Managerial Economics Course Outline
Managerial Economics Course Outline
Managerial Economics Course Outline
Monopolistic Competition Contestable Market Model Firm Strategies in Highly Competitive Markets Firm Competition and Market Structure Monopoly Oligopoly and Cartels Production Decisions in Noncartel Oligopolies Seller Concentration Competing in Tight Oligopolies: Pricing Strategies Competing in Tight Oligopolies: Nonpricing Strategies Buyer Power Market Regulation Free Market Economies Versus Collectivist Economies Efficiency and Equity Circumstances in Which Market Regulation May Be Desirable Regulation to Offset Market Power of Sellers or Buyers Natural Monopoly Externalities Externality Taxes Regulation of Externalities Through Property Rights High Cost to Initial Entrant and the Risk of Free Rider Producers Public Goods and the Risk of Free Rider Consumers Market Failure Caused by Imperfect Information Limitations of Market Regulation
managerial decisions in an organization, most of the subject material in managerial economics has a microeconomic focus. However, since managers must consider the state of their environment in making decisions and the environment includes the overall economy, an understanding of how to interpret and forecast macroeconomic measures is useful in making managerial decisions.
regulators. You will learn principles that should improve your intuition and your managerial decisions. You will also be able to communicate more effectively with your colleagues and with expert consultants. As with much of microeconomic theory, many of the economic principles in this book were originally derived with the help of mathematics and abstract models based on logic and algebra. In this book, the focus is on the insights gained from these principles, not the derivation of the principles, so only a modest level of mathematics is employed here and an understanding of basic algebra will suffice. We will consider some key economic models of managerial decision making, but these will be presented either verbally, graphically, or with simple mathematical representations. For readers who are interested in a more rigorous treatment, the reference list at the conclusion of this text includes several books that will provide more detail. Alternatively, a web search using one of the terms from this book will generally yield several useful links for further exploration of a concept. A note about economic models is that models are simplified representations of a real-world organization and its environment. Some aspects of the real-world setting are not addressed, and even those aspects that are addressed are simplifications of any actual setting being represented. The point of using models is not to match the actual setting in every detail, but to capture the essential aspects so determinations can be made quickly and with a modest cost. Models are effective when they help us understand the complex and uncertain environment and proceed to appropriate action.
Ne
revenue and cost (found by subtracting the cost from the revenue) is called the profit. When costs exceed revenue, there is a negative profit, or loss. The students in our simple venture realize they need to determine whether they can make a profit from a summer ice cream bar business. They met the person who operated an ice cream bar business in this building the previous summer. He told them last summer he charged $1.50 per ice cream bar and sold 36,000 ice cream bars. He said the cost of the ice cream bars wholesale purchase, delivery, storage, and so oncomes to about $0.30 per bar. He indicated his other main costsleasing the building, license, local business association fee, and insurancecame to about $16,000. Based on this limited information, the students could determine a rough estimate of the revenue, costs, and profit they would have if they were to repeat the outcomes for the prior operator. The revenue would be $1.50 per ice cream bar times 36,000 ice cream bars, or $54,000. The variable cost would be $0.30 per ice cream bar times 36,000 ice cream bars, or $10,800. The fixed cost would be $16,000, making the total cost $26,800. The profit would be $54,000 minus $26,800, or $27,200. Based on this analysis, the students are confident the summer business venture can make money. They approach the owner of the building and learn that if they want to reserve the right of first option to lease the building over the summer, they will need to make a nonrefundable $6000 deposit that will be applied to the lease. They proceeded to make that deposit. A few weeks later, all three students were unexpectedly offered summer business internships at a large corporation. Each student would earn $10,000. However, the work site for the internships is far from the beach and they would be in an office all day. They now must decide whether to accept the internships and terminate their plan to run a business at the beach or turn down the internships.
for the prior operator, the students would have a $16,000 accounting fixed cost to report on a tax return. Yet, from the perspective of economic costs, only $10,000 is really still avoidable by not operating the business. The remaining $6000 is gone regardless of what the students decide. So, from an economic cost/profit perspective, viewed after the nonrefundable deposit but before the students declined the summer internships, if the students other costs and revenue were identical to the previous year, they would have economic costs of just $50,800 and an economic profit of $3200. If a business properly measures costs from an economic perspective, ignoring sunk costs and including opportunity costs, you can conclude that a venture is worth pursuing if it results in an economic profit of zero or better. However, this is generally not a valid principle if you measure performance in terms of accounting profit. Most stockholders in a corporation would not be satisfied if the corporation only managed a zero accounting profit because this means there is no residual from the business to reward them with either dividends or increased stock value. From an economic cost perspective, stockholder capital is an asset that can be redeployed, and thus it has an opportunity costnamely, what the investor could earn elsewhere with their share of the corporation in a different investment of equivalent risk. [2] This opportunity cost could be estimated and included in the economic cost. If the resulting profit is zero or positive after netting out the opportunity cost of capital, the investors participation is worthwhile.
R = $1.5 Q,
where R is the revenue and Q is the number of units sold. The cost function for the ice cream bar venture has two components: the fixed cost component of $40,000 that remains the same regardless of the volume of units and the variable cost component of $0.30 times the number of items. The equation for the cost function is
C = $40,000 + $0.3 Q,
where C is the total cost. Note we are measuring economic cost, not accounting cost. Since profit is the difference between revenue and cost, the profit functions will be
= R C = $1.2 Q $40,000.
Here is used as the symbol for profit. (The letter P is reserved for use later as a symbol for price.) Table 2.1 "Revenue, Cost, and Profit for Selected Sales Volumes for Ice Cream Bar Venture" provides actual values for revenue, cost, and profit for selected values of the volume quantity Q. Figure 2.1 "Graphs of Revenue, Cost, and Profit Functions for Ice Cream Bar Business at Price of $1.50", provides graphs of the revenue, cost, and profit functions. The average cost is another interesting measure to track. This is calculated by dividing the total cost by the quantity. The relationship between average cost and quantity is the average cost function. For the ice cream bar venture, the equation for this function would be
Figure 2.1 Graphs of Revenue, Cost, and Profit Functions for Ice Cream Bar Business at Price of $1.50 Essentially the average cost function is the variable cost per unit of $0.30 plus a portion of the fixed cost allocated across all units. For low volumes, there are few units to spread the fixed cost, so the average cost is very high. However, as the volume gets large, the fixed cost impact on average cost becomes small and is dominated by the variable cost component. Figure 2.2 Graph of Average Cost Function for Ice Cream Bar Venture
Q = fixed cost/(price per unit variable cost per unit) = $40,000/($1.50 $0.30) = 33,333.3 or 33,334 units.
Once the operating volume crosses the breakeven threshold, each additional unit contribution margin results in additional profit. We get an interesting insight into the nature of a business by comparing the unit contribution margin with the price. In the case of the ice cream business, the unit contribution margin is 80% of the price. When the price and unit contribution margins are close, most of the revenue generated from additional sales turns into profit once you get above the breakeven level. However, if you fall below the breakeven level, the loss will grow equally dramatically as the volume level drops. Businesses like software providers, which tend have mostly fixed costs, see a close correlation between revenue and profit. Businesses of this type tend to be high risk and high reward. On the other hand, businesses that have predominantly variable costs, such as a retail grocery outlet, tend to have relatively modest changes in profit relative to changes in revenue. If business level falls off, they can scale down their variable costs and profit will not decline so much. At the same time, large increases in volume levels beyond the breakeven level can achieve only modest profit gains because most of the additional revenue is offset by additional variable costs.
between the price charged and the maximum unit quantity that could be sold. This relationship is called a demand curve. Demand curves generally follow a pattern called the law of demand, whereby increases in price result in decreases in the maximum quantity that can be sold. We will consider a simple demand curve for the ice cream venture. We will assume that since the operator of the business last year sold 36,000 units at a price of $1.50 that we could sell up to 36,000 units at the same price this coming summer. Next, suppose the students had asked the prior operator how many ice cream bars he believes he would have sold at a price of $2.00 and the prior operator responds that he probably would have sold 10,000 fewer ice cream bars. In other words, he estimates his sales would have been 26,000 at a price of $2.00 per ice cream bar. To develop a demand curve from the prior operators estimates, the students assume that the relationship between price and quantity is linear, meaning that the change in quantity will be proportional to the change in price. Graphically, you can infer this relationship by plotting the two price-quantity pairs on a graph and connecting them with a straight line. Using intermediate algebra, you can derive an equation for the linear demand curve
P = 3.3 0.00005 Q,
where P is price in dollars and Q is the maximum number of ice cream bars that will sell at this price. Figure 2.3 "Linear Demand Curve for Ice Cream Bar Venture" presents a graph of the demand curve. Figure 2.3 Linear Demand Curve for Ice Cream Bar Venture It may seem awkward to express the demand curve in a manner that you use the quantity Q to solve for the price P. After all, in a fixed price market, the seller decides a price and the buyers respond with the volume of demand. Mathematically, the relationship for ice cream bars could be written
Q = 66,000 20,000 P.
However, in economics, the common practice is to describe the demand curve as the highest price that could be charged and still sell a quantity Q. The linear demand curve in Figure 2.3 "Linear Demand Curve for Ice Cream Bar Venture" probably stretches credibility as you move to points where either the price is zero or demand is zero. In actuality, demand curves are usually curved such that demand will get very high as the price approaches zero and small amounts would still sell at very high prices, similar to the pattern in Figure 2.4 "Common Pattern for Demand Curves". However, linear demand curves can be reasonably good estimates of behavior if they are used within limited zone of possible prices. Figure 2.4 Common Pattern for Demand Curves We can use the stated relationship in the demand curve to examine the impact of price changes on the revenue and profit functions. (The cost function is unaffected by the demand curve.) Again, with a single type of product or service, revenue is equal to price times quantity. By using the expression for price in terms of quantity rather than a fixed price, we can find the resulting revenue function
determine the optimal level of planned production. The marginal revenue measures the change in revenue in response to a unit increase in production level or quantity. The marginal cost measures the change in cost corresponding to a unit increase in the production level. The marginal profitmeasures the change in profit resulting from a unit increase in the quantity. Marginal measures for economic functions are related to the operating volume and may change if assessed at a different operating volume level. There are multiple computational techniques for actually calculating these marginal measures. If the relationships have been expressed in the form of algebraic equations, one approach is to evaluate the function at the quantity level of interest, evaluate the function if the quantity level is increased by one, and determine the change from the first value to the second. Suppose we want to evaluate the marginal revenue for the revenue function derived in the previous section at last summers operating level of 36,000 ice cream bars. For a value of Q = 36,000, the revenue function returns a value of $54,000. For a value of Q = 36,001, the revenue function returns a value of $53,999.70. So, with this approach, the marginal revenue would be $53,999.70 $54,000, or $0.30. What does this tell us? First, it tells us that for a modest increase in production volume, if we adjust the price downward to compensate for the increase in quantity, the net change in revenue is a decrease of $0.30 for each additional unit of planned production. Marginal measures often can be used to assess the change if quantity is decreased by changing sign on the marginal measure. Thus, if the marginal revenue is $0.30 at Q = 36,000, we can estimate that for modest decreases in planned quantity level (and adjustment of the price upward based on the demand function), revenue will rise $0.30 per unit of decrease in Q. At first glance, the fact that a higher production volume can result in lower revenue seems counterintuitive, if not flawed. After all, if you sell more and are still getting a positive price, how can more volume result in less revenue? What is happening in this illustrated instance is that the price drop, as a percentage of the price, exceeds the increase in quantity as a percentage of quantity. A glance back at Figure 2.5 "Graphs of Revenue, Cost, and Profit Functions for Ice Cream Bar Venture for Linear Demand Curve" confirms that Q = 36,000 is in the portion of the revenue function where the revenue function declines as quantity gets larger. If you follow the same computational approach to calculate the marginal cost and marginal profit when Q = 36,000, you would find that the marginal cost is $0.30 and the marginal profit is $0.60. Note that marginal profit is equal to marginal revenue minus marginal cost, which will always be the case. The marginal cost of $0.30 is the same as the variable cost of acquiring and stocking an ice cream bar. This is not just a coincidence. If you have a cost function that takes the form of a linear equation, marginal cost will always equal the variable cost per unit. The fact that marginal profit is negative at Q = 36,000 indicates we can expect to find a more profitable value by decreasing the quantity and increasing the price, but not by increasing the quantity and decreasing the price. The marginal profit value does not provide enough information to tell us how much to lower the planned quantity, but like a compass, it points us in the right direction. Since marginal measures are the rate of change in the function value corresponding to a modest change in Q, differential calculus provides another computational technique for deriving marginal measures. Differential calculus finds instantaneous rates of change, so the values computed are based on infinitesimal changes in Q rather than whole units of Q and thus can yield slightly different values. However, a great strength of using differential calculus is that whenever you have an economic function in the form of an algebraic equation, you can use differential calculus to derive an entire function that can be used to calculate the marginal value at any value of Q. How to apply differential calculus is beyond the scope of this text; however, here are the functions that can be derived from the revenue, cost, and profit functions of the previous section (i.e., those that assume a variable price related to quantity):
marginal revenue at a volume Q = $3.3 $0.0001 Q,marginal cost at a volume Q = $ 0.3,marginal profit at a volume Q = $3 $0.0001 Q.
Substituting Q = 36,000 into these equations will produce the same values we found earlier. However, these marginal functions are capable of more. Since the marginal change in the function is the rate of change in the function at a particular point, you can visualize this by looking at the graphs of the functions and drawing a tangent line on the graph at the quantity level of interest. A tangent line is a straight line that goes through the point on the graph, but does not cross the graph as it goes through the point. The slope of the tangent line is the marginal value of the function at that point. When the slope is upward (the tangent line rises as it goes to the right), the marginal measure will be positive. When the
slope is downward, the marginal measure will be negative. If the line has a steep slope, the magnitude of the marginal measure will be large. When the line is fairly flat, the magnitude will be small. Suppose we want to find where the profit function is at its highest value. If you look at that point (in the vicinity of Q = 30,000) on Figure 2.5 "Graphs of Revenue, Cost, and Profit Functions for Ice Cream Bar Venture for Linear Demand Curve", you see it is like being on the top of a hill. If you draw the tangent line, it will not be sloped upward or downward; it will be a flat line with a zero slope. This means the marginal profit at the quantity with the highest profit has a value of zero. So if you set the marginal profit function equal to zero and solve for Q you find
will be going down, although it may be a net gain to operate for some additional time, such a firm should eventually decide to close down its business. Sometimes, it is appropriate to shut down a business for a period of time, but not to close the business permanently. This may happen if temporary unfavorable circumstances mean even uncommitted costs cannot be covered by revenue in the near term, but the business expects favorable conditions to resume later. An example of this would be the owner of an oil drilling operation. If crude oil prices drop very low, the operator may be unable to cover variable costs and it would be best to shut down until petroleum prices climb back and operations will be profitable again. In other cases, the opportunity cost of resources may be temporarily high, so the economic profit is negative even if the accounting profit would be positive. An example would be a farmer selling his water rights for the upcoming season because he is offered more for the water rights than he could net using the water and farming.
sales revenue. Techniques such as cost-benefit analysis [2] have been developed for this purpose.
Economists have precise techniques for separating the response to a price change into a substitution effect and an income effect. [1] This is beyond the scope of this text. For our purposes, it is sufficient to appreciate that price changes will affect the mix of goods and services that is best and change the consumers overall level of satisfaction. In most cases, the primary response to a price change is a substitution effect, with a relatively modest income effect. However, for goods and services that a consumer cannot substitute easily, a sizeable price change may have a significant income effect. For example, when gasoline prices jumped dramatically in the United States, consumers may have reduced their driving somewhat but were unable to find a substitute for the essential needs served by driving their cars. As a result, consumers experienced a dramatic drop in wealth available for other goods and services and consumed generally less of all of those to compensate for the greater expenditure on gasoline. Normally, price increases result in less consumption of the associated good or service, whereas price decreases results in more consumption. This typical pattern is usually supported by both the substitution effect and the income effect. An interesting exception is the case of Giffen goods, which is a situation where consumption of a good or service may increase in response to a price increase or decrease in response to a price decrease. This anomaly is explained by a strong income effect. An economist named Robert Giffen discovered that Irish consumers increased the use of potatoes in their diet during the Irish Potato Famine of the 1840s, even though the price of potatoes rose dramatically. Basically, because potatoes were a staple of the Irish diet, when the potato price increased, the wealth available to purchase other food items diminished and Irish consumers wanted to purchase more potatoes to compensate for the diminished purchases of other food items.
