Carte CDM and Law PDF
Carte CDM and Law PDF
Carte CDM and Law PDF
Amicus Books
An Introduction
Amicus Books is the initiative of the Icfai University Press to publish a
series of books in various segments of law with a special focus on emerging
issues. These books seek to provide, at one place, a retrospective as well
as prospective view of the contemporary developments in the legal
environment, with emphasis on general and specialized branches of knowledge
and applications.
The books in this series are based on relevant, authoritative and thoughtprovoking articles written by experts and published in leading professional
magazines and research journals. The articles are organized in a sequential
and logical way that makes reading continuous and helps the reader acquire
a holistic view of the subject. This helps in strengthening the understanding
of the subject better and also enables the readers stretch their thoughts
beyond the content of the book. The series is designed to meet the
requirements of executives, research scholars, academicians and students
of professional programs. The Icfai University Press has published over 900
books in this series. For full details, readers are invited to visit our website:
www.amicus.iupindia.org
Clean Development
Mechanism and Law
Edited by
L Lakshmi
Amicus Books
Contents
Overview
29
49
J. de Spibus
85
David M. Driesen
105
126
168
198
List of Cases
210
Index
211
Overview
Due to massive industrialization the planet Earth had been witnessing a
tremendous development in all spheres of human activities. In consequence,
there is increase in huge quantities of atmospheric concentrations of carbon
dioxide, methane, and nitrous oxide in the atmosphere. This in turn has
been found to be escalating the temperature of Earth resulting in global
warming and climate change. The concern for the health of the individuals
made the States realize the likely adverse effects of global climate change on
human health that led them to propose for mitigating the GHGs by
entering the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change
(UNFCCC). The efforts further led to Kyoto Protocol in 1997, which
advocated for framing and implementation of flexible mechanisms enabling
the industrialized countries to pursue their goals of GHG reduction by
purchasing GHG emissions.
The Kyoto Protocol provided for three mechanisms that enabled developed
countries to acquire greenhouse gas reduction credits. These mechanisms
II
III
methodologies approved by the CDM Executive Board (EB), the applicant the industrialised country must establish a baseline estimating the future
emissions. Then it is validated by a third party agency, called a Designated
Operational Entity (DOE), to ensure the project results in real, measurable,
and long-term emission reductions. The EB then decides whether or not to
register the project. If a project is registered and implemented, the EB issues
credits, called Certified Emission Reductions (CERs), known as carbon
credits, where each unit is equivalent to the reduction of one metric tonne
of carbon dioxide. Any proposed CDM project has to use an approved
baseline and monitoring methodology to be validated, approved and
registered. Baseline Methodology will set steps to determine the baseline
within certain applicability conditions whilst monitoring methodology will
set specific steps to determine monitoring parameters, quality assurance, and
equipment to be used, in order to obtain datas to calculate the emission
reductions. With costs of emission reduction typically much lower in
developing countries than in industrialised countries, industrialised
countries can comply with their emission reduction targets at much lower
cost by receiving credits for emissions reduced in developing countries as
long as administration costs are low.
However, the concern is with regards to inclusion of forests in CDM
schemes as they have been excluded from CDM. There is so far no
international agreement about whether projects avoiding deforestation or
conserving forests should be initiated through separate policies and measures
or stimulated through the carbon market. One major concern is the
enormous monitoring effort needed in order to make sure projects are
indeed leading to increased carbon storage. In response to concerns of
unsustainable projects or spurious credits, the World Wide Fund for Nature
and other NGOs devised a Gold Standard methodology to certify projects
that use much stricter criteria than required, such as allowing only
renewable energy projects.
IV
VI
this EU ETS decided to impose strict limits on the use of JI/CDM credits
during the second trading period beginning from 2006. The author intends
to examine the International and European legal framework to find a better
utilization of JI/CDM credits in post-2012 international offsets. Based on
his examination of commissions proposal on the third trading period of the
EU ETS and the related reports the author suggests for introduction of
quantitative and qualitative restrictions for the use of international offsets
within the EU ETS. The author finds that the European view on the
appropriateness of linking the EU ETS with the international project
mechanisms has changed over the years. The efforts of EU ETS were timely
supported by the proposals made by the Environmental Committee of the
European Parliament on the ETS in the Council.
In Links between European Emissions Trading and CDM Credits for
Renewable Energy and Energy Efficiency Projects the author David M.
Driesen critically examines the relationship between the Kyoto mechanisms
and sustainable development. He finds that the short term cost effectiveness
that emission trading fosters does not correspond with the long-term goals
set by the climate change treaty and the principles of sustainable
development. He suggests that European Union can increase demand for
CDM credits by adopting stringent regulations in the trading sector.
However such approach may create pressure to expand the use of cheap
CDM credits. In order to achieve sustainable development the author
suggests the European Union and other nations currently in compliance
with Kyoto targets must take meaningful steps toward sustainable
development, to acquire increased credibility. The developing countries in
turn would recognize the stand of the developed nations and come forward
and express their willingness to make commitments.
Linking Community Forestry Projects in India with International
Carbon Markets: Opportunities and Constraints the authors Rohit
Jindal and Shailesh Nagar identify that prior to Kyoto; community forestry
VII
VIII
energy imported into their regions. Yet such limitations are found to be
effecting the interstate imports under the Interstate Commerce Clause of
the US Constitution. The author therefore intends to explore the possibility
of applying the principles of compensatory tax doctrine to prevent leakage.
The doctrine states that even if a state regulation imposes a burden on
interstate commerce, it may survive constitutional scrutiny if it is designed
to make interstate commerce bear the burden.
In Balancing Cost and Emissions Certainty: An Allowance Reserve for
Cap-and-Trade the authors Brian C. Murray, Richard G. Newell and
William A. Pizer present the scope, advantages, limitations and the legal
regimes for using carbon tax, cap-and-trade systems to control emissions.
They find cap-and-trade system as a system that fixes the quantity of
emissions allowed, but its market price remains uncertain. Whereas, in a
carbon tax the price of emissions is fixed and the quantity of emissions
remains uncertain. Therefore, an alternative system is suggested by the
authors that is fixing a safety valve. The new system would take up a capand-trade system along with a price ceiling at which additional allowances
can be purchased. Till the allowance price remains below the safety-valve
price, this system acts like cap-and-trade. Whereas, once the safety-valve
price is reached, this system behaves like a tax. Thus the safety valve
represents a mechanism that falls between price or quantity of instrument.
The authors therefore advocate for allowance reserve which stipulates both a
ceiling price at which cost relief is provided and a maximum number of
allowances to be issued in exercising that relief. They finally suggest that an
allowance reserve and suggest for tightening the future cap, by placing an
upper limit on the available number of extra allowances.
Joanna Hendy, Suzi Kerr and Troy Baisden in their article Greenhouse
Gas Emissions Charges and Credits on Agricultural Land: What can a
Model Tell Us? examine the impact of emissions from agriculture sector.
IX
In this regard the authors make a study of the land use and emissions
implications of climate policies that provide landowners credits for
regenerating indigenous forest and scrub. The authors, team of economists
from Motu Economic and Public Policy Research, and scientists from
Landcare Research, Agresearch, Scion/Ensis, and NIWA develop LURNZclimate. LURNZ-climate is a computer model that simulates the effect of
climate change policies on rural land use in New Zealand. The study
intended to predict the land-use change across the whole country and
thereby calculate the greenhouse gas implications of land-use change.
Subsequent to this simulation study, New Zealand has been recognized to
have developed the capacity to empirically investigate the potential impacts
of policies designed to charge farmers in proportion to the amount of
methane and nitrous oxide that which is emitted by their livestock and
reward them for regenerating indigenous forest. The first simulation study
finds that agricultural emissions charge based on land use are not so effective
in reducing emissions. The second simulation showed that the inclusion of a
reward for regenerating forest and scrub without a similar reward for
plantation forestry had a negative impact and increased emissions growth.
The authors conclude by stating that a further careful empirical analysis of
potential policies has to be made by devising more tools in second phase of
LURNZ study.
1
Enlisting Carbondioxide Capture
and Storage as a Clean
Development Mechanism Project:
Legal and Regulatory Issues
Considered
Olawuyi Damilola Sunday*
The Clean Development Mechanism of the Kyoto Protocol
provides an incentive for governments and companies in
industrialized countries to invest in Green House Gases (GHG)
reductions projects in developing countries and be credited for
GHG reduction achieved through these projects, through the
issuance of Certified Emission Reductions (CERs). Carbon
dioxide Capture and Storage technology has been identified as
one of such viable projects that can be carried out by
industrialized nations for CERs as it offers high GHG mitigation
potential. Of concern, however, is the lack of a clear, defined
legal and regulatory framework which addresses some of the
technical concerns associated with the CCS technology like
leakage, permanence, boundary issues, and allocation of
*
Faculty of Law, Murray Faser Hall University of Calgary, Alberta, Canada. E-mail: dsolawuy@ucalgary.ca
Introduction
Realizing the likely adverse effects global climate change may impose on human
health, the world community came together under the United Nations
Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC) to jumpstart efforts,
aimed at addressing these concerns. These efforts led to the Kyoto Protocol of
1997 which advocates taking concrete steps and binding commitments to reduce
greenhouse gasses that contribute to global warming. At the heart of The Kyoto
Protocol lie its flexible Mechanisms which allow industrialized countries to pursue
their goals of GHG reduction by purchasing GHG emission reductions from
elsewhere, mostly from non annex I and II countries. 1 One of such mechanisms
is the Clean Development Mechanism (CDM). 2 The CDM provides an incentive
for government and companies in industrialized countries to invest in GHG
reduction projects in developing countries. The CDM also aims to promote
sustainable development in the countries hosting the projects. 3
However, the CDM rules as elaborated by The Marrakech Accords 4 do not
define in clear terms, whether the Carbon dioxide Capture and Storage (CCS)
technology will qualify as a CDM project. Though CCS is not one of the project
types originally included when the CDM was first established, previous studies
show that CCS is a promising emission reduction option with potentially
important environmental, economic and energy supply security benefit. 5 CCS is a
process consisting of the separation of carbon dioxide (CO2) from industrial and
energy related sources, transportation to a storage location and long term
isolation from the atmosphere through storage in geological formations. This
technology has the potential of reducing overall mitigation costs and increasing
flexibility in achieving greenhouse gas emission reductions worldwide. 6 CCS
could in fact yield 15% to 55% of the cumulative mitigation efforts required
worldwide up to the year 2100 (roughly 220 to 2200 GtCO2). 7 It will also be an
important element in furthering the transfer of CCS technology and expertise to
developing countries. 8
The CDM evolved from the Brazilian proposal for a Clean Development
Fund (CDF) in a meeting of the ad hoc group on the Berlin mandate in 1997 just
prior to COP-3. 14 The CDF idea was to finance adaptation measures through
penalties levied on industrialized countries not reaching their targets; to ensure
much more flexibility in achieving emission reductions and for the possibility of
international emissions trading to achieve the emission reductions where it could
be done at the least cost. At the COP-3 in Kyoto, the idea became a subject of so
much disagreements and skepticism. An apparent contradiction emerged
between the goals of emission reduction in the North and sustainable
development in the South due to the differing priorities of different countries and
regions of the world. The differing sets of priorities between developed countries
and the developing countries as they arose at Kyoto, has been roughly tabulated
as follows: 15
Industrialized Countries
Developing Countries
Emissions reduction
Sustainable development
Equity
DC participation
Joint Implementation
Technology Transfer
Sinks
Financial Assistance
Special Circumstances
Clean Environment
Poverty Reduction
The core of the CDM is to transfer and acquire emission reductions between
developing countries and developed countries on a project basis. Developed
countries can get Certified Emission Reductions (CERs) through CDM projects
during this period. Typically, a project proponent will identify an investment that
would lead to reduced greenhouse gases in a developing country and approach
the government of the country where the investment is located in for approval. 18
The government will then decide whether the project meets its sustainable
development needs and approve it as a CDM project.
