Michael W. Macya,b,1 , Manqing Mac,d,1 , Daniel R. Tabinc,d , Jianxi Gaoc,d , and Boleslaw K. Szymanskic,d,e,2
SPECIAL FEATURE
Polarization and tipping points
a
Department of Information Science, Cornell University, Ithaca, NY 14853; b Department of Sociology, Cornell University, Ithaca, NY 14850; c Department of
Computer Science, Rensselaer Polytechnic Institute, Troy, NY 12180; d Network Science and Technology Center, Rensselaer Polytechnic Institute, Troy, NY
12180; and e Institute of Computer Technologies, Społeczna Akademia Nauk, 90-113 Łódź, Poland
polarization | phase transition | tipping points | hysteresis dynamics
factions together, even in the face of a common threat. Our interest in this problem is motivated by a series of crises that might
be expected to activate a broad political identity and unified
response: the Great Recession, Russian electoral interference,
impending climate catastrophe, a global pandemic, and, most
recently, the January 6 attack on the US Congress. It is not
surprising that these events prompted a call to arms. What is
surprising is the direction in which the arms were pointed.
Our goal is not to explain polarization, about which there is an
extensive literature and a lively debate. Instead, we focus narrowly on a phase analysis of polarization, a problem that has
largely escaped attention in previous research. We use a general
model of opinion dynamics to demonstrate the existence of tipping points, at which even an external threat may be insufficient
to reverse the self-reinforcing dynamics of political polarization.
Polarization reaches a tipping point when the rate of increase
suddenly accelerates and when the process displays a phase
change characterized by asymmetric hysteresis loops. The existence of a tipping point in a self-reinforcing dynamic is neither
inevitable nor especially counterintuitive. However, the existence
of multiple tipping points, one when polarization is increasing
and another when it is decreasing, cannot be assumed. Moreover, if the threshold on the downward trajectory falls below the
threshold going up, the dynamics can be hard to reverse. This
study is motivated by the need to call greater attention to that
possibility.
Model
Our model is preceded by the Szymanski model presented in Lu
et al. (8). The Szymanski model applies to polarization among
Downloaded by guest on January 27, 2022
D
emocratic societies thrive on disagreement, debate, and
intense competition among multiple interest groups (1).
Nevertheless, there is growing recognition that political division
can become a liability for democratic governance when multiple lines of controversy become aligned with partisan identities
(2). Political scientists refer to this crystallization of opinion as
“constraint” (3) and point to two principal reasons for concern:
partisan division and extremism. First, the alignment of substantively unrelated issues (e.g., capital punishment, reproductive
rights, and gun control) attenuates intraparty differences, subdues political cacophony, and rearranges an ideological mosaic
into two diametrically opposed political camps (4). Second, issue
alignment and factional bifurcation allow differences of opinion to reinforce one another such that moderate voices become
muffled and the distribution of opinion becomes increasingly
bimodal (5). Analyses of roll-call voting show that political elites
have adopted more extreme positions on core political issues in
recent decades (6), while polarization among voters has become
mainly affective rather than ideological (7). This combination
of partisan division and political extremism can eviscerate the
“cross-cutting cleavages” on which pluralistic diversity depends,
thereby undermining the capacity for compromise required for
effective democratic governance.
In this paper, we point to a third danger, one that has received
too little attention in the growing literature on political and cultural polarization: the existence of a tipping point beyond which
the activation of shared interests can no longer bring warring
PNAS 2021 Vol. 118 No. 50 e2102144118
Significance
Our study was motivated by a highly disturbing puzzle. Confronted with a deadly global pandemic that threatened not
only massive loss of life but also the collapse of our medical
system and economy, why were we unable to put partisan
divisions aside and unite in a common cause, similar to the
national mobilization in the Great Depression and the Second
World War? We used a computational model to search for an
answer in the phase transitions of political polarization. The
model reveals asymmetric hysteresis trajectories with tipping
points that are hard to predict and that make polarization
extremely difficult to reverse once the level exceeds a critical
value.
Author contributions: M.W.M., M.M., J.G., and B.K.S. designed research; M.W.M., M.M.,
D.R.T., and B.K.S. performed research; M.W.M., M.M., D.R.T., J.G., and B.K.S. analyzed
data; M.W.M., M.M., D.R.T., J.G., and B.K.S. wrote the paper; M.W.M., M.M., and B.K.S.
designed simulation experiments; M.W.M., M.M., and D.R.T. implemented software.y
The authors declare no competing interest.y
This article is a PNAS Direct Submission.y
Published under the PNAS license.y
1
M.W.M. and M.M. contributed equally to this work.y
2
To whom correspondence may be addressed. Email: szymab@rpi.edu.y
This article contains supporting information online at https://www.pnas.org/lookup/suppl/
doi:10.1073/pnas.2102144118/-/DCSupplemental.y
Published December 6, 2021.
https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.2102144118 | 1 of 9
POLITICAL SCIENCES
Research has documented increasing partisan division and
extremist positions that are more pronounced among political
elites than among voters. Attention has now begun to focus on
how polarization might be attenuated. We use a general model
of opinion change to see if the self-reinforcing dynamics of influence and homophily may be characterized by tipping points that
make reversibility problematic. The model applies to a legislative body or other small, densely connected organization, but
does not assume country-specific institutional arrangements that
would obscure the identification of fundamental regularities in
the phase transitions. Agents in the model have initially random locations in a multidimensional issue space consisting of
membership in one of two equal-sized parties and positions on
10 issues. Agents then update their issue positions by moving
closer to nearby neighbors and farther from those with whom
they disagree, depending on the agents’ tolerance of disagreement and strength of party identification compared to their
ideological commitment to the issues. We conducted computational experiments in which we manipulated agents’ tolerance
for disagreement and strength of party identification. Importantly, we also introduced exogenous shocks corresponding to
events that create a shared interest against a common threat
(e.g., a global pandemic). Phase diagrams of political polarization reveal difficult-to-predict transitions that can be irreversible
due to asymmetric hysteresis trajectories. We conclude that future
empirical research needs to pay much closer attention to the
identification of tipping points and the effectiveness of possible
countermeasures.