Probably the most important influencing factor is one we considered for the ice cream business in Chapter 2 "Key Measures and Relationships"the price of the item itself. Price is also the key determinant of demand in the theory of the consumer. In the simplest cases, there is a single price that applies to any item or unit of service being sold. However, as we will discuss later in the section on price discrimination, prices may vary depending on who is buying it and how much they are buying. Businesses incur promotional costs to boost the consumption of their products. Promotion can be in the form of advertising, free samples, appearance in business directories, and so on. The theory of the consumer provides a supporting rationale for expenditure on promotion: If a consumer is regarded as deciding how to allocate his wealth across available goods and services, in order for your product to be included as a candidate in that choice, the consumer has to be aware that your product or service exists. However, as we will discuss in Chapter 7 "Firm Competition and Market Structure", large firms often engage in promotion at expenditure levels well beyond what is needed to make your firm and product known to the consumer, as a tactic of competition. Consumer demand may vary depending on where and when the consumption is occurring. Being able to quantitatively assess how consumption changes by location or time is a powerful tool in deciding where and when to sell your product. Some businesses decide to serve broad geographical regions; others target specific locations. Some businesses sell most or all times of the day and days of the year; others limit their operations to a restricted number of hours or periods within a year. What strategy will work best will depend on the product and the companys overall marketing strategy. Businesses have a choice of channels for selling. They can operate their own commercial establishments or sell wholesale to other retailers. Goods can be sold directly at a retail site or via the Internet, telephone, or mail order. Understanding how the channels used will affect demand is important. The selection of price, promotional activities, location, and channel are generally in the control of the business concern. In texts on marketing strategy, [1] the composition of these decisions is called a marketing mix. For a marketing mix to be effective, the different elements need to be consistent. However, there are other important determinants of consumption for a good or service that are largely out of the control of the providing firm. We will next consider some of these determinants. As suggested by the substitution effect in the theory of the consumer, the consumer is able to alter his pattern of consumption to meet his needs as prices and wealth levels change. The most significant swaps are likely to be between goods and services that come close to meeting the same consumer need. For example, a banana can serve as a substitute for a peach in meeting the need for a piece of fruit. Usually the items that act as substitutes to the product of one firm will be sold by a different firm. Consequently, how that other firm elects to price, promote, locate, and channel its goods or services will have an impact on the consumption of substitutable goods or services sold by the first firm. Different goods and services can be strongly related in another way called a complementary relationship. Consumption of some goods and services can necessitate greater consumption of other goods and services. For example, if more automobiles are sold, there will be increased demand for tires, oil, repair services, automobile financing, automobile insurance, and so on. Correctly monitoring and forecasting the demand of key complements can improve the ability of a firm to forecast its own consumer demand. Most firms sell multiple products and services that are related. Within this collection, there are probably important substitute and complementary relationships. A car dealer that sells several models of vehicles has substitutable products that compete with each other. The car dealer may be offering services like repair service and financing that are complementary to vehicle sales. In situations with strong substitute and complementary product relationships, the firm needs to consider these in its demand forecasting and market strategy. Earlier, we discussed the income effect caused by price changes and indicated that this is caused by the consumer realizing an increase or decrease in overall purchasing wealth. Probably a more significant cause of changes in wealth occurs from fluctuations in the economic activity, which will affect the demand for most goods and services. The relationship between demand quantities and economic indicators of economic activity or disposable income can improve business forecasting considerably. Demand is also affected by the demographics of the population of eligible customers. How many people live in a region, their ethnic and socioeconomic composition, and age distribution can explain variations in demand across regions and the ability to forecast in the future as these demographics change.
P = the price per month of their service, in dollars,A = advertising expenditure per month, in dollars,CP = the price per month of the competitors service, in dollars,DIPC = the disposable income per capita, in dollars, as measured by the U.S. Department of Commerce for that month.
Using past data, they estimate the following equation to relate these variables to number of broadband subscribers to their service during a month, symbolized by Q:
Q = 64,000 800 P.
Recall that demand curves are usually expressed with price as a function of quantity. With some basic algebra the equation of the demand curve can be written as
P = $80 $0.00125 Q.
What happens to the demand curve if one of the other variables is a different value? Well, in short, the demand curve would shift. Suppose the competitor decides to increase its price to $35. Repeating the preceding steps, the demand function simplifies to
Q = 66,000 800 P
or, expressed with P as a function of Q,
P = $82.50 0.00125 Q.
Figure 3.1 "Shift in Demand Curve for Broadband Service Caused by Increase of Competitor Price From $25/month to $35/month" shows a graph of the demand curve before and after the shift. Effectively, the result is that the broadband firm would see its demand increase by 2000 customers per month, or alternatively, the firm could raise its price to $32.50 and still maintain 40,000 customers per month.
organization or production activities occur after a purchase is made, usually need to have supplies, trained labor, and management structures in place in advance of the order to be in a position to negotiate a sale. Figure 3.1 Shift in Demand Curve for Broadband Service Caused by Increase of Competitor Price From $25/month to $35/month Without some concrete estimate of what level of demand will result after these planning, designing, and production activities, a business may find itself with an excess of unused capacity or unable to serve the demand that follows. Excess capability is costly because idle resources have an opportunity cost but do not contribute to sales or revenue, especially when the unused resources spoil and cannot be used at a later time. When businesses set production targets too low, they discover missed opportunities for profit and unmet demand that is likely to discourage those consumers from being customers in the future. To a limited extent, a business may be able to alter future demand to be more in line with its capacity because it has control over some determinants of demand, like pricing, promotion, and location. If the business is surprised by demand levels that are higher or lower than expected, these market strategy elements can be adjusted to either stimulate or diminish demand to conform to its production capabilities. Still, the financial performance of an enterprise is improved when the demand is consistent with the levels anticipated in the initial planning stages. Further, most businesses are not in control of all the key determinants of demand. The business cannot control the direction of the overall economy and consumer incomes. The business may be able to guess at, but not control, actions by other companies that sell substitute and complementary goods and services. Anticipating the impact of these outside forces is critical. Businesses can improve demand forecasting with their demand functions using the future values of determinant variables in those demand functions. Forecasts for widely followed economic indicators like disposable income are available from public releases or private forecasting services. If the business has a record of data for these uncontrollable variables, they can apply quantitative forecasting techniques like time series analysis or develop casual models that relate these factors to other variables that can be forecast. Readers are encouraged to look at a text in business forecasting for assistance in doing quantitative forecasts. [1] For variables where past patterns may not continue into the future, like competitor actions on pricing and promotion or unexpected climate events, a business can construct scenarios in which management postulates settings for these factors and then develops a demand forecast for each scenario. Although the future will almost certainly not conform exactly to any single scenario, the exercise prepares them to monitor for changes in these factors and be ready to make a prompt response whenever a similar scenario emerges.
If we let the price increase by 10% from $30 to $33 and repeat the calculation of Q in the demand function, the value of Q will decline to 37,600 subscribers, which is a decline of 2400 customers. As a percentage of 40,000 monthly customers, this would be a 6% decrease. So the price elasticity here would be
clearly displayed, most customers would avoid the station that tried to increase the price and that station would see nearly all of its business disappear. In this situation where the competitors goods are highly substitutable, the price elasticity for a single gasoline station would be very price elastic.
3.7 Consumption Decisions in the Short Run and the Long Run
The main reason most consumers are unable to respond very quickly to an increase in gasoline prices is because there is not an effective substitute for automobile travel. However, if consumers were convinced that gasoline prices were going to continue to rise into the foreseeable future, they would gradually make changes to their lifestyles so that they are able to reduce gasoline consumption significantly. They could purchase more fuel-efficient cars or cars that use an alternative fuel, or they could change jobs or change residences so that they are closer to their places of employment, shopping, and such. Economists distinguish short-run decisions from long-run decisions. A consumer decision is considered short run when her consumption will occur soon enough to be constrained by existing household assets, personal commitments, and know-how. Given sufficient time to remove these constraints, the consumer can change her consumption patterns and make additional improvements in the utility of consumption. Decisions affecting consumption far enough into the future so that any such adjustments can be made are called long-run decisions. Demand functions and demand curves can be developed for short-run or long-run time horizons. Short-run demand curves are easier to develop because they estimate demand in the near future and generally do not require a long history of data on consumption and its determinant factors. Because long-run demand must account for changes in consumption styles, it requires longer histories of data and greater sophistication. Elasticities of demand in the short run can differ substantially from elasticities in the long run. Long-run price elasticities for a product are generally of higher magnitude than their short-run counterparts because the consumer has sufficient time to change consumption styles. There is so much uncertainty about long-run consumption that these analyses are usually limited to academic and government research. Short-run analyses, on the other hand, are feasible for many analysts working for the businesses that must estimate demand in order to make production decisions.
price, but one that is usually higher than the seller actually expects to receive. This falls short of pure first-degree discrimination because the buyer is probably able to negotiate down from the most he would pay, possibly quite a bit if the buyer is a good negotiator. In addition, there is time and effort expended in the negotiating, which is a kind of cost to the transaction that the buyer may see as part of the purchase cost and the seller may see as an added cost of business. Goods and services are sometimes sold or purchased via an auction. This is usually an effective means when the seller has a limited number of items to sell. Run properly, an auction will distinguish those willing to pay more, although it probably will not manage to get a bid as high as the maximum the buyer would have paid. Again, the cost of operating an auction is expensive in comparison to selling using a set, preannounced price. Businesses that sell a product that is in demand with no good substitute available will sometimes employ a sliding price, where they begin selling at a very high price that is attractive to relatively few consumers. After a time when presumably those high-value customers make their purchases, the business will drop the price somewhat and attract purchases from another group that was willing pay slightly less than the first group. Successive price drops can continue until it would be unprofitable for the seller to drop the price any lower. Sliding prices are sometimes used with products that employ new technologies, when the initial seller has the market to itself, at least for a while, and offers a got-to-have item for some customers. Of course, although these eager customers may be willing to pay more, they may be aware of this pricing strategy and delay their purchase, so this approach will not extract the full value customers would have been willing to pay. When goods and services are sold according to a preannounced price, the customary arrangement is that the charge for multiple items is the price times the number of items. This is called linear pricing. However, customers differ in the volume they are interested in purchasing. A business may benefit by offering different prices to those who purchase in larger volumes because either they can increase their profit with the increased volume sales or their costs per unit decrease when items are purchased in volume. Businesses can create alternative pricing methods that distinguish high-volume buyers from low-volume buyers. This is seconddegree price discrimination. A donut shop might offer a free donut to anyone who purchases a whole dozen because the purchase requires less clerk time per donut sold and increases how many donuts get purchased. However, since only those who buy at least a dozen donuts get a free donut, the discount is limited to those people and not the customer who purchases just a donut or two. This would be second-degree price discrimination. Another nonlinear pricing scheme to employ second-degree discrimination is a two-part price. A customer pays a flat charge to be a customer and then pays a per unit charge based on how much they consume. Some services like telephone service are primarily fixed cost and have a very small per unit variable cost. By charging telephone customers a flat monthly fee and low per unit charge, they encourage more use of the service than if they simply charged a linear price per unit and see more revenue in relation to costs. Membership stores that require customers to pay an entry fee before being allowed to shop, but offer lower prices than regular stores for purchased items, is another example of a two-part pricing. Third-degree price discrimination is differential pricing to different groups of customers. One justification for this practice is that producing goods and services for sale to one identifiable group of customers is less than the cost of sales to another group of customers. For example, a publisher of music or books may be able to sell a music album or a book in electronic form for less cost than a physical form like a compact disc or printed text. A second justification for charging different prices to different groups of customers is that one group may be more sensitive to price than the other group. Earlier we discussed elasticity of demand. If we separated the demand for the two groups into separate demand curves, at any given price the more price sensitive group will have stronger negative price elasticity. Sellers are able to increase economic profit by charging a lower price to the price-elastic group and a higher price to the more price-inelastic group. As an example, 25 years ago music was sold in two formats: cassette tapes and compact discs. The production cost of a cassette tape was roughly equivalent to a compact disc, but music on compact discs often retailed at a higher price because it was perceived that customers of compact discs were more demanding of quality and more price inelastic. To apply third-degree price discrimination, the seller must be able to clearly identify and sort the customer by a salient characteristic. For example, a cable provider may be aware that existing subscribers are price inelastic relative to other households that are not existing customers. The cable provider will typically charge reduced rates to attract new customers and is able to execute the price discrimination because it knows whether a customer is an existing customer or not. A sports clothing retailer may know that fans of a team are more price inelastic
in the purchase of apparel displaying the name or mascot of that team than customers who are not fans. However, if the clothing retailer were to attempt to charge differential prices, the customers who are fans would have the incentive to disguise that characteristic, so third-degree price discrimination would not work well in this case.
the short-run capacity of the business operation. In the economic sense of the word, we might think of capacity as the volume level where we have the most efficient operation in terms of average cost. Many businesses can operate over capacity, up to some effective physical limit, but in so doing will pay for that supplemental production volume in higher costs, due to needing to employ either more expensive resources or less productive resources, creating congestion that slows production, or overusing resources that results in higher maintenance costs per unit. If the price earned by the business at these overcapacity volumes is sufficiently high, the firm may realize more profit by operating over capacity than at the capacity point where total average cost is at its lowest. Similarly, if demand is weak and customers will pay a price well in excess of average cost only at volumes lower than capacity, the firm will probably do better by operating below capacity. However, if a firm that is operating well above capacity or well below capacity does not see this as a temporary situation, the discrepancy suggests that the firm is sized either too small or too large. The firm may be able to improve profits in future production periods by resizing its operations, which will readjust the capacity point. If the firm operates in a very competitive market, there may even be little potential for profit for firms that are not operating near their capacity level.
For example, in Figure 4.2 "Graph of Long-Run Average Cost (LRAC) Function Shown as the Short-Run Average Cost (SRAC) at Capacity for Different Scales of Operation", the long-run average cost on curve LRAC at a production rate of 1000 units per period is the lowest cost, or cost at the capacity point, for a cost structure reflected by short-run average cost curve SRAC1. The long-run average cost at a production rate of 2000 units per production period is the lowest cost for average cost curve SRAC2 (which has a capacity of 2000). The long-run average cost at a production rate of 3000 units per production would be the average cost at capacity for SRAC3. Like short-run average cost curves, long-run average cost curves trend downward at low target production rates, although the rate of decline in the long-run average cost curve is somewhat flatter due to the ability to readjust all factors of production. The typical reason for this declining long-run average cost curve at low production levels is because there are efficiencies in cost or production that can be exploited for modest increases in quantity. For example, for a business that is manufacturing major appliances or vehicles that require several assembly steps, in a larger operation it is possible to assign different assembly steps to different workers and, via this specialization, speed up the rate of production over what would be possible if the firm hired the same workers with each worker performing all assembly steps. As we pointed out in the previous chapter, customers who buy in large quantities can sometimes buy at a lower per unit price. Since most firms are buyers as well as sellers, and larger firms will buy in larger quantities, they can reduce the contribution of acquired parts and materials to the average cost. Figure 4.2 Graph of Long-Run Average Cost (LRAC) Function Shown as the Short-Run Average Cost (SRAC) at Capacity for Different Scales of Operation The ability to reduce long-run average cost due to increased efficiencies in production and cost will usually eventually subside. The production level at which the long-run average cost curve flattens out is called the minimum efficient scale. (Since the business is able to adjust all factors of production in the long run, it can effectively rescale the entire operation, so the target production level is sometimes called thescale of the business.) In competitive seller markets, the ability of a firm to achieve minimum efficient scale is crucial to its survival. If one firm is producing at minimum efficient scale and another firm is operating below minimum efficient scale, it is possible for the larger firm to push market prices below the cost of the smaller firm, while continuing to charge a price that exceeds its average cost. Facing the prospect of sustained losses, the smaller firm usually faces a choice between getting larger or dropping out of the market. The increase in capacity needed to achieve minimum efficient scale varies by the type of business. A bicycle repair shop might achieve minimum efficient scale with a staff of four or five employees and be able to operate at an average cost that is no different than a shop of 40 to 50 repair persons. At the other extreme, electricity distribution services and telephone services that have very large fixed asset costs and low variable costs may see the long-run average cost curve decline even for large production levels and therefore would have a very high minimum efficient scale. Most firms have a long-run average cost curve that declines and then flattens out; however, in some markets the long-run average cost may actually rise after some point. This phenomenon often indicates a limitation in some factors of production or a decline in quality in factors of production if the scale increases enough. For example, in agriculture some land is clearly better suited to certain crops than other land. In order to match the yield of the best acreage on land of lower quality, it may be necessary to spend more on fertilizer, water, or pest control, thereby increasing the average cost of production for all acreage used. Businesses that are able to lower their average costs by increasing the scale of their operation are said to have economies of scale. Firms that will see their average costs increase if they further increase their scale will experience diseconomies of scale. Businesses that have achieved at least their minimum efficient scale and would see the long-run average cost remain about the same with continued increases in scale may be described as having constant economies of scale. The impact of an increase of scale on production is sometimes interpreted in terms of returns to scale. The assessment of returns to scale is based on the response to the following question: If all factors of production (raw materials, labor, energy, equipment time, etc.) where increased by a set percentage (say all increased by 10%), would the percent increase in potential quantity of output created be greater, the same, or less than the percent increase in all factors of production? If potential output increases by a higher percent, operations are said to have increasing returns to scale. If output increases by the same percent, the operations show constant returns to scale. If the percent growth in outputs is less than the percent increase in inputs used, there are decreasing returns to scale. Returns to scale are related to the concept of economies of scale, yet there is a subtle difference. The earlier example of gained productivity of labor specialization when the labor force is increased would contribute to increasing returns to scale. Often when there are increasing
returns to scale there are economies of scale because the higher rate of growth in output translates to decrease in average cost per unit. However, economies of scale may occur even if there were constant returns to scale, such as if there were volume discounts for buying supplies in larger quantities. Economies of scale mean average cost decreases as the scale increases, whereas increasing returns to scale are restricted to the physical ratio between the increase in units of output relative to proportional increase in the number of inputs used. Likewise, decreasing returns to scale often translate to diseconomies of scale. If increasing the acreage used for a particular crop by using less productive acreage results in a smaller increase in yield than increase in acreage, there are decreasing returns to scale. Unless the acreage costs less to use, there will be an increase in average cost per unit of crop output, indicating diseconomies of scale.
may be addressed by iteration between output planning and production/procurement planning until there is consistency. Another option is to use sophisticated computer models that determine the optimal output levels and minimum cost production configurations simultaneously. Among the range of procurement and production activities that a business conducts to create its goods and services, the firm may be more proficient or expert in some of the activities, at least relative to its competition. For example, a firm may be world class in factory production but only about average in the cost effectiveness of its marketing activities. In situations where a firm excels in some components of its operations, there may be an opportunity for improved profitability by recognizing these key areas, sometimes called core competencies in the business strategy literature, and then determining what kinds of goods or services would best exploit these capabilities. This is the resource approach to the planning of production. [2] Conceptually, either planning approach will lead to similar decisions about what goods and services to provide and how to arrange production to do that. However, given the wide ranges of possible outputs and organizations of production to provide them, firms are not likely to attain truly optimal organization, particularly after the fact. The cost approach is often easier to conduct, particularly for a firm that is already in a particular line of business and can make incremental improvements to reduce cost. However, in solving the problem of how to create the goods and services at minimal cost, there is some risk of myopic focus that dismisses opportunities to make the best use of core competencies. The resource approach encourages more out-of-the-box thinking that may lead a business toward a major restructuring.
relationship depicted in Figure 4.3 "Typical Pattern of a Derived Demand Curve Relating the Marginal Revenue Product to Quantity of Input Employed in Production"is called a derived demand curve. Figure 4.3 Typical Pattern of a Derived Demand Curve Relating the Marginal Revenue Product to Quantity of Input Employed in Production One difficulty in comparing marginal revenue product to the marginal cost of an input is that the mere increase in any single input is usually not enough in itself to create more units of output. For example, simply acquiring more bicycle frames will not result in the ability to make more bicycles, unless the manufacturer acquires more wheels, tires, brakes, seats, and such to turn those frames into bicycles. In cases like this, sometimes the principle needs to be applied to a fixed mix of inputs rather than a single input. For the accounting firm in the earlier example, the cost to acquire an additional accountant is not merely the salary he is paid. The firm will pay for benefits like retirement contribution and health care for the new employee. Further, additional inputs in the form of an office, computer, secretarial support, and such will be incurred. So the fact that the marginal revenue product of an accountant is $150,000 does not mean that the firm would benefit if the accountant were hired at any salary less than $150,000. Rather, it would profit if the additional cost of salary, benefits, office expense, secretarial support, and so on is less than $150,000.
business. Consequently, the supplier may have little choice about accepting reduced prices.
downstream firm can require documentation of quality control processes in the upstream firm. When upstream firms are concerned that they may not realize a sufficient volume of exchanges over time to justify the investment in fixed assets, the upstream firm can demand a take-or-pay contract that obligates the buyer to either fulfill its intended purchases or compensate the supplier to offset losses that will occur. This type of agreement is particularly important in the case of specific assets in economics, where the supplier would have no viable alternative for redeploying the fixed assets to another use. Although some of these measures may obviate the need for a firm to expand vertically in a value chain, in some circumstances forming the necessary agreements is difficult to accomplish. This is especially the case when one party in a vertical arrangement maintains private information that can be used to its advantage to create a better deal for itself but potentially will be a bad arrangement for the party that does not have that information in advance. As a result, parties that are aware of their limited information about the other party will tend to be more conservative in their agreement terms by assuming pessimistic circumstances and will not be able to reach an agreement. This reaction is called adverse selection in economic literature. [2] In some cases, one party in a vertical arrangement may have production or planning secrets that do not affect the agreement per se but risk being discovered by the other party as the result of any exchange transactions. These secrets may be the result of costly research and development but may pass to the other party at essentially no cost, and the other party may take advantage of that easily obtained information. This is a version of what economists call the free rider problem. [3] Due to the difficulty of protecting against problems of adverse selection and free riders, firms may conclude that vertical integration is the better option.
