Lect Notes 3

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 63

Lecture Notes 3

Approximation Methods
In this chapter, we deal with a very important problem that we will encounter
in a wide variety of economic problems: approximation of functions. Such
a problem commonly occurs when it is too costly either in terms of time or
complexity to compute the true function or when this function is unknown
and we just need to have a rough idea of its main properties. Usually the only
thing that is required then is to be able to compute this function at one or a
few points and formulate a guess for all other values. This leaves us with some
choice concerning either the local or global character of the approximation
and the level of accuracy we want to achieve. As we will see in different
applications, choosing the method is often a matter of efficiency and ease of
computing.
Following Judd [1998], we will consider 3 types of approximation methods
1. Local approximation, which essentially exploits information on the value
of the function in one point and its derivatives at the same point. The
idea is then to obtain a (hopefully) good approximation of the function
in a neighborhood of the benchmark point.
2. Lp approximations, which actually find a nice function that is close to
the function we want to evaluate in the sense of a Lp norm. Ideally, we
would need information on the whole function to find a good approximation, which is usually infeasible or which would make the problem
1

of approximation totally irrelevant! Therefore, we usually rely on interpolation, which then appears as the other side of the same problem, but
only requires to know the function at some points.
3. Regressions, which may be viewed as an intermediate situation between
the two preceding cases, as it usually relies exactly as in econometrics,
on m moments to find n parameters of the approximating function.

3.1

Local approximations

The problem of the local approximation of a function f : R R is to make

use of information about the function at a particular point x0 R, to produce


a good approximation of f in a neighborhood of x0 . Among the various
available method 2 are of particular interest: the Taylor series expansion and
Pade approximation.

3.1.1

Taylor series expansion

Taylor series expansion is certainly the most wellknown and natural approximation to any student.
The basic framework: This approximation relies on the standard Taylors
theorem:
Theorem 1 Suppose F : R R is a C k+1 function, then for x? Rn , we
have

F (x) = F (x? ) +
+

1
2

n
X

1
k!

n
X
F ?
(x )(xi x?i )
xi

i=1
n
X

i=1 i1 =1
n
X

F
(x? )(xi1 x?i1 )(xi2 x?i2 ) + . . .
xi1 xi2
n
X

F
(x? )(xi1 x?i1 ) . . . (xik x?ik )
xi1 . . . xi1
i1 =1
ik =1

+O kx x? kk+1
+

...

The idea of Taylor expansion approximation is then to form a polynomial


approximation of the function f as described by the Taylors theorem. This
approximation method therefore applies to situations where the function is at
least n times differentiable to get a nth order approximation. If this is the

case, then we are sure that the error will be at most of order O kx x? kk+1 .1 .
In fact, we may look at Taylor series expansion from a slightly different

perspective and acknowledge that it amounts to approximate the function by


an infinite series. For instance in the one dimensional case, this amounts to
write
F (x) '
where k =

1 F
?
k! xi (x ).

n
X
k=0

k (x x? )k

As n tends toward infinity, the latter equation may be

understood as a power series expansion of the F in the neighborhood of x ? .


This is a natural way to think of this type of approximation if we just think of
the exponential function for instance, and the way a computer delivers exp(x).
Indeed, the formal definition of the exponential function is traditionally given
by
exp(x)

X
xk
i=0

k!

The advantage of this representation is that we are now in position to give


a very important theorem concerning the relevance of such approximation.
Nevertheless, we need to report some preliminary definitions.
Definition 1 We call the radius of convergence of the complex power series,
the quantity r defined by

k x k <
r = sup |x| :

k=0

r therefore provides the maximal radius of x C for which the complex series
converges. That is for any x C such that |x| < r, the series converges while

it diverges for any x C such that |x| > r.


1


Let us recall at this point that a function f : Rn Rk is O x` if limx0

kf (x)k
kxk`

<

Definition 2 A function F : C C is said to be analytic, if for every

x? there exists a sequence k and a radius r such that


F (x) =

n
X
k=0

k (x x? )k for kx x? k < r

Definition 3 Let F : C C be a function, and x? . x? is a

singularity of F is F is analytic on {x? } but not on .

For example, let us consider the tangent function tan(x). tan(x) is defined by
the ratio of two analytic functions
tan(x) =

sin(x)
cos(x)

since cos(x) and sin(x) may be written as


cos(x) =

(1)n

x2n
(2n)!

(1)n

x2n+1
(2n + 1)!

i=0

sin(x) =

X
i=0

However, the function obviously admits a singularity at x? = /2, for which


cos(x? ) = 0.
Given these definition we can now enounce the following theorem:
Theorem 2 Let F be an analytic function in x C. If F or any derivative

of F exhibits a singularity at xo C, then the radius of convergence in the

complex plane of the Taylor series expansion of F in the neighborhood of x ?

X
1 kF ?
(x )(x x? )k
k! xk
k=0

is bounded from above by kx? xo k.


This theorem is extremely important as it gives us a guideline to use Taylor
series expansions, as it actually tells us that the series at x? cannot deliver
any accurate, and therefore reliable, approximation for F an any point farther
4

away from x? than any singular point of F . An extremely simple example


to understand this point is provided by the approximation of the function
F (x) = log(1 x), where x (, 1), in a neighborhood of x? = 0. First of
all, note that xo = 1 is a singular value for F (x). The Taylor series expansion
of F (x) in the neighborhood of x? = 0 writes
log(1 x) ' (x)

X
xk
k=1

What the theorem tells us is that this approximation may be used for values
of x such that kx x? k is below kx? xo k = k0 1k = 1, that is for x such
that 1 < x < 1. In other words, the radius of convergence of the Taylor

approximation to this function is r = 1. As an numerical illustration, we

report in table 3.1, the true value of log(1 x), its approximate value using

100 terms in the summation, and the absolute deviation of this approximation
from the true value.2 As can be seen from the table, as soon as kx? xo k
approaches the radius, the accuracy of the approximation by the Taylor series
expansion performs more and more poorly.
Table 3.1: Taylor series expansion for log(1 x)
x
-0.9999
-0.9900
-0.9000
-0.5000
0.0000
0.5000
0.9000
0.9900
0.9999

log(1 x)
0.69309718
0.68813464
0.64185389
0.40546511
0.00000000
-0.69314718
-2.30258509
-4.60517019
-9.21034037

100 (x)
0.68817193
0.68632282
0.64185376
0.40546511
0.00000000
-0.69314718
-2.30258291
-4.38945277
-5.17740221

0.00492525
0.00181182
1.25155e-007
1.11022e-016
0
2.22045e-016
2.18735e-006
0.215717
4.03294

2
The word true lies between quotes as it has been computed by the computer and is
therefore an approximation!

The usefulness of the approach:

This approach to approximation is par-

ticularly useful and quite widespread in economic dynamics. For instance,


anyone that has ever tried to study the dynamic properties of any macro
model lets say the optimal growth model has once encountered the
method. Lets take for instance the optimal growth model which dynamics
may be summarized when preferences are logarithmic and technology is
CobbDouglas by the two following equations3
kt+1 = kt ct + (1 )kt

1
1 1
=
kt+1 + 1
ct
ct+1

(3.1)
(3.2)

It is a widespread practice to linearize of loglinearize such an economy around


the steady state, which we will define later on, to study the local dynamic
properties of the equilibrium. Lets assume that the steady state has already
been found and is given by ct+1 = ct = c? and kt+1 = kt = k ? for all t.

let us denote by b
kt the deviation of the capital stock kt with
respect to its steady state level in period t, such that b
kt = kt k ? . Likewise,

Linearization:

we define b
ct = ct c? . The first step of linearization is to reexpress the system

in terms of functions. Here, we can define

F (kt+1 , ct+1 , kt , ct ) =

kt+1 kt + ct (1 )kt

1
ct

and then build the Taylor expansion

1
ct+1
kt+1 + 1

F (kt+1 , ct+1 , kt , ct ) ' F (k ? , c? , k ? , c? ) + F1 (k ? , c? , k ? , c? )b


kt+1 + F2 (k ? , c? , k ? , c? )b
ct+1
3

+F3 (k ? , c? , k ? , c? )b
kt + F4 (k ? , c? , k ? , c? )b
ct

Since we just want to make the case of Taylor series expansions, we do not need to be
any more precise on the origin of these two equations. Therefore, we will take them as given,
but we will come back to their determination in the sequel.

We therefore just have to compute the derivatives of each subfunction, and


realize that the steady state corresponds to a situation where F (k ? , c? , k ? , c? ) =
0. This yields the following system
(
b
kt+1 k ? 1 b
k +b
ct (1 )b
kt = 0
t ? 1

1
1
+1 b
ct+1 c1? ( 1)k ? 2 b
c?2 b
kt+1 = 0
ct + c?2 k
which simplifies to
(
b
kt+1 k ? 1 b
k +b
ct (1 )b
kt = 0
? 1t

?
b
ct + k
+1 b
ct+1 ( 1) kc ? k ? 1 b
kt+1 = 0

We then have to solve the implied linear dynamic system, bu this is another
story that we will deal with in a couple of chapters.

