Government-Sponsored Enterprises (Gses) : An Institutional Overview
Government-Sponsored Enterprises (Gses) : An Institutional Overview
Government-Sponsored Enterprises (Gses) : An Institutional Overview
Summary
Congress chartered government-sponsored enterprises (GSEs) to improve the
workings of credit markets. This report briefly describes the nature of GSEs, their
mixed governmental-private nature, the differences between GSEs and government
agencies, and concerns about and supporting arguments for GSEs. This report will be
updated as events warrant.
CRS Report RL30533, The Quasi Government: Hybrid Organizations with Both Government
and Private Sector Legal Characteristics, by Kevin R. Kosar.
CRS-2
(B) (i) does not exercise powers that are reserved to the Government as sovereign
(such as the power to tax or to regulate interstate commerce);
(ii) does not have the power to commit the Government financially (but it may
be a recipient of a loan guarantee commitment made by the Government); and
(iii) has employees whose salaries and expenses are paid by the enterprise and
are not Federal employees subject to title 5.2
Few scholars of public administration and finance are likely to argue that this definition
is incorrect. However, some have argued that the above definition omits an essential
characteristic a GSE benefits from an implicit federal guarantee to enhance its ability
to borrow money.3
Each GSE is created by Congress with its particular attributes defined in its enabling
legislation and charter. Despite this diversity, there are at least four readily observable
characteristics of GSEs: (1) private sector ownership, (2) limited competition, (3)
activities limited by congressional charter, and (4) chartered privileges that create an
inferred federal guarantee of obligations.
This flexibility has led to controversies. For example, some have argued that GSEs compensate
their executives too generously. Terence OHara, Exit Packages in Dispute at Fannie Mae,
Washington Post, December 28, 2004, p. E1.
CRS-3
GSEs are not banks, credit unions, or savings and loans associations. Excepting the
Farm Credit Banks, none of the GSEs lends money directly to members of the public.
GSEs are for-profit financial entities that provide capital market liquidity. To these ends,
GSEs (to varying degrees) issue capital stock and short- and long-term debt instruments,
guarantee mortgage-backed securities (MBS), purchase loans and hold them in their own
portfolio, fund related activities, and collect fees for guarantees and other services.7
U.S. General Accounting Office, Financial Services Institutions: Information for Assessing the
Governments Potential Financial Exposure, GAO/GGD-98-125 (Washington: GAO, 1998), p.
3.
The other two GSEs the Financing Corporation and the Resolution Funding Corporation
are funding shells, not operating companies. They were given GSE status so that their funding
would not appear to be federal borrowing for purposes of the federal budget. The Student Loan
Marketing Association (Sallie Mae) was not included in the list because it shed its GSE
designation and became the entirely private SLM Corporation in 2004.
CRS-4
government sponsorship. Their securities can collateralize public deposits (e.g., Social
Security Administration and state and local government deposits) and can be held in
unlimited amounts by most banks and thrifts. With one exception (Farmer Mac), they sell
securities to the public without registering them with the Securities and Exchange
Commission, and their corporate earnings are exempt from state and local income taxes,
the latter practice attracting particular controversy.9 All but one (Farm Credit System)
have a line of credit with the Treasury. These statute-created benefits create an inferred
federal guarantee; that is, investors act as if they believe that the federal government
would make good on GSEs debts and obligations in the event of a failure.
Recently, Freddie Mac and Fannie Mae agreed to register voluntarily with the Securities and
Exchange Commission (SEC). See CRS Report RS21263, Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, and SEC
Registration and Disclosures, by Mark Jickling and Barbara Miles.
10
Fannie Mae has suggested that its special GSE status lowers the cost of a home loan by a
quarter to a half of a percent, which means that 400,000 families qualified for mortgages that
would not have otherwise. See Fannie Mae advertisement, Washington Post, May 11, 1999, p.
A5. The Secretary of Housing and Urban Development disagrees. [N]umerous HUD studies
and independent analyses have shown that the GSEs have historically lagged the primary market
instead of led it with respect to funding mortgage loans for low-income and minority home
buyers. Statement of Mel Martinez, Secretary of the Department of Housing, and Urban
Development before U.S. Congress, Senate Committee on Banking, Housing and Urban Affairs,
October 16, 2003, p. 3, available at [http://banking.senate.gov/_files/martinez.pdf].
