APRIL 2018
102
GEO-ECONOMICS AS CONCEPT AND
PRACTICE IN INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS
SURVEYING THE STATE OF THE ART
Sören Scholvin
Mikael Wigell
APRIL 2018
102
GEO-ECONOMICS AS CONCEPT AND PRACTICE
IN INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS
SURVEYING THE STATE OF THE ART
Recent cases of power politics such as China’s One Belt, One Road strategy,
Venezuela’s petro-diplomacy during the era of Hugo Chávez and Western sanctions
against Iran and Russia indicate that economic means have become critical to how
states exert power. Military means, meanwhile, appear to matter less. This shift
in power politics is captured by the term ‘geo-economics’, which we understand
as an analytical approach and, at the same time, a foreign policy practice.
This Working Paper traces the rise of geo-economics since the end of the Cold War.
It surveys the state of the art, distinguishing between approaches that stand in
the tradition of Edward Luttwak’s work and conceptualisations of geo-economics
that go in very different directions. This way, key fault lines that mark research on
geo-economics are revealed. We also develop our own definition of geo-economics
and show how a geo-economic perspective complements major IR theories.
SÖREN SCHOLVIN
MIKAEL WIGELL
Research Fellow
Senior Research Fellow
University of Hanover
Finnish Institute of International Affairs
ISBN 978-951-769-564-0
ISSN 1795-8059
Language editing: Lynn Nikkanen.
The Finnish Institute of International Affairs is an independent research institute that
produces high-level research to support political decisionmaking and public debate both
nationally and internationally.
All manuscripts are reviewed by at least two other experts in the field to ensure the high
quality of the publications. In addition, publications undergo professional language checking
and editing. The responsibility for the views expressed ultimately rests with the authors.
TABLE OF CONTENTS
INTRODUCTION 4
THE RISE OF GEO-ECONOMICS SINCE THE EARLY 1990s 5
Geo-economics in the tradition of Luttwak 6
Non-Luttwakian approaches to geo-economics 8
A DEFINITION OF GEO-ECONOMICS AND ITS CONTRIBUTION TO IR 9
REFERENCES 13
GEO-ECONOMICS AS CONCEPT AND PRACTICE
IN INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS
SURVEYING THE STATE OF THE ART
INTRODUCTION
States increasingly practise power politics by economic
means. Whether it is a question of Iran’s nuclear programme or Russia’s annexation of Crimea, Western
states apparently prefer economic sanctions to military force. In spite of sabre-rattling vis-à-vis North
Korea, the Trump presidency also highlights this trend:
the 2017 National Security Strategy differs from its
predecessors in its emphasis on economic statecraft,
stating that ‘economic security is national security’
(2017: 17). Other major powers are also putting more
emphasis on economic means in power politics: China
is using finance, investment and trade to build alliances and gain influence in countries across Africa, Asia
and Latin America (Holslag 2016; Mattlin and Gaens
2018; Wigell and Soliz Landivar 2018; Yu 2015). Brazil
and South Africa have become cunning agents of economic statecraft, using state-owned banks and stateowned enterprises to create asymmetric relations with
neighbouring countries in order to maintain (sub)
continental spheres of influence (Bond 2004; Flynn
2007; McDonald 2009). Oil-rich states, especially Qatar and Saudi Arabia, deploy ‘chequebook diplomacy’
to wield influence in regional affairs (Blackwill and
Harris 2016). Russia is leveraging its energy resources
to cement political alliances and drive wedges within
counter-alliances (Vihma and Wigell 2016; Wigell and
Vihma 2016).
The ways in which states use economic power to
pursue strategic aims have, thus, become an increasingly important aspect of international relations. Policy advisors and scholars have started to use the term
‘geo-economics’ to describe this form of power politics. Geo-economics proceeds from the assumption
that power and security are not simply coupled to the
physical control of territory, as in classical geopolitical analysis, but also to commanding and manipulating
the economic ties that bind states together. By making
use of the leverage provided by the asymmetric vulnerabilities inherent in these economic interconnectivities (Fjäder 2018), geo-economics provides a way
for states to conduct power politics that does not refer
to military means.
Hence, while competition once again appears to be
the predominant driver of international relations, the
means used by states to engage in strategic competition are not predominantly military, as sometimes assumed in recent debates (e.g. Mead 2014). As the contributions to the edited volume Geo-economics and
Power Politics in the 21st Century (Wigell, Scholvin
and Aaltola 2018) demonstrate, geo-economics has
gained considerable relevance, with major repercussions for international relations. While not succumbing
to any unfounded idealism based on the supposedly
stabilising effects of interdependence on international
relations, geo-economic analysis duly challenges the
simplistic accounts of a return to geopolitics as conducted by Cold War policy advisers such as Zbigniew
Brzezinski and Henry Kissinger, meaning the predominantly military pursuit of foreign policy objectives.
Unfortunately, there is no widely shared definition
of geo-economics, as the overview provided in this paper reveals. Scholars who use the term usually fail to
establish borders between geo-economics and geopolitics. Most scholars furthermore seldom explain what
the ‘geo’ in geo-economics means and what makes
geo-economics different from International Political
Economy (IPE). One might conclude that geo-economics is often used only as a catchword that generates an audience for policy-oriented, semi-scientific
outlets. The state of the art suffers from a gap in terms
of basic conceptual contributions.
This paper addresses this weakness by exploring the
field of geo-economics from a conceptual perspective.
We suggest that geo-economics is both a foreign policy
strategy and an analytical approach. As a foreign policy strategy, it refers to the application of economic
means of power by states so as to realise strategic objectives. Herein, the concept of geo-economics refers
to a certain strategic practice, providing an alternative
option to military-based power politics. Much current
scholarship uses the term geo-economics in this sense,
referring to it as a substitute for ‘economic statecraft’.
APRIL 2018
4
Yet just as with geopolitics, geo-economics is also
an analytical approach. As such, it has much to contribute to foreign policy analysis and International
Relations (IR) scholarship by highlighting factors that
transcend current approaches. Geo-economics resonates with IR Realism by emphasising rivalry amongst
states. Yet by perceiving military force as the ultima
ratio in international politics, IR Realism tends to pay
little regard to non-military forms of power (Baldwin
2013). As we show below, geo-economics can contribute to IR Realism by providing novel conceptual tools
for analysing economic forms of power projection. By
underscoring the importance of interdependence and
economic means in foreign policy, geo-economics also
resonates with IR Liberalism. When it comes to the latter, geo-economics also shares a focus on Innenpolitik,
assuming that how states define their national interests is not only a function of international structures
but also a result of internal political contests. To the
assumption about the state not being a unitary actor,
geo-economics adds an international level – that of
external powers trying to affect the outcome of internal political struggles (Wigell and Soliz Landivar 2018;
Wigell and Vihma 2016).