Loglinearization:

Another common practice is to take a loglinear ap-

proximation to the equilibrium. Such an approximation is usually taken because it delivers a natural interpretation of the coefficients in front of the
variables: these can be interpreted as elasticities. Indeed, lets consider the
following onedimensional function f (x) and lets assume that we want to take
a loglinear approximation of f around x? . This would amount to have, as
deviation, a logdeviation rather than a simple deviation, such that we can
define
x
b = log(x) log(x? )

Then, a restatement of the problem is in order, as we are to take an approximation with respect to log(x):

f (x) = f (exp(log(x)))
which leads to the following first order Taylor expansion
f (x) ' f (x? ) + f 0 (exp(log(x? ))) exp(log(x? ))b
x = f (x? ) + f 0 (x? )x? x
b

If we apply this technic to the growth model, we end up with the following
system

b
ct (1 )b
kt = 0
b
ct + b
ct+1 ( 1)(1 (1 ))b
kt+1 = 0

b
kt+1

1(1) b
kt

1(1)

3.2

Regressions as approximation

This type of approximation is particularly common in economics as it just corresponds to ordinary least square (OLS) . As you know the problem essentially
amounts to approximate a function F by another function G of exogenous variables. In other words, we have a set of observable endogenous variables y i ,
i = 1 . . . N , which we are willing to explain in terms of the set of exogenous
variables Xi = {x1i , . . . , xki }, i = 1 . . . N . This problem amounts to find a set

of parameters that solves the problem


minp

N
X
i=1

(yi G(Xi ; ))2

(3.3)

The idea is therefore that is chosen such that on average G(X ; ) is close
enough to y, such that G delivers a good approximation for the true function
F in the region of x that we consider. This is actually nothing else than
econometrics!
There are however several choices that can be made and that give us much
more freedom than in econometrics. We now consider investigate these choices.

Number of data points:

Econometricians never have the choice of the

points they can use to reveal information on the F function, as data are given
by history. In numerical analysis this constraint is relaxed, we may be exactly
identified for example, meaning that the number of data points, N , is exactly
equal to the number of parameters, p, we want to reveal. Never would a good
econometrician do this kind of thing! Obviously, we can impose a situation
where N > p in order to exploit more information. The difference between
these two choices should be clear to you, in the first case we are sure that
the approximation will be exact in the selected points, whereas this will not
necessarily be the case in the second experiment. To see that, just think of the
following: assume we have a sample made of 2 data points for a function that
we want to approximate using a linear function. we actually need 2 parameters
8

to define a linear function: the intercept, and the slope . In such a case,
(3.3) rewrites
min (y1 x1 )2 + (y2 x2 )2

{,}

which yields the system of orthogonality conditions


(y1 x1 ) + (y2 x2 ) = 0
(y1 x1 )x1 + (y2 x2 )x2 = 0
which rewrites

1 1
x1 x2

y1 x1
y2 x2

A.v = 0

This system then just amounts to find the null space of the matrix A, which,
in the case x1 6= x2 (which we can always impose as we will see next), imposes
vi = 0, i = 1, 2. This therefore leads to

y1 = + x1
y2 = + x2
such that the approximation is exact. When the system is overidentified this
is not the case anymore.
Selection of data points:

This is actually a major difference between

econometrics and numerical approximations. We do control the space over


which we want to take an approximation. In particular, we can spread the
data points wherever we want in order to control information. For instance,
let us consider the particular case of the function depicted in figure (3.1). As
this function exhibits a kink in x? it may be beneficial to concentrate a lot
of points around x? in order to reveal as much information as possible on the
kink.
Functional forms:

One key issue in the selection of the approximating

function is a functional form. In most of the cases, a sequence of monomials


9

Figure 3.1: Selection of points


y = F (x) 6

x?

of different degrees is selected: Xi = {1, xi , x2 , . . . , xp }, One advantage of this


selection is basically simplicity. However, this often turns to be a very bad
choice as many problems then turn out to be illconditioned with such a choice.
The most obvious objection we may formulate against this specification choice
is related to the multicolinearity problem. Assume for instance that you want
to approximate a production function that depends on employment and the
capital stock. The capital stock is basically an extremely smooth variable
as, by construction, it is essentially a smooth moving average of investment
decisions
kt+1 = it + (1 )kt kt+1 =

X
`=0

(1 )` it`

Therefore, taking as a basis for exogenous variables powers of the capital stock
is basically a bad idea. To see that, let us assume that = 0.025 and it is a
white noise process with volatility 0.1, then let us simulate a 1000 data points
process for the capital stock and let us compute the correlation matrix for k tj ,
10

j = 1, . . . , 4, we get:
kt
kt2
kt3
kt4

kt
1.0000
0.9835
0.9572
0.9315

kt2
0.9835
1.0000
0.9933
0.9801

kt3
0.9572
0.9933
1.0000
0.9963

kt4
0.9315
0.9801
0.9963
1.0000

implying a very high correlation between the powers of the capital stock, therefore raising the possibility of occurrence of multicolinearity. A typical answer
to this problem is to rely on orthogonal polynomials rather than monomials.
We will discuss this issue extensively in the next section. A second possibility is
to rely on parcimonious approaches that do not require too much information
in terms of function specification. An alternative is to use neural networks.
Before going to Neural Network approximations, we first have to deal with
a potential problem you may face with all the examples I gave is that when
we solve a model: the true decision rule is unknown, such that we do not
know the function we are dealing with. However, the main properties of the
decision rule are known, in particular, we know that it has to satisfy some
conditions imposed by economic theory. As an example, let us attempt to find
an approximate solution for the consumption decision rule in the deterministic
optimal growth model. Economic theory teaches us that consumption should
satisfy the Euler equation
1

c
= c
t
t+1 kt+1 + 1

(3.4)

knowing that the capital stock evolves as

kt+1 = kt ct + (1 )kt
Let us assume that consumption may be approximated by

(kt , ) = exp 0 + 1 log(kt ) + 2 log(kt )2

(3.5)

over the interval [k; k]. Our problem is then to find the triple {0 , 1 , 2 } such

that

N
X

t=1

1
2
(kt , ) (kt+1 , ) kt+1
+1
11

is minimum. This actually amounts to solve a nonlinear least squares problem. However, a lot of structure is put on this problem as kt+1 has to satisfy
the law of motion for capital:

kt+1 = kt exp 0 + 1 log(kt ) + 2 log(kt )2 + (1 )kt

The algorithm then works as follows

1. Set a grid of N data points, {ki }N


i=1 , for the capital stock over the interval
[k; k], and an initial vector {0 , 1 , 2 }.

2. for each ki , i = 1, . . . , N , and given {0 , 1 , 2 }, compute


ct = (kt , )
and
kt+1 = kt (kt , ) + (1 )kt
3. Compute
ct+1 = (kt+1 , )
and the quantity

1
R(kt , ) (kt , ) (kt+1 , ) kt+1
+1
4. If the quantity
N
X

R(ki , )2

t=1

is minimal then stop, else update {0 , 1 , 2 } and go back to 2.


As an example, I computed the approximate decision rule for the deterministic
optimal growth model with = 0.3, = 0.95, = 0.1 and = 1.5. I consider
that the model may deviate up to 90% from its capital stock steady state
k = 0.1k ? and k = 1.9k ? and used 20 data points. Figure 3.2 reports the
approximate decision rule versus the true decision rule.4 As can be seen
4

The true decision rule was computed using value iteration, which we shall study later.

12

from the graph, the solution we obtained with our approximation is rather
accurate and we actually have

1 X ctrue
cLS
4
i
i
true

= 8.743369e and
N
ci
i=1

true

ci cLS

i
= 0.005140
max
true

c
i={1,...,N }
i

such that the error we are making is particularly small. Indeed, using the
approximate decision rule, an agent would make a maximal error of 0.51% in
its economic calculus i.e. 51 cents for each 100$ spent on consumption.
Figure 3.2: Leastsquare approximation of consumption
1.8

True Decision Rule


LS approximation

1.6

Consumption

1.4
1.2
1
0.8
0.6
0.4
0

0.5

1.5

2.5
3
Capital stock

3.5

4.5

A neural network may be simply viewed as a particular type of function,


which are flexible enough to fit fairly general functions. A neural network may
be simply understood using the standard metaphor of human brain. There is
an input, x, which is processed by a node. Each node is actually a function that
transforms the input into an output which is then itself passed to another node.
For instance, panel (a) of figure 3.3, borrowed from Judd [1998], illustrates the
13

singlelayer neural network whose functional form is


G(x, ) = h

n
X

i g(x(i) )

i=1

where x is the vector of inputs, and h and g are scalar functions. A common
choice for g in the case of the dingle layer neural network is g(x) = x. Therefore, if we set h to be identity too, we are back to the standard OLS model
with monomials. A second a perhaps much more interesting type of neural
Figure 3.3: Neural Networks
x1

x1

x2

x2

..
..
..
..
xn

~
q
>

- y

q
1

R
q

..
..
..
..
xn

(a)

wU
:

s
- - y
3

(b)

network is depicted in panel (b) of figure 3.3. This type of neural network
is called the hiddenlayer feedforward network. In this specification, we are
closer to the idea of network as the transformed input is fed to another node
that process it to get information. The associated function form is given by

G(x, , ) = f

m
X

j h

j=1

n
X
i=1

!
j g(x(i) )
i

In this case, h is called the hiddenlayer activation function. h should be a


squasher function i.e. a monotically nondecreasing function that maps
R onto [0; 1]. Three very popular functions are
1. The heaviside step function
h(x) =

1
0

14

for x > 0
for x < 0

2. The sigmoid function


h(x) =

1
1 + exp(x)

3. Cumulative distribution functions, for example the normal cdf

Z x
x2
1

exp 2
h(x) =
2
2
Obtaining an approximation then simply amounts to determine the set
of coefficients {j , ij ; i = 1 . . . n, j = 1, . . . , m}. This can be simply achieved

running nonlinear least squares, that is solving


min

{,}

N
X
`=1

(y` G(x` , , ))2

One particular nice feature of neural networks is that they deliver accurate
approximation using only few parameters. This characteristic is related to the
high flexibility of the approximating functions they use. Further, as established
by the following theorem by Hornik, Stinchcombe and White [1989], neural
network are extremely powerful in that they offer a universal approximation
method.
Theorem 3 Let f : Rn R be a continuous function to be approximated.
R
Let h be a continuous function, h : R R, such that either (i) h(x)dx

is finite and non zero and h is Lp for 1 6 p 6 or (ii) h is a squashing

function (nondecreasing, limx h(x) = 1,limx h(x) = 0). Let


(
n
X
n (h) =
g : Rn R, g(x) =
j h(wj .x + aj ),
j=1

aj , j R, and w j Rn , wj 6= 0, m = 1, 2, . . .

be the set of all possible single hiddenlayer feedforward neural networks, using
h as the hidden layer activation function. Then, for all > 0, probability
measure , and compact sets K Rn , there is a g (h) such that
Z
sup |f (x) g(x)| 6 and
|f (x) g(x)|d 6
xK

15

This theorem is of great importance as it provides a universal approximation


result that states that for a broad class of functions, neural networks deliver an
accurate approximation to any continuous function. Indeed, we may use for
instance any squashing function of the type we described above, or any simple
function that satisfies condition (i). Nevertheless one potential limitation of
the approach lies into the fact that we have to conduct nonlinear estimation,
which may be cumbersome under certain circumstances.
As an example, we will deal with the function

! !
1 3
3
,2
F (x) = min max , x
2
2
over the interval [3; 3] and consider a single hiddenlayer feedforward network
of the form
Fe(x, , , ) =

1
2
+
1 + exp((1 x + 1 ) 1 + exp((2 x + 2 )

The algorithm is then straightforward


1. Generate N values for x [3; 3] and compute F (x)
2. Set initial values for 0 = {i , i , i ; i = 1, 2}
3. Compute
N
X
i=1

(F (xi ) Fe (xi , ))2

if this quantity is minimal then stop, else update and go back to 2.


