Mit Ch18 Note
Mit Ch18 Note
Mit Ch18 Note
We have assumed until now that the economy was closedthat it did not
interact with the rest of the world. We had to start this way, to keep things
simple and build up your intuition for the basic macroeconomic mechanisms.
We are now ready to relax this assumption. Understanding the macroeconomic
implications of openness will occupy us for this and the next three chapters.
Openness has three distinct dimensions:
1.
2.
3.
In the short run and in the medium runthe focus of this and the next three
chaptersopenness in factor markets plays much less of a role than openness
in either goods markets or financial markets. Thus, I shall ignore openness in
factor markets, and focus on the implications of the first two dimensions of
openness here.
Section 181 looks at openness in the goods market, the determinants of the
choice between domestic goods and foreign goods, and the role of the real
exchange rate.
Section 182 looks at openness in financial markets, the determinants of the
choice between domestic assets and foreign assets, and the role of interest
rates and exchange rates.
Section 183 gives the map to the next three chapters.
The U.S. economy is becoming more open over time. Exports and
imports, which were equal to 5% of GDP during the 1960s, now are
equal to about 12% of GDP (10% for exports, 14% for imports).
In other words, the United States trades more than twice as much
(relative to its GDP) with the rest of the world as it did just 40
years ago.
Although imports and exports have followed broadly the same upward trend, they have also diverged for long periods of time, generating sustained trade surpluses and trade deficits.1 Two episodes
stand out:
First, the large trade deficits of the mid1980s: The ratio of the
trade deficit to GDP reached 3% in 1986, before decreasing to 1%
in the early 1990s.
Second, the large and increasing trade deficits since the mid1990s.
The ratio of the trade deficit to GDP reached 4.5% in 2003, a historical record.
1.
From Chapter 3: The trade balance is the difference between exports and imports:
Exports > imports: Trade surplus (equivalently, positive trade balance)
Exports < imports: Trade deficit (equivalently, negative trade balance)
Country
United States
Japan
Germany
United Kingdom
Export Ratio
10%
12%
36%
25%
Country
Switzerland
Austria
Netherlands
Belgium
Export Ratio
42%
51%
62%
79%
2. Tradable goods: Cars, computers... Non tradable goods: Housing, most medical services, haircuts...
3. For more on the OECD and for the list of member countries, see Chapter 1.
Take for example a country that imports intermediate goods for $1 billion.
Suppose it transforms them into final goods using only labor. Say that total
wages equal $200 million and there are no profits. The value of these final
goods is thus equal to $1,200 million. Assume that $1 billion worth of final
goods is exported and the rest, $200 million, is consumed domestically.
Exports and imports therefore both equal $1 billion. What is GDP in this
economy? Remember that GDP is value added in the economy (see Chapter
2). So, in this example, GDP equals $200 million, and the ratio of exports
to GDP equals $1000/$200 = 5.
Hence, exports can exceed GDP. This is actually the case for a number of
small countries where most economic activity is organized around a harbor
and importexport activities. This is even the case for small countries where
manufacturing plays an important role, such as Singapore. In 2002, the
ratio of exports to GDP in Singapore was 145%.
the same decision. This decision has a direct effect on domestic output: If
buyers decide to buy more domestic goods, the demand for domestic goods
increases, and so does domestic output. If they decide to buy more foreign
goods, then foreign output increases instead of domestic output.
Central to this second decision (to buy domestic goods or foreign goods) is
the price of domestic goods relative to foreign goods. We call this relative
price the real exchange rate. The real exchange rate is not directly observable, and you will not find it in the newspapers. What you will find in
newspapers are nominal exchange rates, the relative prices of currencies.
So, in the rest of this section, we start by looking at nominal exchange
rates, and then see how we can use them to construct real exchange rates.
As the price of the domestic currency in terms of the foreign currency. If for example, we look at the United States and the United
Kingdom, and think of the dollar as the domestic currency and the
pound as the foreign currency, we can express the nominal exchange
rate as the price of a dollar in terms of pounds. In August 2004, the
exchange rate defined this way was 0.55 (1 dollar was worth 0.55
pounds.)