Geo-economics also transcends IR Liberalism and
IR Realism insofar as it is focussed on geographical features that are inherent in foreign policy-making and
international relations. This means that geo-economics
may deal with economic bases of power that have a
clear geographical dimension: some countries possess
resources that others need and these resources are
transported along strategically crucial corridors, for
example. Alternatively, geo-economics is about how
economic instruments are used to control specific geographical areas such as the sphere of influence of a
regional hegemon.
This paper is divided into four sections. We first
trace the rise of the concept of geo-economics in the
post-Cold War era. Second, we critically assess contemporary research that stands in the tradition established by Edward Luttwak, who popularised the term
geo-economics in the early 1990s. Third, we examine
non-Luttwakian approaches to geo-economics. In the
fourth section, we summarise the key fault lines that
presently mark the research on geo-economics, develop a definition for geo-economics and show how
a geo-economic perspective complements the traditional IR theories.
THE RISE OF GEO-ECONOMICS
SINCE THE EARLY 1990s
In a seminal article, Edward Luttwak (1990) used the
term geo-economics to describe how in the postCold War system, the main arena for rivalry amongst
states would be economic rather than military. Luttwak (1993) further elaborated on his ideas in a book
published three years later. With the Soviet threat to
Europe and the United States all but evaporated, he
did not envisage any military confrontation in the near
future. In a similar vein, Samuel Huntington observed
how ‘in a world in which military conflict between
major states is unlikely[,] economic power will be increasingly important in determining the primacy or
subordination of states’ (1993: 72). Hence, in the view
of these early geo-economists, the end of the Cold War
did not equal the ‘end of history’ that Francis Fukuyama (1992) predicted. Instead, they foresaw a transformation of the way conflict was being played out – ‘with
disposable capital in lieu of firepower, civilian innovation in lieu of military-technical advancement, and
market penetration in lieu of garrisons and bases’ (Luttwak 1990: 18). In the new geo-economic era, states
would still be pursuing adversarial goals but through
economic instead of military means.
Luttwak’s ideas quickly fell out of fashion, however, as the ‘new global order’ proclaimed by President
George H. Bush and the Washington Consensus seemed
to have entrenched a more cooperative international
system in which all major powers bought into globalisation and hopes of a long period of economic growth,
creating mutual benefits that would lessen the chances of serious conflict. The realist assumptions inherent
in the early geo-economics paradigm did not appear
useful for this liberal era, in which economic integration and cooperation, not conflict, had become the
dominant features of international relations. However, while economic interdependence increased rapidly
on an international scale in the 1990s, and even more
so in the 2000s, so did the challenges and risks, many
of which are geo-economic in nature. As noted, interdependence is often asymmetric, meaning that it
entails sources of power in bargaining relationships, as
already pointed out by Keohane and Nye (1977) in their
seminal book Power and Interdependence. Risks that
result from interdependence – and that affect states
asymmetrically – include disruptions to global supply
chains and illicit trade flows as well as the use of asymmetric vulnerabilities as strategic leverage (Aaltola et
APRIL 2018
5
al. 2014; Fjäder 2018; World Economic Forum 2015).
These vulnerabilities are propelling economic security to the centre of the global agenda and suggest that
geo-economic calculations should be paramount in
the concerns of both major and minor powers in their
strategic calculus (Wigell 2016).
The concept of geo-economics has, thus, become
increasingly fashionable in academic as well as policy-oriented debates. Yet, as Mattlin and Wigell (2016)
observe, it is striking how many scholars and policy
analysts use the term geo-economics as a catchword
without defining it clearly or at least taking into consideration how others use it. The following overview
highlights how different contemporary understandings of geo-economics are, and how difficult it would
be to draw them together under a common frame.
We start with authors who have an understanding of
geo-economics that is roughly compatible with Luttwak’s and then proceed to varieties of geo-economics
that have less in common with Luttwak’s conceptualisation, or are outright incompatible with it. Building
on these former approaches, we will then present our
own understanding of geo-economics.
Geo-economics in the tradition of Luttwak
Since the end of the Cold War, many scholars have
used the term geo-economics by drawing on Luttwak’s seminal article either explicitly or implicitly.
In many of these analyses, economic statecraft emerges
as a central element of geo-economics. As such, they
largely view geo-economics as a foreign policy practice, providing an alternative to geopolitics in pursuing geostrategic goals. The view is state-centric and
essentialist, although few of these analyses make their
analytical framework explicit. Hudson et al. (1991), for
example, define geo-economics as strategies of territorial control that are economically motivated and
carried out by economic means, the most important
of which are investment and trade. Hsiung (2009) understands geo-economics as a shift from military to
economic security concerns, especially with regard to
China’s new role in global politics. Mattlin and Wigell
(2016) suggest that geo-economic strategies are typical of non-Western powers – Brazil, China and India
– because they rely on non-military means in their soft
balancing vis-à-vis the United States.
Vihma and Wigell (2016) and Wigell and Vihma
(2016) examine the way that Russia has attempted
to project power into its neighbourhood, not only by
military means but also through economics, demonstrating the different strategic natures of geo-economics and geopolitics and the way they may undermine
each other’s effectiveness when applied simultaneously. Herein, Vihma and Wigell also suggest a clear
distinction between geo-economic and geopolitical
power politics. The broad research on how China is
deploying its financial power as a means of pursuing
political aims and on how Germany has imposed its
preferences in the European Union by leveraging its
market power also stands in the Luttwakian tradition
(e.g. Kärkkäinen 2016; Kundnani 2011, 2018; Scholvin
and Strüver 2013; Wigell and Soliz Landivar 2018).
However, contrary to Luttwak’s expectations,
geo-economics has not entirely replaced military
means of statecraft. Economic and military instruments co-exist, being used by states depending on
what they consider adequate for the specific challenges
they are facing. Blackwill and Harris therefore suggest
that ‘for today’s most sophisticated geo-economic actors, geo-economic and military dimensions of statecraft tend to be mutually reinforcing’ (2016: 9). Unfortunately, labelling states that refer to military means
as geo-economic actors, as Blackwill and Harris do,
makes for confusing terminology. Other researchers
also conceptualise geo-economics and geopolitics – the
latter being understood as the pursuit of strategic objectives by military means – as overlapping strategies.
