on Tenure Security FORD FOUNDATION By Lynn Ellsworth FORD FOUNDATION The Ford Foundation is a resource for innovative people and institutions worldwide. Our goals are to: Strengthen democratic values, Reduce poverty and injustice, Promote international cooperation, and Advance human achievement. This has been our purpose for more than half a century. A fundamental challenge facing every society is to create political, economic, and social systems that promote peace, human welfare, and the sustainability of the envi- ronment on which life depends. We believe that the best way to meet this challenge is to encourage initiatives by those living and working closest to where problems are located; to promote collaboration among the nonprofit, government, and business sectors; and to ensure participation by men and women from diverse communities and at all levels of society. In our experience, such activities help build common understanding, enhance excellence, enable people to improve their lives, and reinforce their commitment to society. Asset Building and Community Development Program The Foundations Asset Building and Community Development Program supports efforts to reduce poverty and injustice by helping to build the financial, natural, social, and human assets of low-income individuals and communities. Environment and Development Affinity Group (EDAG) The Environment and Development Affinity Group is an association of Ford Foundation program staff whose mission is to promote global learning and mobilize change in the field of environment and development. It promotes a theory and practice of development worldwide that is compatible with the sustainable and equitable use of environmental assets, including the protection, restoration, and enhancement of environmental quality, and respect for diverse cultural values and vitality. Members of the EDAG support research, convening, peer learning, advocacy, and networking to improve the effectiveness of the Foundations grantmaking in the environment and development field. Mission Statement Property rights have a profound effect on who benefits from forests. Copyright 2004 by the Ford Foundation all rights reserved. Mission Statement 4 Foreword 5 Definitions 6 Feudal Forests and Britains New Forest of William the Conqueror 7 History of the Concept of Tenure Security 10 Security of Tenure and the Property Rights School 11 Tenure Security and the Case of Natural Forests 14 Security of Tenure in the Agrarian Structure School 15 Is There Empirical Evidence for the Theory of the Property Rights School? 16 Tenure Security and Common Property 19 Key Arguments of the Common Property Advocates 20 Institutionalists 22 A Summary of the Four Analytical Traditions 23 Implications and Conclusions 25 Notes 27 Bibliography 29 Credits By Lynn Ellsworth A Place in the World tions. These assets include (2002, pp. 2-3): Human assets such as the education and other marketable skills that allow low-income people to obtain and retain employment that pays a living wage, as well as comprehensive reproductive health which affects the capacity of people to work, overcome poverty, and lead satisfying lives; Financial holdings of low-income people, such as savings, homeowner- ship, and equity in a business; Social bonds and community relations that constitute the social capital and civic culture of a place and that can break down the isolation of the poor, as well as the webs of interpersonal and intergenerational relationships that individuals need as a base of security and support; and Natural resources, such as forests, wildlife, land, and livestock that can underpin communities and provide sustainable livelihoods, as well as environmental services such as a forests role in the cleansing, recycling, and renewal of the air and water that sustain human life. When this approach is applied to communities that are dependent upon converting natural resources into sustainable livelihoods, it becomes a strategy for building the natural assets of these communities. The theoretical bases for building natural assets have been explored by Boyce (2001), Boyce and Pastor (2001), and Boyce and Shelley (2003). Boyce and his co- authors note that the application of asset-building strategies to natural assets is compelling because strategies for building natural assets in the hands of low-income individuals and communities can simultaneously advance the goals of poverty reduction, environmental protection and environmental justice (2001, p. 268). It countermands the conventional wisdom that the poor face an inescapable tradeoff between higher incomes and a better environ- ment. And building natural assets can contribute not only increased income but also nonincome benefits such as health and environmental quality. For more than 20 years Ford Foundation programs around the world have involved support for community-based forestry in its many forms and facets. What does it mean to have secure tenure for a piece of farm land, forest land, or pasture land? And how important might secure tenure be for the creation of sustainable community livelihoods among the hundreds of millions of the worlds poorest people who are dependent upon land as the prime natural asset from which they might develop a livelihood? What rela- tionship does the definition of secure tenure have to the creation, use, and defense of property rights? These are some of the critical issues addressed by Lynn Ellsworth in this informative paper, one of a pair of papers on tenure issues related to forest lands developed by Forest Trends, Inc. at the invitation of the Ford Foundation. Drawing on more than 50 years of academic debate and the evolution of four distinct traditions of land tenure analysis, this paper sets the stage for its close- ly linked partner, a paper entitled Deeper Roots: Strategies for Strengthening Community Property Rights over Forests: Lessons and Opportunities for Practitioners, which is also published in this series. Why is this work of special importance to the Ford Foundation? Why undertake this analysis at this point? What importance could it have for other funders and development organizations? Those questions provide the focus for this brief foreword. For the past five years, much of the work of the Ford Foundation linked to the alleviation of poverty and injustice has been organized conceptually around an asset-building approach in which work at the level of local commu- nities is an important facet. The asset-building approach to poverty alleviation provides a significant departure from other paradigms that focused primarily upon subsidy and transfer programs that temporarily raise the incomes, or the consumption levels, of persons deemed to be poor, without affecting signifi- cantly the determinants of that poverty (cf. Sherraden 1991; Oliver and Shapiro 1995; and Ford Foundation 2002). The asset-building approach builds the enduring resources indeed, the assets that individuals, organizations, or communities can acquire, develop, improve and transfer across genera- Foreword By Michael Conroy 2 A Place in the World A Place in the World 3 From significant support for joint forest management in India, where commu- nities become the guardians of state-owned forests in exchange for limited sustainable use rights, to programs for improving community management of the 70% of Mexicos forest lands that they control, and community involvement in the low-impact restoration of federal forest lands in the United States, community approaches to forestry have been a hallmark of Ford Foundation work in many countries. Ellsworths analysis in this paper illustrates that there is no single form of tenure, no particular pattern of property rights, that is uniquely associated with the most effective management of forest lands. In fact, underlying property ownership regimes have been changing continuously in most countries over long periods of time. Of particular importance is her assertion that the increasingly influential neoliberal property rights school of analysis over-emphasizes the virtues of property rights defined in terms of market trading. Effective markets for land are often nonexistent or flawed. Market-based approaches may create new risks to secure tenure, rather than alleviate them, and may lead to unfair and inefficient allocation of natural assets. Common property regimes provide some useful protection from those market forces, and they are valued because they lessen the risk of alienation of ownership by market forces. Many of the most important values associated with the ownership and stewardship of natural resources are nonmarket values, she notes. And some community-based property regimes are more capable than individualistic property rights regimes to capture the full set of values embodied in those resources. The values associated with tenure security and its importance to the alleviation of poverty in resource-dependent communities cannot be resolved, it would seem, by expert analysis, but perhaps as Ellsworth writes, only by each society through [its] own political means. Michael E. Conroy former Senior Program Officer FORD FOUNDATION NEW YORK: JUNE 2003 References: Boyce, James K. (2001). FromNatural Resources to Natural Assets, NewSolutions, Vol.11 (3), 266-278. Boyce, James K., and Manuel Pastor (2001). Building Natural Assets: NewStrategies for Poverty Reduction and Environmental Protection, Political Economy Research Institute and the Center for Popular Economics, University of Massachusetts Amherst. Available at www.umass.edu/peri/. Boyce, James K., and Barry G. Shelley (2003). Natural Assets: Democratizing Environmental Ownership, Washington: Island Press. Ford Foundation (2002). Sustainable Solutions: Building Assets for Empowerment and Sustainable Development. NewYork. Available at www.fordfound.org. Oliver, Melvin L. (1995). Black Wealth / White Wealth: A NewPerspective on Racial Inequality. NewYork, NY: Routledge. Sherraden, Michael (1991). Assets and the Poor. Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe, Inc. Market-based approaches may create new risks to tenure security, rather than alleviate them, and may lead to unfair and inefficient allocation of natural assets. 4 A Place in the World A Place in the World By Lynn Ellsworth The nature of tenure security and what should be done about it have long been debated in the overlapping worlds of academia and international development. The arguments, concepts, and assump- tions in these debates have influenced land policy around the world. They continue to do so and are now being freshly applied to the case of forests, where underlying ownership is often hotly disputed. This paper provides an overview and analysis of the literature on tenure security, paying special attention to arguments over what tenure security is and how it is related to the goal of helping communities build assets and improve their livelihoods especially communities living in and around natural forests. This literature review is a companion piece to Deeper Roots: Strengthening Community Tenure Security and Community Livelihoods, a paper based on case studies from India, Indonesia, Nepal, Philippines, South Africa, Tanzania, Bolivia, Brazil, and Colombia. 1 In this paper we first lay out the history of western notions of property rights giving special attention to natural forests. This history is important because there we find the original core concepts and arguments that still dominate theory and practice about tenure security. We briefly describe and compare four academic traditions, each of which has something to say about tenure security and livelihoods. These traditions or schools are: Property Rights, Agrarian Structure, Common Property, and Institutionalist. Each of these schools of thought focuses on a different facet of tenure security and in doing so has contributed to how property rights including those related to forests are seen in the real world. The Property Rights school underscores the value to an economy of having tradable property titles. Its analytical attention is focused on examining this value. The Agrarian Structure school draws our attention to troubling equity outcomes of an unrestricted trade in property titles. Someone of this tradition would urge us to consider the values that a middle class of asset owners, protected from tenure insecurity, bring to a democratic society. And in another analytical tradition, those in the Common Property school argue for the recognition and support of traditional, community-based property systems, many of which still operate in the worlds remaining natural forests. In that tradition, the commons is seen as a source of nontradable livelihoods for the poor. Moreover, the commons is seen as a thing that grants many people a place in the world. Finally, the Institutionalist school would urge us to pay attention to how the larger political economy is constantly reshaping property regimes and then providing tenure security or not to those people who claim a particular property right. None of these traditions is in fundamental disagreement with the others over the idea that various kinds of property or tenure rights ought to be secure, although they do often disagree profoundly on other points. What is important for this review is how they understand the very idea of security as well as how each tradition finds a different facet of security of tenure worthy of policy attention. Acknowledgements This paper was produced by Forest Trends at the invitation of the Ford Foundation. The author is grateful for substantial contributions from Andy White. Helpful commentary on earlier drafts was also received from Owen Lynch, Daniel Bromley, John Bruce, and Augusta Molnar. Danile Perrot-Matre and Chetan Agarwal also provided support for the case studies. A Place in the World 5 Definitions Property: the Oxford English Dictionary (OED) says property is a condition of being owned by or belong- ing to some person or persons, hence the fact of owning a thing. Or, it can be the right especially the exclusive right to the possession, use or dispos- al of anything. James Madison (cited in Ketcham, 1990) in a key argument added to this concept when he wrote: property embraces everything to which a man may attach a value and have a right, and which leaves to everyone else the