This document discusses the historical context of violence and trade among three highland groups in insular Southeast Asia. It argues that each group's current attitudes toward violence are a result of their differing experiences within the region's political economy dominated by slave raiding and coerced trade. Groups that played a predatory role, raiding for slaves, are now more positively disposed to violence, while groups that were primarily victims are more negatively disposed. The document provides an overview of the general historical context and maritime trade networks before comparing the three groups' attitudes toward violence, social hierarchy, and debt.
This document discusses the historical context of violence and trade among three highland groups in insular Southeast Asia. It argues that each group's current attitudes toward violence are a result of their differing experiences within the region's political economy dominated by slave raiding and coerced trade. Groups that played a predatory role, raiding for slaves, are now more positively disposed to violence, while groups that were primarily victims are more negatively disposed. The document provides an overview of the general historical context and maritime trade networks before comparing the three groups' attitudes toward violence, social hierarchy, and debt.
This document discusses the historical context of violence and trade among three highland groups in insular Southeast Asia. It argues that each group's current attitudes toward violence are a result of their differing experiences within the region's political economy dominated by slave raiding and coerced trade. Groups that played a predatory role, raiding for slaves, are now more positively disposed to violence, while groups that were primarily victims are more negatively disposed. The document provides an overview of the general historical context and maritime trade networks before comparing the three groups' attitudes toward violence, social hierarchy, and debt.
This document discusses the historical context of violence and trade among three highland groups in insular Southeast Asia. It argues that each group's current attitudes toward violence are a result of their differing experiences within the region's political economy dominated by slave raiding and coerced trade. Groups that played a predatory role, raiding for slaves, are now more positively disposed to violence, while groups that were primarily victims are more negatively disposed. The document provides an overview of the general historical context and maritime trade networks before comparing the three groups' attitudes toward violence, social hierarchy, and debt.
thal of"ifutisu,"the tefln used by the tribes in the
Xingu system (sce Basso 1973: 12-1'+,. 4. Foliage from this pblltis burnedand theas his Icaehed \Vith water lo produce potassium ehloride, the sall ofthe Xinguanos As the villagcrsdescribe it, the Carib tribes' speeialii'ati ol1S in , hell belts and necklaces should also be consldered labor intensive monopolies, sineetheyinvoll'elonganddangeroustripstofind the shell s, and arduous\Vork to craft them into Ihe final produet. 5. AII oftheXingutribeseatfi sh,monkey,andanumberofspeciesof birds, most game animals. 6. The\'i1lagersarefar moreaeute1yattunedtoodorsthan\Ve are, and will oftenspitto reducethesensationofabadsmell. In Jeeountsof interaetionwith both wild Indiansand for es tan imals(with whom wild Indians are believed to share a great deal in eommon) the Xinguanos often remark on thefetid smell. 7. Some of tlIc Xinguanos claim to have seen a tribe eall ed "Thc PeopleWhoLive Inside Trees" somedi stanee totheeastoftheir reservati on. The tree people purportedly live in tree trunks, eat uneooked birds , \Vear no clothes, and spea kin hootsand grunts. Symbolieally, this eulturelesstribefulfill sanani mal-likepotential whieh other wild Indians onl yapproximat e. 8. In 1972, 1witnessed thekillingofan Xingu Indianwho\Vas haeked to death \Vith machetesas we tri ed to hold off hi sJssailants in a room at the Indian Post. .\ftertheexeeuti on, thekillersexhibitcd an iey calm. Oneapproaehed me, pointed to thecorpse and thc wa i)ing relatives and said: "You can take photographs now." 9. Thcse findings are based primaril y on Iny work \Vith Tupi and Arawak spea king informants. 124 6 Raiding, trading and tribal autonomy in insular Southeast Asia THOMAS GIBSON In this paper, warfare in insularSoutheastAsia is examinedthroughthe compari sonofthreegroups ofhighlandshiftingcultivators .I Thethesis is that thecurrent social evaluation ofviolence and aggression within eaeh group is the result of differing historical experi ences wi thin a loosely integratedregional political economydominated bytheinstitu- ti ons of slave raiding and coerced trade. Those groups positively disposed toward bellicosity are those which pl ayed a predominantly preda toryrole in theregion,while those which are negati velydi sposed toward violence in anyform were primaril yprc\. There is, however, nothingdetermini sti cabout the argument , for eachconcreteexample rcpresents onl )' oneofanumberoflogicallypossibleresponsestoagiven sequencc ofhistorical events. All three groups still retaill asignifi cant degreeofautonomyovertheirinternalpoliticalandideol ogical systems, and each must be seen as creatively responding to a changing se t of e>..iernal politi cal and economic forces. In thefi rstpartofthe papcr, abriefoutlineisprovided ofthegeneral hi storical context in which these three soci eti es havedeveloped. [nthe secondpart,anovcrviewofeaehsocich is gi ven. III thethirdpart, their respecti veattitudes toward\'iolcncc, social rankingandindebtednessare 125 THO M A S GIBSON compared and contrasted. The paper concludes with a look at so me of the implications of asking questions about human violence in the contexts of exploitation and of ritual attitudes, as opposed to those of aggression and competition for scarce natural resources. SOUTHEAST ASIA AS A LOOSELY I NT EGRATED R E GION Southeast Asia is a region in which the sea serves as the major means of communication and the land forms the major impediment to it. It is often easier to sail long distances from one island to another, than to walk across the smal!est island (Reid 1984: 151). Dense rain forest and rugged mountains provide a natural barrier behind which tribal popula- bons have been able to preserve a remarkable degree of autonomy into the modern era. This autonomy should not mislead us into assuming, on the one hand, a complete lack of contact between tribesmen and sta te systems. On the other, extensive trade also should not lead us into treating tribal areas and sta tes as belonging to a single, tightly integrated system. I t is precisely the importance of trade in the history of the region, associated with a pattern of predatory raiding, whi ch has al!owed the complex articulation of fundamental!y diverse cultural and political systems. Violen ce and commodities are truly inter-cultural phenomena , which can have very different meanings for neighboring populations, and at the same time exert decisive influences on the development of each trading and raiding partner. Scott (1986) gives an illuminating account ofthe political economy of the coastal Philippines at the time of Spanish contacto His account mal' serve as a model of one of the simpler forms of maritime economies in the region. The Philippines remained peripheral to th e major interna- tional trade routes until relatively late. Even then it was primarily Chinese ships which traded into the islands, and not Philippine ships which sailed to China. As far as domestic Philippine trade is concerned, however: Every community traded with other communities, and most of them did it by boat.. the total impression is one of continual Illovements of rice, camotcs, bananas, coconuts, \Vine, fish , g:lllle, salt and cloth between coastal barrios - to say nothi ng of gold , jewelry, porcclain and slaves . . [Raiding] \Vas the eseemed occupation of the able-bodied maJe who could afford it . .. Although raiders took booty both ashare and afl oat when they eould, then real objcct was 126 Raiding, trading and tribal autonomy slavcs . It is to cal! attention to .. the mixed merchandizing of this] commerce [that it] is here referred to as "trade-raiding." Potential customers for this trade in the Philippines were legion because the purchase of slaves was an ordnary means of investing surpJus wealth ... Filipino commllnities supplied most of their own slave labor by usury and penal aetion, but always preferred aliens for religious purposes - that is , sacrifice. (Scott 1982: 87-9 1) Trade in the western parts of the achipelago had long been more sophisticated. The Sri Vijayan state dominated regional trade between the seventh century and 1025, when it was destroyed by the Chola dynasty ofSouth India. Its rulers had been "content to provide a neutral commercial facility for the exchange of Western, Chinese, and Southeast Asian products" (Hall 1985: 210). In later times, local rulers of coastal sta tes began to supplement their position as mere port custodians, servicing the ships of Chinese or Indian traders, byattempt- ing to secure local products from their hinterlands for the international market. Prior to the fourteenth century these products were in large part gathered in the forests of the interior (items sueh as camphor, sandal- wood and benzoin), or from the sea (items such as pearls) and had to be acquired from autonomous groups of shifting cultivators and hunter- gathercrs (see Reid 1980: 236). After the fal! ofSri Vijaya there fol!owed a two hundred year period in which Arab, Indian and Chinese traders attemptcd to trade directly with the producers of the spices and forest products for which there was a growing demand both in south China and in Europe. However, according to Hall: By the 13th century Asia 's internal trade was baek in the hands of Southeast Asians, as foreign merchants found it once again expedient to deal with Southeast Asia-based intermediaries at major international entrepots rather than attempti ng to deal directl y with the people who controlled the so urce s of supply. (Hall 1985: 24) One aspect ofthis process insufficiently emphasized by Hall is the fact that human labor power itselfbecame a "local product" to be acquired from the hinterland for sale in the entrepots along the coasts. Before indentured labor was developed in the nincteenth centllry, the move- ment of captive peoples and slaves was the primary source of labor mobility in Southeast Asia. Typicall y it too k the for m of transferring people from weak, poli ti cally fragmellted societ cs to stronger and weal thier (mes. The oldest, and demographicall y most important movement was the border raiding against animi st swidden-cultivators and hunter-gathers by the stronger wet-rice culti- vators of the river valleys ... There secms little doubt that the ma jor i.ty of the Southeast Asi an urban population prior to about 1820 was rccruited in a captive 127 THOMAS G IBS ON state . Slavery was an important means whereby animistic peoples \Vere absorbed into the dominant Islam of the city and coast. (Reid 1983: 28-29. 170- 171 ) Warren (1981) has amply documented the explosive growth of the Sulu state during the eighteenth and nineteenth century, a growth that was based upon a system of extracting forest and sea produce, by means of slave labor, for trade with Cantono The labor was itself"produced" by raiding the poorl y defended populations of the Bisayan islands and Luzan. Again, Endicott (1983 ) provides a useful summary of what is known concerning slave raids against the Orang Asli of the Malay peninsula. Throughout the area it is clear that slave-raiding has gone hand in hand with international trade from the earliest times. The forests and mountains which protected the tribesmen of the inte ri or from day-to-day control and routinized exploitation by the coastal states, also left them militarily weak and unable to resist the organizcd slaving expeditions which were periodically launched against them. Shifting cultivation in the tropi cs requires a low population density and is most efncient when the population is evenly dispersed. This is not to sa)' that shifting cultivators were themselves innocent of slave-trading and slavc-;IOIding. Among the Ngaju of south Borneo and the Maloh, Melanau, Ka)'an and Berawan of central Born eo, for example, a class of aristocrats was freed from subsisten ce production for long- di stan ce trade by its ownership of a class of hereditar)' slaves. The Iban also took cap- tives as well as heads from their enemies for ransom, sale or adoptioll. The relative underpopulation of Southeast Asia also had consc- quences for lowland societies in the area. One of the chief aims of warfare for both coastal and inland states was the capture of prisoners to suppl ement the domestic work force (Reid 1980:243; Tambiah 1976: 120). The key to Southeast i\sian social systems was the control of meno Land \Vas assumed to be abundant, and not therefore an index to power (with the partial exceptions of Java and Central Thailand in relati vely modern times). lt is this tha! distinguishes traditional Southeast Asian states from feudal Ol1es. Socicty \Vas held together by verti ca l bonds of obligations between meno (Reid 1983: 5) These bonds of obligation could take the form of voluntary loyalty to a lord , indebtedness to a creditor, or outright ownership b), a purchasing master. Chattel slavery was onl y the endpoint of a continuurn of clyaclic relations of depenclency. 128 Raiding, trading and tribal autonomy he prominence of debt and judicial sentence as sou rces of slavery appea rs to be distmetivc Jll the Southeast .