5.6 Conglomerates
As stated earlier, a conglomerate is a business enterprise that participates in multiple value chains that are different in nature. An example of a conglomerate is General Electric, which engages in the manufacture of appliances, construction of energy facilities, financing of projects, and media ventures, just to name a portion of its product portfolio. One attraction of conglomerates is the ability to diversify so that the firm can withstand difficult times in one industry by having a presence in other kinds of markets. Beyond diversification, a conglomerate can move capital from one of its businesses to another business without the cost and difficulties of using outside capital markets. Often conglomerates will have some divisions that are cash cows in being profitable operations in mature markets, and other businesses that have great potential but require sizeable investment that can be funded by profits from the cashcow businesses. [1] Another argument for conglomerates is that companies with very talented management staffs may be capable of excelling in more than one type of business. For instance, the former chairman of General Electric, Jack Welch, was widely praised as providing superior senior management for the wide range of businesses in which General Electric participated. [1] The concept of cash-cow businesses is an aspect of the Boston Consulting Group matrix for corporate strategy (1970).
management. The culture of a successful manufacturer of consumer goods is not necessarily the culture of a startup software company. When many kinds of businesses are part of the same corporation, it may be difficult to synchronize different business cultures. Economists have developed a theory called transaction cost economics to try to explain when a firm should expand and when it should not, or even when the firm would do better to either break apart or sell off some of its business units. A transaction cost is the cost involved in making an exchange. An exchange can be external or internal. An external exchange occurs when two separate businesses are involved, like the television manufacturer and its parts supplier in the earlier example. Prior to the actual exchange of parts for cash, there is a period in which the companies need to come to agreement on price and other terms. The external transaction costs are the costs to create and monitor this agreement. If a firm decides to expand its boundaries to handle the exchange internally, there are new internal transaction costs. These would be the costs to plan and coordinate these internal exchanges. If exchanges of this nature have not been done before, these internal transaction costs can be significant. Nobel Prize laureate Ronald Coase introduced the concept of transaction costs and also proposed a principle for determining when to expand known as the Coase hypothesis. [1] Essentially, the principle states that firms should continue to expand as long as internal transaction costs are less than external transaction costs for the same kind of exchange. [1] The initial article that stimulated later development of the transaction cost concept was by Ronald Coase (1937).
Another approach to the problem of pricing interdivision exchanges is to base prices on principles rather than negotiation. Academic research has concluded a number of principles for different kinds of situations. In this section, we will limit our consideration to two of these situations. Suppose two divisions in an enterprise, Division A and Division B, exchange a good that is only produced by Division A. More specifically, there is no other division either inside or outside the enterprise that currently produces the good. Division B is the only user of this good, either inside or outside of the enterprise. Under these conditions, theoretically the best transfer price is the marginal cost of the good incurred by Division A. No formal proof of this principle will be offered here, but a brief defense of this principle would be as follows: Suppose the price charged was less than the marginal cost. If Division A decides on the production volume that would maximize its internal divisional profit, then by reducing its volume somewhat, Division A would avoid more cost than it loses in forgone transfer revenue. So Division A would elect to provide fewer units than Division B would want. On the other hand, suppose the transfer price was set at a level higher than the marginal cost. Since the transfer cost becomes a component of cost to receiving Division B, in determining its optimal volume of production, Division B will see a higher marginal cost than is actually the case (or would be the case if Divisions A and B functioned as a single unit). As a result, Division B may decide on a production level that is not optimal for the overall enterprise. By setting the transfer price equal to Division As marginal cost, the decision by Division B should be the same as it would be if the two divisions operated as one. Although the principle is reasonably clear and defensible in theory, the participating divisions in an actual setting may raise objections. If the average cost of the item to Division A is less than the marginal cost, Division B may complain that they should not need to pay a transfer price above the average cost because that is what the actual cost per item is to Division A and the enterprise overall. If the average cost per item exceeds the marginal cost, Division A may complain that setting the transfer price to the marginal cost requires their division to operate at a loss for this item and they should be credited with at least the average cost. Nonetheless, the best decisions by Divisions A and B for the overall profit of the enterprise will occur when the transfer price is based on the marginal cost to Division A in this situation. As a second case situation, suppose the good transferred from Division A to Division B is a good that is both produced and consumed outside the enterprise and there is a highly competitive market for both buyers and sellers. In this instance the best internal transfer price between Division A and Division B would be the external market price. A supporting argument for this principle is this: If the transfer price were higher than the outside market price, Division B could reduce its costs by purchasing the good in the outside market rather than obtaining it from Division A. If the outside market price were higher than the set transfer price, Division A would make higher divisional profit by selling the good on the outside market than by transferring it to Division B.
classical approach to setting wages is that the wage paid to an employee should be no more than the marginal revenue product corresponding to her effort. However, if an employee is paid barely what her efforts are worth to the firm at the margin and if there is a competitive market for the employees services in other firms, the employee may not be motivated to work at maximum capacity or avoid engaging in behaviors that are detrimental to the firm because she can earn as much elsewhere if she is dismissed. An efficiency wage is a wage that is set somewhat above the marginal revenue product of the employee to give the employee an incentive to be productive and retain this job because the employee would sacrifice the difference between the efficiency wage and marginal revenue product if she sought employment elsewhere. This incentive is worthwhile to the firm because it avoids the transaction costs of finding and hiring a new employee. Another contribution of this economic viewpoint of employee motivation is an examination of employee contracts to deal with what is called the principal-agent problem. In this context, the hiring business is a principal that hires an employee (agent) to act on its behalf. The problem occurs when the agent is motivated to take actions that are not necessarily what the employer would want, but the employer is not able to monitor all the activities of the employee and has insufficient information. In the employment relationship the employer evaluates the employee on the basis of her contribution to profit or other objective of the firm. However, the employee evaluates her activities based on the amount of effort involved. To the degree that employees see their compensation and incentives connected to the intensity of effort, the more likely the employee will invest additional effort because there is reduced risk that her efforts will go unrewarded. For example, if employee incentives are based on the overall performance of a team of employees without any discrimination between individual employees, there is an incentive for employees to shirk in performance of their jobs because they still benefit if others do the work and they do not risk putting in an extra effort to see the reward diminished by sharing the incentives with others who did not put in the same effort. The informativeness principle suggests that measures of performance that reflect individual employee effort be included in employee contracts. [2] A third interesting contribution of this perspective on employee motivation is the concept of signaling. [3] When employers hire, they face a pool of possible employees. Some employees will perform well, whereas others will not due to either lack of skills or lack of character. In the interview process, the employer will try to assess which applicants will be good employees, but these evaluation processes are imperfect. The real intentions of the applicant if and when he becomes an employee are largely private information until the person is actually hired and on the job for a while. As a result, employers face an adverse selection problem similar to what was discussed earlier in the context of vertical integration and will often protect against the risk by lowering the compensation offered, even though they would be willing to pay a motivated, qualified employee more. One response to the adverse selection problem by the employee is to take actions on his own that will help distinguish him from others in the applicant pool, which are observable and serve as a signal to the employer. Seeking a college degree has been cited as a kind of signal. Even though much of what the employee learned as part of obtaining the college degree may be of little use in the prospective employment relationship, the fact that the applicant was willing to endure the cost and effort for a college degree, particularly a degree supported with good grades, is evidence that the applicant is more likely to be a dedicated and competent employee. Applicants for employment or hire often have several employment relationships over time. By attaching importance to reputation, employers can both motivate employees to be more diligent in their current positions and establish a mechanism to help distinguish high-quality workers from low-quality workers in future hiring.
their labor in a nonexecutive setting. There are multiple theories for these high executive salaries. One argument is based on economic rent, namely, that talented executives are like star athletes and art performers, being in relatively short supply, so corporations must pay well above their opportunity cost to have their services. Another argument for high executive pay is that they need to be not only compensated for their effort but rewarded for the value they create on behalf of the owners. So part of the higher salary is a share of the profits resulting from their execution of management duties. A third argument for high executive salaries is that firms must often take significant risks to succeed in competitive markets and uncertain conditions. If the firm fails or falls short when its performance is assessed after the fact, the executive may lose his job. In response to this, the executive may avoid bold moves that have a significant risk of failure. In paying an executive highly, the executive is compensated for the additional personal risk he assumes by being willing to take reasonable chances that the corporation must tolerate. Another interesting argument for high executive pay is called tournament theory.[1] This applies to large enterprises with a sizeable team of executives, with a highly paid chief executive officer (CEO), along with several other vice presidents who are in line for consideration to become a future CEO. By paying the CEO generously and well beyond what is economically justifiable on the basis of the CEOs contributions per se, there is a strong incentive for the other executives to put in extra effort so they will become that chief executive, with all the high pay and perquisites, in the future. From the perspective of the shareholders, the gain from those collective extra efforts is worth the high salary to the last winner of the CEO tournament.
The consequence of the preceding assumptions is that all exchanges in a perfectly competitive market will quickly converge to a single price. Since the good is viewed as being of identical quality and utility, regardless of the seller, and the buyers have perfect information about seller prices, if one seller is charging less than another seller, no buyer will purchase from the higher priced seller. As a result, all sellers that elect to remain in the market will quickly settle at charging the same price. In Chapter 2 "Key Measures and Relationships" and Chapter 3 "Demand and Pricing", we examined the demand curves seen by a firm. In the case of the perfect competition model, since sellers are price takers and their presence in the market is of small consequence, the demand curve they see is a flat curve, such that they can produce and sell any quantity between zero and their production limit for the next period, but the price will remain constant (see Figure 6.1 "Flat Demand Curve as Seen by an Individual Seller in a Perfectly Competitive Market"). It must be noted that although each firm in the market perceives a flat demand curve, the demand curve representing the behavior of all buyers in the market need not be a flat line. Since some buyers will value the item more than others and even individual buyers will have decreasing utility for additional units of the item, the total market demand curve will generally take the shape of a downward sloping curve, such asFigure 6.2 "Demand Curve as Seen for All Sellers in a Market". Figure 6.1 Flat Demand Curve as Seen by an Individual Seller in a Perfectly Competitive Market Any amount the firm offers for sale during a production period (up to its maximum possible production level) will sell at the market price. The downward sloping nature of the market demand curve in Figure 6.2 "Demand Curve as Seen for All Sellers in a Market" may seem to contradict the flat demand curve for a single firm depicted in Figure 6.1 "Flat Demand Curve as Seen by an Individual Seller in a Perfectly Competitive Market". This difference can be explained by the fact that any single seller is viewed as being a very small component of the market. Whether a single firm operated at its maximum possible level or dropped out entirely, the impact on the overall market price or total market quantity would be negligible. Although all firms will be forced to charge the same price under perfect competition and firms have perfect information about the production technologies of other firms, firms may not be identical in the short run. Some may have lower costs or higher capacities. Consequently, not all firms will earn the same amount of profit. Figure 6.2 Demand Curve as Seen for All Sellers in a Market Although one seller sees a fixed price for its supply, if all sellers were to increase production, the maximum price that customers would pay to buy all the units offered would drop. As described in the description of the shutdown rule in Chapter 2 "Key Measures and Relationships", some firms only operate at an economic profit because they have considerable sunk costs that are not considered in determining whether it is profitable to operate in the short run. Thus not only are there differences in profits among firms in the short run, but even if the market price were to remain the same, not all the firms would be able to justify remaining in the market when their fixed costs need to be replenished, unless they were able to adapt their production to match the more successful operators.
from the seller who has the lowest price. Since the price has been lowered, all firms will have a lower economic profit than they had collectively before they lowered the price. Some firms may realize they can even drive the price lower, again take sales from their competitors, and increase economic profit. Once again, all firms will be required to follow their lead or drop out of the market because firms that do not drop the price again will lose all their customers. And once again, as all firms match the lowered price, the economic profits are diminished. In theory, due to competition, homogeneous goods, and perfect information, firms will continue to match and undercut other firms on the price, until the price drops to the point where all remaining firms make an economic profit of zero. As we explained earlier, an economic profit of zero is sufficient to sustain operations, but the firm will no longer be earning an accounting profit beyond the opportunity costs of the resources employed in their ventures. Another necessary development in the long run under perfect competition is that all firms will need to be large enough to reach minimum efficient scale. Recall from Chapter 4 "Cost and Production" that minimum efficient scale is the minimum production rate necessary to get the average cost per item as low as possible. Firms operating at minimum efficient scale could charge a price equal to that minimum average cost and still be viable. Smaller firms with higher average costs will not be able to compete because they will have losses if they charge those prices yet will lose customers to the large firms with lower prices if they do not match their prices. So, in the long run, firms that have operations smaller than minimum efficient scale will need to either grow to at least minimum efficient scale or leave the market.
It is often of interest to determine the impact of a changing factor on the market equilibrium. Will the equilibrium quantity increase or decrease? Will the equilibrium price increase or decrease? Will the shift in the equilibrium point be more of a change in price or a change in quantity? The examination of the impact of a change on the equilibrium point is known in economics as comparative statics. In the case of a shifting demand curve, since the supply curve is generally upward sloping, a shift of the demand curve either upward or to the right will result in both a higher equilibrium price and equilibrium quantity. Likewise, a shift in the demand curve either downward or to the left will usually result in a lower equilibrium price and a lower equilibrium quantity. So in response to the introduction of a new substitute good where we would expect a leftward shift in the demand curve, both the equilibrium price and quantity for the existing good can be expected to decrease (see Figure 6.5 "Shift of Market Demand to the Left in Response to a New Substitute and Change in the Market Equilibrium"). Whether a shift in the demand curve results in a greater relative change in the equilibrium price or the equilibrium quantity depends on the shape of the supply curve. If the supply curve is fairly flat, or elastic, the change will be primarily in the equilibrium quantity (see Figure 6.6 "Impact of Elasticity of the Supply Curve on the Impact of a Shift in the Demand Curve"). An elastic supply curve means that a small change in price typically results in a greater response in the provided quantity. If the supply curve is fairly vertical, or inelastic, the change in equilibrium will be mostly seen as a price change (see Figure 6.7 "Impact of Elasticity of the Supply Curve on the Impact of a Shift in the Demand Curve"). Figure 6.5 Shift of Market Demand to the Left in Response to a New Substitute and Change in the Market Equilibrium Figure 6.6 Impact of Elasticity of the Supply Curve on the Impact of a Shift in the Demand Curve The shift is generally in terms of the quantity when the supply curve is elastic. Figure 6.7 Impact of Elasticity of the Supply Curve on the Impact of a Shift in the Demand Curve The shift is generally in terms of the price when the supply curve is inelastic. A shift in the supply curve has a different effect on the equilibrium. Because the demand curve is generally downward sloping, a shift in the supply curve either upward or to the left will result in a higher equilibrium price and a lower equilibrium quantity. However, a shift in the supply either downward or to the right will result in a lower equilibrium price and a higher equilibrium quantity. So for the example of the gasoline market where the supply curve shifts upward, we can expect prices to rise and the quantity sold to decrease (see Figure 6.8 "Shift of Market Supply Upward in Response to an Increase in the Price of Crude Oil and Change in the Market Equilibrium"). The shape of the demand curve dictates whether a shift in the supply curve will result in more change in the equilibrium price or the equilibrium quantity. With a demand curve that is flat, or elastic, a shift in supply curve will change the equilibrium quantity more than the price (see Figure 6.9 "Impact of Elasticity of the Demand Curve on the Impact of a Shift in the Supply Curve"). With a demand curve that is vertical, or inelastic, a shift in the supply curve will change the equilibrium price more than the equilibrium quantity (see Figure 6.10 "Impact of Elasticity of the Demand Curve on the Impact of a Shift in the Supply Curve"). The characterization of a demand curve as being elastic or inelastic corresponds to the measure of price elasticity that was discussed in Chapter 3 "Demand and Pricing". Recall from the discussion of short-run versus long-run demand that in the short run, customers are limited in their options by their consumption patterns and technologies. This is particularly true in the case of gasoline consumption. Consequently, short-run demand curves for gasoline tend to be very inelastic. As a result, if changing crude oil prices results in an upward shift in the supply curve for gasoline, we should expect the result to be a substantial increase in the price of gasoline and only a fairly modest decrease in the amount of gasoline consumed. Figure 6.8 Shift of Market Supply Upward in Response to an Increase in the Price of Crude Oil and Change in the Market Equilibrium Figure 6.9 Impact of Elasticity of the Demand Curve on the Impact of a Shift in the Supply Curve The shift is generally in terms of the quantity when the demand curve is elastic. Figure 6.10 Impact of Elasticity of the Demand Curve on the Impact of a Shift in the Supply Curve The shift is generally in terms of the price when the demand curve is inelastic.
