Competition Law Project
Competition Law Project
Competition Law Project
INTRODUCTION
Since attaining independence in 1947, India for the better part of half a century
thereafter adopted and followed policies comprising of what are known as Command-andControl laws, rules, regulations and executive orders1. The then competition law in India
was the Monopolies and restrictive Trade Practices Act, 1969 (MRTP Act in brief). It was in
1991 that there was widespread economic reform and consequently an economy based on
free market principles came into force. Economic liberalisation in India was seeing the light
of the day and the need for an effective competition regime was recognised. The new
competition Act, 2002 was introduced in replacement of the MRTP Act. The repeal of the
MRTP Act was on the ground that the act was not suited to deal with issues of competition
that may be expected to arise in the new liberal business environment2.
In the MRTP Act, tie-up sales were dealt under Restrictive Trade Practices (RTP). It
was considered as a practise which had the effect of preventing, distorting or restricting
competition or as a practise which tends to obstruct the flow of capital or resource into the
stream of production. An entity, body or undertaking charged with the practise of RTP had to
plead for gateways provided in the MRT Act to avoid being indicted.
Under the Competition Act, Tie-in arrangement is dealt with under the head Vertical
Anti-Competitive Agreement. A tie-in arrangement, under this Act, is not illegal per se but if
it has an appreciable adverse effect on the competition, then it becomes illegal. Tie-in
arrangements have both good and bad effects on the competition. On one hand tie-in
arrangements may result in price discrimination, barriers to new entry in the market,
monopolisation of the tied and tying products. On the other hand tie-in arrangement may
benefit the consumers by providing them with goods or services in a bundle which are
required and at lower price. But tie-in arrangements are more likely to adversely affect the
economy than being beneficial to the economy. Its effects are discussed later in the paper.
1 Dr. Chakravarty, S., MRTP Act metamorphoses into Competition Act pg no. 5
2 Ramappa T., Competition Law in India Policy, Issues and Development
12(2006) (New York, Oxford University Press)
1 | Page
ANTI-COMPETITIVE AGREEMENTS
People of the same trade seldom meet together, even for merriment and diversion,
but the conversation ends in a conspiracy against the public, or in some contrivance to raise
prices.3
This statement of Adam Smith makes it abundantly clear for a need to have a proper
regulatory mechanism for prevention of anti-competitive agreement which not only affect the
market economy leading to monopolistic approach but also victimizes the consumers and
thereby cause harm to the entire economy creating hindrance to the competition in the
market.
Anticompetitive agreements can be said to be agreements that negatively or adversely
impact the process of competition in the market. According to an OECD/World Bank
Glossary, anticompetitive practices refer to a wide range of business practices that a firm or
group of firms may engage in order to restrict inter-firm competition to maintain or increase
their relative market position and profits without necessarily providing goods and services at
a lower cost or higher quality4. Similarly, it can be said that anticompetitive agreements are
agreements between firms or enterprises that restrict or prevent or otherwise unfavourably
affect competition, and that may help increase the market position or share of the parties and
may also be to the disadvantage of the consumer as the products and services may be
available at a higher cost than are available in a competitive market and also may be of a
lower quality.
Prohibition of anti-Competitive Agreements has been provided under Section 3 Chapter II
of the Competition Act, 2002 which besides prohibition of certain agreements also deals with
abuse of dominant position and regulation of combinations of the Act. The provisions of the
Competition Act relating to anti-competitive agreements were notified on 20th May, 2009.
Section 3 of the Act specifically deals with anti-competitive agreements.
3 Smith Adam, An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations,
London Publication (1776) Pg 88 in Parihar, Pratima Anti-competitive
Agreements Underlying Concepts and Principles under the Competition Act,
2002, (2012)Pg 16.
4 World Bank/OECD: Glossary of Industrial Organization on Economics and
Competition Law.
