ARDL

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 13

Do the FDI, Economic growth and Trade affect each other for India: An

ARDL Approach

Anshul Kumar Singh


Department of Humanities and Social Science
IIT Kanpur
ansks@iitk.ac.in

10 Nov 2013

Abstract
This paper examines the dynamic causal relationships between foreign direct investment (FDI),
trade and economic growth in India by applying the bounds testing (ARDL) approach to
cointegration for the period from 1970 to 2012. The bounds tests suggest that the variables of
interest are bound together in the long-run when GDP per capita is the dependent variable. The
empirical findings confirm that there is bi-directional Granger causality between FDI and trade,
unidirectional Granger causality running from FDI to economic growth and from economic
growth to capital investment but there is no Granger causality from economic growth to FDI and
capital investment to per capita GDP.

Key words: FDI, trade openness, economic growth, ARDL cointegration, ECM, India.
JEL classification: C22, F13, F21.

1. Introduction:
The relationship between Foreign Direct investment (FDI), exports and economic growth has
gained importance and attention among policy makers and researchers. Foreign direct investment
(FDI) is often seen as important catalysts for economic growth in the developing countries. FDI
is also an important vehicle of technology transfer from developed countries to developing
countries. It stimulates domestic investment and facilitates improvements in human capital and
institutions in the host countries. International trade is also known to be an instrument of
economic growth (Frankel and Romer, 1999). Trade facilitates more efficient production of
goods and services by shifting production to countries that have comparative advantage in
producing them. Even though past studies show that FDI and trade have a positive impact on
economic growth, the size of such impact may vary across countries depending on the level of
human capital, domestic investment, infrastructure, macroeconomic stability, and trade policies.
The literature continues to debate the role of FDI and trade in economic growth as well as the
importance of economic and institutional developments in fostering FDI and trade. This lack of
consensus limits our understanding of the role of FDI and trade policies in economic growth
processes and restricts our ability to develop policies to promote economic growth.
Even though past studies show that FDI and trade have a positive impact on economic growth,
the size of such impact may vary across countries depending on the level of human capital,
domestic investment, infrastructure, macroeconomic stability, and trade policies. The literature
continues to debate the role of FDI and trade in economic growth as well as the importance of
economic and institutional developments in fostering FDI and trade. This lack of consensus
limits our understanding of the role of FDI and trade policies in economic growth processes and
restricts our ability to develop policies to promote economic growth.
In this paper I try to build up a long term relationship and short term dynamics between FDI
Trade openness per capita GDP and Capital investment variables using an ARDL (autoregressive
distributed lag) approach and ECM model.

2. Literature Review:
Yangru Wu (1999) emphasizes the role of the learning process through FDI in the growth of a
country. Findlay (1978) presents the contagion effect of managerial practices and advanced
technology introduced by foreign firms on the host countrys technology. In contrast, Charkovic
and Levine (2005) claim that FDI creates the crowding out effect on domestic capital and hence
the effect of FDI on growth is either insignificant or negative. In addition, other studies reason
that causality can be the other way and market seeking FDI tends to serve the growing
economies. Similarly, multinational corporations are attracted towards growing and productive
economies. Therefore, this bi-directional behaviour between FDI and GDP can create
simultaneity bias between the two variables.

Further, there is the similar two-way causality discussion between exports and GDP. The first is
the export led growth hypothesis, while the other equally appealing hypothesis is that output
growth causes export growth.
Regarding the export led growth hypothesis, Makki and Somwaru (2004) argue that export
growth increases factor productivity due to gains obtained from increasing returns to scale, by
catering to the larger foreign market. In addition, export growth relaxes the foreign exchange
constraints that result in an increase in the import of capital/technology-intensive intermediate
inputs. Due to the increased exports, efficiency is enhanced because exporters are able to
compete in foreign markets which results in technological advances and grooming of local
entrepreneurs. Grossman and Helpman (1991) advocate that open trade regimes helps in
importation of better technologies and also result in an improved investment climate.
Similarly Rodrik (1995) argues that it is difficult to identify the impact of trade on growth and
there is evidence that countries with higher income for reasons other than trade, tend to trade
more. Another criticism regarding the link between trade and growth comes from Rodriguez and
Rodrik (1999) who argue that failing to take into account institutional factors results in an
upwardly biased estimate of trade coefficients and the other variables. Furthermore, they claim
that the relationship between average tariff rates and economic growth is only slightly negative
and nowhere statistically significant.