like advantage hence a man may be said to have property in his rights. Madison was arguing that one of the duties of government is to protect not just the movable property of its citizens (as Locke had argued), but also their other nonmarket values such as a right to justice. This issue comes up again in this paper in the latter sections. Property regime: Institutionalist thinkers define a property regime as a social relationship among three parties. The three parties are the person with a right of any kind, the person who forbears from violating that right, and a third party (usually government or a court) who guaran- tees the right and obligation to forbear. Commons, Right of Common, Access rights: The commons is the undivided land belonging to the members of a local community as a wholeland held in joint occupation, not in the lords domain which later came to be waste- lands not already in the lords domain. (OED). The OED also notes that there is a use of the term specific to the legal profession, being the right of common, which refers to a use or access right to another mans land, examples being pasturing, collecting turf, fish or wood for fire or repairs. Common property: A scholarly distinction that refers to those commons that have managerial rules that regulate use of the commons (Bruce, 1998). Tenure: The word has its origins in the Latin word tenere meaning to hold or grasp. The OED says tenure is the action or fact of holding anything material or nonmaterial. The OED also allows for tenure to mean terms of holding or title. The former is typically employed in the academic literature. In a recent review paper, Devlin (2001) makes a useful distinction between tenure and property rights. She notes that when academic writers talk about property rights they tend to mean what William Blackstone did when he said property rights refer to full and despotic dominion over something, including the right to trade, buy, sell, mortgage, and use at will (Blackstone, cited in Thompson, 1991). However, when contemporary writers talk about tenure rights, Devlin points out that they are usually implicitly referring to a subset of that despotic dominion, which in most cases means limited use or access rights to a resource such as a forest, as well as the duration of those rights over time and across generations. This paper follows Devlins lead on this. Title: a legal right to the possession of land or property; the evidence of such right (OED). Open-access resource: a resource, the use of which is unregulated and unmanaged such that anyone may freely use it without distinction or hindrance. Public or State property: property owned by any level of government and distinct from a commons. Definitions of terms related to tenure have changed over time and continue to change. And usage varies widely among academic disciplines. Moreover, legal usage is frequently at variance with dictionary definitions and popular use. This situation makes picking out a definition for some terms a diplomatic task. 6 A Place in the World Prior to and with the rise of the seigniorial systemin the feudal era, much of Europe had vast tracts of dense forests inhabited by all manner of bark-strippers, hunters, collectors of forest products, charcoal-burners, blacksmiths, wood-ash dealers, bandits and religious hermits all living at the margins of the communitys and lords powers. Forest use was intense and unregulated (Bloch, p. 8), very much like an open-access resource. In fact, the great forests of the early middle ages were not clearly under the reign of the manorial system, being isolated from communal life (Bloch, p. 8). Both lord and peasant also hunted and grazed cattle, pigs, and horses in the forests, so much so that a common unit of measurement of a forest was how many pigs it might sustain (Bloch, p. 7). From 1050 onwards, and intensifying in the late 12th to the end of the 13th century, enterprising lords throughout Europe initiated a period of large-scale forest clearances (assarts). New manors and villages were established relentlessly in what had once been forest and marsh. Forests soon came to be islands in a sea of agrarian land use. Many villages opposed forest clearances accustomed as they were to benefit from the grazing or the free enjoyment of the forests wealth. So it was often necessary to sue them [the peasants], or buy them off, especially where they had the support of some local lord who shared their interest in forest privileges. The archives are full of records relating to litigation of this kind. (Bloch, p. 18). Some of those disputes were solved with violence against the peasantry. Villages opposing a forest clearance could be and were razed. In the specific case of England, there is some evidence that prior to the Norman conquest in 1066, local lords tried to claim hunting rights in some forests. There was even an office of forest warden. But as a conqueror, William took these minor Anglo-Saxon traditions to an entirely new level of property rights for the crown. By right of conquest, he declared about a third of England as royal forest for his use. It was called New Forest. His seizure meant that he alone could have the income from all forest products in New Forest. It is useful to recall that the English forests were inhabited with villages as well as the usual forest inhabitants noted above. In fact, only about a third of the land in question was actually forested in the popular sense of the term. Many areas of it might be better described as thinly forested grazing lands and heath. Williams act created a howl of popular outrage and generated legends such as Robin Hood and The Tale of Gamelyn. The seizure was thought unjust: rich men bemoaned it and poor men shuddered at it (Anglo-Saxon Chronicles cited in Rampey, 2001). Moreover, William created an entirely new Forest Law outside the common law that prohibited the locals from cultivating land or using the forests products. The Forest Law was administered by a frequently corrupt army of forest officials answerable only to the king (Rampey, 2001). Their role was to extract fines and collect taxes, providing a perpetual source of revenue for the Crown. Over time, commoners wrested back from their kings various rights of common to use New Forest products such as the common of mast, marl, pasture, and turbary. Custom, as opposed to right of common also allowed commoners to cut fern and gorse and raise bees in New Forest. But to this day, New Forest remains Crown property (Rampey, 2001; Cooper, 2001). Feudal Forests and Britains New Forest of William the Conqueror Custom, as opposed to right of common, also allowed commoners to cut fern and gorse and raise bees in New Forest. Custom, as opposed to right of common, also allowed commoners to cut fern and gorse and raise bees in New Forest. History of the Concept of Tenure Security History of the Concept of Tenure Security Security of tenure is an idea that is embedded in grand philosophical, political and economic theories and beliefs about how our contemporary society came to be. Because these theories and beliefs concern the nature of government, justice, and economic systems, they are inherently controversial. So a bit of history is necessary to help us gain a perspective above the fray of argument. In this section, we see that most of the western concepts related to tenure security originated in an historical discussion about how Britain, Europe, and Russia were transformed away from feudalism. Property rights and tenure security played a role in that transformation, although the nature of their role remains contested. Much of feudal Europe was characterized by variations on the manor or seigniorial system of organizing agrarian life. It featured a set of mutual obligations and duties between lord and the various classes of nonlord. 1 Although enlightenment philosophers liked to attack feudalism from a political rights point of view, not all the mutual duties and obligations were exploitative. The manorial system arose after the fall of the Roman Empire in a lengthy melding of local and Roman custom with Germanic tribal traditions at a time when people felt a great need for physical security. 2 The manorial system solved both a security and an economic problem of organization so well, it spread with the Frankish conquests into northern Italy, Spain, and later into the Slavic territories. The Normans took it into England in 1066. And from England, feudalism spread to Scotland and to Ireland [CDE/EB]. In the manor, land was not traded to outsiders, but held by the lord of the manor, who might be a king, an ecclesiastic, a baron, or more often, a much lesser noble. The peasants resident in a manor cultivated land in one of many local variations of the open-field system. Land was divided into strips and planted under collective management rules. Each peasant might have three strips: one for winter crops, one for summer crops, and a third for fallow. Land was sometimes traded among members of a manor, and in some places [as in parts of Russia], land was redistributed every few years using demographic criteria [White 1996, Bloch 1966]. The manors territory had several parts, each under different man- agement and ruled by different ideas about property. For example, the demesne was the land of the lord for his own immediate use. The arable bits of it were often mixed in pell-mell (with shifting boundaries) with the arable land reserved for the peasantry. There was also meadowland (typically also held in common for additional pasturing of animals) woodland, and waste. The local woodlands and fishponds usually belonged to the lord, although there was again significant variation on this. Wastes were typically unused bits of land such as swamps, gullies, and distant forest. If fought over, they were property of the lord by virtue of his power, but this was not everywhere the case. Wastes were usually managed as an open-access resource and to some observers they got lumped in conceptually with the commons. Last, fallow land used for pasture could also be referred to as the common [Bloch, 1966]. The peasant typically owed labor service, a share of the crop, and military service to his lord. In turn, the lord owed the peasant military and legal protection. Most important for this paper, the lord could not take away the land the principal means of livelihood from the peasant. Moreover, in times of poor harvest important lords were to use their coin and credit to prevent starvation (CDE/EB). In addition, there was often a very large set of locally varied and sometimes codified use rights to the different parts of a manors territory that meant peasants could and did supplement their livelihoods by collecting timber and A Place in the World 7 other resources form the lords forests, the commons, and the wastes. In some places, villages were even incorporated and had by laws under which the reciprocal rights and duties of lord and peasant were laid out. Land transactions, for example, might take place in a court of tradition rather than in the lords courts as long as outsiders to the manor were not involved. It is also important that unfree peasants could convert their in-kind service obligations to the lord for fixed rents. Eventually, they could buy their freedom as well. The manor also regulated exchange with markets, each manor acting (in a very rough analogy) like a shareholding corporation, producing various products, some of which were consumed locally, some of which were exchanged. This deal between lord and peasant gave each person a geographic place in the world that could not easily be denied. It was a place that 8 A Place in the World could be passed on to children, although the land itself was not very tradable. This deal granted a secure place in the world. It marked the early meaning of security of tenure. For a feudal peasant, it meant that the means of life a livelihood in a specific place in the world would be granted him in exchange for predictable service to a specific person. Not all peasants were unhappy with that particular feudal arrangement (e.g., in Vende in France prior to the French Revolution). After the 12th century the feudal system and the deal for a place in the world slowly began to fall apart. In Britain, for example, the manorial and open-field systems were incrementally undermined by both political and market forces from the tenth century onward. Then, in the late 18th century in the name of productive efficiency, those forces culminated in violent physical and legal attacks by that countrys powerful class upon the weak in the remnant commonages and open fields. That period featured the enclosing of unfenced open fields and commons. This created immense levels of injustice and suffering. A powerless, unenfranchised peasantry lost its last bit of commonages and many of its economic rights of common as England entered the late mercantile and capitalist eras (CDE/EB, 2001]. The peasants lost their place in the world. And they wandered. Many ended up working in cities or emigrating. Debate among historians on the causes and benefits of these enclosures is by no means resolved. The nature of the falling apart of the feudal system and the exact how of it are still debated by historians, especially when it comes to figuring out the balance of market and nonmarket forces that were brought to bear to untie people from their feudal rights and place in the world. Many scholars now focus on how tenure rights to land moved from being secure and uncontested to insecure and contested. 