The Fourth Conference of the Parties (COP-4) to the UNFCCC held in
November 1998 passed the Buenos Aires Plan of Action (BAPA). This plan
requests the COP to set up detailed structures, rules, guidelines, operation
procedure and methodology for CDM, so that CDM can be fully applicable by
2000. After a few years of tough negotiation,. Bonn Agreement. was adopted by
the COP-6 in July 2001, which set a political basis for the future implementation
of CDM. In November 2001, the COP-7 was held in Marrakech where the
negotiation for CDM had a new improvement. Several agreements were made to
specify some important CDM issues, such as its operation pattern, rules, and
procedures. 19 An Executive Board (EB) of CDM was also formed to take
responsibility for making series of decisions on many detailed technical issues for
the implementation of CDM.
It is however surprising to note that the CDM rules do not define what a
CDM project is, it only states the eligibility requirements and the project
requirements. This has created uncertainties as to whether CCS projects qualify
as CDM projects. The only explicit reference made to CCS in the Kyoto Protocol
is that Annex-I countries need to research, promote, develop and increasingly
use CO2 sequestration technologies. 20 The Marrakech Accords also was only able
Funding for CDM projects must not divert funding from existing official
development assistance. 25
The requirements also include that the project has to generate CERs
compared to the baseline emission, the methodology applied by the project has
to be approved and if the project has a great environmental impact, a solution
has to be made to minimize that impact. The project baseline should also be
gases. 31 CCS involves the use of technology, first to collect and concentrate the
CO2 produced in industrial and energy related sources, transporting it to a
suitable storage location, and then storing it away from the atmosphere for a
long period of time. 32 Application of CCS to biomass energy sources could result
in the net removal of CO2 from the atmosphere by capturing and storing the
atmospheric CO2 taken up by the biomass. 33 CCS also has the potential to
reduce overall mitigation costs and increase flexibility in achieving greenhouse
gas emission reductions.
The Carbon dioxide Capture and Storage process can be split into four
separate stages:
i.
ii.
10
iii.
12
development and its deployment as a CDM project. Most of these relate to the
injection and storage of CO2 and the long-term stewardship of the storage site.
These concerns will now be discussed under three heads:
a.
b.
c.
14
3.2.1 Monitoring
The modalities and procedures for the CDM requires that the monitoring plan for
a CDM project activity provides for the collection and archiving of all relevant
data necessary for estimating greenhouse gas emissions and determination of
baselines. 62 Monitoring is a basic requirement for CCS project and as an
important part of the whole risk management strategy. A framework to ensure
appropriate monitoring is thus necessary, this framework should include
monitoring of the amount of CO2 injected to the reservoir and the relevant data
from the injection project, and identification of all potential sources of increased
emissions outside the project boundary that are significant and attributable to the
project activity during the crediting period.
In my view, proper and long-term monitoring of the reservoir is required, so
that leakage from the site will be detected and appropriately accounted for. It is
important that the monitoring program covers the CO2 storage and addresses
possible leakage pathways in an appropriate way. These leakage pathways
would have been identified during the analysis of the storage site. It should be
decided who is responsible for the monitoring after the crediting period, the
project participants or the host country, and the length of this period. The
monitoring system must be technically feasible, able to detect physical leakage
(during project operation & long-term leakage) including fugitive emissions
above a certain level (i.e. above the threshold, assuming that a threshold is
introduced and accepted), and should not be prohibitively costly.
A legal framework is necessary to provide for and enforce standard
procedures / best practice, and monitoring guidelines for various types of
formations, including operational rules such as: well injection pressure, injection
rate, temperature, etc.
16
18
There are few established guidelines for the specific kinds of monitoring that
should be done for CCS in the short- and long-term, including who should be
doing the monitoring, for how long a site should be monitored, and how to
determine long-term MMV responsibilities in case of existing CO2 compliance
systems, such as the EU Emissions Trading Scheme (EU ETS), 67 trans-border
projects, or projects in international waters. The Australian government recently
developed principles for regulating CCS projects that also include general
guidelines for when in the CCS process the MMV step should take place, and
how it should be done. 68 There is however a need for a standard regulatory
framework which will regulate MMV in all jurisdictions covered by the Kyoto Protocol.
ii.
Long-term Liability: There are three types of liability issues that are
relevant for longterm CCS projects: environmental, in situ, and
trans-national liability. 72 Environmental liability is associated with any CO2
leakage from the storage sites that may affect the global climate by
contributing to CO2 concentrations in the atmosphere. In the event of any
CO2 leakage or migration to the atmosphere, responsibility must be
assigned to address any harm caused to the global climate. In situ liability is
20
ii.
b.
c.
d.
22
e.
f.
g.
h.
i.
j.
k.
l.
Conclusion
CCS technology has the potential of reducing overall mitigation costs, increasing
flexibility in achieving greenhouse gas emission reductions and in contributing
positively to the attainment of the overall CDM objectives. Its viability and global
acceptability as a CDM Project will however depend on how soon the COP/MOP
to the Kyoto Protocol can provide a legal/ regulatory framework which will
address the concerns of permanence, leakage, project boundary, liability
amongst others which have consistently been identified as the ills of his viable
technology. This is a task which must be accomplished without further delay. This
work will be a useful guide to the COP/MOP in achieving this necessary task.
Endnotes
1
Non Annex I and II countries under UNFCCC include developing countries like
China, India and Nigeria amongst others.
The other flexible mechanisms are emissions trading and Joint Implementation
(JI).see online: See Online: United Nations Framework Convention on Climate
Change, http://unfccc.int/resource/docs/convkp/kpeng.html
Decision 17/CP.7 of the Seventh session of The Conference of Parties to the UNFCC
(COP-7) in Marrakech.
McKee, B, Solutions for the 21st Century, Zero Emissions Technologies for Fossil
Fuel (2002) OECD/IEA, at 2-4.
24
Ibid.
See for e.g., International Energy Agency,. Legal Aspect of Storing CO2. (2005)
International Energy Agency at 3.
10
See for e.g., Anderson, S & R, Prospects for Carbon Capture and Storage Technologies
(2003)2 ENDA, see also Bachu, S. and Celia, M., Geological Sequestration of CO2: Is
Leakage unavoidable and acceptable?, (2002,Sixth International Conference on
Greenhouse Gas Control Technologies, Kyoto, Japan, October).
11
12
Ibid at 689-690.
13
14
15
Youba Sokona, The Clean Development Mechanism: What Prospects for Africa?
(2005) ENDA at 1.
16
It has thus been variously described as the Kyoto surprise, The Kyoto baby, the
win-win mechanism and as having the handwriting of both the South and the
North. see Aslam, M.A.,. The Clean Development Mechanism: unraveling the.
Mystery, (1998)Islamabad 2 at 21, see also Karen Holm Olsen, Supra note 14 at 2.
17
See also Unep Ris Centre, Clean Development Mechanism Legal Issues Guidebook
to the Clean Development Mechanism, online: Unep Ris Centre www.uneptie.org/
energy/publications/files/cdm_LEGAL_issues.htm - 10k -
18
See Foundation for International Environmental Law and Development, note 2 above.
19
The basic rules for CDM can be found in Decision 15, Decision 17 and the
attachments of COP-7. Supra note 2.
20
21
22
See paragraphs 28 -30 of the annex of Decision of the COP-7 (Clean Development
Mechanism Modalities and Procedures). Supra note 2.
23
24
25
26
Ibid.
27
28
CO2 emissions also result from some industrial and resource extraction processes,
as well as from the burning of forests during land clearance.
29
For example, flue gas from a coal-fired power plant typically contains about 14%
CO2, 5% O2, and 81% N2. online: IPCC, http://www.ipcc.ch
30
Under IPCC scenario B1 in its Climate Change 2001 report, emissions of CO2 will
have to be reduced by approximately 40% by 2100 in order to stabilize the
atmospheric concentration of CO2 at no more than 50% above its current level
online: IPCC, http://www.ipcc.ch.
31
Other mitigation options include energy efficiency improvements, the switch to less
carbon-intensive fuels, nuclear power, renewable energy sources, enhancement of
biological sinks, and reduction of non- CO2 greenhouse gas emissions. See
generally Susanne Haefeli,. CCS issues. Accounting and Baselines under the
UNFCC. (2004) OECD/IEA at 8.
32
IPCC,. Special Report on Carbon Dioxide Capture and Storage,. September 2005,
Chapter 5, online: IPCC, http://www.ipcc.ch/activity/srccs/index.htm
33
34
35
In which the CO2 is scrubbed from the gas exiting the combustion or production
process. These are the most commonly used technologies today and, for example,
they can capture up to 99 per cent of the processed/flue gas exiting a boiler or a
gas sweetening unit.
36
In which a synthetic hydrogen and CO2 rich gas is produced from the fuel. This
approach is used in Integrated Gasification Combined Cycle plants (IGCC). It is a
clean coal technology under development with few already existing plants in Europe
and the US, but with promising prospects as a large-scale technology.
37
In which the combustion process is fired with oxygen rather than air to create a flue
gas primarily comprising CO2. This approach is still in a R&D phase. All three
processes consume a significant amount of energy, and thus entail costs. This is
referred to as the. energy penalty. of the capture process. The energy penalty
typically ranges between 15 to 40 per cent of the energy output in the case of CO2
capture at a coal-fired power plant. See generally Thambimuthu, K.,. Zeroing
emissions with CO2 Capture and Storage, Presentation at COP8, online: IEA,
http://www.iea.org/envissu/cop8/ieaside/kelly.pdf.
26
38
CO2 transmission pipelines already exist in countries like the USA. see online: US
Department of Energy, Capture Sequestration R&D Projects Database, http://www.
fossil.energy.gov/fred/feprograms.jsp?prog=Carbon+Sequestration
39
The transportation chosen will very much depend on the storage site, because the
farther this is from land the more expensive it will be to carry the CO2.
40
The Norwegian State oil company has been injecting around a million tones of CO2
a year since 1996. a by-product of the gas they produce from the North Sea
Sleipner west gas field, directly into sub-seabed formations.
41
This stores CO2 captured in the United States. see note 38 above.
42
43
44
Ibid at 8-10.
45
Ibid.
46
47
48
49
50
NM_0167 White Tiger Oil Field CCS project in Vietnam; NM_0168 capture of CO2
from LNG complex and its storage in an aquifer in Malaysia; and SSC_038
Anthropogenic Ocean Sequestration by Changing the Alkalinity of Ocean Surface
Water, Online: UNFCC, http://cdm.unfccc.int/methodologies
51
52
53
54
55
56
57
58
59
Global risks involve the release of CO2 that may contribute significantly to climate
change if some fraction leaks from the storage formation to the atmosphere.
60
Local risks refer to local hazards that may exist for humans, ecosystems and
groundwater if CO2 leaks out of a storage formation.
61
62
63
64
65
66
The most often used techniques are time-lapse 3D seismic imaging (also called 4D
seismic) and vertical seismic profiling (VSP) in wells, along with injection well
pressure and rate monitoring, but a consensus of the most appropriate techniques to
use has not been reached. Ibid at 8-10.
67
Ibid.
68
69
Generally considered to cover the timeframe of the project and any contractual time
period covering post-injection.
70
71
72
TNO, Environmental Challenges of the E&P Industry: Dealing with CO2 online:
TNO, http://gcceuconference. epu.ntua.gr/Portals/1/documents/02.Elewaut.pdf
73
So much work is currently been done in this regard to effect changes into
International treaties like the London Convention /London Protocol, Convention for
the Protection of the Marine Environment of the North-East Atlantic (OSPAR), to
address these Trans boundary liability issues. See International Energy Agency,.
Legal Aspects of Storing CO2, (2005) OECD/IEA, at 12-18.
28
74
CSLF, Considerations on Legal Issues for Carbon Dioxide Capture and Storage
Projects, Report from the Legal, Regulatory and Financial Issues Task Force, 13
August 2004. http://www.cslforum.org/documents/Legal_Issues_Report_P14C.pdf
75
M.A. de Figueiredo, D.M. Reiner, and H.J. Herzog, Framing the Long-Term In Situ
Liability Issues for Geologic Carbon Storage in the United States, Mitigation and
Adaptation Strategies for Global Change, 10: 647-657, October 2005,
http://sequestration.mit.edu/pdf/Framing_the_Long-Term_Liability_Issue.pdf
76
77
78
The Conference was attended by six thousand participants from one hundred eighty
countries. online: UNFCCC, http://unfccc.int/2860.php
79
80
Ibid.