In his study of the competition between China and India, Scott (2008) points out that control over sealines
of communication is essential to geo-economics and
geopolitics, as is access to vital resources. Grosse (2014)
analyses China’s domestic capital accumulation and
broader economic development, arguing that increasing economic bases of national power enable the People’s Republic to change the structures of the global
economy according to its preferences. Whereas Scott
clearly distinguishes between geo-economics and geopolitics, Grosse proposes that geo-economics is the
merger of economic and geopolitical goals and implies
that there are hybrid strategies of economic and military power projection.
In his contribution to the aforementioned volume
Geo-economics and Power Politics in the 21st Century, Scholvin (2018) argues that secondary powers
in sub-Saharan Africa – Angola, Ethiopia, Kenya and
Nigeria – refer to a mix of geo-economics and geopolitics in their foreign policies, thus trying to shape their
respective near abroad. The mix of geo-economics and
geopolitics applies to the Indian-Pakistani rivalry as
APRIL 2018
6
well (Pattanaik 2018). Analysing Western sanctions
imposed on Iran, Rivlin (2018) concludes that these
would probably not have been successful were it not
for the latent military threat posed to Iran by the
United States. From a broader perspective, Möttölä
(2018) also reasons that geo-economics and geopolitics can co-occur: during the Obama administration,
US geo-economics was about the Trans-Pacific Partnership and the Transatlantic Trade and Investment
Partnership. At the same time, the superpower shifted
its own military focus towards the Asia Pacific region,
supported its European partners militarily against
Russia, and built military partnerships with regional
countries and major European powers in the Middle
East.
The aforementioned terminological muddle becomes particularly apparent in an article by Sanjaya
Baru, the former Director for Geo-economics and
Strategy at the International Institute of Strategic
Studies. Baru defines geo-economics as the mutual
interplay of economics and geopolitics: economic developments, such as the declining economic power of
a specific state, have geopolitical impacts; geopolitical
change, such as territorial conquest, influences economics. Yet elsewhere in the same text, geo-economic
power appears as a status that derives from successfully applied economic power, as Baru argues that Japan turned into an economic power in the 1980s but
‘it never became a geo-economic power, having failed
to convert its newfound economic clout into military
and political power’ (2012: 51). From an analytical perspective, it is problematic that only successful policies
qualify as geo-economics. Apart from that, if applied
economic power turns a state into a geo-economic
power (as a status) or constitutes geo-economic power (as a practice), what is the difference between a
geo-economic and a geopolitical power, considering
that Baru defines geo-economics as the mutual impact
of economics and geopolitics? And why, according to
the above quote, do geo-economic powers refer to
military means?
A related problem has to do with defining geo-economics by its ends (and not by its means). For Youngs,
geo-economics revolves around ‘the use of statecraft
for economic ends’ (2011: 14). Coleman (2005) and
Sidaway (2005) investigate flows of finance and trade,
looking at the political aspects behind them. O’Hara
and Heffernan (2006) understand geo-economics as
being about the natural resources that a region contains and the politics of controlling and exploiting
these resources. However, as Blackwill and Harris
(2016) point out, defining different types of power
politics by their respective ends is not convincing: if a
library is destroyed by cruise missiles, one would not
speak of cultural warfare; if a factory is destroyed the
same way, one would not call this economic warfare.
What matters in classifying acts of aggression is the
means used by the aggressor.
The volume Connectivity Wars suffers from similar problems. In its introduction, Leonard argues that
there are three new arenas in which conflicts amongst
states are now being carried out: economics, international institutions and infrastructure. Key to understanding international relations in the 21st century is
interdependence: ‘the very things that connected the
world are now being used as weapons’ (2016: 15). This
leads to tactics by which state A seeks to make state
B dependent on itself – through economic relations,
institutional affiliations and infrastructures – in order
to gain political leverage. Although this concept seems
convincing, the defining features of geo-economics
addressed by Leonard do not say anything specific
about how power is used. For example, bombing airports and power plants, which are infrastructures, is
not geo-economics. Building hub airports on which
entire continents depend and establishing power stations that guarantee the electricity supply of neighbouring countries is geo-economics. Beyond that,
Leonard does not explain what the geo in geo-economics is about, turning geo-economics into an overly
broad and somewhat semi-scientific form of IPE.
Blackwill and Harris also fail to explain the geo
dimension properly. They try to distinguish between
geo-economics and geopolitics, arguing that the latter ‘explain[s] and predict[s] state power by reference
to a host of geographic factors (territory, population,
economic performance, natural resources, military
capabilities, etc.)’. Geo-economics, meanwhile, is ‘a
parallel account of how a state builds and exercises
power by reference to economic factors’ (2016: 24).
Firstly, economic factors somewhat confusingly appear in both definitions. What is more, economic performance and military capabilities are not geographical
factors. Unless one maintains that everything is geographical because everything is located somewhere,
geographical factors are limited to place-specific features – a mountain range that serves as a natural barrier against military invasions or vast energy resources
that constitute the fundament for economic prosperity, for instance. Whenever such factors are taken into
APRIL 2018
7
consideration in explanations of foreign policy and international relations, it can reasonably be argued that
geo-economics and geopolitics (instead of economics
and politics) are analysed. Before returning to these
thoughts, the next section provides an overview of
approaches to geo-economics that do not stand in the
Luttwakian tradition.
Non-Luttwakian approaches to geo-economics
Some publications that may appear under the label
of geo-economics have less in common with Luttwak’s view of geo-economics as economic statecraft.
Scholvin and Draper (2012) as well as Scholvin and
Malamud (2014) concentrate on the impact of material
structures in geographical space on Brazil’s and South
Africa’s respective regional economic relations. Käpylä
and Mikkola (2016) explain that geographical conditions induce states to cooperate in the Arctic because
open confrontation would risk everyone’s economic
objectives. This concept of geo-economics – geographical conditions shaping economic outcomes – equals
the understanding of geopolitics historically held by
geographers, who thought of geopolitics as political
outcomes shaped by geographical conditions (Scholvin
2016). For many policy advisers and IR scholars, meanwhile, geo-economics and geopolitics refer to how
states aim to control flows and spaces, not geographical conditions influencing policies.
