Sukuk

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 15

Sukuk and their Contemporary Applications

M M T U


P   AAOIFI S C

T  M. Y D

In the name of Allah, the Merciful and Mercy-Giving

Introduction
Praise be to Allah and only to Him!
And blessings on those of His Servants He has chosen!

As to what follows
Among the duties of the Shariah Council, as stated in the statutes of the Accounting and
Auditing Organization for Islamic Financial Institutions is the following:

To bring about mutual conformity or approximation between the


conceptualizations and the practical applications of Shariah supervisory
boards of Islamic financial institutions so as to avoid inconsistencies and
contradictions between the fatawa and the implementations of these
institutions in ways that lead to the effectiveness of the role of Shariah
supervisory boards in Islamic financial institutions and central banks.

Investment Sukuk worth enormous amounts have appeared in our times, and have
been widely subscribed to by many Islamic banks. At the same time, many scholars
have expressed their opinions in relation to the compliance of Sukuk with the
precepts of the Shariah. Therefore, the Shariah Council in its prior meeting at al-
Madina al-Munawwarah decided to study the subject at its next annual meeting in
Makkah al-Mukarramah. As the responsibility to prepare a concise report of the
issues requiring further study and debate was given to me, I have therefore prepared
this modest brief as a working paper for discussion of the subject at the coming
meeting, Allah willing.

Muhammad Taqi Usmani


Chairman of the Shariah Council
pìâìâ=~åÇ=íÜÉáê=`çåíÉãéçê~êó=^ééäáÅ~íáçåë=

In the name of Allah, the Merciful and Mercy-Giving

Sukuk and their Contemporary


Applications
All praise to Allah, Lord of All the Worlds!
Peace and Blessings upon our Leader and our Prophet, Muhammad, the Finest of the
Prophets, and upon his family and Companions, and upon everyone who follows them in
righteousness until the Day of Judgment!

As to what follows: The issuance of Sukuk on the basis of the rules of the Shining Shariah
of Islam is among the objectives of Islamic banking, and is also one of the greatest means
of establishing Islamic economies in society. This, however, is on condition that the tools
used to develop and structure Sukuk are in consonance with the fundamental principles
which distinguish Islamic economic systems from others. The interest-based system
prevalent in the world today regularly issues bonds that yield interest from capital-
intensive enterprises that bring great profits and regular revenues. Yet, the holders of such
certificates are no more than lenders to the sponsors of such enterprises; and their
earnings come from the interest on their loans in a percentage that accords with the price
of interest in the marketplace. The profits of these enterprises after costs, including
interest payments 1, return exclusively to the sponsors. The basic concept behind issuing
Islamic Sukuk, however, is for the holders of the Sukuk to share in the profits of large
enterprises or in their revenues. If Sukuk are issued on this basis they will play a major
role in the development of the Islamic banking business and thereby contribute
significantly to the achievement of the noble objectives sought by the Shariah. Among
the benefits of Sukuk are the following:

1. Sukuk are among the best ways of financing large enterprises that are beyond the
ability of a single party to finance.
2. Sukuk provide an ideal means for investors seeking to deploy streams of capital
and who require, at the same time, the ability to liquidate their positions with
ease whenever the need should arise. This is because it is envisioned that a
secondary market for the trading of Sukuk will develop. Thus, whenever investors
require cash from their investments, or from a part of the same, it will be possible
for them to sell their Sukuk holdings, or a part thereof, and receive their value
from their original investment plus earnings, if the enterprise is profitable, in
cash.
3. Sukuk represent an excellent way of managing liquidity for banks and Islamic
financial institutions. When these are in need of disposing of excess liquidity they

1
To bond holders. YTD

2
pìâìâ=~åÇ=íÜÉáê=`çåíÉãéçê~êó=^ééäáÅ~íáçåë=

may purchase Sukuk; and when they are in need of liquidity, they may sell their
Sukuk into the secondary market.
4. Sukuk are a means for the equitable distribution of wealth as they allow all
investors to benefit from the true profits resulting from the enterprise in equal
shares. In this way, wealth may circulate on a broad scale without remaining the
exclusive domain of a handful of wealthy persons. 2 This is clearly among the most
important of all the higher purposes sought by an Islamic economic system.

Today, there are many Sukuk in the market, all claiming to be Islamic Sukuk. In this
brief study, I mean to shed light on the mechanisms they use and on the extent to which
these comply with the precepts of Islamic jurisprudence, and its principles, and its higher
purposes. The issuers of these Sukuk have expended a great deal of effort to make them
competitive with the conventional bonds prevalent in today's capital markets. By
endowing these Sukuk with the same characteristics of bonds, they have attempted to
facilitate their acceptance in both Islamic and conventional markets.

