy
needs to be designed and implemented in the context of complex interdependent
23
relationships between multiple stakeholders (Glasbergen, 1996). The notion of social
learning is of major importance for collective action processes in the sustainable
management of CBEs. In an industry as dynamic as tourism, the community must
learn to ‘read’ the signs of health and ill-health in their environment, to understand
the conditions of and trends in the environment around them and in the tourism
opportunities around them. The case of La Cienega, above, demonstrates the fate
of a community with no opportunity for learning.
Finally, CPRs are evolutionary in nature, adapting management to changing
contexts. Analysis of the tourism industry reveals a highly dynamic environment
which must constantly adapt to changing demands and social trends, political and
economic climates and other ‘external’ forces, such as terrorism and health scares.
Governance of CBE initiatives can learn from the flexibility of institutions governing
CPRs, specifically the need to monitor outcomes and allow for institutions to evolve
according to new demands.
5.2
Constraints of the CPR Approach
Although CPR theory offers us a useful approach to analysing CBE, it also has
several constraints. First, CPR theory has tended to focus on the appropriation of
resources, where the resource system supplies primary products to a subsistence or
market economy. As such, CPR theory tends to dwell on quantities of stock
produced. Tourism, however, depends on the development of secondary and
tertiary goods and services, where ‘added value’ and quality are the keys to success.
It is vital, therefore, that the monitoring of outcomes from CBE is adapted to take into
account quality demands and the more complex and sophisticated expectations of
the end users.
Second, there is only little evidence of separate CPR communities, especially in the
developing world context, working together. In tourism terms, nearby initiatives might
be seen as competing for tourists. In reality, there is great scope for CBE initiatives
in nearby communities to cooperate and create a wider ecotourism market through
regional, and even national strategies. Third party help will be needed to ensure
integration of local CBE initiatives at regional and national levels. In addition,
tourism is a global industry: national plans can fail because of the power of
multinational providers (such as airlines), making local CBE initiatives particularly
vulnerable. CBE initiatives must find ways to align their programmes with
governments’ national goals and institutions and ensure that central government
agencies properly represent their interests at national levels. This calls for
sophisticated integration between institutional levels and, in particular, well-designed
and effective collective-choice platforms that are capable of making themselves
heard at the policy level. As well as providing tourism platforms, NGOs can play a
vital role as brokers between the operational level of CBEs and the policy level.
Finally, the tourism industry encompasses many different sectors (such as hotels,
transport, visitor attractions, restaurants), providing a highly complex service chain,
where one enterprise cannot be operated in isolation from the others. CBE initiatives
must find ways to integrate the operation of different service sector providers when
devising collective action rules.
24
5.3 Future research directions
This paper has only scratched the surface of applying CPR theory to CBE projects.
In evaluating existing research on CBE projects around the world, it is evident that
the real gaps in analysis lie in a lack of in-depth analysis of the institutional
arrangements governing CBEs, at all three levels, and the integration of decision
making between institutional levels.
In particular, review of the ability of a community to establish effective collective
choice level platforms for resource negotiation and the role that third parties, such as
NGOs, might play in that establishment would seem especially pertinent areas for
future research.
REFERENCES
Adams W. M. & Infield, M. (2003. Who is on the Gorilla’s Payroll? Claims on Tourist
Revenue from a Ugandan National Park, World Development, 31(1):177-90.
Agardy, M. Tundi (1993). Accommodating Ecotourism in Multiple Use Planning of Coastal
and \marine Protected Areas, Ocean and Coastal Management, 20(3):219-39.
Allen, J. (1992). ‘Post-industrialisation and Post-fordism’, in S. Hall, D. Held and T. McGrew
(eds) Modernity and its Future, Polity Press, Oxford.
Boyd, S. W. & Butler, R. W. Tourism and national parks: the origin of the concept, in,
Butler, R. W. & Boyd, S. W. (eds), Tourism and National Parks: Issues and
implications, John Wiley & Sons, Chichester.
Britton, R. A. (1977). Making Tourism more Supportive of Small State Development the
case of St. Vincent, Annals of Tourism Research, 4(5):268-78.
