Industrial Organization in Context
Innovation I
Stephen Martin
March 2010
c 2010 ()
Innovation I
03/10
1 / 40
Schumpeter
Schumpeter Mark I (The Theory of Economic Development, 1934, p. 66):
it is not essential to the matter — though it may happen — that
the new combinations should be carried out by the same people
who control the productive or commercial process which is to be
displaced by the new. On the contrary, new combinations are, as
a rule, embodied, as it were, in new …rms which generally do not
arise out of the old ones but start producing beside them; . . . in
general it is not the owner of stage-coaches who builds railways.
If this vision of innovation in a market system is correct, to promote
innovation means facilitating the establishment of new, and often
relatively small, …rms.
c 2010 ()
Innovation I
03/10
2 / 40
Schumpeter
Schumpeter Mark II (Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy, 1943, p. 82):
As soon as we go into details and inquire into the individual
items in which progress was most conspicuous, the trail leads not
to the doors of those …rms that work under conditions of
comparatively free competition but precisely to the doors of the
large concerns . . . and a shocking suspicion dawns upon us that
big business may have had more to do with creating that
standard of life than with keeping it down.
This alternative vision of the innovative process leads to the idea that poor
static market performance (large …rms that are able to hold price above
marginal cost for extended periods of time) may be a small price to pay for
good dynamic market performance (a cornucopia of new products,
produced ever more e¢ciently).
c 2010 ()
Innovation I
03/10
3 / 40
Schumpeter
Large-…rm advantages in R&D?
larger …rms are able to spread …xed cost of research over a larger sales
base;
large …rms may have advantages in …nancial markets;
larger …rms may be better able to exploit economies of scale and
scope in research, if such economies exist;
(the serendipity e¤ect) a large, diversi…ed …rm is more likely to be
able to exploit an unexpected discovery.
But: large, established …rms may become bureaucratic and resistant to
change; familiarity with established products and processes may make
management slow to see the advantages to be gained from new products
or processes.
c 2010 ()
Innovation I
03/10
4 / 40
Pro…t to be gained from innovation: monopoly
Figure: Pro…t to be gained by innovation under monopoly; p = 100 Q;
c1 = 50; c2 = 25; Q1 = 25, P1 = 100 25 = 75, Q2 = 37.5, P2 = 62.5.
c 2010 ()
Innovation I
03/10
5 / 40
Pro…t to be gained from innovation: monopoly
Compare monopoly pro…t before and after cost-reducing innovation
Inverse demand equation
p = 100
Q.
Constant marginal and average cost, output, and pro…t
MC = AC = c1 = 50 ! qm = 25, π 1 = 625
MC = AC = c2 = 25 ! qm = 37.5, π 2 = 1406.5.
π2
c 2010 ()
π 1 = 1406.25
Innovation I
625 = 781.25.
03/10
6 / 40
Pro…t to be gained from innovation: perfect competition
Figure: Pro…t to be gained by innovation under perfect competition;
p = 100 Q; p1 = p2 = c1 = 50; c2 = 25; q1 = q2 = 50.
c 2010 ()
Innovation I
03/10
7 / 40
Pro…t to be gained from innovation: perfect competition
Compare long-run perfect competition pro…t (0) with innovator’s maximum pro…t when
fringe …rms can use the old technology.
MC = AC = 50, long-run equilibrium price = 50, quantity supplied =
50 units, π 1 = 0.
If a single …rm develops a cost-reducing innovation for which it
receives a completely e¤ective patent and is able to produce at MC =
AC = 25: sell slightly more than 50 units of output at a price slightly
less than 50,
π 2 = (50 25)(50) = 1250.
π2
c 2010 ()
π 1 = 1250
0 = 1250 > 781.25.
Innovation I
03/10
8 / 40
Pro…t to be gained from innovation
Perfect competition versus monopoly
This is a general result:
for a monopolist, the payo¤ to innovation is the di¤erence between
the monopoly pro…t it will get with a new product or process and the
monopoly pro…t it gets in any case with the existing technology.
for an innovating …rm in a competitive industry — a …rm that
innovates to escape the constraints of static product market
competition — all of the pro…t that ‡ows from successful innovation
is a net gain.
c 2010 ()
Innovation I
03/10
9 / 40
Large …rm advantages?