To analyze the debate on the FDIs role as a complement or substitute to international trade, Wei,
Wang and Liu (2001) expound that according to Hechscher-Ohlin- Samuelson models, trade can
substitute for international movement of factors of production including FDI. For example, by
exporting capital intensive commodities in exchange for labour intensive commodities, the
perfectly immobile factors move through exports and imports. Helpman (1984) and Krugman
(1985) argue that if countries are asymmetric, the capital abundant country provides the
headquarter services in a labor intensive country through FDI in exchange for finished varieties
of differentiated goods. So FDI generates complementary trade flows from labour intensive
countries. However, if the countries are symmetric, there is a substitution effect and capital
intensive goods are exchanged for labor intensive goods.
Fosu and Magnus (2006) examine the long-run impact of foreign direct investment and trade on
economic growth in Ghana between 1970 and 2002. Using an augmented aggregate production
function growth model and by applying the bounds testing approach to cointegration, they found
cointegration relations between growth and its determinants in the aggregate production function
model. Their results indicated the impact of FDI on growth to be negative. Trade however was
found to have significant positive impact on growth.

Theoretical growth studies suggest at best a very complex and ambiguous relationship between
trade restrictions and growth. The endogenous growth literature has been diverse enough to
provide a different array of models in which trade restrictions can decrease or increase the
worldwide rate of growth. Note that if trading partners are asymmetric countries in the sense that
they have considerably different technologies and endowments, even if economic integration
raises the worldwide growth rate, it may adversely affect individual countries (see Grossman and
Helpman, 1991a,b; Lucas, 1988; Rivera-Batiz and Xie, 1993; Young 1991).
It is worthwhile to note that the theoretical growth literature has given more attention to the
relationship between trade policies and growth rather than the relationship between trade openess
and growth. Therefore, the conclusion about the relationship between trade barriers and growth
cannot be directly applied to the effects of changes in trade volumes on growth.

3. Data sources and description of variables


I have used the annual time series data in this study on economic growth, FDI, trade and capital
stock, which cover the 1970-2012 periods. The data has been obtained from different sources,
including Tunisia Central Bank annual reports, World Bank indicators etc.
The economic growth variable, which is measured by real GDP per capita, is noted by Y. F is the
value of real gross foreign direct investment inflows to GDP ratio; Trade openness is the total
sum of exports and imports divided by GDP and is noted by T; capital stock (K) is measured by
the real value of gross fixed capital formation (GFCF).

4. Methodology and empirical results


4.1 Unit roots Tests
In time series analysis, variables must be tested for stationarity before running the causality test.
For this test, in this current study we use the conventional ADF tests, the Phillips-Perron test
following Phillips and Perron (1988) and the Kwiatkowski-Phillips-Schmidt-Shin test proposed
by Kwiatkowski-Phillips-Schmidt-Shin (1992).
The ARDL / Bounds Testing methodology of Pesaran and Shin (1999) and Pesaran et al. (2001)
is based on the assumption that all variables are mixed of I(0) or I(1). So, before applying this
test, we determine the order of integration of the variables using the unit root tests. The objective
is to ensure that the variables are not I(2) so as to avoid spurious results. In the presence of
variables integrated of order two, we cannot interpret the values of F statistics.

The results of the stationarity tests show that all variables are non-stationary at level. These
results are given in Table 1. The ADF, the Phillips-Perron and KPSS tests applied to the first
difference of the data series reject the null hypothesis of non-stationarity for all the variables used
in this study (Table 2). It is, therefore, worth concluding that all the variables are integrated of order
one.
Table 1. Unit root test results on the log values of the variables at I(0)
ADF

Phillip-Perron

KPSS

Variables

Test
statistic

Critical
value at
5%

SIC
lag
Max
=9

Test
statistic

Critical
value at
5%

Bandwidth

Test
statistic

Critical
value at
5%

Bandwidth

Ln(F)