Bromley, D. W. (1995). Resources and Economic Development: An Institutionalist
Perspective, Journal of Economic Issues XIX: 779-796.
Budowski, G. (1976). Tourism and Conservation: conflict, coexistence or symbiosis,
Environmental Conservation, 3:27-31.
Burns, P. M. (2004). Tourism Planning: a third way? Annals of Tourism Research, 31(1):2443.
Burns, P. M. & Holden, A. (1995). Tourism: A New Perspective, Prentice-Hall, London.
Butler, R. (1980). The Concept of Tourist Area Cycle of Evolution: implications for
management of resources. Canadian Geographer, 24(11):5-12.
Ceballos-Lascurain, H. (1996). Tourism and Protected Areas: the state of nature based
tourism around the world and guidelines for its development. IUCN, Gland.
CEBSE (1999). Strengthening Capacity of Communities Involved in Tourism Deevelopment,
the case of Salto del Limon, Samana.
htpp://www.leida.de/papers/RARE/body_rare.html, accessed 18/08/2003.
CEBSE (2000). Trajectories and Challenges of an Ecotourism Project, the case of Salto del
Limon, Samana. htpp://www.saltolimon.org/verbrev_e.pdf, accessed 20/07/2003.
Clelland, R. (2003). An Evaluation of the Distribution of Benefits in Ecotourism: a case
study of the Dominican Republic, masters thesis in Ecotourism, Faculty of the
Environment, University of Portsmouth, UK.
Cohen, E. (1978). The Impact of Tourism on the Physical Environment, Annals of Tourism
Research, 5(2):215-37.
Cohen, E. (1979). A Phenomenology of Tourist Experiences, Sociology 13:179-201.
Crittendon, A. (1975). Tourism’s Terrible Toll: International Wildlife, 5(2):4-12.
Deng, J., King, B. & Bauer, T. (2002). Evaluating Natural Attractions for Tourism, Annals of
Tourism Research, 29(2):422-438.
Dowling, R. K. (1993). Tourism Planning, people and the Environment in Western Australia,
Journal of Travel Research, 31(4):52-8.
25
Dowling, R. & Charters, A. (2000). Best Practice Ecotourism in Queensland. Tourism
Queensland, Brisbane.
Doxey, G. (1976). When Enough’s Enough: the natives are restless in old Niagara,
Heritage Canada 2:26-7.
Drumm, A. (1998). New Approaches to Community-Based Ecotourism Management:
learning from Ecuador. In, K. Lindberg, M. Epler Wood and D. Engeldrum (eds),
Ecoturism: A Guide for Planners and Managers, Vol. 2, The Ecotourism Society,
Vermont, pp:197-213.
Duperly-Pinks, (2002). Community Tourism: ‘style and fashion’ or facilitating
empowerment? In Ian Boxhill, Orville Taylor & Johannes Maerk (Eds.) Tourism and
Change in the Caribbean and Latin America. (pp:137-61). Arawak Publications,
Jamaica.
Eagles, P. F. J. (2002). Trends in Park Tourism: economics, finance and management,
Journal of Sustainable Tourism, 10(2):132-53.
Ecotourism Society, (1991). The Ecotourism Society Newsletter 1, no. 1 (spring 1999),
TIES, Vermont.
Edwards, V. M. (1996). “Ecotourism: a Sustainable Use of the Aotearoa/New Zealand
Coast?” In Taussik, J. & Mitchell, J. (Eds.), Partnerships in Coastal Zone
Management, Samara Publishing Ltd., Cardigan, UK.
Edwards, V. M. (1997). “Ecotourism: a sustainable land use?” Paper presented at The
Battle for the Tourist, Eindhoven University of Technology, The Netherlands, 8-10
June, 1997.
Edwards, V. M. & Steins, N. A. (1998). Developing an Analytical Framework for MultipleUse Commons. Journal of Theoretical Politics. 10(3): 347-383.
Edwards, V. M. and Steins, N. A. (1999). A Framework for Analysing Contextual Factors in
Common Pool Resource Research. Journal of Environmental Policy and Planning.
1(3):205-221.