COMPUTER SCIENCES
Edited by Helen V. Milner, Princeton University, Princeton, NJ, and approved July 2, 2021 (received for review March 1, 2021)
Downloaded by guest on January 27, 2022
legislators in a two-party political system. Legislators reveal their
positions on issues through votes on bills. The Rice Index (9)
of voting behavior measures partisan polarization. The dynamics are governed by differential equations that assume legislators
optimize their chances of reelection by aligning their votes with
the needs of their constituents, parties, and donors, whose influence acts as an invisible hand (10), balancing legislators’ and
parties’ commitment to partisan and bipartisan strategies. The
authors fitted the model parameters to training data and demonstrated its strong predictive power on voting records of the last
30 US Congresses.
Following Lu et al. (8), we model partisan polarization at the
elite level, not in the general population. (By endowing a social
network with local structure, our model becomes applicable to
much larger populations with lower density of interaction, but
we leave that investigation to future research.) However, unlike
Lu et al. (8), the model in this study is not intended as a tool for
empirical prediction. Instead, we use a theoretical model to look
for tipping points in the system-level dynamics that emerge out of
a set of assumptions about interpersonal interaction. Although a
legislative body is the prototypical application, unlike Lu et al.
(8), our model is not based on the Congress of the United States
or any other country, and there are no legislature-specific institutional assumptions that would prevent the model from being
applied to any small, densely connected organization. By design,
the model omits distinctive features that would limit its applicability to a particular organizational setting, such as pressure
from lobbyists or constituents, internal organizational structure
that constrains access to other members, or power differentials
between organizational leaders who can sanction noncompliant members. The model avoids specific institutional practices,
customs, or formal rules that might constrain behavior. These
complications are abstracted away so that we can investigate general properties of tipping points in the polarization of opinion
that might arise in diverse organizational settings. A model that
does not correspond to any particular empirical instantiation can
thereby also be said to capture lawful regularities that may be
broadly relevant.
The model in this study also differs from Lu et al. (8) in
that it is agent-based rather than equation-based. An agentbased model can be conceptualized as a “population of models,”
in contrast with an equation-based “model of a population”
(11). In the latter, features of the system interact (e.g., the
size, density, clustering, and polarization of the population).
In an agent-based model, the agents interact, such that the
properties of the system emerge out of the dynamics of their
interactions. Like equation-based models, agent-based models
can be empirically calibrated for predictive accuracy. Alternatively, the models can also be highly abstract, based on a set of
simple, but plausible, behavioral assumptions, similar to gametheoretic models used to explore the complexity of cooperation
(12) or tipping points in neighborhood segregation (13). Both
approaches—empirical prediction and theoretical exploration—
are useful for the study of polarization, but the approach here
is theoretical. As in game-theoretic applications, the goal is to
generate hypotheses, leaving their testing to follow-up empirical
studies.
Attribute Set. Each agent has an attribute set M consisting of
the agent’s party identity and the agent’s positions on issues.
Although legislators occasionally change parties, we assume that
party identity is a fixed binary attribute. For simplicity, we assume
there are only two parties, each with 50 members (like the
current US Senate), but the model generalizes to multiparty
systems with a governing (majority) coalition and a minority
opposition. (Robustness tests show that the two-party results
generalize to multiparty systems; see SI Appendix, Figs. S5–S7 for
details.)
2 of 9 | PNAS
https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.2102144118
Unlike party identification, positions on issues are continuous
and susceptible to change. An agent’s position on an issue can
range continuously from +1 (extreme support) to −1 (extreme
opposition). We limit the number of salient issues to 10, which
is more than sufficient to ensure that polarization must arise out
of cross-cutting cleavages; i.e., two agents who agree on some
issues might nevertheless disagree on others. (See SI Appendix,
Fig. S1 for robustness tests for the number of dimensions.) Were
the model limited to only one issue dimension, such cross-cutting
divisions could not occur. In contrast, if two agents happen to
disagree on one issue, agreement on a second issue will greatly
increase the similarity between the agents, and the resulting
increase in attraction could then lead one of the two agents to
switch sides on the issue on which the agents disagreed. Although
a single issue is insufficient, there is little to be gained by having more than 10 issues. If two agents happen to disagree on 10
issues, agreement on an 11th issue will have relatively little effect
on the overall similarity between their opinion profiles. In short,
allowing only one issue would make polarization trivially easy,
but as more dimensions are added to the model, the distribution
of opinion on each additional dimension has a declining effect
on the polarization dynamics.
Influence. We incorporate two core assumptions that inform pre-
vious computational models of opinion dynamics: influence and
homophily (14–17). Influence refers to repositioning of an agent
on issues in response to neighbors to whom the agent is attracted.
Homophily refers to an agent’s attraction to a network neighbor
that increases with the similarity of their attribute sets. Influence and homophily can create a self-reinforcing dynamic, in
which agreement strengthens influence, which then attenuates
remaining disagreement.