The last step can be performed using a nonlinear minimizer, such that we
are actually performing nonlinear leastsquares. Figure 3.4 plots the approximation where N = 1000 and the solution vector yields the values reported
in table 3.2. Note that from the form of the vector, we can deduce that the
first layer handle positive values for x, therefore corresponding to the left part
of the function, while the second layer takes care of the negative part of the
16

Table 3.2: Neural Network approximation


1
2.0277

1
6.8424

1
-10.0893

2
-1.5091

2
-7.6414

2
-2.9238

function. Further, it appears that the function is no so badly approximated


by this simple neural network, as
1
E2 =
N
and
E

N
X
i=1

b 2
(F (xi ) Fe (xi , )

! 21

= 0.0469

e
b
= max F (xi ) F (xi , ) = 0.2200
i

Figure 3.4: Neural Network Approximation


2.5
2

True
Neural Network

1.5
1
0.5
0
0.5
1
1.5
2
3

0
x

All these methods actually relied on regressions. They are simple, but
may be either totally unreliable and illconditioned in a number of problem, or
17

difficult to compute because they rely on nonlinear optimization. We will now


consider methods which will actually be more powerful and somehow simpler
to implement. They however require introducing some important preliminary
concepts, among which that of orthogonal polynomials

3.2.1

Orthogonal polynomials

This class of polynomial possesses by definition the orthogonality property which will prove to be extremely efficient and useful in a number of
problem. For instance, this will solve the multicolinearity problem we encountered in OLS. This property will also greatly simplify the computation of the
approximation in a number of problems we will deal with in the sequel. First
of all we need to introduce some preliminary concepts.
Definition 4 (Weighting function) A weighting function (x) on the interval [a; b] is a function that is positive almost everywhere on [a; b] and has a
finite integral on [a; b].
An example of such a weighting function is (x) = (1x)1/2 over the interval

[-1;1]. Indeed, limx1 (x) = 2/2, and 0 (x) > 0 such that (x) is positive
everywhere over the whole interval. Further
1
Z 1

2 1/2
(1 x )
dx = arcsin(x) =
1

Definition 5 (Inner product) Let us consider two functions f1 (x) and f2 (x)

both defined at least on [a; b], the inner product with respect to the weighting
function (x) is given by
hf1 , f2 i =

f1 (x)f2 (x)(x)dx
a

For example, assume that f1 (x) = 1, f2 (x) = x and (x) = (1 x2 )( 1/2),


then the inner product over the interval [-1;1] is
1
Z 1
p

x
2

dx = 1 x = 0
hf1 , f2 i =
1x
1
1
18

Hence, in this case, we have that the inner product of 1 and x with respect
to (w) on the interval [-1;1] is identically null. This will actually define the
orthogonality property.
Definition 6 (Orthogonal Polynomials) The family of polynomials {Pn (x)}
is mutually orthogonal with respect to (x) iff

hPi , Pj i = 0 for i 6= j
Definition 7 (Orthonormal Polynomials) The family of polynomials {Pn (x)}
is mutually orthonormal with respect to (x) iff it is orthogonal and
hPi , Pi i = 1 for all i
Table 3.3 reports the most common families of orthogonal polynomials (see
Judd [1998] for a more detailed exposition) and table 3.4 their recursive formulation
Table 3.3: Orthogonal polynomials (definitions)
Family
Legendre
Chebychev
Laguerre
Hermite

3.3

(x)
1
(1 x2 )1/2
exp(x)
exp(x2 )

[a; b]
[1; 1]
[1; 1]
[0, )
(, )

Definition
n
dn
2 n
Pn (x) = (1)
2n n! dxn (1 x )
1
Tn (x) = cos(n cos (x))
dn
n
Ln (x) = exp(x)
n! dxn (x exp(x))
dn
2
Hn (x) = (1)n exp(x2 ) dx
n exp(x )

Least square orthogonal polynomial approximation

We will now discuss one of the most common approach to approximation that
goes back to the easy OLS approach we have seen previously.
19

Table 3.4: Orthogonal polynomials (recursive representation)


Family
Legendre

0
P0 (x) = 1

1
P1 (x) = x

Recursion
Pn+1 (x) =

Chebychev

T0 (x) = 1

T1 (x) = x

Tn+1 (x) = 2xTn (x) Tn1 (x)

Laguerre

L0 (x) = 1

L1 (x) = 1 x

Ln+1 (x) =

Hermite

H0 (x) = 1

H1 (x) = 2x

Hn+1 (x) = 2xHn (x) 2nHn1 (x)

2n+1
n+1 xPn (x)

2n+1x
n+1 Ln (x)

n
n+1 Pn1 (x)

n
n+1 Ln1 (x)

Definition 8 Let F : [a, b] R be a function we want to approximate,


and g(x) a polynomial approximation of F . The least square polynomial ap-

proximation of F with respect to the weighting function (w) is the degree n


polynomial that solves
min

deg(g)6n a

(F (x) g(x))2 (x)dx

This equation may be understood adopting an econometric point of view,


as (w) may be given a weighting matrix interpretation we find in GMM
estimation. Indeed, (x) furnishes an indication on how much we care about
approximation errors as a function of x. Therefore, setting (x) = 1, which
amounts to put the same weight on any x then corresponds to a simple OLS
approximation.
Let us now assume that g(x) =

Pn

i=0 ci i (x),

where {k (x)}nk=0 is a se-

quence of orthogonal polynomials, the least square problem rewrites


!2
Z b
n
X
min
F (x)
ci i (x)) (x)dx
n
{ci }i=0

i=0

for which the first order conditions are given by


!
Z b
n
X
F (x)
ci i (x)) i (x)(x)dx = 0 for i = 0, . . . , n
a

i=0

20

which yields
ci =
Therefore, we have
F (x) '

hF, i i
hi , i i

n
X
hF, i i
i (x)
hi , i i
i=0

There are several examples of the use of this type of approximation. Fourier
approximation is an example of those which is suitable for periodic functions.
Nevertheless, I will focus in a coming section on one particular approach, which
we will use quite often in the next chapters: Chebychev approximation.
Beyond least square approximation, there exists other approaches that
departs from the least square by the norm they use:
Uniform approximation, which attempt to solve
lim max |F (x) pn (x)| = 0

n x[a;b]

The main difference between this approach and L2 approximation is that


contrary to L2 norms that put no restrictions on the approximation on
particular points, the uniform approximation imposes that the approximation of F at each x is exact, whereas L2 approximations juste requires
the total error to be as small as possible.
Minimax approximations, which rest on the L norm, such that these
approximations attempt to find an approximation that provides the best

uniform approximation to the function F that is we search the degree n


polynomial that achieves
min kF (x) g(x)k

deg(g)6n

There are theorems in approximation theory that states that the quality
of this approximation increases polynomially as the degree of polynomials increases, and the polynomial rate of convergence is faster for
21

smoother functions. Nevertheless, if this approximation can be as good


as needed for F , no use of its derivatives is made, such that the derivatives may be very poorly approximated. Finally, such approximation
methods are extremely difficult to compute.

3.4

Interpolation methods

Up to now, we have seen that there exist methods to compute the value of a
function at some particular points, but in most of the cases we are not only
interested by the function at some points but also between these points. This
is the problem of interpolation.

3.4.1

Linear interpolation

This method is totally straightforward and known to everybody. Assume you


have a collection of data points C = {(xi , yi )|i = 1, . . . , n}. Then for any

x [xi1 , xi ], we can compute y as


y=

xi yi1 xi1 yi
yi yi1
x+
xi xi1
xi xi1

Although, such approximations have proved to be very useful in a lot of applications, it can be particularly inefficient for different reasons:
1. It does not deliver an approximating function but rather a collection of
approximations for each interval;
2. it requires to identify the interval where the approximation is to be
computed, which may be particularly costly when the interval is not
uniform;
3. it can obviously perform very badly for nonlinear functions.
Therefore, there obviously exist alternative interpolation methods that perform better, but which are not necessarily more efficient.
22

3.4.2

Lagrange interpolation

This type of approximation is quite demanding as it consider a collection of


data C = {(xi , yi )|i = 1, . . . , n} with distinct xi called the Lagrange data.