2
Flexible Mechanisms for Climate
Change Compliance: Emission
Offset Purchases under the Clean
Development Mechanism
Christopher Carr* and Flavia Rosembuj**
The authors provide an overview of recent developments on clean
development mechanism a specific type of offset program for
climate change compliance. Their article gives a background on
how CDM of the Kyoto Protocol works and investigates aspects
of CDM purchase agreements from a legal perspective. They
found out that "the international carbon market has shown how
market-based mechanisms can muster capital to address global
climate change and transfer climate-friendly technology to the
developing world.
*
**
Counsel Vinson & Elking LLP, 1455, Pennsylvania Avenue, NW, Washington, D. C., 2004.
E-mail: Ccarr@velaw.com
Senior Legal Counsel, Co-financing and project finance, legal department, World Bank. 1818 H street
NW, MC 6-401 Washington D.C. 20433. E-mail: frosembuj@worldbank.org
2008 N.Y.U. Environmental Law Journal. This article was originally published in the NYU Environmental
Law Journal, Vol. 16. Reprinted with permission.
Source: wbcarbanfinance.org
30
Introduction
From 2005 through 2006, the international market for carbon credits
experienced tremendous growth and reached an annual market value of over
US $30 billion. 1 As part of this growth, new tools, skills, and capital have been
introduced into the international carbon market to address the global problem of
climate change.
Broadly speaking, the international carbon market has involved two types of
market-based tools to reduce greenhouse gas emissions. The first tool is a cap
and trade program. Under such a program, emissions are capped at a certain
level by regulatory fiat, regulated entities are allocated allowances to emit a
certain amount of Greenhouse Gases (GHGs), and these entities can then trade
allowances to meet their compliance obligations. An entity whose emissions fall
below its allocated amount can sell unneeded allowances for compliance
purposes. An entity whose emissions are higher than its allocated amount can
purchase allowances from others who are willing to sell them.
The second type of program is an emission offset, or project based
program. As opposed to a cap and trade regime, offsets involve a baseline and
trade regime. These offset credits are generated from projects that reduce GHG
emissions below a certain baseline outside of a regulated cap. These credits can
then be sold to entities that can use them to meet regulatory compliance
obligations inside a cap.
This article focuses on a specific type of offset program the Clean
Development Mechanism of the Kyoto Protocol (CDM). 2 This article (i) begins
with an overview of the Kyoto flexible mechanisms (including the CDM), (ii)
explains how CDM offset credits are generated, (iii) examines the growth of the
international carbon market, (iv) explores aspects of CDM offset purchase
agreements, and (v) summarizes several lessons learned. In sum, the
international carbon market has shown how market-based mechanisms can
muster capital to address global climate change and transfer climate-friendly
technology to the developing world. This article provides an overview of recent
developments in the CDM and an understanding of how market based
mechanisms may address global climate change. This is, however, only an
overview, and other sources delve into these topics in greater detail.
31
32
ii.
iii.
Each one of the above mentioned assets (ERUs, CERs and AAUs) represents
one metric ton of CO2 equivalent. 18 One ton of a GHG reduction from a CDM
or JI project anywhere in the world can be converted into a ton of carbon dioxide
equivalent by multiplying it by a pre-determined global warming potential. 19 This
conversion allows for a common currency whereby ERUs, CERs, and AAUs can
be freely exchanged for compliance purposes, as each represents a ton of
carbon dioxide equivalent. A party to the Kyoto Protocol can also authorize a
private entity to participate in these flexible mechanisms. 20 In this way,
companies and other non-sovereigns can undertake climatefriendly projects and
generate emission reduction credits. These credits can then be used for
compliance purposes, or sold or traded in emissions markets to others who may
need the emission credits for compliance purposes.
33
The CDM, on which this article focuses, began operation shortly after the
adoption of the Marrakech Accords. The Marrakech Accords resulted from
the 2001 meeting of all of the parties that are signatories to the UNFCCC
(Conference of the Parties or COP). The Marrakech Accords supplemented the
Kyoto Protocol by identifying in detail the modalities and procedures by which the
flexible mechanisms would operate. 21
The CDM directs the design and development of emission reduction offset
projects located in the developing world under the Kyoto Protocol. For instance,
the CDM provides the framework for the development of baselines and
monitoring methodologies for measuring emission reductions from projects. It
also develops procedures by which emission reductions could be verified by
independent third parties. 22
Although the Kyoto Protocol was negotiated in 1997, it did not enter into
force until February 16, 2005, when the required number of countries finally
ratified it. 23 When Kyoto became effective, the CDM was ready for a period of
significant growth in the volume of GHG emission reductions that could be
generated by environmentally-friendly projects.
34
to generate CERs, the project proponents must present a counterfactual, that is,
a description of the reductions that would have occurred in the absence of the
investment. 30 Each PDD must describe the baseline scenario 31 from which this
additionality is measured and must include a detailed monitoring plan. 32
A written Letter of Approval (LOA) from the host developing country must
also be obtained for the project. 33 The Kyoto Protocol is an international
agreement between sovereign parties, but through this letter of approval a
sovereign can devolve rights and obligations to private entities, allowing them to
take advantage of the flexible mechanisms.
The PDD, together with the LOA, is submitted by the project sponsor to an
independent entity for validation. 34 This entity is known as the Designated
Operation Entity (DOE). 35 The DOE reviews the PDD and submits it together with
the LOA to the EB. The formal acceptance by the EB of the validated project as a
CDM project activity is known as registration. A request for registration is
considered granted and the registration final within eight weeks of the EBs
receipt of the request, unless prior to the expiry of that period three or more
members of the EB (or a party involved in the CDM project itself) request review
of the proposed CDM activity. 36
In the implementation phase, the project is carried out and the monitoring
plan submitted in the PDD takes effect. Based on the monitoring plan in the PDD,
GHG reductions are calculated and submitted for verification as CERs. 37 A
different DOE needs to be hired by the project sponsors (unless the project is
small scale) to verify the GHG reductions and to generate a verification report
that certifies in writing the amount of additional emission reductions attributable
to the project. 38
If everything goes as planned, the EB ultimately issues the CERs in the
amount of one CER for each ton of carbon dioxide equivalent of emissions
reduced. 39 A percentage of the CERs issued is transferred to a special account
used to finance projects that help developing countries adapt to the adverse
impacts of climate change. The remaining CERs are forwarded to the accounts of
the participants in the CDM project.
35
36
Other regulatory regimes, including those in the United States, could also
link to either the CDM, the EU ETS, or other regulatory regimes, depending on
the specific provisions in each system and applicable law. 49 Through this linking,
it could be possible for credits to be traded between the regulatory regimes of
different countries.
A wide variety of projects have been launched under the CDM, including
renewable energy projects such as wind and hydroelectric; energy efficiency
projects; fuel switching; capping landfill gases; better management of methane
from animal waste; the control of coal mine methane; and controlling emissions
of certain industrial gases including HFCs and N2O. 50 CDM projects have taken
place throughout the developing world, including in Asia, Africa, and Central
and South America. 51
However, certain countries have dominated the market. The World Bank
estimates that from 2002 through 2006, China represented 60% of the
cumulative CDM market in terms of credit volume. 52 Based on the number of
projects (as opposed to credit volume), China still represents 50% of the
market. 53 Other dominant sellers include India and Brazil. 54 These concentrations
aside, CDM projects have been registered in over 45 countries. 55 In total, as of
October 2007, over 80 million CERs have been issued from over 20 countries. 56
Early purchases of carbon credits received a significant boost with the
commencement of the Prototype Carbon Fund (PCF) of the World Bank, which
began carbon purchases in the year 2000. The basic concept of the PCF is quite
simple: the fund collects contributions from participating entities and uses those
funds to facilitate projects that reduce GHG emissions. The emission reductions
so generated are then distributed to the entities that contributed to the fund pro
rata based on the amount of their respective contributions. The Prototype Carbon
Fund helped to pioneer the development of the carbon market and demonstrate
how CDM and JI transactions could work. 57 Notably, since the development of
the PCF there has been a proliferation of carbon funds both in the World Bank
and the private sector. The World Bank currently manages ten carbon funds with
approximately US$2 billion in capital commitments. 58
At the time of this writing, over 700 projects have made it through the
rigorous CDM process and been both validated by a Designated Operational
Entity and registered by the CDM Executive Board. 59 This has also led to the
37
38
39
40
One constant in both World Bank CER and VER contracts is that the seller
bears the risk that the agreed upon project activity, such as capping a landfill or
improving energy efficiency, will not take place. 82 The assumption underlying this
allocation is that the seller is best-positioned to assess and bear project risk.
However, significant differences in Kyoto risk allocation can be seen
between the World Bank VER and CER contracts. Under the VER General
Conditions, the buyer (the World Bank acting as trustee of a carbon fund) bears
the risk that the project may not be registered and commits to make a payment
based on the agreed-upon monitoring protocol if that registration does not occur
within a specific time period. Furthermore, under the VER General Conditions,
the Bank bears the risk that the agreed-upon methodology will not be not
approved by the CDM Executive Board, and a less favorable methodology will be
applied to the project.83 By comparison, in a CER contract, the seller bears these
risks.84
Another crucial issue in ERPA contracting regards the remedies that are
available if a seller breaches its obligations under an ERPA. Both the World Bank
VER and CER General Conditions provide for three remedies in the event of a
sellers unintentional failure to deliver the contracted-for emission reductions: (i)
allow delivery in subsequent years, (ii) convert the amount of emission reductions
subject to a delivery failure to a call option, or (iii) if, and only, if, the delivery
failure persists for three consecutive years or in any of the last three years of the
contract, terminate the ERPA and recover the World Banks costs. 85 Notably, the
World Bank forgoes the right to terminate for just one or two years delivery
failure, as long as the breach is not an intentional breach. Rather, there must be
a continuing delivery failure in order for the World Bank to have the right to
terminate. The intent behind this approach is to enhance the income flow stability
to the seller, to allow it to obtain financing for the project. Both the CER and VER
General Conditions provide for more stringent remedies in the event of an
intentional breach. 86
By comparison, some CER contracts by other buyers require the seller to
guarantee delivery. Under such contracts, if the seller fails to deliver emission
reductions from a project, it must deliver CERs from a different source to the
buyer. Guarantee provisions have the potential of converting an ERPA from an
41
asset to a liability for the seller. This occurs if a project fails to deliver emission
reductions and the seller incurs higher costs for obtaining those emission
reductions from a different source. However, sellers that offer guaranteed
delivery can obtain higher prices. 87
Other provisions unique to ERPAs as compared with other purchase and
sale agreements can be seen in the World Bank General Conditions. For
instance, ERPAs allocate the responsibility between buyer and seller for paying for
the share of proceeds required to fund certain CDM administrative expenses and
adaptation measures. 88 Under the VER General Conditions the buyer pays the
share of proceeds, while under the CER General Conditions the seller pays the
share of proceeds. 89 This allocation mirrors the allocation of risk in Kyotocompliant projects.
In 2006, CER prices averaged above US$10.00. One study has shown a
significant range in CER prices from around US$6.00 to over US$24.00. 90 Thus,
CER prices exist along a wide band, indicative of the significant variety in risk
between projects, be it project risk, the choice of remedies, the existence of a
delivery guarantee, or some other allocation of risk. This price variation is
indicative of significant differences in risk between projects, and demonstrates the
impact of the allocation of risk and responsibilities in ERPAs on carbon prices.
Average CER prices in 2006 were demonstrably higher than VER prices, further
reflecting the importance of risk in emission reductions pricing. 91
The future is likely to continue to see some convergence in contracting
terms, although varying project activities and approaches to risk make cookiecutter contracts unlikely to emerge soon in the wider market.