Nearly all previous models of opinion dynamics shared the
assumption that influence is positive, thereby strengthening
agreement. However, Schelling (13) famously showed how stable
division (e.g., residential segregation) emerges when influence
is negative, thereby exacerbating differences, as when in-group
neighbors are influenced to move out in response to out-group
members who move in. In this context, negative influence is not
to be confused with influence to adopt a peer’s negatively valued trait (e.g., smoking or vandalism). Rather, negative influence
refers to the tendency for an in-group member to differentiate from an out-group neighbor. Applied to opinion dynamics,
negative influence (or “distancing”) has also been shown to generate polarization into opposing ideological camps (18–20), an
empirical pattern that is dramatically illustrated by historical
data on partisan differences of opinion regarding global warming (SI Appendix, Fig. S10). We model positive and negative
influence by assuming that an agent adjusts its positions on
issues to be closer to a neighbor to whom the agent is attracted
and to differentiate from a neighbor from whom the agent is
repelled (4).
Homophily. Axelrod (14) showed how homophily can create local
communities demarcated by impermeable cultural boundaries
that preclude influence between members of different communities that have no shared attributes. Although Axelrod assumed
discrete attributes, the dynamics were generalized to continuous
attributes in models of “bounded confidence” (15, 16). Even with
discrete attributes, cultural differentiation in the Axelrod model
has been shown to eventually collapse into monoculture due to
cultural drift (21).
Importantly, collapse into monoculture does not occur if
homophily (the principle that “likes attract”) is combined with
xenophobia, in which “opposites repel” (4). As with bounded
confidence models (15, 16), our agents have a threshold for tolerance of disagreement. The threshold defines a reference distance
that an agent compares with the distance to a neighbor when
Macy et al.
Polarization and tipping points
[1]
where the weight β ∈ [0, 1] is a continuous exogenous parameter
that corresponds to party identification.
In sum, our model borrows from the classic models of
Schelling (negative influence) and Axelrod (homophily), along
with models of bounded confidence (threshold distances). Our
contribution is not in proposing a new model of opinion dynamics or a new explanation of polarization. Instead, we narrowly
focus on a single question: Is there a tipping point beyond which
polarization becomes difficult or impossible to reverse, even in
response to exogenous shocks that pose a shared threat?
Exogenous Shocks. Following Condie and Condie (22), we model
Downloaded by guest on January 27, 2022
exogenous shocks as potentially unifying events, such as a global
pandemic, economic collapse, attack by a foreign adversary or
terrorist (whether foreign or domestic), or impending climatic
catastrophe. The shock is implemented by creating an additional
issue on which all agents strongly agree. (Our model also predicts other responses to exogenous shocks, such as changes in
party affiliation, but we leave these possibilities for future investigations and focus here on bipartisan unity in the face of a
common threat.) The responses to shocks are driven by the levels of polarization at the time they arise. The shock occurs at
a level of polarization that is manipulated as a control parameter. When the shock occurs at time step ts , every agent i adds
a new issue M + 1 and sets it to Zi,ts = 1, regardless of party
identity or positions on the other 10 issues. An exogenous weight
parameter γ controls the importance of the shock relative to the
other 11 attributes in calculating Dij . Agents then update their
positions on the shock issue in the same way they update positions on other issues through the positive and negative influence
of other agents.
Model Execution. At time t = 0, each agent i is assigned an initial vector Zi,0 of M = 11 dimensions. The first dimension is
binary and static, corresponding to party identity. The other 10
dimensions are continuous and change over time, corresponding to positions on issues. Agents are initialized with a randomly
assigned party identity (either −1 or 1), while location on each
issue is randomly drawn from a normal distribution with mean
zero and SD 0.25, with the range truncated where necessary to
the unit interval in absolute value. Thus, at time t = 0, the parties
have no preexisting ideological differences, and an agent’s position on a given issue cannot be predicted from the agent’s party
identity or position on any of the other dimensions. The ranMacy et al.
Polarization and tipping points
P+ =
1
1+e
m (Dij −(1−α))
.
[2]
We set m = 10, but the results are robust as the function
approaches a deterministic threshold with m ≫ 10. However, as
m approaches one, the function becomes linear, which introduces sufficient noise to attenuate (but not eliminate) polarization. (See SI Appendix, Fig. S2 for tests of the robustness of the
results to different values of m.)
If j ’s influence is positive, Zid,t+1 is a weighted average of Zid,t
and Zjd,t on each dynamic dimension d :
Zid,t+1 = Zid,t + (L − Zid,t )|Dij − c|ran,
[3]
where ran is a uniform random real number in the unit interval, d is the dimension that is updated, c = 1, and L = Zjd,t . The
expression L − Zid,t in Eq. 3 defines the distance i must move to
reach j on d . The expression |Dij − c| means that the fraction of
that distance that i will move decreases with the overall distance
between i and j across all M dimensions (including d ). Simply
put, the smaller the disagreement on a given issue, the easier it
is to resolve, in accordance with the principle of homophily (or
likes attract).