Others relate geo-economics to the rise of new actors that matter for economic and political dynamics
beyond the national scale. For instance, Barton (1999)
argues that while the era of geopolitics was about hegemonic states and stability in international relations,
the era of geo-economics is marked by highly flexible
non-state actors and borderless transnational relations. Mercille (2008) suggests that whereas businesspeople act according to a geo-economic logic, the logic
behind the actions of politicians is geopolitical. From a
slightly different perspective, Cowen and Smith (2009)
suggest that the assemblage of territory, economy and
people under the authority of nation-states – key criteria of the era of geopolitics – is being recast, mainly
because territorial borders have lost the defining role
they used to play in the economy and society. The era
of geo-economics is characterised by global production becoming increasingly segmented, which is part
and parcel of the rise of transnational enterprises as
key actors. Likewise, security threats such as terrorism
are not bound to territorial borders.
Defining geo-economics via its particular territorial
logic, Cowen and Smith furthermore reason that it was
crucial to international relations long before the end
of the Cold War: the rise of the United States to global
powerhood in the early 20th century was about free
trade or rather ‘the accumulation of wealth through
market control’ (2009: 42). The United States arguably neglected military territorial control, which was
essential to the geopolitical strategies pursued by the
European great powers of these days. Smith (2005) accordingly suggests that the imperial liberalism pursued
during the presidencies of Woodrow Wilson, Franklin
D. Roosevelt and George W. Bush were geo-economic
projects, albeit ones that depended on the US military
as some sort of global police force.
Whereas these approaches share a meta-theoretical basis with the Luttwakian tradition, being essentialist approaches, adherents of Critical Geopolitics
concentrate on discursive practices, which offer possibilities for imagining and re-imagining geographical space. Scholars who stand in this tradition look at
how geo-economics operates as a discourse, shaping
and reproducing the worldviews of security strategists
and foreign policy-makers, and how it becomes entrenched in state practices. For many critical geographers, the geo-economic discourse masks neoliberal
restructuring and securitisation projects. Essex (2013)
and Sparke (2002, 2006), for example, deconstruct the
ideological underpinnings of transnational governance
imperatives that they summarise as geo-economics.
In Domosh’s words, ‘the term geoeconomics does not
describe a situation; rather, it conjures up a range of
meanings, cultures, and places through which description can happen. Geoeconomics, in other words,
does not refer simply to a description of economic spatial strategies but instead encompasses a way of seeing
the world in which those strategies come to be seen as
plausible and desirable’ (2013: 945).
These perspectives draw on Critical Geopolitics, not
taking geo-economic claims at face value but rather
seeing them ‘as representational power moves which,
notwithstanding their discursive inventiveness, can
still have powerful real world effects’ (Sparke and
Lawson 2003: 316). Adherents of Critical Geopolitics,
which emerged in the 1990s, see essentialist versions
of geo-economics and geopolitics as ‘an ideological exercise which […] pits geographically defined political
organisations against one another’ (Dalby 1990: 39).
For them, Luttwak’s geo-economics equals ‘extending
the same realist assumptions [that have] underpinned
APRIL 2018
8
and legitimized Cold War militarism’ (Ó Tuathail 1998:
107). Hence, critical scholars ought to promote ‘interpretations of world events that are counter to dominant government and media representations’ (Flint
2006: 16).
Constructivists have also interpreted geo-economics as a securitising discourse. The concept of
securitisation, as developed particularly by the Copenhagen School of IR, highlights how security risks
often become appropriated – or even discursively
constructed as threats – so as to legitimise extraordinary counter-measures (e.g. Buzan, Wæver and de
Wilde 1997). For example, Morrissey suggests that the
grand strategy of the United States in the Middle East
has revolved around ‘the discursive identification and
positing of the Persian Gulf as a precarious yet pivotal
geoeconomic space’ (2011: 874). He argues that it is this
perpetual scripting of the region as being ‘pivotal for
the effective functioning and regulation of the global
political economy [that] legitimizes a strategic argument for the necessity of military interventionism’
(2011: 879).
However, Morrissey does not find it necessary to
analyse whether the Persian Gulf might actually hold
a special relevance for the global economy. When seeing nothing but discourses, such analyses fail to capture material structures that influence international
relations and are beyond the control of those who
shape discourses. What is more, adherents of Critical
Geopolitics usually keep quiet about the fact that the
alternative interpretations that they advance implicitly are – at least from their own constructivist perspective – neither better/more correct nor worse/less
correct than the discourses that shape geo-economic
practices. As Vihma notes, the curious absence of the
author in the text ‘protects the critical scholar against
charges that he himself [or she herself] has misread
political events or history’ (2017: 12). And while analytical suspicion serves an important function, the
warning against geo-economic thought that constructivists from Geography and IR make by arguing that
geo-economics helps to mask neoliberal agendas and
securitisation projects raises the question of whether
such considerations should limit the scholarly agenda.
Critical Geopolitics has provided many useful insights concerning the discursive underpinnings of
geo-economic power politics. Yet the output of this
scholarship suffers from certain weaknesses. Much
of it starts with the assumption that geo-economic
policy advice and research is essentially ideological,
comprising intentional misinformation that serves disguised interests. This universal suspicion tends to lead
to conclusions that are hard to fathom – at least for
readers who do not share the sometimes highly partisan political convictions held by these critical scholars.
Its current neglect of material realities is also problematic. Furthermore, it appears to us that an approach
that limits itself to simply deconstructing geo-economics has come to a dead end. This does not need to
be the case. Although it would be rather challenging
to meld IR Constructivism with geo-economics as defined in this paper, constructivist-oriented research
could make a contribution to geo-economics by investigating the role of state identities and ideas in shaping
geo-economic behaviour. Indeed, much constructivist
scholarship does not disregard the existence of material reality but investigates how ideational factors interact with it (for a discussion, see e.g. the articles in
the special issue of the International Studies Review,
volume 6, issue 2). Herein lies a gap in geo-economic
research as advanced by us.
A DEFINITION OF GEO-ECONOMICS AND
ITS CONTRIBUTION TO IR
Thus far, this paper has shown that geo-economics
has gained considerable prominence in studies of
international relations and foreign policy. Yet the
state of research suffers from a muddle of sometimes
incompatible ideas of what geo-economics is about.
The key fault lines identified in the previous sections
are:
• Is geo-economics, first, an analytical framework for international relations scholarship
and foreign policy analysis or, second, a type of
statecraft or, third, a particular form that the
international system has taken, with the territorial logic of geopolitics becoming increasingly
meaningless?