the marginal cost of attracting one more unit from one supplier is equal to the highest price that will attract the purchase of one more unit from a buyer. At the price charged at equilibrium, some buyers are getting a bargain of sorts because they would have been willing to purchase at least some units even if the price had been somewhat higher. The fact that market demand curves are downward sloping rather than perfectly flat reflects willingness of customers to make purchases at higher prices. At least in theory, we could imagine taking all the units that would be purchased at the equilibrium price and using the location of each unit purchase on the demand curve to determine the maximum amount that the buyer would have been willing to pay to purchase that unit. The difference between what the customer would have paid to buy a unit and the lower equilibrium price he actually paid constitutes a kind of surplus that goes to the buyer. If we determined this surplus for each item purchased and accumulated the surplus, we would have a quantity called consumer surplus. Using a graph of a demand curve, we can view consumer surplus as the area under the demand curve down to the horizontal line corresponding to the price being charged, as shown in Figure 6.11 "Graph of Market Demand and Market Supply Curves Showing the Consumer Surplus and Producer Surplus When the Market Is in Perfect Competition Equilibrium". On the supplier side, there is also a potential for a kind of surplus. Since market supply curves are usually upward sloping, there are some sellers who would have been willing to sell the product even if the price had been lower because the marginal cost of the item was below the market price, and in perfect competition, a producer will always sell another item if the price is at least as high as the marginal cost. If, as before, we assessed each item sold in terms of its marginal cost, calculated the difference between the price and the marginal cost, and then accumulated those differences, the sum would be a quantity called the producer surplus. Figure 6.11 Graph of Market Demand and Market Supply Curves Showing the Consumer Surplus and Producer Surplus When the Market Is in Perfect Competition Equilibrium The producer surplus reflects the combined economic profit of all sellers in the short run. For a graph of the supply curve, the producer surplus corresponds to the area above the supply curve up to the horizontal line at the market price, again as shown inFigure 6.11 "Graph of Market Demand and Market Supply Curves Showing the Consumer Surplus and Producer Surplus When the Market Is in Perfect Competition Equilibrium". Consumer surplus will increase as the price gets lower (assuming sellers are willing to supply at the level on the demand curve) and producer surplus will increase as the prices gets higher (assuming buyers are willing to purchase the added amount as you move up the supply curve). If we asked the question, at what price would the sum of consumer surplus plus producer surplus would be greatest, the answer is at the equilibrium price, where the demand curve and supply curve cross. To support this claim, suppose sellers decided to increase the price above the equilibrium price. Since consumers would purchase fewer items, the quantity they could sell is dictated by the demand curve. The new producer surplus, as seen in Figure 6.12 "Change in Consumer Surplus and Producer Surplus When Sellers Increase Price Above the Equilibrium Price", might be higher than the producer surplus at the equilibrium price, but the consumer surplus would be decidedly lower. So any increase in producer surplus comes from what had been consumer surplus. However, there is a triangular area in Figure 6.12 "Change in Consumer Surplus and Producer Surplus When Sellers Increase Price Above the Equilibrium Price", between the supply and demand curve and to the right of the new quantity level, which represents former surplus that no longer goes to either consumers or producers. Economists call this lost surplus a deadweight loss. If the price were lower than the equilibrium price, we encounter a situation where producer surplus decreases and at best only some of that decrease transfers to consumers. The rest of the lost producer surplus is again a deadweight loss, as seen inFigure 6.13 "Change in Consumer Surplus and Producer Surplus When Buyers Force the Price Below the Equilibrium Price". The important point is that changing the price is worse than just a shift of surplus from consumers to producers, or vice versa. If the entire sum of consumer surplus and producer surplus could grow at a different price, it could be argued that the government could use a tax to take some of the excess received by one group and redistribute it to the other party so everyone was as well off or better off. Unfortunately, due to the deadweight loss, the gain to one of two parties will not offset the loss to the other party. So the equilibrium point is not only a price and quantity where we have agreement between the demand curve and supply curve, but also the point at which the greatest collective surplus is realized. Figure 6.12 Change in Consumer Surplus and Producer Surplus When Sellers Increase Price Above the Equilibrium Price
Note the creation of a deadweight loss that was formerly part of either consumer surplus or producer surplus when the market operated at the perfect competition equilibrium. Figure 6.13 Change in Consumer Surplus and Producer Surplus When Buyers Force the Price Below the Equilibrium Price Note the creation of a deadweight loss that was formerly part of either consumer surplus or producer surplus when the market operated at the perfect competition equilibrium.
would benefit by allowing free entry and exit in the passenger air travel market. Initially, the change resulted in several new airlines and increases in the ranges of operations for existing airlines, as well as more flight options and lower airfares for consumers. After a time, however, some of the larger airlines were able to thwart free entry by dominating airport gates and controlling proprietary reservation systems, causing a departure from the contestable market model.
buyer side, consumers usually have a limited perspective on the prices and products of all sellers and may not always pay the lowest price available for a good or service (although the Internet may be changing this to some degree). Finally, for the perfect competition model to play out according to theory, there needs to be a reasonable level of stability so that there is sufficient time for the long-run consequences of perfect competition to occur. However, in our fast-changing world, the choices of goods and services available to consumers, the technologies for producing those products and services, and the costs involved in production are increasingly subject to rapid change. Before market forces can begin to gel to create price competition and firms can modify their operations to copy the most successful sellers, changes in circumstances may stir enough such that the market formation process starts anew.
7.2 Monopoly
Often, the main deterrent to a highly competitive market is market power possessed by sellers. In this section, we will consider the strongest form of seller market power, called a monopoly. In a monopoly there is only one seller, called a monopolist. Recall that in perfect competition, each firm sees the demand curve it faces as a flat line, so it presumes it can sell as much as it wants, up to its production limit, at the prevailing market price. Even though the overall market demand curve decreases with increased sales volume, the single firm in perfect competition has a different perception because it is a small participant in the market and takes prices as given. In the case of flat demand curves, price and marginal revenue are the same, and since a profit-maximizing producer decides whether to increase or decrease production volume by comparing its marginal cost to marginal revenue, in this case the producer in perfect competition will sell more (if it has the capability) up the point where marginal cost equals price. In a monopoly, the demand curve seen by the single selling firm is the entire market demand curve. If the market demand curve is downward sloping, the monopolist knows that marginal revenue will not equal price. As we discussed in Chapter 2 "Key Measures and Relationships", when the demand curve is downward sloping, the marginal revenue corresponding to any quantity and price on the demand curve is less than the price (see Figure 7.1 "Graph Showing the Optimal Quantity and Price for a Monopolist Relative to the Free Market Equilibrium Price and Quantity"). Because the condition for optimal seller profit is where marginal revenue equals marginal cost, the monopolist will elect to operate at a quantity where those two quantities are in balance, which will be at volume marked QM in Figure 7.1 "Graph Showing the Optimal Quantity and Price for a Monopolist Relative to the Free Market Equilibrium Price and Quantity". Since the monopolist has complete control on sales, it will only sell at the quantity where marginal revenue equals marginal cost but will sell at the higher price associated with that quantity on the demand curve, PM, rather than the marginal cost at a quantity of QM. Figure 7.1 Graph Showing the Optimal Quantity and Price for a Monopolist Relative to the Free Market Equilibrium Price and Quantity If the marginal cost curve for the monopolist were instead the combined marginal cost curves of small firms in perfect competition, the marginal cost curve would correspond to the market supply curve. The perfect competition market equilibrium would occur at a volume QC, with a price PC. The monopolist could afford to function at this same volume and price and may even earn some economic profit. However, at this volume, marginal cost is greater than marginal revenue, indicating greater profit by operating at a lower volume at a higher price. The highest profit will result from selling QM units at a price of PM. Unfortunately, consumers do worse at the monopolists optimal operation as they pay a higher price and purchase fewer units. And as we noted in the previous chapter, the loss in consumer surplus will exceed the profit gain to the monopolist. This is the main reason monopolies are discouraged, if not outlawed, by governments.
term cartel from the OPEC oil exporting group that is frequently described as a cartel. However, though OPEC has considerable market power and influence on prices, there are oil exporters that are not in OPEC, and internally OPEC only sets member targets rather than fully coordinating their operations.) In theory, a cartel would operate at the same production volume and price as it would if its productive resources were all run by a monopolist. In a cartel, every member firm would sell at the same price and each firm would set its individual production volume such that every firm operates at the same marginal cost. For the same reason that monopolies are considered harmful, cartels are usually not tolerated by governments for the regions in which those markets operate. Even the collusion that is a necessary component of a true cartel is illegal. However, although cartels could theoretically function with the same power as a monopolist, if the cartel truly contains multiple members making independent decisions, there is a potential instability that can undo the cartel arrangement. Because monopolists gain added profit by reducing production volume and selling at a price above marginal cost, individual members may see an opportunity to defect, particularly if they can do so without being easily detected. Since the cartel price will be well above their marginal cost, they could profit individually by increasing their own production. Of course, if the defection is discovered and the other members retaliate by increasing their volumes as well, the result could be a substantially lower market price and lower economic profits for all cartel members. Another problem for cartels is how to divide the profits. Suppose a cartel had two member firms, A and B. Firm A has more efficient facilities than Firm B, so the cartel solution will be to allow Firm A to provide the bulk of the production volume. However, if Firm A claims its share of the profits should be proportional to its share of the production volume, Firm B may object to voluntarily withholding its production only to allow to Firm A to grab most of the sales and profit, and the arrangement could end. Also, since optimal cartel operation means that all firms set production so all have the same marginal cost, the firms need to share internal information for the cartel to determine the total volume where marginal revenue equals marginal cost and how that volume gets divided between firms. Again, some firms may have the incentive to keep the details of their operations private from other firms in the cartel.
mathematical models that attempt to address oligopoly operation. Next we will consider some of the insights of these analyses without the mathematics. One approach that economists have used to model the behavior of oligopoly firms, known as the Bertrand model or price competition, is to assume all firms can anticipate the prices that will be charged by their competitors. If firms can reasonably anticipate the prices that other firms will charge and have a reasonable understanding of market demand, each firm can determine how customers would react to its own price and decide what production level and price leads to highest profit. The soft drink market is an example of a market that could operate in this manner. Another approach for modeling oligopoly behavior, known as the Cournot model or quantity competition, is to assume all firms can determine the upcoming production levels or operating capacities of their competitors. For example, in the airline industry, schedules and gate arrangements are made months in advance. In essence, the airlines have committed to a schedule, their flying capacities are somewhat fixed, and what remains is to make the necessary adjustments to price to use the committed capacity effectively. In comparing models where firms anticipate price to those where firms anticipate production volume or capacity commitment, firms that anticipate quantity levels tend to operate at lower production levels and charge higher prices. This occurs because in a quantity competition model, firms subtract the planned operation of their rivals from the market demand curve and assume the residual is the demand curve they will face. This leads to the presumption that the price elasticity of their own demand is the same as the price elasticity of overall market demand, whereas in price competition models the elasticity of the firms own demand is seen as greater than the price elasticity of overall market demand (as was the case in the perfect competition model). The number of selling firms also has an effect on the likely outcome of oligopoly competition. As the number of firms increases, the market equilibrium moves toward the equilibrium that would be expected in a perfectly competitive market of firms with the same aggregate production resources. Another issue that can affect the prices and quantity volumes in an oligopoly market is the existence of a leader firm. A leader firm will make a decision on either its price or its volume/capacity commitment and then the remaining follower firms determine how they will react. An example of a leader firm in an industry might be Apple in the portable media player market. Apple decides on how it will price its iPod products and other manufacturers then decide how to price their products. Although the leader firm commits first in these models, in order to determine its own best course of action, it needs to anticipate how the follower firms will react to its decision.
Although concentration ratios are easy to calculate and easily understood, there are two shortcomings. First, the number of firms in the ratio is arbitrary. There is no reason that a fourfirm concentration ratio indicates concentration potential any better than a three-firm or fivefirm concentration ratio. Second, the ratio does not indicate whether there are one or two very large firms that clearly dominate all other firms in market share or the market shares for the firms included in the concentration ratio are about the same. An alternative concentration measure that avoids these problems is the HHI. This index is computed by taking the market shares of all firms in the market, squaring the individual market shares, and finally summing them. The squaring has the effect of amplifying the larger market shares. The highest possible value of the HHI is 10,000, which occurs in the case of a monopoly (10,000 = 1002). If, on the other hand, you had a market that had 100 firms that each had a market share of 1%, the HHI would be 100 (1 = 12, summed 100 times). For the previous 10-firm example, the HHI would be 1302. Although there is no inherent reason for squaring market shares, the HHI includes all firms in the computation (avoiding the issue of how many firms to include) and reflects the variation in magnitude of market shares. As far as interpreting these concentration measures, the following statements provide some guidance on the potential for market power by sellers: If CR4 is less than 40 or the HHI is less than 1000, the market has fairly low concentration and should be reasonably competitive. If CR4 is between 40 and 60 or the HHI is between 1000 and 2000, there is a loose oligopoly that probably will not result in significant exercise of market power by sellers. If CR4 is above 60 or the HHI is above 2000, then there is a tight oligopoly that has significant potential for exercise of seller power. If CR1 is above 90 or the HHI is above 8000, one firm will be a clear leader and may function effectively as a monopoly. Again, a high concentration measure indicates a potential for exploitation of seller power but not proof it will actually happen. Another important caution about these measures is that the scope of the market needs to be considered. In the case of banking services, even with the mergers that have resulted in higher seller concentration, if you look at measures of bank concentration at the national level, there seems be a loose oligopoly. However, if you limit the scope to banking in a single city or region, it is very likely that only few banks serve those areas. There can be modest concentrations when examining national markets but high concentration at the local level. [1] See U.S. Census Bureau (2010).
decide it would be better to let prices go higher so that profits will increase, even if that allows the new entrant to be able to remain in the market. 3. Yield management. Another method for taking advantage of the power to set prices is yield management, where the firm abandons the practice of setting a fixed price and instead changes prices frequently. One goal is to try to extract higher prices from customers who are willing to pay more for a product or service. Normally, with a fixed announced price, customers who would have been willing to pay a significantly higher price get the consumer surplus. Even if the firm employs third-degree price discrimination and charges different prices to different market segments, some customers realize a surplus from a price well below the maximum they would pay. Using sophisticated software to continuously readjust prices, it is possible to capture higher prices from some of these customers. Yield management can also make it more difficult for other firms to compete on the basis of price since it does not have a known, fixed price to work against. A good example of yield management is the airline industry. Airlines have long employed price discrimination in forms of different classes of customers, different rates for flyers traveling over a weekend, and frequent flyer programs. However, in recent years, the price to buy a ticket can change daily, depending on the amount of time until the flight occurs and the degree to which the flight has already filled seats. 4. Durable goods. When firms in monopolies and oligopolies sell long-lived durable goods like cars and televisions, they have the option to sell to customers at different times and can attempt to do something similar to first-degree price discrimination by setting the price very high at first. When the subset of customers who are willing to pay the most have made their purchase, the firms can drop the price somewhat and attract another tier of customers who are willing to pay slightly less than the first group. Progressively, the price will be dropped over time to attract most customers at a price close to the maximum they would be willing to pay. However, economists have pointed out that customers may sense this strategy, and if patient, the customer can wait and pay a much lower price than the perceived value of the item. Even if the firm has little competition from other firms, a firm may find itself in the interesting situation of competing with itself in other production periods. In theoretical analyses of monopolies that sold durable goods, it has been demonstrated that when durable goods last a long time and customers are patient, even a monopolist can be driven to price items at marginal cost. [2] One response to the durable goods dilemma is to sell goods with shorter product lives so that customers will need to return sooner to make a purchase. U.S. car manufacturers endeavored to do this in the middle of the 20th century but discovered that this opened the door for new entrants who sold cars that were designed to last longer. Another response is to rent the use of the durable good rather than sell the good outright. This turns the good into a service that is sold for a specified period of time rather than a long-lived asset that is sold once to the customer (for at least a long time) and allows more standard oligopoly pricing that is applied for consumable goods and services. This arrangement is common with office equipment like copiers.