The most prominent characteristics of conventional bonds may be summarized as


follows:
1. Bonds do not represent ownership on the part of the bond holders in the
commercial or industrial enterprises for which the bonds were issued. Rather,
they document the interest-bearing debt owed to the holders of the bonds by the
issuer, the owner of the enterprise.
2. Regular interest payments are made to the bond holders. The amount of interest
is determined as a percentage of the capital and not as a percentage of actual
profits. Sometimes the interest is fixed, while oftentimes in bonds with longer
tenors the rate of interest is allowed to float.
3. Bonds guarantee the return of principal when redeemed at maturity, regardless
of whether the enterprise was profitable or otherwise.
The issuer of such bonds is not required to return more than the principal and the
agreed amount of interest. Whatever profits may have been earned by the enterprise
accrue entirely and exclusively to the issuer. So the bond holders have no right to seek a
share in the profits beyond the interest.

These characteristics are not to be found in Islamic Sukuk, at least not directly. Even so,
the issuers of Islamic Sukuk today have attempted to distinguish their Sukuk, however
indirectly, with many of these same characteristics. For this reason they have developed
a variety of mechanisms. Let us now study these mechanisms in the light of the
following three points.

1. Bond Holders' Ownership of Enterprise Assets


The first point, or the bond owners' ownership of enterprise assets, is that the
majority of Sukuk are clearly different in this respect from interest-based bonds.
Generally, Sukuk represent ownership shares in assets that bring profits or revenues,
like leased assets, or commercial or industrial enterprises, or investment vehicles that
may include a number of projects. This is the one characteristic that distinguishes
Sukuk from conventional bonds. However, quite recently, the market has witnessed a

2
See al-Qur'an at VII:59. YTD

3
pìâìâ=~åÇ=íÜÉáê=`çåíÉãéçê~êó=^ééäáÅ~íáçåë=

number of Sukuk in which there is doubt regarding their representation of


ownership. For example, the assets in the Sukuk may be shares of companies that do
not confer true ownership but which merely offer Sukuk holders a right to returns.
Such Sukuk are no more than the purchase of returns from shares; and this is not
lawful from a Shariah perspective. Likewise, there has been a proliferation of certain
Sukuk that are based on a mix of ijarah, istisna' and murabahah contracts undertaken
by Islamic banks or institutions such that these are packaged and sold to Sukuk
holders who hope to obtain the returns from these operations. The inclusion of
murabahah contracts into such Sukuk, however, cannot but bring into question the
issue of the sale of debt, 3 even if the percentage of the murabahah contracts may be
considerably less than that of the ijarah, musharakah and istisna' contracts. All of this
requires careful review.

2. Regular Distributions to Sukuk Holders


In reference to the second point, most of the Sukuk that have been issued are
identical to conventional bonds with regard to the distribution of profits from their
enterprises at fixed percentages based on interest rates (LIBOR). In order to justify
this practice, the issuers include a paragraph in the contract which states that if the
actual profits from the enterprise exceed the percentage based on interest rates, then
that amount of excess shall be paid in its entirety to the enterprise manager (whether
a mudarib, or a partner, or an investment agent) as an incentive for the manager to
manage effectively. I have even seen in the structure of certain Sukuk that they do not
state that such excess will become the right of the manager as an incentive but,
instead, they state no more than that the holders of the Sukuk will be entitled to a
fixed percentage based upon the rate of interest at the time of regular distributions (as
if the excess as an incentive was established as a tacit provision of the agreement). If
the actual profits are less than the prescribed percentage based on interest rates, then
the manager may take it upon himself to pay out the difference (between the actual
profits and the prescribed percentage) to the Sukuk holders, as an interest free loan to
the Sukuk holders. Then, that loan will be recovered by the lending manager either
from the amounts in excess of the interest rate during subsequent periods, or from
lowering or increasing the cost of repurchasing assets at the time the Sukuk are
redeemed as will be explained in detail in the third point, below, Allah willing.

3. Guaranteeing the Return of Principal


As to the third point, virtually all of the Sukuk issued today guarantee the return of
principal to the Sukuk holders at maturity, in exactly the same way as conventional
bonds. This is accomplished by means of a binding promise from either the issuer or
the manager to repurchase the assets represented by the Sukuk at the stated price at
which these were originally purchased by the Sukuk holders at the beginning of the
process, regardless of their true or market value at maturity.

Then, by these complex mechanisms, Sukuk are able to take on the same
characteristics as conventional, interest-bearing bonds since they do not return to
investors more than a fixed percentage of the principal, based on interest rates, while
guaranteeing the return of investors' principal at maturity.