3 The idea was that things that were once nonmarket and not tradable (your right to be in a geographic place) became tradable in marketplaces, In feudal Europe peasants could supplement their livelihoods by collecting timber from the lords forests. A Place in the World 9 creating new winners and losers in the larger society. Some scholars study how things that could not be transformed into marketable commodities were simply discarded by society, often after lengthy political battles and economic processes. Some scholars even say that the creation of tradable property rights in fenced plots of land (which may or may not include forested land) was representative of a critical sea change that took place in the industrializing worlds notion of property rights. And a few people even argue that tradable title in land was the single most important change that allowed capitalism to flourish as it did [North and Thomas, 1977]. That is a bit extreme, and it is important to note that this argument has usually been made without reference to accepted historical fact. But since the argument gets a lot of popular press, it is important to note that many historians and sociologists say that granting property rights such an elevated status in history grossly oversimplifies the record and neglects the role of a dozen other important factors from technology to the use of force to the very deliberate efforts of those in power to create, structure, and nurture into existence the market economy we know today [Polanyi, 1944]. The rise of the environmental movement in Europe and the United States has added a new dimension to this debate that is espe- cially relevant in this paper. While some of natures values can be partly commodified and traded using Western-style individual property rights regimes such as carbon or watershed services many values such as a place in the world or landscape beauty cannot be so traded. Nor can religious or cultural values associated with a particular place. This raises a question: can people have rights in values that arent traded or cant be completely traded? James Madison (see defi- nitions of property on page 5) said we do have rights to such values justice for example. And environmentalists have inspired themselves from him. They argue that nonmarketable and intergenerational values originating in nature are real and need to be protected. They say that conventional market-based solutions to preserving these values while sometimes useful will not preserve enough of them. They believe that in order to protect more of those values, ownership of some of natures nonmarketable values must accrue to government or to local communities, to be held in trust for the future. These debates are relevant outside the world of historians of Europe and that of the environmental community. In many developing countries and in the formerly communist countries, all kinds of widely varying community property rights systems can still be found. Many survived colonial and communist attempts to remove them as well as the steady pressure of market and demographic pressures. 4 Some scholars insist that these community-based property regimes are an obstacle to market development and productive efficiency. For them, the job of developers in those countries is to create a full Western-style set of property rights in all things, complete with land administration systems, titles, and deed registries. While nobody disputes the power of tradable title property regimes to unleash entrepreneurial energy, we History of the Concept of Tenure Security As England entered the late mercantile and capitalist eras, a powerless, unenfranchised peasantry lost its last bit of commonages and many of its economic rights of common. The peasants lost their place in the world. 10 A Place in the World shall see in this paper that there are good arguments for developing new forms of modern property rights that are gentler to and more inclusive of the worlds remaining community-based property rights systems, systems which after all provide many nonmarket advantages to those who are using them [Polanyi, 1944; Moore, 1944]. At the heart of all of these historical views and debates about property rights is a near-universal notion that a good property rights regime ought to grant people something called security of tenure. We have already seen that a feudal notion of what that phrase means is a place in the world. But today, it turns out that there is considerable variation among contemporary scholars about what security of tenure really means in the nonfeudal world. There is argument about who should benefit from tenure security, what its virtues are to a society, how to achieve it in the policy arena, and the role it plays in relating communities to markets and livelihoods. The next section reviews those debates, roughly classifying the great many academic ideas on the subject into four traditions or schools of thought based on the aspect of security of tenure that is thought to be important for policy making. Security of Tenure and the Property Rights School CONCEPTS AND ARGUMENTS The Property Rights School is an old one in academia. 5 When members of this school talk about property rights they mean individual, private, tradable titles in whatever resource is at hand. They believe that such titles are an indispensable precondition to economic growth and development and the cause of the prosperity of western countries. Moreover, property systems anchored in individual, tradable titles are (in their view) the best option around for managing property of all kinds because they encourage efficiency in producing things. 6 We will see later that the idea of efficiency itself is contested by many scholars with a different analytical vision of how the world works. Members of the Property Rights school are often evolutionists who think that as soon as a population grows, a resource will get scarce and then everyone will spontaneously agree to create a private property system that honors individualized tradable title. 7 At the same time, and in a bit of contradiction to the evolutionary character of much of their thinking, members of this school also say that governments in developing countries should do everything possible to hasten, assist, and nurture the creation of tradable private property rights in resources. 8 Moreover, whatever cant be individualized in their view should become property of the State. Property Rights people cite a famous story of psychological and philosophical virtue to recruit people into their school, a story based in the political economy of Jeremy Bentham and David Ricardo. 9 To make a complex story short, it goes as follows: if everything is marked up with an individual title, the rare combination of a marketplace in proximity to security of tenure over things will spontaneously unleash pent-up entrepreneurial energy (or greed to use Benthams word). Moreover, if everyone freely trades things based on individual comparative advantage, all will end up better off than they were before trading. And last but not least, the system of trading has the desirable and unex- pected result that everyone will find a place in the world that leads to his or her own most productive, efficient use to society at large. Property Rights scholars of this school go even further to say that even if two people make a trade and one loses out on the deal, the world is still a better place provided the winner has the potential to compensate the loser. This notion is called Pareto Optimality. It should also be noted that winners in this analytical framework are A Place in the World 11 In most countries with an endowment of the worlds remaining natural forests, the government claims most or all the forests as publicly owned. In many cases they are ignoring local claims to the forest. Forests in fact are subject to multiple, overlapping claims to their resources. Some of the people making ownership claims are not even local residents. This complex situation means that communities living in and around natural forests often have no security of tenure over the asset they may even think of as their own. This creates social justice problems in many parts of the world, not just for indigenous and traditional forest peoples, but also for many rural communities who are outraged to realize that their forest commons has been claimed by the government. Why is state ownership so common? The first explanation is simply the bald fact that state property in many countries is a relic of monarchic, colonial, or communist times. And, forest management was often the last thing to get localized during the democratic revolutions of Europe. Hence it got exported during the colonial period. In developing countries the era of nationalism and the move to independence often did not change this colonial heritage in forest property rights. A second reason often cited for state ownership of forests is that of market failure. This merits some explanation. Many economists adhere to the notion that when goods are not completely privatized and put into individual tradable title, the market can underproduce the good. Forests, for example, filter water, prevent erosion, provide landscape beauty, and conserve biodiversity. Unless these things or functions can be commoditized, priced, and actively traded, underproduction will result, and government ought to step in. Supporters of this theory are also convinced that government is the sole entity capable of providing these environmental services. The implication is that the rights of communities living in and around forests can be disregarded in the broader public interest. Some people of this view also argue that com- munities cannot themselves produce public good values so government must be the forest manager. There are practical problems with these market failure arguments for state ownership of forests. The first problem is that in the real world (as opposed to the world of scholarly theorizing), government ownership doesnt really solve the problem of underproduction of nontimber forest values such as biodiversity or carbon. In fact, the track record of governments in managing natural forests for values other than timber is lamentable. Those not familiar with forestry should understand that governments everywhere typically contract out forests to timber companies in a system of notoriously ill-managed concession contracts. These contracts focus almost entirely on timber extraction. Many people would argue that government ownership of forests in such cases is really about who gets to profit from the timber, and not about addressing market failure or providing more environmental services for the broad public interest. The second practical problem with the market failure justification for state ownership is that it ignores the social justice claims of forest-dependent communities. This used to be acceptable. But in a democratizing world, community claims to forest ownership are increasingly seen as legitimate however troubling they may be because of the ethnic character of the claim or the lack of interest communities sometimes show in environmental stewardship. Important events are happening around the world with the rise of property rights claims over their forests by communities: their rights are in fact being recognized, although with significant limits. Tenure Security and the Case of Natural Forests 12 A Place in the World thought to be more energetic and efficient than losers, because the trading game is supposed to reward them. In a famous variation on this story, some Property Rights people argue that when we dont attach tradable title to something, we will all race each other to grab it before the other one gets it [Hardin, 1968]. They say that in the ensuing free-for-all we will totally destroy the actual resource. Property Rights theorists think the only way we can save ourselves from such tragedy is to set up private property and individualized tradable title. This was once called (but is no longer) the tragedy of the commons hypothesis. In sum, the Property Rights story has many philosophical and political assumptions that are important to recognize. 10 These are: Trading is always voluntary and never happens at sword point (as opposed to the case of the New Forest in the box on page 6). The ultimate goal of society and the property rights system is to produce ever more commodities. Uneven distribution of commodities among people doesnt matter, as long as those who win through the trading game have the potential to compensate the losers, although they dont actually have to do so for the trading game to be the best one for a society. Banks already exist and have a rule that they will use the title 11 to the land only as collateral for credit. No other system of collateral or credit is possible or even imagined in this story. Trading costs are the same for everyone. Everyone also has perfect information about everything, and no deals are made through lying, cheating, violence, or fraud. Laziness and inefficiency should be punished by the tradable title system and efficiency rewarded by it. EVIDENCE The Property Rights story may appear logical enough in the U.S. and in Europe, where it took 1,000 years of history to embed individualized tradable title of property into our legal system. But outside those countries, the belief that it has produced optimal outcomes appears wrong. This is because there are so many community-based property regimes with some vitality left in them and plenty of people who still want them to exist. For this reason, critics of the Property Rights school ask if the theory has any empirical basis. In trying to respond to this challenge, Property Rights theorists have had to vastly over- simplify matters in order to measure particular aspects of their theory. Hypotheses they try to measure are usually statements like: tradable titles in land create more output. tenure security means more labor and loan activity There are still many community- based property regimes with some vitality left in them. A Place in the World 13 (and hence by proxy more output). tradable titles mean everyone is better off. All of these equations are hard to support in a definitive, once-and- for-all way using real-world data, so theorists tend to rely on vague correlations that are not inconsistent with their original story. In one influential review paper of the evidence for the Property Rights story, the author [Deininger, 1999] cites a wide range of data from different countries in the world (see the box on page 15) to conclude: there is broad agreement that secure individual land rights will increase incentives to undertake productivity-enhancing land-related invest- ments and that establishment of such rights would constitute a clear Pareto improvement [Deininger, 1999, p. 35]. The claim to broad agreement on this point may be overreaching. For some, the empirical work to date has simply been difficult, flawed, or inconclusive (see Place and Otsuka, forthcoming). Others interpret the data differently. For example, one review of the empirical evidence on tenure at the FAO (by someone who is not a member of the Property Rights school) summarized the problems with the data on tenure security by concluding: the putative relationship between security provided by a modern land title and capital investment in land has simply not been established with sufficient precision to allow any explanatory value confronted with conflicting evidence [Riddell, 2000 p. 6]. And another survey of the South Asian evidence about property rights concluded that: strong evidence linking [tradable property] rights to production and investment is scarce for South Asia despite significant regional variation within the subcontinent [Faruqee and Carey, 1997 p. 1]. A related problem in the empirical literature is the tendency to confuse correlations with causality and statistical significance with real-world significance. 