\sian pattern Since inability to paya judi cial fine rna} be takcn as <3 variaban on inability to pay l debt, \Ve rnay safely regard debt as the most fundamental source of Southeast Asian slavcry. (ibid: 159) In lowlancl societies as \\'ell, then, trade goes along with slavcry, allhough in a rather clifferent wa). In Ihe first place, prosperity clerives so much from tracle that all social relationships become mercantilizecl, ancl anv inabilih to maintain one' s creditworthiness soon leacls to one's a' commoclity oneself. In the second place, centrali zed state powcr was usually so wcak that semi-autonomous wealthy merchants were ablc to surrouncl themsclves with virtual armies of slaves to defend themselves ancl their possessions. Privately owned slaves constitute a lilll itati on on the power of the monarch and tend to disappear where central power is greatest (i bid: 18). But in the great trading citi es along the coast, monarchs tended to be weak, and real power was in the hands of a merchl nt plutocracy. Crudcl y speaking, Southeast Asian soeieti es can thus be groupecl into at least four types as regarcl s their experi enee of slavery. First, there are the wcak, fragmented societies of the highlands whi eh served primarily as a source of goods and slaves for the lowlands. Second, there are the la rger, more organized societies of th e hi ghl ands which maintainecl their OWIl class of sI aves for ritual purposes and to fr ee a small aristocracy fOI long-distance trade. Thircl, there are the predatory trade-raicling soeieties of the coastal arcas who regarded slaves primarily as a COIl1- ll10ditv to be traclecl on to large urban centers. Ancl fourth , there are thesc urban centers themselves. There is a fifth type of societ)' represen- ted bv Bali ancl the Taraja which seems to have generated internally a large \'olume of sI aves for e:\1lort cluring certain periods (v<1ll der Kraan 198 3; Bi galke 1983). Relatively clense populations dependen t on fi xed- fiel d, wet-ri ce agriculture \Vere necessar)' for this somewhat un usual si tuation to arise. 1t is incvitable then, that the highlalld soeieties which managed to lai nta in their autonomy from lowl and statcs should give a great deal of prominence to those same lowland sta tes in terms both of practical rncasures of resistance and of sym bolism. Violent raidi ng, coerced trade rOl jungle proclucts, ancl clebt bondage are al! probl ema tic areas to which SOrne sort of response is reguired by their insertion in the regional politiea} econOll1v. 12 THOMAS GIBSON RAIOING ANO TRAOING IN SOUTHEAST ASIAN CULTURES Theprecedingdiscussion ofthe looselyintegrated regionaleconomyof insular Southeast Asia has defined the context in which the societies now to be described have had to operate. In thefol!owing discussion of three groups of shifting cultivators, I shall focus on the moral and symbolic values attached to activities in which raiding and tradingare involved. The Buid TheBuid are one ofa numberofhighland groups in Mindoro knovm col!ectively to tile lowlanders as "Mangyan," a term which has strong connotations of inferiority, wildness, and even slavery. It should be pointed out, however, thatthe lowlanders havebegun to use sandugu, Clone blood,"or"blood brothers,"as aterm ofreferenceand add'ress for the highlanders. Theimplication of, and reason for using this term, is that the lowlanders would like the highlanders to feel bound to the lowland speakers by ties ofartificial kinship. Thesetiesshould obligate thehighlandersto treatthelowlanderswithaffection andgratitude, but aboye al! to trade and to pay theirdebts. Thehighland Buid reject the term as presumptuous, for they view the lowland traders as anecessary evil, whoseviewofsocietyas madeupofmoralandmaterialdebtorsand crt:ditors is the direct antithesis oftheir own. In theBuid valuesystem, violence is onlytheultimateoutcomeofa wholeseriesofnegativeformsofinteractionwhichbeginswithboastful- ness (buagun) andquarrelinggarisugan "reciprocal aggression"). Isug, "aggression,"connotesal! thathas a negative value in Buid sociallife: the uncontrol!ed expression ofindividual emotion and theassertion of egotistic desires, the attempt to dominate others, and, ultimately, physical violence and murder. They regard maisug, "aggrcssive" behavior, as being typical oftheir lowland Christian antagonists, \\'ho the)' continual!y hold up as anegative example. This word has a\Vide distri hutionin thePhilippines. AmongtheTausugMuslims, itrdersto al! that is positivelyvalued in men: virility, courage, and the ability to stand upfor onc'shonor(Ki efer 1972: 53).TheBuid, by contrast, ha\'e no word for "courage," in the sense ofa positively valued aggressi\'e attitudein theface ofphysicaldanger. Thereare manywordsfor fcarof 130 Raiding, trading and tribal automon y andAightfrom danger,neitherofwhich is seen as beingreprehensible. Indced, they are the onl yrational response to danger. It is recognized that Buid may on occasion act in an aggressive manner, but such behavior is attributed either to a weak mind, unable to control the emonons ofits soul and body, orto affliction with afa ngarisuga n "spirit which causes aggression." Iam aware ofonly onehomicide occurring within aBuid populationofonethousand in aten yearperiod, and that was carried out by aman with a fearsome reputation as a sorcerer. Ratherthan compete in perfonningacts ofcourage, Buid youth are mostlikely tospendtheirtimelearninglove poemswith which tocourt young girls, The southern Buid and the neighboring Hanunoo have preservedascriptwhich was used throughoutthePhilippinesin ancient times. Themainpurposeofthisscriptis torecordand memorizepoetry. Thesortofprestigeonecanacquirewithone'sknowledgeofpoetry, and the sort of"conquests" one can make are the very oppos,ite ofthose acquired through "bravery" and violence. Seduction is not associated with aggression among the Buid as it is in other cultures which value aggressiveness in men. Thepoemsthemselvesarefull ofgentleimagery. Inaddition to theircategoricalaversion to aggressive behaviorofany kind, theBuidplacean extremelyhigh valueon individual autonomy. This is taken to such an extreme that even parents are reluctant to intcrfere in thebehavioroftheirchildren more than is necessary. ' 1 'hey striveinsteadto substitutethedependencyofsmal! childrenonspecific adults with their dependenc\' on the adult community as a whole. Betwcen adults, there should be no hillt ofdependency, either emo- tionalormaterial. Suchattitudesaccountin partfortheextremely high rate ofdivorce among the Buid. While the optimal economic unit in Buid society consists of one adult maJe and one adult female, and virtuallyal! adults belong to such a couple at a n ~ one time, there is a high rateofturnoverin thecompositionofcouples.Adivorce is almost always caused by one partner deciding to marry a new spouse. The abandoned partner recei ves a sum ofmutual!y agreed compensation andthenbeginshis orherown searcbforane\\!spouse, oftensetti ngoff a chai n reaction. Children soon learn to acceptwhatever step-parents Come their \Vay. (EIsewhere I have described in dctail Buid attitudes towardsdyadic relations ofdependenc)' [Gibson 1985J.) In order to maximize individual autonomy and mobility, some mechanism must be found which allo\\'s people to detach themsclvcs from theirprcscntsctofcompanionsandattachthemselvesto anewsct 131 T H OMA S G1BSON without much trouble. Thi s mccha ni sm is what 1 call "sharing," and was first clearly identifi ed in the study of hunting and gathering societi es. It is based on the principIe that "cntitlelllent does not depcnd in any wa) on donation" (Woodburn 1982: 441 ). Individual s are obligated to share certain goods and services with the rest of the community. Among the Buid the most obvious example is again meat, wh ich is only butcherecl on ritual occasiollS, and whi ch must be sharcd out in porti ons which are identical in both quantity and quality among all those prcsent regardless of age or sex. Performing these rituals is no route to augmented status, for the)' are onl)' carried out in responsc to illness or c1 eath withi n the sponsoring householcJ. Their/ performancc is thus a de monstration not of the wealth and vitalty of the sponsors, but of their misfortune. No one is obliged to receive a portion of meat, and no one is obliged to repav the individual s whose sacrifices they Ilavc attended in th e past. T he only obligation is on the giver. 