As the price of the foreign currency in terms of the domestic currency. Continuing with the same example, we can express the nominal exchange rate as the price of a pound in terms of dollars. In
August 2004, the exchange rate defined this way was 1.8 (1 pound
was worth 1.8 dollars.)
Exchange rates between the dollar and most foreign currencies change every
day, every minute of the day. These changes are called nominal appreciations or nominal depreciationsappreciations or depreciations for short.
You may have encountered two other words to denote movements in exchange rates: revaluations and devaluations. These two terms are used
when countries operate under fixed exchange ratesa system in which
two or more countries maintain a constant exchange rate between their
currencies. Under such a system, increases in the exchange ratewhich
6. Warning. There is no agreed upon rule among economists or among newspapers as
to which of the two definitions to use. You will encounter both. Always check which
definition is used.
7. E: Nominal exchange ratePrice of domestic currency in terms of foreign currency.
(From the point of view of the U.S. looking at the United Kingdom, the price of a dollar
in terms of pounds.)
8. Appreciation of the domestic currency Increase in the price of the domestic currency in terms of foreign currency Increase in the exchange rate
9. Depreciation of the domestic currency Decrease in the price of the domestic
currency in terms of foreign currency Decrease in the exchange rate
are infrequent by definitionare called revaluations (rather than appreciations). Decreases in the exchange rate are called devaluations (rather
than depreciations).10
Figure 182 plots the nominal exchange rate between the dollar and the
pound since 1970. Note the two main characteristics of the figure:
The trend increase in the exchange rate. In 1970, a dollar was worth
only 0.41 pounds. In 2003, a dollar was worth 0.59 pounds. Put
another way, there was an appreciation of the dollar vis`avis the
pound over the period.
The large fluctuations in the exchange rate. In the space of less than
ten years in the 1980s, the value of the dollar increased from 0.42
pounds in 1981 to 0.82 pounds in 1985, only to go back down to
0.54 pounds by early 1988. Put another way, there was a very large
appreciation of the dollar in the first half of the 1980s, followed by
a large depreciation later in the decade.
Figure 182. The Nominal Exchange Rate Between the Dollar and the
Pound, 19702003 (Caption. While the dollar has appreciated visavis
the pound over the past 33 years, this appreciation has come with large
swings in the nominal exchange rate between the two currencies, especially
in the 1980s.)
If we are interested however in the choice between domestic goods and
foreign goods, the nominal exchange rate gives us only part of the information we need. Figure 182 for example tells us only about movements
in the relative price of the two currencies, the dollar and the pound. To
U.S. tourists thinking of visiting the United Kingdom, the question is not
only how many pounds they will get in exchange for their dollars, but how
10. We shall discuss fixed exchange rates in Chapter 20.
much goods will cost in the United Kingdom, relative to how much they
cost in the United States. This takes us to our next stepthe construction
of real exchange rates.
The first step would be to take the price of a Cadillac in dollars and
convert it to a price in pounds. The price of a Cadillac in the United
States is $ 40,000. A dollar is worth 0.55 pounds, so the price of a
Cadillac in pounds is 40,000 dollars x 0.55 = 22,000.
The second step would be to compute the ratio of the price of the
Cadillac in pounds to the price of the Jaguar in pounds. The price of
a Jaguar in the United Kingdom is 30,000. So the price of a Cadillac in terms of Jaguarsthat is, the real exchange rate between the
United States and the United Kingdomwould be $22,000/$30,000
= 0.73.
11. Check that, if we expressed both in terms of dollars instead, we would get the same
result for the real exchange rate.
10
The price of U.S. goods in dollars is P . Multiplying it by the exchange rate, Ethe price of dollars in terms of poundsgives us
the price of U.S. goods in pounds, EP .