If j ’s influence is negative, then c = 0 and i moves away from
j in the direction that increases the distance from i to j on
each dynamic dimension d . The value of L depends on values
of Zid,t , Zjd,t . If Zid,t > Zjd,t or Zid,t = Zjd,t < 0, then L = 1. If
Zid,t < Zjd,t or Zid,t = Zjd,t > 0, then L = −1. If Zid,t = Zjd,t = 0,
and L is chosen randomly to be 1 with probability 0.5 and −1
otherwise. As the distance from i to j increases along each
dynamic dimension d , the maximum possible distance from i to
L decreases; i.e., the distance that i needs to move to be as far
away from j as possible decreases, while the fraction of that distance that i moves away from j increases with the overall distance
Dij . In short, negative influence is the mirror image of positive
PNAS | 3 of 9
https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.2102144118
SPECIAL FEATURE
COMPUTER SCIENCES
Dij = Dijparty β + Dijissues (1 − β),
dom start is not meant to correspond to the historical origins of
political parties in the real world. On the contrary, newly formed
parties often emerge with extreme polarization levels, as noted
by Madison in The Federalist Papers. However, previous theoretical research cautions against starting the model in a converged
state, since doing so might obscure the possibility that the system dynamics cannot reach that equilibrium. Instead, van Strien
et al. (23) and Brändle et al. (24) demonstrate that repeating initialization with random starting positions in agent-based models
is a reliable way of finding stability points. In addition to the random start, we model hysteresis loops by starting in a completely
polarized configuration to see if polarization eventually collapses
as the control parameters decline. (See SI Appendix, Figs. S1
and S5–S7 for robustness tests for the number of dimensions
and parties.)
Following initialization at time step t = 0, an agent i is randomly chosen to update its state at the next time step t + 1 by
the influence of a neighbor j randomly chosen without regard to
party; i.e., members are equally likely to be influenced by members of the other party. The agent then updates its state Zi,t
to a new state Zi,t+1 in response to the state of its neighbor,
Zj ,t , as follows. First, i assesses its proximity to j relative to a
continuous intolerance parameter α ∈ [0, 1] that is identical for
all agents and represents the minimum distance for tolerance
of disagreement. If α = 0, every distance Dij will be tolerated,
and all influence will be positive; thus, i will move closer to j
on each issue. If α = 1, no distance will be tolerated, and all
influence will be negative; thus, i will move away from j on
each issue.
Formally, the probability of positive influence (P+ ) is a cumulative logistic function of the distance Dij between i and j with
steepness m as follows:
POLITICAL SCIENCES
deciding whether to move closer to or farther from this neighbor.
As the reference distance approaches one, the agent becomes
highly intolerant, such that even small disagreements on the
issues are unacceptable. As the reference distance decreases, the
agent becomes more open-minded and willing to listen to and
compromise, even with those whose opinions on the issues differ
sharply.
Formally, agents’ responses to their neighbors depend on their
proximity to their neighbors in an M-dimensional attribute space
that includes party identity and positions on issues. The closer
an agent is to its neighbor across all dimensions, the more likely
the neighbor’s influence will be positive rather than negative. An
agent i’s distance Dij to a neighbor j is the weighted average
of their Euclidean distances on the 10 issues and their distance
as party members. Agents from the same party have zero partisan distance, and agents from different parties have distance one.
The agents also have continuous Euclidean distances over the 10
issues, rescaled to a minimum of zero (the agents are identical on
all issues) to one (the agents maximally disagree on all issues).
The overall distance between two agents is then the weighted
average of their partisan distance and ideological distances:
influence: The larger the disagreement between neighbors, the
harder it is to resolve, in accordance with the principle of
xenophobia (or opposites repel).
After updating all 10 issues, another i, j pair is randomly
drawn, and the time step increments by one. The process iterates
until it either stabilizes in a steady state or reaches an arbitrary
time limit.
The model records two measures of polarization at each time
step: partisan polarization and extremism. Partisan polarization
is measured as the expected difference on a randomly chosen
issue between randomly chosen members of the two political
parties. The range is from zero (no difference on any issue) to
one (maximum possible differences on every issue). Extremism
is measured as the expected SD for a randomly chosen issue (i.e.,
the mean of the SDs over all issues).
Parameters. We manipulate four global parameters hypothesized
to exhibit tipping dynamics:
• α is the minimum distance for tolerance of disagreement, used
to investigate the effects of intolerance toward those with dissimilar issue positions and party identity, as α increases from
zero (complete tolerance) to one (complete intolerance).
• β is the importance of party identity relative to positions on
issues in Dij , used to investigate the effects of party identification as β increases from zero (party is ignored) to one (issues
are ignored).
• γ is the strength of the shock relative to all other dimensions in
Dij , used to find the magnitude of the shock needed to reverse
polarization as γ increases from zero (shock is ignored) to one
(all else is ignored).
• σ is the level of extremism at which an exogenous shock
occurs, used to investigate the reversibility of polarization
as σ increases from zero (no polarization) to one (complete
polarization).
Although intolerance and party identification are agent-level
attributes that can vary locally within an organization, our interest is in comparisons across organizations, not across individuals
within an organization. We therefore assume every agent in the
entire population has an identical value on these parameters and
observe how the level of polarization changes as this value differs
across organizations. In addition, when the parameters take limiting expected values, the population variance must go to zero.
By holding the variance constant at zero, we isolate the effect
of manipulating the parameter level from changes in parameter
variance. (We tested the robustness of the results for midrange
parameter settings using Gaussian distributions and found little
Downloaded by guest on January 27, 2022
A
B
C
change.) Lastly, the logistic probability function in Eq. 2 means
that two agents can have opposite responses to a neighbor, even
when all else is identical.
Intolerance and party identification are also modeled as independent control parameters. The correlation between these
parameters has varied historically. For example, in the 1960s,
party identification was relatively low in the United States, and
some of the most intense conflicts happened within parties (e.g.,
divisions over civil rights, Vietnam, and environmental protection). More recently, intense partisanship has been accompanied
by intolerance of disagreement, especially disagreement from
within one’s own party. We use a computational experiment to
identify the independent effects of two processes that are rarely
independent in natural settings.