Lagrange interpolation amounts to find a degree n 1 polynomial P (x), such

that yi = P (xi ). Therefore, the method is exact for each point. Lagrange

interpolating polynomials are defined by


Pi (x) =

Y x xj
xi x j
j6=i

Note that Pi (xi ) = 1 and Pi (xj ) = 0. The interpolation is then given by


P (x) =

n
X

yi Pi (x)

i=1

The obvious problem that we can immediately see from this formula is that
if the number of point is high enough, this type of interpolation is totally
untractable. Indeed, just to compute a single Pi (x) this already requires 2(n
1) substractions, n multiplications. Then this has to be constructed for the

n data points to compute all needed Pi (x). Then to compute P (x) we need
n additions and n multiplications. Therefore, this requires 3n2 operations!
Therefore, one actually may actually attempt to compute directly:
P (x) =

n1
X

i x i

i=0

which may be obtained by solving the linear system

or

y1 = 0 + 1 x1 + 2 x21 + . . . + n1 xn1

y2 = 0 + 1 x2 + 2 x2 + . . . + n1 xn1
2
2
..

yn = 0 + 1 xn + 2 x2n + . . . + n1 xn1
n
A = y
23

where = {0 , 1 , . . . , n1 }0 and A is the socalled Vandermonde matrix for

xi , i = 1, . . . , n

A=

1 x1 x21
1 x2 x22
.. . .
.. ..
.
.
. .
1 xn x2n

xn1
1
xn1
2
..
.
xn1
n

If the Lagrange formula guarantees the existence of the interpolation, the


following theorem guarantees its uniqueness.
Theorem 4 Provided the interpolating points are distincts, there is a unique
solution to the Lagrange interpolation problem.
The proof of the theorem may be sketched as follows. Assume that besides
P (x), there exists another interpolating polynomial P ? (x) of degree at most
n 1 that also interpolates the n data points. Then, by construction, P (x)

P ? (x) is at most of degree n 1 and is zeros at all n nodes. But the only

polynomial of degree n 1 that has n zeros is 0, such that P (x) = P ? (x).

Here again, the method may be quite demanding from a computational point of

view, as we have to invert a matrix of size (nn). There then exist much more
efficient methods, and in particular the socalled Chebychev approximation
that works very well for smooth functions.

3.5

Chebychev approximation

Chebychev approximation uses . . . Chebychev polynomials as a basis for the


polynomials (see figure 3.5). These polynomials are described by the recursion
Tn+1 (x) = 2xTn (x) Tn1 (x) with T0 (x) = 1, T1 (x) = x
which admits as solution
Tn (x) = cos(n cos1 (x))
as aforementioned these polynomials form an orthogonal basis with respect to
the weighting function (x) = (1 x2 )1/2 over the interval [1; 1]. Neverthe-

less, this interval may be generalized to [a; b], by transforming the data using
24

the formula

ya
1 for y [a; b]
ba
Beyond the standard orthogonality property, Chebychev polynomials exhibit
x=2

a discrete orthogonality property which writes as

n
0 for i 6= j
X
n for i = j = 0
Ti (rk )Tj (rk ) =
n
i=1
for i = j 6= 0
2

where rk , k = 1, . . . , n are the roots of Tn (x) = 0.

Figure 3.5: Chebychev polynomials


1
n=1
n=2
n=3
n=4

0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1
1

0.8

0.6

0.4

0.2

0
x

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

A first theorem will state the usefulness of Chebychev approximation.


Theorem 5 Assume F is a C k function over the interval [1; 1], and let
Z
2 1 F (x)Ti (x)

ci =
dx for i = 0 . . . n
1
1 x2

and

gn (x)

c0 X
+
ci Ti (x)
2
i=1

25

Then, there exists < such that for all n > 2


kF (x) gn (x)k 6

log(n)
nk

This theorem is of great importance as it actually states that the approximation gn (x) will be as close as we might want to F (x) as the degree of
approximation n increases to . In effect, since the approximation error is

bounded by above by log(n)


and since the latter expression tends to zero
nk
as n tends toward , we have that gn (x) converges uniformly to F (x) as n

increases. Further, the next theorem will establish a useful property on the
coefficients of the approximation.

Theorem 6 Assume F is a C k function over the interval [1; 1], and admits
a Chebychev representation

F (x) =

c0 X
+
ci Ti (x)
2
i=1

then, there exists c such that


|ci | 6

c
for j > 1
ik

This theorem is particularly important as it states that the smoother the


function to be approximated is (the greater k is), the faster is the pace at
which coefficients will drop off. In other words, we will be able to achieve a
high enough accuracy using less coefficients.
At this point, we have established that Chebychev approximation can be
accurate for smooth functions, but we still do not know how to proceed to get
a good approximation. In particular, a very important issue is the selection
of interpolating data points, the socalled nodes. This is the main problem
of interpolation: how to select nodes such that we minimize the interpolation
error? The answer to this question is particularly simple in the case of Chebychev interpolation: the nodes should be the zeros of the nth degree Chebychev
polynomial.
26

We are then endowed with data points to compute the approximation.


Using m > n data points, we can compute the (n 1)th order Chebychev
approximation relying on the Chebychev regression algorithm we will now

describe in details. When m = n, the algorithm reduces to the socalled


Cebychev interpolation formula. Let us consider the following problem: Let
F : [a; b] R, let us construct a degree n 6 m polynomial approximation of
F on [a; b]:

G(x)

n
X
i=0

xa
1
i Ti 2
ba

1. Compute m > n + 1 Chebychev interpolation nodes on [1; 1], which


are the roots of the degree m Chebychev polynomial

2k 1
for k = 1 . . . , m
rk = cos
2m
2. Adjust the nodes, rk , to fit in the [a; b] interval
xk = (rk + 1)

ba
+ a for k = 1 . . . , m
2

3. Evaluate the function F at each approximation node xk , to get a collection of ordinates


yk = F (xk ) for k = 1 . . . , m
4. Compute the collection of n + 1 coefficients = {i ; i = 0 . . . n} as

i =

m
X

yk Ti (rk )

k=1
m
X

Ti (rk )2

k=1

5. Form the approximation


G(x)

n
X
i=0

xa
i Ti 2
1
ba
27

Note that step 4 actually can be interpreted in terms of an OLS problem as


because of the orthogonality property of the Chebychev polynomials i
is given by
i =

cov(y, Ti (x))
var(Ti (x))

which may be recast in matricial notations as


= (X 0 X)1 X 0 Y
where

X=

T0 (x1 )
T0 (x2 )
..
.

T1 (x1 )
T1 (x2 )
..
.

..
.

Tn (x1 )
Tn (x2 )
..
.

T0 (xm ) T1 (xm )

Tn (xm )

and Y =

y1
y2
..
.
ym

We now report two examples implementing the algorithm. The first one
deals with a smooth function of the type F (x) = x . The second one evaluate the accuracy of the approximation in the case of a nonsmooth function:
F (x) = min(max(1.5, (x 1/2)3 ), 2).

In the case of the smooth function, we set = 0.1 and approximate the

function over the interval [0.01; 2]. We select 100 nodes and evaluate the
accuracy of degree 2 and 6 approximation. Figure 3.6 reports the true function
and the corresponding approximation, table 3.5 reports the coefficients. As
can be seen from the table, adding terms in the approximation does not alter
the coefficients of lower degree. This just reflects the orthogonality properties
of the Chebychev polynomials, that we saw in the formula determining each
i . This is of great importance, as it states that once we have obtained a high
order approximation, obtaining lower orders is particularly simple. This is
the economization principle. Further, as can be seen from the figure, a good
approximation to the function is obtained at rather low degrees. Indeed, the
difference between the function and its approximation at order 6 is already
good.
28

Table 3.5: Chebychev Coefficients: Smooth function

c0
c1
c2
c3
c4
c5
c6

n=2
0.9547
0.1567
-0.0598

n=6
0.9547
0.1567
-0.0598
0.0324
-0.0202
0.0136
-0.0096

Figure 3.6: Smooth function: F (x) = x0.1


Approximation

1.1
1

0.9

True
n=2
n=6

0.8

0.05
0.1

0.7
0.6
0

Residuals

0.05

0.5

1
x

1.5

0.15
0

29

n=2
n=6
0.5

1
x

1.5

Matlab Code: Smooth Function Approximation


m
= 100;
% number of nodes
n
= 6;
% degree of polynomials
rk = -cos((2*[1:m]-1)*pi/(2*m)); % Roots of degree m polynomials
a
= 0.01;
% lower bound of interval
b
= 2;
% upper bound of interval
xk = (rk+1)*(b-a)/2+a;
% nodes
Y
= xk.^0.1;
% compute the function at nodes
%
% Builds Chebychev polynomials
%
Tx
= zeros(m,n+1);
Tx(:,1) = ones(m,1);
Tx(:,2) = xk(:);
for i=3:n+1;
Tx(:,i) = 2*xk(:).*Tx(:,i-1)-Tx(:,i-2);
end
%
% Chebychev regression
%
alpha
= X\Y;
% compute the approximation coefficients
G
= X*a;
% compute the approximation

In the case of the nonsmooth function we consider (F (x) = min(max(1.5, (x


1/2)3 ), 2)), the coefficients remain large even at degree 15 and the residuals
remain high at order 15. This actually indicates that Chebychev approximations are well suited for smooth functions, but have more difficulties to capture
kinks. Nevertheless, increasing the order of the approximation drastically, we
can achieve a much better approximation.
In the later case, it seems that a piecewise approximation would perform
better. Indeed, in this case, we may compute 3 approximation
for x (, x), G(x) = 1.5
for x (x, x), G(x)

xa
2

1
i
i
i=0
ba

Pn

for x (x, ), G(x) = 2


where x is such that

(x 1/2)3 = 1.5
30

Table 3.6: Chebychev Coefficients: Nonsmooth function


n=3
-0.0140
2.0549
0.4176
-0.3120

c0
c1
c2
c3
c4
c5
c6
c7
c8
c9
c10
c11
c12
c13
c14
c15

n=7
-0.0140
2.0549
0.4176
-0.3120
-0.1607
-0.0425
-0.0802
0.0571

n=15
-0.0140
2.0549
0.4176
-0.3120
-0.1607
-0.0425
-0.0802
0.0571
0.1828
0.0275
-0.1444
-0.0686
0.0548
0.0355
-0.0012
0.0208

Figure 3.7: Nonsmooth function: F (x) = min(max(1.5, (x 1/2)3 ), 2)


Approximation
Residuals
3
1
True
n=3
n=3
2
n=7
n=7
n=15
0.5
1
n=15
0

1
2
4

0
x

0.5
4

31

0
x

and x satisfies
(x 1/2)3 = 2
In such a case, the approximation would be perfect with n = 3. This suggests
that piecewise approximation may be of interest in a number of cases.