(once again)
large …rms able to spread …xed cost of research over a larger sales
base;
large …rms advantages in …nancial markets;
large …rms are better able to exploit economies of scale and scope in
research, if such economies exist;
(the serendipity e¤ect) a large, diversi…ed …rm is more likely to be
able to exploit an unexpected discovery.
c 2010 ()
Innovation I
03/10
10 / 40
Concentrated market advantages?
leading …rms in concentrated industries will earn economic pro…ts,
and so be able to …nance costly R&D e¤orts.
with few signi…cant rivals, a large …rm can be con…dent that it would
be able to appropriate the pro…ts ‡owing from success — that the
innovation would not be imitated by numerous small rivals and the
pro…ts competed away.
c 2010 ()
Innovation I
03/10
11 / 40
Market structure & innovation
An inverted-[ relation between seller concentration and the rate of
technical progress (Villard, 1958, p. 491):
[I]ndustries where “competitive oligopoly” prevails are likely to
progress most rapidly and that therefore “competitive oligopoly”
may well be the best way of organizing industry. The basic point
is that progress is likely to be rapid (1) when …rms are large
enough or few enough to a¤ord and bene…t from research and
(2) when they are under competitive pressure to
innovate—utilize the results of research.
c 2010 ()
Innovation I
03/10
12 / 40
Firm structure & innovation
Large …rms have advantages over small in raising funds to …nance
R&D
Small …rms less likely to be locked-in (by internal bureaucracies) to
established technologies
Arrow (1983)
Smaller …rms will tend to specialize more in the research phase
and in smaller development processes; larger …rms will devote a
much smaller proportion of their research and development
budget to the research phase. They will specialize in the larger
developments and will buy a considerable fraction of the research
basis for their subsequent development of innovations.
c 2010 ()
Innovation I
03/10
13 / 40
Firm size & innovation
Caveat investigator: let the researcher beware!
There is no unambiguous measure of the degree of innovation or
technological progress.
Measures that have been used
R&D inputs: spending on R&D; employment of scientists & engineers
R&D output: patents (an elastic yardstick); productivity growth (a
residual approach — that part of changes in input-output relations that
is not explained by changes in input usage)
c 2010 ()
Innovation I
03/10
14 / 40
Firm size & innovation
(Cohen and Klepper, 1996b): empirical studies show that
the probability that a …rm does R&D at all rises with …rm size;
for most industries, among …rms that do R&D, R&D is roughly
proportional to …rm size;
among …rms that do R&D, R&D productivity — the number of
innovations per unit of spending on R&D — falls as …rm size rises.
c 2010 ()
Innovation I
03/10
15 / 40
Firm size & innovation
(Cohen and Klepper, 1996, p. 933):
. . . larger …rms pursue more marginal R & D projects than
smaller …rms because they have a bigger output over which they
can apply the results of the projects . . . Consequently, the
average project they pursue has a lower return, measured in
terms of the number of patents or innovations, than smaller
…rms. . . . The greater output over which larger …rms can apply
their R & D enables them to pro…t more from R & D than
smaller …rms, which leads them to undertake more R & D
projects at the margin than smaller …rms. By undertaking more
R & D, larger …rms achieve a lower average cost of production
and/or higher product quality and hence greater pro…ts than
smaller …rms. This explains why larger …rms can prosper despite
the lower average productivity of their R & D.
c 2010 ()
Innovation I
03/10
16 / 40
Firm size & innovation
(Cohen and Klepper, 1996a)
Innovations the use of which is proportional to output levels are more
pro…table for large …rms than for small, all else equal
Large …rms tend to favor process innovation
Small …rms tend to favor product innovations.
c 2010 ()
Innovation I
03/10
17 / 40
Market structure & innovation
Scherer (1967): inverted-[ relationship between concentration ratios
and employment of technical personnel in 56 U.S. manufacturing
industries in 1960: employment of technical personnel rose with the
four-…rm seller concentration through values between 50 and 55 per
cent, and fell thereafter.
Scott (1984) inverted-[ relationship between R&D spending per
dollar of sales and seller concentration for 3388 lines of business of
437 U.S. manufacturing …rms; peak at a four-…rm seller concentration
ratio of 64 per cent. The inverted-[ relationship disappears when he
controls for unobserved …rm and industry e¤ects.