Feeny, D. (1988).
Fennell, D. (1999). Ecotourism: an introduction. Routledge, London.
Elliot, J. (1994). Tourism Policies and Public Sector Management. Routledge, London.
Feeny, D. (1988). The Demand for and Supply of Institutional Arrangements, in Vincent
Ostrom, David Feeny and Hartmut Picht (eds) Rethinking Institutional Analysis and
Development: Some Issues, Alternatives, and Choices, pp. 159-209. San Francisco,
CA: Institute for Contemporary Sudies Press.
Foucat, V. S. Avilla. (2002). Community-based Ecotourism Management Moving Towards
Sustainability, in Ventanilla, Oaxaca, Mexico. Ocean and Coastal Management,
45(8):511-29.
Galjart, B. (1992). Cooperation as Pooling: A Rational Choice Perspective, Rural Sociology,
XXXII: 389-07.,
Getz, D. (1990). Festivals, Special Events and Tourism, Van Norstand Reinhold, New York.
Giddens, A. (1998). The Third Way: the renewal of social democracy, Polity Press,
Cambridge.
Glasbergen, P. (1996), “Learning to manage the environment,” in W.M. Lafferty and J.
Meadowcroft (eds.), Democracy and the environment: Problems and prospects (pp.
175-193). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Goldsmith, E. (1974). Pollution by Tourism, The Ecologist, 48(1):47-8.
Goodwin, H. (1995). Tourism and the Environment, Biologist, 42(3):129-33.
Gordon, R. (1990). The Prospects for Anthropological Tourism in Bushmanland, Cultural
Survival Quarterly, 14(1):6-8.
Gunn, C. (1994). Tourism Planning. (3rd ed.) Taylor Francis, New York.
Hardin, G. (1968), “The tragedy of the commons,” Science 162: 1243-1248.
Healy, R. G. (1994). The ‘Common Pool’ Problem in Tourism Landscapes, Annals of
Tourism Research, 2193):596-611.
Hitchcock, R. & Brandenburgh, R. (1990). Tourism, conservation, culture, in the Kalahari
Desert, Botswana, Cultural Survival Quarterly, 14(2):20-4.
26
Holden, A. (2000). Environment and Tourism, Routledge, London.
Holmes, A. D. (2003). Resident Perspectives of ecotourism as a tool for community-based
development: a case study of Arroyoi Surbido, Samana, Dominican Republic.
Masters Thesis, University of Florida.
Honey, Martha. (1999). Ecotourism and Sustainable Development: who owns paradise?
Island Press, Washington DC.
Hunter, C. & Green, H. (1995). Tourism and the Environment: a sustainable relationship?,
Routledge, London.
Huybers, T. & Bennett, J. (2003). Inter-firm Cooperation at Nature-based Tourism
Destinations, Journal of Socio-Economics, 32(5)571-87.
Inskeep, E. (1991). Tourism Planning, Van Nostrand Reinhold, New York.
IUCN (2002). World Commission on Protected Areas,
http://www.wpa.iucn.org/wcpainfo.aboutwcpa.html, accessed March 2002.
Lash, S. and Urry, J. (1987). The End of Organized Capitalism, Polity Press, Cambridge.
Lea, J. (1988). Tourism and Development in the Third World. Routledge, London.
Lindberg, K. (1991). Policies for Maximising Nature Tourism’s Ecological and Economic
Benefits, World Resources Institute, Washington, DC.
Lindberg, K. & Hawkins, D. (eds). (1993). Ecotourism: a Guide for Planner and
Managers, The Ecotourism Society, North Bennington, VT.
Lindberg, K. & McKercher, B. (1997). Ecotourism: a critical oversight, Pacific Tourism
Review, 1(1):65-79.
Lindberg, K. (1998). Economic Aspects of Ecotourism, in K. Lindberg, M. Epler Wood and
D. Engeldrum (eds), Ecoturism: A Guide for Planners and Managers, Vol. 2, The
Ecotourism Society, Vermont, pp:87-117.
Lindberg, K., Epler Wood, M. & Engeldrum, D. (1998). Ecotourism: a guide for planner
and managers, volume 2. The Ecotourism Society, VT.