12 And as Platteau [2000] points out, no matter what the shaky data actually says about the individualized private title is best thesis, it can almost never support conclusive policy pathways, given the institutional complexities of so many countries whose property regimes outsiders so want to change. 13 The fact is that the empirical evidence for the virtues and mechanics of the founding story of the Property Rights school is mixed for most parts of the world that dont share the legal history of Europe and the United States. Some data support the story. Some dont. And contradictory data can be found in the same place in different times. For example, in Kenya a tradable title system looked positive when it was first instituted, but in the long run, it didnt [see Bruce et al. 1994]. Some empirical studies also refer to data that can support multiple stories and theories [e.g., the case of Gavian and Fafchamps, 1996 or Besley, 1995]. On the tragedy of the commons hypothesis, the empirical work is more straightforward. There, scholars have been obliged to make a distinction between managed commons and open-access resources. It turns out that the prediction of tragedy may be reasonably accurate only for open-access resources, not for managed commons. The discussion of Evidence Some Property Rights people argue that when we dont attach tradable title to a resource, we will all race each other to grab it before the other one gets it. 14 A Place in the World the work of the Common Property school elsewhere in this paper elaborates on this point. POLICY VIEWS It is important to see that tenure security is desirable to members of the Property Rights school because it is a means to the larger goal of reallocating assets so as to reward the efficient and penalize the inefficient. From a policy point of view, the Property Rights school reduces security of tenure to the idea of a paper title that can be traded or mortgaged in densely operating land markets. And the policy implication is that wed all do best by setting up privatized, individualized titling systems for whatever resource is at hand. Bringing that argument to forests, Property Rights theorists think that forests and land are meant to be traded into their most efficient use rather than serve as places where nonmarket values are produced. In fact, nonmarket values of land and forests have no place in this worldview: they are invisible or relegated to the nebulous class of things called externalities, all of which can be sacrificed for the greater good of productive efficiency. Thus, forests are assets as long as their underlying values can be traded. Nontraded values of forests are not an asset class to members of this school. Security of Tenure in the Agrarian Structure School CONCEPTS AND ARGUMENTS The Agrarian Structure school is a useful way to categorize an eclectic group of economic theorists, development policy analysts, and social justice activists who agree with most of the story that the Property Rights people tell, but who part ways on the idea that tradable title leads to a universal or optimal result, either from the point of view of productivity or of social values. 14 Researchers and activists working within this tradition see benefits for society at large in the existence of a middle class of small farmers, artisans, or business people, especially when the majority of its citizens are rural and engaged in farm work. Followers of this school look at property rights and ask: what kind of agrarian structure do we want to see and what kind of tenure security can we arrange to favor that structure? Note that Agrarian Structure here refers to the distribution of farm size (or other resource-based assets like forests or commons) among farmers. 15 In this view, tradable title can in some circumstances protect striving small farmers from predatory governments and corporations. This is because title can be fought for with a piece of paper in courts of law. Nonetheless, those of this tradition argue that tradable title is not automatically the small guys best friend: it can provide as much The Property Rights school tends to overlook the nontradable values of forests. A Place in the World 15 insecurity of tenure as security. This is because tradable title easily exposes the small guy to market forces without subsidy, aid, or legal protection from natural disaster. For example, distress or forced sales of farms in times of family crisis or bad weather can send such otherwise efficient farmers out into the streets without a home. Agrarian Structure analysts say that such sales have nothing to do with effi- ciency, and that when it comes to land (or forests), this kind of trading in general will not necessarily lead to the most efficient people winning, especially since luck and deviousness often play a big role in cementing land sales. Members of this school also point to the many places in the world where tradable title led to perverse accumulation of land by the wealthy few: a corporation, a hacienda owner, or an absentee landlord. This is called costly inequality [Carter, 2000]. It is so named because if you accept a highly unequal agrarian order, you lose out on all the efficiency that a middle class of farmers generates. This group of scholars sees security of tenure as something beyond title. It is more the political will to put into place the means to assure the striving poor and middle class community members some degree of organized protection from unfettered market forces. To shore up their argument, they point to data that show that wealthy landowners tend to be less efficient per hectare or per person than small farmers. A good number of scholars with a Jeffersonian frame of mind also fit within this Agrarian Structure tradition. To them, the costs of inequality are not just about losses in efficiency. They subscribe to a philosophical view that ownership of resources for communities has plenty of noneconomic virtues that we need as a society. These people cite studies that show how United States homeowners tend to be more civically involved, and that their children are less likely to drop out of Is There Empirical Evidence for the Theory of the Property Rights School? The Property Rights school does have some data in developing countries to back up its views, but they are hardly definitive. Much of these data were recently reviewed by a supporter of that school (Deininger 1999) and merit some attention. The author of the review cites as evidence for the virtues of tradable title the massive productivity leaps in China that took place recently after reforms allowed for individual production on collective land. That link between an individualized title system and economic virtue is not universally held. For example, one scholar of China points out that equally impressive gains in productivity occurred when China first went communist and collectivized its assets, a fact suggesting that it might be the size and locally perceived desirability of the institutional change rather than the type of institutional change that influences such productivity leaps (Sicular, 2000). The same review also cites a study from a region in Ghana where faint evidence exists for part of the Property Rights story. That study featured three sites, but only one clearly supported the notion that secure tenure increases labor investments in agriculture, while many African studies not referenced support an opposite viewpoint. Other cases cited to support elements of the Property Rights theory can be found in the Amazon, Niger, Paraguay, and in Thailand. Yet, a closer look at these data shows that the Property Rights people may not be on solid ground, except perhaps for their research in Thailand. For example, in the Niger study, it turns out that the data there merely suggested that tenure security did somehow matter to farmers, a point nobody would contest (Gavian and Fafchamps, 1996). They do not, however, prove the underlying story of the Property Rights school. And in Paraguay, all the researcher found was that some farmers got more credit if they had title, but then again, credit access was unevenly distributed (Carter and Olinto, 1996), which was the main point of that bit of research. 16 A Place in the World school or be arrested [Rossi and Weber, 1995]. This strand of thinking about asset ownership as the basis of democracy goes back to Thomas Jefferson and to an earlier British political philosophy that owning land gave you a stake in the country or a place in the world that the landless could not understand. Some legal scholars of this school would go further to suggest that widely diffused individual property rights insulate political minorities from oppression by the rich and powerful and from the whims of leg- islatures and government agencies that too often serve only the needs of the powerful [McEvoy, 1998 in Jacobs, 1998, and citing Reich, 1964 and Michelman 1981]. 16 POLICY VIEWS In the international arena, advocates of the Agrarian Structure view criticize World Bank-promoted market-assisted land reforms, saying such reforms are too slow and fail at social justice goals. People working in the Agrarian Structure school advocate quicker and more compre- hensive reforms [de Janvry et al., 2001]. Yet, given the great many implementation failures of otherwise well-intentioned land reforms in Latin America and in parts of Asia, this group now debates how to do reform right in places like Zimbabwe, South Africa and Brazil where equalizing land reform remains a major social and political problem. Scholars here admit to a good body of problematic evidence that says that land reforms are often hard to gain political support for and end up with unpredictable, perverse outcomes that nobody wanted. This is because reforms are time consuming, difficult to do fairly, and easily undermined by incompetence, inefficiency, corruption, political conservativism, not to mention the many legal ways that the powerful have to halt the erosion of their power. 17 Nonetheless, in the policy arena members of the Agrarian Structure school continue to advocate land reform. 18 They also support limits on the tradability of titles or on the actual nature of property rights (as in Nepals land reforms of the early 1960s). These limits are so that costly inequality doesnt recreate itself over time as the wrong people buy and sell title. Note that these trading limits can be about use, stewardship of the underlying resource, or size of holdings. Agrarian Structure people also suggest that governments should provide an appropriate mix of subsidies and credit systems to support or favor the emergence of the middle resource owner. 19 In this analytical vision, markets are recognized as valuable things which add value but also things that punish and reward unfairly. Markets are sources of tenure insecurity. The market makes for no guarantee that people can hang on to their assets and livelihood and at the same time supply the world with something other than their own free wage labor (which it may not even want). Hence, this analytical tradition advocates control and regulation of markets to benefit asset ownership among a specific class of people. Regulation is needed to provide tenure security, not just paper titles. Tenure Security and Common Property CONCEPTS AND ARGUMENTS A third academic and activist school has taken up the cause of a differ- ent type of property relationship, that of the commons. We can call this the Common Property school and by it mean that group of scholars influenced by the research emerging from members of the International Association for the Study of Common Property. Members of this school do not argue with the Property Rights theorists on the notion that tradable title can catalyze entrepreneurial energy or with Jeffersonian scholars on the dangers to a democracy of A Place in the World 17 over-concentrated property ownership. Rather, Common Property advocates object to the crude and simplistic portrayal of nonindi- vidualized common resources as things that are inevitably destroyed unless they are controlled by a system of individualized, tradable property titles. 