Blundell et al. (1999): for 340 UK manufacturing …rms for the years
1972–1982, more concentrated industries had fewer innovations, as
did industries facing less import competition. But within an industry,
(1999, p. 550) “it was the high market share …rms who tended to
commercialize more innovations. . . .”
c 2010 ()
Innovation I
03/10
18 / 40
Rivalry & innovation
Schumpeter Mark II: there is a positive impact of market
concentration on innovation because the leading …rms in
concentrated markets are shielded from rivalry — they earn economic
pro…ts that allow them to …nance innovation, and (having few rivals),
they will be able to act in con…dence that they will be able to collect
whatever pro…t ‡ows from successful innovation.
(Baily and Gersbach, 1995): for nine industries in Germany, Japan,
and the United States, international rivalry promotes competitivity
(1995, p. 308):
Vigorous global competition against the best-practice companies
not only spurs allocative e¢ciency, it can also force structural
change in industries and encourage the adoption of more e¢cient
product and process designs.
They also …nd (1995, p. 345) that competition by foreign …rms, not bound
or blinded by traditional ways of doing things, has a much greater impact
on performance
than competition by domestic …rms.
c
2010 ()
Innovation I
03/10
19 / 40
Rivalry & innovation
Broadberry and Crafts (2001)
market structure, trade association activity, and UK innovation in the
1950s.
Little evidence that trade association activity a¤ected innovation
Negative impact of seller concentration on innovation.
(2001, p. 112)
On balance, the evidence . . . goes against the claim that market
power promotes innovation.
c 2010 ()
Innovation I
03/10
20 / 40
Demand-pull
Jacob Schmookler (1962, 1966)
In a market system, more resources will be invested in innovations
that are expected to be more pro…table, all else equal, and expected
pro…t will be positively related to output.
(1962, p. 18, footnote omitted)
. . . expected pro…ts from invention, the ability to …nance it, the
number of potential inventors, and the dissatisfaction which
invariably motivates it—are all likely to be positively associated
with sales.
In a market system it is the lure of pro…t that directs the allocation of
resources to innovation (as it directs the allocation of resources to
other activities).
c 2010 ()
Innovation I
03/10
21 / 40
Technology-push
Exogenous technological advance is a prerequisite to pro…table innovation
(Rosenberg, 1974, p. 97):
. . . the progress made in techniques of navigation in the sixteenth
and seventeenth centuries owed much to the great demand for
such techniques in those centuries. . . . But . . . a great potential
demand existed in the same period for improvements in the
healing arts generally, but that no such improvements were
forthcoming. The essential explanation is that the state of
mathematics and astronomy a¤orded a useful and reliable
knowledge base for navigational improvements, whereas medicine
at that time had no such base.
c 2010 ()
Innovation I
03/10
22 / 40
Testing
Distinguish
fundamental innovations, the result of exogenous technological leaps,
and
incremental innovations, which perfect and apply fundamental
innovations, and which are more likely to respond to the lure of
pro…tability.
(Scherer, 1982a)
Patenting activity by 443 large U.S. …rms responded immediately to
demand ‡uctuations,
patenting responded more to di¤erences in sales in areas like chemicals
and electronics, less in sectors using traditional technologies.
c 2010 ()
Innovation I
03/10
23 / 40
R&D Spillovers
Arrow (1962, p. 615):
no amount of legal protection can make a thoroughly
appropriable commodity of something so intangible as
information. The very use of the information in any productive
way is bound to reveal it, at least in part. Mobility of personnel
among …rms provides a way of spreading information. Legally
imposed property rights can provide only a partial barrier, since
there are obviously enormous di¢culties in de…ning in any sharp
way an item of information and di¤erentiating it from similar
sounding items.
c 2010 ()
Innovation I
03/10
24 / 40
R&D Spillovers
Spillovers may have bene…cial e¤ects, from a social point of view
1956 U.S. antitrust consent decree required AT&T to openly license
patent-controlled technology at reasonable rates:
facilitated the development of UNIX
AT&T required cross-licenses of patents from …rms to which it
granted licenses under the consent decrees, and this pattern of
cross-licenses contributed to rapid entry into and growth of the U.S.
semiconductor chip industry.
c 2010 ()
Innovation I
03/10
25 / 40
R&D Input Spillovers
When the R&D e¤orts of one …rm help rivals reach their own research goals
The pharmaceutical industry:
is characterized by high rates of publication in the open scienti…c
literature, and many of the scientists . . . stressed the importance
of keeping in touch with the science conducted both within the
public sector and by their competitors. Nearly all of them had a
quite accurate idea of the nature of the research being conducted
by their competitors, and they often described the ways in which
their rivals’ discoveries had been instrumental in shaping their
own research.
