A Lunch in Warsaw Was The Beginning of A Brilliant Career
A Lunch in Warsaw Was The Beginning of A Brilliant Career
A Lunch in Warsaw Was The Beginning of A Brilliant Career
political science. I dont remember if I had the smarts to ask him what political
science was: I didnt know what it was, Przeworski related in a 2005 interview.
I was twenty years old and I would have gone anywhere to do anything.
The environment at Northwestern became Przeworskis first real contact with
political science, a subject that was not taught at universities in Communist
Poland. He returned to Warsaw, was given the opportunity to defend his
American doctoral dissertation in Poland, and was once again invited to the
United States by the University of Pennsylvania to participate in an international
research project. There he remained and came to spend, like many other winners
of the Johan Skytte Prize, many happy years at the University of Chicago, a
unique institution and a place committed to the pursuit of ideas. You could
walk into the office of the dean and say: Look, Ive been sitting on this project
for five years. Im sick and tired of it, and Im close to finishing but I need some
time off. And you walked out with time off.
Przeworski, somewhat disparagingly termed a Western Marxist by the
orthodox, took his place at the seminar table in earnest in 1980, when he
published Social Democracy as a Historical Phenomenon in the New Left
Review. The problem statement and lines of argument were well known among
the academic Left. Przeworski brought forward the classic controversial issues
that caused schisms between revolutionary Communists and reformist Social
Democrats, and between orthodox Marxists and so-called revisionists. At first,
he was met with dense silence, eventually by condemnation. This was not true
Marxism.
His question of whether Social Democracy could have done better, and if so
how, was not answered with references to the foundational documents of
Marxism. Przeworski argued there were empirical lessons that could, with
theoretical acumen and methodological imagination, be transformed into general
insights. In a series of works, whose main results are collected in two books
Capitalism and Social Democracy and Paper StonesPrzeworski developed an
analysis that clarified the implications of Social Democracy, having chosen to
work within the confines of bourgeois democracy and universal suffrage. He
stressed the necessity of class compromisethat the workers movement must
include more social groups in their electoral base and not only manual
workersand why the welfare state with strong emphasis on redistribution was
probably the best the workers movement could aspire to.
In parallel with his American career, Przeworski has sustained contact with his
native Poland. As early as 1986, long before most others, he began to sense
radical transformations in the air that once they broke through to the light of day
in 1989/1990 took almost everyone by surprise, politicians and political
scientists alike. The walk in Warsaw on that day in June 1986 with Jerzy Wiatr,
a friend and a Communist, was an eye-opener. Wiatr told him that the
2
between democracy and dictatorship. On average, total income grew at the same
rate in both types of regimes.
But surely democratized countries must first have achieved a certain level of
economic development? Firstly, the economy, then democracy. No, answers
Przeworski and thus shoots holes through yet another tenacious belief that has
dominated the social sciences for decades. There is no clear empirical
connection between a countrys level of development and the commencement of
processes toward democratization, as once claimed by modernization theory.
Przeworskis results, to return to the example of China, say that despite the
countrys incredible economic development, we cannot expect democratic
development to follow. It is at least equally likely that China will remain a
dictatorship, albeit an increasingly prosperous one, unless forces other than the
specifically economic trigger democratization. Nor will strong economic
development in Russia automatically shore up the countrys now tottering
democratic institutions.
However, once in place, how is democracy secured? Przeworskis analyses
show that the key to democratic survival is, yes, economic development. Above
a certain economic threshold, which Przeworski himself sets at 4,000 dollars
per capita and year, no democracy has thus far failed. If democracy arises at all,
it will be fragile as long as income levels are very low. India is therefore
something of an enigma in democracy studies: despite its (former) extreme
poverty, the country has remained democratic for more than 60 years. At the
same time, we know from Przeworskis research that, thanks to economic
development, Indian democracy is becoming more secure all the time.
That it is economic development that as good as guarantees the survival of
democracy is a fundamental insight, and for many reasons one that calls
attention to economic policy and poverty reduction as one of the most crucial
global problems today. In every aspect we examined, the differences between
poor and rich countries are enormous, Przeworski writes in Democracy and
Economic Development. Poverty reduction, which covers everything from
microloans to vaccines and public healthcare, should in other words be the focus
of world interest now more than everbut unfortunately it is not.
Adam Przeworskis interest in life-and-death issues has advanced political
science. Empirical brilliance, theoretical acumen, and methodological
imagination are united in this scholar of political science, who once journeyed to
the United States of America for doctoral studies in a subject he had never heard
of.
For the Prize Committee: Li Bennich-Bjrkman, Johan Skytte chair in
Eloquence and Government, Uppsala University; Jrgen Hermansson, professor
4