Results
We analyze tipping points in polarization as we vary the levels of party identity, tolerance of disagreement, and the timing
and importance of exogenous shocks. Fig. 1 frames the central
question that motivates our study: Can we reverse polarization
by reducing the level of the factors that cause polarization to
increase? The answer is “yes” if the phase transition is linear or
sigmoidal (Fig. 1 A and B). The answer is “maybe” if the transition is a first-order knife-edge transition with a sudden regime
shift (Fig. 1C) or a hysteresis loop with two different thresholds
for forward and backward transitions (Fig. 1D). The answer is
“no” if the transition involves an asymmetric hysteresis trajectory
with bifurcation (Fig. 1E).
Fig. 1C illustrates the intuition that if polarization increases
as the control parameter increases, then we might expect that
polarization also decreases as the control parameter decreases,
even when correlated vectors are characterized by a phase transition (as in Fig. 1C). In short, Fig. 1C provides the context for
calling attention to the possibility (illustrated in Fig. 1 D and
E) that polarization might instead fail to decrease. The key difference between Fig. 1 D and C is the existence of two critical
points: CP , at which polarization starts to rise uncontrollably,
and CR , at which recovery from high polarization is possible.
If CP > CR (i.e., the loop runs counter-clockwise), reducing the
level of the control parameter to CP would not be sufficient to
reduce the level of polarization; the control parameter needs
to drop all the way down to CR . Hence, the greater the asymmetry in the critical values, the farther the control parameter
must be reduced below CP before there will be any effect on
polarization.
Fig. 1E shows an asymmetric hysteresis loop that is irreversible. The important difference from Fig. 1D is the
D
E
Fig. 1. Schematic of phase transitions. A and B show continuous phase transitions that lack a tipping point. C is a discontinuous knife-edge (first-order)
transition that is hard to predict but usually reversible. D illustrates a phase transition with a sudden catastrophic shift between alternative stable states in a
hysteretic loop with two different thresholds for forward transition to polarization (CP ) and backward transition to recovery (CR ). A reduction in the control
parameter to below CP is insufficient for recovery but a further reduction could eventually allow recovery to occur. In E, recovery is no longer possible, no
matter how low the control parameter might go.
4 of 9 | PNAS
https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.2102144118
Macy et al.
Polarization and tipping points
Downloaded by guest on January 27, 2022
A
B
C
D
Fig. 2. Tipping points in the level of party identity. Polarization is measured as partisan difference (A and C) and extremism (B and D). A and B show a
higher critical value in the polarizing trajectory than in the recovery trajectory. This means that there would be little effect on partisan divisions (A) or
extremism (B) should the strength of party identity drop below CP , the critical value at which rising polarization suddenly explodes. CP drops sharply when
the level of intolerance increases from α = 0.1 to α = 0.3 (C and D); i.e., party identity does not need to be strong in order to trigger a phase transition to
high polarization. Moreover, the hysteresis trajectory becomes asymmetric, indicating bifurcation and the irreversibility of polarization, even if the strength
of party identity were to drop to zero.
Macy et al.
Polarization and tipping points
PNAS | 5 of 9
https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.2102144118
SPECIAL FEATURE
COMPUTER SCIENCES
erance, the differences between the two parties will be difficult
to reduce by lowering the strength of party identity. With only
moderate intolerance, it becomes impossible.
Fig. 3 is similar to Fig. 2, except that the dynamics are driven
by intolerance. Fig. 3 A and B show the phase transition for two
values of party identity, β = 0.3 and β = 0.5. Fig. 3 A and C
measure polarization as partisan differences and Fig. 3 B and D
as extremism. The results show that, above the critical point for
polarization, a subsequent decrease in political intolerance will
not bring the parties back together (Fig. 3A) or reduce extremism (Fig. 3B) until the level of intolerance has dropped far below
the level at which polarization increased. Fig. 3 C and D show
that an increase in party identity shrinks the width of the hysteresis loop, but as we observed in Fig. 2, this does not mean
polarization becomes more easily reversed. On the contrary, an
increase in party identity reduces CR even further, approaching the point of bifurcation, at which polarization cannot
be reversed.
Fig. 4 reports the phase analysis for an external shock about
which all agents initially agree. In all three panels α = β = 0.5.
When the shock occurs, there is a “tug of war” between the
ability of the shock to spread agreement to the other issues vs.
the other issues spreading disagreement to the shock. Fig. 4A
shows a clockwise hysteresis loop as the strength of the shock
increases. There is a critical level of γ (CR ) above which a shock
nearly always leads to recovery, even if the shock occurs at or
near full polarization. There is a second critical level of γ (CP <
CR ), below which a shock almost never leads to recovery, even
if the shock occurs at or near zero polarization. Between these
two critical points, a shock may or may not lead to recovery,
depending on the level of polarization at which the shock occurs.
Fig. 4 B and C illustrate bifurcation in the polarization trajectories for shocks that occur within the critical region depicted
POLITICAL SCIENCES
disappearance of CR . That is because the “gap” between the critical points in Fig. 1E is even more extreme than it is in Fig. 1D,
and CR is below the minimal value of the control parameter. In
short, in Fig. 1D, a reduction in the control parameter to below CR
is insufficient for recovery, but a further reduction could eventually allow the system to recover. In Fig. 1E, recovery is no longer
possible, no matter how low the control parameter might go.
Figs. 2–4 reveal a hysteresis phase transition as we increase
the levels of party identity (Fig. 2), intolerance of disagreement
(Fig. 3), and the strength of an exogenous shock (Fig. 4). Fig. 2
shows the phase transition for party identity using two values of
intolerance (α = 0.1 and α = 0.3; we examine additional parameter combinations in Fig. 5). Polarization is measured as partisan
differences (Fig. 2 A and C) and extremism (Fig. 2 B and D).