Maarleveld, M., Röling, N., Seegers, S., and C. van Woerkum (1996), Social Learning for
Collective Resource Management: Facilitation, Institutions and Policies.
Wageningen, The Netherlands: Wageningen Agricultural University, Department of
Communication and Innovation Studies.
Mackinnon, B. (1995). Beauty and the Beasts of Ecotourism, Business Mexico, 5(4): 44-7.
Mathieson, A. and Wall, G. (1982). Tourism: Economic, Social and Physical Impacts,
Longman, London.
Mbaiwa, J. E. (2002). The Socio-economic and Environmental Impacts of Tourism
Development on the Okavango Delta, North-Western Botswana, Journal of Arid
Environments, 54(2):447-67.
Mieczkowski, Z. (1995). Environmental Issues of Tourism and Recreation, University Press of
America, Lanham.
Monbiot, G. (1994). No Man’s Land, Macmillan, London.
Mowforth, M. & Munt, I. (1998). Tourism and Sustainability: new tourism in the third world.
Routledge, London.
Munt, I. (1994). Eco-tourism or ego-tourism? Race and Class, 36(1):49-60.
Murphy, P. (1985). Tourism: the community approach, Routledge, London.
Nicholson-Lord, D. (1997). The Politics of Travel: is tourism just colonialism in another
guise? The Nation, October 6th 1997, p.12.
Oakerson, Ronald J. (1992) ‘Analyzing the Commons: A Framework’, in Daniel W.
Bromley et al. (eds.) Making the Commons Work: Theory, Practice and Policy, pp.
41-59. San Francisco, CA: Institute for Contemporary Studies Press.
Obua, J. & Harding, D. (1996). Visitor Characteristics and Attitudes Towards Kibale
National Park, Uganda, Tourism Management, 17(7):495-505.
Ostrom, Elinor (1986). An Agenda for the Study of Institutions. Public Choice 48: 3-25.
Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective
Action. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
27
Ostrom, E. (1995). Design complexity to govern complexity. In: S. Hanna & M. Munasinghe
(Eds.), Property rights and the environment: Social and ecological issues, pp. 33-46.
Washington D.C.: The World Bank.
Ostrom, E. (1995), “Constituting social capital and collective action,” R. O. Keohane and E.
Ostrom (eds.), Local commons and global interdependence: Heterogeneity and cooperation in two domains (pp. 125-160). London: Sage Publications Ltd.
Ostrom, Elinor, Roy Gardner and James Walker (1995), Rules, Games, and Common-Pool
Resources. Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press.
Page, S. J. & Dowling, R. K. (2002). Ecotourism. Prentice Hall, Harlow.
Pattullo, P. (1996). Last Resorts: The cost of tourism in the Caribbean, Cassell, London.
Pearce, D. (1995). Tourism Today: a geographical analysis, Longman, London.
through Community-Based Management. Vancouver: The David Suzuki Foundation.
Reed, M. G. (1997). Power Relations and Community-Based Tourism Planning. Annals of
Tourism Research, 24(3):566-91.
Reingold, L. (1993). Identifying the Elusive Ecotourist, In, Going Green, a supplement to
the Tour and Travel News, October 25, PP;36-7.
Roe, Leader-Williams, and Dalal-Clayton 1997
Röling, N. G. (1994), “Communication support for sustainable natural resource
management,” IDS Bulletin 25: 125-133.
Röling, N .G., and J. Jiggins (1998), “The ecological knowledge system,” in N. G.
Ross, S. & Wall, G. (1999). Evaluating Ecotourism: the case of North Sulawes, Indonesia,
Tourism Management, 20:673-82.
Runge, C. Ford (1981) ‘Common Property Externalities: Isolation, Assurance, and Resource
Depletion in a Traditional Grazing Context’, American Journal of Agricultural
Economics, 63: 595-607.
Ryan, C. (1991). Recreational Tourism: a social science perspective. Routledge, New York.
Ryan, C. (1999). Issues of Sustainability in Tourism, Tourism Management, 20(2):177.