• As a fourth option, should we conceptualise
geo-economics as the impact of geographical
conditions on economics, similar to how geographers traditionally conceptualised geopolitics,
being the impact of geographical conditions on
politics?
• Is geo-economics, as a form of statecraft, defined by its means or by its ends; or, perhaps,
by a mix of both?
APRIL 2018
9
• Related to this, what is the relationship between geo-economics and military power?
Can military means be part of a geo-economic
strategy? Do they complement it? Or is the use
of military power incompatible with geo-economics?
• Who applies geo-economics? Are private enterprises geo-economic actors and, if so, should
we conceptualise geo-economics as their strategies, as opposed to geopolitical strategies pursued by states?
• If we understand geo-economics as an analytical approach, is it a policy-oriented version
of IPE and IR Realism or does it somehow narrow the perspective on issues that have a geo
dimension?
• Considering that geo-economics is also a discourse, how should we, as scientists, deal with
the fact that geo-economics is, at least partly,
socially constructed, potentially so as to legitimise action that aims at realising disguised interests?
Answering these questions is, of course, somewhat arbitrary and we are not saying that research based on
other definitions of geo-economics does not generate
important insights and valid results. Nevertheless, as
noted, we suggest understanding geo-economics as a
foreign policy strategy and an analytical framework,
focussed on states as key actors in international relations and foreign policy. Geo-economics as a foreign
policy strategy – or practical geo-economics – refers
to the application of economic means of power so as to
realise strategic objectives. It is ‘the geostrategic use of
economic power’ (Wigell 2016: 137). This means that
geo-economics is not, in our understanding, about a
fundamental shift in the international system.
Yet the strategic imperatives of foreign policy have
changed since the Cold War. Ours is no longer a bipolar world in which two blocs of states stand largely isolated from each other. Today, the world is more
interdependent and interconnected than at any time
in history. Almost all states depend on the secure and
steady flows of capital, data and goods that crisscross
the globe. The asymmetric vulnerabilities and dependencies inherent in this international system make economic power a potent means by which to pursue strategic objectives. This does not imply that geo-economics would have actually eclipsed more military-based
power politics or that it could not co-occur with it.
Still, the ability to wield economic leverage forms an
essential means of power politics in today’s world,
much more so than in the past.
In the same vein as geopolitics and military bases
of national power, the geo dimension in geo-economics means that the economic bases of national power
must have decisive geographical features. Russia’s use
of natural gas as a strategic leverage vis-à-vis former
Soviet republics and the European Union is practical
geo-economics because we cannot understand this
strategy without taking the geographical features of
natural gas into consideration. Vast amounts of this
vital resource are located in Russia, not in Poland or
Ukraine. Pipelines connect Russia’s natural gas deposits to the non-Russian consumers, enabling Russia
– but also transit countries – to cut supplies (Vihma
and Wigell 2016; Wigell and Vihma 2016). Alternatively, the objective of geo-economic strategies must be
geographically delimited. The mere use of monetary
and financial policies in pursuit of strategic objectives
does not qualify as geo-economics. However, as Kundnani’s (2011, 2018) publications on Germany’s role in
the Eurozone and Márquez Restrepo’s (2018) analysis
of Venezuela’s project of regional leadership during the
era of Hugo Chávez exemplify, monetary and financial
policies become tools of geo-economics whenever they
are applied to control a sphere of influence. Cowen and
Smith’s (2009) characterisation of US imperialism in
the early 20th century also chimes with this understanding of geo-economics, although one may call into
question the supposed absence of military means for
territorial control in the grand strategy of the United
States in those days.
Defining geo-economics and particularly its geo
dimension this way, we partly detach ourselves from
Luttwak’s seminal article. Luttwak argued that the
global flows of capital, data, goods and people penetrating sovereign state space do not mean that states
change the territorial character. States regulate the
economy in numerous ways, for example by collecting taxes and providing public goods such as transport
infrastructure. Being territorially bound, states aim
at nationally best outcomes instead of outcomes that
would be best for the global economy as a whole. For
Luttwak, this territoriality and the resulting competitive behaviour of states constitute the geo dimension
in geo-economics. He proposed that ‘the international
economy [is] affected by that fraction of its life that is
geo-economic rather than simply economic in character’ (1990: 22–23).
APRIL 2018
10
Yet in our world of global flows and interconnectivities, the strategic imperatives of state practice are
changing. All states increasingly depend on these fluid
circulations of capital, data, goods, and people for their
national security and welfare. States have to secure
steady access to positive flows – for example commercial and financial flows or technology networks – and
ensure their resilience vis-à-vis negative flows such as
narcotics trade. States remain security providers but
they increasingly need to provide security by controlling these flows in addition to their national territory; and it is economic means of power, not military
force, that in most cases appear suitable for this task
(Brattberg and Hamilton 2014).
Given the frequent confusion of terms, we consider it necessary to stress that practical geo-economics
is not a simple revival of mercantilism, at least not in
Luttwakian terms. Comparing the logic of geo-economics to the logic of mercantilism, Luttwak pointed
out that mercantilist states used military means as a
supreme force to achieve their goals. The Portuguese
dominated the spice trade with India in the early 16th
century because they had sunk the dhows of their
economically superior Arab competitors. British piracy from the 1650s to the 1730s was effective against
Spain’s economic supremacy in trade with the Americas. The United States forced Japan to open its domestic
market to imports by sending a navy squadron into the
harbour of Tokyo in July 1853. In the era of geo-economics, military power no longer trumps economic
power: nobody would sink foreign export car ferries to
support domestic manufacturers or deliver import-restricted high-tech hardware by airborne assaults to
customers in need of them.
As an analytical concept, geo-economics resonates
with IR Realism. Luttwak accordingly wrote that states
‘are inherently inclined to strive for relative advantage against like entities’ (1990: 19). Geo-economics
transcends IR Realism insofar as it recognises that
geographical features that are particular to places
and spaces shape international relations and foreign
policy – not only the distribution of power amongst
states. While Structural Realism in Waltz’s (1959, 1979)
tradition is alien to geopolitical consideration, Classical Realism (e.g. Morgenthau 1948) incorporates geographical factors and some more recent contributions,
most importantly Mearsheimer’s (2001) ‘offensive realism’, refer to geographical conditions that influence
international relations and foreign policy. Nevertheless, these references to geography in contemporary IR
Realism tend to remain side issues. This focus on geographical features and the aforementioned alternative
understanding of the geo dimension – specific places
or spaces being the objective of the application of economic power – moreover help to distinguish geo-economics from IPE. Broadly defined, IPE deals with ‘the
interplay of economics and politics in the world arena’
(Frieden and Lake 2014: 1), capturing both the way in
which political decisions affect market operations and
the way in which economic forces mould political decisions. IPE scholars are broadly concerned with international economic relations. Geo-economics has a
narrower scope of interest, being limited to economic
power from a geographical and strategic viewpoint.