V. Lessons Learned
Several lessons can be learned from the growth of the carbon market. First, both
the EU ETS and CDM were successful in bringing substantial amounts of capital
into the carbon market in a short amount of time. In the two years following the
entry into force of the Kyoto Protocol in 2005, the carbon market experienced
tremendous growth from a prototype market to one measured in the tens of
42
billions of dollars. The market expanded to include a wide variety of project types
and market participants.
Second, the CDM was instrumental in developing a regulatory infrastructure
capable of generating significant amounts of offset credits. This regulatory
infrastructure includes a process for validating projects, creating and revising
emission reduction methodologies, and issuing credits subject to third-party
verification.
This CDM regulatory infrastructure can serve as a model for other national
and international programs. Few regulatory programs satisfy every goal of every
stakeholder, and the CDM is no exception. One significant challenge for the
CDM will be to evolve to scale. Increased scale, if properly implemented, can
allow more capital, development and technology benefits to flow to the
developing world, while also scaling up increased greenhouse gas emission
reductions in a cost-effective manner.
Third, the international carbon market is just that a market. Markets
respond to incentives. Early CDM projects involved credits that could be
generated both quickly and relatively inexpensively. This is not surprising since
markets seek the most efficient mechanism for creating economic value. The
question of what incentives are provided by the international carbon market is
driven in significant part by political decisions that shape the regulatory structure.
Risk in the carbon market has had a significant impact on the pace of
projects and the price of carbon credits. Even though the framework of the Kyoto
Protocol was agreed to in 1997, the volume of projects did not increase
significantly until the entry into force of the Kyoto Protocol nearly seven years
later. In the interim period, a number of buyers took innovative approaches to
assessing risks, including the purchase of carbon credits under VER structures
before the entry into force of the Kyoto Protocol. The World Bank played a
significant role in spearheading the learning by doing of how transactions
could take place in the international carbon market. However, the allocation of
Kyoto risk continues to have an impact on projects and carbon pricing. Various
approaches to allocating rights and responsibilities have allowed parties to tailor
risks and benefits to their particular needs. Market continuity is also a significant
issue. CDM projects involve upfront costs, including the regulatory costs of
getting a project and its methodology approved by the CDM Executive Board, as
43
well as capital costs in implementing the project itself. These upfront costs can be
a particularly significant issue for renewable energy projects, which require a
certain length of time to recover costs through carbon payments. If these projects
cannot recover payments for carbon credits beyond 2012, the end of the first
Kyoto commitment period, many worthwhile projects may not be feasible. At the
time of this writing, much remains to be done to ensure a viable and vibrant
post-2012 international carbon market.
In sum, carbon finance has shown that a market-based mechanism can
draw significant amounts of capital, both public and private, to the problem of
climate change, as well as spur economic activity in, and transfer climate-friendly
technology to, developing countries. The international carbon market has
learned significant lessons, and has developed a regulatory infrastructure for
offset credits through the CDM. These lessons learned can provide a roadmap
not only for improving the CDM, but also for expanding the carbon market to
include new market participants and regulatory regimes.
Endnotes
1
KARAN CAPOOR & PHILIPPE AMBROSI, STATE AND TRENDS OF THE CARBON MARKET 2007 3
(World Bank 2007), available at http://carbonfinance.org/ docs/Carbon_Trends_
2007-_FINAL_-_May_2.pdf.
44
Id. at Art. 2.
Id.
Id.
Kyoto Protocol, supra note 2, at Annex B. For background on the negotiation of the
Kyoto Protocol and the design of the CDM, see RAUL ESTRADA-OYUELA, A Commentary
on the Kyoto Protocol, in ENVIRONMENTAL MARKETS: EQUITY AND EFFICIENCY (Graciela
Chichilnisky & Geoffrey Heal eds., Columbia University Press 2000); FARHANA YAMIN
(ED.), CLIMATE CHANGE AND CARBON MARKETS: A HANDBOOK OF EMISSION REDUCTION
MECHANISMS (Earthscan 2005); MICHAEL GRUBB, THE GREENHOUSE EFFECT: NEGOTIATING
TARGETS (Royal Inst. of Intl Affairs 1989); MICHAEL GRUBB ET. AL., THE KYOTO PROTOCOL:
A GUIDE AND ASSESSMENT (Royal Inst. of Intl Affairs 1999).
10
11
12
13
14
15
Id.
16
17
18
19
The Kyoto Protocol regulates six greenhouse gases, each of which is indexed, on a
per-ton basis, based on global warming potential relative to carbon. Thus, one ton
of carbon equals one tCO2e. Methane is 23 times more potent than carbon as a
GHG, and thus reducing one ton of methane is equivalent to reducing 23 tons of
carbon. The industrial gas HFC-23 is 12,000 times more potent than carbon as a
GHG. Energy Information Administration [EIA], Comparison of Global Warming
45
Potentials from the Second and Third Assessment Reports of the Intergovernmental
Panel on Climate Change (IPCC), http://www.eia.doe.gov/oiaf/1605/gwp.html (last
visited Nov. 12, 2007); see also Kyoto Protocol, supra note 2, at Art. 5, 3.
20
See, e.g., Conference of the Parties Serving as the Meeting of the Parties to the Kyoto
Protocol, Montreal, Nov. 28, 2005Dec. 10, 2005, Modalities and procedures for a
clean development mechanism, 7, UN Doc. FCCC/KP/CMP/2005/8/Add.1
(Mar. 30, 2006), available at http://cdm.unfccc.int/Reference/COPMOP/08a01.pdf
[hereinafter Modalities and Procedures].
21
22
See UNFCCC, Verify and Certify ERs of a CDM project activity, http://cdm.unfccc.int/
Projects/pac/howto/CDMProjectActivity/VerifyCertify/ index.html (last visited Nov.
20, 2007).
23
24
The COP/MOP, a subset of parties to the UNFCCC, consists of those parties that
have also ratified the Kyoto Protocol. Thus, the United States and Australia are not
members of the COP/MOP. See Kyoto Protocol, supra note 2, at Art. 13, 12.
25
For a detailed review of law-making by COPs, see Jutta Brunne, COPing with
Consent: Law-Making Under Multilateral Environmental Agreements, 15 LEIDEN J.
INTL L. 1 (2002).
26
27
Id. at 5.
28
29
Id. at 3538.
30
Id. at 43.
31
Id. at 4448.
32
Id. at 53.
33
Id. at 40(a).
34
Id. at 35.
35
Id. at 2627.
36
Id. at 41.
37
46
38
The CDM allows for expedited procedures for small scale projects. See United
Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change, Small scale CDM project
activities, http://cdm.unfccc.int/Projects/pac/pac_ssc.html (last visited Nov. 20, 2007).
39
UNFCCC, Verify and Certify ERs of a CDM project activity, supra note 22.
40
41
42
Interview by unknown with Yvo De Boer, Executive Secretary, UNFCCC, in Bonn, Fr.
(October 30, 2006), available at http://www.ecologie.gouv.fr/ IMG/pdf/interview_
yvo_de_boer.pdf.
43
Council Decision 2002/358, 2002 O.J. (L 130) 1, 13 (EC); see also Council
Directive 2003/87, 2003 O.J. (L 275) 32, 3235 (EC).
44
Council Directive 2003/87, Art. 11, 2003 O.J. (L 275) 32, 36 (EC).
45
46
47
48
The use of credits from forestry projects and large hydroelectric projects is restricted.
See Council Directive 2004/101, arts. 11(a)(b), 2004 O.J. (L 338) 18, 2021 (EC).
49
See e.g., Climate Stewardship and Innovation Act, S. 280, 110th Cong.
144145 (2007).
50
51
Id. at 24.
52
Id.
53
Id., citing to Jorgen Fenhann, UNEP Risoe Centre, CDM projects by host region,
http://cdmpipeline.org/cdm-projects-region.htm (last visited Nov. 20, 2007).
54
55
56
57
See DAVID FREESTONE, The World Banks Prototype Carbon Fund: Mobilizing New
Resources for Sustainable Development, in LIBER AMICORUM IBRAHIM F.I. SHIHATA
265, 280 (Sabine Schlemmer-Schulte & Ko-Yung Tung eds., 2001).
58
See WORLD BANK, CARBON FINANCE FOR SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT 19 (2006), available
at http://carbonfinance.org/docs/CFU_AR_2006.pdf.
47
59
60
61
62
This section draws heavily on the Authors prior work, available at Christopher Carr
& Flavia Rosembuj, World Bank Experiences in Contracting for Emission Reductions,
15 ENVTL. LIAB. 114, 116 (Mar.Apr. 2007).
63
See id.
64
Intl Emissions Trading Assn [IETA], Buyer Limited and Seller Co., Ltd.: Emissions
Reduction Purchase Agreement (Dec. 3, 2005) (draft for discussion purposes),
available at http://www.ieta.org/ieta/www/pages/download.php?docID=1318; see
also Certified Emission Reductions Sale and Purchase Agreement [CERSPA],
http://www.cerspa.com/downloads/CERSPA_Template_Eng_v1_4-2007.doc (last visited
Nov. 7, 2007) (an open source contract template for buying and selling CERs).
65
66
Id.
67
Carr & Rosembuj, supra note 62, at 118. While transactions may involve a variety of
other risks, focusing on these two types of risks helps to understand the
fundamentals of CDM transactions.
68
Id. at 11617.
69
Id. at 117. See Intl Bank for Reconstruction and Dev. [IBRD], General Conditions
Applicable to Verified Emission Reductions Purchase Agreement: Clean Development
Mechanism Projects, at 3, (Feb. 1, 2006), available at http://carbonfinance.
org/docs/VERGeneralConditions.pdf [hereinafter VER General Conditions] (providing
a definition of Emission Reductions).
70
Carr & Rosembuj, supra note 62, at 118; Conference of the Parties Serving as the
Meeting of the Parties to the Kyoto Protocol, Montreal, Nov. 28, 2005Dec. 10,
2005, Report of the Conference of the Parties serving as the meeting of the Parties to
the Kyoto Protocol on its first session, 8, UN Doc. FCCC/KP/CMP/20005/ 8/Add.1
(Mar. 30, 2006), available at http://cdm.unfccc.int/Reference/COPMOP/08a01.
pdf#page=31. The CDM Executive Board supervises the CDM, under the authority
and guidance of the Conference of the Parties serving as the Meeting of the Parties
to the Kyoto Protocol.
71
48
72
Id. at 117; see, e.g., Intl Emissions Trading Assn [IETA], Code of CDM Terms:
Version 1.0, available at http://www.ieta.org/ieta/www/pages/getfile.php?docID=
1794 (Sept. 11, 2006).
73
Id. at 117.
74
Id. at 117.
75
WORLD BANK CARBON FINANCE UNIT, THE ROLE OF THE WORLD BANK IN CARBON FINANCE: AN
APPROACH FOR FURTHER ENGAGEMENT 13 (2006), available at http://carbonfinance.org/
docs/Role_of_the_WorkBank.pdf.
76
77
Id.
78
Id. at 117.
79
For instance, in the United States, companies have voluntarily bought and sold
emission reductions in the absence of a federal greenhouse gas regulatory program.
80
81
See, e.g., PROJECT ENTITY & INTERNATIONAL BANK FOR RECONSTRUCTION AND DEVELOPMENT
(AS TRUSTEE OF FUND), CLEAN DEVELOPMENT MECHANISM CERTIFIED EMISSION REDUCTIONS
PURCHASE AGREEMENT (2006), http://carbonfinance.org/docs/CER_ERPA_07_07_06_
model.doc.
82
Id. at 118. See, e.g., VER General Conditions, supra note 69; see also IBRD, General
Conditions Applicable to Certified Emission Reductions Purchase Agreement (2006),
http://carbonfinance.org/docs/CERGeneralConditions.pdf [hereinafter CER General
Conditions].
83
84
See, e.g., CER General Conditions, supra note 82; Carr & Rosembuj, supra note 62,
at 118.