1 have argued elsewhere that th e characteristic manner in which Buid cOllduct cOl1\CrsatiollS, help each other vvork 011 their fields, and, indeed, mlrTy and divorce may best be described as the sharing of speec], labor and sexual intercoursc IGibson 1986: 44-48, 83-84). Tll e underl)'ing principIe is that strictly d:adi c rclationships are likel y to !cad to either competition and aggression, or to dominance and indebtcd- ness. If each indi \'idual sees himself or herself as interacting only witll a un di fferentiated social group, th e possibility of losing one's personal autononw is minimized. Sha ring prevents ties of personal depenclcnc" from ari sing b) l1laking the individual dependent onl)' on the group, ancl so ensUTCS both autollomy and equality within thc group. Buie! ritual acti vitv is also carried out on a cooperative basis, and no individual adopts the role of speciali::t with privileged access to the spirit \VorJd. 1\11 adult men possess spirit familiars , and m\' stical power derives from large numbers of men chanting together. Constant particip;ltion in obligatory coll ectivc ri tual, in whi ch the Icgitirnac\ of rcligiolTS belicf deri\es f10m personal cxperi ence of the spirit \Vorld, and 110t from traditioll as interprctccl by elders or speeiali sts, from a sacred te:i!t, or from the pri\'i1cged cxpclienec of a charislllatie figure , provides t!te Buid \\ith a shared ce,e of belicf ancl a cl cep conviction of the rca lit)' of invisible p()\\ns (Cibson 1986 148) Buid vie\' themselves as the prcy of a host cf evil spirits who fcast 011 them when they die in the same \Va\ that thc Huid feast 011 their mm pigs. ::meling within thc humall community is bcl ievee! to Tender 1 ~ '- Raiding, trading and tribal automony peoplc more vulnerable to attack by these evil spirits. In the religious spherc, then, aggression is associated with violence, killing, and in the case of the most dangerous evil spi rit, cannibali sm. The most feared spiri t is the fangablang, a giant said to resemble a Christi an lowlane!er. The Buid may be sa ie! to have an economic system which maxi mizcs a ma rried couple's ability to be virtuall )' self-suffici ent, and a political system which maximi zes people's ability to form ancl c1issolve social rclationships. It eliminates competition for pmvcr ~ l l l d prcstige by restricting ally form of dyadic interaction. 'rhe two institutions which 1 ha\'e saie! constitute thc l!lain forms of interaction between neighboring societies in Southeast Asia, raiding and trae! ing, are both assigncd negati ve symbolic values and referred to the exterior of the soci ety. Buie! acquire lowland trade partners and put up with the c\ ploitation they suffer bccause they must (cE Gibson 1986: 16). But thc concepts of debt and dcpendency on which this trade is bascd are not allowed to operate wi thi n Buid society. Raiding is a matter of suffering predation by nil and aggressive outsiders in the material and mystical \VorJe!s, but countcr- ra icl ing is confined to th e imaginary world of spirit mecl ium- ship. Fli ght, and quick integration into ne\V communities through the institu ti ons of divorce and sharing, are thc IlIain c1efenses against raiding in thc material world. Put more ahstractly, one can characteri ze the Buid and other groups ofpeop!c like them as having an ideologv of ascribed equality: people are considered equal no matter how successflll the)' are in various activities. The llongot he I1ongot of northern Lllzon resemble thc Buie! in their egalitarian values ancl ass erti on of indi vi dual autonomy. Thcy differ from the Buid primarilv in terms of thci r attitudes tO\vare!s violen ce and competition. Scott (1979), ",ho has \Vorked out a cl assification of "unhispanizcd" Phili ppine societies acco rdi ng to class structure, includ es the Ilo ngot with he Mangya n in his "classless" category. Despite thcir fondness for heacl hunting, Seott resists pl acing them in hi s category of "",arrior societi es" bccause they do not "practice coup counting whi ch might produce a warrior elite." Thcy also Iack a class term for accomplished W<lrriors ' \vhich distinguishes a catcgory of men with shared status, privilege and responsibility in the community" (1979: 156) \Vhilc i ncJ udi ng the I1ongot and other \iol ent, class)css socicties wit h peaceful , 1 -,-, ) ) THOMAS GIBS O N c1assless societies is perfectl > l,=gitimate given the purposes of Scott's c1assification, 1 require for my own purposes a c1assification which privileges attitudes toward violence, aggression and dependency. The motivation for engaging in violence among !longot youth is precisely to achieve equality with adult meno The Ilongot do possess a form of ranking, but it is of the simplest sort: that between youth and age. Where the Buid are uncomfortable with and play down the dependency of children on adults, the [Jongot emphasi ze it and play around with the opposition between the passion of youth and the knowledge of age. Inside the hou se men tl1 ydek [commandJ women, who in tmn pass their commands on to children, and children are quick to tl1ydek those who are younger than themselves. The dynamics of tl1ydek tend ultimately to permit all adults the ordedy poi se of the platform - while requests for betel, food, tool s, and water set childrcn in almost continuous motion across the relativelv unordered Hoor. (M. Rosa ldo 1980: 72) . The impetus toward violence comes from the fact that yo ung men must pro ve their passion, or aggressiveness, in order to acquire a wife and gain the respect of other adult meno Of coursc, in dail y life, unmarried youths are the subordinates of thcir established scniors. Though free to move and to resist requests that contradict their plans and wis hes, young men lack wives and gardens of their own and so are subject to "commands" (tl1ydek) by seni or kinfolk in whose households they reside. Adult men may decide to "Iend" the labor of their sons, and thus affinn their ti es of kinship and concern with their adult fellows. (M. Rosaldo 1980: 155) With marriage as with beheading, thc youth transforms his social self by demonstrating that he is an "equal" - dependent on no other man, and equivalent, in "angry" force, to al!. (Ibid: 165) Among the !longot, then, courting is associated with aggression. In line with the cultural idealization of males as warriors is a relati"cly greater elaboration of gender symbolism, in which tbe sexual division of labor is more explicit, and the inability of women to