Page | 2
Page | 3
ANTI-COMPETITIVE VERICAL
AGREEMENT
In Horizontal Agreements the parties to the
agreement are enterprises at the same stage
of the production chain engaged in similar
trade of goods or provision of services
competing in the same market.
For e.g. agreements between producers or
between wholesalers etc.
ANTI-COMPETITIVE
AGREEMENT
In Vertical Agreements the parties to the
agreements are non-competing enterprises at
different stages of the production chain.
For e.g. agreements essentially between
manufacturers and suppliers i.e. between
producers and wholesalers or between
manufacturers and retailers etc.
Page | 6
TIE-IN ARRANGEMENT
As defined in Explanation (a) to sub-section (4) of Section 3, tie-in arrangement
includes any arrangement requiring a purchaser of goods, as a condition of such purchase, to
purchase some other goods. The product or service that is required by the buyer is called the
tying product or service and the product that is forced on the buyer is called the tied product
or service.
A product or service is to be treated as being the subject of a tie-in arrangement when
its supply is offered on the condition that the buyer who ordered for some product or service
Page | 7
of
the machine to use a specific brand of paper i.e. (product B). The paper sales occur
over time and vary across users, based on their demand for the copies. A customer
would not need to determine how much paper to buy at the time the machine was
bought. But under the tying contract, whatever paper was required would have to be
bought from the machine seller.
The dynamic tied sale is different from the static tie in another way. The good
involved in a dynamic tie are required to use the product. For example, one cannot use
a photocopy machine without a paper but one can enjoy Xbox without the Halo game.
Therefore, all the customers that buy the product A must also buy product B in a
dynamic tie.
FORMS OF TYING
Tying can take the following forms:
Page | 9
US LAW ON TYING
Section 1 of the Sherman Act, 1890 and Section 3 of the Clayton Act, 1914 deal with the
concepts of Tying. A tying agreement is subject to both these provisions and although the
wording in the two sections differs, both of them apply a similar substantive standard. Section
1 of the Sherman Act prohibits every agreement in restraint of trade depending upon the
unreasonableness of such a restraint. Section 3 of the Clayton Act forbids tying agreements
when the effect....may be to substantially lessen competition or tend to create a monopoly.
Though there appears to be no difference between these two laws, the Courts, in their
7 Hilti v commission; T-30/89 [1990] ECR-II-163, [1992] 4 CMLR 16, CFI
Page | 10
8 Jefferson Parish Hospital Dist. No. 2 et al. v. Hyde,[ 466 U.S. 2 (1984)]
9 United States v. Microsoft Corp., [253 F.3d 34 (D.C. Cir. 2001)]
Page | 11
The Rule of Reason co-exists with a per se rule in two senses 13. Firstly some courts have
declined to find two products tied together when the challenged arrangement seems
reasonable, either because it served legitimate functions or because threats to competition
seemed fanciful. Most frequently, the courts have ended up classifying a practice as exclusive
dealing rather than tying, with the result that it is made subject to the rule of reason.
Secondly, the per se rule do not exhaust the concerns of antitrust law. A refusal to condemn a
particular restraint per se does not necessarily mean that antitrust law is indifferent to that
restrain or affirmatively approves it, the rule of reason remains applicable.
Tying arrangements that do not meet all of the elements of a per se tying claim may still be
held unlawful as unreasonable restraints of trade under a rule of reason analysis. Unlike a per
se analysis, where the focus of the inquiry is on the tying product, a rule of reason inquiry
looks at the competitive effect of the arrangement in the relevant market for the tied product.
However, it is unlikely that a tying arrangement that passes muster under the strict per se
standard will be found to violate the less rigorous rule of reason test
Although Jefferson Parish still represents the general position in the U.S. with respect
to tying, the Court of Appeals judgment in Microsoft III indicates a preference, in some
circumstances at least, for a rule of reason approach, noting the Supreme Courts warning in
Broadcast Music v. CBS that it is only after considerable experience with certain business
relationships that courts classify them as per se violations.