recognition than existing firms spend to maintain brand recognition. Hence new entrants are discouraged by what is perceived as a high startup fee, which is a type of barrier to entry. 2. Excess capacity. Ordinarily a firm will plan for a capacity that is sufficient to support the production volume. Because capacity is often planned in advance and actual production volume may vary from period to period, the firm may have some excess capacity in some periods. And since there is inherent uncertainty in future demand, firms may even invest in capacity that is never fully utilized. However, firms in oligopolies may invest, or partially invest, in capacity well beyond what is needed to cover fluctuations in volume and accommodation of uncertainty as a means of competing. If the sellers in an oligopoly have been successful in collectively holding back on quantity to drive up the price and profits, since the price is well above average cost, there is an opportunity for one firm to offer the product at a lower price, attract a sizeable fraction of the new customers attracted by the lower price, and make a sizeable individual gain in profit. This gambit may come from a new entrant or even an existing seller. This tactic may work, at least for a time, if the firm introducing the lower price does it by surprise and the other firms are not prepared to ramp up production rapidly to match the initiators move. One way to protect against an attack of this nature is to have a significant amount of excess capacity, or at least some additional capacity that could be upgraded and brought online quickly. The firm doing this may even want to clearly reveal this to other sellers or potential sellers as a signal that if another firm were to try an attack of this nature, they are prepared to respond quickly and make sure they take advantage of the increased sales volume. 3. Reputation and warranties. As a result of fluctuations in cost or buyer demand, being a seller in a market may be more attractive in some periods than others. During periods that are lucrative for being a seller, some firms may be enticed to enter on a short-term basis, with minimal longterm commitments, enjoy a portion of the spoils of the favorable market, and then withdraw when demand declines or costs increase. Firms that intend to remain in the market on an ongoing basis would prefer that these hit-andrun entrants not take away a share of the profits when the market is attractive. One measure to discourage this is to make an ongoing presence desired by the customer so as to distinguish the product of the ongoing firms from the product of the short-term sellers. As part of advertising, these firms may emphasize the importance of a firms reputation in providing a quality product that the firm will stand behind. Another measure is to make warranties a part of the product, a feature that is only of value to the buyer if the seller is likely to be available when a warranty claim is made. Like high-cost advertising, even the scope of the warranty may become a means of competition, as is seen in the automobile industry where warranties may vary in time duration, number of driven miles, and systems covered. 4. Product bundling. In Chapter 3 "Demand and Pricing", we discussed the notion of complementary goods and services. This is a relationship in which purchasers of one good or service become more likely to purchase another good or service. Firms may take advantage of complementary relationships by selling products together in a bundle, where consumers have the option to purchase multiple products as a single item at lower total cost than if the items were purchased separately. This can be particularly effective if there are natural production economies of scope in these complementary goods. If competitors are unable to readily match the bundled product, the firms gain can be substantial. A good example of successful product bundling is Microsoft Office. Microsoft had developed the word processing software Word, the spreadsheet software Excel, the presentation software PowerPoint, and the database software Access. Individually, each of these products was clearly outsold by other products in those specialized markets. For example, the favored spreadsheet software in the late 1980s was Lotus 1-2-3. When Microsoft decided to bundle the packages and sell them for a modest amount more than the price of a single software package, customers perceived a gain in value, even if they did not actively use some of the packages. Since all the components were software and distributed on floppy disks (and later on CDs and via web downloads), there was a strong economy of scope. However, when Microsoft introduced the bundle, the firms selling the leader products in the individual markets were not able to match the product bundling, even though some attempted to do so after Microsoft has usurped the market. Consequently, not only was the product bundle a success, but the individual components of Microsoft Office each became the dominant products. 5. Network effects and standards. In some markets, the value of a product to a buyer may be affected by the number of other buyers of the product. For example, a cell phone becomes more valuable if most of the people you would like to phone quickly also carry a cell phone. Products that increase in value when the adoption rate of the product increases, even if some units are sold by competitors, are said to have network effects.
One impact of network effects is that industry standards become important. Often network effects occur because the products purchased need to use compatible technologies with other products. In some markets, this may result in some level of cooperation between firms, such as when appliance manufacturers agree to sell units with similar dimensions or connections. However, sometimes multiple standards emerge and firms may select to support one standard as a means of competing against a firm that uses another standard. Sellers may group into alliances to help improve their success via network effects. In the once-vibrant market for VCR tapes and tape players, the initial standard for producing tapes was called Betamax. This Betamax standard was developed by Sony and used in the VCR players that Sony produced. Soon after Betamax was introduced, the electronics manufacturer JVC introduced the VHS standard. Consumers first had to purchase the VCR player, but the value of the product was affected by the availability and variety of tapes they could acquire afterward, which was determined by whether their player used the Betamax standard or the VHS standard. Eventually the VHS standard prevailed, favoring JVC and the other firms that allied with JVC. Up until the videotape was eclipsed by the DVD, the VCR industry moved to using the VHS standard almost exclusively. This illustrates a frequent development in a market with strong network effects: a winner-take-all contest. Another example of a winner-take-all situation can be seen with operating systems in personal computers. Although there were multiple operating systems available for PCs in the 1980s, eventually Microsofts MS-DOS and later Windows operating systems achieved a near monopoly in personal computer operating systems. Again, the driver is network effects. Companies that produced software saw different markets depending on the operating system used by the buyer. As MS-DOS/Windows increased its market share, companies were almost certain to sell a version of their product for this operating system, usually as their first version and perhaps as their only version. This, in turn, solidified Microsofts near monopoly. Although other operating systems still exist and the free operating system Linux and the Apple Macintosh OS have succeeded in some niches, Microsoft Windows remains the dominant operating system.
service provided by demanding more tiring or dangerous working conditions. When the industrial revolution created strong economies of scale that supported very large firms with strong employer purchasing power, laborers faced a difficult situation of low pay and poor working conditions. One of the reasons for the rise of the labor unions in the United States was as a way of creating power for the laborers by requiring a single transaction between the employer and all laborers represented by the union. Figure 7.2 Graph Showing the Optimal Quantity and Price for a Monopsonist Relative to the Free Market Equilibrium Price and Quantity
improvement for some and at a loss to no one. In the case of monopoly, which we examined in "Firm Competition and Market Structure", the price and quantity selected by the monopolist is not efficient because it would be possible, at least in principle, to require the monopolist to set the price at the perfect competition equilibrium, reclaim the deadweight loss in consumer surplus and producer surplus, and redistribute enough of the surplus so the monopolist is as well off as it was at the monopoly price and the consumers are better off. Equity corresponds to the issue of whether the distribution of goods and services to individuals and the profits to firms are fair. Unfortunately, there is no simple single principle, like Pareto efficiency, that has been adopted as the primary standard for equity. Although there is general support for the idea that the distribution of goods and services ought to favor those with greater talents or those who work harder, there are also those who view access to basic goods and services as reasonable expectations of all citizens. Despite the impossibility of developing a general consensus on what constitutes equity, when enough people become concerned that the distribution of goods and services is too inequitable, there are likely to be pressures on those in political power or political unrest. Most microeconomists tend to view active regulation of individual markets as worthy of consideration when there are inefficiencies in the functioning of those markets. Since managerial economics (and this text) has a microeconomics focus, we will address the merit of market regulation from this perspective as well. Problems of inequity are usually regarded as a problem of macroeconomics, best handled by wealth transfers, such as income taxes and welfare payments rather than intervention in the markets for goods and services. Still, there are instances where regulatory actions directed at specific markets reflect equity concerns, such as requiring companies to offer basic services at lifeline rates for low-income customers.
that can be used as a basis for opposing any buyouts or mergers that will increase market concentration. Where market concentration has already advanced to high levels, firms can be instructed to break up into separate companies. About a century ago, monopolies had developed in important U.S. industries like petroleum, railroads, and electric power. Eventually, the U.S. federal government mandated these monopolies split apart. As mentioned in earlier chapters, the fact that there are a few large sellers does not automatically constitute abusive use of market power if there is free entry and active competition between sellers. However, if those large sellers collude to hold back production volumes and raise prices, there is a loss in market surplus. The United States has laws that outlaw such collusion. While firms may be able to collude with indirect signals that are difficult for government antitrust units to identify at the time, courts will consider testimony that demonstrates that collusion has taken place. In "Firm Competition and Market Structure", we discussed the market power tactics of using low prices to drive out existing competitors and keep out new entrants. When the purpose of the price drop is merely to chase out competition, the practice is labeled predatory pricing and is considered illegal. Of course, the firms engaging in price decreases often take the position that they are in a competitive market and are simply competing on the basis of reduced profit margins, just as firms are expected to compete according to the theory of the perfect competition model. Courts are left to determine whether such actions are simply aggressive competition or are intended to create a more concentrated market that allows for greater profits in the long run. As an alternative to taking actions to limit large firms from exploiting their size, another form of regulation is to encourage more competition by helping small or new competitors. Either subsidies or tax breaks may be offered to help these firms offset the disadvantages of being small in the market and to eventually emerge as an independent player in the market. In cases where a concentrated seller market exists and the product or service is considered critical to the buyers and the overall economy, the government may decide to intervene strongly by setting a limit on prices or mandating that the product be provided at a minimum quantity and quality. In situations where there is buyer power, the goal of regulation may be to push prices higher. For example, in agriculture crop markets where the seller farmers often have little market power, but there is concentration on the buyer side, the government will try to keep prices higher by mandating minimum prices or direct assistance to farmers in the form of price support programs. Another response to market power on one side of the market is to support market power on the other side of the market. Using the crop market example again where there is buyer power, the government has sanctioned the creation of grower cooperatives that control the quantity of the amount sold to processors and thus keep the price higher.
costs plus an amount to cover the opportunity costs of assets or capital contributed by the corporations owners, the challenge is to be able to justify the costs rather than seek to trim its costs. Some regulatory agencies try to motivate regulated monopolies to be innovative or cut costs by allowing them to keep some of the surplus created in exchange for lower rates in the future. However, regulation is a game where the regulatory agency and the public utility corporation are both competing and cooperating. And the transaction costs of outside oversight of the regulatory monopoly are substantial. So, as noted earlier, there is no free lunch.
8.6 Externalities
The second generic type of market failure is when parties other than the buyer and seller are significantly affected by the exchange between the buyer and seller. However, these other parties do not participate in the negotiation of the sale. Consequently, the quantities sold and prices charged do not reflect the impacts on these parties. Economists call the effects of market activity on the third parties externalitiesbecause they fall outside the considerations of buyer and seller. Although the concern with significant externalities is usually due to harm to the third party, externalities can be beneficial to third parties as well. Harmful externalities are callednegative externalities; beneficial externalities are called positive externalities. Some examples of negative externalities are pollution of air or water that is experienced by persons other than those directly related to the seller or buyer, injury or death to another person resulting from the market exchange, inconvenience and annoyances caused by loud noise or congestion, and spoiling of natural habitats. Some examples of positive externalities are spillover effects of research and development used for one product to other products or other firms, training of a worker by one firm and thereby creating a more valuable worker for a future employer, stimulation of additional economic activity outside the market, and outside benefactors of problem-solving services like pest control. Negative externalities clearly create an inequity because the third parties are harmed without any compensation. However, significant negative externalities also create inefficiency. Recall that inefficiency means there is a way to make someone better off and no one worse off. Take the case of a negative externality like air pollution caused when an automobile owner purchases gasoline to use in his car. Hypothetically, if a representative for outside parties were present at the negotiation for the sale, she might be willing to pay an amount to the buyer and an amount to the seller in exchange for foregoing the sale by compensating the buyer with the consumer surplus they would have received and the producer with the economic profit they would have received, with the sum of those payments being worth the avoidance of the externality impact of the air pollution. Even in the case of a positive externality, there is inefficiency. However, in this case, the third parties would actually benefit from more market exchanges than the sellers and buyers would be willing to transact. In principle, if third parties could participate in the market, they would be willing to pay the buyer or seller up to the value of the positive externality if it would induce more market activity. Regulation of externalities usually takes two forms: legal and economic. Legal measures are sanctions that forbid market activity, restrict the volume of activity, or restrict those who are allowed to participate as buyers and sellers. As examples of these, if an appliance is prone to start fires that might burn an entire apartment complex and injure others besides the buyer, the sale of the appliance might be banned outright. If sales of water drawn from a river would threaten a wildlife habit, sales may be limited to a maximum amount. A firearms manufacturer might be allowed to sell firearms but would be restricted to sell only to people of at least a certain age who do not have a criminal record. Because legal measures require monitoring and enforcement by the government, there are transaction costs. When a legal measure is excessive, it may actually create a reverse form of inefficiency from denying surplus value to buyers and sellers that exceeds the benefit to other parties.
correct tax. In the case of positive externalities, the optimum tax is negative. In other words, the government actually pays the seller an amount per unit in exchange for a reduction of an equal amount in the price. Theoretically, the optimum tax would be the negative of the marginal value of a unit of consumption to third parties. For example, if the positive externality from hiring an unemployed person and giving that person employment skills would be worth $2.00 per hour, the employer could be subsidized $2.00 per hour to make it more attractive for them to hire that kind of person. Although the notion of an externality tax sounds straightforward, actual implementation is difficult. Even when there is general agreement that a significant externality exists, placing a dollar value on that externality can be extremely difficult and controversial. The optimal tax is the marginal impact on third parties; however, there is no guarantee that the total tax collected in this fashion will be the total amount needed to compensate for the total externality impact. The total collected may be either too little or too much. Also, recall the impact of a tax from the earlier discussion of comparative statics in competitive markets in "Market Equilibrium and the Perfect Competition Model". A tax has the impact of either raising the supply curve upward (if the seller pays the tax) or moving the demand curve downward (if the buyer pays the tax). "Change in Market Equilibrium in Response to Imposing an Externality Tax" for a graphic illustration of a tax charged to the buyer. To the extent that the supply and demand curves are price elastic, the tax will lower the amount consumed, thereby diminishing the externality somewhat and possibly changing the marginal externality cost. Consequently, actual externality taxes require considerable public transaction costs and may not be at the correct level for the best improvement of market efficiency. Figure 8.1 Change in Market Equilibrium in Response to Imposing an Externality Tax Note the tax may cause a decrease in the equilibrium quantity, which may change the optimal externality tax.
8.9 High Cost to Initial Entrant and the Risk of Free Rider Producers
Next, we will consider the third generic type of market failure, or the inability for a market to form or sustain operation due to free riders, by looking at two causes of this kind of failure in this section and the next section. Although the sources are different, both involve a situation where some party benefits from the market exchange without incurring the same cost as other sellers or buyers. New products and services are expensive for the first firm to bring them to market. There may
be initial failures in the development of a commercial product that add to the cost. The firm will start very high on the learning curve because there is no other firm to copy or hire away its talent. The nature of buyer demand for the product is uncertain, and the seller is likely to overcharge, undercharge, or alternatively set initial production targets that are too high or too low. If the firm succeeds, it may initially have a monopoly, but unless there are barriers of entry, new entrant firms will be attracted by the potential profits. These firms will be able to enter the market with less uncertainty about how to make the product commercially viable and the nature of demand for the product. And these firms may be able to determine how the initial entrant solved the problems of designing the product or service and copy the process at far less initial cost than was borne by the initial entrant. If the product sold by the initial firm and firms that enter the market later look equivalent to the buyer, the buyer will not pay one of these firms more than another just based on its higher cost. If the market becomes competitive for sellers, the price is likely to be driven by the marginal cost. New entrant firms may do well, but the initial entrant firm is not likely to get a sufficient return on the productive assets it had invested from startup. In effect, the other firms would be free riders that benefit from the startup costs of the initial entrant without having to contribute to that cost. The market failure occurs here because, prior to even commencing with a startup, the would-be initial entrant may look ahead, see the potential for free riders and the inability to generate sufficient profits to justify the startup costs, and decide to scrap the idea. This market failure is a market inefficiency because it is hypothetically possible for the initial entrant, subsequent entrants, and buyers to sit at a negotiation and reach an arrangement where startup costs are shared by the firms or buyer prices are set higher to cover the startup costs, so that all firms and buyers decide they would be better off with that negotiated arrangement than if the market never materialized. Unfortunately, such negotiations are unlikely to emerge from the unregulated activities of individual sellers and buyers. One of the main regulatory measures to address this problem is to guarantee the initial entrant a high enough price and sufficient volume of sales to justify the up-front investment. Patents are a means by which a product or service that incorporates a new idea or process gives the developer a monopoly, at least for production that uses that process or idea, for a certain period of time. Patents are an important element in the pharmaceutical industry in motivating the development of new drugs because there is a long period of development and testing and a high rate of failure. Companies selling patent-protected drugs will sell those products at monopoly prices. However, the process for manufacturing the drug is usually readily reproducible by other companies, even small generic manufacturers, so the price of the drug will drop precipitously when patent protection expires. In fact, patent-holding firms will usually drop the price shortly prior to patent expiration in an attempt to extract sales from the lower portion of the demand curve before other firms can enter. In cases where there is not a patentable process, but nonetheless a high risk of market failure due to frightening away the initial entrant, government authorities may decide to give exclusive operating rights for at least a period of time. This tool was used to encourage the expansion of cable television to the initial entrant in a region to justify the high up-front expenses. Other government interventions can be the provision of subsidies to the initial entrant to get them to market a new product. The government may decide to fund the up-front research and development and then make the acquired knowledge available to any firm that enters the market so there is not such a difference between being the initial entrant or a subsequent entrant. Another option is for the government itself to serve in the role of the initial entrant and then, when the commercial viability is demonstrated, privatize the product or service.
have affected his neighbors. The benefit obtained by the neighbors does not detract from the benefit gained by the buyer. When benefits of a purchased good or service can benefit others without detracting from the party making the purchase, economists call the product a public good. The difficulty with public goods is that the cost to create a public good by a seller may be substantially more than an individual buyer is willing to pay but less than the collective value to all who would benefit from the purchase. For example, take the cost of tracking down criminals. An individual citizen may benefit from the effort to locate and arrest a criminal, but the individual is not able or willing to hire a police force of the scale needed to conduct such operations. Even though the result of hiring a police force may be worth more to all citizens who benefit than what a company would charge to do it, since there are no individual buyers, the market will not be able to function and there is market failure. As with the market failure for initial entrants with high startup cost, there is a potential agreement where all benefactors would be willing to pay an amount corresponding to their value that, if collected, would cover the cost of creating the good or service. The problem is that individuals would prefer to let someone else pay for it and be a free rider. So the inability of the market to function is a case of inefficiency. In perfect competition, the optimal price to be charged is the marginal cost of serving another customer. However, in the case of public goods, the marginal cost of serving an additional benefactor can be essentially zero. This creates an interesting dilemma whereby the theoretical optimal pricing for the good is to charge a price of zero. Of course, that adds to the market failure problem because the cost of production of the good or service is not zero, so it is not feasible to operate a market of private sellers and buyers in this manner. Usually the only way to deal with a public good of sufficient value is for the government to provide the good or service or pay a private organization to run the operation without charging users, or at least not fully charging users. This is how key services like the military, police protection, fire stations, and public roadways are handled. There may be some ability to charge users a modest fee for some services, but the revenue would not be sufficient to support a market served by private firms. For example, governments build dams as a means of flood control, irrigation, and water recreation. The agency that manages the dam may charge entry fees for boating on the lake or use of water released from the dam. However, the agency still needs to remain a public agency and likely needs additional finances from other public revenues like income or sales taxes to support its continued operations. An interesting public good problem has emerged with the ability to make high-quality digital copies of books and music at very low marginal cost. When someone purchases a music CD (or downloads a file of commercial music) and then allows a copy to be made for someone else, the creation of the copy does not diminish the ability to enjoy the music by the person who made the initial purchase. Artists and producers claim that the recipients of the copies are enjoying the media products as free riders and denying the creators of the products full payment from all who enjoy their products, although there is some debate whether copying is a bona fide market failure concern. Nonetheless, publishers have pursued measures to discourage unauthorized copies, whether via legal prohibition or technology built into the media, or media players, to thwart the ability to make a clean copy.