3
Generally speaking, the sale of debt is prohibited by Shariah law. YTD

4
pìâìâ=~åÇ=íÜÉáê=`çåíÉãéçê~êó=^ééäáÅ~íáçåë=

We will now speak about these mechanisms firstly from the perspective of Islamic
jurisprudence and secondly from the perspective of the higher purposes of Islamic
finance and economics.

From the Shariah perspective, there are three questions:

First: Stipulating the amount in excess of the price of interest for the manager of the
enterprise under the pretense that this is an incentive for good management.
Second: The manager's commitment, if the actual profits are less than the yield from
the fixed rate of interest during any of the times for distribution, to lend the amount
of the shortfall to the holders of the Sukuk. Thereafter the amounts of such loans will
be recovered either through the actual profits of the enterprise at the times of
following distributions or through the sale of the enterprise's assets at maturity.
Third: The binding promise by the manager that he will purchase the assets
represented by the Sukuk at their face value, and not at their market value on the day
they are redeemed.

One: Stipulating an Incentive for the Manager


With regard to the stipulation of an incentive for the manager of the enterprise, its
justification may be found in what certain jurists have mentioned in regard to the
lawfulness of offering incentives in contracts of wakalah or in brokerage. Al-Imam al-
Bukhari mentioned the same on the authority of the Companion Ibn `Abbas and Ibn
Sirin:

Said Ibn `Abbas: "There is no impediment to one's saying, 'Sell this cloth and
whatever is in excess of this or that 4 will be yours.'" Said Ibn Sirin: "When
someone says, 'Sell it for this much and whatever profits are realized beyond that
will be yours, or will be shared between us,' then there is no problem with that."

This opinion was adopted by the Hanbali school of jurisprudence. In Al-Kafi by Ibn
Qudama it is written:

If someone says, "Sell this for ten, and whatever you receive in excess will be
yours," then that excess will be lawful for the seller because Ibn `Abbas did not
see any impediment to doing so. 5

This opinion is recorded by Ibn Abi Shaybah in his Al-Musannaf from Ibn `Abbas,
Ibn Sirin, Shurayh, `Amir al-Sha`bi, al-Zuhri, and al-Hakam. `Abd al-Razzaq added
Qatada and Ayyub to those who agreed. The arrangement, however, was considered
makruh (undesirable) by Ibrahim al-Nakha`i and Hammad, as related by `Abd al-
Razzaq, and by al-Hasan al-Basri and Tawus ibn Kaysan as related by Ibn Abi
Shaybah. 6 This is the opinion of the majority, other than the Hanbali scholars. Al-
Hafidh Ibn Hajr commented on the opinion of Ibn `Abbas mentioned by al-Bukhari:

4
naming an actual price, or a margin. YTD
5
Ibn Qudamah, Al-Kafi, vol. 2, p. 253.
6
Ibn Abi Shaybah, Al-Musannaf, vol. 6, pp. 107-108.

5
pìâìâ=~åÇ=íÜÉáê=`çåíÉãéçê~êó=^ééäáÅ~íáçåë=

This, too, refers to the wages of a broker. But, as these are unknown 7, the
majority of jurists have not allowed the arrangement, saying if the broker sells the
item for the owner on this basis, he will be entitled to no more than the fee
customarily awarded for similar sales. Some jurists have interpreted the statement
by Ibn `Abbas to mean that he saw the situation as analogous to that of a
partnership. The same interpretation was given by Ahmad ibn Hanbal and Ishaq.
Ibn al-Tin recorded that some jurists stipulated, for its acceptance as lawful, that
people at the time understand the price of the goods to equal more than what was
stated; but his opinion was challenged on the grounds that ignorance of the actual
amount of the fee still remains. 8

Badr al-Din al-`Ayni wrote:

As to the opinion of Ibn `Abbas and Ibn Sirin, well, the majority of scholars do
not allow such a sale. Among those who disliked it are Sufyan al-Thawri and the
jurists from Kufa. Likewise, al-Shafi`i and Malik did not allow it. If someone sells
on this basis he will be entitled to a fee equal to what is customary for such a sale.
Ahmad and Ishaq, however, have allowed the sale, saying, "This is actually a
partnership, for at times a partner will not profit." 9

Of course, all of this is said in relation to the fees of a broker if other than the excess
over the stated original price of the sale is not specified. However, if the broker's fee is
stated as a determined amount, and then the broker is told, 'If you sell this for more
than this, the excess will be yours in addition to your predetermined fee,' then it
should be clear that the majority will not oppose it. This is because the ignorance
with regard to the fee is lifted when it is determined in advance. Then, if the broker
sells the item for more than a certain amount, the excess will be his as an incentive for
better management.

