There Are Two Kinds of Welfare Programs in The United States: Those
There Are Two Kinds of Welfare Programs in The United States: Those
There Are Two Kinds of Welfare Programs in The United States: Those
Social Welfare
There are two kinds of welfare programs in the United States: those
that benefit most or all of the people and those that help only a small
number of them. In the first category are Social Security and
Medicare, programs that provide retirement benefits or medical
assistance to almost every citizen who has reached a certain age. In
the second are programs such as Medicaid and Food Stamps that offer
help only to people with low incomes.
Legally, the differences between the two kinds of programs is
that the first have no means test (that is, they are available to everyone
without regard to income) while the second are means tested (that is,
you must fall below a certain income level to enjoy them). Politically,
the programs differ in how they get money from the government. The
first kind of welfare programs represent majoritarian politics: nearly
everyone benefits, nearly everyone pays. The second kind represent
client politics: a (relatively) few number of people benefit, but almost
everyone pays.
This political difference has a huge impact on how the
government acts in regard to these programs. Social Security and
Medicare are sacrosanct. The thought of making any changes that
might lower the benefits these programs pay is so politically risky that
most politicians never even discuss the possibility. When programs
such as these run into trouble because of rising expenses (Medicare is
in deep trouble today, and Social Security will be in even deeper
trouble in a few decades), politicians scramble to look for ways of
maintaining benefits while hiding the rising costs or postponing
dealing with them. As we shall see later in this chapter, there has been
a sharp growth in the proportion of people who are retired and are thus
entitled to Social Security and Medicare. To keep benefits flowing to
these individuals, people who are not retired will have to pay more and
more in taxes. No politician wants to raises taxes or cut benefits, so
they adopt a variety of halfhearted measures (like slowly increasing
the age at which people can get these benefits) designed to postpone
the tough decisions until they are out of office.
Client-based welfare programs-those that are tested-are a very
different matter. Like many other client-based programs, their
order to claim the benefits. Some people think that about Food
Stamps, the program that gives low-income people free stamps that
they can exchange for food. There have been a few publicized cases
of people using food stamps to buy luxury items. But no powerful
opposition to the program has developed, because in general the only
thing the beneficiaries have in common is that they have low incomes.
Many Americans can imagine becoming poor, and so they probably
are willing to allow such a program to operate as part of a governmentsupplied safety net that might, someday, help them.
But AFDC was a different matter. Having to accept AFDC
was not something the typical taxpayer thought would ever happen to
him or her. Moreover, the beneficiaries werent just poor; some of
them did things-such as having babies without getting married-that
most Americans thought were simply wrong. The legitimacy of
AFDC was thus in jeopardy, because it either made possible or
actually encouraged behavior that most Americans found improper.
In this chapter we provide examples of both majoritarian and
client welfare programs and describe how they have changed over the
years. There are far too many social welfare programs to describe
them all here; rather, the main purpose of this chapter is to explain the
key features of the two main kinds of these programs.
one-fourth of the work force, private charities and city relief programs
nearly went bankrupt.
The election of 1932 produced an overwhelming congressional
majority for the Democrats and placed Franklin D. Roosevelt in the
White House. Almost immediately a number of emergency measures
were adopted to cope with the depression by supplying federal cash to
bail out state and local relief agencies and by creating public work jobs
under federal auspices. These measures were recognized as temporary
expedients, however, and were unsatisfactory to those who believed
that the federal government had a permanent and major responsibility
for welfare. Roosevelt created the Cabinet Committee on Economic
Security to consider long-term policies. The committee drew heavily
on the experience of European nations and on the ideas of various
American scholars and social workers, but it understood that it would
have to adapt these proposals to the realities of American politics.
Chief among these was the widespread belief that any direct federal
welfare program might be unconstitutional. The Constitution nowhere
explicitly gave to Congress the authority to set up an unemployment
compensation or old-age retirement program. And even if a welfare
program were constitutional, many believed, it would be wrong
because it violated the individualistic creed that people should help
themselves unless they were physically unable to do so.
But failure by the Roosevelt administration to produce a
comprehensive social security program, his supporters felt, might
make the president vulnerable in the 1936 election to the leaders of
various radical social movements. Huey Long of Louisiana was
proposing a Share Our Wealth plan; Upton Sinclair was running for
governor of California on a platform calling for programs to End
Poverty in California; and Dr. Francis E. Townsend was leading an
organization of hundreds of thousands of elderly people on whose
behalf he would demanded government pensions of $200 a month.
The plan that emerged from the cabinet committee was
carefully designed to meet popular demands within the framework of
popular beliefs and constitutional understandings. It called for two
kinds of programs: (1) an insurance program for the unemployed and
elderly, to which workers would contribute and from which they
would benefit when they became unemployed or retired; and (2) an
assistance program for the blind, dependent children, and the aged.