Scheyvens, R. (2000). Promoting Women’s Empowerment Through Involvement in
Ecotourism: experiences from the Third World. Journal of Sustainable Tourism,
8(3):232-49.
Scheyvens, R. (2002). Tourism for Development: empowering communities. Pearson,
Edinburgh.
Shaw, G. & Williams, A. (1994). Critical Issues in Tourism: a geographical perspective,
Blackwell, London.
Shaw, G. & Williams, A. (1997). Individual Consumption of Tourism, in France, L. (ed).
Sustainable Tourism, Earthscan, London. pp:102-5.
Singh, K. (1994), Managing Common-pool Resources: Principles and Case Studies: Delhi:
Oxford University Press.
Smith, V. (ed.) (1989). Hosts and Guests: the anthropology of tourism, University of
Pennsylvania Press, Philadelphia.
Steins, Nathalie A. (1995) ‘Securing Access to the Sea: The Creation of an Artificial
Common Property Resource’, paper presented at the 5th International Conference of
the International Association for the Study of Common Property, Bodoe, Norway.
Steins, N. A. & Edwards, V. M. (1999). Collective Action in Common-Pool Management: the
contribution of a social constructivist perspective to existing theory. Society and
Natural Resources. 12:539-557.
Steins, N. A. & Edwards, V. M. (1999). Platforms for Collective Action in Multiple-Use
Common Pool Resource Management - Special Issue. Agriculture and Human
Values. 16:241-255.
Stonich, S., Sorenson, J. and Hundt, A. (1995). Ethnicity, Class and Gender in Tourism
Development of the Bay of Islands, Honduras. Journal of Sustainable Tourism,
3(1):1-28.
Swallow, B., and D. W. Bromley (1995), “Institutions, governance and incentives in common
property regimes for African rangelands,” Environmental and Resource Economics 6:
99-118.
28
Taylor, G. (1995). The Community Approach: does it really work? Tourism Management,
16(7):487-9.
Tosun, C. (2000). Limits to Community Participation in the Tourism Development Process
in Developing Countries. Tourism Management, 21:613-33.
Wade, R. 1988. Village republics: economic conditions for collective action in South India.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Wall, G. (1982). Cycles and Capacity: incipient theory or conceptual contradiction, Tourism
Management, 3(3):188-92.
Wall, G. (1994). Ecotourism: old wine in new bottles?, Trends, 31(2):4-9.
Wallace, G. N. & Pierce, S. M. (1996). An Evaluation of Ecotourism in Amazonas, Brazil.
Annals of Tourism Research, 24(4):843-73.
Wearing, S. & Larsen, L. (1996). Assessing and Managing the Socio-cultural Impacts of
Ecotourism: revisiting the Santa Elena Rainforest Project, The Environmentalist,
16:117-33.
Whelan, T. (ed.) (1991). Nature Tourism: managing fir the environment, Island Pres,
Washington DC.
Wheeller, B. (1993). Willing Victims of the Ego Trap. Tourism in Focus, 9:14.
Wilkinson, P. and Pratiwi, W. (1995). Gender and Tourism in an Indonesian Village. Annals
of Tourism Research, 22(2):283-99.
Williams, P. (1992). A local Framework for Ecotourism Development, Western Wildlands,
18(3):14-19.
Woods, (1996).
World Resources Institute, (1993). Ecotourism: rising interest in nature vacations has mixed
results for host countries and the resources they promote, in Environmental Almanac,
Houghton Mifflin, Boston.
World Tourism Organisation. (1995). Compendium of Tourism Statistics 1985-1989, WTO,
Madrid.
World Tourism Organisation. (1996). Global Overview – preliminary results. WTO, Madrid.
World Tourism Organisation. (1999). Tourism: 2020 Vision – Executive Summary. WTO,
Madrid.
World Tourism Organisation. (2000). Sustainable Development of Tourism: a compilation of
good practices. WTO, Madrid.