On this basis, the Standard for Mudarabah approved by the Shariah Council reads as
follows:

If one of the two parties should stipulate for itself a specific amount (of profit),
the mudarabah will be void. This prohibition, however, is not inclusive of an
agreement by the two parties that if the profits exceed a certain percentage then
one of those two parties will receive the excess exclusively such that the
distribution will be according to what the two have agreed. 10

The operations manager in a Sukuk will manage on the basis either of its being a wage-
earning employee (ajir) or an investment agent (wakil), thus resembling a broker, or on
the basis of its being an investment manager (mudarib), or a working partner (sharik
`amil). All of these possibilities are covered by the Standard. However, when the jurists

7
at the time of the agreement between the owner and the broker. YTD
8
Ibn Hajr, Fath al-Bari, vol. 4, p. 451.
9
Badr al-Din al-`Ayni, `Umdah al-Qari, vol. 12, p.133.
10
AAOIFI Standard 13, para 8.5

6
pìâìâ=~åÇ=íÜÉáê=`çåíÉãéçê~êó=^ééäáÅ~íáçåë=

gave permission for this arrangement, they did not consider that it would be used to carry
out operations on the basis of interest rates or to maintain the status quo of the
conventional, riba-based market. The right of the manager to an amount in excess of the
prescribed percentage has been called an incentive for better management of the assets. 11
Such an incentive, however, may only be understood as an incentive if it is linked to what
exceeds the minimum amount of expected profits from the commercial or industrial
enterprise for which the Sukuk were issued. For example: if the minimum amount of
expected profits is 15%, then it may be said that the actual profits in excess of that
percentage may be paid to the manager as an incentive. This is because that excess
amount may logically be ascribed to good management. The problem is that the
prescribed percentage in these Sukuk is not linked to the expected profits from the
enterprise, but to the costs of financing or to the prevalent rates of interest in the market;
rates that vary every day, or every hour of the day. Obviously, there is no connection
between these and the profitability of the commercial or industrial enterprise.
Oftentimes, this rate will be considerably lower than the expected rate of return from the
enterprise. Thus, for example, if the expected rate of return from the enterprise is 15%,
the interest rate at the same time may be no more than 5%. If, owing to poor
management, the actual rate of return from the enterprise falls to 10%, then how may
what is in excess of 5% be given to the manager as a reward for "good management"? 12
How can this be, even when poor management resulted in profits dipping from [an
expected] 15% to only 10%? It should therefore be clear that what is being called an
"incentive" in these Sukuk is not truly an incentive but rather a method for marketing
these Sukuk on the basis of interest rates. It should also be clear that this aspect is not free
of legal repugnance (karahah), even if we do not declare it prohibited (haram) outright.

The foregoing is from the perspective of Islamic jurisprudence only. From the perspective
of the higher purposes of Islamic economics, such "incentives" in today's Sukuk actually
defeat the purpose of an Islamic economic system in which wealth is equitably
distributed among investors. Sukuk that are based on such "incentives" distribute profits
to investors on the basis of prevalent interest rates, and not on the basis of actual returns
from an enterprise.

If Shariah supervisory boards have tolerated such irregularities (mafasid) when Sukuk
began to be issued, and at a time when Islamic financial institutions were few in number,
the time has now come to revisit the matter… and to rid Sukuk from now on from such
blemishes. Either Sukuk should be free of all such "incentives" or these should be based
the enterprise's expected profits. These should certainly not be based on prevalent interest
rates. This will then become a truly distinguishing characteristic of Islamic financial
institutions, and one that sets them apart from their conventional, interest-based
counterparts.

Two: Stipulating Loans when Profits Fall Below Prescribed Percentages


There is absolutely nothing in the Shariah to justify a loan when actual profits are less
than the prescribed percentages. The one undertaking the loan is the operations manager,
and the manager is the one that sells the assets to the Sukuk holders at the beginning of

11
Or the enterprise in general. YTD
12
i.e., assuming that the incentive is linked to the 5% rate in the market for interest. YTD

7
pìâìâ=~åÇ=íÜÉáê=`çåíÉãéçê~êó=^ééäáÅ~íáçåë=

operations. If it is then stipulated that the manager will make loans to the Sukuk holders
at times (for distribution) when actual returns fall below the (promised) rate of return,
the transaction will come under the heading of a sale with a credit. It is well known that
the Prophet, upon him be peace, prohibited sales linked to credits. The same was related
by Malik in his al-Muwatta on the authority of trusted narrators (balaghan), and by Abu
Dawud and al-Tirmidhi whose version reads, "A sale and a credit are not lawful." Al-
Tirmidhi added, "This is a good and a sound hadith." In his commentary on this
narration, Ibn `Abd al-Barr wrote:

This hadith is recorded on the authority of `Amr ibn Shu`ayb, from his father,
from his grandfather, from the Prophet, upon him be peace. It is a sound hadith
that has been related by many reliable narrators on the authority of `Amr ibn
Shu`ayb; and `Amr ibn Shu`ayb is a reliable narrator (i.e., his narrations are
reliable) when those who relate his narrations are themselves reliable. 13