Mainstream IR Realism also suffers from the conviction that military issues will always trump economic considerations on the scale of strategic priorities
(e.g. Mearsheimer 2001; Waltz 1979). This overlooks
how much power politics relies on various economic
means that can be used in pursuit of strategic aims.
This is well demonstrated by the aforementioned efforts of the Obama administration to advance two economic mega-communities. And while there is, except
for the case of Russia and arguably also China, little evidence of any military balancing amongst non-Western
powers against the United States, we do observe efforts
of soft balancing – that is, balancing through non-military means (Pape 2005). The BRICS Bank is only one
emerging institution routing around the Western-led
order. China, most prominently, is using its growing
financial capacities in pursuit of its political objectives
in Asia and beyond (Huotari and Hanemann 2014;
Huotari 2018). Herein, geo-economics can contribute
to IR Realism by opening up new perspectives on the
economic power projection.
Geo-economics may also contribute IR Liberalism.
Recent years have laid bare the limitations of the liberal interdependence paradigm. In the aftermath of the
Cold War, a central belief emerged that as the world
grew economically more interdependent, states would
come to abandon power politics in favour of more
cooperative foreign policies and integration into the
liberal, rule-based world order (e.g. Ikenberry 1998;
Mandelbaum 2002). These convictions still appeal to
many influential scholars (e.g. Ikenberry 2011). Yet
what we have been witnessing for the past few years
is the simultaneous increase in interdependence and
strategic competition, even conflict, albeit often pursued by means other than military (Haass 2017; Wright
2017). In this regard, geo-economics can provide
APRIL 2018
11
analytical tools for theorising about power politics
under conditions of interdependence.
At the same time, geo-economics incorporates the
liberal conviction that domestic power constellations
are critical for foreign policy. IR Liberalism seldom
links this to the behaviour of outsiders, meaning to
the way an external power can affect the outcome of
those internal political contests. Geo-economics, by
contrast, assumes that outsiders shape the way national interests are defined. For example, US economic
‘reward power’, working through financial and trade
inducements, has empowered pro-US constituencies in Latin America, paving the way for the ‘War on
Drugs’, the ‘Washington Consensus’ and other US-led
initiatives (Long and Friedman 2017). Through various
finance, investment and trade deals, China has created
local interest groups in the Global South that lobby for
establishing closer relations with the People’s Republic
(Mattlin and Nojonen 2015; Wigell and Soliz Landivar
2018). Likewise, Russia has been pursuing various energy mega-deals, offering a range of short-term incentives for certain local actors and creating long-term
liabilities vis-à-vis Russia (Conley et al. 2017; Wigell
and Vihma 2016).
In short, we argue that existing work in the orthodox traditions of IR insufficiently addresses certain vital aspects of what goes on in contemporary
international relations. IR Liberalism overlooks how
power politics continues to be played out under conditions of interdependence and how economic power
may be used to pursue strategic goals in a confrontational manner. IR Realism downplays the fact that
economic power may often be more consequential
than military power. It also tends to neglect – albeit
not to disregard – geographical conditions as a set of
factors that influence international relations and foreign policy. IR Constructivism, particularly Critical
Geopolitics, suffers from a certain underestimation of
material conditions and how they matter regardless
of discourses. At the same time, all major IR schools
offer tie-ins for geo-economics, which, as we have
argued in this paper, provides a useful framework
for understanding the use of various economic instruments by states in the pursuit of strategic goals.
APRIL 2018
12
REFERENCES
Aaltola, Mika et al. 2014. ‘Towards the Geopolitics of Flows:
Implications for Finland’. FIIA Report 40.
Abdelal, Ravi. and Kirshner, Jonathan. (1999) ‘Strategy,
Economic Relations, and the Definition of National
Interests’, Security Studies, 9, 1-2, pp. 119–156. Barton,
Jonathan R. 1999. ‘“Flags of Convenience”: Geoeconomics and Regulatory Minimisation’. Tijdschrift voor
Economische en Sociale Geografie 90.2: 142–55.
Baru, Sanjaya. 2012. ‘Geo-economics and Strategy’. Survival 54.3: 47–58.
Blackwill, Robert D. and Harris, Jennifer M. 2016. War by
Other Means: Geoeconomics and Statecraft. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Bond, Patrick. 2004. ‘The ANC’s “Left Turn” and South
African Sub-imperialism’. Review of African Political
Economy 102: 599–616.
Buzan, Barry, Ole Wæver and Jap de Wilde. 1997. Security: A
New Framework for Analysis. Boulder: Lynne Rienner.
Coleman, Matthew. 2005. ‘U.S. Statecraft and the US–
Mexico Border as Security/Economy Nexus’. Political
Geography 24.2: 189–205.
Conley, Heather A., James Mina, Ruslan Stefanov and
Martin Vladimirov. 2016. The Kremlin Playbook:
Understanding Russian Influence in Central and
Eastern Europe (Lanham: Rowman and Littlefield).
Cowen, Deborah and Neil Smith. 2009. ‘After Geopolitics?:
From the Geopolitical Social to Geoeconomics’. Antipode 41.1: 22–48.
Dalby, Simon. 1990. Creating the Second Cold War: The
Discourse of Politics. London: Pinter.
Domosh, Mona. 2013. ‘Geoeconomic Imaginations and
Economic Geography in the Early Twentieth Century’.
Annals of the Association of American Geographers
103.4: 944–66.
Essex, James. 2013. Development, Security, and Aid: Geopolitics and Geoeconomics at the U.S. Agency for
International Development. Athens: University of
Georgia Press.
Fjäder, Christian. O. 2018 (forthcoming). ‘Interdependence as Dependence: Economic Security in the Age of
Global Interconnectedness’. In Geo-Economics and
Power Politics in the 21st Century: The Revival of
Economic Statecraft, edited by Mikael Wigell, Sören
Scholvin and Mika Aaltola. London: Routledge.