CRS-5
government backing of Fannie Mae as sufficient indication of the quality of Fannie
Mae obligations.11
This impression of federal backing has been encouraged by the federal governments past
actions. For example, when the Farm Credit System was in crisis in the late 1980s, the
federal government arranged a bailout.12
Hybrid Nature. GSEs are chartered for a public purpose but are privately owned,
for-profit firms. As an instrumentality, the GSE is to serve the public good; yet, the
primary accountability of GSE management is not to the federal government or the public,
but to owners of GSE stock and securities. As a chief executive officer of Sallie Mae
once told a Senate oversight subcommittee, We are a private corporation and as such,
with stockholders and bondholders, we have a fiduciary responsibility to those
individuals.13 Indeed, the recent managerial turnover at Freddie Mac and Fannie Mae
was due, in great part, to its use of inaccurate accounting methods to report earnings that
are attractive to investors.14 The for-profit nature of the GSE also means it has incentives
to seek profits in product and service markets outside its government charter.15
Size and Systemic Risk. GSEs, in fact, are among the largest financial
institutions in the United States. Investors inference of federal backing is one factor that
has enabled GSEs to grow rapidly; on average, the combined size of Fannie Mae and
Freddie Mac has more than doubled every five years since 1968.16 For example, the
combined debt outstanding of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac is approximately $1.7 trillion
in 2004. The Federal Home Loan Bank System had $754 billion in consolidated debt
outstanding in 2003.17 GSE securities are held by both U.S. and foreign banks and
financial institutions. Therefore, some observers believe the failure of a GSE has the
11
12
On the rescue of the Farm Credit System, see U.S. General Accounting Office, Farm Credit
System: Repayment of Federal Assistance and Competitive Position, GAO/GGD-94-39
(Washington: DC 1994).
13
Statement of Edward A. Fox, President and CEO of Sallie Mae, before U.S. Senate,
Committee on Labor and Human Resources, Subcommittee on Education, Arts, and Humanities,
Oversight of Student Loan Marketing Association (Sallie Mae), hearings, 102nd Cong., 2nd sess.
(Washington: GPO, 1982), p. 135.
14
See CRS Report RS21567, Accounting and Management Problems at Freddie Mac, by Mark
Jickling; and CRS Report RS21949, Accounting Problems at Fannie Mae, by Mark Jickling.
15
For example, GSEs used their government privileges to raise funds for nonmortgage
investments, a policy that has attracted the attention of GAO. See U.S. General Accounting
Office, Federal Oversight Needed in Nonmortgage Investments, GAO/GGD-98-48 (Washington:
GAO, 1998).
16
Office of Federal Housing Oversight, 2005 Report to Congress (Washington: OFHEO, June
15, 2005), p. 63; and website of the Federal Home Loan Banks, Office of Finance
[http://www.fhlb-of.com/issuance/debt_outstanding.html].
CRS-6
potential to create worldwide, destructive spillover effects.18 Moreover, the larger a GSE
grows, the more difficult it becomes to end its government charter without disruptions to
capital markets.
Subsidization. GSEs borrow money at significantly lower interest rates than
competitors because of the inferred federal guarantee and the government-bestowed
privileges. Collectively, then, the federal government effectively subsidizes GSEs. The
Congressional Budget Office estimated this subsidy to be over $13.5 billion in the year
2000 alone.19 This situation generates a number of issues. The first is the equity issue.
Specifically, critics question whether it is fair for government to give GSEs an advantage
over private banking firms.20 The second matter is the question of continued government
intervention. Again, the goal of each of these GSEs was to overcome barriers to the free
flow of credit. Once these barriers have been removed, observers ask if extensive
government intervention (in the form of a GSE) in the market is still appropriate. Critics
of continued GSE existence argue that GSEs should be graduated into private status (as
was done with Sallie Mae).21 Third, and relatedly, is the question of efficiency. The
financial landscape has been dramatically altered by nationwide banking, better access to
capital markets by housing and farm interests, and a huge increase in consumer debt
financing. Thus, the subsidies conferred on housing and agriculture through GSEs come
into question.
18
For example, see International Monetary Fund, Global Financial Stability Report, September
2003, available at [http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/GFSR/2003/02/index.htm].
19
Congressional Budget Office, Federal Subsidies and the Housing GSEs: Subsidies in 2000
(Washington: CBO, 2001), p. 2.
20
U.S. Congressional Budget Office, Assessing the Public Costs and Benefits of Fannie Mae and
Freddie Mac (Washington: CBO, 1996), p. xii. Private companies further complain that the
government-conferred privileges of GSEs inhibit private competition against GSEs.
21
Peter J. Wallison et al., Privatizing Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, and the Federal Home Loan
Banks: How and Why (Washington: The AEI Press, 2004).
22