The entire community of scholars is agreed on this (prohibition) and no one is known to
have held a dissenting opinion. Ibn Qudamah wrote:

If someone sells on condition that the purchaser give credit (to the seller), or
advance him a loan, or if the buyer stipulates the same, that will be unlawful and
the sale will be void. This is the opinion of Malik and al-Shafi`i, and I know of
no dissenting opinion. 14

At another place, he wrote:

If he stipulates that he lease his house to him at a rate lower than the market rate,
or that he take a lease on the lender's house at a rate higher than the market rate,
then this will be even more unlawful. 15

With regard to the mechanism used in the Sukuk, the manager is not willing to offer the
loan unless he receives more than his due share of the actual profits by means of the
"incentive" which is stipulated for him when the percentage of actual profits exceeds the
percentage based on the prevalent interest rate of interest. Therefore, such a loan, in view
of the opinion voiced by Ibn Qudamah, is emphatically all the more unlawful.

At times, the manager who undertakes the loan may be a partner in the enterprise, or a
mudarib. Such an undertaking [on his part], too, is in opposition to the requirements of
the contract and falls under the same prohibition as that against a sale linked to a credit
(or a loan) in exactly the same way. Thus, it is not lawful.

Three: The Manager's Promise to Repurchase Assets at Face Value


The third issue is that in true commercial enterprises, where the Shariah is concerned, the
return of investors' capital cannot be guaranteed. In Shariah compliant dealings, reward
always follows after risk. The legal presumption with regard to Sukuk is that there can be
no guarantee that capital will be returned to investors. Instead, they have a right to the

13
Ibn `Abd al-Barr, al-Tamhid, vol. 24, p.284.
14
Ibn Qudamah, op. cit., vol. 4, p. 162.
15
Ibn Qudaman, op. cit., vol. 4, p. 211.

8
pìâìâ=~åÇ=íÜÉáê=`çåíÉãéçê~êó=^ééäáÅ~íáçåë=

true value of the [Sukuk] assets, regardless of whether their value exceeds that of their face
value or not. All of today's Sukuk, however, guarantee by indirect means Sukuk holders'
principal. The manager pledges to the Sukuk holders that he will purchase Sukuk assets
at face value upon maturity, regardless of their true value on that day. What this means is
that the principal paid originally by the Sukuk holders will be returned to them at
maturity. There is no other significance to such a commitment. If the enterprise is not
profitable, the losses will be borne by the manager. If it is profitable, however, the profits
will accrue to the manager, regardless of how great the amount. The Sukuk holders have
no right to other than the return of their principal, as is the case in conventional bonds.

In considering the lawfulness of this commitment, we note that the manager of the
Sukuk may act in his capacity as an investment manager, mudarib, for the Sukuk holders,
or as a partner, sharik, or as an investment agent, wakil, for them.

A Commitment by a Mudarib
That such a commitment to investors on the part of a mudarib is void should be obvious
because it is a capital guarantee by the mudarib to the investors, and no jurist has ever
averred that such an arrangement is lawful. The Standard on Mudarabah approved by the
Shariah Council states:

If the loss at the time of closing operations is greater than the earnings, the losses
will be deducted from the capital and the manager, in his capacity as a trust
holder, amin, will not bear any of the loss as long as there is no negligence or
mala fides on his part. If the costs are equal to the earnings, the investors will
receive their capital back, and the mudarib will earn nothing. When profits are
earned, these will be distributed among the two parties (investor and manager) in
accordance with what the two have decided. 16

Thus, I can see no possible justification for such a commitment by a mudarib. It is,
however, mentioned in some Sukuk that the manager does not make this commitment in
his capacity as a mudarib, but in another capacity. This is clearly illogical because the
mudarib has no other capacity in this deal.

A Commitment by a Sharik
The manager may also act as the partner of the Sukuk holders. Then, in the same way
that it is unlawful for a mudarib to guarantee the return of capital to investors, it is also
unlawful for one partner to guarantee the return of capital to the other partner or
partners. This is because to do so would effectively interrupt the partnership in the event
of losses; and that is something that no jurist has ever allowed. The Standard on
Musharakah approved by the Shariah Council states:

It is unlawful for the conditions of partnership or for the basis of profit


distribution to include any text or condition that leads to the possibility that the
sharing of profits will be interrupted. If this happens, the partnership will be
void. 17

16
AAOIFI Standard 13, 7.8.
17
AAOIFI Standard 12, 3.1.5.7

9
pìâìâ=~åÇ=íÜÉáê=`çåíÉãéçê~êó=^ééäáÅ~íáçåë=

The Standard specifically mentions the unlawfulness of such a commitment in one of the
following paragraphs, where it states:

It is lawful for one of the parties to the partnership to issue a binding promise to
purchase the assets of the partnership during the period of partnership or at the
time of dissolution at market value or at an agreed price at the time of purchase.
A promise to purchase the assets at face value, however, is unlawful. 18

In the Basis for Conclusions for the Standard it is stated:

The justification for the ruling of "unlawful" with regard to the binding promise
by one of the partners to purchase the assets of the partnership at face value is
that this is the same as a capital guarantee, which is unlawful. The justification for
a ruling of "lawful" for repurchase at market value comes from the fact that there
is nothing in this arrangement that guarantees anything to the partners. 19

Certain contemporary scholars have attempted to justify a commitment that implies a


capital guarantee by saying that while it may be prohibited in a partnership of contract,
shirkah `aqd, it is not prohibited in a partnership of property, shirkah milk. They then
claim that the sort of partnership that occurs in Sukuk (especially Sukuk with leased
assets) is a partnership of property and not a partnership of contract. However, when we
consider the reality of these two types of partnership, it is clear that the type of
partnership that occurs in Sukuk is a partnership of contract and not a partnership of
property. This is because the purpose of the partnership [in these Sukuk] is not merely to
own physical assets for the purpose of consumption or personal benefit but for the
purpose of joint investment. This is the fundamental difference between a partnership of
property and a partnership of contract.

To be more specific, when we consider what the classical jurists have mentioned
regarding the reality of a partnership of contract, it should be clear to us that a
partnership of contract may be distinguished from a partnership of property in three
ways:
1. The purpose of the partnership of contract is to jointly seek profits; whereas the
purpose of the partnership of property is no more than to have possession of
something and make use of it.
2. A partnership of contract makes each partner the agent of the other in investment
enterprises, whereas partners in a partnership of property are entitled to dispose
of their own share [of the jointly owned property] as they wish; while they are
absolute strangers with regard to the shares of the other partner or partners.
3. The partners in a partnership of contract are free to distribute profits among
themselves in whatever proportion they agree among themselves. A partnership of
property is different. In it, each partner is entitled only to the profits earned by
his own share. So, when each partner puts his share to work separately, each
partner will profit solely from the returns earned by his own share.

18
AAOIFI Standard 12, paragraph 3.1.6.2
19
AAOIFI Standards, p. 230

10
pìâìâ=~åÇ=íÜÉáê=`çåíÉãéçê~êó=^ééäáÅ~íáçåë=

Each of the characteristics [of a partnership of contract] described above is to be found in


Sukuk.

Shaykh Mustafa al-Zarqa', may Allah bless him, wrote clearly and concisely of the
difference between the two types of partnership in what follows:

Joint ownership always occurs in things that are shared. Such a partnership, if it
occurs in physical wealth only, with no agreement as to its investment by means
of a collective effort, will be called a partnership of property. This is countered by
the partnership of contract in which two or more persons contract among
themselves to invest wealth or labor and then to share the profits, as occurs in
commercial and industrial partnerships. 20

At another place, the Shaykh spoke of the difference between the two types:

The partnership of contract: This is a contract between two parties or more to


cooperate on a profitable activity and to share in its profits. Partnership, in its
essence, can be either a partnership of property shared between a number of
persons as a result of some natural reason, such as inheritance, or it can be a
partnership of contract in which a group agrees to undertake an investment
activity in which they assist one another with capital or labor and then share in
the results of the same. Thus, a partnership of property is a sort of joint
ownership rather than anything contractual, even if the reason for the partnership
may be traced back to a contract; as in the case of two people who purchase
something together, so that they share its ownership. This is a partnership of
property (joint ownership). There is no contract between the owners, however, to
put the property to use, or to invest it through commerce or leasing or by any
other means of earning profits. A partnership of contract, on the other hand, has
investment and the earning of profits as its objective. This is the partnership that
it intended here, and this is the partnership that is numbered among the
nominate contracts, al-`uqud al-musammah. 21

Thus, the Shaykh explained that whenever the purpose of a partnership is investment or
earning, regardless of whether that is to take place by means of commerce, or by means of
leasing, the partnership will be a partnership of contract. Since it is obvious that the
purpose of Sukuk is investment or earning by means of leasing assets, it is impossible to
call Sukuk a partnership of property. Therefore, it is not lawful for one partner to
guarantee the capital of another partner either directly or indirectly.