-2.79*

-3.52

-2.56*

-3.52

0.13*

0.15

Ln(K)

-1.57*

-3.52

-1.31*

-3.52

0.20*

0.21(.10)

Ln(Y)

-1.55*

-3.52

-1.55*

-3.52

0.215*

0.216(.10)

Ln(T)

-1.44*

-3.52

-1.65*

-3.52

0.14*

0.15

*with trend and Intercept

Table 2. Unit root test results on the log values of the variables at I(1)
ADF

Phillip-Perron

Variables

Test
statistic

Critical value at
5%

SIC lag Max


=9

Test
statistic

Critical value
at 5%

Bandwidth

Ln(F)

-6.30*

-1.95

-7.29*

-1.95

40

Ln(K)

-8.94***

-3.52

-5.45*

-1.95

Ln(Y)

-7.33***

-3.52

-9.30***

-3.52

Ln(T)

-5.71***

-3.52

-5.71***

-3.52

***with trend and Intercept and * without trend and Intercept

4.2 Bounds tests for cointegration


In order to empirically analyze the long-run relationships and short run dynamic interactions
among the variables of interest (trade, FDI, capital investment and economic growth), we apply
the autoregressive distributed lag (ARDL) cointegration technique as a general vector
autoregressive (VAR) model of order p in the vector of these variables = ( , , , ). The
ARDL / Bounds Testing methodology of Pesaran and Shin (1999) and Pesaran et al. (2001) has a

number of features that many researchers feel give it some advantages over conventional
cointegration testing. For instance: It can be used with a mixture of I(0) and I(1) data; It involves
just a single-equation set-up, making it simple to implement and interpret; Different variables
can be assigned different lag-lengths as they enter the model.
The ARDL models used in this study are expressed as follows:
ln

1
=1 2

D ln K t
q1
i=1 a 2i

ln

1
=1 2

D ln Ft

q1
i=1 a 2i

= 01 + 11 ln 1 + 21 ln 1 + 31 ln 1 + 51 ln 1 +

2
=1 3

3
=1 4

+ 1

D ln K ti

D ln Tti

q3
i=1 a 4i

D ln Fti

3
=1 4

+ 3

D ln K ti

D ln Tti

q3
i=1 a 4i

D ln Fti

p
i=1 a1i

D ln Yti

=1 1

p
i=1 a1i

D ln Yti

(3)

= a01 + b14 ln Yt1 + b24 ln K t1 + b34 ln Tt1 + b44 ln Ft1 +


q2
i=1 a 3i

+ 2t (2)

= 01 + 13 ln 1 + 23 ln 1 + 33 ln 1 + 43 ln 1 +
2
=1 3

(1)

= a01 + b12 ln Yt1 + b22 ln K t1 + b32 ln Tt1 + b42 ln Ft1 +


q2
i=1 a 3i

=1 1

+ 4t (4)

Where all variables are as previously defined, ln(.) is the logarithm operator, D is the first
difference, and are the error terms.
The bounds test is based on the joint F-statistic which its asymptotic distribution is non-standard
under the null hypothesis of no cointegration. The first step in the ARDL bounds approach is to
estimate the five equations (1, 2, 3 and 4 ) by ordinary least squares (OLS). The estimation of the
five equations tests for the existence of a long-run relationship among the variables by
conducting an F-test for the joint significance of the coefficients of the lagged levels of the
variables. Two sets of critical values for a given significance level can be determined (Pesaran et
al., 2001). The first level is calculated on the assumption that all variables included in the ARDL
model are integrated of order zero, while the second one is calculated on the assumption that the
variables are integrated of order one. The null hypothesis of no cointegration is rejected when the
value of the test statistic exceeds the upper critical bounds value, while it is accepted if the Fstatistic is lower than the lower bounds value. Other ways, the cointegration test is inconclusive.
The use of this approach is guided by the short data span. We choose a maximum lag order of 2
for the conditional ARDL vector error correction model by using the Akaike information criteria

(AIC). The calculated F-statistics are reported in Table 3 when each variable is considered as a
dependent variable (normalized) in the ARDL-OLS regressions.
Table 3: Results from bound tests
Dependent Variable

Independent Variables

F-Statistic

F
K, Y, T
2.894
K
F, Y, T
2.842
Y
F, K, T
7.084
T
F, K, Y
2.92
Lower-bound critical value for without intercept and trend at 1% = 3.42
Upper-bound critical value for without intercept and trend at 1% = 4.84

Result
No Cointegration
No Cointegration
Cointegration
No Cointegration

Lower and Upper-bound critical values are taken from Pesaran et al. (2001), Table CI(ii) Case I.