85
VER General Conditions, supra note 69, at 13.03(a)(i); CER General Conditions,
supra note 82, at 13.03(a)(i); Carr & Rosembuj, supra note 62, at 118.
86
87
88
Conference of the Parties Serving as the Meeting of the Parties to the Kyoto Protocol,
Montreal, Can., Nov. 28-Dec. 10, 2005, Annex 66, UN Doc.
FCCC/KP/CMP/2005/8/Add.1 (March 30, 2006). The adaptation fee includes a two
per cent deduction from CERs issued for projects (except those located in Least
Developed Countries). The administrative fee US$0.10 per CER issued for the first
15,000 CERs for which issuance is requested in a given calendar year and US$0.20
49
per CER issued for any amount in excess of 15,000 CERs for which issuance is
requested in that calendar year. Id. at Decision 7/CMP.1, 37.
89
VER General Conditions, supra note 69, at 5.05; CER General Conditions, supra
note 82, at 5.05.
90
91
3
Linking the EU Emissions Trading
Scheme to JI, CDM and Post-2012
International Offsets
J. de Spibus*
The author evaluates the Linking-Directive approved by European
Union Emissions Trading Scheme (EU ETS). The author finds
that though the Linking directive did not impose any limit on the
import of JI/CDM credits yet it required the Member States to
set maximum quantity of Kyoto units. The directive lead to collapse
of prices in the EUs emission markets, in consequence the EU
ETS decided to impose strict limits on the use of JI/CDM credits
during its second trading period. The author intends to examine
the International and European legal framework to find a better
utilization of JI/CDM credits in post-2012 international offsets.
The author finds that the European view on the appropriateness
of linking the EU ETS with the international project
mechanisms has changed over the years. Therefore, the author
suggests for introducing quantitative and qualitative restrictions
for the use of international offsets within the EU ETS.
*
Former professor of International and European lLaw (university of fribaurg); consultant, NCCR trade
regulation. World Trade Institute, Haller Strasse 6, Berne, Switzerland. E-mail: joelle.desepibus.@unifr.ch
50
Introduction
The so-called Linking-Directive adopted in 2004 doesnt impose any limit on
the import of JI/CDM credits under the European Union Emissions Trading
Scheme (EU ETS), but requires from the Member States to set, in accordance with
their supplementarity obligations under the Marrakesh Accords, the maximal
amount of Kyoto units each covered installation is entitled to use for compliance
under the scheme. Fearing a second price collapse of the European Union
Allowance, the Commission decided, however, in 2006 to impose strict limits on
the use of JI/CDM credits during the second trading period. This paper examines
the legal basis of the Commissions decision and explores further the
international and European legal framework within which the current debate on
the use of JI/CDM credits and post-2012 international offsets takes place. It
analyses in particular the recent proposal of the Commission on the third trading
period of the EU ETS and the related report of rapporteur Doyle of the European
Parliament and discusses the necessity to introduce quantitative and qualitative
restrictions for the use of international offsets within the EU ETS against the
backdrop of the international negotiations on a new global deal on climate
change.
While the international discussions about a global and comprehensive post2012 agreement to fight climate change started in Bali in December 2007, the
first trading period of the European Union Emissions Trading Scheme (EU ETS)
has come to an end. Its environmental effectiveness is highly contested, as
Member States, facing a type of Prisoners Dilemma, 1 were unable to resist the
temptation to hand out generous emissions allowances, causing the collapse of
the price of the European Union Allowance (EUA) 2 at the end of 2006 and
reducing to zero the incentives to abate emissions and to develop alternative
fuels and more energy-efficient technologies. The question naturally arises as to
whether the second (20082012) and third trading periods (20132020) of the
EU ETS will witness a more positive environmental outcome.
Although the European Commission 3 has cut the proposed amount of
allowances (the cap) for the second trading period by about 10%, many
analysts 4 expect the shortage of allowances to be covered entirely by the import
51
52
within
the
Community
(ETS-Directive). 18
The
scheme
53
the case that the amount of credits reached 6% of the total quantity of allowances
and to consider whether a maximum percentage, for example 8%, should be
introduced.
The most frequently invoked reason for the inclusion of the project-based
mechanisms was that they reduce the compliance costs for the sectors covered
under the EU ETS by broadening the range of opportunities to reduce emissions
in another Member State or outside the EU at lower costs. 27 Another advantage is
that they allow sources not covered by the ETS-Directive to engage in
implementing cost-effective reduction options. Finally, the combination of
emission caps and the possibility to use CDM and JI was meant to help kick-start
the international carbon market. Many environmental Non-Governmental
Organisations (NGOs) were, however, opposed to the use of JI and CDM credits
within the EU ETS, because they feared that a massive import of Kyoto units into
the system would significantly lower the market price of the EUA and lead to little
or no domestic abatement. 28 They also expressed doubts about the
environmental quality of the credits generated by the Kyoto Protocols projectbased mechanisms. 29
54
55
56
57
58
59
60
61
this privileged treatment is that these countries are especially vulnerable to the
effects of climate change and are responsible only for a very low level of
greenhouse gas emissions. 82 Finally, in the event that the conclusion of an
international agreement on climate change is delayed, operators are allowed to
have recourse to credits from project activities in third countries with which the
Community has concluded agreements. 83 However, once an international
agreement on climate change has been reached, only CERs from third countries
which have ratified that agreement shall be accepted in the Community scheme. 84
The reasons given by the Commission for allowing the exchange of CDM
and JI credits is that it gives operators certainty that they may use them after the
end of the second trading period. Clearly, the Commission also wants to avoid a
price collapse similar to the one seen in the first trading period. This risk is all the
more real, as the number of JI/CDM credits considerably exceeds the reduction
required from operators with respect to their 2005 emissions. 85 Moreover, if the
seven Member States which required the annulment of the Commissions
decision regarding their NAPs were to win their legal challenge, another
significant quantity of allowances would flow into the EU ETS and diminish further
the relative scarcity of allowances imposed by the Commission.
b. In the Case of a Global International Climate Agreement
The ETS-Proposal foresees that upon the conclusion of a future international
agreement the ETS-Directive should provide for an automatic adjustment of the
use of credits from JI/CDM credits and potentially additional types of credits
and/or mechanisms envisaged under such an agreement. Operators may use up
to half of the additional reduction taking place due to the international
agreement CERs, ERUs or other types of credits earned in countries which have
concluded the international agreement. 86 Once an international agreement on
climate change has been reached, no CERs from third countries which have not
ratified that agreement may be accepted as complying with the ETS.
62
rapporteur of the Green Party, finalised her draft report on the Effort-Sharing
Proposal. 88 The vote on both reports by the Environmental Committee of the
European Parliament is scheduled for 7 October2008. 89
In line with the Commission the Doyle Report endorses the strategy of the
European Council with respect to the overall emission reduction targets, i.e. a
reduction of greenhouse gas emissions of 20% or 30% with respect to 1990
levels in the case of the conclusion of an international agreement on climate
change. 90 In contrast to the ETS-Proposal, the report suggests that an increase of
the reduction commitment would occur only after the ratification of a global
international agreement and not as soon as it is concluded. 91
Regarding the use of international offsets the report stipulates that operators
should be allowed to use external credits up to an average of 5% of their
emissions during the period from 2013 to 2020, provided they use less credits
from CDM and JI projects during the 2008-2012 period than the equivalent of
6,5% of their 2005 emissions and that they do not carry over entitlements from
that period. In other words, operators under the ETS have the choice to either use
external credits at a level of 5% of their annual greenhouse gas emissions 92 or
to bank the credits they had been granted in the second trading period.
According to the Doyle Report, this option enables operators to use external
credits for almost half of their abatement effort between 2013 and 2020 and
would ensure that in the period 20082020, operators effectively reduce
emissions below those for 2005.
Unlike the Commissions proposal, the report also addresses the growing
criticism levelled against the Kyoto Protocol project mechanisms by requiring
additional qualitative guarantees with respect to the environmental integrity of
international offsets. 93 Accordingly, the rapporteur proposes to accept exclusively
JI/CDM credits and/or other external credits provided for by a global climate
accord if they come from so-called Gold Standard-type projects. 94 Where
bilateral agreements with third countries are concluded, the report further
specifies that credits envisaged by these agreements may also come from
sustainable forestry activities in developing countries. 95 Finally, the rapporteur
suggests that operators may use credits up to a non-specified percentage of their
emissions from sustainable actions to reduce deforestation and increase
63
64
of the project on the sustainable development of the host country. 102 Finally, the
Stakeholder Consultation Guidelines set out by the Gold Standard must be
respected; these lay down strict criteria for the involvement and information of
local stakeholders, in particular NGOs supporting the Gold Standard.
By requiring that credits come from Gold Standard-type projects, the Doyle
Report ensures that the Gold Standard is not entrusted a monopoly position with
regard to the certification of external credits allowed into the ETS. The question
as to which criteria will have to be fulfilled and who is responsible for formalising
and controlling them must thus still be answered.
65
developing countries would have to keep emissions between 15% and 30% below
baseline. 107 He concludes thus that an EU target compatible with limiting climate
change to 2 degrees Celsius would require reductions of emissions within the EU
to
at
least 30% below 1990 levels plus support for developing countries through CDM
or another carbon mechanism of the order of magnitude of an additional 10
percentage points. 108
The necessity for taking stronger action is, in particular, recognised by the
Hassi Report on Effort-Sharing. Recalling that the European Parliament had itself
called in October 2006 for a 30% reduction target, the rapporteur proposes to
turn upside down the Commissions proposal by using the reduction target
of 30%1 as a starting point and keeping the 20% reduction as a fallback option in
the case that no international agreement on climate change is concluded. 109
Hassi finally advocates that the recourse to credits resulting from projects in third
countries should, as a rule, not replace the domestic reduction effort but reflect
an additional commitment taken by industrialised countries to assist developing
countries. She proposes instead that the EU endorses a so-called additional
external commitment, which, in the case of the conclusion of a global climate
accord, would mandate the EU to assist developing countries in their activities to
mitigate climate change. 110
66
hence expect that in the absence of decisive action supporting the deployment of
renewable energies 116 and/or nuclear energy in the recently liberalised power
industry, the European power industry will be locked into a fuel mix with a high
share of fossil fuels 117 for many decades to come.
The significant recourse to international offsets envisaged by the ETSProposal is indeed likely to prevent the expected EUA price from increasing
sufficiently to ensure a rapid decarbonisation of the power industry as called for
by Al Gore 118 to meet the recommendations of the IPCC. 119 It is interesting to
note that the Commission once again has recourse to a 50% ceiling for external
credits, which echoes the limit initially proposed for the Linking Directive and
the ceiling established in its decision in 2006 for the second trading period. 120
Unlike the latter decision the new 50% ceiling does not provide for exceptions in
favour of the new Member States and is exclusively applicable to the covered
sectors of the ETS in the case of the conclusion of a new global climate accord.
67
Commission replied that its proposal does not preclude any decision of the EU to
require stricter criteria within the framework of the future climate accord. 123
Moreover, by keeping all options open the EU is ensured more leverage during
the international negotiation process and greater room for maneuvre to craft
new innovative instruments.
While these arguments are at first sight appealing, the lack of a clear
position of the EU on the environmental integrity of external credits has its
drawbacks. Indeed, the EU partly forfeits its reputation as a leader in the climate
change debate and runs the risk of continuing to finance the false emission
reductions of projects that do not foster sustainable development. The proposal
of the Doyle Report, restricting the use of external credits to Gold Standard-type
credits, represents, in this respect, a good compromise. 124 Even if the proposal
remains unsatisfactory in terms of the clarity of its wording, it offers a good
starting point for a stricter policy regarding the use of international offsets in a
situation where lessons from the international carbon market have still to be
learnt.