In fact, that it is unlawful for a partner or a mudarib to make such a commitment is a


matter that requires very little in the way of justification because it is an established fact
of Islamic jurisprudence that has been emphasized by fiqh academies, and at specialized
seminars, and by the Shariah Council itself. If we were to open this door, the managers of
Islamic banks would then be able to guarantee the capital of depositors by committing to

20
Mustafa al-Zarqa', al-Madkhal al-Fiqhi al-`Amm, Vol. 1, p. 263.
21
Mustafa al-Zarqa', op. cit., vol. 1, p. 551.

11
pìâìâ=~åÇ=íÜÉáê=`çåíÉãéçê~êó=^ééäáÅ~íáçåë=

purchase shares in investment accounts at their face value; thus negating the single
difference between conventional deposits and deposits in Islamic banks.

A Commitment by an Investment Agent


In some Sukuk, the manager is neither a mudarib nor a partner but an agent for the
Sukuk holders whose function is to invest the assets represented by the Sukuk. Then, is it
lawful [for the agent/manager] to promise the Sukuk holders that he will purchase the
assets at maturity for their face value? The answer is that such a commitment by an
investment agent, even if it is less egregious than a commitment by a partner or a
mudarib, it too is unlawful. This is because agency, wakalah, is a contract of trust,
amanah; and there can be no guarantees except as regards negligence or mala fides. The
aforementioned commitment is tantamount to a guarantee and is therefore unlawful.
This point is mentioned in para 1/2/2 of the Standard for Guarantees, issued by the
Shariah Council, as follows:

It is not lawful to stipulate a guarantee from a mudarib, or an investment agent,


or a partner among partners, regardless of whether the guarantee is for the
principal or for the profits. Likewise, an operation may not be marketed on the
basis that investor capital is guaranteed.

In the following para it is written:

It is unlawful to combine agency with a guarantee in a single transaction because


to do so is contrary to the requirements of both. This is because to stipulate a
guarantee by an investment agent transforms the operation into a loan with
ribawi interest, guaranteeing [the return of] principal while offering returns from
the investment.

It might, however, be imagined possible to justify such a commitment from an


investment agent on the basis of an issue that was established by the Standard in the same
para, where it is stated:

However, if the agency is not encumbered by a stipulation of guarantee [or


surety], and a guarantee for the agent was given in a separate agreement by
another, the agent will be a guarantor, but not in his capacity as agent, such that
if the agency were withdrawn he would remain a guarantor. 22

Then it might be said that the investment agent, though not originally a guarantor,
became a guarantor as a result of the commitment which is conducted separate from the
contract of agency.

The answer to this is that the proposed analogy contains a false comparison because the
agent described in the Standard acts as a guarantor under a separate agreement for a
debtor in the enterprise, such that the agent will not be responsible [as guarantor] unless
the debtor fails to make a required payment. The agent therefore does not guarantee for
the seller that his sale will be profitable under all circumstances. In the case of the Sukuk,

22
AAOIFI Standard 5: para 2.2.1 and 2.2.2

12
pìâìâ=~åÇ=íÜÉáê=`çåíÉãéçê~êó=^ééäáÅ~íáçåë=

the investment agent does not guarantee for a specific debtor, but rather against the
failure of the enterprise, such that his guarantee remains valid even after every debtor has
performed its obligations and the enterprise suffers losses as a result of falling prices in the
market, or for any other reason. So, how can the first instance be compared to this?

Then, adding to the confusion in regard to this commitment is that the manager is the
seller of the assets to the Sukuk holders, as is the case in most Sukuk, so that the
commitment leads to a sale of `iynah. 23 This is because he commits to buy what those to
whom he has committed are selling; unless the `iynah is negated by means of the
conditions which are well known in Islamic jurisprudence.

The Higher Purposes of Islamic Economics


To this point, this entire study has been conducted from the perspective of Islamic
jurisprudence. However, if we consider the matter from the perspective of the higher
purposes of Islamic law or the objectives of Islamic economics, then Sukuk in which are
to be found nearly all of the characteristics of conventional bonds are inimical in every
way to these higher purposes and objectives. The noble objective for which riba was
prohibited is the equitable distribution among partners of revenues from commercial and
industrial enterprises. The mechanisms used in Sukuk today, however, strike at the
foundations of these objectives and render the Sukuk exactly the same as conventional
bonds in terms of their economic results. Islamic banks were not established so that they
could offer the same products, and engage in the same operations, as conventional banks
in the prevalent interest-based banking system. Instead, the purpose was to gradually
open up new horizons for business, commerce, and banking that would be guided by
social justice in accordance with the principles established by the Shariah of Islam.
Undoubtedly, such an ambitious undertaking requires a gradual approach; and a gradual
approach may be imagined with a careful and detailed plan that outlines all of its various
stages. Likewise, if the undertaking is to advance it will require continual follow up
throughout each of its stages. A gradual approach does not mean that its progress will
depend on a single step for an undetermined period of time.