own advantage and to the disadvantage of the unknowing party. This type of situation is called a moral hazard. For example, if an entrepreneur is raising capital from outside investors, he may present a biased view of the prospects of the firm that only includes the good side of the venture to attract the capital, but the outside investors eventually lose their money due to potentially knowable problems that would have discouraged their investment if those problems had been known. In some cases, the missing information is not technically hidden from the party, but the effective communication of the key information does not occur. For example, a consumer might decide to acquire a credit card from a financial institution and fail to note late payment provisions in the fine print that later become a negative surprise. Whether such communication constitutes proper disclosure or moral hazard is debatable, but the consequences of the bad decision occur nonetheless. Exchanges with moral hazard create equity and efficiency concerns. If one party is taking advantage of another partys ignorance, there is an arguable equity issue. Ho wever, the inadequate disclosure results in a market failure when the negative consequences to the ignorant party more than offset the gains to the parties that disguise key information. This is an inefficient market because the losing parties could compensate the other party for its gains and still suffer less than they did from the incidence of moral hazard. Further, the impact of poor information may spread beyond the party that makes a poor decision out of ignorance. As we have seen with the financial transactions in mortgage financing in the first decade of this century, the consequences of moral hazard can be deep and widespread, resulting in a negative externality as well. Market failures from imperfect information can occur even when there is no intended moral hazard. In "Economics of Organization", we discussed the concept of adverse selection, where inherent risk from uncertainty about the other party in an exchange causes a buyer or seller to assume a pessimistic outcome as a way of playing it safe and minimizing the consequences of risk. However, a consequence of playing it safe is that parties may decide to avoid agreements that actually could work. For example, a company might consider offering health insurance to individuals. An analysis might indicate that such insurance is feasible based on average incidences of medical claims and willingness of individuals to pay premiums. However, due to the risk that the insurance policies will be most attractive to those who expect to submit high claims, the insurance company may decide to set its premiums a little higher than average to protect itself. The higher premiums may scare away some potential clients who do not expect to receive enough benefits to justify the premium. As a result, the customer base for the policy will tend even more toward those individuals who will make high claims, and the company is likely to respond by charging even higher premiums. Eventually, as the customer base grows smaller and more risky, the insurance company may withdraw the health insurance product entirely. Much of the regulation to offset problems caused by imperfect information is legal in nature. In cases where there is asymmetric information that is known to one party but not to another party in a transaction, laws can place responsibility on the first party to make sure the other party receives the information in an understandable format. For example, truth-in-lending laws require that those making loans clearly disclose key provisions of the loan, to the degree of requiring the borrower to put initials beside written statements. The Sarbanes-Oxley law, created following the Enron crisis, places requirements on the conduct of corporations and their auditing firms to try to limit the potential for moral hazard. When one party in an exchange defrauds another party by providing a good or service that is not what was promised, the first party can be fined or sued for its failure to protect against the outcomes to the other party. For example, if a firm sells a defective product that causes harm to the buyer, the firm that either manufactured or sold the item to the buyer could be held liable. A defective product may be produced and sold because the safety risk is either difficult for the buyer to understand or not anticipated because the buyer is unaware of the potential. Governments may impose safety standards and periodic inspections on producers even though those measures would not have been demanded by the buyer. In extreme cases, the government may direct a seller to stop selling a good or service. Other regulatory options involve equipping the ignorant party with better information. Government agencies can offer guidance in print or on Internet websites. Public schools may be required to make sure citizens have basic financial skills and understand the risks created by consumption of goods and services to make prudent decisions. Where adverse selection discourages the operations of markets, regulation may be created to limit the liability to the parties involved. Individuals and businesses may be required to purchase or sell a product like insurance to increase and diversify the pool of exchanges and, in turn, to reduce the risk of adverse selection and make a market operable.
INTRODUCTION
INTRODUCTION
Introduction The term economics has been derived from a Greek Word Oikonomia which means household. Economics is a social science. It is called social because it studies mankind of society. It deals with aspects of human behavior. It is called science since it studies social problems from a scientific point of view. The development of economics as a growing science can be traced back in the writings of Greek philosophers like Plato and Aristotle. Economics was treated as a branch of politics during early days of its development because ancient Greeks applied this term to management of city-state, which they called Polis. Actually economics broadened into a full fledged social science in the later half of the 18th century. Definition of Economics Classical economists like Adam Smith, Ricardo, Mill Malthus and others; socialist economist like Karl Marx; neoclassical economists like Alfred Marshall, AC Pigou and Lionel Robbins and modern economists like JM Keynes, Samuelson and others have made considerable contribution to the development of Economics. Hence a plethora of definitions are available in connection with the subject matter of economics. These are broadly divided into A. Wealth Definition,
B. Welfare Definition, C. Scarcity Definition and D. Growth Definition A. Wealth Definition Really the science of economics was born in 1776, when Adam Smith published his famous book An Enquiry into the Nature and Cause of Wealth of Nation. He defined economics as the study of the nature and cause of national wealth. According to him, economics is the study of wealth- How wealth is produced and distributed. He is called as father of economics and his definition is popularly called Wealth definition. But this definition was severely criticized by highlighting the points like; Too much emphasis on wealth, Restricted meaning of wealth, No consideration for human feelings, No mention for mans welfare Silent about economic problem etc B. Welfare Definition It was Alfred Marshall who rescued the economics from the above criticisms. By his classic work Principles of Economics, published in 1890, he shifted the emphasis from wealth to human welfare. According to him wealth is simply a means to an end in all activities, the end being human welfare. He adds, that economics is on the one side a study of the wealth; and the other and more important side, a part of the study of man. Marshall gave primary importance to man and secondary importance to wealth. Prof. A C Pigou was also holding Marshalls view. This definition clarified the scope of economics and rescued economics from the grip of being called Dismal science, but this definition also criticized on the grounds that welfare cannot be measured correctly and it was ignored the valuable services like teachers,lawyers,singers etc (non-material welfare)
C. Scarcity Definition After Alfred Marshall, Lionel Robbins formulated his own conception of economics in his book The Nature and Significance of Economic Science in 1932. According to him, Economics is the science which studies human behavior as a relationship between ends and scares means which have alternative uses. He gave importance to four fundamental characters of human existence such as; 1. Unlimited wants- In his definition ends refers to human wants which are boundless or unlimited. 2. Scarcity of means (Limited Resources) the resources (time and money) at the disposal of a person to satisfy his wants are limited. 3. Alternate uses of Scares means- Economic resources not only scarce but have alternate uses also. So one has to make choice of uses. 4. The Economic Problem when wants are unlimited, means are scarce and have alternate uses, the economic problem arises. Hence we need to arrange wants in the order of urgency. The merits of scarcity definition are; this definition is analytical, universal in application, a positive study and considering the concept of opportunity cost. But this also criticized on the grounds that; it is too narrow and too wide, it offers only light but not fruit, confined to micro analysis and ignores Growth economics etc.. D. Modern Definition The credit for revolutionizing the study of economics surely goes to Lord J.M Keynes. He defined economics as the study of the administration of scares resources and the determinants of income and employment. Prof. Samuelson recently given a definition based on growth aspects which is known as Growth definition. Economics is the study of how people and society end up choosing, with or without the use of money to employ scarce productive resources that could have alternative uses to produce various commodities and distribute them for consumption, now or in the future, among various persons or groups in society. Economics analyses the costs and the benefits of improving patterns of resources use. Main features of growth definition are; it is applicable ev en in barter economy, the inclusion of time element makes the scope of economics dynamic and it is an improvement in scarcity definition. Meaning and Definition of Managerial Economics.
Managerial Economics as a subject gained popularit-y in U.S.A after the publication of the book Managerial Economics by Joel Dean in 1951. Joel Dean observed that managerial Economics shows how economic analysis can be used in formulating policies. Managerial economics bridges the gap between traditional economic theory and real business practices in two ways. Firstly, it provides number of tools and techniques to enable the manager to become more competent to take decisions in real and practical situation. Secondly, it serves as an integrating course to show the interaction between various areas in which the firm operates. According to Prof. Evan J Douglas, Managerial economics is concerned with the application of business principles and methodologies to the decision making process within the firm or organization under the conditions of uncertainty. It seeks to establish rules and principles to facilitate the attainment of the desired economic aim of management. These economic aims relate to costs, revenue and profits and are important within both business and non business institutions. Spencer and Siegleman defined managerial Economics as the integration of economic theory with business practice for the purpose of facilitating decision making and forward planning of management managerial economics helps the managers to analyze the problems faced by the business unit and to take vital decisions. They have to choose from among a number of possible alternatives. They have to choose that course of action by which the available resources are most efficiently used. Cristopor I Savage and John R Small opinioned that managerial economics is some thing that concerned with business efficiency. In the words of Michael Baye,Managerial Economics is the study of how to direct scares resources in a way that mostly effectively achieves a managerial goal. Objectives and Uses (importance) of managerial Economics Objectives: The basic objective of managerial economics is to analyze the economic problems faced by the business. The other objectives are: 1. To integrate economic theory with business practice. 2. To apply economic concepts and principles to solve business problems. 3. To allocate the scares resources in the optimal manner. 4. To make all-round development of a firm. 5. To minimize risk and uncertainty 6. To helps in demand and sales forecasting. 7. To help in profit maximization. 8. To help to achieve the other objectives of the firm like industry leadership, expansion implementation of policies etc... Importance: In order to solve the problems of decision making, data are to be collected and analyzed in the light of business objectives. Managerial economics provides help in this area. The importance of managerial economics maybe relies in the following points: 1. It provides tool and techniques for managerial decision making. 2. It gives answers to the basic problems of business management. 3. It supplies data for analysis and forecasting. 4. It provides tools for demand forecasting and profit planning. 5. It guides the managerial economist. 6. It helps in formulating business policies. 7. It assists the management to know internal and external factors influence the business. Following are the important areas of decision making; a) Selection of product. b) Selection of suitable product mix. c) Selection of method of production. d) Product line decision. e) Determination of price and quantity. f) Decision on promotional strategy. g) Optimum input combination. h) Allocation of resources. i) Replacement decision. j) Make or buy decision.
k) Shut down decision. l) Decision on export and import. m) Location decision. n) Capital budgeting. Scope of Managerial / Business Economics The scope of managerial economics refers to its area of study. Scope of Managerial Economics is wider than the scope of Business Economics in the sense that while managerial economics dealing the decisional problems of both business and non business organizations, business economics deals only the problems of business organizations. Business economics giving solution to the problems of a business unit or profit oriented unit. Managerial economics giving solution to the problems of non profit organizations like schools, hospital etc., also. The scope covers two areas of decision making (A) operational or internal issues and (B) Environmental or external issues. A) Operational/internal issues These issues are those which arise within the business organization and are under the control of the management. They pertains to simple questions of what to produce, when to produce, how much to produce and for which category of consumers. The following aspects may be said to be fall under internal issues. 1. Demand analysis and Forecasting: - The demands for the firms product would change in response to change in price, consumers income, his taste etc. which are the determinants of demand. A study of the determinants of demand is necessary for forecasting future demand of the product. 2. Cost analysis: - Estimation of cost is an essential part of managerial problems. The factors causing variation of cost must be found out and allowed for it management to arrive at cost estimates. This will helps for more effective planning and sound pricing practices. 3. Pricing Decisions: - The firms aim to profit which depends upon the correctness of pricing decisions. The pricing is an important area of managerial economics. Theories regarding price fixation helps the firm to solve the price fixation problems. 4. Profit Analysis: - Business firms working for profit and it is an important measure of success. But firms working under conditions of uncertainty. Profit planning become necessary under the conditions of uncertainty. 5. Capital budgeting: - The business managers have to take very important decisions relating to the firms capital investment. The manager has to calculate correctly the profitability of investment and to properly allocate the capital. Success of the firm depends upon the proper analysis of capital project and selecting the best one. 6. Production and supply analysis: - Production analysis is narrower in scope than cost analysis. Production analysis is proceeds in physical terms while cost analysis proceeds in monitory term. Important aspects of supply analysis are; supply schedule, curves and functions, law of supply, elasticity of supply and factors influencing supply B) Environmental or external issues It refers to the general business environment in which the firm operates. A study of economic environment should include: 1. The types of economic system in the country. 2. The general trend in production, employment, income, prices, savings and investments 3. Trends in the working of financial institutions like banks, financial corporations, insurance companies etc.. 4. Magnitude and trends in foreign trade. 5. Trends in labour and capital market. 6. Government economic policies viz., industrial policy, monitory policies, fiscal policy, price policy Functions and Responsibilities of managerial economist A managerial economist can play an important role by assisting the management to solve the difficult problems of decision making and forward planning. Managerial economists have to study external and internal factors influencing the business while taking the decisions. The important questions to be answered by the managerial economists include: 1. Is competition likely to increase or decrease? 2. What are the population shifts and their influence in purchasing power? 3. Will the price of raw materials increase or decrease? Etc... 4. .managerial economist can also help the management in taking decisions regarding internal operation of the firm. Following are the important specific functions of managerial economist; 1. Sales forecasting.
2. Market research. 3. Production scheduling 4. Economic analysis of competing industry. 5. Investment appraisal. 6. Security management analysis. 7. Advise on foreign exchange management. 8. Advice on trade. 9. Environmental forecasting. 10. Economic analysis of agriculture Sales forecasting The responsibilities of managerial economists are the following; 1. To bring reasonable profit to the company. 2. To make accurate forecast. 3. To establish and maintain contact with individual and data sources. 4. To keep the management informed of all the possible economic trends. 5. To prepare speeches for business executives. 6. To participate in public debates 7. To earn full status in the business team. Chief Characteristics of Managerial or Business economics. Following are the important feature of managerial economics 1) Managerial economics is Micro economic in character. Because it studies the problems of a business firm, not the entire economy. 2) Managerial economics largely uses the body of economic concepts and principles which is known as Theory of the Firm or Economics of the firm. 3) Managerial economics is pragmatic. It is purely practical oriented. So Managerial economics considers the particular environment of a firm or business for decision making. 4) Managerial economics is Normative rather than positive economics (descriptive economics). Managerial economics is prescriptive to solve particular business problem by giving importance to firms aim and objectives. 5) Macro economics is also useful to managerial economics since it provides intelligent understanding of the environment in which the business is operating. 6) It is management oriented. Managerial economics as a tool for decision making and forward planning. Decision making: Decision making is an integral part of modern management. Perhaps the most important function of the business manager is decision making. Decision making is the process of selecting one action from two or more alternative course of actions. Resources such as land, labour and capital are limited and can be employed in alternative uses, so the question of choice is arises. Managers of business organizations are constantly faced with wide variety of decisions in the areas of pricing, product selection, cost control, asset management and plant expansion. Manager has to choose best among the alternatives by which available resources are most efficiently used for achieving the desired aims. Decision making process involves the following elements; 1. The identification of the firms objectives. 2. The statement of the problem to be solved. 3. The listing of various alternatives. 4. Evaluation and analysis of alternatives. 5. The selection best alternative 6. The implementation and monitoring of the alternative which is chosen. Following are the important areas of decision making; a) Selection of product. b) Selection of suitable product mix. c) Selection of method of production. d) Product line decision. e) Determination of price and quantity. f) Decision on promotional strategy. g) Optimum input combination.
h) Allocation of resources. i) Replacement decision. j) Make or buy decision. k) Shut down decision. l) Decision on export and import. m) Location decision. n) Capital budgeting. Forward Planning: -Future is uncertain. A firm is operating under the conditions of risk and uncertainty. Risk and uncertainty can be minimized only by making accurate forecast and forward planning. Managerial economics helps manager in forward planning Forward planning means making plans for the future. A manager has to make plan for the future e.g. Expansion of existing plants etc...The study of macro economics provides managers a clear understanding about environment in which the business firm is working. The knowledge of various economic theories viz, demands theory, supply theory etc. also can be helpful for future planning of demand and supply. So managerial economics enables the manager to make plan for the future. Economics Vs Managerial economics. Economics . Dealing both micro and macro aspects 2. Both positive and normative science. 3. Deals with theoretical aspects 4. Study both the firm and individual. 5. Wide scope Managerial Economics Dealing only micro aspects 2. Only a normative science. 3. Deals with practical aspects. 4. Study the problems of firm only. 5. Narrow scope.