The reference to the Gold Standard is pertinent, as the requirements of this
label, supported by numerous NGOs, do indeed represent an innovative and yet
pragmatic way to ensure better environmental quality of greenhouse gas
emission offsets. The Gold Standard, however, does not address all criticisms
levelled against the CDM mechanism. For instance, the verification of the Gold
Standard Requirements is done by the same private entities which are criticised
for their insufficient neutrality and sometimes dubious professionalism. 125 Also,
there is a lack of control of the work of the Gold Standard organisation by
democratic institutions. Finally, a restriction of the CDM mechanisms to
renewable energy and end-use energy projects presents, besides the obvious
advantages of this kind of projects in limiting the dependence on fossil fuels, also
has disadvantages. First, it reduces the scope of this mechanism to discover and
address cheap mitigation options and impairs the stability of the international
carbon market. 126 Second, the additionality 127 of renewable energy and enduse efficiency projects is often doubtful and subject to gaming. 128 Third, many
experts suggest that the offset mechanism does not represent an appropriate
instrument to encourage this type of project and that they would be better
68
III. Conclusions
The debate on the criteria governing the linkage of the EU ETS with international
offsets takes place against the backdrop of the international negotiations on a
new global deal on climate change which is expected to be concluded in
Copenhagen at the end of 2009. Its general boundaries are set by the unilateral
commitment of the EU in 2007 to reduce its greenhouse gas emissions by 20%
or by 30% and the Bali Action Plan adopted at the end of 2007, which makes
any commitment of developing countries dependent on a clearly identifiable
support of developed countries, including technology transfer, financing and
capacity-building. 131
The European view on the appropriateness of linking the EU ETS with the
international project mechanisms has changed over the years as the discussion
on the numerous interpretations of the supplementarity criteria testifies.
Whereas the Commission was initially sceptical as to an integration of Kyoto
credits into the EU ETS, fearing lax international rules on CDM and JI, 132 the
position has changed due to the pressure from emitters. By the time the Linking
Directive was finally adopted, a general shift of attitudes had taken place as the
absence of a clear limit for CDM und JI by this Directive attests. A major reason
for this change of heart was that companies covered by the EU ETS had made
69
clear that they would remain inflexible regarding the initial amount of EUAs
allocated unless they could get access to the CDM. 133
The collapse of the EUA in 2006, however, somewhat dampened the
enthusiasm generated by the successful kick-off of the international carbon
market. Moreover, the IPCC stressed that industrialised countries had to step up
their domestic reduction effort significantly to stabilise global warming. 134
Further, the analysis of a growing number of academics and observers of the
CDM market shows that many CDM projects are not additional 135 and that the
mechanism in its current form is unable to mobilise funds on the scale they are
needed. 136 Especially in the United States, which is likely to take a firmer grip on
climate change after the presidential elections at the end of 2008 and where
many states are preparing to set up emission trading schemes, the linking with
external credits is intensely debated. Whereas certain critics argue that the
recourse to international offsets leads to large transfers of money in favour of
China and India which are not matched by any significant emission
reductions, 137 others are in favour of their use but call for strict procedural
safeguards to ensure their environmental integrity. 138
In the European Union, the upcoming vote in October 2008 by the
Environmental Committee of the European Parliament on the ETS- and BurdenSharing proposals and later on the vote in the Council is mobilising thousands of
stakeholders behind the scenes. The pressure to maintain the current system is
important, as the considerable financial interests of both the covered industries of
the EU ETS and the stakeholders of the international carbon markets are at
stake. 139 Given the wide spectrum of views among the Member States and the
European Parliament, the stage is no doubt set again for an intense tug-ofwar. 140 It remains to be seen whether the final compromise on the linking issue
will ultimately meet the common climate challenge.
References
Anger Niels (2006). Emissions trading beyond Europe: linking schemes in a post-Kyoto
world, ZEW Discussion paper n. 6-58.
Barker Terry (2008). Achieving the 2C Target through carbon trading, Cambridge Centre
for Climate Change Mitigation Research and Tyndall Centre for Climate Change
Research.
70
Bygrave Stephen, Bosi Martina (2004). Linking Project-based Mechanisms with Domestic
Greenhouse Gas Emissions Trading Schemes, IEA, OECD.
CAN (2008). NGO briefing on the European Commissions legislative proposals on 2020
greenhouse gas effort sharing and the review of the European Emission Trading Scheme
at http://www.climnet.org/EUenergy/ET/270208NGOETS_briefing.pdf
De Larragan Javier de Cendra (2006). Linking the project based mechanisms with the EU
ETS: the present state of affairs and challenges ahead, p. 99-123, in: Peeters Marjan,
Deketelaere Kurt R. eds., EU climate change policy: the challenge of new regulatory
initiatives, Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham.
Delbeke Jos (2008). Time to rethink the CDM. Current uncertainty around the Clean
Development Mechanism has deeper roots than the EU ETS review and needs longer-term
solutions, Environmental Finance, p. 18.
De Spibus Jolle (2007a). Scarcity and Allocation of Allowances in the EU Emissions
Trading Scheme A Legal Analysis. NCCR Trade Regulation Working Paper n. 2007/32,
at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1088726
De Spibus Jolle (2007b). The European Emission Trading Scheme Put to the Test of
State Aid Rules. NCCR Trade Regulation Working Paper n. 2007/3, at http://ssrn.com/
abstract=1088716
De Spibus Jolle (2008). The Liberalisation of the Power Industry in the European Union
and its Impact on Climate Change A Legal Analysis of the Internal Market in Electricity,
NCCR Trade Regulation Working Paper n. 10/2008, at: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/
papers.cfm?abstract_id=1137823
Driesen David M. (2006). Links Between European Emissions Trading and CDM Credits
for Renewable Energy and Energy Efficiency Projects, at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/
papers.cfm?abstract_id=881830
EEA (2007). Indicator EN27, electricity production by fuel.
Egenhofer Christian, van Schaik Louise, Cornland Deborah (2005). Improving the Clean
Development Mechanism, European Climate Platform, CEPS and CLIPORE.
Flachsland Christian, Edenhofer Ottmar, Jakob Michael, Steckel Jan (2008). Developing
the International Carbon Market, Linking Options for the EU ETS, Potsdam Institute for
Climate Impact Research, Potsdam.
Hgstad Flm Karoline (2007). A Multi-level Analysis of theEU Linking Directive Process
The Controversial Connection between EU and Global Climate Policy, Fridtjof Nansen
Institute.
Hampton Kate (2007). Linking to action in developing countries at http://www.carboninvestors.
org/Linking.pdf
Helm Dieter (2008). The Economic Implications of the EU Climate Change Policy,
Presentation at the European Central Bank, at http://www.blue-emu.net/presentations/
ECB_March_6_2008.pdf
Helme Ned, Movius Diana, Ogonowski Matt, Schmidt Jake (2008). The Dual Markets
Approach to Reducing Emissions from Deforestation and Degradation in Developing
71
Countries, p. 103- 117, in: Egenhofer Christian (ed.), Beyond Bali, Strategic issues of the
post-2012 climate change regime.
Hhne Niklas (2008). CDM in the EU Climate Package Internal vs. external effort effort
sharing under the Climate Package -assessing the role of the Clean Development
Mechanism, Presented at the Conference Effort sharing under the Climate Package
assessing the role of the Clean Development Mechanism, European Parliament, 3 June,
2008, at: http://www.ecologic-events.de/cdm-workshop/download/hoehne_slides.pdf
IPCC (2007). Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the
Intergovernmental Panel on Climate, Technical Summary.
International Rivers (2008). Bad Deal for the Planet. Why Carbon Offsets Arent Working
and How to Create a Fair Global Climate Accord at: http://www.internationalrivers.org/
en/node/2826.
Klepper Gernot, Peterson Sonja (2005). Emissions Trading, CDM, JI, and More The
Climate Strategy of the EU, Kiel Working Paper n. 1238.
Kurkowski Susan (2006). Distributing the right to pollute in the European Union: Efficiency,
Equity and the Environment, N.Y.U. Environmental Law Journal, v. 14, p. 698- 733.
Langrock Thomas, Sterk Wolfgang (2004). The Supplementarity Challenge: CDM, JI & EU
Emissions Trading, Policy Paper 1, Wuppertal Institute for Climate, Environment and Energy.
Lefevere Jrgen (2005). Linking Emissions Trading Schemes: The EU ETS and the Linking
Directive, p. 511- 533, in: Freestone David, Streck Charlotte eds., Legal aspects of
implementing the Kyoto Protocol mechanisms: making Kyoto work, Oxford University
Press, Oxford.
Lohmann Larry (2008). Carbon Trading, Climate Justice and the Production of Ignorance:
Ten Examples, The Corner House, at: http://www.thecornerhouse.org.uk/summary.
shtml?x=561681.
Meijer Ernestine, Werksman Jacob (2005). Keeping it Clean Safeguarding the
Environmental Integrity of the Clean Development Mechanism, in: Freestone David, Streck
Charlotte eds. Legal aspects of implementing the Kyoto Protocol mechanisms: making
Kyoto work, Oxford University Press, Oxford.
Michaelowa Axel (2004). How Europe embraced the CDM The role of researchers and
interest groups in changing Minds, at http://www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/media/A/C/
Michaelowa_(2004n)_How_Europe_embraced.pdf1
Michaelowa Axel (2005). CDM: current status and possibilities for reform, Hamburgisches
Weltwirtschaftsinstitut.
Michaelowa Axel (2007). Le mcanisme de dveloppement propre nuit-il la protection
internationale du climat? Revue de politique conomique n. 9, p. 20-23.
Michaelowa Axel, Purohit Pallav (2007). Additionality determination of Indian projects,
Can Indian CDM project developers outwit the CDM executive Board? Climate Strategies.
72
73
Endnotes
1
The Prisoners Dilemma results from the fact that all Member States will benefit when
emission reductions goals are met but each Member State has an incentive to overallocate allowances to in-state firms providing them an opportunity to become net
sellers to the emissions credit market. See Kurkowski (2006: 716).
See The World Bank (2008: 9), Openeurope (2007), WWF (2007).
The Kyoto Protocols project mechanisms are the CDM and the JI. CDM stands for
clean development mechanism and JI for joint implementation. CDM and JI projects
lead to the emission of so-called Certified Emission Reductions (CERs) in the case of
the CDM and Emission Reduction Units (ERUs) in the case of JI. They are commonly
called the Kyoto units and may be used by the Parties included in Annex B for
compliance under the Kyoto Protocol.
Delbeke (2008), Wara (2008), Wara et. al., (2008), Lohmann (2008), International
Rivers (2008), Voigt (2008), Schneider (2007), Muller (2007), Michaelowa (2007),
Pearson (2006), Egenhofer et. al., (2005), De Larragan (2005), Meijer et. al., (2005),
Michaelowa (2005), Bygrave et. al., (2004).
74
10
An international offset in this context represents a credit which certifies the reduction,
removal, or avoidance of greenhouse gas emissions by a project taking place
outside of the European Union and that is used to compensate for greenhouse gas
emissions occurring in the European Union. See also for a more general definition of
the meaning of an offset the Offset Quality Initiative (2008: 2).
11
Although crucial for the environmental integrity of the ETS, the linkage of the EU ETS
with other emission trading schemes will not be examined in this publication. See for
a thorough discussion on this subject inter alia Flachsland et. al., (2008), Schle et. al.,
(2006), Anger (2006).
12
13
14
15
European Parliament (2008). Draft report on the proposal for a directive of the
European Parliament and of the Council amending Directive 2003/87/EC so as to
improve and extend greenhouse gas emission allowance trading system of the
Community of 11th June 2008, Committee on the Environment, Public Health and
Food Safety, rapporteur Avril Doyle, (COM (2008)0016C6-0043/20082008/
0013(COD), the Doyle report.
16
75
17
18
19
20
Article 9 ETS-Directive.
21
22
23
24
25
The conversion was to be done by Member States, which were granted the right to
issue one new allowance in exchange for one CER or ERU. Under the proposal
Member States kept the freedom to impose other criteria for the conversion of Kyoto
credits into allowances. See Lefevere (2005: 524).
26
The comitology procedure in the European Union refers to the committee system,
which oversees the acts implemented by the European Commission on behalf of the
Council of Ministers. Amendments submitted to this procedure may be decided more
quickly than those governed by the normal legislative process. See http://europa.eu/
scadplus/glossary/comitology_en.htm.