Undoubtedly, Shariah supervisory boards, academic councils, and legal seminars have
given permission to Islamic banks to carry out certain operations that more closely
resemble stratagems than actual transactions. Such permission, however, was granted in
order to facilitate, under difficult circumstances, the figurative turning of the wheels for
those institutions when they were few in number [and short of capital and human
resources]. It was expected that Islamic banks would progress in time to genuine
operations based on the objectives of an Islamic economic system and that they would
distance themselves, even step by step, from what resembled interest-based enterprises.
What is happening at the present time, however, is the opposite. Islamic financial
institutions have now begun competing to present themselves with all of the same
characteristics of the conventional, interest-based marketplace, and to offer new products
that march backwards towards interest-based enterprises rather than away from these.

23
This is a sale of appearances or of assistance, depending on the root of the word in Arabic; though, in
fact, both derivations are accurate portrayals of the transaction. This is because it is essentially a loan in the
form of a sale; so that it is a sale in appearance only and a means of offering assistance. This is accomplished
by one's buying back what one has sold for a lower price than that for which one originally sold it. The
difference, ostensibly profit, is actually a loan. YTD.

13
pìâìâ=~åÇ=íÜÉáê=`çåíÉãéçê~êó=^ééäáÅ~íáçåë=

Oftentimes these products are rushed to market using ploys that sound minds reject and
bring laughter to enemies.

In order to promote Sukuk, the justification given is that international ratings agencies
will not grant the desired, investor-grade ratings unless these mechanisms are used to
guarantee the return of principal to investors, and to distribute profits from capital at
specified rates. Without these mechanisms, so they say, it will not be possible to market
Sukuk widely. The answer to this objection is that if we are to continue to run behind
the international ratings agencies, agencies that do not distinguish between halal and
haram, it will never be possible for us to move forward with authentic Islamic products
which actually serve the purposes of Islamic economics. This is because these agencies
have matured in an interest-based atmosphere that is unable to acknowledge the quality
of an investment unless its capital is guaranteed and its returns are distributed on the
basis of interest. At the same time, the quality of a product from a Shariah perspective
depends upon the sharing of risk and the equitable distribution of profits between
investors. Thus, the Islamic mentality is diametrically opposed to the mentality of those
institutions.

As a result, Islamic Sukuk were introduced for Islamic banks and financial institutions
which aim to move beyond riba. Therefore, Sukuk should be circulated among these
banks on that basis. For the same reason, Sukuk should be acceptable between them so
that they have no need of conventional ratings. Recently, an Islamic ratings agency was
established. Islamic banks and financial institutions should strive to support that agency
so that they no longer have a need for conventional ratings agencies.

Actually, the number of Islamic banks and financial institutions today is not to be
overlooked, and thank God! The numbers increase day after day; and the growth of
Islamic banks in many countries is greater than that of conventional banks. It is now
incumbent upon these Islamic banks and financial institutions to cooperate among
themselves for the purpose of developing authentic products that are far removed from
empty stratagems, free from all association with riba, and that aim to serve the higher
purposes of Islamic law in the spheres of economics, development, and social justice.
None of this will come about without the guidance and encouragement of Shariah
supervisory boards. If these boards continue with their present policies, however, Islamic
banks will stumble on the road, and there is a danger, God forbid, that this virtuous
movement will fail. It is time for Shariah supervisory boards to review their policies, and
to moderate the license [they have granted] until now to benefit Islamic financial
institutions. Instead, the Shariah supervisory boards need to apply themselves to
upholding the Shariah Standards issued by the Shariah Council, standards which are not
insensitive to the real needs of these institutions. Personally, I am certain that if Shariah
supervisory boards uphold these Standards, the exceptional professional qualifications
found in today's Islamic financial institutions will have no difficulty in developing viable
alternatives to these dubious products… Allah willing.

Summary and Recommendations


1. Sukuk should be issued for new commercial and industrial ventures. If they are
issued for established businesses, then the Sukuk must ensure that Sukuk holders
have complete ownership in real assets.

14
pìâìâ=~åÇ=íÜÉáê=`çåíÉãéçê~êó=^ééäáÅ~íáçåë=

2. The returns of enterprises should be returned to Sukuk holders regardless of what


amounts they reach after costs, including the manager's fees, or the share of the
mudarib in profits. If there is to be an incentive for a manager, then let it be
based on the profits expected from the enterprise and not on the basis of an
interest rate.
3. It is unlawful for a manager to lend money when actual profits are less than
expected.
4. It is unlawful for a manager, whether a mudarib or a partner or an agent, to
commit to repurchase of assets at face value. Instead, their resale must be
undertaken on the basis of the net value of the assets, or at a price that is agreed
upon at the time of purchase.
5. Shariah supervisory boards must abide by the Shariah Standards issued by the
Shariah Council.

Finally, all praise is due to Allah, Lord of All the Worlds!

15

You might also like