In Microsoft III, the Court of Appeals concluded that a per se rule was inappropriate,
due to the fact that the circumstances in Microsoft III differed from previous cases, and that
the separate products approach used in Jefferson Parish was not a suitable approach given
that it was backward looking. The case was therefore referred back to the District Court with
a direction to conduct a rule of reason analysis which balanced the anticompetitive effects
and efficiencies.
Article 81(1) of the EC Treaty includes as agreements that which are incompatible
with the common market and the agreements that make the conclusion of contracts subject to
acceptance by the other parties of supplementary obligations which, by their nature or
according to commercial usage, have no connection with the subject of such contracts. Article
82 includes tying as an abuse of dominant position, thus Article 81 is attracted when tying is
part of an agreement concluded by a non-dominant supplier and a buyer. However,
Regulation 2790/1999 on Vertical restraints provides for a safe harbour system whereby
vertical agreements involving tying will be presumed compatible with article 81 if the market
share of the supplier is below 30% in the relevant market.14
Tying agreements are not illegal per se. An illegal tying agreement takes place when a seller
requires a buyer to purchase another, less desired or cheaper product, in addition to the
desired product, so that the competition in the tied product would be lessened. Sherman act
also pointed out that there should be separateness of products which are tied because if the
products are identical and market is same then there is no unlawful tying agreement.
The European Commission and European Courts have adopted a unified approach
to the different forms of tying and bundling. 15 In other words, contractual tying( including the
tying of primary products and consumables) and integration of products have been assessed
in the same way without taking into account the different underlying effects of them on
competition.
The formal framework of the tying analysis is almost a carbon copy of the U.S. per se
approach, following a four-stage assessment:
1) To establish market power (dominance) of the seller in relation to the tying product;
2) To identify tying which means to demonstrate that (a) customers are forced (b) to purchase
two separate products (the tying and the tied product);
3) To assess the effects of tying on competition;
4) To consider whether any exceptional justification for tying exists
14 Ioannis Lianos, Vertical Restraints, and the Limits of Article 81(1) EC: Between
Hierarchies And Networks, 3 J.Competition L. & Econ. 625 in Sundararajan, Preethi, An
Analytical Study of Nature and Types of Vertical Anti-Competitive Agreements, Pg. 21.
15 Gupta, Anisha, Concept of Tying and Bundling and its Effect on Competition:
A Critical Study of it in Various Jurisdictions (2010) Pg. 24
Page | 14
The
guidance on Abusive Exclusionary conduct, however, simply notes that the Commission may
also examine whether combining two independent products into a new, single product might
enhance the ability to bring such a product to the market to the benefit of customers
18 Article 82 Staff Discussion Paper, Point 205 in Gupta, Anisha, Concept of
Tying and Bundling and its Effect on Competition: A Critical Study of it in Various
Jurisdictions (2010)
Page | 17
Page | 18
On examination of the agreement between the DTH service provider and the customer, it was
noted by the DG that no such clause which directly restricts or forces the customer to enter
into tie-in arrangement is there. However, on account of the lack of customer awareness and
lack of availability of Set Top Boxes and other equipments in open market, the customer does
end up buying all the related equipments from the DTH service providers only. The sale of
Set Top Box, Smart Card and Dish Antenna is tied-in as all the three equipments are provided
in one package and are not readily available for sale in open market-independent of each
other. These three components are technically essential as each performs a specific function
for availing the DTH service transmission. Owing to the lack of practical interoperability and
lack of consumer awareness, the customer has no alternative but to purchase these three
equipments from the DTH service provider whose service he is availing. This ultimately
results in tie-in arrangements of the Consumer Premises Equipment from the DTH service
provider. Except Dish TV, no other DTH service provider, under investigation, has
specifically and clearly mentioned in its agreement with the customer that a customer can
avail or procure compatible Set Top Box from any other source. This offer of Dish TV is also
of no benefit to customer as neither the compatible Set Top Box is commercially and readily
available in the open market, nor the consumer is really aware of this possibility
Summing up the findings, the DG concluded as under:
The entire forgoing discussion and the recent developments indicate that the tie-in sale
of the Customer Premises Equipment is happening on account of non-availability of
Conditional Access Module (CAM), Set Top Box etc. in the open market, lack of consumer
awareness as well as lack of enforcement of licensing conditions by any regulatory authority.