Flint, Colin. 2006. Introduction to Geopolitics. London:
Routledge.
Flynn, Matthew. 2007. ‘Between Subimperialism and Globalization: A Case Study in the Internationalization of
Brazilian Capital’. Latin American Perspectives 34.6:
9–27.
Frieden, Jeffry A. and David A. Lake. 2014. International
Political Economy: Perspectives on Global Power and
Wealth. London: Routledge.
Fukuyama, Francis. 1992. The End of History and the Last
Man. New York: Avon Books.
Grosse, Tomasz G. 2014. ‘Geoeconomic Relations between
the EU and China: The Lessons from the EU Weapon
Embargo and From Galileo’. Geopolitics 19.1: 40–65.
Haass, Richard N. 2017. A World in Disarray: American
Foreign Policy and the Crisis of the Old Order. New
York: Penguin Books.
Holslag, Jonathan. 2016. ‘Geoeconomics in a Globalized
World: the Case of China’s Export Policy’. Asia Europe
Journal 14.2: 173–84.
Hsiung, James C. 2009. ‘The Age of Geoeconomics, China’s
Global Role, and Prospects of Cross-strait Integration’.
Journal of Chinese Political Science 14.2: 113–33.
Hudson, Valerie et al. 1991. ‘Why the Third World Matters, Why Europe Probably Won’t: The Geoeconomics
of Circumscribed Engagement’. Journal of Strategic
Studies 14.3: 255–98.
Huntington, Samuel P. 1993. ‘Why International Primacy
Matters’. International Security 17.4: 68–83.
Huotari, Mikko. 2018 (forthcoming). ‘Learning Geo-economics: China’s Experimental Path towards Financial
and Monetary Leadership’. In Geo-Economics and
Power Politics in the 21st Century: The Revival of
Economic Statecraft, edited by Mikael Wigell, Sören
Scholvin and Mika Aaltola. London: Routledge.
Huotari, Mikko and Thilo Hanemann. 2014. ‘Emerging
Powers and Change in the Global Financial Order’.
Global Policy 5.3: 298–310.
Ikenberry, G. John. 1998. ‘Institutions, Strategic Restraint,
and the Persistence of American Postwar Order’.
International Security 23.3: 43–78.
Ikenberry, G. John. 2011. Liberal Leviathan: The Origin,
Crisis and Transformation of the American World
Order. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Keohane, Robert O., and Joseph S. Nye. 1977. Power and
Interdependence: World Politics in Transition.
Boston: Little, Brown.
Kundnani, Hans. 2011. ‘Germany as a Geo-economic
Power’. Washington Quarterly 34.3: 31–45.
Kundnani, Hans. 2018 (forthcoming). ‘Germany’s Liberal
Geo-economics: Using Markets for Strategic Objectives’. In Geo-Economics and Power Politics in the
21st Century: The Revival of Economic Statecraft,
edited by Mikael Wigell, Sören Scholvin and Mika Aaltola. London: Routledge.
Käpylä, Juha and Harri Mikkola. 2016. ‘The Promise of the
Geoeconomic Arctic: a Critical Analysis’. Asia Europe
Journal 14.2: 203–20.
Kärkkäinen, Anniina. 2016. ‘Does China Have a Geoeconomic Strategy Towards Zimbabwe?: The Case of the
Zimbabwean Natural Resource Sector’. Asia Europe
Journal 14.2: 185–202.
Leonard, Mark. 2016. ‘Introduction: Connectivity Wars’.
In Connectivity Wars: Why Migration, Finance and
Trade Are the Geo-economic Battlegrounds of the
Future, edited by Mark Leonard, 13–30. London:
ECFR.
Leonard, Mark (ed.). 2016. Connectivity Wars: Why
Migration, Finance and Trade Are the Geo-economic
Battlegrounds of the Future. London: ECFR.
Luttwak, Edward N. 1990. ‘From Geopolitics to Geo-economics: Logic of Conflict, Grammar of Commerce’.
National Interest 20: 17–23.
Luttwak, Edward N. 1993. The Endangered American
Dream: How to Stop the United States from Becoming
a Third-World Country and How to Win the Geo-economic Struggle for Industrial Supremacy. New York:
Simon & Schuster.
Mandelbaum, Michael. 2002. The Ideas that Conquered
the World: Peace, Democracy, and Free Markets in
the Twenty-First Century. New York: Public Affairs.
Márquez Restrepo, Martha L. 2018 (forthcoming). ‘Oil
as a Strategic Means in Venezuela’s Foreign Policy:
The Cases of ALBA and Petrocaribe, 1998–2013’. In
Geo-Economics and Power Politics in the 21st Century: The Revival of Economic Statecraft, edited
by Mikael Wigell, Sören Scholvin and Mika Aaltola.
London: Routledge.
Mattlin, Mikael and Mikael Wigell. 2016. ‘Geoeconomics in
the Context of Restive Regional Powers’. Asia Europe
Journal 14.2: 125–34.
Mattlin, Mikael and Bart Gaens. 2018. ‘Development Lending as Financial Statecraft?: A Comparative Exploration of the Practices of China and Japan’. In Geo-Economics and Power Politics in the 21st Century: The
Revival of Economic Statecraft, edited by Mikael
Wigell, Sören Scholvin and Mika Aaltola. London:
Routledge.
McDonald, David A. (ed.). 2009. Electric Capitalism,
Recolonising Africa on the Power Grid. Cape Town:
HSRC Press.
Mead, Walter. R. 2014. ‘The Return of Geopolitics: The
Revenge of the Revisionist Powers’. Foreign Affairs
93.3: 69–79.
Mearsheimer, John J. 2001. The Tragedy of Great Power
Politics. New York: Norton.
Mercille, Julien. 2008. ‘The Radical Geopolitics of US Foreign Policy: Geopolitical and Geoeconomic Logics of
Power’. Political Geography 27.5: 570–86.
Morrissey, John. 2011. ‘Closing the Neoliberal Gap: Risk
and Regulation in the Long War of Securitization’.
Antipode 43.3: 874–900.
Möttölä, Kari. 2018 (forthcoming). ‘US Grand Strategy
in Flux: Geo-economics, Geopolitics and the Liberal
International Order’. In Geo-Economics and Power
Politics in the 21st Century: The Revival of Economic
Statecraft, edited by Mikael Wigell, Sören Scholvin
and Mika Aaltola. London: Routledge.