scale the same heights of achievement as men is stressed. MicheJle Rosaldo (1980) points out that the ideal of autonomy among the !longot applies less to individual s than to households. Divorce is rare and a cause for violence (pp. 8, I n). Women are exchanged in marriage by men, and are always under their authority (p. 84). Ilongot men must acquirc control over a woman to become autonomous, and until they do they are dependent on th e men who already control 134 Raiding, trading and tribal al1tomony women. Thi s notion that one must gain control over women leads to a rel uctance to relinquish control over them, unless it be in return for control over another. Thus Ilongot youths reae! aggressively to the suitors of their sisters. Because marrying, Iike beheading, provides young men with terms that will define their adult status, all men of a cohort may find themselves caught up in fights concerning women - and it is not smpris ing that Ilongots oft en allay the liget I."pass ion" or "aggression"] sparked by marriage with an "exchange" of maiden "sisters". . (p. 170) Tbe notion that marriage is a strenuous achievement, rather than a natural result of physical maturation, parallels the need to achieve equali ty with adult men through acts of bra very and violence. The Ilongot economy is built around a symbolic opposition between the "eoll ective" activity of men in hunting, meat distribution and pollardi ng the trees in swiddens, and the "individual" activity of \\lomen in planting, weeding and harvesting rice in swiddens (R. Rosaldo 1981 ). While women probabl y cooperate with one another as much as do men, "women's cooperative labor is seen as casual and informal, deserving neither cclebratory feasting nor other public note" (M. Rosaldo 1980: 133). Thc llongot hold a "cultural view of rice as private produce, the fruit of individual effort in a private field" (M. Rosaldo 1980: 133). Hunting, on the other hand, even though it is often carried out by individ uals for the private sale of meat in the market, is always bound up witb the public domain; game is either traded with outsiders or shared withi n the group: it is never intended for consumption by a single llOusehold . And the reluctance ofIl ongots to talk about inequality of skill among hunters is rooted in a view of game as a collective product, publicly appropriate amI consumed. (I bid: 118) Adults both refu sed to boast about how much ga me they had bagged , and persisted in maintaining thei r doctrine that no man was a more gifted ht1 ntsman than another ... Men who found themsel ves again and again compelled to coopera te on short-term projects fe lt they could not enlist the aid of men who St008 aboye or below them upon any imagined ladder. Onl y equals, as thev 5aw it, could work toget her in improvi sed and coordinated hamlOny. (R. Rosaldo 1980: 145-46) This brings us to what rsee as the peculiaritv of the ll ongot among all the Southeast Asan societies so far descri bed, and which disposes me to place them in a class on their own. Thcy place enormous stress on 135 THO M AS G IBSO N achi evcl11e nt and competiti on, and yet they regul ate these types of bcha\'i or in such a way that inequalih' cloes not res ult o That is, for thc Il ongot, ac hi evement is not a matter of "more or less," but of "whethcr or not ": wheth er or not a man has taken a head , acquired a \Vife, provid ecl JOeat for the settlement. Having acquired the status of adult- hood, there are no furth er statuses to be attained, onl y the one to be maintained. For not onl y must equality be achi eved in th e first instan ce, it is a fragil e thing whi ch is constantl y being put in question. :\ dail y \Vorld in whieh autonomous and equaJ adults engage in eoopcrati\'e interaction is ShO\\'ll , through oratory, to be as fragile as it oft en is ' .. (:-VI. RosaJdo 1980: 220'1 Oratory is the domaill in which the Il ongot pl ay around with the notion of dyad ic excha nge and the danger of imbalances between equal s whi ch may result from it. Oratorical negobati ons are nne of the chi ef cultural mcchanisms used by the ll ongot to define and crea te equality bctween men o They are designed to move fr om a situabon in which neg;, tive reciprocity obtains between fe uding groups, through the bal anced reciproci ty of negoti ati on to the generali zed reciprocity of the ki lI group, They requi re two balanced groups to even be initiated: if one group is much stronger than its enemy, it si mpl y absorbs it or hounds it out of exi stell ce , Formal eovenant appears, in short, to requi re an equaJity of diffcrcllce, strength, and "anger" . , . Although covenants by th emselves do not neeess itate further dealings, marri ages over time provide th e groun ds for future visits and eooperati on; as sueh, they eonstitute a sort of transiti on fr om a state of di ffe renee and balaneed oppos iti on to one of mu tuality and aekno\\'l edgcd bonds ([ bid: 210-11) It is as if Bui d-type rul es of sharing and the repression of aggression are foll owed within Il ongot berta n (l iterall )' , "groups of peopl e of one kincl ," label ed by the Rosaldos' "bilateral descent groups"). But where the Btlid oppose the operati on of these \ ;]ues wi thin their own society to the contraIS values operative in lo",land Christi an society, the two \'alue systems operate in differcnt social si tuati ons within Il ongot society. Aggression, exchangc, and potcntial debt are Il ot evil per se in Ilongot society, They are inevitable chardcteri sti cs of d stage in the maJe I1ongot's li fe cvel e, as he seeks to acquire a \Vi fe , pro\'e his abilih to defend hi s dutonomy, and cooperate \\' ith adll lt men as an equal. '['bey are bal anced by the knowledge, mutualih Jll d acknowledged equality of adlllts, 136 F\a iding, tradi ng and tribal autonomy The Il ongot have dn econol1l v \vhich stresscs tbe alltonomy of the household as opposed to the individual or the commlll1ity more strongly than the Buid, Their politi cal S)'stCIll also binds an indi\ icl ual to hi s "kin" group h) opposing it to other potent iJl ly hostile "ki n" grollpS, Whcrc the BlIid see competiti on as leacl ing to the eventual cl ominati on of one party over th e other, and so necessa ril y evil , thc Il ongot vi ew compctiti on as a necessary stage in the achi evement of ecuality. Jt mar be noted that the Ilongot live at thc headwaters of the largest ri,'cr in Luzon, as far from the coast as one can geL Slave raiding \Vas not the pers istent threat in thi s area that it \\'as throughollt thc Visavan islands to the south , The onl y society in nort hern LlIzon whi ch chattel slavcs was the Bengll et, where thcy \Vere employecl for mine labor. Raiding tllfoughout the highl ands of northern LlI zon was alwavs more ritual and political than economi c in moti ve: it was heads and rcvcnge that warri ors desired, not pri soners to keep or trade as sla ves. 1t is al so possibl e that trade has not pl ayed as important a rol e in Il ongot hi story as it has in soeieti es cl oscr to the coast. Aside fr om scattered references to the sale of game, the Rosaldos make littl e menti on of trdde, or depcncl cncy on tradi ng partners, In sum, 1 