3.6

Piecewise interpolation

We have actually already seen piecewise approximation method: the linear


interpolation method. But there exist more powerful and efficient method that
use splines. A spline can be any smooth function that is piecewise polynomial,
but most of all it should be smooth at all nodes.
Definition 9 A function S(x) on an interval [a; b] is a spline of order n if
1. S(x) is a C n2 function on [a; b],
2. There exist a collection of ordered nodes a = x0 < x1 < . . . < xm = b
such that S(x) is a polynomial of order n 1 on each interval [xi ; xi+1 ],

i = 0, . . . , m 1

Examples of spline functions are


Cubic splines: These splines functions are splines of order 4. These
splines are the most popular and are of the form

Si (x) = ai + bi (x xi ) + ci (x xi )2 + di (x xi )3 for x [xi ; xi+1 ]


B 0 splines: These functions are splines of order 1:

0, x < xi
0
1, xi 6 x 6 xi+1
Bi (x) =

0, x > xi+1
32

B 1 splines: These functions are splines of order 2 that actually describe


tent functions:

0,

xxi

x < xi
xi 6 x 6 xi+1
xi+1 xi ,
Bi1 (x) =
xi+2 x
xi+2 xi+1 , xi+1 6 x 6 xi+2

0,
x > xi+2

Such a spline reaches a peak at x = xi+1 and is upward (downward)


sloping for x < xi+1 (x > xi+1 ).
Higher order spline functions are defined by the recursion:

x xi
xi+n+1 x
n1
n1
n
Bi (x) =
Bi (x) +
Bi+1
(x)
xi+n xi
xi+n+1 xi+1
Cubic splines are the most widely used splines to interpolate functions. Therefore, we will describe the method in greater details in such a case.

Let

us assume that we are endowed with Lagrange data i.e. a collection of


nodes xi and corresponding values for the function yi = F (xi ) to interpolate: {(xi , yi ) : i = 0 . . . n}. We therefore have in hand n intervals [xi ; xi+1 ],

i = 0, . . . , n 1 for which we search n cubic splines

Si (x) = ai + bi (x xi ) + ci (x xi )2 + di (x xi )3 for x [xi ; xi+1 ]


The problem is then to select 4n coefficients {ai , bi , ci , di : i = 0, . . . , n 1}

using n + 1 nodes. We therefore need 4n identification conditions to identify


these 4n coefficients.
The first set of restrictions is given by the collection of restrictions imposing
that the spline approximation is exact on the nodes
S(xi ) = yi for i = 0, . . . , n 1 and Sn1 (xn ) = yn
which amounts to impose
ai = yi for i = 0, . . . , n 1
33

(3.6)

and
an1 + bn1 (xn xn1 ) + cn1 (xn xn1 )2 + dn1 (xn xn1 )3 = yn (3.7)
The second set of restrictions imposes continuity of the function on the upper
bound of each interval
Si (xi ) = Si1 (xi ) for i = 1, . . . , n 1
which implies, noting hi = xi xi1
ai = ai1 + bi1 hi + ci1 h2i + di1 h3i for i = 1, . . . , n 1

(3.8)

This furnishes 2n identification restrictions, such that 2n additional restrictions are still needed. Since we are dealing with a cubic spline interpolation,
this requires the approximation to be C 2 , implying that first and second order
derivatives should be continuous. This yields the following n 1 conditions
for the first order derivatives

0
Si0 (xi ) = Si1
(xi ) for i = 1, . . . , n 1

or
bi = bi1 + 2ci1 hi + 3d3i1 h2i for i = 1, . . . , n 1

(3.9)

and the additional n 1 conditions for the second order derivatives


00
(xi ) for i = 1, . . . , n 1
Si00 (xi ) = Si1

or
2ci = 2ci1 + 6d3i1 hi for i = 1, . . . , n 1

(3.10)

Equations (3.6)(3.10) therefore define a system of 4n 2 equations, such that

we are left with 2 degrees of freedom. Hence, we have to impose 2 additional


conditions. There are several ways to select such conditions
1. Natural cubic splines impose that the second order derivatives S000 (x0 ) =
Sn00 (xn ) = 0. Note that the latter is actually not to be calculated in our
34

problem, nevertheless this imposes conditions on both c0 and cn which


will be useful in the sequel. In fact it imposes
c0 = c n = 0
An interpretation of this condition is that the cubic spline is represented
by the tangent of S at x0 and xn
2. Another way to fix S(x) would be to use potential information on the
slope of the function to be approximated. In other words, one may set
0
S00 (x0 ) = F 0 (x0 ) and Sn1
(xn ) = F 0 (xn )

This is the socalled Hermite spline. However, in a number of situation such information on the derivative of F is either not known or does
not exist (think of F not being differentiable at some points), such that
further source of information is needed. One can then rely on an approximation of the slope by the secant line. This is what is proposed
by thesecant Hermite spline, which amounts to approximate F 0 (x0 ) and
F 0 (xn ) by the secant line over the corresponding interval:
S00 (x0 ) =

S0 (x1 ) S0 (x0 )
Sn1 (xn ) Sn1 (xn1 )
0
and Sn1
(xn ) =
x1 x 0
xn xn1

But from the identification scheme, we have S0 (x1 ) = S1 (x1 ) = y1 and


Sn1 (xn ) = yn , such that we get
b0 = (y1 y0 )/h1 and bn1 = (yn yn1 )/hn
Let us now focus on the natural cubic spline approximation, which imposes
c0 = cn = 0. First, note that the system (3.6)(3.9) has a recursive form, such
that from (3.9) we can get
di1 =

1
(ci ci1 ) for i = 1, . . . , n 1
3hi

Plugging this results in (3.9),we get


bi b1i1 = 2ci1 hi + (ci ci1 )hi = (ci + ci1 )hi for i = 1, . . . , n 1
35

and, (3.8) becomes


1
ai ai1 = bi1 hi + ci1 h2i + (ci ci1 )h2i
3
1
= bi1 hi + (ci + 2ci1 )h2i for i = 1, . . . , n 1
3
which we may rewrite as
ai ai1
1
= bi1 + (ci + 2ci1 )hi for i = 1, . . . , n 1
hi
3
Likewise, we have
1
ai+1 ai
= bi + (ci+1 + 2ci )hi+1 for i = 0, . . . , n 2
hi+1
3
substracting the last two equations, when defined, we get
1
1
ai+1 ai ai ai1

= bi bi1 + (ci+1 + 2ci )hi+1 (ci + 2ci1 )hi


hi+1
hi
3
3
for i = 1, . . . , n 2, which is then given, taking (3.6) and (3.7) into account,

by

3
hi+1

(yi+1 yi )

3
(yi yi1 ) = hi ci1 + 2(hi + hi+1 )ci + hi+1 ci+1
hi

for i = 1, . . . , n 2. We however have the additional n 1th identification

restriction that imposes c0 = 0 and the last restriction cn = 0 We therefore


endup with a system of the form
Ac = B
where

2(h0 + h1 )
h1

h1
2(h1 + h2 )
h2

h
2(h
+ h3 )
h3
2
2

A=
.
..

hn3
2(hn3 + hn2 )
hn2
hn2
2(hn2 + hn1 )
36

c1

c = ... and B =
cn1

3
h1 (y2
3
hn1 (yn

y1 )
..
.

yn1 )

3
h0 (y1

y0 )

3
hn2 (yn1

yn2 )

The matrix A is then said to be tridiagonal (and therefore sparse) and is also
symmetric and elementwise positive. It is hence positive definite and therefore
invertible. We then got all the ci , i = 1, . . . , n 1 and can compute the bs
and ds as
bi1 =

yn yn1 2cn1
yi yi1 1
(ci +2ci1 )hi for i = 1, . . . , n1 and bn1 =

hi
3
hn
3hn

and

cn1
1
(ci ci1 ) for i = 1, . . . , n 1 and dn1 =
3hi
3hn
finally we have had ai = yi , i = 0, . . . , n 1 from the very beginning.
di1 =

Once the approximation is obtained, the evaluation of the approximation

has to be undertaken. The only difficult part in this job is to identify the interval the value of the argument of the function we want to evaluate belongs to
i.e. we have to find i {0, . . . , n 1} such that x [xi , xi+1 ]. Nevertheless,
as long as the nodes are generated using an invertible formula, there will be no

cost to determine the interval. Most of the time, a uniform grid is used, such
that the interval [a; b] is divided using the linear scheme xi = a + i, where
= (b a)/(n 1), and i = 0, . . . , n 1. In such a case, it is particularly

simple to determine the interval as i is given by E[(x a)/]. Nevertheless


there are some cases where it may be efficient to use nonuniform grid. For

instance, in the case of the function we consider it would be useful to consider

the following simple 4 nodes grid {3, 0.5 3 1.5, 0.5 + 3 2, 3}, as taking this

grid would yield a perfect approximation (remember that the central part of
the function is cubic!)

