The Theory of Stock Market Efficiency
The Theory of Stock Market Efficiency
The Theory of Stock Market Efficiency
by Ray Ball,
MARKET EFFICIENCY:University ofRochester*
ACCOMPLISHMENT
S AND
LIMITATIONS
1
BANK OF AMERICA JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE
FIGURE 1
EPS Increases
Market Index
EPS
Decreases
2
BANK OF AMERICA JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE
5
VOLUME 8 NUMBER 1 SPRING 1995
3
BANK OF AMERICA JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE
Despite
its
insights
and
accomplishments, however, the theory of
efficient markets has obvious limitations.
For example, it treats information as a
commodity that means the same thing to
all investors. It also assumeswith
potentially serious consequences, in my
viewthat information is costlessly
incorporated into prices. In reality, of
course,
investors
interpret
events
differently;
they
face
considerable
uncertainty about why others are trading;
and, especially in the case of smaller
firms, they face high costs (as a
percentage of firm value) in acquiring
and processing information. Given these
limitations, it is not surprising that
researchers soon began to accumulate
evidence that appeared to contradict the
theory. Whether the existence of such
anomalous" findings indicates a fatal
flaw in the theoryor, more likely, the
value of incorporating greater realism
only time and more research will tell.
My aim in this article is to provide an
admittedly
somewhat
personal
perspective on the accomplishments and
limitations of the theory, and to offer a
few suggestions about how the theory
might be modified to explain some of the
contradictory evidence. Briefly put, my
view is this: the theory of efficient
markets was an audacious and welcome
change from the comparative ignorance
about stock market behavior that
preceded it; and despite its now-obvious
theoretical and empirical flaws, it has
profoundly influenced both the theory
and practice of finance.
4
BANK OF AMERICA JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE
5.
11. V. Roberts. "Stock Market "Patterns" and Financial Analysis: Methodological Suggestions." Journal of l:iuance I t (1959). p. .
For a review of the random walk literature and precedents, see F.F. Fama. "Ffficient Capital Markets: A Review of Theory and Empirical
Work." Journal <>J' Finance!^ < 1970). 383-1 P.
Stimulated by a new research design known as the event study, a large body of empirical
research in the 1970s provided consistent evidence of the stock market's ability to process
information in a rational, in some cases ingenious, fashion.
ACCOMPLISHMENTS OF THE
THEORY OF STOCK MARKET
EFFICIENCY
It is difficult to trace the influence of
ideas because their effects range from
the direct and concrete (such as the
effects on financial practice I noted
earlier) to the more subtle and abstract
(for example, their influence on how we
think about issues, and on the concepts
and language we use).
To gain some appreciation of how
thoroughly the research on market
efficiency has changed our thinking
about stock markets, imagine the
mindset of an observer of stock markets
prior to the research that began in the
late 60s. Ordinarily we view the markets
reaction to information through the lens
of chronological time. Reading the daily
financial press, for example, we observe
the market's response at a single point in
time to what is often a bewildering
variety of events and circumstances
affecting companies values. There are
announcements
of
earnings
and
dividend, new promotional campaigns,
labor disputes, staff retrenchments, new
5
BANK OF AMERICA JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE
surprising and illuminating example: announcements of new public stock offerings are associated
with an immediate 3% average stock price
reduction. The prevailing explanation of this
negative market response is as follows: Investors
recognize that managers, as representatives of
existing shareholders, are more likely to issue new
FIGURE 2
STOCK PRICE CHANGES IN
RELATION TO STOCK
SPLITS*
-10-5
10
Stock prices rise during the 30 months before stock splits. Because all the information in the split is public knowledge bt the time it occurs, the
stock price reaction to the split is complete by "month 0." The graph shows price movements for the average firm. Firms with larger splits tend to
experience larger price movements. Source: FFJR (1969).
Summing Up
Encouraged, then, by its initial accomplishments and reinforced by other theoretical
15.
9
VOLUME 8 NUMBER 1 SPRING 1995
Defects in Efficiency as a
Model of Stock Markets
Failure to Incorporate Information Acquisition and Processing Costs. One of the most
important explanations of these anomalies is likely
to be the neglected role of information costs.
Information costs are neither new to economists
nor inconsistent with competitive markets.
Nevertheless, the costs of acquiring and
processing information have received scant
attention in the theory and empirical research on
stock market efficiency.
The first event studies such as the FFJR
study of stock splits and the Ball-Brown study of
annual earnings reports investigated relatively
simple cases in which information is wridely
disseminated in the financial press and on the
wire services to analysts and other investors. The
cost to individual investors of acquiring such
public information (as opposed to the cost of
producing that same information prior to
disclosure) w^as assumed to be negligible. The
information was also assumed to be simple to use,
with negligible processing (or interpretation)
costs.