Young, G. (1973).Tourism: blessing or blight, Penguin, Harmondsworth.
i ‘Fordism’ (taking its name from Henry Ford’s assembly line of mass-produced cars) refers to a
consumerist approach where economies of scale are achieved through mass production and mass
consumption of goods. Hence, ‘post-Fordism’ represents a qualitative shift from mass production and
consumption to more flexible systems of production and organisation. The theory makes links to the
way in which goods and services are consumed, including the emergence of niche and segmented
markets (Allen, 1992; Mowforth & Munt, 1998).
ii Tourism Concern is a UK based NGO campaigning, mostly on behalf of host nations, for improved
tourism provision (www.tourismconcern.org.uk).
iii Economic empowerment might be achieved, for example, by providing employment opportunities
and increased income. The economic gains to the community should be sustainable and shared
between many households in the community. Psychological empowerment by, for example, providing
the ability to learn new skills, and increased self-esteem through the outside recognition of the
uniqueness and value of a community’s culture and natural resources. Social empowerment can be
provided directly by inspiring individuals and families to work together on a tourism project and create
a more cohesive society, and indirectly through the building of schools, churches and youth centres
fro some of the revenue raised. Political empowerment might be achieved through the community’s
sense of control of use of their own natural resources and environment.
iv The Three other factors were: Co-operation among different partners in the pursuit of the project’s,
or initiative’s, objectives (36%); Environmental commitment of the project’s promoters (36%); and
Continuous monitoring of the project’s performance (36%).
29
v In the commons debate, there has been considerable confusion concerning the terminology of
common pool and common property resources. A wide range of resources might be used in common
by more than one person: thus comprising a common pool from which individuals might draw
‘resource units’ (Ostrom, 1990). Such resources may or may not have formal and informal rights
attached to them concerning control of their use. By terming a resource as ‘property’, we identify it as
a reservoir or flow of benefits to which rights can be attached. Thus, property rights are social
institutions which have evolved as a means of enforcing claims to that benefit stream. By attaching
rights to property, we show the intention to enforce duties of a potential user to observe restricted (or
prohibited) access to and use of the resource.
vi While property rights classifications of commons can be helpful, they can also be misleading in that
they suggest that each resource system will fall neatly into a single category. There are three other
basic classifications of property rights for common pool resources: (i) open access, where no use
rights are attached to a specific group, resulting in a general ‘free for all’; (ii) public property, where
access rights for the public are held in trust by the Crown or state; and (iii) private property, where
tradable rights are owned by an individual, household or company, who may allocate various rights of
use to groups of individuals to use the resource in common. Much of the original work conducted on
the analysis of common pool resources has focused on resources that are subject to a single,
extractive resource use. However, more recent work has extended research to ‘multiple use’
commons, where the resources system is enjoyed by multiple types of uses and users (see, for
example, Feeny et al., 1990, 1996; Barrett, 1991; Edwards, 1996; Selsky and Creahan, 1996; Van
Ginkel, 1996;; Steins, 1996; Edwards & Steins, 1998).
vii It should be noted that the physical and technological characteristics of the resource can indirectly
affect outcomes through patterns of interactions, but can also directly affect the outcomes,
independent of human interaction. This is represented in the framework (Figure 2), where a line
shows a direct link between the physical nature of the common and the technology available and
outcomes of use.
viii Oakerson (1992: 52) argues that the presence of inequities might be revealed as a breakdown in
collective action and subsequent inefficiency of use results from users failing to receive a ‘reasonable
and fair return on their contribution’. In the evaluation of outcomes of resource management, we must
be aware that the researcher’s and users’ concepts of efficiency and equity are social constructs. For
example, researchers are often inclined to view efficiency in terms of ecological sustainability, but
local users may have a different point of view. Oerlemans and Steins (1994) report that farmers in the
Hills of Nepal could not make the concept of sustainable agriculture explicit: their perception of
sustainability can be described as social sustainability, namely enough yield to feed their family,
enough labour to work the fields and non-decreasing soil fertility. In the evaluation of outcomes, we
must make explicit which meaning we ascribe to efficiency and equity.
ix
El Salto de Limon is located in the northeastern corner of the Dominican Republic, on the peninsula
of Samana, between the popular tourist area of Las Terrenas and the town of Samana.
30