27
28
29
See for a thorough analysis of the discussion on the influence of the various
stakeholders on the final content of the Linking Directive Hgstad Flm (2007: 25 ff.).
30
76
States pleaded for the full fungibility between CERs, ERUs and EUAs, many
environmental NGOs opposed any linking or at least required strict limits for their
use within the EU ETS. See Lefevere (2005: 520), Hgstad Flm (2007: 25ff.)
31
32
See for a discussion on the opportunities and threats of the inclusion of the CDM
and JI in the EU ETS Lefevere (2005: 520ff.).
33
On the insistence of the European Parliament a clause has been added, which
requests CDM and JI projects regarding dams with a capacity over 20 MW to
comply with relevant international guidelines.
34
35
The Marrakesh Accords adopted by the Conference of the Parties (CoP 7) define the
modalities of the use of the project-based mechanisms adopted by the Kyoto
Protocol. The supplementarity requirement was integrated in the Marrakesh
Accords on the insistence of the European Union. See Langrock et. al., (2004:6).
36
The Marrakesh Accords stipulate: the use of the mechanisms shall be supplemental
to domestic action and that domestic action shall thus constitute a significant effort
made by each Party included in Annex I to meet its quantified emission limitation
and reduction commitments under Article 3, paragraph 1. See Article 1 Draft
Decision-/CMP.1 (Mechanisms) contained in Decision 15 /CP.7. See also Langrock
et. al., (2004: 6)
37
38
39
According to the Kyoto Protocol the 15 old Member States of the EU have to reduce
a basket of six greenhouse gases by 8% over the period 20082012 with respect to
their emissions in 1990. As Article 4 of the Kyoto Protocol allows groups of countries
to agree on a common reduction target, the EU has subsequently redistributed this
target among the different countries in a burden-sharing agreement. The ten new
Member States, which joined the EU in 2005, are only liable under the Kyoto
Protocol. Malta and Cyprus have no reduction commitments at all.
40
At the meeting of the Environment Council held on 16 and 17 June 1998, the
Member States of the European Union agreed to divide the 8% emission reduction
for the European Community between the Member States. Each Member State is
individually responsible for reaching the specific target set under this agreement.
77
Member States targets vary significantly, ranging from a reduction of 21% for
Germany and Denmark to an increase of 25% for Greece. The EU burden-sharing
agreement was made legally binding through its inclusion in the ratification decision,
adopted by the Council on 4 March 2002. See Council Decision 2002/358/EC
concerning the approval, on behalf of the European Community, of the Kyoto
Protocol to the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change and the
joint fulfillment of commitments thereunder.
41
Art. 2.3 par. 4 of the third guidance on the criteria of Annex III reads: The level of
effort to reduce greenhouse gases a Member State is required to undertake is
determined by assessing the amount of reduction it is required to undertake in
relation to base year emissions, greenhouse gas emissions in 2004, and projected
emissions in 2010.41 In the next step, half of the figure representing the highest
effort is calculated. This figure is considered to be the maximum overall amount of
JI/CDM credits that a Member State can make use of in addition to domestic action,
while respecting its commitments to ensure that the use of the Kyoto mechanisms is
supplemental to domestic action. See European Commission, COM (2006) 725.
42
It has however to be noted that the ceiling does not fix the overall domestic reduction
effort of Member States as the latter remain free to engage in international trading
of emission allowances, as set out under Article 17 of the Kyoto Protocol.
43
44
The formulation proposed by the European Union during the negotiations of the
Marrakesh Accords was that each party should acquire and surrender no more
emission certificates from abroad than the equivalent of 50% of the difference
between five times the emissions in one of the years between 1994 and 2002, on
the one hand, and its number of assigned units, on the other. See Langrock et. al.,
(2004: 6).
45
Article 17 of the Kyoto Protocol foresees that Parties included in Annex B may
participate in emissions trading for the purposes of fulfilling their commitments
under Article 3 of the Kyoto Protocol.
46
Point 2.3 reads: In respect of Member States which do not intend to purchase any
Kyoto units with government funds, a Member State may allow its operators covered
by the Community scheme to make use of CDM/JI credits to the full amount of this
limit. See European Commission, COM (2006) 725.
47
48
Point 2.3 reads: In respect of Member States which intend to purchase Kyoto units
with government funds, these purchases are taken into account. The amount of
JI/CDM credits that can be used by installations in the Community scheme in that
Member State is reduced by the annual average amount of intended or substantiated
government purchases. See European Commission, COM (2006) 725.
78
49
50
European Commission (2008a: 15), Ellerman et. al., (2008: 33). With respect to
verified emissions in 2007 the reduction represents 7.1%. EU-15 will undertake most
of the overall 20082012 effort, with a cap set at 8.7% lower than verified 2005
emissions while emissions in EU-12 will be allowed to increase by 3.6% above the
2005 benchmark. See The World Bank (2008: 10).
51
EU ETS emissions have actually grown by an average of 1% per year since 2005,
with a more vigorous growth in the Eastern Member States. Thus some analysts
revised their forecasts slightly upward with regard to the likely shortfall in the second
trading period. See for a view of analysts expectations on the shortfall of allowances
in the second and third trading period The World Bank (2008: 9ff.).
52
53
54
See for an analysis of the legal risks taken by the Commission when reducing the
proposed caps for the second trading period de Sepibus (2007a: 18).
55
For instance, the Commission reduced the proposed cap of Lithuania by 47%, of
Latvia by 56%, of Estonia by 4 % and of Poland by 26.7%. Overall, the Commission
cut by 10.4 % the overall caps originally proposed by the Member States, leading to
a maximum of 2.098 million EUAs. See The World Bank (2008: 9 ff.).
56
The NAPs of Bulgaria and Romania are not included in these figures as they have
special circumstances due to their having recently joining the EU (in 2007). See
Schleich et. al., (2007: 22).
57
See for an analysis of the approval process of the NAPs Ellerman et. al., (2007),
Zapfel (2007), de Sepibus (2007a).
58
59
60
79
The reduction objective of 30% is explicitly made subject to the condition that other
developed countries commit themselves to comparable emission reductions and
economically more advanced developing countries make an adequate contribution.
See European Council, 7224/1/07 REV 1. The Conclusions of the European Council
were themselves based on a climate package presented by the Commission in
January 2007. See European Commission, COM (2007) 2.
62
63
The COP 13 is the 13th Conference of the Parties of the UNFCCC and includes, in
particular, also the US.
64
The MOP 3 is the 3rd Conference of the Parties of the Kyoto Protocol and does not
include the US, which has not ratified the Kyoto Protocol.
65
66
See for more details on the negotiation process Egenhofer et. al., (2008: 25ff.),
Watanabe et. al., (2008: 4ff.), Ott et. al., (2008: 91ff).
67
68
See Ott et. al., (2008: 93). The claim of developing countries to receive funds and
help from industrialised countries is based on the fact that they have emitted less
greenhouse gases and thus have less responsibility for climate change than
industrialised countries. Moreover, they are less able to finance emissions reductions.
See table of per capita emissions in Neuhoff (2008: 60).
69
Watanabe et. al., (2008: 9). In comparison the project-based emission reduction in
2007 amounted to a value of US$ 6 billion in 2007. See The World Bank (2008: 2).
70
80
Capture and Storage (CCS) (COM (2008) 13/18) and a revision of the Directive
promoting the use of renewable energy sources (COM (2008)19).
71
72
73
74
The Commission proposes to allow the annual use by Member States of credits from
greenhouse gas emission reduction projects in third countries of up to 3% of each
Member States emissions from sources outside the ETS in 2005.74 This quantity is
equivalent to a third of the reduction effort in 2020. Each Member State is allowed to
transfer the unused part of this limit to another Member State.
75
76
77
The two new gases are nitrous oxide and perfluorocarbons. Overall, these sectors
represent nowadays about 60% of total greenhouse gas emissions in the EU. See
European Commission, Memo 08/34, 23 January 2008.
78
The Commission estimates that EU ETS sectors must contribute more than other
sectors because it is cheaper to reduce emissions in the electricity sector than in most
other sectors. See European Commission, Memo 08/34, 23 January 2008.
79
This means that there is a threat that companies may relocate to third countries with
less stringent climate protection laws.
80
Whereas ERUs from JI projects may be taken into account for emission reductions
until 2012, CERs may be taken into account with respect to emission reductions until
2012 but also from 2013 onwards. See Article 11a, par. 2 and 3 ETS-Proposal.
81
These credits may be used until those countries have ratified an agreement with the
Community or until 2020, whichever is the earlier. See Article 11, par. 4 ETSProposal.
81
82
This entitlement applies to all least developed countries until 2020 provided that
they have by then either ratified a global agreement on climate change or a bilateral
or multilateral agreement with the Community. See Art. 11a par. 4 ETS-Proposal.
83
See Article 11a par. 5 ETS-Proposal. The agreements concluded by the Community
have to provide for the use of credits in the Community scheme from renewable
energy or energy efficiency technologies which promote technological transfer and
sustainable development. Any such agreement may also provide for the use of
credits from projects where the baseline used is below the level of free allocation
under the measures referred to in Article 10a of the ETS-Proposal or below the levels
required by Community legislation. See Article 11a par. 6 ETS-Proposal.
84
85
86
87
European Parliament (2008). Draft report on the proposal for a directive of the
European Parliament and of the Council amending Directive 2003/87/EC so as to
improve and extend greenhouse gas emission allowance trading system of the
Community, rapporteur Avril Doyle, (COM(2008)0016 C6-0043/2008 2008/
0013(COD)) Doyle Report.
88
See European Parliament (2008). Draft report on the effort of Member States to
reduce their greenhouse gas emissions to meet the Communitys greenhouse gas
emission reduction commitments up to 2020, Rapporteur Satu Hassi, (COM
(2008)0017 C6-0041/2008 2008/0014(COD)) Hassi Report.
89
90
For instance, a 20% reduction effort by 2020 compared to 1990, which would be
raised to 30% in the case of an international agreement on climate change.
91
Amendment to Article 11a par. 7 ETS-Proposal. See Doyle report, cited above.
92
82
93
The mechanisms are indeed increasingly criticised by experts and academics for their
focus on unsustainable projects incapable of reducing the dependence of developing
countries on fossil fuels, their inability to guarantee additional emission reductions
and their potential for generating perverse policy incentives. See Wara (2008), Wara
et. al., (2008), Lohmann (2008), Schneider (2007), Michaelowa (2007), Pearson (2006).
94
Amendments to Recitals 22, 25, Art. 11a par. 2, 3, 4, 7 of the ETS-Proposal. See
Doyle Report, cited above.
95
See Amendment to Article 11a par. 6 of the ETS-Proposal. See Doyle Report, cited
above.
96
Amendment to Article 28 paragraph 4 subparagraph 1 a (new) of the ETSProposal. See Doyle Report, cited above. For a discussion on the inclusion of forest
activities by the future climate regime see in particular Helme et. al., (2008: 103 ff.)
97
See cdmgoldstandard.org.
98
See UNFCCC (2005). Decision adopted by the Conference of the Parties serving as
the meeting of the Parties to the Kyoto Protocol 30 March 2006, 3/CMP.1 Modalities
and procedures for a clean development mechanism as defined in Article 12 of the
Kyoto Protocol, FCCC/KP/CMP/2005/8/Add.1.
99
100 Renewable energy projects are defined as the generation and delivery of energy
services (e.g. mechanical work, electricity, heat) from non-fossil and non-depletable
(landfill gas excluded) energy sources. End-use energy efficiency projects are
defined as activities that reduce the amount of energy required for delivering or
producing non-energy physical goods or services. See Paragraph III.d.2 and 3 of the
The Gold Standard Premium Quality Carbon Credits Requirements (The Gold
Standard Requirements) published at: http://www.ecofys.com/com/publications/
documents/GSV2_Requirements_20080731_2.0.pdf
101 See Annex I of the Gold Standard Toolkit.
102 See Paragraph VII.a of the Gold Standard Requirements.
103 Many stakeholders in the international carbon market, such as the World Bank, were
however disappointed by the Commissions Proposal insofar as the use of CERs is so
far limited to the use of credits from projects initiated before 2012 or of projects
from least developed countries. See The World Bank (2008: 34).