But what about those academic research designs that simulate trading strategies that in fact
have substantial information acquisition and
processing costs? In such cases, the abnormal
returns reported by the research could be
significantly overstated. Consider the following:
If 1,000 professors of finance worldwide annually
incur costs of $50,000 each (including salary,
computer costs, and overhead) in searching for
anomalies, the expected return from their discovery of pricing errors in the market could be as
much as 5% per year (or $50 million) on a $1
billion portfolio. And, if they have been searching
for 20 years, the expected return from producing
such private information could be many times
larger.
But, if the expected returns from such strategies
are this large, why have some researchers
published their anomalous evidence? Why have
14 R.J. Shiller, Do Stock Prices they not instead used that information for private
gain?
Move Too Much to Bejustified by
3. More generally, what are the expected gains from
Subsequent
producing and trading on private information?
15Changes in Dividends?, American
4. What is the meaning of gains from a trading rule
Economic Review 71, (1981a), 421-436.
that is simulated using historical data together
with
modern
computing
and
statistical
167. V.I.. Bernard and J. Thomas.
techniques? (Does this differ from, say, the
Evidence That Stock Prices Do
simulated gains from owning a helicopter gunship
Not Fully
during the Middle Ages?)
hS. For a survey, see M. Reinganum, The Collapse of the Efficient Market
Hypothesis: A Look at the Empirical Anomalies of the 1980s." Selected Readings
in Investment Management (Institutional Investor, 1988).
What is the predicted rate of return in a competitive market for an investor like
Warren Buffett who sits on the corporate board, is a close friend of the CEO,
and has a voice in major corporate decisions?
19.
For a defense of beta, see S.P. kothari and J. Shanken in this issue.
Differences among investors' information ami hciiefs are an added Nource of uncertainty and hence
JOURNAL OF APPLIED
3 CORPORATE
FINANCE
27.
For some informal evidence of a sharp decline in market risk premiums over the
past 20 years, see J.R. Woolridge, "Do Stock Prices Reflect Fundamental
Values?. (in this issue).
15
30.
theory including the DCF present value model, the option pricing model, and
efficient market theory itself. Each of these financial models is concerned
exclusively with investor demand for (and hence the price of) a certain asset in
relation to other assets with given prices. Indeed, I would argue that the failure
to consider the supply of investments is perhaps the greatest deficiency in
modern J'inancial economic theory.
Ball and Kothari (1989) provide evidence that endogenous risk variation explains
much of the serial correlation observed in Fama and French (1988). A related
issue is the evidence of apparent price reversals in De Bondt and Thaler (1985,
1987). Both Chan (1988) and Ball and Kothari (1989) report that the equity
betas of the most extreme losing" stocks can be expected to increase because
of the extreme increase in their market debt-equity ratios. Conversely, the
extreme "winning stocks are likely to have equity beta decreases due to
extreme leverage reductions.
26 R. Ball, 'Anomalies in
Relationships Between Securities'
Yields and Yield- Surrogates, Journal
of Financial Economics 6, (1978), 103-126. I
borrowed the word anomaly from
Thomas Kuhns famous book, The Structure of
Scientific Revolutions (University of Chicago
Press, 1970), which introduced
the term to the
1
JOURNAL OF Mll.ll.l8> CORPORATE
FINANCE
The theoretical developments of the 60s and 70s have helped transform the
practice
of finance.
CONCLUDING OBSERVATIONS
Are stock markets efficient? Yes
and no. On the one hand, the
research provides insights into stock
price behavior that were previously
unimaginable. On the other hand, as
research has come to show, the
theory of efficient markets is, like all
theories, an imperfect and limited
way of viewing stock markets. The
issue will be impossible to solve
conclusively while there are so many
binding limitations to the asset
pricing models that underlie empirical
tests of market efficiency.
Our models of asset pricing
began w^ith the CAPM and thus have
an accumulated history of only 30
years. With such a limited tradition in
asset pricing, we could hardly expect
to have a strong basis for concluding
that security prices do (or do not)
immediately restore equilibrium in
response
to
new
information,
particularly in the presence of
extreme uncertainty. Bearing such
constraints in mind, I believe that
much of the evidence on stock price
behavior does not and cannot reliably
address
the
factual
issue
of
efficiency at this point in time. Our
* RAY BALL
is Wesray Professor of Accounting at the University of Rochesters Simon School of Business.
17
7. K.F. Fama. L. Fisher. M.C.Jensen and R. Roll. "The Adjustment of Stock Prices
13- Teachers and researchers made frequent reference to the Sharpe-Lintner
model well before it was formally tested (by Black. Jensen, and Scholes in 19~2
and Eama and MacBeth in 1973), relying in part on the strong evidence of market
efficiency and on the perceiv ed overlapping of the two ideas.
25. Shiller (1981), cited earlier.