(The phase transition is illustrated with a single realization of
the model; see SI Appendix, Fig. S3 for nearly identical results
based on the mean over 20 realizations.) The recovery trajectory with α = 0.1 (Fig. 2A) has a much smaller critical value
(CR ) than the forward trajectory. This means that a reduction in
the strength of party identity will have no effect on reducing the
level of polarization unless the strength of party identity declines
far below CP , the critical value for polarization to increase. The
explanation is intuitive: Once the two parties differ on the issues,
polarization no longer requires a strong party identity (relative
to the importance of issues) in assessing the distance to other
agents (Dij ).
With slightly greater intolerance (α = 0.3), the dynamics
become even more troubling. In Fig. 2 C and D, party identity
does not need to be strong in order to trigger a phase transition to high polarization. Moreover, the hysteresis trajectory
becomes asymmetric, indicating bifurcation and the irreversibility of polarization, even if the strength of party identity were to
drop to zero. In sum, Fig. 2 shows that, even with minimal intol-
A
B
C
D
Downloaded by guest on January 27, 2022
Fig. 3. Tipping points in the level of intolerance. The tipping point for intolerance is similar to the dynamics in Fig. 2. A and B show the phase transition
for two values of party identity, β = 0.3 and β = 0.5. Beyond a critical point CP , a subsequent increase in political tolerance will not bring the parties back
together (A) or reduce extremism (B), unless the level of intolerance has dropped far below the level at which polarization increased. C and D show that
an increase in party identity shrinks the size of the hysteresis loop by reducing CR even further, approaching the point of bifurcation at which polarization
cannot be reversed.
in Fig. 4A (γ = 0.45). The black lines show the trajectories of
the 10 preexisting issues (excluding the shock), and orange shows
the trajectories of disagreement regarding the shock. The shock
occurs at a level of polarization (σ = 0.65) at which the probability to polarize reaches 0.5. Fig. 4B shows how a shock can reverse
a polarizing trajectory, while Fig. 4C shows how the recovery can
also fail, even though all parameters are identical to those in Fig.
4B. Although the probability of polarization increases linearly
with the level of polarization at which the shock occurs, there is
no change in the bifurcation of the trajectories. (See SI Appendix,
Fig. S8 for changes in the probability of recovery with changes in
the level of polarization at which the shock occurs and for shocks
with higher and lower salience; see SI Appendix, Fig. S4 for populations with higher and lower levels of party identification and
intolerance.)
Fig. 5 generalizes the results in Figs. 2 and 3 to the entire
range of party identity and intolerance. The red surface shows
the forward trajectory as polarization increases, and the blue surface shows the recovery. The critical points (where the trajectory
experiences a sharp change) are indicated in green along the cliff
edge. The void between the red and blue regions corresponds
to the hysteresis loops in Fig. 3 (in Fig. 5 A and B) and in Fig.
2 (in Fig. 5 C and D). The width of the loops decreases from
front to back, due to the larger decrease in the critical values
for polarization compared to the decrease in critical values for
recovery.
In all four panels, polarization becomes increasingly hard to
reverse as party identity and intolerance increase. It is not surprising that polarization increases with the strength of party
identity and intolerance. Intuitively, we would then expect polarization to diminish should party identity and intolerance decline.
Fig. 5 shows that this is not necessarily the case. Across much of
the parameter space, polarization tends to persist, even after the
conditions that caused it are abated.
6 of 9 | PNAS
https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.2102144118
Discussion
We use a general model of opinion dynamics to demonstrate
the existence of tipping points, at which even an external threat,
such as a global pandemic, economic collapse, foreign adversary, climate change, or a violent assault on Congress, may
be insufficient to reverse the self-reinforcing dynamics of partisan polarization. Polarization reaches a tipping point when
the rate of increase suddenly accelerates and when the process displays a phase change characterized by an asymmetric
hysteresis loop. The model applies to small, densely connected
organizations like a legislative body, but abstracts away empirical
particularities, such as organizational structure and institutional
arrangements, in order to investigate phase transitions in the
self-reinforcing dynamics of influence and homophily. Our modeling strategy most closely resembles Schelling’s (13) seminal
demonstration of a tipping point in neighborhood segregation
using a simple checkerboard. The core assumption in our model
is the self-reinforcing dynamics of influence and homophily:
Influence leads individuals to adopt the opinions of those to
whom they are attracted and to differentiate from an out-group,
while homophily sorts the population into mutually antagonistic
clusters of like-minded combatants.
We measure polarization as the levels of extremism and partisan division. Extremism in the distribution of opinion indicates
the erosion of common ground on which people can agree.
Partisan division indicates the alignment of issues and the disappearance of the “cross-cutting cleavages” that pluralists have
long regarded as the bedrock of a stable democracy (25).
Tipping points in political polarization are important for two
reasons. First, the existence and location of phase transitions
can be hard to predict, obscuring the risk of an impending collapse of common ground. Second, phase transitions can preclude
the ability to recover the previous state, as occurred with the
split of Czechoslovakia in 1993. We look for tipping points by
Macy et al.
Polarization and tipping points
SPECIAL FEATURE
manipulating three exogenous parameters: party identification,
intolerance of those who disagree, and external shocks that introduce a new issue on which a population is united. Phase diagrams
reveal a difficult-to-predict transition that can be irreversible if
recovery follows an asymmetric hysteresis trajectory. Above a
threshold level of polarization, remediation may be unable to offset the self-reinforcing dynamics of increasing division, such that
polarization becomes difficult or impossible to reverse.