E¤ective R&D e¤ort in high science-content sectors like pharmaceuticals
requires that researchers keep abreast of the knowledge frontier in their
…eld. The interactions this requires reveal what they are doing to
researchers working in other places, just as they learn what other
researchers are doing.
c 2010 ()
Innovation I
03/10
26 / 40
R&D Output Spillovers
When …rst-discoverers are not able to collect all of the economic pro…t generated by their
innovation.
An innovator would not be able to appropriate the consumers’ surplus
generated by the new product or process without engaging in price
discrimination (charge each consumer his or her personal maximum
price for each unit purchased) — the private return to investment in
innovation will, in general, be less than the social return.
For 48 US new product innovations, Mans…eld et al. (1981) report
that 60 percent of successful patented innovations were imitated
within four years of introduction.
For a sample of 100 US manufacturing …rms, Mans…eld (1985)
reports survey evidence indicating that rivals have information about
R&D decisions in 12–18 months, and information about new products
or processes in 12 months or less.
c 2010 ()
Innovation I
03/10
27 / 40
R&D Output Spillovers
Such leakages occur (Mans…eld, 1985, p. 221) because
input suppliers and customers are important channels (since they
pass on a great deal of relevant information), patent applications
are scrutinized very carefully, and reverse engineering is carried
out. In still other industries, the di¤usion process is accelerated
by the fact that …rms do not go to great lengths to keep such
information secret, partly because they believe it would be futile
in any event.
c 2010 ()
Innovation I
03/10
28 / 40
R&D Spillovers
Neither R&D input spillovers nor R&D output spillovers are unambiguously bad, from a
social point of view.
R&D input spillovers increase the productivity of such R&D e¤orts as do
take place, and make it more likely that some …rm will discover (which is
what is important from a social point of view).
R&D output spillovers improve static product market performance after
discovery takes place.
But both types of spillovers reduce the incentives of …rms to invest in
innovation.
c 2010 ()
Innovation I
03/10
29 / 40
Appropriability and absorptive capacity
Arrow argued that knowledge ‡ows freely throughout the economy.
A contrary view is that one must work to acquire and maintain the
ability to absorb knowledge (Cohen and Levinthal, 1989, pp. 569–70)
we argue that while R&D obviously generates innovations, it also
develops the …rm’s ability to identify, assimilate, and exploit
knowledge from the environment—what we call a …rm’s
‘learning’ or ‘absorptive’ capacity. While encompassing a …rm’s
ability to imitate new process or product innovations, absorptive
capacity also includes the …rm’s ability to exploit outside
knowledge of a more intermediate sort, such as basic research
…ndings that provide the basis for subsequent applied research
and development.
c 2010 ()
Innovation I
03/10
30 / 40
Appropriability and absorptive capacity
Tacit knowledge
Vonortas (1994, p. 415):
technological knowledge involves a combination of
poorly-de…ned, and often incomplete, know-how and a set of
highly codi…ed information which is hard to acquire and utilize
e¤ectively.
Where knowledge is tacit, …rms need to maintain their own stock of
knowledge and technical ability to absorb knowledge generated
elsewhere in the economy.
c 2010 ()
Innovation I
03/10
31 / 40
Appropriability and absorptive capacity
Tacit knowledge
Angelmar (1987, pp 73–74) studies business responses to a question
“whether it bene…ts to a signi…cant degree from patents, trade
secrets, or other proprietary methods of production or operation” to
measure industry appropriability conditions.
For 160 business units that were parts of large …rms in 1978,
R&D spending per dollar of sales was consistently higher, the greater
appropriability.
there was a positive impact of seller concentration on R&D spending in
industries with low appropriability and low customer switching costs,
a negative impact of seller concentration on R&D spending in
industries with high appropriability and high customer switching costs.
c 2010 ()
Innovation I
03/10
32 / 40
Appropriability and absorptive capacity
Tacit knowledge
Where other market conditions do not favor private investment in
innovation, high seller concentration has the e¤ects envisaged by
Schumpeter Mark II.