As an example of spline approximation, figure 3.8 reports the spline approximation to the nonsmooth function F (x) = min(max(1.5, (x1/2) 3 ), 2)
considering a uniform grid over the [-3;3] interval with 3, 7 and 15 nodes. In
37

3
2
1
0

Figure 3.8: Cubic spline approximation


Approximation
Residuals
1.5
True
n=3
n=3
n=7
1
n=7
n=15
n=15
0.5
0

1
2
4

0
x

0.5
4

0
x

order to gauge the potential of spline approximation, we report in the upper


panel of figure 3.9 the L2 and L error of approximation. The L2 approximation error is given by kF (x)S(x)k while the L is given by max |F (x)S(x)|.
It clearly appears that increasing the number of nodes improves the approxi-

mation in that the error is driven to zero. Nevertheless, it also appears that
convergence is not monotonic in the case of the L error. This is actually related to the fact that F , in this case is not even C 1 on the overall interval. In
fact, as soon as we consider a smooth function this convergence is monotonic,
as can be seen from the lower panel that report it for the function F (x) = x 0.1
over the interval [0.01;2]. This actually illustrates the following result.
Theorem 7 Let F be a C 4 function over the interval [x0 ; xn ] and S its cubic
spline approximation on {x0 , x1 , . . . , xn } and let > maxi {xi xi1 }, then
kF Sk 6
and
0

kF S k

5
kF (4) k 4
384

p
9 + (3) (4)
6
kF k 3
216

This theorem actually gives upper bounds to spline approximation, and indicates that these bounds decrease at a fast pace (power of 4) as the number of
38

Figure 3.9: Approximation errors


F (x) = min(max(1.5, (x 1/2)3 ), 2) over [3; 3]

L2 error

0.03

0.8

L error

0.6

0.02

0.4
0.01

0.2

0
0

20
40
# of nodes

0
0

60

20
40
# of nodes

60

F (x) = x0.1 over [0.01; 2]


3

x 10

L2 error

0.2

L error

0.15

0.1
1
0
0

0.05
20
40
# of nodes

0
0

60

39

20
40
# of nodes

60

nodes increases (as diminishes). Splines are usually viewed as a particularly


good approximation method for two main reasons:
1. A good approximation may be achieved even for functions that are not
C or that do not possess high order derivatives. Indeed, as indicated in
theorem 7, the error term basically depends only on fourth order derivatives, such that even if the fifth order derivative were badly behaved then
an accurate approximation may be obtained.
2. Evaluation of splines is particularly cheap as they involve most of the
time at most cubic polynomials, the only costly part being the interval
search step.
nbx
a
b
dx
x
y

=
=
=
=
=
=

Matlab Code: Cubic Spline Approximation


8;
% number of nodes
-3;
% lower bound of interval
3;
% upper bound of interval
(b-a)/(n-1);
% step in the grid
[a:dx:b];
% grid points
min(max(-1.5,(x(i)-0.5)^3),2);

A
= spalloc((nbx-2),(nbx-2),3*nbx-8);
% creates sparse matrix A
B
= zeros((nbx-2),1);
% creates vector B
A(1,[1 2])=[2*(dx+dx) dx];
for i=2:nbx-3;
A(i,[i-1 i i+1])=[dx 2*(dx+dx) dx];
B(i)=3*(y(i+2)-y(i+1))/dx-3*(y(i+1)-y(i))/dx;
end
A(nbx-2,[nbx-3 nbx-2])=[dx 2*(dx+dx)];
c
a
b
d
S

=
=
=
=
=

[0;A\B];
y(1:nbx-1);
(y(2:nbx)-y(1:nbx-1))/dx-dx*([c(2:nbx-1);0]+2*c(1:nbx-1))/3;
([c(2:nbx-1);0]-c(1:nbx-1))/(3*dx);
[a;b;c(1:nbx-1);d];
% Matrix of spline coefficients

One potential problem that may arise with the type of method we have
developed until now is that we have not imposed any particular restriction on
the shape of the approximation relative to the true function. This may be of
great importance in some cases. Let us assume for instance that we need to
approximate the function F (xt ) that characterizes the dynamics of variable x
40

in the following backward looking dynamic equation:


xt+1 = F (xt )
Assume F is a concave function that is costly to compute, such that it is beneficial to approximate the function. However, as we have already seen from the
previous examples, many methods generate oscillations in the approximation.
This can create some important problems as it implies that the approximation
is not strictly concave, which is in turn crucial to characterize the dynamics of
variable x. Further, the approximation of a strictly increasing function may be
locally decreasing. All this may create some divergent path, or even generate
some spurious steady state, and therefore spurious dynamics. It is therefore
crucial to develop shape preserving methods preserving in particular the
curvature and monotonicity properties for such cases.

3.7

Shape preserving approximations

In this section, we will see an approximation method that preserves the shape
of the function we want to approximate. This method was proposed by Schumaker [1983] and essentially amounts to exploit some information on both
the level and the slope of the function to be approximated to build a smooth
approximation. We will deal with two situations. The first one Hermite
interpolation assumes that we have information on both the level and the
slope of the function to approximate. The second one that uses Lagrange
data assumes that no information on the slope of the function is available.
Both method was originally developed using quadratic splines.

3.7.1

Hermite interpolation

This method assumes that we have information on both the level and the
slope of the function to be approximated. Assume we want to approximate
the function F on the interval [x1 , x2 ] and we know yi = F (xi ) and zi = F 0 (xi ),
i = 1, 2. Schumaker proposes to build a quadratic function S(x) on [x1 ; x2 ]
41

that satisfies
S(xi ) = yi and S 0 (xi ) = zi for i = 1, 2
Schumaker establishes first that
Lemma 1 If

then the quadratic form

z1 + z 2
y2 y 1
=
2
x2 x 1

S(x) = y1 + z1 (x x1 ) +

z2 z 1
(x x1 )2
2(x2 x1 )

satisfies S(xi ) = yi and S 0 (xi ) = zi for i = 1, 2.

The construction of this function is rather appealing. If z1 and z2 have the


same sign then S 0 (x) has the same sign as z1 and z2 over [x1 ; x2 ]:
S 0 (x) = z1 +

(z2 z1 )
(x x1 )
(x2 x1 )

Hence, if F is monotically increasing (decreasing) on the interval [x1 ; x2 ], so is


S(x). Further, z1 > z2 (z1 < z2 ) indicates concavity (convexity), which S(x)
satisfies as S 00 (x) = (z2 z1 )/(x2 x1 ) < 0 (> 0).

However, the conditions stated by this lemma are extremely stringent and

do not usually apply, such that we have to adapt the procedure. This may be
done by adding a node between x1 and x2 and construct another spline that
satisfies the lemma.
Lemma 2 For every x? (x1 , x2 ) there exist a unique quadratic spline that
solves

S(xi ) = yi and S 0 (xi ) = zi for i = 1, 2


with a node at x? . This spline is given by

01 + 11 (x x1 ) + 21 (x x1 )2
S(x) =
02 + 12 (x x? ) + 22 (x x? )2
where

where z =

01 = y1
02 = y1 +

for x [x1 ; x? ]
for x [x? ; x2 ]

11 = z1 21 =
z+z1
?
22 =
2 (x x1 ) 12 = z

2(y2 y1 )(z1 (x? x1 )+z2 (x2 x? )


x2 x1

42

zz1
2(x? x1 )
z2 z
2(x2 x? )

If the later lemma fully characterized the quadratic spline, it gives no information on x? which therefore remains to be selected. x? will be set such that the
spline matches the desired shape properties. First note that if z1 and z2 are
both positive (negative), then S(x) is monotone if and only if z1 z > 0 (6 0)
which is actually equivalent to
2(y2 y1 ) R (x? x1 )z1 + (x2 x? )z2 if z1 , z2 R 0
This essentially deals with the monotonicity problem, and we now have to
tackle the question of curvature. To do so, we compute the slope of the secant
line between x1 and x2
=

y2 y 1
x2 x 1

Then, if (z2 )(z1 ) > 0, this indicates the presence of an inflexion point

in the interval [x1 ; x2 ] such that the interpolant cannot be neither convex nor
concave. Conversely, if |z2 | < |z1 | and x? satisfies
x1 < x ? 6 x x 1 +

2(x2 x1 )(z2 )
(z2 z1 )

then S(x), as described in the latter lemma, is convex (concave) if z1 < z2


(z1 > z2 ). Further, if z1 z2 > 0 it is also monotone.
If, on the contrary, |z2 | > |z1 | and x? satisfies
x x2 +

2(x2 x1 )(z1 )
6 x? < x2
(z2 z1 )

then S(x), as described in the latter lemma, is convex (concave) if z1 < z2


(z1 > z2 ).
This therefore endow us with a range of values for x? that will insure that
shape properties will be preserved.
1. Check if lemma 1 is satisfied. If so set x? = x2 and set S(x) as in lemma
2. Then stop else go to 2.
2. Compute = y2 y1 /x2 x1
43

3. if (z1 )(z2 ) > 0 set x? = (x1 + x2 )/2 and stop else goto 4.
4. if |z1 | < |z2 | set x? = (x1 + x)/2 and stop else goto 5.
5. if |z1 | > |z2 | set x? = (x2 + x)/2 and stop.
We have then in hand a value for x? for [x1 ; x2 ]. We then apply it to each
subinterval to get x?i [xi ; xi+1 ] and then solve the general interpolation
problem as explained in lemma 2.

Note here that everything assumes that with have Hermite data in hand
i.e. {xi , yi , zi : i = 0, . . . , n}. However, the knowledge of the slope is usually
not the rule and we therefore have to adapt the algorithm to such situations.

3.7.2

Unknown slope: back to Lagrange interpolation

Assume now that we do not have any data for the slope of the function, that
is we are only endowed with Lagrange data {xi , yi : i = 0, . . . , n}. In such a

case, we just have to add the needed information an estimate of the slope of

the function and proceed exactly as in Hermite interpolation. Schumaker


proposes the following procedure to get {zi ; i = 1, . . . , n}. Compute

and

1
Li = (xi+1 xi )2 + (yi+1 yi )2 2
i =

yi+1 yi
xi+1 xi

for i = 1, . . . , n 1. Then zi , i = 1, . . . , n can be recovered as

Li1 i1 + Li i
if i1 i > 0
zi =
i = 2, . . . , n 1
Li1 + Li
0
if i1 i 6 0

and

z1 =

3n1 sn1
31 z2
and zn =
2
2

Then, we just apply exactly the same procedure as described in the previous
section.
44

Up to now, all methods we have been studying are unidimensional whereas


most of the model we deal with in economics involve more than 1 variable.
We therefore need to extend the analysis to higher dimensional problems.