The tipping dynamics of party identity are revealing.
Intuitively, it might appear that a decline in issue importance
relative to party membership would lead to interparty disagreement, but that is not what we observe. Instead, party identity
becomes an organizing template that aligns issue positions into
a polarized pattern. The level of partisan division undergoes a
knife-edge transition at a critical point in the level of party identification. Moreover, once issues have become aligned with a party,
the polarization persists unchanged, even if party identification
were to all but disappear. Political intolerance displays similar phase dynamics, with a hard-to-predict critical point beyond
which polarization becomes unlikely to reverse, even with an
infusion of open-minded pragmatism.
The response of the system to an external shock is particularly alarming. The shock rallies both sides to a common cause
on a highly salient issue. Above a critical level of salience (i.e.,
the strength of the shock relative to preexisting issues), unity
in the face of a common threat brings people together, increasing
Macy et al.
Polarization and tipping points
the strength of mutual attraction and attenuating disagreement
on previously contentious issues. The shock thus reverses what
had been a steadily rising level of partisan and ideological division. However, the opposite happens if the level of salience
falls below a tipping point. Instead of coming together, deep
divisions on other issues can metastasize to the external shock,
depending on the level of polarization when the shock occurs.
The implications of our findings go beyond the demonstration
that polarization can attenuate the unifying response to external shocks. Future research might also examine the effects of
a shock on party realignment, as happened in the 1930s New
Deal realignment following the economic collapse of 1929 (26).
If parties are internally divided in their response to the shock,
our model predicts a dynamic in which factions within opposing parties could become attracted to one another and repelled
by members of their own party. In short, the results suggest
hypotheses about the timing, length, and impact of shocks that
present an agenda for future empirical research that is of both
theoretical and practical importance.
We see indications of empirical validation in recent events.
Prior to 2019, one might have assumed that a global pandemic
would bring together those who disagreed on issues for which
hot-button righteous indignation was a luxury that could no
longer be afforded. Instead, mask wearing became a partisan
crest that identified friend and foe on a partisan battlefield. Similar dynamics can be observed in the two impeachment trials of
PNAS | 7 of 9
https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.2102144118
POLITICAL SCIENCES
COMPUTER SCIENCES
Downloaded by guest on January 27, 2022
Fig. 4. Tipping points in the effects of an exogenous shock. In all three panels, α = β = 0.5. A shows a clockwise hysteresis loop traversed by the system
with the increasing strength of an external shock, about which all agents initially agree. B and C illustrate bifurcation in the polarization trajectories for
shocks that occur within the critical region depicted in A (γ = 0.45). The black lines show the trajectories of the 10 preexisting issues (excluding the shock),
and orange shows the trajectories of disagreement regarding the shock. The shock occurs at a level of polarization (σ = 0.65) at which the probability to
polarize reaches 0.5. B shows how a shock can reverse a polarizing trajectory, while C shows how the recovery can also fail, even though all parameters are
identical to those in B. See SI Appendix, Fig. S9 for the effects of an exogenous shock on partisan difference.
Downloaded by guest on January 27, 2022
Fig. 5. Robustness tests over the entire range of party identity and intolerance. The red surface shows the forward trajectory as polarization increases and
the blue surface shows the recovery. The critical points (where the trajectory experiences a sharp change) are indicated in green along the cliff edge. The
void between the red and blue regions corresponds to the hysteresis loops in Fig. 3 (in A and B) and Fig. 2 (in C and D). The critical values fluctuate widely for
very small α and β. The width of the loops decreases along with the increase of the control parameters due to the larger decrease in the critical values for
polarization compared to the decrease in critical values for recovery. In all four panels, polarization becomes increasingly hard to reverse as party identity
and intolerance increase.
former President Donald Trump. In the first trial, evidence of
collusion with a foreign government failed to exert the expected
unifying effect. In the second case, an attack on the US Capitol initially elicited bipartisan outrage, followed by a reversal of
position among Republican leaders in the weeks leading up to
the Senate trial.
Nevertheless, we make no claims about the model’s predictive
accuracy. The model is highly abstract and remains to be empirically calibrated and tested. Nor can we assume that tipping points
would obtain in radically different applications, such as affective polarization, voter polarization, or media polarization. For
example, social media and cable news have been credited with
replacing the “median voter” with partisan “echo chambers” and
“filter bubbles,” while other studies have concluded that media
polarization is more of a symptom than a cause of ideological
division (27); thus, it remains an open question whether future
algorithmic changes in Facebook’s News Feed could reverse the
process. Future research is needed to investigate the possibility
that tipping dynamics generalize to other models of polarization.
In closing, our study should be viewed as a small, but important, first step. The sources of political and ideological polarization have been widely investigated, but relatively little attention
has been directed to the possibility that the causal mechanisms
are characterized by irreversible tipping points. The lack of attention does not reflect the low importance of the problem. The
historical lesson from climate research may be instructive. As
with incremental global warming (28), the dynamics of reversibility cannot be revealed with observational data tracking changes
over time in the level of polarization. Instead, climatologists have
relied on increasingly sophisticated and empirically calibrated
computational models to show how the self-reinforcing dynamics of global warming can be reversed through the reduction of
carbon and methane emissions only up to a critical threshold,
beyond which civilization as we know it may be doomed. We
extend the concern with an environmental tipping point to the
study of polarization. The need for empirical calibration in our
model calls for increased investment in the study of irreversible
phase change, while our findings call for urgency in mobilizing
remediation efforts before it is too late.