O’Hara, Sarah and Michael Heffernan. 2006. ‘From
Geo-Strategy to Geo-economics: The “Heartland”
and British Imperialism Before and After Mackinder’.
Geopolitics 11.1: 54–73.
Ó Tuathail, Gearóid. 1998. ‘Introduction’. In The Geopolitics Reader, edited by Gearóid Ó Tuathail, Simon
Dalby and Paul Routledge, 103–13. London: Routledge.
Pape, Robert. A. 2005. ‘Soft Balancing Against the United
States’. International Security 30.1: 7–45.
Pattanaik, Smruti S. 2018 (forthcoming). ‘India, Pakistan
and the Contest for Regional Hegemony: The Role of
Geo-economics’. In Geo-Economics and Power Politics in the 21st Century: The Revival of Economic
Statecraft, edited by Mikael Wigell, Sören Scholvin
and Mika Aaltola. London: Routledge.
Rivlin, Paul. 2018 (forthcoming). ‘Leverage of Economic
Sanctions: The Case of US Sanctions against Iran,
1979–2016’. In Geo-Economics and Power Politics in
the 21st Century: The Revival of Economic Statecraft,
edited by Mikael Wigell, Sören Scholvin and Mika Aaltola. London: Routledge.
Scholvin, Sören. 2016. ‘Geographical Conditions and
Political Outcomes’. Comparative Strategy 35.4:
274–83.
Scholvin, Sören. 2018 (forthcoming). ‘Geo-economics and
Geopolitics in Sub-Saharan African Power Politics’.
In Geo-Economics and Power Politics in the 21st
Century: The Revival of Economic Statecraft, edited
by Mikael Wigell, Sören Scholvin and Mika Aaltola.
London: Routledge.
Scholvin, Sören and Peter Draper. 2012. ‘The Gateway to
Africa?: Geography and South Africa’s Role as an Economic Hinge Joint Between Africa and the World’.
South African Journal of International Affairs 19.3:
381–400.
Scholvin, Sören and Georg Strüver. 2013. ‘Tying the Region
Together or Tearing It Apart?: China and Transport
Infrastructure Projects in the SADC Region’. In Monitoring Regional Integration in Southern Africa 2012,
edited by André du Pisani, Gerhard Eramus and Trudi
Hartzenberg, 175–93. Stellenbosch: Tralac.
Scholvin, Sören and Andrés Malamud. 2014. ‘Is There a
Geoeconomic Node in South America?: Geography,
Politics and Brazil’s Role in Regional Economic Integration’. ICS Working Paper 2/2014.
Scholvin, Sören and Mikael Wigell. 2018. ‘Power Politics
by Economic Means: Geo-economics as an Analytical
Approach and Foreign Policy Practice’. Comparative
Strategy 37.1: 73–84.
Scott, David. 2008. ‘The Great Power “Great Game”
Between India and China: “The Logic of Geography”’.
Geopolitics 13.1: 1–26.
Sidaway, James D. 2005. ‘Asia–Europe–United States: The
Geoeconomics of Uncertainty’. Area 37.4: 373–77.
Smith, Neil. 2005. The Endgame of Globalization. London:
Routledge.
Sparke, Matthew. 2002. ‘Not a State, But More than a State
of Mind: Cascading Cascadias and the Geoeconomics of Cross-Border Regionalism’. In Globalization,
Regionalization and Cross-Border Regions, edited by
Markus Perkmann and Ngai-Ling Sum, 212–38. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.
Sparke, Matthew. 2006. ‘A Neoliberal Nexus: Economy,
Security and the Biopolitics of Citizenship on the
Border’. Political Geography 25.2: 151–80.
Sparke, Matthew and Victoria Lawson. 2003. ‘Entrepreneurial Political Geographies of the Global-Local Nexus’. In A Companion to Political Geography, edited by John Agnew, Katharyne Mitchell and
Gearóid O’Tuathail, 315–34. Oxford: Blackwell.
Vihma, Antto. 2017. ‘Geoeconomic Analysis and the Limits
of Critical Geopolitics: A New Engagement with
Edward Luttwak’. Geopolitics 23.1: 1–12.
Vihma, Antto and Mikael Wigell. 2016. ‘Unclear and Present Danger: Russia’s Geoeconomics and the Nord
Stream II Pipeline’. Global Affairs 2.4: 377–88.
Waltz, Kenneth. 1979. Theory of International Politics.
Reading: Addison-Wesley.
White House. 2017. ‘National Security Strategy of the
United States of America’. http://nssarchive.us/
wp-content/uploads/2017/12/2017.pdf (10 January
2018).
Wigell, Mikael. 2016. ‘Conceptualizing Regional Powers’
Geoeconomic Strategies: Neo-Imperialism, Neo-Mercantilism, Hegemony, and Liberal Institutionalism’.
Asia Europe Journal 14.2: 135–51.
Wigell, Mikael and Antto Vihma. 2016. ‘Geopolitics versus
Geoeconomics: The Case of Russia’s Changing Geostrategy and Its Effects on the EU’. International
Affairs 92.3: 605–27.
Wigell, Mikael, Sören Scholvin and Mika Aaltola (eds). 2018
(forthcoming). Geo-Economics and Power Politics in
the 21st Century: The Revival of Economic Statecraft.
London: Routledge.
Wigell, Mikael and Ana Soliz Landivar. 2018 (forthcoming). ‘China’s Economic Statecraft in Latin America:
Geostrategic Implications for the United States’. In
Geo-Economics and Power Politics in the 21st Century: The Revival of Economic Statecraft, edited
by Mikael Wigell, Sören Scholvin and Mika Aaltola.
London: Routledge.
World Economic Forum. 2016. ‘The Age of Economic Coercion: How Geo-politics is Disrupting Supply Chains,
Financial Systems, Energy Markets, Trade and the
http://www3.weforum.org/docs/WEF_
Internet’.
Age_of_Economic_coercion.pdf (14 January 2018).
Wright, Thomas J. 2017. All Measures Short of War: The
Contest for the 21st Century and the Future of American Power. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Youngs, Richard. 2011. ‘Geo-economic Futures’. In Challenges for European Foreign Policy in 2012: What
Kind of Geo-economic Europe?, edited by Ana Martiningui and Richard Youngs, 13–17. Madrid: FRIDE.
Yu, Lei. 2015. ‘China’s Strategic Partnership with Latin
America: A Fulcrum in China’s Rise’. International
Affairs 91.5: 1047–68.