(Giving assistance as well as providing insurance for the aged was
necessary because for the first few years the insurance program would
not pay out any benefits.) The federal government would use its
power to tax to provide the funds, but all of the programs (except for
old-age insurance) would be administered by the states. Everybody,
rich or poor, would be eligible for the insurance programs. Only the
poor, as measured by a means test (a measure to determine that
incomes are below a certain level), would be eligible for the assistance
programs. Though bitterly opposed by some, the resulting Social
Security Act passed swiftly and virtually unchanged through Congress.
It was introduced in January 1935 and signed by President Roosevelt
in August of that year.
The idea of having the government pay the medical and
hospital bills of the elderly and the poor had been discussed in
Washington since the drafting of the Social Security Act. President
Roosevelt and his Committee on Economic Security sensed that
medical care would be very controversial, and so health programs
were left out of the 1935 bill in order not to jeopardize its chances of
passage.5
The proponents of the idea did not abandon it, however.
Working mostly within the executive branch, they continued to press,
sometimes publicly, sometimes behind the scenes, for a national health
care plan. Democratic presidents, including Truman, Kennedy, and
Johnson, favored it; Republican president Eisenhower opposed it;
Congress was deeply divided on it. The American Medical
Association attacked it as socialized medicine. For thirty years key
policy entrepreneurs, such as Wilbur Cohen, worked to find a formula
that would produce a congressional majority.
The first and highest hurdle to overcome, however, was not
Congress as a whole but the House Ways and Means Committee,
especially its powerful chairman from 1958 to 1975, Wilbur Mills of
Arkansas. A majority of the committee members opposed a national
health care program. Some members believed it wrong in principle;
others feared that adding a costly health component to the Social
Security system would jeopardize the financial solvency and
administrative integrity of one of the most popular government
programs. By the early 1960s a majority of the House favored a health
care plan, but without the approval of Ways and Means it would never
reach the floor.
benefit levels, and to administer the program. Washington did set(and over the years, continued to increase) a number of rules
governing how the program would work, however. Washington told
the states how to calculate applicants income and required the states
to give Medicaid to AFDC recipients. The states had to establish
mandatory job-training programs for many AFDC recipients and to
provide child care programs for working AFDC parents. Washington
also required that women on AFDC identify their childrens fathers.
In addition to the growing list of requirements, Washington
also created new programs for which AFDC recipients were eligible,
such as Food Stamps, the Earned Income Credit (a cash grant to poor
parents who are working), free school meals, various forms of housing
assistance, and certain other benefits. But while all this was
happening, public opinion moved against the AFDC program.
The combination of souring public opinion, increasing federal
regulations, and a growing roster of benefits produced a program that
irritated almost everyone. The states disliked having to conform to a
growing list of federal regulations, but critics complained that the
states offered very different levels of benefits. The public hated the
program because they thought it was weakening the family by
encouraging out-of-wedlock births (since AFDC recipients received
additional benefits for each new child). But some scholars denied that
this was happening. The public worried that AFDC recipients were
working covertly on the side; the data proved that this was true of at
least half of them in several large cities. AFDC recipients saw that the
actual (that is, inflation-adjusted) value of their AFDC checks was
going down. Critics countered that if you added together all the
benefits they were receiving (food stamps, Medicaid, housing
assistance, and so on), benefit levels were actually going up.
Politicians complained that healthy parents were living off of AFDC
instead of working. Other politicians rejoined that AFDC mothers
needed to stay home with their young children or to get day care so
they could work. The AFDC law was revised many times, but never
in a way that satisfied all, or even most, of its critics. Though AFDC
recipients were only a small fraction of all Americans, they had
become a large political problem.
What made matters worse was that the composition of people
in the program had changed. In 1970 about half of the mothers on
AFDC were there because their husband had died or divorced them;
only a quarter had never been married.6 By 1994 the situation had
changed dramatically: only about a quarter of AFDC mothers were
widowed or divorced, and over half had never been married at all.
And though most women on AFDC for the first time got off of it after
just a few years, almost two-thirds of the women on AFDC at any
given moment had been on it for eight years or more.
These facts, combined with the increased proportion of out-ofwedlock births in the country as a whole, made it virtually impossible
to sustain political support for what had begun as a noncontroversial
client program.
increases in the scope of the program and the size of the benefits.
From 1950 to 1975 there was only one period (1959-1965) when
Congress allowed more than two years pass without either increasing
retirement benefits or broadening the kinds of workers covered by the
plan.8
It is not hard to see why. The House comes up for reelection
every two years. Though some members no doubt voted to increase
benefits out of a sincere conviction that the elderly needed more help,
every member knew that it was a political asset to be able to say that
he or she had voted to provide more benefits. By 1954 Social Security
was so well established that a Republican president proposed to a
Republican-controlled Congress that benefits be increased. The vote
in the House was 356 in favor, 8 opposed.