From these results, it is clear that there is a long run relationship amongst the variables when per
Capita GDP is the dependent variable because its F-statistic (7.084) is higher than the upperbound critical value (4.84) at the 1% level. This implies that the null hypothesis of no
cointegration among the variables in equation (1) is rejected. However, for the other equations
(2) - (4), the null hypothesis of no cointegration is accepted.

4.3 Granger short run and long run causality tests


Once cointegration is established, the conditional ARDL (, 1 , 2 , 3 ) long-run model for
ln
( ) can be estimated as:
ln = 0 +

=1 1

1
=0 2

2
=0 3

3
=0 4

+ (5)

The orders of the ARDL model (, 1 , 2 , 3 ) in the five variables are selected by using AIC.
Equation (5) is estimated using the following ARDL (1, 0, 0, 0) specification. The results
obtained by normalizing on FDI, in the long run are reported in Table 4.
Table 4. Estimated long run coefficients using the ARDL approach
Variable

Coefficient

t-Statistic

Probability

C
Ln(K)
Ln(F)
Ln(T)

-3.05
0.54
0.01
-0.03

-4.59
5.38
2.85
-1.01

0.00
0.00
0.007
0.3227

The estimated coefficients of the long-run relationship are significant for capital investment and
FDI but not significant for trade. Capital investment and FDI have a positive significant impact
on per Capita GDP. Trade variable is negatively signed but not significant at the 5% level.
Following the research papers of Narayan and Smyth (2008), we obtain the short-run dynamic
parameters by estimating an error correction model associated with the long-run estimates. The
long-run relationship between the variables indicates that there is Granger-causality in at least
one direction which is determined by the F-statistic and the lagged error-correction term. The
short-run causal effect and is represented by the F-statistic on the explanatory variables while the
t-statistic on the coefficient of the lagged error-correction term represents the long-run causal
relationship (Odhiambo 2009; Narayan and Smyth, 2006). The equation where the null
hypothesis of no cointegration is rejected is estimated with an error-correction term .
The vector error correction model is specified as follows:
ln

= 0 +

3
=0 4

ln

= 0 +

3
=0 4

ln

3
=0 4

ln

3
=0 4


= 0 +

= 0 +

=1 1

1
=0 2

2
=0 3

2
=0 3

2
=0 3

2
=0 3

+ 1 + 1 (6)

=1 1

1
=0 2

+ 1 + 1 (7)

=1 1

1
=0 2

+ 1 + 1 (8)

=1 1

1
=0 2

+ 1 + 1 (9)

Where a1i, a2i, a3i and a4i are the short-run dynamic coefficients of the models convergence to
equilibrium and is the speed of adjustment.
The equations (6) (9) are estimated by OLS regression separately. The results of the short-run
dynamic coefficients associated with the long-run relationships obtained from the equation (6)
are given in Table 5. Beginning with the results for the long-run, the coefficient on the lagged
error-correction term is significant at 1% level with the expected sign, which confirms the result
of the bounds test for cointegration. Its value is estimated to -0.46 which implies that the speed
of adjustment to equilibrium after a shock is high. Approximately 46% of disequilibria from the
previous years shock converge back to the long-run equilibrium in the current year. In the long
run FDI, capital and trade Granger cause GDP per capita. This result implies that causality runs
interactively through the error-correction term from FDI, capital and trade to real GDP per
capita. In the short run, capital investment, FDI is significant and has an important impact on per
capita GDP. Trade have a negative impact but not significant.