20 They say it is essential to make a distinction between unmanaged, open-access resources and managed common property. This group of scholars points out that the common resources of the world provide emergency and back-up livelihoods for the poor and hence need not all be privatized, lest like in England, the poor who depend on them end up without a place in the world, strangers in their own land [Thompson, 1991, p. 184]. And we are warned not to demonize the poor who depend on commons, as happened in England. Remember that there, the poor who survived in the world by virtue of their access to the commons had to be deemed vile and lazy by the powerful, so they could be uprooted and turned into rolling stones, with no direction home. And the poor had no say in the matter, since they could not vote and were not the policymakers and legislators of the day. As one famous ideologue of enclosing the commons (Vancouver) said: The appropriation of forests would be the means of producing a number of useful hands for agricultural employment by gradually cutting up and annihilating that nest and conservatory of sloth, idleness, and misery, which is uniformly to be witnessed in the vicinity of all commons, wastelands, and forest. [Vancouver, cited in Thompson [1991]. And indeed, Vancouver got his way without much trouble. The ancient common lands of England, Scotland and Wales vanished, and in the case of Scotland, the forests vanished with them. Proponents of the commons have used both rational choice logic models and empirical studies to make their case. 21 Their key arguments are listed in the box on page 19. Common Property scholars see virtues in common property that the Property Rights theorists dont. 22 These are: The commons supports a physical and cultural space that strengthens social linkages among people across time something that marketplace transactions alone cannot do. A commons can be the more efficient way to manage a resource, given physical attributes that can inhibit the use of full tradable title. A commons may be the only fair, practical or humane way to manage some resources, in the sense that leaving a common property regime unchanged often comes with fewer political and economic negatives than does changing it to a system of tradable individual titles. A commons often provides access to survival resources (mushrooms, dead wood, drought-tolerant plants, game, etc) for otherwise unpropertied people in search of a livelihood when other means have failed. The commons gives people a place in the world they might not otherwise have and thus gives them some small measure Tenure Security and Common Property The poor who survived in the world by virtue of their access to the commons had to be deemed vile and lazy by the powerful, so they could be uprooted and turned into rolling stones, with no direction home. 18 A Place in the World of personal choice and flexibility in fixing their fate and in launching themselves into the wider world. The people affected are very often the poor and the marginalized, the very people whom organizations of economic development aim to help. Common property regimes tend to allocate many resources among many stakeholders under local concepts of fairness, using a combination of power, history, custom, and other non-market mechanisms [Swallow, 1997 and 2000]. For example, a forest even though it is worth a lot in timber may be allocated to the production of fallow, mushrooms, and spring water because the rights and needs of nontimber users are considered as important as those who would cut the timber and sell it. A local society that does this is weighing the value of the things inside the commons differently from the output-oriented and profit-maximizing society of the Property Rights world. Common property advocates agree with Property Rights people that security of tenure is important. But they argue fiercely that tradable, individualized title is hardly needed to get most of the benefits attributed to tradable title systems. Under this view, membership in a group that has a secure claim is an equally viable way of obtaining tenure security. They also point out that title to land is not the only thing that works as collateral, as informal lending markets worldwide show and as successes like Bangladeshs Grameen Bank illustrate. The fact is that in many common property regimes in the world individuals have invested in improvements even though they didnt have tradable title to their resource. EVIDENCE AND POLICY VIEWS Critics of the commons ask: how resilient are common property sys- tems in the face of market forces and population growth? And how easy is it to come up with robust management rules for the underlying natural resource? If such regimes are not resilient, then Common Property advocates might well be accused of being just as utopian as the Property Rights school. Unfortunately the data on the robustness of the common property regimes in the world can be used to support many sides of the question. In some areas, the commons has been under political attack and demographic pressure, but the commons survives. In others, a commons didnt survive at all, or it changed over time to adapt to new circumstances. In yet other places, entirely new common property rules have been built. 23 For example, in Quintana Roo, Mexico, [Bray, 2000] a commons is being rebuilt successfully, The Agrarian Structure school generally supports land reform, but admits it can lead to perverse outcomes. A Place in the World 19 while in the case of the rubber tappers groups in Rondnia, Brazil, success of a new commons is not so clear [Rosendo, 2000]. Perplexed by the range of outcomes in managing any given com- mons, one group sympathetic to the commons has tried to find ways to predict what kind of property regime is best for what resource and when. Scholars interested in making such determinations try to create predictor variables, also referred to as design principles, 24 with the intention of giving people prescriptive policy advice on how to create a commons. These variables characterize the resource and the group trying to manage it. For example, divisibility is supposed important for the resource while group size and heterogeneity are supposed to be crucial design variables for the managing group. This particular academic project has so far met with mixed results. On the one hand it allows better and more precise description of specific commons situations. On the other, it appears that there are plenty of commons that have turned out all right in defiance of the design principles and predictor variables. This has led some to suggest that the design principles are not very useful [Stein, 2001]. A compromise view is that the design principles are just ways to reckon the forces for and against you when your agenda is either to create or revive a specific common property regime. If you have a lot of the principles on your side, your chances of winning the battle and setting up something sustainable are good. But if you dont, it still doesnt mean you cant win. Its just that the battle may be tough and long. Common Property advocates point out that imposing individualized tradable title systems can make matters worse in terms of efficiency and equity, especially where there is communal management of a resource already in place. They urge government to find ways to support these property systems. For example, some are actively seeking legislation to Key Arguments of the Common Property Advocates a) There are more property rights choices in the world than those described by the Property Rights school, from both a theoretical and an empirical point of view. In fact the real world harbors things that might loosely be classified as private property, state property, common property, or open-access resources, as well as property that combines characteristics of these types of property. b) A resource that has no owners and no rules about its management should be considered an open-access resource. Society can decide to leave some resources as open-access if it wants. c) A commons is often held under customary rights with historical claims, but a commons can also be created from scratch. Many can be found in urban areas. They are by no means archaic. d) Common property has a history, logic, and utility that makes it valuable today, even to urban societies. e) The physical characteristics of some resources (lakes, watersheds, oceans, rivers, etc.) can lend themselves to a common property ownership, although this turns out to be highly variable in the real world. What is a commons in one place can be private elsewhere, and what is state-owned in one place can be open-access elsewhere, and so on. f) Some commons are managed such that the underlying physical resource is sustained across generations, although not invariably so. g) Individual and state title to a resource has very often led to degradation of the resource or to hoarding of the resource. Efficient outcomes are not guaranteed by individual or state title. This means that such types of property regimes are not inherently superior to a commons in terms of the underlying sustainability of the resource. 20 A Place in the World support common property regimes and to recognize the rights of communities rather than individuals to own the forest they use and manage. 25 Common Property advocates also criticize the Property Rights theorists for attempts to dismember commons around the world, and they question the lack of the same supporting infrastructure (policies, courts, laws, credit, technical assistance) that is usually granted to defending individually held private property [Bromley, 1989 and 2000]. And instead of dismembering a commons, some members of this group urge that property that is now in public or government hands be passed back to communities where it can be managed as newly created local commons. 26 In sum, the Common Property framework emphasizes that the commons provides poorer members of a community with last-resort livelihoods as well as security of tenure in the form of a place in the world. The unique contribution of this school to the security of tenure discussion is that security is not necessarily achieved only through formal titling systems, but can be amply granted within the many community-based property regimes that still exist throughout the world. Institutionalists CONCEPTS AND ARGUMENTS The Institutionalist school features a multidisciplinary method of analysis that looks under the hood of assumptions and definitions other schools take for granted. In assessing resources and property regimes, one author explains the Institutionalist approach as follows: An alternative perspective starts from the politics of resource access and control among diverse social actors, and regards processes of environmental change as the outcome of negotiation or contesta- tion between social actors who may have very different priorities in natural resource use and management. [Mearns, 2001, p.1] Common Property advocates may share that view, and Institutionalists often sympathize with Common Property ideas. What separates the Institutionalists from the other schools is a research agenda that pays more attention to how society decides that something is either commons, state property, private property, open-access resource or some combination of the four property types. In another key difference, Institutionalists point out (persuasively) that no one type of property is either ideal, inevitable, best, most effi- cient, or intrinsically linked to the physical nature of the group, culture, or resource. They also argue that political power and the distribution of resource endowments at any point in time is more important than prop- erty type in determining who gets security of tenure and who doesnt. 27 To Institutionalists, property regimes are constantly evolving to reflect the endless negotiations and adjustments of a society whose values change over time, as does the relative power of different groups in society. 28 Of course the state of markets matters too, and Institutionalists delight in seeing how changing economic situations affect machinations over property rights. They observe that previ- ously uninteresting resources can suddenly become valuable due to changing technologies and market conditions, thus leading to all kinds of claim-making over who owns it. As to predicting outcomes of all that contestation, Institutionalists say that an algebraic theory cant predict it: human creativity as well as luck, the weather, and warfare will all matter. 29 Institutionalists also see property rights as a social relationship among three parties (see definitions on page 5). In their view, many variables affect property regimes: historical power, demographics, A Place in the World 21 culture, the organization of society, the associated value system, relative prices, and the legal regime. All of these interact to explain how the underlying resource (forests, land, commodities) gets managed at any particular time. One of the members of the school gave the following summary as an Institutionalist take on property and tenure: Property regimes after all are human artifacts reflecting instru- mental origins they take on their special character by virtue of col- lective perceptions regarding what is scarce (and hence possibly worth protecting with rights) and what is valuable (and hence certainly worth protecting with rights). Property is a social instrument and particular property regimes are chosen for particular purposes New institu- tional arrangements are continually established to define the property regimes over land and related natural resources whether the regime be one we would call state property, private individual property, or one of common property. These institutional arrangements locate one indi- vidual vis--vis others both within a group (if there is one) and with individuals outside of the group [Bromley, 2000]. The notion that property regimes locate individuals toward others is especially important. This is in fact a key strand of legal theory dating back to feudal times, when specific kinds of property were thought to give people (various classes of peasant, cottager, knight, and lord) a specific place in an ordered society [Rose, 1994]. This idea is at the heart of the place in the world promoted by the Common Property people. Institutionalists say that tradable title is only part of tenure security. The larger issue they ask is: how defensible is any kind of property claim (tradable or not) in the face of the predations of more powerful people? History and current politics in any country provide us with abundant cases of how easy it is for the state to overturn claims that were once recognized as secure if someone wants to grab a resource that might be securely owned by someone else. For example, a gov- ernment can systematically undermine a commons regime to favor logging companies or discriminate against an uneducated, unorganized peasantry or indigenous tribe with customary claims over an historical commons. 30 For this reason, Institutionalists argue that security of tenure comes from the ability to mobilize coercive power to enforce claims. In their view, this coercive ability matters as much if not more than the fact that you hold a piece of paper granting you title. POLICY VIEWS In the policy arena, this school is sympathetic to Common Property and Agrarian Structure ideas, but recognizes that policies emanate from a political economy and hence create specific winners and losers. Institutionalists favor a kind of policy analysis that looks at who might stand to gain or lose from any particular change in a property regime. 