Majoritarian politics remains good politics unless the costs to
the voters begin to exceed their benefits. Though Social Security and
Medicare were supposed to be insurance programs, in fact they are
not. When a retired person takes out in benefits bears little
relationship to what he or she has previously paid in taxes. These
programs are in fact devices whereby people now working are taxed to
provide benefits for people now retired.
Three things began to change the politics of these programs.
First, Congress raised retirement benefits to the point where tax
increases were necessary to pay for them. A tax that had taken only 1
percent of a workers salary in 1935 was taking over 7.5 percent of it
by 1990. Second, older people began to live longer, and so the number
of retired people who had to be supported increased. By 1975 only
about three workers were paying taxes for every one person who was
retired; early in the next century the ration will fall to about two to
one. Third, the cost of health care began to shoot up. By 1985 the
price of a hospital room was almost five times greater than it had been
in 1970.
By 1977 Congress for the first time had to raise Social Security
taxes without raising benefits. The bill carried the House by only
twenty-six votes, a far cry from the nearly unanimous votes by which
retirements bills had once passed. The days of easy votes on Social
Security had come to an end.9
Client Politics
people will find a way to buy what they want. Nevertheless, Congress
works on the assumption that irritating physicians and economists is a
lot better than outraging retired persons on Medicare.
The essence of the price-control system, adopted in 1983, is to
replace the traditional way of paying hospitals (sending them a check
to cover their customary costs) with a new policy of paying a flat fee
for each particular treatment, from broken bones to brain tumors,
regardless of what they cost. Doctors and hospitals that couldnt
deliver the service for what the government would pay would have to
swallow the extra cost themselves; if they could treat the patient for
less, they could pocket the difference. Sounds good, but there is a
hitch: some hospitals reacted to the price controls by not becoming
more efficient but by scrimping on services and discharging patients
quicker but sicker.13
Despite the anguish of having to figure out how to deliver the
greatest benefits for the least tax dollars, Congress and the White
House could no resist trying to create an entirely new health benefit.
The law was called the Medicare Catastrophic Coverage Act of 1988.
It should have been called the Politically Catastrophic Act of 1988.
The idea was simple enough: elderly people are especially
worried about having to pay for some medical catastrophe, such as
cancer, a stroke, or Alzheimers disease. These illnesses can quickly
consume almost anyones savings. Under the existing Medicare plan,
the government would pay your hospital bills for only 150 days in any
given year. The catastrophic illness bill dealt with the by guaranteeing
that the government would pay your hospital bills for the whole year,
every year, after you had paid a deductible. The cost of this additional
coverage was to be paid for largely by the elderly themselves, with the
increase in fees to be the greatest for the most affluent.
Though the idea was simple, the problem was that the
beneficiaries didnt think the new law provided any real benefit,
certainly not one they wanted to pay for. They expressed their feelings
in a tidal wave of opposition, and within eighteen months Congress
was forced to back down and repeal the Medicare Catastrophic
Coverage Act. The House vote to pass the act in 1988 had been 302 to
127; the House vote to repeal it in 1989 was 352 to 63. It was the most
dramatic reversal in the history of welfare legislation.
In the 1996 election, Clinton and Dole agreed that perhaps a
bipartisan commission should be formed to debate the future of
Medicare. But everybody still handled the subject with kid gloves,
and a commission that might have produced some positive results was
never formed. President Clinton and congressional Republicans had
already suggested postponing the Medicare crisis by cutting the
amount of money going to doctors and hospitals. They disagreed only
on how big the cut should be. Cutting payments to hospitals, however,
does not seem a viable solution to the problem because hospitals must
make up for such cuts either by reducing services or by charging
paying customers more money.
At least for Social Security the tactic of turning to a commission
had already been tried. In 1996 a second advisory commission on
Social Security produced three reports but no clear majority opinion
about what should be done to maintain the program. The most
challenging recommendation was that the system be revised to allow
people to put some fraction of their Social Security taxes into the stock
market. There they could earn much higher returns than what is
typical of federal bonds, where the Social Security trust fund is
currently invested. Younger workers seemed to like the idea, because
many dont think Social Security will be there for them when they
retire. Older workers and retirees dont like the idea, because it entails
a certain amount of risk to current benefit levels.
When costs rise, majoritarian politics no longer looks so easy.
Public Support
Aid to the Poor By contrast, client politics get easier when the
legitimacy of its beneficiaries declines. After many efforts to reform
AFDC, the 104th Congress passed and President Clinton signed a law
that turns the program back to the states. The law that created AFDCTitle IV of the Social Security Act-was abolished.