The regression for the underlying ARDL equation (7) fits very well and the model is globally
significant. It also passes all the diagnostic tests against serial correlation (Durbin Watson test
and Breusch-Godfrey test), heteroscedasticity (White Heteroskedasticity Test). The Ramsey
RESET test also suggests that the model is well specified. All the results of these tests are shown
in Table 6.
The stability of the long-run coefficient is tested by the short-run dynamics. Once the ECM
model given by equation (7) has been estimated, the cumulative sum of recursive residuals
(CUSUM) and the CUSUM of square (CUSUMSQ) tests are applied to assess the parameter
stability (Pesaran and Pesaran (1997)). Graphs 1 and 2 plot the results for CUSUM and
CUSUMSQ tests. The results indicate the absence of any instability of the coefficients because
the plot of the CUSUM and CUSUMSQ statistic fall inside the critical bands of the 5%
confidence interval of parameter stability.

Table 5. Results of equation (6), ARDL (1, 0, 0, 0) selected based on AIC


Variable

Coefficient

t-Statistic

Probability

C
D(ln(F))
D(ln(K))
D(ln(T))
ECM(-1)

-7.500352

-8.117119

0.00

0.01

2.37

0.02

0.23

4.49

0.00

-0.05

-0.90

0.38

-3.59

0.00

-0.46

R-squared

0.45

F-statistic
Durbin-Watson
stat

5.69

0.00

1.99

Table 6. Results of diagnostic tests


Test staistic
Ramsey RESET Test (log likelihood ratio)
White Heteroskedasticity test
Breusch-Godfrey Serial Correlation test

2.198332
1.043919
1.575165

Probability

0.1474
0.4622
0.2221

Graph 1. Plot of CUSUM Test for equation (6)


20
15
10
5
0
-5
-10
-15
-20
1980

1985

1990
CUSUM

1995

2000

2005

2010

5% Significance

Graph 2. Plot of CUSUMSQ Test for equation (6)


1.4
1.2
1.0
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0.0
-0.2
-0.4
1980

1985

1990

1995

CUSUM of Squares

2000

2005

2010

5% Significance

Results of short run Granger causality tests are shown in Table 8. In the short-run, the F-statistics
on the explanatory variables suggest that at the 10% level or better there is bi-directional Granger

causality between FDI and trade, unidirectional Granger causality running from FDI to economic
growth and from economic growth to capital investment. There is no Granger causality from
economic growth to FDI and capital investment to per capita GDP. The Granger causality test results
for the relationship between FDI and capital investment are interesting. These results indicate that
there is no significant Granger causality from FDI to capital investment or from capital investment
to FDI. Turning to the Granger causality test results for trade openness and capital investment,
there is also no significant Granger causality from trade to capital investment or from capital
investment to trade. The results support the idea that FDI will only be growth enhancing.
We can conclude that FDI which promotes trade and economic growth in the short-run for India.
FDI is the main catalyser of economic growth in India.
Table 8. Results of short run Granger causality

Variables
D(ln(Y))
D(ln(F))
D(ln(K))
D(ln(T))

D(ln(Y))
-

F-statistic
D(ln(F))
D(ln(K))

D(ln(T))

4.12*

0.17

2.27

0.47

0.69

5.93*

5.63*

0.73

0.07

0.80

3.65**

2.66

Direction of causality
F -> Y
T -> F
Y -> K
F -> T

(*) and (**) denote statistical significance at the 5% and 10% levels respectively.

5. Conclusion
The paper examines the dynamic causal relationship among the series of economic growth,
foreign direct investment, trade and capital investment for India for the period of 1970-2012. It
implements ARDL model to cointegration to investigate the existence of a long run relation
among the above noted series; and the Granger causality within VECM to test the direction of
causality between the variables. The topic merits special importance due to the possible
interrelations among the series with implications for economic growth. The results show that
there is cointegration among the variables specified in the model when per capita GDP is the
dependent variable. Capital investment and FDI promote economic growth in India in the long
run. These results indicate that there is no significant Granger causality from FDI to capital
investment or from capital investment to FDI. Turning to the Granger causality test results for
trade openness and capital investment, there is also no significant Granger causality from trade to
capital investment or from capital investment to trade.
Foreign direct investment is the catalyser of economic growth in India. This finding generates
important implications and recommendations for policy makers in India. The results suggest that
for FDI to bring in the anticipated positive impacts on trade, Indian government will undertake
serious reforms with clear objectives and strong commitments.