31 They avoid pronouncing on what is Pareto Optimal or efficient, since such terms are seen as value-laden, biased, and utopian. In their view, good policy making involves deciding what kind of society we want to have in terms of our culturally specific notion of fairness. Institutionalists ask us to think about the distribution of assets and income as well as to give some thought to what kind of world we want our grandchildren to inherit. Do we want to value only what we can Policy Views Property is a social instrument and particular property regimes are chosen for particular purposes 22 A Place in the World sell? Do we only want more things forever? We can choose, Institutionalists say, and in saying this they ask us to examine how we make such choices and how we set up rules and systems to do so. And the we is important. Institutionalists want to know who is doing the deciding and how that groups power is influencing the decision. As for policy recommendations relating to property rights, Institutionalists support the idea of an inclusive property regime that respects many forms of propertynot just individualized tradable titles. Moreover, they argue that to defend property rights of any kind we need three things: government that works; the absence of predation by either government or private parties; and the absence of special interest lobbying that captures government and prevents it from deciding things fairly in the broad public interest. If all of those pieces of the puzzle are put together, then it is possible in the Institutionalist world that we could make our way to a widely shared prosperity. And to the Institutionalist, prosperity does not mean well get to Pareto Optimal heaven. These latter policy arguments come from Mancur Olsen, who wrote with pragmatism that these three conditions do not guarantee perfect markets, the maximum socially useful innovation, or an ideal allocation of resources. Nor do they assure that there is an income distribution with broad appeal. Olsen also suggested that these hard-to-obtain conditions are most likely to be found in rights-respect- ing democracies where the institutions are structured in ways that give authoritative decision making as much as possible to encompassing interests. And by encompassing, he meant the broad public interest as opposed to special interest lobbies. In sum, the Institutionalist contribution to the security of tenure discussion is to point out that whatever security of tenure people have does not depend on title per se or on the bit of commons that the poor may now have access to, but instead rests on a battery of legal and governance systems that reflect the values of the society, of which title and the existence of common property are just a reflection and outcome. Livelihoods of course depend on many of the underlying resources inside the property regime, a fact that just adds to the ferocity of the claims for the resource. Your ability to contest and defend claims to resources will then weigh heavily on your ability to earn a livelihood. Hence, for Institutionalists, the question in developing countries is not just about getting property rights clear and demarcated. Its about how to build the rules of a political and legal system so that the government can effectively serve as the advocate of the broadest public interest in the midst of all that claim-making and contestation, while at the same time honoring all kinds of property. [Olsen, 2001]. A Summary of the Four Analytical Traditions We have attempted to synthesize four of the most important scholarly traditions that address tenure security and how it affects community livelihoods. Each of the four traditions has contributed a valuable analysis of a facet of the concept called security of tenure. All have influenced tenure policy and land reforms in developing countries. And in reviewing the many ideas about security of tenure, this paper has noted that scholars differ in their conception of what security of tenure is, who should get it, its virtues for society, and how it is obtained. Property Rights theorists reduce security of tenure to a legal claim to a tradable title in a piece of property. In their view, the virtue to society of this way of defining tenure security is that it kick starts a land market that rewards efficient producers of marketed values. Their policy prescription is to set up individualized tradable titles in all things. A Place in the World 23 Scholars from the Agrarian Structure tradition find that the mar- ket itself creates risks to tenure security that result in an unfair and inefficient allocation of assets. They urge regulatory constraints on land and asset markets to manage this risk. The virtue of doing so, they say, is to stabilize an agrarian middle class, a class that is vital to maintaining a meaningful democracy and civic life. Researchers interested in Common Property enrich the idea of tenure security by noting the useful role that common property has in allowing the poor a place in the world that is less at risk from alienation by market forces. Common Property is also thought to be a fair way to manage many natural resources with physical charac- teristics that do not easily lend themselves to commoditization and individual tradable title. On the policy front, common property advocates make a case for more inclusive national legal systems that honor existing community-based property regimes and any remaining commons. The primary beneficiaries of doing so are poor rural commu- nities whose livelihoods often depend on natural resources. Institutionalist scholars contribute to the discussion by urging us to look under the hood of the concepts and to examine the institu- tional and political underpinnings of tenure security. Security of tenure, in their view, is the assurance that your property claims will be respected by other members of society. A third party with the ability to defend you effectively is necessary, especially if your property claims are challenged. This implies a social relationship among three parties in which property and kinds of property are built in a process of constant negotiation. For Institutionalists, security of tenure is a notion that is less about title and registration systems and more about emphasizing the need for functioning and transparent legal systems that benefit from a government that adjudicates fairly in the broad public interest. This is necessary so that those who think their Implications and Conclusions place in the world is under threat can get a fair hearing of their case. Implications and Conclusions A number of conclusions and implications can be drawn from this review including: There is no convincing empirical evidence from any of the analytical approaches that one type of property or property right is inherently more efficient, optimal, or ideal, as the notions of what constitutes efficiency, idea, and optimal are themselves constantly changing in a given society. An extension of the above point follows. The empirical evidence shows that there is no single property regime that will lead to attaining any of the main goals of foreign aid: social justice, livelihood generation, sound forest management, biodiversity conservation, or economic prosperity. Such outcomes are situation- and site-specific, hard to predict, and in any case not necessarily enduring through time. This is because the powers of the various players contesting for security and various property rights are constantly changing, so the underlying property regime is changing all the time as well. The Property Rights school overemphasizes the virtues of Institutionalist scholars contribute to the discussion by urging us to look under the hood of concepts and to examine the institutional and political underpinnings of tenure security. 24 A Place in the World market trading when it comes to natural resources like land and forests. There are often no markets to begin with, or flawed markets in those countries. And where markets are active and perfect, the Property Rights analysis ignores many facets of tenure security that are of great importance: how property rights get created in the first place; the importance of nonmarket values like tenure security or a place in the world; the distribution of assets in a society; the relevance of the commons as a valid type of property in the modern world; and the importance of understanding the broader political economy that defines power, justice, and the very notion of property among people in a given society. Natural resources especially land and including forests create many nonmarket values. These values accrue to individuals, communities, and the wider society. Many of these are not easily commoditized or traded in property regimes that emphasize individualized tradable title. Even when these rights can be defined and traded, it is not clear they ought to be, or if trading will result in the optimal production of the desired values. (A well-known example of these values in the world of forestry includes the environmental services that forests provide.) Other nonmarket values like a place in the world and tenure security can be added to that list of nontraded values. One of the problems we face is that while the importance of a place in the world value has declined in western society, it has not declined in developing countries. Many community-based property regimes continue to emphasize the nonmarket value of tenure security and a place in the world for their members. Do these nonmarket values constitute a form of property? And if so, do people have a right to them and does government have a duty to protect that right? These are critical questions this review has raised. The Institutionalist approach would suggest that these questions can not be answered by expert analysis, but only by each society through its own political means. A last conclusion is an observation. A degree of convergence may be emerging within the scholarly world among the different theories and approaches regarding tenure security and property rights. The Property Rights group is beginning to consider equity arguments and the legitimacy of community-based property regimes, and many practitioners now adopt Institutionalist approaches to designing land policy to reflect the political economy. This convergence may facilitate The Common Property school makes an important distinction between open-access resources and a managed commons. The Common Property school makes an important distinction between open-access resources and a managed commons. A Place in the World 25 more concerted and more effective action to address property rights in those parts of the world where tenure insecurity undermines local livelihoods. Lynn Ellsworth is a partner at Creative Strategy Group, a strategy and research consulting firm in New York City. She has 17 years of experience in international development, getting her start as a program officer in the social sciences division of the International Development Research Center in West Africa. She has been a key strategist behind the creation of a number of trusts and foundations in developing countries. She has a Ph.D. in agricultural economics from the University of Wisconsin-Madison. 1 The peasantry was also divided into classes that included slaves, free and unfree peasants, depending on the nature of their relationship to the lord of the manor. The cottager was also an important class, often a household servant or a descendant of one. A cottager had a customary grant of a house and smaller plot of land for sub- sistence gardening. It is significant froma securi- ty of tenure point of viewthat in England there were frequent legal attempts to regulate the deal that cottagers got and to assure that each cottage came with at least four acres to provide the cot- tager with a minimal livelihood. 2 For example, in the late Roman period, both slaves and free cultivators worked the large agri- cultural villa estates. This class division was then overlain with class concepts brought by the invading Germans, specifically, two newcate- gories of people. First were the tribal people or the karl who were free tribal members cultivat- ing their own land and who had to participate in civic functions such as policing and juries. Second were freedmen whose origins are more speculative possibly freed slaves or remnants of a partly assimilated conquered people. Since they were not of the tribe they did not participate in civic functions like courts. 3 Not all feudal property regimes were horrible to peasants. In the Vende in France, the local prop- erty regime had evolved in such a way that it accorded great stability to peasants, so much so that during the French Revolution the Vende peasantry launched a counter-revolution to pro- tect their feudal place in the world. Even the young Napoleon sawthe virtue of their cause and refused to fight themdown, choosing instead to lead the charge into Italy. 4 Africa is a place where this is well documented, fromthe Swynerton Plan in Kenya to various attempts throughout southern Africa to enclose the African commons (Duggan, 1988). 5 North and Thomas (1977) gave a powerful impe- tus to this school by applying property rights as a theory of change in studying economic history. Norths latter work however is more complex and, in this readers view, appears to defy categoriza- tion as a Property Rights advocate. 6 The classic statement of this is in Demsetz (1968). For the case of forests, this kind of argu- ment is made by Mendolsohn (1994). 7 It is worth noting that nobody offers serious empirical evidence for this kind of historical argument. They just make an isnt it just logical? argument rather than one anchored in an accu- rate accounting of history. See for example North and Thomas, (1977) or Hardin (1968). Also, see Field (1989) for a thorough debunking of the North and Thomas argument about the evolutionary character of property rights. 