1. D. B. Truman, The Governmental Process (Alfred A. Knopf, New York, 1951).
2. D. Baldassarri, A. Gelman, Partisans without constraint: Political polarization and
trends in American public opinion. AJS 114, 408–446 (2008).
3. P. E. Converse, “The nature of belief systems in mass publics” in Ideology and
Discontent, D. E. Apter, Ed. (Free Press, New York, 1964), pp. 206–261.
4. D. DellaPosta, Y. Shi, M. Macy, Why do liberals drink lattes? AJS 120, 1473–1511 (2015).
5. P. Dreyer, J. Bauer, Does voter polarisation induce party extremism? The moderating
role of abstention. West Eur. Polit. 42, 824–847 (2019).
6. N. McCarty, K. T. Poole, H. Rosenthal, Polarized America: The Dance of Ideology and
Unequal Riches (MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, 2006).
7. S. Iyengar, Y. Lelkes, M. Levendusky, N. Malhotra, S. J. Westwood, The origins and
consequences of affective polarization in the united states. Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 22,
129–146 (2019).
8. X. Lu, J. Gao, B. K. Szymanski, The evolution of polarization in the legislative branch
of government. J. R. Soc. Interface 16, 20190010 (2019).
9. S. A. Rice, Quantitative Methods in Politics (Alfred A. Knopf, New York,
1928).
10. A. Smith, The Theory of Moral Sentiments (Penguin, New York, 2010).
11. M. Macy, R. Willer, From factors to actors: Computational sociology and agent-based
modeling. Annu. Rev. Sociol. 28, 143–166 (2002).
8 of 9 | PNAS
https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.2102144118
Data Availability. Simulated data have been deposited in GitHub
(29).
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS. M.W.M. was supported by NSF Division of Social and
Economic Sciences Grant1756822. M.M. and B.K.S. were supported by Army
Research Office Grant W911NF-16-1-0524. J.G. was supported by NSF Grant
2047488; and the Rensselaer–IBM AI Research Collaboration.
Macy et al.
Polarization and tipping points
SPECIAL FEATURE
22. S. A. Condie, C. M. Condie, Stochastic events can explain sustained clustering and polarisation of opinions in social networks. Sci. Rep. 11, 1355
(2021).
23. M. J. van Strien, S. H. Huber, J. M. Anderies, AGrêt-Regamey, Resilience in socialecological systems: Identifying stable and unstable equilibria with agent-based
models. Ecol. Soc. 24, 8 (2019).
24. J. M. Brändle, G. Langendijk, S. Peter, S. H. Brunner, R. Huber, Sensitivity analysis
of a land-use change model with and without agents to assess land abandonment
and long-term re-forestation in a swiss mountain region. Land (Basel) 4, 475–512
(2015).
25. R. Dahl, Pluralist Democracy in the United States (Rand McNally, Chicago, IL,
1967).
26. E. C. Ladd, C. D. Hadley, Transformations of the American Party System (Norton, New
York, 1978).
27. K. Arceneaux, M. Johnson, “More a symptom than a cause: Polarization and partisan news media in America” in American Gridlock: The Sources, Character, and
Impact of Political Polarization (Cambridge University Press New York, NY, 2015),
pp. 309–336.
28. J. C.
Rocha,
G.
Peterson,
Ö.
Bodin,
S.
Levin,
Cascading
regime
shifts
within
and
across
scales.
Science
362,
1379–1383
(2018).
29. M. Ma, Polarization experiment simulation. GitHub. https://github.com/mongooma/
polarizationTipping. Deposited 25 July 2021.
Downloaded by guest on January 27, 2022
POLITICAL SCIENCES
COMPUTER SCIENCES
12. R. Axelrod, The Complexity of Cooperation: Agent-Based Models of Competition and
Collaboration (Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ, 1997).
13. T. Schelling, Dynamic models of segregation. J. Math. Sociol. 1, 143–186 (1971).
14. R. Axelrod, The dissemination of culture: A model with local convergence and global
polarization. J. Conflict Resolut. 41, 203–226 (1997).
15. G. Deffuant, F. Amblard, G. Weisbuch, T. Faure, How can extremism prevail? A study
based on the relative agreement interaction model. J. Artif. Soc. Soc. Simul. 5, 1
(2002).
16. R. Hegselmann, U. Krause, Opinion dynamics and bounded confidence models,
analysis and simulation. J. Artif. Soc. Soc. Simul. 5, 2 (2002).
17. A. Flache, M. Macy, Local convergence and global diversity: From interpersonal to
social influence. J. Conflict Resolut. 55, 970–995 (2007).
18. M. W. Macy, J. A. Kitts, A. Flache, S. Benard, “Polarization in dynamic networks:
A hopfield model of emergent structure” in Dynamic Social Network Modelling
and Analysis, R. Brieger, K. Carley, P. Pattison, Eds. (The National Academies Press,
Washington, DC, 2003), pp. 162–173.
19. N. P. Mark, Culture and competition: Homophily and distancing explanations for
cultural niches. Am. Sociol. Rev. 68, 319–345 (2003).
20. D. Baldassarri, P. Bearman, Dynamics of political polarization. Am. Sociol. Rev. 72,
784–811 (2007).
21. K. Klemm, V. M. Eguı́luz, R. Toral, M. S. Miguel, Global culture: A noise-induced
transition in finite systems. Phys. Rev. E Stat. Nonlin. Soft Matter Phys. 67, 045101
(2003).
Macy et al.
Polarization and tipping points
PNAS | 9 of 9
https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.2102144118