6. References
Carkovic, Maria and Levine, Ross. Does Foreign Direct Investment Accelerate Economic
Growth? in Theodore H. Moran, Edward D. Graham, and Magnus Blomstrm, eds., Does
Foreign Direct Investment Promote Development? Washington, DC: Institute for International
Economics, 2005, pp. 195-220
D. Kwiatkowski, P. C. B. Phillips, P. Schmidt, and Y. Shin (1992): Testing the Null Hypothesis
of Stationarity against the Alternative of a Unit Root. Journal of Econometrics 54, 159178.
Findlay, Ronald, 1978. "Some Aspects of Technology Transfer and Direct Foreign Investment,"
American Economic Review, American Economic Association, vol. 68(2), pages 275-79, May.
Francisco Rodriguez & Dani Rodrik, 2001. "Trade Policy and Economic Growth: A Skeptic's
Guide to the Cross-National Evidence," NBER Chapters, in: NBER Macroeconomics Annual
2000, Volume 15, pages 261-338 National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
Frankel, J.A. and D. Romer, 1999. Does trade cause growth? American Economic Review, 89:
379-99.
Frimpong, Joseph Magnus & Oteng-Abayie, Eric Fosu, 2006. "Bounds testing approach: an
examination of foreign direct investment, trade, and growth relationships," MPRA Paper 352,
University Library of Munich, Germany, revised 09 Oct 2006.
Grossman, Gene M., and Elhanan Helpman. 1991a. Quality Ladders in the Theory of Growth.
Review of Economic Studies, 58(1): 43-61.
Grossman, Gene M., and Elhanan Helpman. 1991b. Endogenous Product Cycles. Economic
Journal, 101(408): 1229-1241.
Grossman, Gene M. & Helpman, Elhanan, 1991. "Trade, knowledge spillovers, and growth,"
European Economic Review, Elsevier, vol. 35(2-3), pages 517-526, April.
Helpman, Elhanan, 1984. "A Simple Theory of International Trade with Multinational
Corporations," Journal of Political Economy, University of Chicago Press, vol. 92(3), pages 45171, June.
Kwan, Andy C C & Wu, Yangru & Zhang, Junxi, 1999. " Fixed Investment and Economic
Growth in China," Economic Change and Restructuring, Springer, vol. 32(1), pages 67-79.
Lucas, Robert E. 1988. On the Mechanics of Economic Development. Journal of Monetary
Economics, 22(1): 3-42.

Makki, S.S and Somwaru, A., 2004. Impact of foreign direct investment and trade on economic
growth: Evidence from developing countries American Journal of Agriculture Economics,
86(3)(August 2004):795-801.
Paul R. Krugman, 1985. "Increasing Returns and the Theory of International Trade," NBER
Working Papers 1752, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
Pesaran, M. and Shin, Y. (1999), An Autoregressive Distributed Lag Modeling Approach to
cointegration Analysis in S. Strom, (ed) Econometrics and Economic Theory in the 20th
Century: The Ragnar Frisch centennial Symposium, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
Pesaran, M.H., Shin, Y. and Smith, R.J. 2001. Bounds testing approaches to the analysis of
level relationship. Journal of Applied Economics 16: 289-326.
Phillips, P.C.B and P. Perron (1988), "Testing for a Unit Root in Time Series Regression",
Biometrika, 75, 335346
Rivera-Batiz, Luis A., and Paul M. Romer. 1991b. International Trade with Endogenous
Technological Change. European Economic Review, 35(4): 971-1004.
Rodrik, Dani, 1995. "Trade Strategy, Investment and Exports: Another Look at East Asia,"
CEPR Discussion Papers 1305, C.E.P.R. Discussion Papers.
Romer, P., 1990. Endogenous technological change. Journal of Political Economy 98, 71102.
Wei, Y. and Liu, X. (2001) Foreign Direct Investment in China: Determinants and Impact,
Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd. (IBNS 1 84064 494X)
Young, Alwyn. 1991. Learning by Doing and the Dynamics Effects of International Trade.
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106(2): 369-405.

You might also like