3.8

Multidimensional approximations

Computing a multidimensional approximation to a function may be quite cumbersome and even impossible in some cases. To understand the problem, let
us restate an example provided by Judd [1998]. Consider we have data points
{P1 , P2 , P3 , P4 } = {(1, 0), (1, 0), (0, 1), (0, 1)} in R2 and the corresponding

data zi = F (Pi ), i = 1, . . . , 4. Assume now that we want to construct the approximation of function F using a linear combination of {1, x, y, xy} defined

as

G(x, y) = a + bx + cy + dxy
such that G(xi , yi ) = zi . Finding a, b, c, d amounts to solve the linear system

1
1
0 0
a
z1
1 1

0 0

b = z2
1

0
1 0
z3
c
z4
1
0 1 0
d

which is not feasible as the matrix is not full rank.


This example reveals two potential problems:

1. Approximation in higher dimensional systems involves crossproduct


and therefore poses the problem of the selection of polynomial basis
to be used for approximation,
2. More important is the selection of the grid of nodes used to evaluate the
function to compute the approximation.
We now investigate these issues, by first considering the simplest way to
attack the question namely considering tensor product bases and then
moving to a second way of dealing with this problem considering complete
polynomials. In each case, we explain how Chebychev approximations can be
obtained.
45

3.8.1

Tensor product bases

The idea here is to use the tensor product of univariate functions to form a
basis of multivariate functions. In order to better understand this point, let
us consider that we want to approximate a function F : R2 R using simple

univariate monomials up to order 2: X = {1, x, x2 } and Y = {1, y, y 2 }. The


tensor product basis is given by

{1, x, y, xy, x2 , y 2 , x2 y, xy 2 , x2 y 2 }
i.e. all possible 2terms products of elements belonging to X and Y .
We are now in position to define the nfold tensor product basis for functions of n variables {x1 , . . . , xi , . . . , xn }.
Definition 10 Given a basis for n functions of the single variable xi : Pi =
i
{pki (xi )}k=0
then the tensor product basis is given by

1
n

Y
Y
...
B=
pk11 (x1 ) . . . pknn (xn )

k1 =0

kn =0

An important problem with this type of tensor product basis is their size.
For example, considering a mdimensional space with polynomials of order
n, we already get (n + 1)m terms! This exponential growth in the number
of terms makes it particularly costly to use this type of basis, as soon as the
number of terms or the number of nodes is high. Nevertheless, it will often
be satisfactory or sufficient for low enough polynomials (in practice n=2!)
Therefore, one often rely on less computationally costly basis.

3.8.2

Complete polynomials

As aforementioned, tensor product bases grow exponentially as the dimension


of the problem increases, complete polynomials have the great advantage of
growing only polynomially as the dimension increases. From an intuitive point
of view, complete polynomials bases take products of order lower than a priori
given into account, ignoring higher terms of higher degrees.
46

Definition 11 For N given, the complete set of polynomials of total degree


in n variables is given by
(
Bc =

xk11

. . . xknn : k1 , . . . , kn > 0,

n
X

ki 6

i=1

To see this more clearly, let us consider the example developed in the previous
section (X = {1, x, x2 } and Y = {1, y, y 2 }) and let us assume that = 2. In

this case, we end up with a complete polynomials basis of the type

B c = 1, x, y, x2 , y 2 , xy = B\{xy 2 , x2 y, x2 y 2 }

Note that we have actually already encountered this type of basis, as this is
typically what is done by Taylors theorem for many dimensions
F (x) ' F (x? ) +
..
.
+

n
X
F ?
(x )(xi x?i )
xi
i=1

n
n
X
F
1 X
...
(x? )(xi1 x?i1 ) . . . (xik x?ik )
k!
xi1 . . . xi1
i1 =1

ik =1

For instance, considering the Taylor expansion to the 2dimensional function


F (x, y) around (x? , y ? ) we get
F (x, y) ' F (x? , y ? ) + Fx (x? , y ? )(x x? ) + Fy (x? , y ? )(y y ? )

1
+
Fxx (x? , y ? )(x x? )2 + 2Fxy (x? , y ? )(x x? )(y y ? )
2
!
+Fyy (x? , y ? )(y y ? )2

which rewrites
F (x, y) = 0 + 1 x + 2 y + 3 x2 + 4 y 2 + 5 xy
such that the implicit polynomial basis is the complete polynomials basis of
order 2 with 2 variables.
47

The key difference between tensor product bases and complete polynomials bases lies essentially in the rate at which the size of the basis increases. As
aforementioned, tensor product bases grow exponentially while complete polynomials bases only grow polynomially. This reduces the computational cost of
approximation. But what do we loose using complete polynomials rather than
tensor product bases? From a theoretical point of view, Taylors theorem gives
us the answer: Nothing! Indeed, Taylors theorem indicates that the element
in B c delivers a approximation in the neighborhood of x? that exhibits an
asymptotic degree of convergence equal to k. The nfold tensor product, B,
can deliver only a k th degree of convergence as it does not contains all terms
of degree k + 1. In other words, complete polynomials and tensor product
bases deliver the same degree of asymptotic convergence and therefore complete polynomials based approximation yields an as good level of accuracy as
tensor product based approximations.
Once we have chosen a basis, we can proceed to approximation. For example, we may use Chebychev approximation in higher dimensional problems.
Judd [1998] reports the algorithm for this problem. As we will see, it takes advantage of a very nice feature of orthogonal polynomials: they inherit their orthogonality property even if we extend them to higher dimensions. Let us then
assume we want to compute the chebychev approximation of a 2dimensional
function F (x, y) over the interval [ax ; bx ] [ay ; by ] and let us assume to

keep things simple for a while that we use a tensor product basis. Then
the algorithm is as follows
1. Choose a polynomial order for x (nx ) and y (ny )

2. Compute mx > nx + 1 and my > ny + 1 Chebychev interpolation nodes


on [1; 1]
zkx

= cos

2k 1
, k = 1, . . . , mx
2mx

= cos

2k 1
, k = 1, . . . , my
2my

and
zky

48

3. Adjust the nodes to fit in both interval

bx ax
x
xk = ax + (1 + zk )
, k = 1, . . . , mx
2
and
yk = ay + (1 +

zky )

by ay
2

, k = 1, . . . , my

4. Evaluate the function F at each node to form


{k` = F (xk , y` ) : k = 1, . . . , mx ; ` = 1, . . . , my }
5. Compute the (nx +1)(ny +1) Chebychev coefficients ij , i = 0, . . . , nx ,
j = 0, . . . , ny as
my
mx X
X


k` Tix (zkx ) Tjy z`y

!
! my
ij = mk=1 `=1
x
X
X

2
Tjy z`y
Tix (zkx )2
`=1

k=1

which may be simply obtained in this case as


=

T x (z x )0 T y (z y )
kT x (z x )k2 kT y (z y )k2

6. Compute the approximation as


G(x, y) =

ny
nx X
X
i=0 j=0

ij Tix

y ay
x ax
y
1 Tj 2
1
2
bx ax
by ay

which may also be obtained as

y ay
x ax
y
x
1 T 2
1
G(x, y) = T
2
bx ax
by ay
As an illustration of the algorithm we compute the approximation of the CES
function
1

F (x, y) = [x + y ]
49

on the [0.01; 2][0.01; 2] interval for = 0.75. We used 5th order polynomials
for both x and y and 20 nodes for both x and y, such that there are 400
possible interpolation nodes. Applying the algorithm we just described, we
get the matrix of coefficients reported in table 3.7. As can be seen from the
table, most of the coefficients are close to zero as soon as they involve the
crossproduct of higher order terms, such that using a complete polynomial
basis would yield the same efficiency at a lower computational cost. Figure
3.10 reports the graph of the residuals for the approximation.
Table 3.7: Matrix of Chebychev coefficients (tensor product basis)
kx \ k y
0
1
2
3
4
5

0
2.4251
1.2744
-0.0582
0.0217
-0.0104
0.0057

1
1.2744
0.2030
-0.0366
0.0124
-0.0055
0.0029

2
-0.0582
-0.0366
0.0094
-0.0037
0.0018
-0.0009

3
0.0217
0.0124
-0.0037
0.0016
-0.0008
0.0005

4
-0.0104
-0.0055
0.0018
-0.0008
0.0004
-0.0003

5
0.0057
0.0029
-0.0009
0.0005
-0.0003
0.0002

Matlab Code: Chebychev Coefficients in R2 (Tensor Product Basis)


rho = 0.75;
mx = 20;
my = 20;
nx = 5;
ny = 5;
ax = 0.01;
bx = 2;
ay = 0.01;
by = 2;
%
% Step 1
%
rx = cos((2*[1:mx]-1)*pi/(2*mx));
ry = cos((2*[1:my]-1)*pi/(2*my));
%
% Step 2
%
x
= (rx+1)*(bx-ax)/2+ax;
y
= (ry+1)*(by-ay)/2+ay;

50

%
% Step 3
%
Y
= zeros(mx,my);
for ix=1:mx;
for iy=1:my;
Y(ix,iy) = (x(ix)^rho+y(iy)^rho)^(1/rho);
end
end
%
% Step 4
%
Xx = [ones(mx,1) rx];
for i=3:nx+1;
Xx= [Xx 2*rx.*Xx(:,i-1)-Xx(:,i-2)];
end Xy = [ones(my,1) ry];
for i=3:ny+1;
Xy= [Xy 2*ry.*Xy(:,i-1)-Xy(:,i-2)];
end
T2x = diag(Xx*Xx);
T2y = diag(Xy*Xy);
a
= (Xx*Y*Xy)./(T2x*T2y);

Figure 3.10: Residuals: Tensor product basis

0.01
0.005
0
0.005
0.01
0.015
0
0.5
1
1.5
y

1.5

51

0.5

If we now want to perform the same approximation using a complete polynomials basis, we just have to modify the algorithm to take into account the
fact that when iterating on i and j we want to impose i + j 6 . Let us
compute is for = 5. This implies that the basis will consists of
1, T1x (.), T1y (.), T2x (.), T2y (.), T3x (.), T3y (.), T4x (.), T4y (.), T5x (.), T5y (.),
T1x (.)T1y (.), T1x (.)T2y (.), T1x (.)T3y (.), T1x (.)T4y (.),
T2x (.)T1y (.), T2x (.)T2y (.), T2x (.)T3y (.),
T3x (.)T1y (.), T3x (.)T2y (.),
T4x (.)T1y (.)