EP
P
(18.1)
12. : Real exchange ratePrice of domestic goods in terms of foreign goods (For example, from the point of view of the U.S. looking at the United Kingdom, the price of
U.S. goods in terms of British goods)
11
Figure 184 plots the evolution of the real exchange rate between the
United States and the United Kingdom from 1970 to 2003, constructed
13. Real appreciation Increase in the price of the domestic goods in terms of foreign
goods Increase in the real exchange rate
14. Real depreciation Decrease in the price of the domestic goods in terms of foreign
goods Decrease in the real exchange rate
12
While the nominal exchange rate went up during the period, the
real exchange rate went down: In 1970, the real exchange rate was
equal to 1.04; in 2003, it was down to 0.60.
How do we reconcile the fact that there was both a nominal appreciation (of the dollar vis a vis the pound) and a real depreciation (of
U.S. goods vis a vis British goods) during the period? To see why,
return to the definition of the real exchange rate:
=E
P
P
14
Canada
Mexico
Western Europe
China
Japan
Rest of Asia *
Others
Proportion of
Exports to
23
13
23
4
7
14
11
Proportion of
Imports from
18
11
21
13
9
17
6
16
number. So its level is also arbitrary; here it is set equal to 1 in the first
quarter of 2000.
The most striking aspect of the figure is something we already saw when
looking at the bilateral exchange rate between the United States and the
United Kingdom in Figure 184, the large swing in the real exchange rate
in the 1980s. U.S. goods were about 40% more expensive relative to foreign
goods in the mid1980s than they were either at the beginning or at the
end of the decade. In other words, there was a large real appreciation in
the first half of the 1980s, followed by an even larger real depreciation in
the second half. This large swing, which as we have seen has its origins in
the movement of the nominal exchange rate, is so striking that it has been
given various names, from the dollar cycle to the more graphic dance of
the dollar. Note the similar, but smaller movements of the dollar from the
mid 1990s on, with an increase of 25% from 1995 to 2001, and a decrease
since then. Many economists wonder whether we are in the middle of a
second large swing, a second dollar cycle. In the coming chapters, we shall
return to these swings, look at where they come from, and what effects
they have on the trade deficit and economic activity.
18
Lets start by looking more closely at the relation between trade flows and
financial flows. When this is done, we shall look at the determinants of
these financial flows.
The first two lines record the exports and imports of goods and services. Exports lead to payments from the rest of the world, imports
to payments to the rest of the world. In 2003, imports exceeded exports, leading to a U.S. trade deficit of $490 billionroughly 4.5%
of U.S. GDP.
Exports and imports are not the only sources of payments to and
from the rest of the world. U.S. residents receive investment income on their holdings of foreign assets, and foreign residents receive investment income on their holdings of U.S. assets. In 2003,
investment income received from the rest of the world was $275 billion, and investment income paid to foreigners was $258 billion, for
a net balance of $17 billion.
Finally, countries give and receive foreign aid; the net value of these
payments is recorded as net transfers received. These net transfers amounted in 2003 to $68 billion. This negative amount reflects
19
the fact that, in 2003, the United States wasas it has traditionally
beena net donor of foreign aid.
The sum of net payments to and from the rest of the world is called the
current account balance. If net payments from the rest of the world are
positive, the country is running a current account surplus; if they are
negative, the country is running a current account deficit. Adding all
payments to and from the rest of the world, net payments from the United
States to the rest of the world were equal in 2003 to $490 +$17 $68 =
$541 billion. Put another way, in 2003, the United States ran a current
account deficit of $541 billionroughly 5.0% of its GDP.22
Table 183. The U.S. Balance of Payments, 2003, in billions of U.S. dollars
Current Account
Exports
Imports
Trade balance (deficit= ) (1)
Investment income received
Investment income paid
Net investment income (2)
Net transfers received (3)
Current account balance (deficit=) (1)+(2)+(3)
Capital account
Increase in foreign holdings of U.S. assets (4)
Increase in U.S. holdings of foreign assets (5)
Capital account balance (deficit=) (4)-(5)
Statistical discrepancy
1018
1508
490
275
258
17
68
541
856
277
579
-38
20
21
This is yet another reminder that, even for a rich country such as the United
States, economic data are far from perfect. (This problem of measurement
manifests itself in another way as well. The sum of the current account
deficits of all the countries in the world should be equal to zero: One countrys deficit should show up as a surplus for the other countries taken as a
whole. However, this is not the case in the data: If we just add the published
current account deficits of all the countries in the world, it would appear
that the world is running a large current account deficit! Some economists
speculate that the explanation is unrecorded trade with the Martians. Most
others believe that mismeasurement is the explanation.)