DEMAND CONCEPTS
Meaning of Demand Demand is a common parlance means desire for an object. But in economics demand is something more than this. In economics Demand means the quantity of goods and services which a person can purchase with a requisite amount of money. According to Prof.Hidbon, Demand means the various quantities of goods that would be purchased per time period at different prices in a given market. Thus demand for a commodity is its quantity which consumer is able and willing to buy at various prices during a given period of time. Simply, demand is the behavior of potential buyers in a market. In the opinion of Stonier and Hague, Demand in economics means demand backed up by enough money to pay for the goods demanded. In other words, demand means the desire backed by the willingness to buy a commodity and purchasing power to pay. Hence desire alone is not enough. There must have necessary purchasing power, ie, .cash to purchase it. For example, everyone desires to posses Benz car but only few have the ability to buy it. So everybody cannot be said to have a demand for the car. Thus the demand has three essentials-Desire, Purchasing power and Willingness to purchase. Demand Analysis Demand analysis means an attempt to determine the factors affecting the demand of a commodity or service and to measure such factors and their influences. The demand analysis includes the study of law of demand, demand schedule, demand curve and demand forecasting. Main objectives of demand analysis are; 1) To determine the factors affecting the demand. 2) To measure the elasticity of demand. 3) To forecast the demand. 4) To increase the demand. 5) To allocate the recourses efficiently Law of Demand
The law of Demand is known as the first law in market. Law of demand shows the relation between price and quantity demanded of a commodity in the market. In the words of Marshall the amount demanded increases with a fall in price and diminishes with a rise in price. According to Samuelson, Law of Demand states that people will buy more a t lower price and buy less at higher prices. In other words while other things remaining the same an increase in the price of a commodity will decreases the quantity demanded of that commodity and decrease in the price will increase the demand of that commodity. So the relationship described by the law of demand is an inverse or negative relationship because the variables (price and demand) move in opposite direction. It shows the cause and effect relationship between price and quantity demand. The concept of law of demand may be explained with the help of a demand schedules. Individual demand Schedule An individual demand schedule is a list of quantities of a commodity purchased by an individual consumer at different prices. The following table shows the demand schedule of an individual consumer for apple. Price of Apple (In Rs.) 10 8 6 4 2 Quantity demanded 1 2 3 4 5
When the price falls from Rs 10 to 8, the quantity demanded increases from one to two. In the same way as price falls, quantity demanded increases. On the basis of the above demand schedule we can draw the demand curve as follows;
The demand curve DD shows the inverse relation between price and demand of apple. Due to this inverse relationship, demand curve is slopes downward from left to right. This kind of slope is also called negative slope Market demand schedule Market demand refers to the total demand for a commodity by all the consumers. It is the aggregate quantity demanded for a commodity by all the consumers in a market. It can be expressed in the following schedule. Market Demand Schedule for egg. Price per dozen(Rs) A B 10 1 8 2 6 3 4 4 Demand by consumers Market Demand
2 3 4 5
C 0 1 2 3
D 0 0 1 2 3 6 10 14
18
Derivation of market demand curve is a simple process. For example, let us assume that there are four consumers in a market demanding eggs. When the price of one dozen eggs is Rs.10, A buys one dozen and B buys 2 dozens. When price falls to Rs.8, A buys 2 , B buys 3 and C buys one dozen. When price falls to Rs.6, A buys 3 b buys 4,C buys 2 and D buys one dozen and so on. By adding up the quantity demanded by all the four consumers at various prices we get the market demand curve. So last column of the above demand schedule gives the total demand for eggs at different prices,ie,Market Demand as given below; Assumptions of Law of Demand Law of demand is based on certain basic assumptions. They are as follows 1) There is no change in consumers taste and preference 2) Income should remain constant. 3) Prices of other goods should not change. 4) There should be no substitute for the commodity. 5) The commodity should not confer any distinction. 6) The demand for the commodity should be continuous. 7) People should not expect any change in the price of the commodity. Why does demand curve slopes downward? Demand curve slopes downward from left to right (Negative Slope). There are many causes for downward sloping of demand curve:1) Law of Diminishing Marginal utility As the consumer buys more and more of the commodity, the marginal utility of the additional units falls. Therefore the consumer is willing to pay only lower prices for additional units. If the price is higher, he will restrict its consumption 2) Principle of Equi- Marginal Utility Consumer will arrange his purchases in such a way that the marginal utility is equal in all his purchases. If it is not equal, they will alter their purchases till the marginal utility is equal.
3) Income effect. When the price of the commodity falls, the real income of the consumer will increase. He will spend this increased income either to buy additional quantity of the same commodity or other commodity. 4) Substitution effect. When the price of tea falls, it becomes cheaper. Therefore the consumer will substitute this commodity for coffee. This leads to an increase in demand for tea. 5) Different uses of a commodity. Some commodities have several uses. If the price of the commodity is high, its use will be restricted only for important purpose. For e.g. when the price of tomato is high, it will be used only for cooking purpose. When it is cheaper, it will be used for preparing jam, pickle etc... 6) Psychology of people. Psychologically people buy more of a commodity when its price falls. In other word it can be termed as price effect. 7) Tendency of human beings to satisfy unsatisfied wants. Exceptions to the Law of Demand. (Exceptional Demand Curve). The basic feature of demand curve is negative sloping. But there are some exceptions to this. I.e... In certain circumstances demand curve may slope upward from left to right (positive slopes). These phenomena may due to; 1) Giffen paradox The Giffen goods are inferior goods is an exception to the law of demand. When the price of inferior good falls, the poor will buy less and vice versa. When the price of maize falls, the poor will not buy it more but they are willing to spend more on superior goods than on maize. Thus fall in price will result into reduction in quantity. This paradox is first explained by Sir Robert Giffen. 2) Veblen or Demonstration effect. According to Veblen, rich people buy certain goods because of its social distinction or prestige. Diamonds and other luxurious article are purchased by rich people due to its high prestige value. Hence higher the price of these articles, higher will be the demand. 3) Ignorance. Some times consumers think that the product is superior or quality is high if the price of that product is high. As such they buy more at high price. 4) Speculative Effect. When the price of commodity is increasing, then the consumer buy more of it because of the fear that it will increase still further.
5) Fear of Shortage. During the time of emergency or war, people may expect shortage of commodity and buy more at higher price to keep stock for future. 6) Necessaries In the case of necessaries like rice, vegetables etc., People buy more even at a higher price. 7) Brand Loyalty When consumer is brand loyal to particular product or psychological attachment to particular product, they will continue to buy such products even at a higher price. 8) Festival, Marriage etc. In certain occasions like festivals, marriage etc. people will buy more even at high price. Exceptional Demand Curve (perverse demand curve)
When price raises from OP to OP1 quantity demanded also increases from OQ to OQ1. In other words, from the above, we can see that there is positive relation between price and demand. Hence, demand curve (DD) slopes upward. CHANGES IN DEMAND Demand of a commodity may change. It may increase or decrease due to changes in certain factors. These factors are called determinants of demand. These factors include; 1) Price of a commodity 2) Nature of commodity 3) Income and wealth of consumer 4) Taste and preferences of consumer 5) Price of related goods (substitutes and compliment goods) 6) Consumers expectations. 7) Advertisement etc.. Demand Function. There is a functional relationship between demand and its various determinants. I.e., a change in any determinant will affect the demand. When this relationship expressed mathematically, it is called Demand Function. Demand function of a commodity can be written as follows: D = f (P, Y, T, Ps, U) Where, D= Quantity demanded P= Price of the commodity Y= Income of the consumer T= Taste and preference of consumers. Ps = Price of substitutes U= Consumers expectations & others f = Function of (indicates how variables are related) Extension and Contraction of Demand. Demand may change due to various factors. The change in demand due to change in price only, where other factors remaining constant, it is called extension and contraction of demand. A change in demand solely due to change in price is called extension and contraction. When the quantity demanded of a commodity rises due to a fall in price, it is called extension of demand. On the other hand, when the quantity demanded falls due to a rise in price, it is called contraction of demand. It can be understand from the following diagram.
When the price of commodity is OP, quantity demanded is OQ. If the price falls to P2, quantity demanded increases to OQ2. When price rises to P1, demand decreases from OQ to OQ1. In demand curve, the area a to c is extension of demand and the area a to b is contraction of demand. As result of change in price of a commodity, the consumer moves along the same demand curve. Shift in Demand (Increase or Decrease in demand) When the demand changes due to changes in other factors, like taste and preferences, income, price of related goods etc... , it is called shift in demand. Due to changes in other factors, if the consumers buy more goods, it is called increase in demand or upward shift. On the other hand, if the consumers buy fewer goods due to change in other factors, it is called downward shift or decrease in demand. Shift in demand cannot be shown in same demand curve. The increase and decrease in demand (upward shift and downward shift) can be expressed by the following diagram.
DD is the original demand curve. Demand curve shift upward due to change in income, taste & preferences etc of consumer, where price remaining the same. In the above diagram demand curve D1- D1 is showing upward shift or increase in demand and D2-D2 shows downward shift or decrease in demand. Comparison between Extension/Contraction Shift in Demand extension/contraction of Demand and shift in demand SL. No 1 Demand is varying due to Demand is varying due to changes in price changes in other factors 2 Other factors like taste, Price of commodity preferences, income etc... remain the same
remaining the same. Consumer moves along the same demand curve
Meaning of Elasticity Law of demand explains the directions of changes in demand. A fall in price leads to an increase in quantity demanded and vice versa. But it does not tell us the rate at which demand changes to change in price. The concept of elasticity of demand was introduced by Marshall. This concept explains the relationship between a change in price and consequent change in quantity demanded. Nutshell, it shows the rate at which changes in demand take place. Elasticity of demand can be defined as the degree of responsiveness in quantity demanded to a change in price. Thus it represents the rate of change in quantity demanded due to a change in price. There are mainly three types of elasticity of demand: 1. Price Elasticity of Demand. 2. Income Elasticity of Demand. and 3. Cross Elasticity of Demand. Price Elasticity of Demand Price Elasticity of demand measures the change in quantity demanded to a change in price. It is the ratio of percentage change in quantity demanded to a percentage change in price. This can be measured by the following formula. Price Elasticity = Proportionate change in quantity demanded Proportionate change in price OR Ep = Change in Quantity demanded / Quantity demanded Change in Price/price OR Ep = (Q2-Q1)/Q1 (P2-P1) /P1 , Where: Q1 = Quantity demanded before price change Q2 = Quantity demanded after price change P1 = Price charged before price change P2 = Price charge after price change. There are five types of price elasticity of demand. (Degree of elasticity of demand) Such as perfectly elastic demand, perfectly inelastic demand, relatively elastic demand, relatively inelastic demand and unitary elastic demand. 1) Perfectly elastic demand (infinitely elastic) When a small change in price leads to infinite change in quantity demanded, it is called perfectly elastic demand. In this case the demand curve is a horizontal straight line as given below. (Here ep= ) 2) Perfectly inelastic demand In this case, even a large change in price fails to bring about a change in quantity demanded. I.e. the change in price will not affect the quantity demanded and quantity remains the same whatever the change in price. Here demand curve will be vertical line as follows and ep= 0
3) Relatively elastic demand Here a small change in price leads to very big change in quantity demanded. In this case demand curve will be fatter one and ep=>1
4) Relatively inelastic demand Here quantity demanded changes less than proportionate to changes in price. A large change in price leads to small change in demand. In this case demand curve will be steeper and ep=<1
5) Unit elasticity of demand ( unitary elastic) Here the change in demand is exactly equal to the change in price. When both are equal, ep= 1, the elasticity is said to be unitary.
The above five types of elasticity can be summarized as follows SL No 1 type Perfectly elastic Numerical expression description infinity Shape of curve Horizontal
2 3 4 5
0 1 >1 <1
of Demand Income elasticity of demand shows the change in quantity demanded as a result of a change in consumers income. Income elasticity of demand may be stated in the form of formula: Ey = Proportionate Change in Quantity Demanded Proportionate Change in Income Income elasticity of demand mainly of three types: 1) Zero income Elasticity. 2) Negative income Elasticity 3) Positive income Elasticity. Zero income elasticity In this case, quantity demanded remain the same, eventhogh money income increases.ie, changes in the income doesnt influence the quantity demanded (Eg.salt,sugar etc). Here Ey (income elasticity) = 0 Negative income elasticity -In this case, when income increases, quantity demanded falls.Eg, inferior goods. Here Ey = < 0.
Positive income Elasticity - In this case, an increase in income may lad to an increase in the quantity demanded. i.e., when income rises, demand also rises. (Ey =>0) This can be further classified in to three types: a) Unit income elasticity; Demand changes in same proportion to change in income.i.e, Ey = 1 b) Income elasticity greater than unity: An increase in income brings about a more than proportionate increase in quantity demanded.i.e, Ey =>1 c) Income elasticity less than unity: when income increases quantity demanded is also increases but less than proportionately. I.e., Ey = <1 Business decision based on income elasticity. The concept of income elasticity can be utilized for the purpose of taking vital business decision. A businessman can rely on the following facts. If income elasticity is greater than Zero, but less than one, sales of the product will increase but slower than the general economic growth If income elasticity is greater than one, sales of his product will increase more rapidly than the general economic growth. Firms whose demand functions have high income elasticity have good growth opportunities in an expanding economy. This concept helps manager to take correct decision during business cycle and also helps in forecasting the effect of changes in income on demand. Cross Elasticity of Demand Cross elasticity of demand is the proportionate change in the quantity demanded of a commodity in response to change in the price of another related commodity. Related commodity may either substitutes or complements. Examples of substitute commodities are tea and coffee. Examples of compliment commodities are car and petrol. Cross elasticity of demand can be calculated by the following formula; Cross Elasticity = Proportionate Change in Quantity Demanded of a Commodity Proportionate Change in the Price of Related Commodity If the cross elasticity is positive, the commodities are said to be substitutes and if cross elasticity is negative, the commodities are compliments. The substitute goods (tea and Coffee) have positive cross elasticity because the increase in the price of tea may increase the demand of the coffee and the consumer may shift from the consumption of tea to coffee. Complementary goods (car and petrol) have negative cross elasticity because increase in the price of car will reduce the quantity demanded of petrol. The concept of cross elasticity assists the manager in the process of decision making. For fixing the price of product which having close substitutes or compliments, cross elasticity is very useful. Advertisement Elasticity of Demand Advertisement elasticity of demand (Promotional elasticity of demand) measure the responsiveness of demand due to a change in advertisement and other promotional expenses. This can be measured by the following formula; Advertisement Elasticity = Proportionate Increase in Sales Proportionate increase in Advertisement expenditure. There are various determinants of advertisement elasticity, they are; 1. Type of commodity- elasticity will be higher for luxury, new product, growing product etc., 2. Market share larger the market share of the firm lower will be promotional elasticity. 3. Rivals reaction if the rivals react to increase in firms advertisement by increasing their own advertisement expenditure, it will reduce the advertisement elasticity of the firm.
4. State of economy if economic conditions are good, the consumers are more likely to respond to the advertisement of the firm. Advertisement elasticity helps in the process of decision making. It helps to deciding the optimum level of advertisement and promotional cost. If the advertisement elasticity is high, it is profitable to spend more on advertisement. Hence, advertisement elasticity helps to decide optimum advertisement and promotional outlay. Importance of Elasticity. The concept of elasticity of demand is much of practical importance; 1. Production- Producers generally decide their production level on the basis of demand for their product. Hence elasticity of demand helps to fix the level of output. 2. Price fixation- Each seller under monopoly and imperfect competition has to take into account the elasticity of demand while fixing their price. If the demand for the product is inelastic, he can fix a higher price. 3. Distribution- Elasticity helps in the determination of rewards for factors of production. For example, if the demand for labour is inelastic, trade union can raise wages. 4. International trade- This concept helps in finding out the terms of trade between two countries. Terms of trade means rate at which domestic commodities is exchanged for foreign commodities. 5. Public finance- This assists the government in formulating tax policies. In order to impose tax on a commodity, the government should take into consideration the demand elasticity. 6. Nationalization- Elasticity of demand helps the government to decide about nationalization of industries. 7. Price discrimination- A manufacture can fix a higher price for the product which have inelastic demand and lower price for product which have elastic demand. 8. Others- The concept elasticity of demand also helping in taking other vital decision Eg.Determining the price of joint product, take over decision etc.. Determinants of elasticity. Elasticity of demand varies from product to product, time to time and market to market. This is due to influence of various factors. They are; 1. Nature of commodity- Demand for necessary goods (salt, rice,etc,) is inelastic. Demand for comfort and luxury good are elastic. 2. Availability/range of substitutes A commodity against which lot of substitutes are available, the demand for that is elastic. But the goods which have no substitutes, demand is inelastic. 3. Extent /variety of uses- a commodity having a variety of uses has a comparatively elastic demand.Eg.Demand for steel, electricity etc.. 4. Postponement/urgency of demand- if the consumption of a commodity can be post pond, then it will have elastic demand. Urgent commodity has inelastic demand.
5. Income level- income level also influences the elasticity. E.g. Rich man will not curtail the consumption quantity of fruit, milk etc, even if their price rises, but a poor man will not follow it. 6. Amount of money spend on the commodity- where an individual spends only a small portion of his income on the commodity, the price change doesnt materially affect the demand for the commodity, and the demand is inelastic... (match box, salt Etc) 7. Durability of commodity- if the commodity is durable or repairable at a substantially less amount (eg.Shoes), the demand for that is elastic. 8. Purchase frequency of a product/time if the frequency of purchase of a product is very high, the demand is likely to be more price elastic. 9. Range of Prices- if the products at very high price or at very low price having inelastic demand since a slight change in price will not affect the quantity demand. 10. Others the habit of consumers, demand for complimentary goods, distribution of income and wealth in the society etc., are other important factors affecting elasticity. Measurement of Elasticity There are various methods for the measurement of elasticity of demand. Following are the important methods: 1. Proportional or Percentage Method: Under this method the elasticity of demand is measured by the ratio between the proportionate or percentage change in quantity demanded and proportionate change in price. It is also known as formula method. It can be computed as follows: ED = Proportionate change in quantity demanded Proportionate change in price. OR = Change in Demand Original Quantity demanded Change in Price Original price 2. Expenditure or Outlay Method: This method was developed by Marshall. Under this method, the elasticity is measured by estimating the changes in total expenditure as a result of changes in price and quantity demanded. This has three components If the price changes, but total expenditure remains constant, unit elasticity exists. If the price changes, but total expenditure moves in the opposite directions, demand is elastic (>1). If the price changes and total revenues moves in the same direction, demand is inelastic (<1). This can be expressed by the following diagram.
3. Geometric or Point method: This also developed by Marshall. This is used as a measure of the change in quantity demanded in response to a very small change in the price. In this method we can measure the elasticity at any point on a straight line demand curve by using the following formula; ED = Lower section of the Demand curve Upper section of Demand curve.