Table 3.8: Matrix of Chebychev coefficients (Complete polynomials basis)


kx \ k y
0
1
2
3
4
5

0
2.4251
1.2744
-0.0582
0.0217
-0.0104
0.0057

1
1.2744
0.2030
-0.0366
0.0124
-0.0055

2
-0.0582
-0.0366
0.0094
-0.0037

3
0.0217
0.0124
-0.0037

4
-0.0104
-0.0055

5
0.0057

A first thing to note is that the coefficients that remain are the same as
the one we got in the tensor product basis. This should not be any surprise
as what we just find is just the expression of the Chebychev economization we
already encountered in the unidimensional case and which is just the direct
consequence of the orthogonality condition of chebychev polynomials. Figure
3.11 report the residuals from the approximation using the complete basis. As
can be seen from the figure, this constrained approximation yields quantitatively similar results compared to the tensor product basis, therefore achieving
almost the same accuracy while being less costly from a computational point
of view. In the matlab code section, we just report the lines in step 4 that
are affected by the adoption of the complete polynomials basis.
52

Matlab Code: Complete Polynomials Specificities


a=zeros(nx+1,ny+1);
for ix=1:nx+1;
iy = 1;
while ix+iy-2<=kappa
a(ix,iy)=(Xx(:,ix)*Y*Xy(:,iy))./(T2x(ix)*T2y(iy));
iy=iy+1;
end
end

Figure 3.11: Residuals: Complete polynomials basis

0.02
0.01
0
0.01
0.02
0

0.5

0.5

1.5
2

1.5
2

3.9

Finite element approximations

Finite element are extremely popular among engineers (especially in aeronautics). This approach considers elements that are zero over most of the
domain of approximation. Although they are extremely powerful in the case
of 2dimensional problems, they are more difficult to implement in higher
dimensions. We therefore focus on the bidimensional case.
53

3.9.1

Bilinear approximations

A bilinear interpolation proposes to interpolate data linearly in both coordinate directions. Assume that we have the values of a function F (x, y) at the
four points
P1 = (1, 1) P2 = (1, 1)
P3 = (1, 1)
P4 = (1, 1)

A cardinal interpolation basis on [1; 1] [1; 1] is provided by the set of


functions

b1 (x, y) = 41 (1 x)(1 y) b2 (x, y) = 14 (1 x)(1 + y)


b3 (x, y) = 41 (1 + x)(1 y) b4 (x, y) = 14 (1 + x)(1 + y)
All functions bi are zero on all Pj , i 6= j, but on the point to which is associated

the same index (i = j). Therefore, an approximation of F (x, y) on [1; 1]


[1; 1] is given by

F (x, y) ' F (1, 1)b1 (x, y)+F (1, 1)b2 (x, y)+F (1, 1)b3 (x, y)+F (1, 1)b4 (x, y)
If we have data on [ax ; bx ] [ay ; by ], we use the linear transformation we have
already encountered a great number of times

y ay
x ax
2
1, 2
1
bx ax
by ay

Then, if we have Lagrange data of the type {xi , yi , zi : i = 1, . . . , n}, we

proceed as follows

1. Construct a grid of nodes for x and y;


2. Construct the interpolant over each square applying the previous scheme;
3. Piece all interpolant together.
Note that an important issue of piecewise interpolation is related to the continuity of the approximation: individual pieces must meet continuously at
common edges. In bilinear interpolation, this is insured by the fact that two
interpolants overlap only at the edges of rectangles on which the approximation is a linear interpolant of 2 common end points. This would not be
54

insured if we were to construct biquadratic or bicubic interpolations for example. Note that this type of interpolation scheme is typically what is done
when a computer draw a 3d graph of a function. In figure 3.12, we plot
the residuals of the bilinear approximation of the CES function we approximated in the previous section, with 5 uniform intervals (6 nodes such that x =
{0.010, 0.408, 0.806, 1.204, 1.602, 2.000} and y = {0.010, 0.408, 0.806, 1.204, 1.602, 2.000}).

Like in the spline approximation procedure, the most difficult step once we
have obtained an approximation is to determine the square the point for which
we want an approximation belongs to. We therefore face exactly the same type
of problems.
Figure 3.12: Residuals of the bilinear approximation

1
0.5
0
0.5
1
0

0.5

1.5

1
1.5

0.5
2

3.9.2

Simplicial 2D linear interpolation

This method essentially amounts to consider triangles rather than rectangles


as an approximation basis. The idea is then to build triangles in the x y

plane. To do so, and assuming that the lagrange data have already been
55

transformed using the linear map described earlier, we set 3 points


P1 = (0, 0), P2 = (0, 1), P3 = (1, 0)
to which we associate 3 functions
b1 (x, y) = 1 x y, b2 (x, y) = y, b3 (x, y) = x
which are such that all functions bi are zero on all Pj , i 6= j, but on the point

to which is associated the same index (i = j). b1 b2 and b3 are the cardinal
functions on P1 , P2 , P3 . Let us now add the point P4 = (1, 1), then we have
the following cardinal functions for P2 , P3 , P4 :
b4 (x, y) = 1 x, b5 (x, y) = 1 y, b6 (x, y) = x + y 1
Therefore, on the square P1 , P2 , P3 , P4 the interpolant for F is given by

if x + y 6 1
F (0, 0)(1 x y) + F (0, 1)y + F (1, 0)x
G(x, y) =

F (0, 1)(1 x) + F (1, 0)(1 y) + F (1, 1)(x + y 1) if x + y > 1

It should be clear to you that if these methods are pretty easy to implement

in dimension 3, it becomes quite cumber some in higher dimensions, and noth


that much is proposed in the literature, are most of these methods were designed by engineers and physicists that essentially have to deal with 2, 3 at
most 4 dimensional problems. We will see that this will be a limitation in a
number of economic applications.

56

Bibliography
Hornik, K., M. Stinchcombe, and H. White, MultiLayer Feedforward Networks are Universal Approximators, Neural Networks, 1989, 2, 359366.
Judd, K.L., Numerical methods in economics, Cambridge, Massachussets:
MIT Press, 1998.
Schumaker, L.L., On Shapepreseving Quadratic Spline Interpolation, SIAM
Journal of Numerical Analysis, 1983, 20, 854864.

57

Index
Analytic function, 4

Tensor product bases, 46

Chebychev approximation, 24

Vandermonde matrix, 23

Complete polynomials, 47
complete polynomials, 46
Economization principle, 28
Hiddenlayer feedforward, 14
Least square orthogonal polynomial
approximation, 19
Linearization, 6
Local approximations, 2
Loglinearization, 7
Multidimensional approximation, 45
Neural networks, 11
Ordinary least square, 8
Orthogonal polynomials, 18
Radius of convergence, 3
Singlelayer, 14
Splines, 32
Taylor series expansion, 2
58

Contents
3 Approximation Methods
3.1

Local approximations
3.1.1

3.2

1
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Regressions as approximation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

3.2.1

Taylor series expansion

Orthogonal polynomials . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

18

3.3

Least square orthogonal polynomial approximation . . . . . . .

19

3.4

Interpolation methods . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

22

3.4.1

Linear interpolation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

22

3.4.2

Lagrange interpolation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

23

3.5

Chebychev approximation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

24

3.6

Piecewise interpolation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

32

3.7

Shape preserving approximations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

41

3.7.1

Hermite interpolation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

41

3.7.2

Unknown slope: back to Lagrange interpolation . . . . .

44

Multidimensional approximations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

45

3.8.1

Tensor product bases . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

46

3.8.2

Complete polynomials . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

47

Finite element approximations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

53

3.9.1

Bilinear approximations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

53

3.9.2

Simplicial 2D linear interpolation . . . . . . . . . . . . .

55

3.8

3.9

59

60

List of Figures
3.1

Selection of points . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

10

3.2

Leastsquare approximation of consumption . . . . . . . . . . .

13

3.3

Neural Networks . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

14

3.4

Neural Network Approximation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

17

3.5

Chebychev polynomials . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

25

x0.1

3.6

Smooth function: F (x) =

. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

29

3.7

Nonsmooth function: F (x) = min(max(1.5, (x 1/2)3 ), 2) .

31

3.8

Cubic spline approximation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

38

Approximation errors

. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

39

3.10 Residuals: Tensor product basis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

52

3.11 Residuals: Complete polynomials basis . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

54

3.12 Residuals of the bilinear approximation . . . . . . . . . . . . .

56

3.9

61

62

List of Tables
3.1
3.2

Taylor series expansion for log(1 x) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Neural Network approximation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

17

3.3

Orthogonal polynomials (definitions) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

19

3.4

Orthogonal polynomials (recursive representation) . . . . . . .

20

3.5

Chebychev Coefficients: Smooth function . . . . . . . . . . . .

29

3.6

Chebychev Coefficients: Nonsmooth function . . . . . . . . . .

31

3.7

Matrix of Chebychev coefficients (tensor product basis) . . . .

50

3.8

Matrix of Chebychev coefficients (Complete polynomials basis)

52

63

You might also like