Now that we have looked at the current account, we can return to an issue
we touched on in Chapter 2, the difference between GDP, the measure
of output we have used so far, and GNP, another measure of aggregate
output. This is done in the Focus box GDP versus GNP: The Example of
Kuwait.
The two definitions are not the same: Some domestic output may be produced by capital owned by foreigners, while some foreign output may be
produced by capital owned by domestic residents.
The answer is that either definition is fine, and economists use both. Gross
domestic product (GDP), the measure we have used so far, corresponds
to value added domestically. Gross national product (GNP) corresponds to the value added by domestically owned factors of production.
22
GNP is equal to GDP plus net factor payments from the rest of the world
(factor payments from the rest of the world minus factor payments to
the rest of the world). While GDP is now the measure most commonly
mentioned, GNP was widely used until the early 1990s, and you will still
encounter it in newspapers and academic publications.
For most countries, the difference between GNP and GDP is typically small,
because factor payments to and from the rest of the world roughly cancel.
For the United States in 2003, the difference between GDP and GNP was
$43 billionabout 0.4% of GDP (This is an unusually small number, by
historical standards. But, for the United States, the difference between the
two has never exceeded 1% of GDP.)
There are a few exceptions. Among them is Kuwait. When oil was discovered in Kuwait, Kuwaits government decided that a portion of oil revenues
would be saved and invested abroad rather than spent, so as to provide future Kuwaiti generations with investment income when oil revenues came
to an end. Kuwait ran a large current account surplus, steadily accumulating large foreign assets. As a result, it now has large holdings of foreign
assets, and receives substantial investment income from the rest of the
world. Table 1 gives GDP, GNP, and net factor payments for Kuwait, from
1989 to 1994.
Table 1. GDP, GNP, and Net Factor Payments in Kuwait, 19891994
Year
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
GDP
7143
5328
3131
5826
7231
7380
GNP
9616
7560
4669
7364
8386
8321
23
24
Lets think of these assets for now as domestic oneyear bonds and foreign
oneyear bonds. To continue with our focus on the United States and the
United Kingdom, consider for example the choice between U.S. oneyear
bonds and U.K. oneyear bonds, from the point of view of a U.S. investor.
25
Figure 186. Expected Returns from Holding OneYear U.S. Bonds or OneYear U.K. Bonds
Lets now make the same assumption we made in Chapter 14 when discussing the choice between shortterm bonds and longterm bonds, or between bonds and stocks. Lets assume that you and other financial investors
care only about the expected rate of return and therefore want to hold only
the asset with the highest expected rate of return. In that case, if both U.K.
bonds and U.S. bonds are to be held, they must have the same expected
rate of return, so that the following arbitrage relation must hold
(1 + it ) = (Et )(1 + it )(
1
e )
Et+1
Reorganizing
(1 + it ) = (1 + it )(
Et
e )
Et+1
(18.2)
Equation (18.2) is called the uncovered interest parity relation, or simply the interest parity condition.26
The assumption that financial investors will hold only the bonds with the
highest expected rate of return is obviously too strong, for two reasons:
26. The word uncovered is to distinguish this relation from another relation called the
covered interest parity condition. The covered interest parity condition is derived by
looking at the following choice:
Buy and hold U.S. bonds for one year. Or buy pounds today, buy one-year U.K. bonds
with the proceeds, and agree to sell the pounds for dollars a year ahead at a predetermined price, called the forward exchange rate.