The Personal Responsibility and Work Opportunity
Reconciliation Act of 1996 as designed to do several things. First, it
lets the states run welfare programs for the poor as they see fit, without
tight federal regulation. Each state will get a fixed federal block grant
to pay for what is now called Temporary Assistance for Needy
Families (TANF). The block grants are fixed in size; they wont go up
automatically, though states that achieve certain goals-such as
reducing out-of-wedlock births or increasing welfare recipients who
work-will be eligible for extra benefits. Second, the new law requires
that most welfare recipients find work, by placing limits on how long
they can get benefits. Third, the bill denies food stamps for legal
aliens and denies TANF for illegal aliens.
The work requirements are at the heart of the bill. To keep
receiving their block grants, the states must ensure that all adults who
receive benefits are working within two years of receiving a TANF
grant. Furthermore, federal money cannot be used to support any adult
for more than five years, and mothers will have their TANF grants
reduced if they do not identify the fathers of their children. New
machinery has been put into place to track down deadbeat dads.
Unmarried mothers under the age of eighteen will qualify for a TANF
grant only if they live with a parent (or in an adult-supervised setting)
and attend school.
Food Stamps, Medicaid, the Earned Income Credit, child
nutrition and child care grants, and Supplementary Security Income
(SSI) continue to be available to TANF recipients, though in some
cases under stricter limits
Many state governors supported the bill (they may be wondering
why now that they have full responsibility for administering TANF).
Many liberal Democrats and childrens advocates denounced the bill,
but it passed both houses of Congress by large majorities. At the time
he signed the bill, President Clinton said he disagreed with some of its
provisions and planned to offer some legislation to change these items.
Whatever happens on this front, it is clear that unmarried moms have
lost their status as a legitimate client group.
Aid to the Homeless No issue better illustrates the tensions within
American social welfare politics than the problem of the homeless.
The streets and parks of many cities are filled with homeless people.
That much is clear. Everything else is in dispute.
People disagree concerning how many people are homeless, why
they are homeless, and what should be done about it. Many liberals
argue that there are millions of homeless people, that most of them are
the victims of high housing costs or cuts in social services, and that the
government should (at a minimum) not harass them and (at a
maximum) provide them with shelter. Many conservatives, by
contrast, argue that there are relatively few homeless people, that most
of them are mentally ill or drug-dependent, and that the government
should use the criminal justice and mental health systems to get them
off the streets and into institutions.
When government is faced with a problem over which there is
such profound disagreement, no one should be surprised to discover
that it adopts a policy that satisfies neither group. In many cities the
police enforce laws against public disorder but not against sleeping on
the streets; local agencies supply shelters, but only during cold
weather; health organizations offer treatments to mentally ill or drugdependent people, but they do not require it.
The federal government has so far limited its role to supplying
money to the states and cities to help pay for the variety of local
programs. Beginning in 1987, Congress has authorized spending
money for emergency food, shelter, and health care for the homeless.
Aid to Immigrants The political controversies surrounding
homelessness pale in comparison to the present and potential political
battles over immigration. In the early 1990s an estimated 1.25 million
immigrants entered the country each year. Most entered legally, but
some unknown fraction entered illegally (so-called undocumented
aliens). Not since the early decades of this century has the United
States experienced anything like this level of immigration.
The majority of these new immigrants are from Mexico, China,
and Haiti, and they are different in both culture and appearance from
the descendants of European immigrants who make up the majority of
Americans. While many Americans of European ancestry cherish
their grandparents tales of how they came to this country, todays
immigrants face a very different set of circumstances. Rather than
landing on Ellis Island and spreading out across many states, an
estimated 90 percent of todays immigrants are concentrated in six
states: California, Florida, Illinois, New Jersey, New York, and Texas.
California alone was the final destination of about half of all
immigrants to the United States in the 1980s.
Most studies by economists indicate that the impact of
immigration on the wages and unemployment rate of less-skilled
workers is virtually nil. This holds even in such dramatic cases as the
1980 influx of some 125,000 Cubans into Miami, Florida. Although
the Cuban immigration increased the citys labor force by almost 8
percent, it had virtually no deleterious economic effects on the citys
less-skilled workers. Nevertheless, many Americans believe that
Summary
We can explain the politics of social welfare policy in America
principally in terms of two factors: who benefits and who pays, and the
beliefs citizens have about social justice. Neither factor is static:
gainers and losers vary as the composition of society and the workings
of the economy change, and beliefs about who deserves what are
modified as attitudes toward work, the family, and the obligations of
government change.
The benefits and costs of the policies help explain the popularity
of two social welfare programs and the controversy surrounding
others. Social Security and Medicare provide widely distributed
benefits and impose widely distributed costs. The politics surrounding
their enactment and expansion have been majoritarian. The Aid to
Families with Dependent Children (AFDC) program provided benefits