would argue that the lIongot represents a society which bas not cl eveloped the sa me absolute rejecbon of violence/raidi ng and debt/tradi ng as ha\e the Buicl , and that thcre is less e\' icl cll ce of the presence of the in thcir symbol ic life, due tu their relative isolati on from the Ill aritime \Vorld , The l ban The Iba n are vigorous traders and raiders, as their bi story attests (Pringle 1970). As Sahl ins (1972: 224- 226) has argued, they are unusual for "tri bal" people in keeping an exact account of lahor exchanged bet\\'een households, and in limiting the sharing of staple food surpluses, This is because lhe latter must be stored up for tracle \\'i th outsiders, Asicl e from other fu nctions, the acqui si ti on of prestige goods such as jars and gongs in traJe al so serves as a buffer <lgai nst a poor ri ce ha rn st: Each scason, sorne slIeceed in producing a surpJus, whil e othcrs fi nd Ihernselves wi th a defi cit; farnili es exehange gongs ror ri cel. or [rice! for gongs , Ja rs (l a;au), though to a lll ueh lesser (', tent, are ll seJ in the salllc \\'ay, Aga in, Ill onev - obtaincd from the marketing of rorest produce - is often llScd to purcha"e rice , , (Freeman 1970: 267) 13:- THOMAS C IBSON The Iban method of shifting cultivation is such that the labor of young men is only reguired for hvo or three months ayear. The domestic group, or bilek usually contains enough women and older men to free young men for the acti vihes of tradi ng and raiding, or bejalai (Freeman 1970: 222- 24). The Iban live al ong large, navigable rivers and possess a fair degree of maritime skil!. This meant that they are likel y to have been more intensively in volved in mari time trade than mountain dwellers, and are thus somewhat more sophisticated. But it al so gave them the ability to mobilize much larger numbers of people than shifting cultivators inhabiting rugged mountain tenain. At the same time, th ey had to auopt more aggressive tactics in their own defen se. In the nineteenth century they were able to put thousands of warri ors to sea in war boats holding 60 to 100 men cacho They are reported to have served as mercenaries in IIl an un war Aeets, the most fea red slave raiders in al! of Southeast Asi a, although later th ey beca me their bitter enemies (Pringle 1970: 50-5 3, 76). They have gone from being the must successful and expansi.onist warriors of Sarawak, during the nineteenth century, sweeping all other shifting cultivators before them, to being widel y traveled migrant traders and laborers in the twenti eth: For Iban young men then (a nd particul arl y since the cessati on ofheadh unting), going on journeys is the grca test and most consuming interest life has to offcr . . . the most powerful incentt ve is the very considerable social prestige which a much-traveled ma n can commancl . Above all , it is only after having accompli shed Ill any successful journe)'s that ama n begins the performance of the seri cs of elaborate rituals (all based on the instituti on ofheadhunting) which confer prestige in middl e and old age. (Frceman 1970: 222-24) T radi honall y, Whcn he had takcn a head, and only then, was an Iba n male entitled to havc the back ofhis hands tatooed. With this achi eved, hi s pro\Vess was on constant display . .. A successflll young head-hunter, it is sa id , could have his pi ck oftllc most desirabl e young women, and \Vas mllch sought after as a husband. In contrast, aman whu had nc\ cr taken a head, or who \Vas kn own to be rc1uctant in battl e. woul d bc told b, t:1C \Vomen he courted: ... "FiTSt scale the posts of an enemy 10ng-holl se; firstbedcck your ha ir as does he who has taken a hcad." (Freeman 1979: 238) Vi olence and aggression were directly Iinked to courting, and head- hunting itself was preliminary to a ritual intended to secure both fe rti lity 138 Raiding, trading and tribal autonomy and prestige fo r its mal e sponsor. These head-hunting ritual s are "occasians for the celebrati an of the preoccupati ons and the narcissism of mcn" ([' recman 1968: 388). The lbans are known to have takcn their enemies capti ve for sale or ransom, as \Vell as merely taking their heads. But there was no place in Iban ~ o i e t y for a class of hercditarv sl aves. Freeman presen ts convine- ing argu ments that war eapti ves \\'ere not incorporated as a permanent stratum in Iban society, but were either ransomed or adopted into a bilek. thc fundamental corporate group, as cqual members, with egual rights to inheritance. ' nlC Cllstom of rituall y enfranchising and adopting capti ves takcn in war, which was integral to thc tradi ti onal society of Iban, is a striking expression of their cgalitaritl Il values. (Freeman 198 1: 47; cf. Rousseau 1980: 59) Olle must not gel carried away, however, in cxtolling Iban "egalitarianism" sim ply beca use unequal statuses were not, in princ ipIe, hereditary. Blek units maintained careful aecounts of labor crcdits anu debits between each other, and if an individual or hi s bilek eould not repay a debt, he might be obliged to pay the debt "in part or in wholc by the labor ofhimself or others ofhis bilek" (Freeman 1981 : 49). At thc other end of the ladJ er of achi cvcment, \vas the raja brani, literally, "ri eh and brave man ": Once he had succeeded in taking a trophy heaJ , a warri or was entitl ed to tatl oo on the backs of his hands, and hus adorned he could, if he had also amassed sufficient \\'ealth, come lo be recogni zed as raja brani . This, howc\'Cr , was not the ene! to an ambiti ous incli vi dual's quest for reknown, for there was <lI so in Iban culture an ascencling scquence of complex ritual s, or gawai a171 at, spceifi eall y assoc iated \Vilh thc cult ofh cadhunting, tha! he cou ld, ir he chose, pcrform. These gawai a171 at (l it. true rituaJs) were al wa)' s perfo rmcc by indiyiduals . . . Su eh rituals. the more eompl ex of which (lasting for four or five days) dcmanded exlcnsivc rcsourccs, \Ve rc pcrformed beforc and aft er maj or raids, \Vith the celebran! t3king the invocat ion (ti171ang) a stagc furthcr on each occasiOIl unti l, over a span of fort)' or more \'cars, the sequence 'Nas complete. (fi' recman 1981 : 40) Even ritual Me. then, is eharacterized hy a hierarchy of achi eved statuscs. Shamans fall into three classes: "raw" or novi ce, "ripe" or full y ini tialcd, and "transfo rmed" or transvestite. Frecman describeu the boasts of onc master shaman, and his denigration of the abilities of all others (Freeman J967: 320). Al though skill in rice cultivation \\'3S important to a man's prcsti ge, it 139 GIBSO N is primaril y success in competitive and violent endeavors away from the longhouse that is the measure of prestige within it. Internal ranking is the resu lt of mastering an external realm of activity. The Iban sce themselves as predators of the outside world: of neighboring tri bes, whom they raid for heads; ofthe environment, whose virgin forests the\' cut down; of the regional economy, in which they eam wages for brief spclls befor e retuming home. They stand in marked contrast to the BlIid, who see themseh-es as the prey of the olltside world. In short, while the Bll id got the \Vorst of the