The rate of return to these two alternatives, which can both be realized at no risk today,
must be the same. The covered interest parity condition is a riskless arbitrage condition.
26
It ignores risk: The exchange rate a year from now is uncertain; that
means that holding U.K. bonds is more risky, in terms of dollars,
than holding U.S. bonds.27
gives
(1 + it ) =
(1 + it )
e
[1 + (Et+1
Et )/Et )]
(18.3)
This gives us a relation between the domestic nominal interest rate, it , the
foreign nominal interest rate, it , and the expected rate of appreciation of
e
the domestic currency, (Et+1
Et )/Et . As long as interest rates or the
expected rate of depreciation are not too largesay below 20% a yeara
good approximation to this equation is given by28
27. Whether holding U.K. bonds or U.S. bonds is more risky actually depends on which
investors we are looking at. Holding U.K. bonds is more risky from the point of view
of U.S. investors. Holding U.S. bonds is more risky from the point of view of British
investors. (Why?)
28. This follows from Proposition 3 in Appendix 2 at the end of the book.
27
it it
e
Et+1
Et
Et
(18.4)
This is the form of the interest parity condition you must remember: Arbitrage implies that the domestic interest rate must be equal to the foreign
interest rate minus the expected appreciation rate of the domestic currency.
Note that the expected appreciation rate of the domestic currency is also
the expected depreciation rate of the foreign currency.29 So equation (18.4)
can be equivalently stated as saying that the domestic interest rate must
be equal to the foreign interest rate minus the expected depreciation rate
of the foreign currency.
Lets apply this equation to U.S. bonds versus U.K. bonds. Suppose the
oneyear nominal interest rate is 2.0% in the United States, 5.0% in the
United Kingdom. Should you hold U.K. bonds or U.S. bonds? The answer:
If you expect the pound to depreciate by more than 3.0%, then, despite the fact that the interest rate is higher in the United Kingtom
than in the United States, investing in U.K. bonds is less attractive
than investing in U.S. bonds. By holding U.K. bonds, you will get
higher interest payments next year, but the pound will be worth less
in terms of dollars next year, making investing in U.K. bonds less
attractive than investing in U.S. bonds.
29. If the dollar is expected to appreciate by 3% vis a vis the pound, then the pound is
expected to depreciate by 3% vis a vis the dollar.
28
the coming month to be equal to the rate of depreciation over the last
month. The dollar was worth 100,000 cruzeiros at the end of July 1993,
and worth 134,600 cruzeiros at the end of August 1993, so the rate of
appreciation of the dollar vis a vis the cruzeiroequivalently the rate of
depreciation of the cruzeiro vis a vis the dollarin August was 34.6%. If
depreciation is expected to continue at the same rate in September as it
did in August, the expected return from investing in Brazilian bonds for a
month is
1.369
= 1.017
1.346
The expected rate of return in dollars from holding Brazilian bonds is only
(1.017 1) = 1.6% per month, not the 36.9% per month that looked so
attractive. Note that 1.6% per month is still much higher than the monthly
interest rate on U.S. bonds (about 0.2%). But think of the risk and the
transaction costsall the elements we ignored when we wrote the arbitrage
condition. When these are taken into account, you may well decide to keep
your funds out of Brazil.
The arbitrage relation between interest rates and exchange rates (either
in the form of equation (18.2) or equation (18.4)) will play a central role
in the following chapters. It suggests that, unless countries are willing to
tolerate large movements in their exchange rate, domestic and foreign interest rates are likely to move very much together. Take the extreme case
of two countries that commit to maintaining their bilateral exchange rates
at a fixed value. If markets have faith in this commitment, they will expect
the exchange rate to remain constant, and the expected depreciation will
be equal to zero. In that case, the arbitrage condition implies that interest
rates in the two countries will have to move exactly together.30 Most of
the time, as we shall see, governments do not make such absolute commite
30. If Et+1
= Et , then the interest parity condition implies it = it .