8 Some scholars raise ethical questions about why outside developers need to give in to an urge to fix something as complicated and con- tentious as property rights in someone elses country, especially when it is not clear that the existing property systemis broken. This has been most remarked upon in Africa, but is the case for other places as well. Some say when it comes to tenure and titles, we might be better off abandoning a social engineering philosophy of development and letting property regimes in developing countries evolve in their own time without interference (Platteau, 2001). 9 See Rose (1994) for a critical version of this kind of storytelling. 10 Many staff at the World Bank tend to argue these points froma property rights perspective and make use of these philosophical ideas. See the papers in the bibliography by Deininger (1999, 2000, and 2001) as well as Deininger and Feder (no date) on the World Banks Land Policy Network website or the paper by Feder and Feeny (1993). 11 In the United States a movement of Property Rights activists has emerged. They subscribe to a particular legal school of thinking that says prop- erty means sole and despotic dominion over the asset. (Blackstone, cited in Thompson, 1991). No unbundling of those rights or governmental restriction on property rights is possible. In their view, a person with title should have the right to do anything at all with his or her property, which can include destroying old growth forests, shooting endangered wolves, polluting the air, or blasting jet engine noise at the surrounding community (see essays in Bromley, 2000 for an elaboration, the papers in Jacobs, 1999 or those in Geisler and Daneker, 2000). In this American movement, any society-imposed constraint on sole and despotic dominion constitutes a taking of the value of their property. Partisans of this idea want govern- ment to pay compensation for such takings. This is the reverse of a common environmentalist posi- tion that the polluter should pay. Notes 26 A Place in the World Notes 12 See McCloskey (2001) for an elaboration on these habits within economics. 13 The China case is fascinating. Those who think tradable individual title matters a lot tend to cite the case of Chinas reforms that gave individuals residual rights to production. For example, one study of a county in China showed that those affected by the property reforms cleared more land and produced more things, although the extent to which land clearing is socially desirable was not mentioned (Lin, 1992; McMillan et al. 1989; and Jacoby et al. 1998]. Sometimes this school cites Carter and Yao (1998), who found that Chinese farmers who had the right to transfer land tended to use more green manure, and Yao, (1998) who said that when farmers had transfer rights they tended to send family members off to work somewhere off-farm. This latter point is proof to theorists of this ilk that tradable title allows everyone to find his or her output-enhanc- ing place in the world. On the notion that more titles allowpeople greater access to credit, they cite Feder et al.s (1988) study of Thailand and Carters (1997) study of Paraguay. The latter found that some farmers got more credit after titling (see also Carter and Olinto, 1996). They also cite their own collection of anecdotes that supports their case (Binswanger et al. 1995). Inconclusive studies also exist. Also, see Deacon (1994) who brings up a larger issue that stable political regimes are needed to get property regimes going in the first place. Those who think tradable title in land is not so important in creat- ing incentives to work hard and invest and get credit and thus generate efficiency-enhancing outcomes tend to cite a great many studies, especially in Africa where nontradable title is a common situation. See for example Atwood (1990); Carter and Weiber (1995); Migot-Adholla et al. (1994). Others just find the real-life situa- tions are more complex than the theoretical posi- tion of title = security. For example, Place and Migot-Adholla (1998) find that in a couple of dis- tricts of Kenya, farmers are motivated to get title not to increase investment but just to have a more secure place in the world. Platteau (2000) and (2001) provides masterful and exhaustive surveys of the African evidence on this point, undermining much of the Property Rights story. On the notion that trading in land does NOT lead to efficient outcomes, people cite reviews at FAO by Molina (1997) and Trivelli, (1997) and Riddell (1998). For a U.S. case see Gatzlaff et al. (1998). For a summary of the contradictory studies show- ing a relationship between forest clearance and tenure security, see Godoy et al. (1998). 14 Many of this school in academia might also ally themselves with the Institutionalists on many issues (see elsewhere in this paper), but because of the distinct emphasis in their work on problems related to the distribution of land, I put theminto a separate category. See the works in the bibliogra- phy by Michael Carter for an example of the kind of thinking of a development economist of this school. For a fascinating historical overviewof two different reformists of this school in the United States NewDeal era, see Gilbert and OConnors (1998) chapter in the Jacobs book Who Owns America? The chapter in the same book by John Gaventa presents this kind of viewfor Appalachia. The Land Tenure Center and the associated faculty at the UW-Madison represent a good number of the members of this school, although again, it should be repeated that some would not necessar- ily claimmembership in this school and in other contexts would find more comfort in the Institutionalist title. 15 It turns out that there is reasonable empirical evidence to showthat middle farmers or small farmers do tend to make more efficient use of their land. Why this is so is still a research question. Some believe it is because of Chayanovs observa- tion that small farmers are willing to work harder to keep their place in the world, since they value the independence more than just throwing in the plough and going off to a factory where they become part of a pool of free and unlimited sup- plies of labor. Although there is some evidence for this point, it is not always consistent nor does it provide unshakable proof. 16 See Bromley (1989, 1992a, 1992b) for variants of the basic argument of this school. An historical viewfor howthese kinds of arguments emerged in the U.K. can be found in Eversley (1910), Grove (2000), Ravenshen and Thompson (1991). Other overviews and summaries and key articles of this school can be found in McKean (2000), Ostrom (1994 and 1999), and Oakerson (1989). A nonacademic viewfromwithin this school can be seen at Open Spaces Society (2000), a group that also maintains a delightful website. 17 These analysts might be called the social jus- tice members of the Agrarian Structure tradition. The activists among thempoint to the successful outcome of many of the NewDeal land reforms in the United States that effectively gave land title to tenants and sharecroppers in the rural South. One evaluation of those programs found that a genera- tion after implementation, such reforms had sig- nificant long-run effects, transforming a group of landless black tenants into a permanent landed middle class that ultimately emerged in the 1960s as the backbone of the civil rights movement in the South (Salamon, 1979, cited in Gilbert and OConnor, 1998). 17 See Thiesenheusen, 1997 for a reviewof the Latin American experiences or Martin (2000) for Southern Africa. Also look at Deiningers (1999) articles on the World Banks market-assisted land reformwebsite for a reviewof policies that are supposed to be justified by such difficulties. 18 Some Property Rights people do so as well, for different reasons. They ignore the social justice issues, and argue that land reformis good for growth (Deininger and Van den Brink, 2000). 19 It is also important to say that people of this school would not argue that a rural middle class need be maintained forever. They would recognize that technology change in agriculture and a deeply globalized rural economy may one day obviate the efficiencies that a middle class represents. 20 See Bromley (1989, 1992a, 1992b) for variants of the basic argument of this school. An historical viewfor howthis kind of argument emerged in the U.K. can be found in Eversley (1910), Grove (2000). Other overviews and summaries and key articles of this school can be found in McKean (2000), Ostrom(1994 and 1999), and Oakerson (1989). A nonacademic viewfromwithin this school can be seen at Open Spaces Society (2000). 21 Thompson s (1991) book has a chapter on the commons that eloquently summarizes and adds to this historical literature. 22 See also Berkes (1989), Murphree, (1997), Thompson (1971), McKean (2000), and Platteau (2001) for various statements on the virtues of common property. 23 Readers can browse the archives of the annual meetings of the International Association for the Study of Common Property for many examples of all these various outcomes. Recently, Riseth (2000) reports mixed results as does Walters (2000). Senecal-Altrecht (2000) and Silva- Forsberg (2000) describe some successes. Wily (2000) and Palmer (2001) describe in great detail many recent legal changes in Africa that are start- ing to recognize the many viable commons regimes in Africa. 24 See Ostroms (1990 and 1994) work on these. Schlager (1998) and McKay (2000) are examples of scholars trying to elaborate on the design prin- ciples. 25 Lynch (1995) has the clearest statement of this advocacy position, used to good effect in Philippines and being seeded elsewhere in Asia and Africa. 26 A good survey of the common property world as it relates to forests can be found in Arnold (1998). Note as well that some members of this school also object to the termCommons (see definitions in the introduction) and prefer the phrase communi- ty-based property rights systems or talk about common pool resources (Ostrom, 1990). 27 Useful thinking fromthis school might be found in Bromley (1989 and 2000), especially the arti- cles and essays in his book Sustaining Development. Also look at Bromleys (1994) articles, Olsen (2001) and of course Thompsons (1991) fascinating analysis of the rise and fall of the commons in U.K. Jacobs (1999) book is also a good place to get up to date. Douglass Norths recent book (1999) cited in the bibliogra- phy also seems to this writer to belong in the Institutionalist school, despite Norths long-standing affiliations with the transactions cost people within the Property Rights school. As for on-the-ground studies, a good example of a recent Institutionalist approach might be Southgate (2000), who looks at the jockeying that can go on to manipulate property rights in Ecuador. Singer (200) also presents a big picture Institutionalist viewof tenure change. Sen (2000) might also be classed with this school, at least as a major influence. For an Institute of Development Studies UK variant of institutionalismusing the vocabulary of entitlements and rights borrowed fromSen, see Mearns (2000) and Bebbington, (1999). 28 Even a feeble workers union can suddenly become powerful when a load of strawberries arrives for shipment on a hot day. Such a day provided the impetus to the career of one of the U.S.s most powerful labor leaders, Jimmy Hoffa (story described in Olsen, 2001, p. 97). A Place in the World 27 29 Institutionalists would appreciate the observa- tion that Napoleon (as emperor) lost property rights over a whole world after Waterloo, and it is worth noting that he claims to have lost the battle because of unexpected rain that prevented him frommoving his cannons close to the British, thus allowing time for the Prussians to arrive (who were working with the British in that battle); hence he could not fight each army sequentially as he had hoped (Herold, 1955). A more typical Institutionalist story is paraphrased from Bromleys 1989 book: A rancher in a remote corner of Montana got up one morning and rode out across his vast estate. In one corner he found a City Man building a house. Rancher: Hey, you cant build here. This is my land. City Man: Says who? Rancher: I do. I inherited this land from my father. City Man: Howd he get it? Rancher: He inherited it fromhis father. City Man: Howd he get it? Rancher: He fought the Indians for it. City Man: Fine. Then you can fight me for it. 30 There, a coalition of indigenous people won secure legal claimto a mahogany-rich forest, but within five years the policies and legal systemand dubious behavior of logging firms quickly led to an outcome where the logging companies and gov- ernment managed to log out the actual resource with just a fewpayoffs to indigenous leaders. See Roper (2000) for the full story. 