regional system of trading and raiding, the Iban thrived on t. The Iban ma)' be said to ha\'c a politi cal economy which maximi zes the autonomy of a domestic group (bilek), fr ees men for raiding and trad ing by assigning most of the agriclIlturallabor to th e femal e members of th e bilek, and allows for the temporar)' organiza tion of largc groups of men under charismatic individual s, \Vho lead their follo\Vers on trading expeditions, migrations to new river bas ins, and on headhunting expeditions (F' reeman 1981: 35-36). The over-all ethos is one of achie\' ed ranking. Every individual is expected to prove himsel f, but there is a fin ely graded ladder of achievement, with the ranking of individuals according to merit the ultimate goal. AN O 1'0 sllmmari ze: the Buid rej ect an)' form of violence, aggression, or e\-en competition. Among the Buid, cIen quarr eling is thought to ha\'(: mysti call y dan gerous eonsequences for the vitality of both hllmans and crops. The !l ongot and the Iban stress the competit ive achievement of status by typically engaging in sporadi c, violent assa ults on members of neighboring soci eties in order both to demonstrate the virility of their male members and to acquir e mysti cal vitality by obtaining heads. The stress on individual achievement also lends a rather c)'clic charactcr to violen ce in these societies. Raiding parties are organized by ambitious individual s more or less according to whim 1M. Rosaldo 1980: 139; Frceman 198 1: 36). As a reslllt, rncrnbers of thesc societies hal'c historicall y acquired a great deal of notor et)' as headhunters. AIl these societies represent specialized adaptations to the regional polti eal economy. Al! lad instituted hierarchy. The cxtreme empllJsi s on indi vidu al autonomy and rejcction of super-household allt]ority evident among them must bc seen as a rejcct ion of the poltiC:J1 \alues of I-H) Raidlng, trading and tribal autonom y thcir predatory lowland neighbors Far fr om cOll stituting primordi al classless societies, they must be seen as political groups whi ch have been able to mai ntain significant degrees of autonomy only by developi'lg special social mechani sms for evading control by the lowh: .ds. '1 'he are neithcr pri stine tribesmen, nor are they, to borrow a phrase from Fox's argument concerning South 1ndian hunter-ga thers, mere adjuncts of agrarian sta tes (Fox 1969). Fo:>. and Gardner (1966) argue that the central features of South Asian hunter-gatherer societies are attributable to their enclavcment within agraria n states. These features include highl y migratory indi vidual s, a stress on individual autonom)', and a va lue system which condemns aggress ion and competi tion. These features make them clearly compar- able lo the Buid. Fox and Gardner go on, however, to characte ri ze these societi es as non-cooperative and as lacking sharing or reciprocity between fa mil )' groups. This secms to be rather an exaggeration, for as among most hunter-gatherer groups, even in South India , meat whi ch is not traded is shared out equally among all members of a camp, while gathcred vegetable foods are retained within the famil y (Gardner 1972: 41 5; Morris 1977: 231; Ro)' 1925: 69- 88) l'\ evertheless, it remains possible that the expos ure of the South Asian hunter-gatherers to a dense, fixed-fi eld agricultural populati on has pl aced them under greater inter-cultural pressure than the Southeast Asian highlanders exposed onl)' to the sporad ic interventions of the coastal trade-ori ented states. Onc result of such pressure might be a necess it)' to further intensify individual mobility and to further dimini sh the sizc of sharing groups. Mobility and sharing are mutuall y reinforcing institutions and serve as a highl y cffective mcafls of evading control by neighbors who cannot be resi sted mil itaril y. As I ha ve argued above, shar ing is characterized by a radical disconnection between giver and recipi ent. It is this character- istic lack of strong dyadic bonds which has led writers like Gardner to characterize mem bers of societies organized around sharing as "atom- iSlic." But if one looks at sharing in terms of the moral bonds which llnite the individual to the group, this characterization appears inadequate. These bonds are often emphasi zed in collective rituals. which act out the mystical dependcncv of the individual on the group. Therc are many ins<lllces of socicties in highland Southeast Asia whose members are rcpcatcdly dcseribed in the literature as being systematicall y cheated of the Illarkct pricc of the produce the\ bring to trade, and as beng perlT1 <Jllcntly incl cbted to lowland trad c.rs. lndeed, 141 THOMAS CISSON these forest dwellers are often called by a term which means "sIave" or debt slave, e.f;. Sakai for the Orang Asli, Ata, Aeta or Agta for the Philippine ),egritos, and .\Jangyan for the highlanders of Mindoro. Since the lowlanders aIready regard the members of these groups as debt slaves, it would be fatal for those people themselves to acknowledge the principIe of debt. These societies thus reject, ofien explicitly, the mast fundamental principIe of lowland state societies: dyadic dependencv phrased in an idiom or moral and material indebtedness . . Individual mobility and a systein of sharing which allows people to enter into immediate social relations without regard to past transactions are t\vo essential features ofBuid society. But the rejection of attempts to acquire prestige through acts of violence or through feast sponsorship sets the Buid off from the IIongot and Iban as well . Among the Buid, the symbolic equation of violence and dominance with life threatening external forces is so complete that the central life generating rituals of the !longot and Iban are negated: headhunting and the competitivc sacrificing of large animals. Where animal sacrifice is carried out, it is done in as non-aggressive a manner as possible. The Buid share with the Ilongot and Iban a refusal to grant political power to any individual or office in their respective societies. It has been remarked again and again that the most "conserva ti ve" cultural groups are those which lack internal stratification: finding no point of appli- cation within the enclaved society on which to apply pressure, external agencies must try to control members of the former one by one. Colonial states confronted with such a society, tried to create "chiefs" where none had existed, usually with little success (see, for example, the appointment of Iban penghulu , "headmen, " by the Brookes [Pringle, 1970: 157]). In the extreme case of the Buid, even boastful behavior is seen as immora!. It is quite inaccurate to characterize members of such cultures as "submissive": they do not respond to attcIlIpts to dominate them with violen ce as do !longot and Iban, but they are just as insistcnt on the maintenance of their personal autonomy . Buid will ofien resort to suicide if imprisoned by the state, or even threatened with imprison- mento They will not voluntarily work for wages, disliking being placed in a position where they must obey the will of another. They \ViII, however, at times render labor at