In the above diagram, AB is a straight line demand curve with P as its middle point. Further it is assumed that AB is 6 cm. then, At point P, ED = PB/PA=3/3=1 At point P1, ED = P1B/P1A= 4.5/1.5= 3=>1, At point A, ED = AB/A= 6/0= (infinity), At point P2, ED = P2B/P2A = 1.5/4.5 = 1/3 = <1, At point B, ED = B/BA = 0/6 = 0 4. Arc Method: the point method is applicable only when there are minute (very small) changes in price and demand. Arc elasticity measures elasticity between two points. It is a measure of the average elasticity According to Watson, Arc elasticity is the elasticity at the midpoint of an arc of a demand curve. formula to measure elasticity is: ED = Q/ P (P1+P2)/ (Q1+Q2) or Change in D x Average P Average D Change in P. Where, Q= change in quantity Q1= original quantity
3. Firm level it is more important from managerial view point as it helps the management in decision making with regard to the firms demand and production. Types of Demand Forecasting. Based on the time span and planning requirements of business firms, demand forecasting can be classified into short term demand forecasting and long term demand forecasting. Short term Demand forecasting: Short term Demand forecasting is limited to short periods, usually for one year. Important purposes of Short term Demand forecasting are given below; 1. Making a suitable production policy to avoid over production or underproduction. 2. Helping the firm to reduce the cost of purchasing raw materials and to control inventory. 3. Deciding suitable price policy so as to avoid an increase when the demand is low. 4. Setting correct sales target on the basis of future demand and establishment control. A high target may discourage salesmen. 5. Forecasting short term financial requirements for planned production. 6. Evolving a suitable advertising and promotion programme. Long term Demand Forecasting: this forecasting is meant for long period. The important purpose of long term forecasting is given below; 1. Planning of a new unit or expansion of existing on them basis of analysis of long term potential of the product demand. 2. Planning long term financial requirements on the basis of long term sales forecasting. 3. Planning of manpower requirements can be made on the basis of long term sales forecast. 4. To forecast future problems of material supply and energy crisis. Demand forecasting is a vital tool for marketing management. It is also helpful in decision making and forward planning. It enables the firm to produce right quantities at right time and arrange well in advance for the factors of production. Methods of Demand Forecasting (Established Products) Several methods are employed for forecasting demand. All these methods can be grouped into survey method and statistical method. Survey Method. Under this method, information about the desire of the consumers and opinions of experts are collected by interviewing them. This can be divided into four types; 1. Opinion Survey method: This method is also known as Sales- Force Composite method or collective opinion method. Under this method, the company asks its salesmen to submit estimate for future sales in their respective territories. This method is more useful and appropriate because the salesmen are more knowledgeable about their territory. 2. Expert Opinion: Apart from salesmen and consumers, distributors or outside experts may also be used for forecast. Firms in advanced countries like USA, UK etc...make use of outside experts for estimating future demand. Various public and private agencies sell periodic forecast of short or long term business conditions. 3. Delphi Method: It is a sophisticated statistical method to arrive at a consensus. Under this method, a panel is selected to give suggestions to solve the problems in hand. Both internal and external experts can be the members of the panel. Panel members are kept apart from each other and express their views in an anonymous manner
4. Consumer Interview method: Under this method a list of potential buyers would be drawn and each buyer will be approached and asked about their buying plans. This method is ideal and it gives firsthand information, but it is costly and difficult to conduct. This may be undertaken in three ways: A) Complete Enumeration In this method, all the consumers of the product are interviewed. B) Sample survey - In this method, a sample of consumers is selected for interview. Sample may be random sampling or Stratified sampling. C) End-use method The demand for the product from different sectors such as industries, consumers, export and import are found out. Statistical Methods It is used for long term forecasting. In this method, statistical and mathematical techniques are used to forecast demand. This method is relies on past data. This includes; 1. Trent projection method: Under this method, demand is estimated on the basis of analysis of past data. This method makes use of time series (data over a period of time). Here we try to ascertain the trend in the time series. Trend in the time series can be estimated by using least square method or free hand method or moving average method or semi-average method. 2. Regression and Correlation: These methods combine economic theory and statistical techniques of estimation. in this method, the relationship between dependant variables(sales) and independent variables(price of related goods, income, advertisement etc..) is ascertained. This method is also called the economic model building. 3. Extrapolation: In this method the future demand can be extrapolated by applying binomial expansion method. This is based on the assumption that the rate of change in demand in the past has been uniform. 4. Simultaneous equation method: This means the development of a complete economic model which will explain the behaviour of all variables which the company can control. 5. Barometric techniques: Under this, present events are used to predict directions of change in the future. This is done with the help of statistical and economic indicators like: Construction contract, Personal income Agricultural income Employment GNP Industrial production Bank deposit etc Forecasting Demand for a New Product. Joel Dean has suggested six approaches for forecasting the demand for new products. 1. Evolutionary Approach: In this method, the demand for new product is estimated on the basis of existing product. E.g. Demand forecasting of colour TV on the basis of demand for black & white TV. 2. Substitute Approach: The demand for the new product is analyzed as substitute for the existing product. 3. Growth curve Approach: On the basis of the growth of an established product, the demand for the new product is estimated. 4. Opinion Polling Approach: In this approach, the demand for the new product is estimated by inquiring directly from the consumers by using sample survey.
5. Sales Experience Approach: The demand is estimated by supplying the new product in a sample market and analyzing the immediate response on that product in the market.. 6. Vicarious Approach: Consumers reactions on the new products are fount out indirectly with the help of specialized dealers. Factors Affecting Demand Forecasting. The following are the important factors governing demand forecasting: 1. Prevailing Business conditions (price level change, percapita income, consumption pattern, saving, investments, employment etc.., 2. Condition within the Industry (Price product-competition policy of firms within the industry). 3. Condition within the firm. (Plant capacity, quality, important policies of the firm). 4. Factors affecting Export trade (EXIM control, EXIM policy, terms of export, export finance etc..,) 5. Market behaviour 6. Sociological Conditions (Population details, age group, family lifecycle, education, family income, social awareness etc...) 7. Psychological Conditions (taste, habit, attitude, perception, culture, religion etc) 8. Competitive Condition (competitive condition within the industry) Criteria for Good forecasting Method. A good forecasting method should satisfy the following criteria: 1. Plausibility-It should be reasonable or believable. 2. Simplicity- It should be simple and easy. 3. Economy it should be less costly. 4. Accuracy it should be as accurate as possible. 5. Availability Relevant data should be easily available. 6. Flexibility it should be flexible to adopt required changes. Concept of Revenue For the purpose of demand analysis, it is considered useful to distinguish between various types of revenue: Average Revenue (AR); AR means the total receipts from sales divided by the number of unit sold. AR= TR/Q Total Revenue (TR): TR means the total sales proceeds .it can be ascertained by multiplying quantity sold by price. TR =PxQ Incremental Revenue (IR): IR measures then differences between the new TR and existing TR IR=R2-R1 =R Marginal Revenue (MR); It is the additional revenue which would be earned by selling an additional unit of a firms products. It shows the change in TR when one more or one less unit is sold. MR= R2-R1/Q2-Q1 = R/Q Where, R1= TR before price change R2= TR after price change Q1 = old quantity before price change Q2 = new quantity after price change
The relationship between AR, TR and MR can be understand with the help of the following table Quantity AR TR MR demande d (Q) 1 9 9 9 2 8 16 7 3 7 21 5 4 6 24 3 5 5 25 1 6 4 24 -1 7 3 21 -3 8 2 16 -5 9 1 9 -7 The study of the above table reveals that: 1. So long as AR is falling, MR will be less than AR 2. MR falls more steeply than AR 3. TR will be rising so long as MR is positive 4. Where MR is negative, TR will be falling 5. TR will be maximum at the point where MR is Zero. The relation Elasticity .>1 Elasticity .=1 Elasticity <1 between elasticity of demand and TR can be summarized as under: Change in price Rises in price TR falls TR unchanged TR rises Fall in price TR rises TR unchanged TR falls
PRODUCTION
Introduction In Economics the term production means process by which a commodity(or commodities) is transformed in to a different usable commodity. In other words, production means transforming inputs( labour ,machines ,raw materials etc.) into an output. This kind of production is called manufacturing. The production process however does not necessarily involve physical conversion of raw materials in to tangible goods . it also includes the conversion of intangible inputs to intangible outputs . For example , production of legal, medical ,social and consultancy services- where lawyers, doctors, social workers consultants are all engaged in producing intangible goods. An input` is good or service that goes in to the process of production and out put is any good or service that comes out of production process. Fixed and variable inputs. In economic sense, a fixed input is one whose supply is inelastic in the short run .Therefore, all of its users cannot buy more of it in short run. Conceptually, all its users, cannot employ more of it in the short run. If one user buys more of it, some other users will get less of it. A variable input is defined as one whose supply in the short run is elastic, eg:Labour, raw materials etc. All the users of such factors can employ larger quantity in the short run.
In technical sense ,a fixed input remains fixed (constant) up to a certain level of output whereas a variable input changes with change in output . A firm has two types of production function:(1) Shot run production function (2) Long run production function Production function Production function shows the technological relationship between quantity of out put and the quantity of various inputs used in production. Production function is economic sense states the maximum output that can be produced during a period with a certain quantity of various inputs in the existing state of technology. In other words, It is the tool of analysis which is used to explain the input - output relationships. In general, it tells that production of a commodity depends on the specified inputs. in its specific tem it presents the quantitative relationship between inputs and output . inputs are classified as:1 . Fixed input or fixed factors. 2. Variable input or variable factors. Short run and Long run Shot run refers to a period of time in which the supply of certain inputs (E.g. :- plant, building ,machines, etc) are fixed or inelastic. Thus an increases in production during this period is possible only by increasing the variable input . In some Industries, short run may be a matter of few weeks or a few months and in some others it may extent even up to three or more years. The long run refers to a period of time in which supply of all the input is elastic ; but not enough to permit a change in technology. In the long run, the availability of even fixed factor increases. Thus in the long run, production of commodity can be increased by employing more of both ,variable and fixed inputs. In the strict sense ,production function is defined as the transformation of physical input in to physical out put where out put is a function input .It can be expressed algebraically as; Q=f (K,L etc).Where Q- Is the quantity of out put produced during a particular period K, L etc are the factors of production f -denotes the function of or depends on. The production functions are based on certain assumptions; 1. Perfect divisibility of both inputs and out put; 2. Limited substitution of one factor for the others 3. Constant technology; and 4. Inelastic supply of fixed factors in the short run Cobb-Douglas Production Function. One of the important tool of statistical analysis in production function that measures the relation between change in physical input is cob-Douglas production function . The concept was originated in USA. This is more peculiar to manufacturing concerns. The cob-Douglas formula says that labour contributes about 75% increases in manufacturing production while capital contributes only 25%.The formula is as follows:O=KLaC (1-a) Where O is output. L is the quantity of labour C is the quantity of capital employed K and a(a<1)are positive constants. a and 1-a measure percentage response of output to percentage change in labour and capital respectively. The production function shows at One (1%)percentage change in labour, capital remaining constant, is associated with 0.75% change in output . Similarly One percentage change in capital, labour
remaining constant, is associated with a 20%change in output. Returns to scale are constant. That is if factors of production are increased, each by 10 percentage then the output also increases by 10 percentage The laws of production Production function shows the relationship between a given quantity of input and its maximum possible out put. Given the production function, the relationship between additional quantities of input and the additional output can be easily obtained. This kind of relationship yields the law of production The traditional theory of production studies the marginal input-output relationship under (I) Short run; and (II) long run. In the short run, input-output relations are studied with one variable input, while other inputs are held constant .The Law of production under these assumptions are called the Laws of variable production. In the long run input output relations a re studied assuming all the input to be variable. The long-run input output relations are studied under `Laws of Returns to Scale. Law of Diminishing Returns (Law of Variable Proportions) The Laws of returns states the relationship between the variable input and the output in the short term. By definition certain factors of production (e.g.-Land, plant, machinery etc) are available in short supply during the short run . Such factors which are available in unlimited supply even during the short periods are known as variable factor. In short-run there fore ,the firms can employ a limited or fixed quantity of fixed factors and an unlimited quantity of the variable factor . In other words, firms can employ in the short run varying quantities of variable inputs against given quantity of fixed factors. This kind of change in input combination leads to variation in factor proportions. The Law which brings out the relationship between varying factor properties and output are there fore known as the Law of variable proportions.. The variation in inputs lead to a disproportionate increase in output more and more units of variable factor when applied cause an increase in output but after a point the extra output will grow less and less. The law which brings out this tendency in production is known as Law of Diminishing Returns` The Law of Diminishing returns levels that any attempt to increase output by increasing only one factor finally faces diminishing returns. The Law states that when some factor remain constant ,more and more units of a variable factor are introduced the production may increase initially at an increasing rate; but after a point it increases only at diminishing rate. Land and capital remain fixed in the short-term whereas labour shows a variable nature. The following table explains the operation of the Law of Diminishi ng Returns. No. of Workers 1 2 3 Total product Average product Marginal product
10 22 36
10 11 12
10 12 14
16 14 10 6 3 0 (-2)
OX axis represents the units of labour and OY axis represents the unit of output . The total output(TP)curve has a steep rise till the employment of the 4th worker. This shows that the output increases at an increasing rate till the employment of the 4th labour . TP curve still goes on increasing but only at a diminishing rate. Finally TP curve shows a downward trend. The Law of Diminishing Returns operation at three stages .At the first stage, total product increases at an increasing rate .The marginal product at this stage increases at an increasing rate resulting in a greater increases in total product .The average product also increases. This stage continues up to the point where average product is equal to marginal product .the law of increasing returns is in operation at this stage The Law of increasing Returns operates from the second stage on wards .At the second stage , the total product continues to increase but at a diminishing rate . As the marginal product at this stage starts falling ,the average product also declines . The second stage comes to an end where total product become maximum and marginal product becomes zero. The marginal product becomes negative in the third stage. So the total product also declines. The average product continues to decline in the third stage. Assumptions of Law Diminishing Returns The Law of Diminishing Returns is based on the following assumptions;Returns is based on the following assumptions;1. The production technology remains unchanged 2. The variable factor is homogeneous. 3. Any one factor is constant 4. The fixed factor remains constant. Law of Returns to scale In the long run all the factor of production are variable ,and an increase in output is possible by increasing all the inputs. The Law of Returns to scale explains the technological relationship between changing scale of input and output. The law of returns of scale explain how a simultaneous and proportionate Increase in all the inputs affect the total output. The increase in output may be proportionate , more than proportionate or less than proportionate. If the increase in output is proportionate to the increase in input , it is constant Returns to scale .If It is less then proportionate it
is diminishing returns to scale . The increasing returns to the scale comes first ,then constant and finally diminishing returns to scale happens. Increasing Returns to scale When proportionate increase in all factor of production results in a more than proportionate increase in output and this results first stage of production which is known as increasing returns to scale. Marginal output increases at this stage. Higher degree of specialization, falling cost etc will lead higher efficiency which result increased returns in the very first stage of production. Constant Returns to scale Firms cannot maintain increasing returns to scale indefinitely after the first stage , firm enters a stage when total output tends to increase at a rate which is equal to the rate of increase in inputs. This stage comes in to operation when the economies of large scale production are neutralized by the diseconomies of large scale operation. Diminishing Returns to Scale In this stage ,a proportionate increase in all the input result only less than proportionate increase in output . This is because of the diseconomies of large scale production. When the firm grows further, the problem of management arise which result inefficiency and it will affect the position of output. Economies of Scale The factors which cause the operation of the laws of returns the scale are grouped under economies and diseconomies of scale . Increasing returns to scale operates because of economies of scale and decreasing returns to scale operates because of diseconomies of scale where economies and diseconomies arise simultaneously. Increasing returns to scale operates when economies of scale are greater then the diseconomies of scale and returns to scale decreases when diseconomies .overweight the economies of scale . Similarly when economies and diseconomies are in balance ,returns to scale becomes constant. When a firm increases all the factor of production it enjoys the same advantages of economies of production . The economies of scale are classified as ; 1. Internal economies. 2. .External economies Internal economies of scale Internal economies are those which arise form the explanation of the plant-size of the firm .Internal economies of scale may be classified;(a) Economies in production. (b) Economies in marketing (c) Economies in economies (d) Economies in transport and storage A . Economies in production :-it arises term 1. Technological advantages 2. Advantages of division of labour and specialization B . Economies in marketing;-It facilitates through 1. Large scale purchase of inputs.
2. Advertisement economies ; 3. Economies in large scale distribution 4. Other large-scale economies C . Managerial economies ;- It achieves through 1. Specialization in management 2. Mechanization of managerial function. D . Economies in transport and storage Economies in transportation and storage costs arise form fuller utilization of transport and storage facilities. External Economies of scale External or pecuniary economies to large size firms arise from the discounts available to it due to; 1 . Large scale purchase of raw materials 2 . Large scale acquisition of external finance at low interest 3 . Lower advertising rate fun advertising media. 4 . Concessional transport charge on bulk transport. 5. Lower wage rates if a large scale firm is monopolistic employer of certain kind of specialized labour Thus External economies of scale are strictly based on experience of large scale firms or well managed small scale firms. Economies of scale will not continue for ever. Expansion in the size of the firms beyond a particular limit , too much specialization, inefficient supervision, Improper labour relations etc will lead to diseconomies of scale . Isoquant curve. The terms Iso-quant has been derived from the Greek word iso means `equal` and Latin word quantus means `quantity`. The iso-quant curve is therefore also known as`` equal product curve ``or production indifference curve . An iso- quant curve is locus of point representing the various combination of two inputs capital and labour yielding the same output. It shows all possible combination of two inputs, namely- capital and labour which can produce a particular quantity of output or different combination of the two inputs that can give in the same output . An isoquant curve all along its length represents a fixed quantity of output. The following table illustrates combination of capital (K) and labour (L) which give the same output say-20units. The combinations Capital Labour Output of A uses one unit of K and 12 units of L to produce is20 units. likewise the combinations B,C,D and E give the same output -20 units. Combination A 1 12 20 B 2 8 20
C D E
3 4 5
5 3 2
20 20 20