31 Boscolo (2000), with no particular affiliation with this school, gives an example of an analysis of this type related to forest concession contracts. Ainslee, Andrew. (2000) Wading In: The Realities of Land Tenure Reformin the Communal Areas of the Eastern Cape Province South Africa Paper pre- sented at 8th Biennial Conference of the International Association for the Study of Common Property. Arnold, J.E.M. (1998) Managing Forests as Common Property FAO Forestry Paper #136 Arrighi, Giovanni. (1970) Labor Supplies in Historical Perspective Journal of Development Studies Vol. 6, #3. Atwood, D.A. (1990). Land Registration in Africa: the impact on agricultural production World Development, Vol. 18: p. 659-671. Bebbington, Tony et al. (1999). Poverty, Sustainable Livelihoods, and Natural Resource Management paper presented to the World Banks Natural Resource Management Group. Berkes, Firket et al. (1989) The Benefits of the Commons Nature 340 (July): 91-93. Besley, Timothy. (1995) Property Rights and Investment Incentives: Theory and Evidence fromGhana Journal of Political Economy 103/5: 903-937. Binswanger, Hans et al. (1995) Power, Distortions, Revolt, and Reforms in Agricultural Land Relations in Jere Behrman and T. N. Srinivasan, eds., Handbook of Development Economics Vol. 3. Amsterdam: North Holland Press. Bloch, Marc. 1966. French Rural History (Davis, University of California Press). Boscolo, Marco and Jeffrey R. Vincent. (2000). Promoting Better Logging Practices in Tropical Forests: A Simulation Analysis of Alternative Regulations. Land Economics Vol. 76, #2. Bray, David Barton. Adaptive Management, Organizations and Common Property Management: Perspectives fromthe Community Forests of Quintana Roo, Mexico. Paper prepared for the panel Community Forestry in Mexico: Concordance and Contradiction between Institutions, Policies and Economies. Eighth Biennial Conference International Association for the Study of Common Property Bloomington, IN May 31-June 4. Bromley, Daniel. (1989a) Property Relations and Economic Development: The Other Land Reform World Development Vol. 17, #6, pp. 867-877. Bromley, Daniel. (1989b) The Ideology of Efficiency: Searching for a Theory of Policy Analysis Journal of Environmental Economics and Management Vol. 19, pp. 86-107. Bromley, Daniel. (1989c) Economic Interests and Institutions: The Conceptual Basis of Public Policy (Basil Blackwell). Bromley, Daniel. (1992a) The Commons, Common Property, and Environmental Policy Environmental and Resource Economics 2: 1 pp. 1-17. Bromley, Daniel. (1992b). Making the Commons Work: Theory, Practice and Policy. San Francisco: Institute for Contemporary Studies. Bromley, Daniel. (1998). Tenure Regimes and Sustainable Resource Management in Oglethorpe (1998). Bromley, Daniel. (2000) Sustaining Development: Environmental Resources in Developing Countries Northampton, MA: Elgar Press. Bromley, Daniel and Sjaastad, Espen. (2000). The Prejudices of Property Rights: On Individualism, Specificity, and Security in Property Regimes Development Policy Review, 18 (4): 365-89. December. Bruce, John and S.E. Migot-Adholla (eds.) 1994) Searching for Land Tenure Security in Africa. Dubuque, Iowa: Kendall Hunt Press. Bruce, John. (1998) Reviewof Tenure Terminology Land Tenure Center Tenure Brief (July) #1. CDE/EB. (2001). Columbia Desk Encyclopedia and essays in Encyclopedia Britannica (manorial sys- tem, feudalism, open-field system). Carter, Michael R. and Yang Yao. October 1999. Market versus Administrative Reallocation of Agricultural Land in a Period of Rapid Industrialization. Paper # 2203. Rural Development, Development Research Group. The World Bank. Carter, Michael R. and Yang Yao. October 1999. Specialization without Regret: Transfer Rights, Agricultural Productivity and Investment in an Industrial Economy. Paper #2202. Rural Development, Development Research Group. The World Bank. Carter, Michael. R. and Pedro Olinto. (1996) Does Land Titling Activate a Productivity-Promoting Land Market? Econometric Evidence fromRural Paraguay. Unpublished paper, University of Wisconsin-Madison Department of Agricultural Economics. Carter, Michael R. and K.D. Weibe. (1990) Access to Capital and Its Impact on Agrarian Structure and Productivity in Kenya American Journal of Agricultural Economics 72: 1146-50. Carter, Michael R. and Frederic Zimmerman. (2000) Can Time and Markets Eliminate Costly Land Ownership Inequality Paper presented to the Annual World Bank Conference on Development Economics April 2000. Cooper, Graham. 2001. The NewForest History at www.hants.gov.uk/newforest/history De Janvry, Alain, et al. (2001) Comments on World Bank Property Rights Paper at www.world- bank.org, Land Policy Network electronic confer- ence on property rights and land reform, 2001. De Soto, Hernando. (2000) The Mystery of Capital: Why CapitalismTriumphs in the West and Fails Everywhere Else. Basic Books, USA. Deacon, Robert. (1994) Deforestation and the Rule of Lawin a Cross Section of Countries Land Economics (November) 70:4, pp. 414-30. Deininger, Klaus. (2000). The Theory Behind Market Assisted Land Reform on website of World Bank Land Policy Network (www.worldbank.org). Deininger, Klaus and Hans Binswanger. (1999) The Evolution of the World Banks Land Policy: Principles, Experience and Future Challenges The World Bank Research Observer Vol. 14, #2 (August) pp. 247-76. Deininger Klaus and Rogier van den Brink (2000) HowLand ReformCan Contribute to Economic Growth and Poverty Reduction: Empirical Evidence FromInternational and Zimbabwean Experience Unpublished paper, World Bank Land Policy Thematic Group. Deininger, Klaus and Gershon Feder. (no date) Land Institutions and Markets Unpublished paper on World Banks Land Policy Network website. Deininger, Klaus. (no date) Making Negotiated Land ReformWork: Initial Experience from Colombia, Brazil and South Africa Unpublished paper at website of World Banks Land Policy Network site. Demsetz, Harold. 1967. Toward a Theory of Property Rights American Economic ReviewVol. 57, #2, pp. 347-359. Duggan, William. 1988. An Economic Analysis of Southern African Agriculture (Praeger Press, NewYork). Bibliography 28 A Place in the World Eversely, Lord. 1910. The Story of the Battle During the Last 45 years for Public Rights over the Commons, Forests, and Footpaths of England and Wales (London, Cassell and Company) Faruqee, Rashid and Kevin Carey. (1997) Land Markets in South Asia: What Have We Learned? Paper on the World Banks Land Policy Networks website. Feder, Gershon and David Feeny. (1993) The Theory of Land Tenure and Property Rights in Hoff et al. The Economics of Rural Organization: Theory, Practice, and Policy (World Bank, Washington DC). Feder, G. , T. Onchan, Y. Chalanwong, and C. Hongladarom. (1998). Land Policies and FarmProductivity in Thailand. Johns Hopkins University Press. Baltimore, MD for the World Bank. Field, Barry. (1989) The Evolution of Property Rights, Kyklos 42(3): 319-45. Gatzlaff, Dean et al. (1998) Cross Tenure Differences in Home Management and Appreciation Land Economics Vol. 74 #3 pp. 328-42. Gavian, Sarah and Marcel Fafchamps. (1996) Land Tenure and Allocative Efficiency in Niger American Journal of Agricultural Economics 41: 460-471. Geisler, Charles and Gail Daneker. (2000). Property and Values: Alternatives to Public and Private Ownership (Island Press, Washington DC). Gibson, Clark et al. (2000) People and Forests: Communities, Institutions, and Governance (MIT Press, Cambridge). Gilbert, Jess and Alice OConnor. (1998). Leaving the Land Behind: Struggles for Land Reformin U.S. Federal Policy, 1933-1965, chapter 7 of Jacobs, (1998). Godoy, Ricardo et al. (1998) The Role of Tenure Security and Private Time Preference in Neotropical Deforestation Land Economics Vol 74 #2, pp. 162-70. Grove, Richard (2000) Fighting for the Fakenham Commons: the Legacy of Sir Thomas More, his Utopia, and the Last Rural Rebellion in England Paper presented at 8th Biennial Conference of the International Association for the Study of Common Property. Hardin, Garrett. (1968) The Tragedy of the Commons Science Vol. 162, pp. 1243-1248. Jacobs, Harvey, (ed.). (1998) Who Owns America? Social Conflict Over Property Rights (Madison, University of Wisconsin Press). Lin, J.Y. (1992) Rural Reforms and Agricultural Growth in China American Economic ReviewVol. 82, p. 34-51. Lynch, Owen (1995) Recognizing Private Community-Based Rights in Balancing Acts: Community Forestry and International Lawin Asia and the Pacific (Washington DC, World Resources Institute). McKay, Bonnie (2000) Emergence of Self- Organized Cooperation paper presented at 8th Biennial Conference of the International Association for the Study of Common Property. McKean, Margaret. (2000). Common Property: What is it, what is it good for, and what makes it work? Chapter two of Gibson, Clark et al. 2000. McMillan, J. et al. (1989). The Impact of Chinas economic reforms on agricultural productivity growth Journal of Political Economy, 97, p. 781-807. Mearns, Robin, et al. 1997. The Institutional Dynamics of Community-Based Natural Resource Management: An Entitlements Approach (Institute of Development Studies, Sussex). Murphree, Marshall. (1997) Congruent Objectives, Competing Interests, and Strategic Compromise: Concept and Evolution of Zimbabwes CAMPFIRE Program Paper presented to Conference on Representing Communities: Histories and Politics of Community-Based Resource Management, Georgia, USA, 1997. North, Douglass and Robert Thomas. (1977) The first economic revolution Economic History Review, Vol. 30, pp. 229-241. OED. Oxford English Dictionary (full-length edition). Olson, Mancur. (2000). Power and Prosperity: Outgrowing Communist and Capitalist Dictatorship (Basic Books, NewYork). Open Spaces Society. (2000) Cherishing your common land: community action and History at www.oss.org.uk Ostrom, Elinor, et al. (1994) Rules, Games, and Common Pool Resources Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Ostrom, Elinor. (1990) Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Palmer, Robin et al. The Struggles Continue: Evolving Land Policy and Tenure Reforms in Africa final chapter in Camilla Toulmin and Julian Quan (eds.) Evolving Land Rights: Policy and Tenure in Africa London, IIED. Place, Frank and Keijiro Otsuka. (forthcoming) Issues and Theoretical Framework in Place and Otsuka eds. Land Tenure and Natural Resource Management: A Comparative Study of Agrarian Communities in Asia and Africa. Platteau, Jean-Phillipe. (2001). Institutions, Social Norms, and Economic Development (Harwood Academic Publishers, NewYork). Polanyi, Karl. 1944. The Great Transformation (Beacon Press, NewYork). Rampey, Leslie. 2001. The English Royal Forest and the Tale of Gamelyn on the web at www.geoci- ties.com/lrampey/erf.htm Riddell, James. (2000). Emerging Trends in Land Tenure Reform: Progress Towards a Unified Theory (Rome, FAO Land Tenure Service). Riseth, Jan Age and Arild Valn (2000) A Perspective on the Sami-Norwegian Case of Co-Management in the Reindeer Industry: Regional Failure and Success at the End of the Old Millennium Paper presented at 8th Biennial Conference of the International Association for the Study of Common Property. Roper, J. Montgomery. (2000) Whose Territory Is It? Resource Contestation and Organizational Chaos in Bolivias Multiethnic Indigenous Territory Paper presented at the 2000 meeting of the Latin American Studies Association, Miami, March 16-18, 2000. Rose, Carol. (1994). Property and Persuasion: Essays on the History, Theory and Rhetoric of Ownership WestviewPress, Boulder Colorado. Rosendo, Srgio. Working with many voices: the dynamics of decision-making in rubber tappers' organisations in Rondnia, Brazilian Amazonia. Eighth Biennial Conference International Association for the Study of Common Property Bloomington, IN. Schlager, Edella et al. (1998) Resolving Common Pool Resource Dilemmas and Heterogeneities Among Resource Users Paper presented at 8th Biennial Conference of the International Association for the Study of Common Property. Sen, Amartya. (1999) Democracy as a Universal Value Journal of Democracy Vol. 10, #3, pp. 3-17. Senecal-Albrecht, Daniel. (2000) Dont Wait for Boldt: Building Co-Management fromthe Ground Up: The Success of Salmon Fishermens Groups in Western Alaska Paper presented at 8th Biennial Conference of the International Association for the Study of Common Property. Sicular, Terry. (1999) Investment versus Institutional Transformation to promote Growth: Perspectives fromChina Panel presentation on Economic Development Economic Growth and International Trade, Yale University, April 16. Silva-Forsberg, Maria Clara. (2000) HowCan A Forest Be Sustainable Facing Growing Population Pressure? Center for Sustainable Development Studies Paper, Costa Rica. Singer, Joseph. (2000). Property and Social Relations: FromTitle to Entitlement, Chapter 1 in Geisler and Danker, (2000). Southgate, Douglas and Hugo Ramos. (2000). Subverting Local Institutions: Arresting Social Capital Formation and Environmental Conservation in Latin America Paper presented to the Biennial Conference of the International Association for the Study of Common Property, 2000. Steins, Nathalie, Victoria Edwards and Niels Roling. (2000). Redesigned Principles for CPR Theory in June Common Property Resource Digest. Thompson, E.P. 1991. Customs in Common (New York: The NewPress). Walters, Bradley. (2000) Muddy Intertidal Mangroves and Murky Common Property Theories Paper presented at 8th Biennial Conference of the International Association for the Study of Common Property. Ward, R. Gerard. Changing Forms of Communal Tenure in Larmour 1997. White, Andy and Alejandra Martin. (2001) Who Owns the Worlds Forests? Forest Trends, Washington, D.C. Wily, Liz Alden. (2000) Reconstructing the African Commons 8th Biennial Conference of the International Association for the study of Common Property Bloomington, IN. Yao, Yang. Unpublished. Job Access and Wage Equity in Eastern Chinas Rural Industry. Zimmerman, Frederick. (2000) Barriers to Participation of the Poor in South Africas Land Redistribution World Development Vol. 28, #8, pp. 1439-1460. Bibliography Photographs: COVER, MOREY MILBRANDT / ARTVILLE; JAMES FAHN PAGE 1, JAMES FAHN 6, iSTOCKPHOTO 8, 12, 14, 18, 24 JAMES FAHN INSIDE BACK COVER, MOREY MILBRANDT / ARTVILLE BACK COVER, MOREY MILBRANDT / ARTVILLE credits Editor JAMES FAHN Author LYNN ELLSWORTH CREATIVE STRATEGY GROUP 165 DUANE STREET NEW YORK, NY 10013 212-732-1025 EMAIL: LYNNELLSWORTH@VERIZON.NET Publication design: MODINO GRAPHICS 212.431.4354 WWW.MODINO.COM MODINO100@AOL.COM Printing: COLAHAN SAUNDERS CORP. Paper/Soy Inks: PRINTED WITH SOY INKS ALL FIBER 100% RECYCLED (50% POST-CONSUMER) Design Interns: WENDY CRUZ, BASILISA JIMINEZ, CATHY JIMINEZ MARCH 2004 Environment and Development Affinity Group: JEFFREY YOUNG CAMPBELL, US/NEW YORK MILAGRE NUVUNGA, EAST AFRICA/NAIROBI, KENYA Co-chairs SHARON ALPERT, US/NEW YORK CARL ANTHONY, US/NEW YORK CHARLES BAILEY, ASIA/HANOI, VIETNAM IRENE BAIN, ASIA/BEIJING, CHINA GANESAN BALACHANDER, ASIA/NEW DELHI, INDIA DEBORAH BARRY, LATIN AMERICA/MEXICO CITY, MEXICO MICHELLE DEPASS, US/NEW YORK CYNTHIA M. DUNCAN, US/NEW YORK JAMES FAHN, US/NEW YORK PABLO FARIAS, US/NEW YORK SHARRY LAPP, MIDDLE EAST & NORTH AFRICA/CAIRO, EGYPT ADRIAN LOPEZ, LATIN AMERICA/MEXICO CITY, MEXICO CECILIA MELLO, LATIN AMERICA/RIO DE JANEIRO, BRAZIL NGUYEN THI THANH AN, ASIA/HANOI, VIETNAM PAULA NIMPUNO, SOUTHERN AFRICA/JOHANNESBURG, SA UJJWAL PRADHAN, ASIA/JAKARTA, INDONESIA SUZANNE SISKEL, ASIA/JAKARTA, INDONESIA ANA TONI, LATIN AMERICA/RIO DE JANEIRO, BRAZIL TRAN PHUONG MAI, ASIA/HANOI, VIETNAM AURELIO VIANNA, LATIN AMERICA/RIO DE JANEIRO, BRAZIL TO COMMENT AND SHARE YOUR EXPERIENCES WITH ASSET BUILDING EMAIL US AT: ASSETSAPPROACH@FORDFOUND.ORG The underlying ownership of forests is often hotly disputed. www.fordfound.org A Program Learning Product of the Environment and Development Affinity Group OTHER PUBLI CATIONS SUSTAINABLE SOLUTIONS DIVERSITY ON THE FARM DEEPER ROOTS BORROWED FROM THE FUTURE FORD FOUNDATION ASSET BUILDING AND COMMUNITY DEVELOPMENT PROGRAM