absurdly low rates of remuneration as a sort of tribute to lowland patrons who furnish them sorne protectian against the more violent elemcllts of the lowland population. It is when groups ofhighlanders engagcdl in a sulDsistcl'lce systcm sueh 142 Raiding, trading and tribal autonomy as hunting and gathering or shifting cultivation are brought into unavoidable confrontation with the members of aggressive state systems rhal om: is most likely to find Buid-type systems developing. The mode of subsisten ce must be compatible with a certain degree of mobility, and the highlanders must inhabit a tenain sufficiently resistent to eas)' penetration by subjects oflowland states to make this cultural adaptation feasi ble. It is not unlikely that all the formerIy autonomous societies in sim ila rIy exposed geographicallocations which had an internally ranked structure have long since been incorporated into the hierarchical state systems of the lowlands, and that the autonomous groups which have survived have done so beca use they possessed an ideology which rejected any form of dominance. CONCLUSIONS The argument of this paper is that any explanation of the role of violence and domination in the social lives of insular Southeast Asia shifting cultivators must be sought in terms of their relations to the regional politica! economy. This relation is inAuenced by their geographical situati ons, and their consequent degree of exposure to the trading and raiding economy of the region. But it is impossible to argue that their idcologies are "caused" in any sense by their own subsistence economies or by their role in the larger regional system. It is possible to argue, howevcr, that their continued existence as autonomous political and cultural groups can be explained in terms of their development of ideologies appropriate to that end, given their different geographical situati ons. G roups which failed to develop appropriate ideologies were either absorbed into lowland states or eliminated. There remains an urgcn t need to understand the interaction of societies with autonomous ideologies and value systems in a common regional economy, without eithcr reducing these ideologies to epiphenomena of the wider s)'stem, or ignoring the real effects of commodity relations and milita!)' force Upon the component societies in thc regional system. 'fhe argument in this paper addresses the question of the "causes" of war and peace in Southeast Asia in a manner very different to the many of the papers in this volume. In conclusion, 1 would like brieAy to indicate sorne of the areas of disagreement, and the implications these have for our understanding of human violen ce and war in general. Somc writers view war as a natural phenomenon, susceptible of I-B THOMAS GIBSO N explanation in terrn s of universallaws, rather than of parti cular histori- cal dc\ dopments. Their tendency is to look for pan-human drivcs to rnaximize either inclusi ve fitness (Chagnon, thi s volurn e), or access to natural resources (Ferguson, Haas, thi s voJume). Thcse attempts to treat a socio-hi storical phenomenon in naturali sti c tcrms have familiar effects: sine: war is assumed to always derive from the sarne essential cause, it is treated as a single , unitary phenornenon, easil y identifiabl e across time and space. What is needed, rather, is an atternpt to differentiate types of inter-group viol ence, and to recogni ze that each t:pe may require an entirel y different sort of theory to account for it. As Ferguson (thi s vol ume) notes, questions about war and viol enee var)' depending 011 th e broader theoretical context in whi ch they are asked. If they are asked in the context of individual motivations or sentiments, such as aggression, there will be a tendency to concentrate on either biological or psychological issues, whi ch have a timeless universal quality. If they are rai sed in the context of a struggl e for scarcc resources , between evenl y balanced opponents, there is a tendeney to vi ew it as a game betwcen pl aye rs who begin as equ als and onl y end as "winner" al1 d "Ioser. " There is a reduction of inter-group violence to timel ess questi ons of ta ctics and strateg)', of"game theory. " Focusi ng on aggression and focusing on scarcity are both conduci ve to a view of viol ent conAi ct as somchow pathological , the product of maladaptive personality or social structures. Violence is both an inevitabl e and an evil part of the human condition. In this paper, violence has been di scussed in relation to exploitation and to ritual. This approach highlights the rol e of vi plence in what is perhaps its most preva k nt and sigllificant form since the origin of sta tes and classes: the exploitation of a \\caker group - class, gen der. ethnicit)', nati on, race- by a stronger group. In thi s view, viol ence and war ar e not "about" natural scarcity or indi vidual sentiments, but "about" socially- produced surpluses (for some) and scarciti cs (for the others). Occasional c1ashes betwecn the ruling elites operating two parall el systems of exploi tati on, which is the normal subject of in vestigati ons of "war," l11a: ' then be seen for what it is: a subsidiar)' and intermittant form of violence. Furtherrnore, for the group whi ch profits from the \iolcnce built into a system, violence will be seen as anything but a ll egati\c phenomenon. It \Vill , 011 the contrary, be eelcbrated and glorifi ed. This brings li S to the question of ri tual. Violence in any society \\iJl be I-H Raiding, trading and tribal autonomy assigncd a \ alue, and it \Vill h, ve different values in different situati ons. Very rarel y is it seen as evil in all situati ons, although the Buid provide a rare case in which it is. In political economies based on the coe rei ve exlraction of surplus value from neighboring soci eti es, inter-group vi olell ce may even be feti shi zed as a product of mysti cal vitality in itself. ' ''hus violence is neit] er a necessary part of social life, nor is it nccessaril y seen as an evil: there are societi es whi eh systematically deva lue it, just as there are soci eti es, or ruling groups within societies, which vi c\\ it as the ultimate good when exerci sed in appropri ate contcxts against thc right opponents. Notes 1 Thi s paper is based on researeh earried out among the Buid in the ficldfrom 1979 to 198 1, andagai n in 1985, andonlibrary research cOIlJueted in 1985-b6. The second peri od in the fi eld and the li bra ry rescareh was fu nded by the Harr y Frank Cuggenheim Foundati on. Different versions ofthi s paper ha ve becll prcsented at the confcrence 0 11 the Anthropology of War hclJ at the School of Ameri ca n Researeh, at the Scminar on Eql1ali ty and Incqua li ty held by the London School of <, conomi cs Department of Social Anthropology, and in the Coll oquiulll of the Department of Anthropology of the Uni versity of Roehester. 1 hi s draft has benefited from corn mellts by parti cipants in a11 these lTleetings, and from detail ed comments by Wli alTl Henrv Scott, Mauri ee Bl oeh, and !erome Rousseau. My thanks to all of th em. Whi le 1 have not al ways foll oweJ their adviee, 1 have allVays found it stimulating. 1-+5