The recent development of the news of the likelihood of availability of Conditional Access
Module (CAM) in open market will be a positive step towards achieving interoperability. This
can be further enhanced and fully interoperability, which is technically possible, can be
Page | 20
However, for both the above types of price discrimination to take place, it is a
prerequisite that the firm has market power in the tying market. However, such price
discrimination can have ambiguous effects in efficiency and consumer welfare. These
agreements may also at times allow an increase in output that will efficiently serve marginal
buyers who would otherwise have not been able to buy the tying product if it, were just sold
at a separate price. However, it has to be kept in mind that been tying can increase monopoly
profits.20
(2) Another worrisome outcome of tie-in arrangements is when there is a demand for multiple
units of the tying product and not the tied product. In such a scenario, the seller might use
bundling as a means to push off slow moving products as tied products. Alternatively, a
monopolist of the tying product can thus maximize profits by squeezing out that consumer
surplus without losing customers by making the tying product unavailable unless buyers take
a tied product form it at a price above the tied market price. Hence, either ways, however the
monopolist decides to handle the situation, the consumer will either be faced to pay a
premium for the product or pay for and buy products that he does not need.
(3) Tying can also increase market power in the tied market by foreclosing enough of the tied
market to reduce rival entry, efficiency, existence or expandability. Tying can create the aforementioned anticompetitive effects if one relaxes the unrealistic assumption that tied market
rivals face no fixed costs, have constant marginal costs that do not at all depend on output,
and can expand instantaneously to supply to the whole market. For instance, if there are costs
to entering a market, it is profitable for a firm that makes two products to bundle them to
deter entry by an equally efficient rival that can only enter one of those markets. The reason
is that the bundle leaves less of the market available to then rival, and thus can make the
profits of entry lower than the costs of entry. 21
20 Einer Elhuage, Tying, Bundled Discounts and the Single Monopoly Profit
Theory, 123 Harv. L. Rev. 397
21 Edwin Hughes, The Left Side Of Antitrust: What Fairness Means And Why It
Matters, 77 Marq. L. Rev. 265
Page | 22
22 Einer Elhauge & Damien Geradin, Global Competition Law and Economics, (Hart
Publishing, USA), First Edn. Reprint, 2008, 498-505 in
Page | 23
CONCLUSION
This research paper attempts to explain the basic concept of tying along with a critical
study of it across various jurisdictions. The U.S. and E.U. positions have been considered
along with the difference in their approaches, to bring out the advantages and disadvantages
of these approaches. Case laws have been analysed to understand the working and
enforcement of the Competition/Antitrust Laws.
It can be concluded from this research that the initial Per-Se Illegality Approach in
respect of tying is not a correct stand. Every case of tying should be judged on its own merits
and demerits and not in regard with straight- line jacket formulae. A Per Se Approach
prohibits certain acts without regard to the particular effects of the acts, i.e. no investigation
into the question of possible pro-competitive effects. The Per-Se prohibition is justified for
types of conduct that have manifestly anti-competitive implications and a very limited
potential for precompetitive benefits.
A Rule of Reason Approach on the other hand is about investigating the
effects of the challenged conduct, taking into account the particular facts of the case. The
Courts decide whether the questioned practice imposes an unreasonable restraint on
competition taking into account a variety of factors. The Rule of Reason Approach which
considers the pros and cons of each case is more favourable to the Indian legal system.
This paper also highlights the various effects that a tying arrangement has on the
competition and economy of the country. It can be said that tying arrangement has
widespread adverse affect on the economy of the country.
Page | 24