30
ments to maintain the exchange rate, but they often do try to avoid large
movements in the exchange rate. This puts sharp limits on how much they
can allow their interest rate to deviate from interest rates elsewhere in the
world.
How much do nominal interest rates actually move together in major countries? Figure 187 plots the threemonth nominal interest rate in the
United States and the threemonth nominal interest rate in the United
Kingdom (both expressed at annual rates), since 1970. The impression from
the figure is of related but not identical movements. Interest rates were very
high in both countries in the early 1980s, and high againalthough much
more so in the United Kingdom than in the United Statesin the late
1980s. Both have been low since the early to mid 1990s. At the same time,
differences between the two have sometimes been quite large: In 1990, for
example, the U.K. interest rate was nearly 7% above the U.S. interest rate.
In the coming chapters, we shall return to why such differences emerge,
and what their implications may be.31
Figure 187 ThreeMonth Nominal Interest Rates in the United States
and in the United Kingdom, 19702003 (Caption. U.S. and U.K. nominal
interest rates have largely moved together over the last 33 years.)
31
Openness in financial markets allows a choice between domestic assets and foreign assets. This choice depends primarily on their relative rates of return, which depend on domestic interest rates and
foreign interest rates, and on the expected rate of appreciation of
the domestic currency.
Summary
Openness in goods markets allows people and firms to choose between domestic goods and foreign goods. Openness in financial markets allows financial investors to hold domestic financial assets or
foreign financial assets.
32
The multilateral real exchange rate, or real exchange rate for short,
is a weighted average of bilateral real exchange rates, with the weight
for each foreign country equal to its share in trade.
The current account and the capital account are mirror images of
each other. Leaving aside statistical problems, the current account
plus the capital account must sum to zero. A current account deficit
is financed by net capital flows from the rest of the world, thus
by a capital account surplus. Similarly, a current account surplus
corresponds to a capital account deficit.
33
Key terms
tariffs
quotas
capital controls
tradable goods
revaluation
devaluation
merchandise trade
foreign exchange
balance of payments
current account
capital account
investment income
34
statistical discrepancy
Further Readings
If you want to learn more about international trade and international economics, a very good textbook is by Paul Krugman and Maurice Obstfeld,
International Economics, Theory and Policy, 6th ed. (New York: Pearson
Addison Wesley, 2002).
If you want to know current exchange rates between nearly any pair of currencies in the world, look at the currency converter on http://www.oanda.com.
35
17.5
Figure 18-7. U.S. and U.K. Three-Month Nominal Interest Rates, 1970-2003
IUS
IUK
15.0
12.5
Percent
10.0
7.5
5.0
2.5
0.0
1970
1972
1974
1976
1978
1980
1982
1984
1986
1988
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
2002
Year t+1:
$1
$(1+it )
$1
$ Et (1+i*t) (1/Eet+1)
Et
Et (1+i*t)
Holding:
U.S. bonds
U.K. bonds
1.25
1.20
1.15
1.10
1.05
1.00
0.95
0.90
0.85
0.80
1973
1975
1977
1979
1981
1983
1985
1987
1989
1991
1993
1995
1997
1999
2001
2003
Figure 18-4. Real and Nominal Exchange rates between the U.S. and the the U.K., 1970-2003
2.0
1.8
1.6
1.4
1.2
1.0
0.8
EXCN
REXCN
0.6
1970
1972
1974
1976
1978
1980
1982
1984
1986
1988
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
2002
0.90
Figure 18-2. The Nominal Exchange Rate between the dollar and the pound, 1970-2003
0.84
0.78
0.72
0.66
0.60
0.54
0.48
0.42
0.36
1970
1972
1974
1976
1978
1980
1982
1984
1986
1988
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
2002
0.16
0.14
0.12
Percentage of GDP
0.10
0.08
0.06
0.04
0.02
EXPORTS_GDP
IMPORTS_GDP
0.00
1960
1965
1970
1975
1980
1985
1990
1995
2000