Where market conditions favor private investment in innovation even
by small …rms, the inclination of large …rms to pursue the quiet life
makes Schumpeter Mark I a better explanation for market
structure-dynamic market performance relationships.
c 2010 ()
Innovation I
03/10
33 / 40
Uncertainty
The creative process is inherently uncertain.
How a particular approach will turn out cannot be foreseen; in the
words of one drug-industry researcher (quoted in Tapon and Cadsby,
1996, pp. 389–90):
I think that rational drug design is obviously very admirable. It’s
more than a great idea, it’s a move in the right direction. It
applies as much rationality to your programs as possible. But,
you’re not going to be able to predict 100% . . . of the outcome.
You’re always going to have things that happen that nobody
really foresaw and you look back in hindsight and say that there
is no way that we could have predicted that outcome. . . There is
a certain amount of good luck involved . . . you have to have the
breaks; if you don’t have the breaks in drug development you
may have great di¢culty in getting any compound.
c 2010 ()
Innovation I
03/10
34 / 40
Uncertainty
Not only is it uncertain, ex ante, how a particular research project
may turn out, but it may also be uncertain, ex post, whether results
obtained have interesting commercial possibilities.
The market for genuinely new products may not be immediately
recognized.
For example, the fundamental innovation embodied in the now
ubiquitous post-it R sticker was essentially an adhesive substance
that was not terribly adhesive, developed in 1968. The product was
…rst introduced in 1980, 12 years later.
Uncertainty, too, reduces the incentives of …rms to invest in R&D.
c 2010 ()
Innovation I
03/10
35 / 40
Basic vs. applied R&D
(National Science Foundation, 2001)
Basic Research: directed toward increases in knowledge or
understanding of the fundamental aspects of phenomena and of
observable facts, without speci…c application or commercial objectives
Applied Research: research directed toward gaining knowledge or
understanding necessary for determining the means by which a
recognized and speci…c need or commercial objective may be met.
Development: the systematic use of the knowledge or understanding
gained from research directed toward the production of useful
materials, devices, systems or methods, including design and
development of prototypes and processes (excludes quality control,
routine product testing, and production).
c 2010 ()
Innovation I
03/10
36 / 40
Basic vs. applied R&D
Basic Research: carried out mostly in universities; “public good”
aspects strongest and spillovers likely to be bene…cial.
hence, increasing appropriability of the fruits of university R&D
potentially harmful
Applied Research, Development: carried out mostly in the private
sector, where results will be applied; absorptive capacity more
important.
c 2010 ()
Innovation I
03/10
37 / 40
R&D and market structure
Schumpeter Mark I: turnover of leading …rms — today’s dominant
…rm displaced by an innovative entrant, which is in its turn displaced
by a later innovator
Schumpeter Mark II: the dominant …rm’s comparative advantage in
innovation allows it to maintain its dominant position, and this goes
hand in hand with good dynamic market performance.
c 2010 ()
Innovation I
03/10
38 / 40
R&D and market structure
Strategic entry deterrence
The prediction of many models is that the duopoly pro…t gained by
an entrant will be less than the pro…t lost by an incumbent should
entry occur — it follows that an incumbent could (à contre cœur )
pay a potential entrant enough to make the entrant indi¤erent to the
prospect of entry, leaving the incumbent better o¤
Example: reverse payment patent settlement agreements in which a
pharmaceutical company holding a patent pays the producer of a
generic substitute to keep the generic o¤ the market.
c 2010 ()
Innovation I
03/10
39 / 40
R&D and market structure
Strategic entry deterrence
By the same token, if the incumbent can be certain of innovating …rst
by spending more than a potential entrant, it will have a greater
incentive to do so — the pro…t it would lose should entry occur is
more than the duopoly pro…t the entrant would gain.
But if the outcome of innovation is uncertain, the replacement e¤ect
identi…ed in Arrow’s static model comes into play — the incumbent is
certain to get economic pro…t until entry occurs, and this reduces its
incentive to invest in innovation, relative to an entrant for which all
post-innovation economic pro…t would be a gain.
c 2010 ()
Innovation I
03/10
40 / 40