83
84
119 According to the IPCC report the CO2 emissions of industrialised countries must be
reduced between 50% and 85% to ensure the highest probability of stabilising the
global temperature increase between 2 and 2.4 degrees Celsius above pre-industrial
levels. See IPCC (2007: 15).
120 European Commission, COM (2006) 725.
121 Wara (2008), Wara et. al., (2008), Lohmann (2008), Schneider (2007), Michaelowa
(2007), Pearson (2006).
122 Greenpeace (2008), WWF (2008), See European Parliament (2008). draft Hassi
Report, cited above.
123 Oral response of the Commission staff member Jrgen Salay at the hearing of the
European Parliament on the Hassi Report in June 2008. See also Salay (2008).
124 A similar proposal is made by Satu Hassi in her draft report on Effort-Sharing, where
she argues for limiting the use of Kyoto units and other international offsets to
projects on renewable energies and energy efficiency and discounting the credits
generated by 50%. See European Parliament (2008), draft Hassi Report, cited
above.
125 See for instance Wara et. al., (2008), Schneider (2007).
126 Hampton (2007 :10).
127 The term additionality in this context means that CDM project must lead to emission
reductions which would not have occurred in the absence of the project.
128 Michaelowa et. al., (2008), Michaelowa (2007), Purohit et. al., (2007), Michaelowa
et. al., (2007), Willis et. al., (2006).
129 See Driesen (2006), Willis et. al., (2006).
130 See WWF (2008).
131 See Ott et. al., (2008: 93). The claim of developing countries to receive funds and
help from industrialised countries is based on the fact that they have emitted less
greenhouse gases and thus have less responsibility for climate change than
industrialised countries. Moreover, they are less able to finance emissions reductions.
See table of per capita emissions in Neuhoff (2008: 60).
132 See Michaelowa (2004: 3).
133 See Hgstad Flm (2007), Michaelowa (2004: 4).
134 IPCC (2007: 15).
135 The term additional means that the projects do not lead to real emissions
reductions, which would have occurred in the absence of the project. See Schneider
(2007), Wara (2008), Wara et. al., (2008), Michaelowa (2007).
136 Sterk (2007).
85
4
Links between European Emissions
Trading and CDM Credits for
Renewable Energy and Energy
Efficiency Projects
David M. Driesen*
This article asks whether the European Unions (EU) Emissions
Trading Scheme has encouraged investment in renewable energy
and energy efficiency projects in developing countries. So far, it
has produced very little investment in either in spite of the EU's
decision to allow credits for projects undertaken in developing
countries through the Kyoto Protocols Clean Development
Mechanism. This may reflect the relatively high cost of renewable
energy and the awkwardness of assessing the additionality of
energy efficiency projects. While the literature generally
associates emissions trading with innovation, emissions trading
does not encourage innovation with high short term costs, even
when such innovation has strong positive spillover effects.
University professor, Syracuse University College of law, E. I. white hall Syracuse, NY. 13244-1030.
E-mail: ddriesen@law.syr.edu
86
87
Improved energy efficiency decreases the need to burn fossil fuels and
thereby decreases the emissions associated with that burning. Thus, enhanced
energy efficiency comports with a view of sustainable development as linked to
reducing the throughput of materials and pollution needed to adequately support
a good life. 5
Increased reliance upon renewable energy is even more crucial to
sustainable development. Fossil fuels constitute non-renewable resources. If the
present generation exhausts these resources it will leave nothing for future
generation, thereby raising an inter-generational equity issue. 6 Sustainable
development will require increased consumption and energy use in developing
countries in order to meet the basic needs of very large populations of people.
To the extent this growth comes from increased use of fossil fuels, it will create
serious long-term and short term health and environmental hazards that will
undermine the goal of adequately meeting peoples basic need for a healthful
life with adequate environmental quality. 7
The drafters of the Kyoto Protocol created the CDM, in part to meet the
need for sustainable development. 8 And the European Parliament cited the
potential of European demands for credits to aid in achieving sustainable
development as a reason to allow use of credits from CDM projects to satisfy the
obligations of European polluters regulated under the ETS. 9 Therefore, an
evaluation of the CDMs capacity to move developing countries away from fossil
fuels provides one measure of CDMs success as an instrument of sustainable
development.
Furthermore, developing country success in moving away from a fossil fuel
basis for economic development would facilitate evolution of an adequate
climate change regime. The Kyoto Protocol constitutes a first step toward meeting
the Framework Conventions goal of avoiding dangerous interference with the
climate. While the continuation of business as usual in many countries has
already rendered this goal impossible to meet, the Kyoto Protocol will prove a
partial success if it begins an evolution significantly ameliorating climate change
dangers. Developing countries are unlikely to commit to meaningful cuts in
greenhouse gas emissions; unless they come to believe that a sustainable path of
reducing dependence on fossil fuels is a viable approach. The cost of renewable
energy has fallen as its use has increased. 10 Many renewable energy options,
however, remain much more costly than fossil fuel options. More deployment of
88
currently expensive renewable energy will increase learning by doing and drop
the price, thus making a path away from fossil fuels attractive. If developing
countries do not commit to significant cuts in emissions, prospects for meeting
long-term goals for ameliorating climate change are bleak. Hence, the question
of whether the European trading program will interact with CDM to increase
deployment of renewables and realization of energy efficiency matters greatly to
the future of climate change policy and sustainable development more generally.
89
Thus, they have less incentive to innovate than they would have under a
comparably designed traditional regulation, which would require reductions from
all regulated sources.
The assumption that trading produces innovation conflicts with the induced
innovation hypothesis that economists frequently employ to analyze
innovation. 21 This hypothesis assumes that necessity is the mother invention i.e.,
that firms will tend to innovate when the cost of employing conventional
approaches is high. 22 But trading lowers the cost of employing conventional
approaches by allowing polluters to shift reduction obligations to the facilities
with the lowest compliance costs. The induced innovation hypothesis would
therefore suggest that trading does not encourage more innovation than
comparable performance standards without trading. 23
The Kyoto mechanisms serve the Framework Conventions goal of
encouraging cost effectiveness. 24 They create incentives for polluting facilities (or
countries) to purchase credits reflecting the cheapest possible approaches to
pollution control. This poses an issue, because the cheapest current emission
reduction options may not coincide with those offering the greatest long-term
environmental benefits or even the lowest longterm economic costs. 25 For
example, even if massive investment in deploying solar technology or fuel cells
would bring prices down to very low levels over time and provide enormous
environmental benefits (less smog, climate change, coal mining, oil drilling, and
oil spills), emissions trading will not make such investments economically rational
unless the current costs of deploying solar power or fuel cells is less than that of
other emission decreasing options.
The emissions trading literature tends to create an image of trading as
magic, rather than as a type of regulatory program. 26 Trading encourages
buyers to avoid making expensive local reductions by purchasing as many credits
as they need to meet regulatory obligations, no more. 27 And it encourages them
to buy the cheapest available credits to meet these targets. This means that the
sellers can only sell as many cheap credits as the buyers need, and cannot sell
credits costing more to generate than the cheapest emission reductions available
in the program.
90
91
Directive, however, left the choice of targets to national governments within the
European Union, subject to some supervision by the European Commission. 34 A
recent study commissioned by the World Wildlife Fund has found that the caps of
many countries for phase one demand insufficient reductions to change business
as usual or adequately contribute to meeting Kyoto targets. 35 This implies weak
demand for CDM credits.
While the 2003 Directive followed the European Commission Proposal in
targeting a narrow sector and leaving reduction decisions largely to national
governments, it departed from the proposal by enlarging the possible sources of
credits. First, it allows credits for projects that reduce any one of six greenhouse
gases, including some, such as methane, that usually are very difficult to
monitor. 36 Second, it opens up the possibility of negotiating mutual recognition
of credits with non-EU trading programs. 37 Finally, it envisages some use of CDM
and joint implementation credits, but leaves the details to subsequent
elaboration. 38
The European Parliament amended the 2003 Directive in 2004, largely in
order to address the linkages between the ETS and the Kyoto mechanisms. 39 This
Linking Directive sought to increase the diversity of low-cost compliance
options while safeguarding the environmental integrity of the communitys
trading scheme. 40 It opined that this linkage would increase demand for CDM
credits and thereby provide aid to developing countries . . . in achieving their
sustainable development goals. 41 Accordingly, it authorized use of credits from
CDM projects, called Certified Emission Reductions (CERs) beginning in 2005. 42
But the Directive punts on the vital issue of the extent to which operators
may rely upon CERs to fulfill their obligations under the Directive. It allows each
Member State to authorize regulated sources to satisfy a specified percentage
of their emission reduction obligations through the purchase of CERs. 43 The
Linking Directive also suggested that the percentage should be small by requiring
compliance with the Kyoto Protocols supplementarity obligation, the obligation
to use credits only to supplement domestic compliance efforts. 44 But in the same
paragraph, it stated that domestic action will thus constitute a significant
element of the effort made, which suggests wider use of CERs, since domestic
action can remain a significant element even if a small majority of credits
92
comes from CERs. 45 Thus, a crucial paragraph about the extent of reliance on
CERs looks like an effort to paper over policy differences on the role of CERs and
accordingly yields vague guidance. It tracks fairly similar language found in the
Marrakech Accords to the Kyoto Protocol. 46 The European Parliament clearly
decided, however, to prohibit credits for projects involving land use or nuclear
power. 47 The Linking Directive also discourages the use of large hydropower
credits by requiring member states to ensure that relevant international criteria
will be respected when approving use of these CERs. 48 Hence, the total
demand for CERs will be limited by the percentages allocated for CERs in
national trading plans under the ETS Directive and by several discrete limitations
on problematic projects.
The supplementary concept, then, limits the maximum potential demand for
CDM and JI credits. The amount of the limitation depends upon the volume of
demand for credits. The demand for credits, in turn, depends on the amount
reductions required in the trading scheme and the percentage of reductions
allowed for CER. Individual countries, not the EU, make the decisions about
precisely how much reduction to demand in the trading program and what
percentage of that reduction may come from CERs.
The World Bank has estimated that the annual average demand for all Kyoto
credits (including AAUS, CDM, and JI) at 600 to 1150 MtCO2e. 49 The ETS regulates
sectors representing 46% of European CO2 emissions. 50 Accordingly, NATSOURCE
has estimated that the European Emission Trading Scheme will generate demand
for credits of 110 MtCO2ee. 51 This amount might prove less than the demand
generated by governments and private parties outside of the trading scheme. 52 The
NATSOURCE estimate, however, represents total demand for JI and CDM credits,
not CDM alone (the topic of this article). Nevertheless, this number represents a
reasonable estimate of total potential ETS demand for CDM credits.
These numbers, however, are subject to some caveats. As of this writing the
National Allocation Plans do not include firm targets for 2012 or firm numbers
limiting the use of credits from the project-based mechanisms for phase II of the
ETS. Weak targets will lower demand. Conversely stronger targets will increase
demand. Final decisions about what percentages of project based credits to
allow into the system will also influence demand emanating from the ETS.
93
94
CDM has done a magnificent job of encouraging renewable energy. After all, 19
of the 35 registered projects as of November 1, 2005, were renewable
projects. 55
Figure 1: Registered Projects # of Projects Based on Type (as of Nov. 1, 2005)
But examining the projects from the more meaningful perspective of how
many CERs different types of projects generate yields a very different picture.
Approved renewable energy projects CDM are expected to generate only. 7
MtCO2e over the lifetime of the approved projects.
Registered
Projects: Type
# of Projects
(as of 11/22/05)
% of CERs /
Yr
Renewables
19
638,965
8%
Energy Efficiency
6,580
0%
Large Hydro
104,155
1%
Non-Renewables
12
7,072,276
90%
Total
35
7,821,976
100%
95
It also constitutes less than 1% of the European potential demand for project
mechanisms credit. As companies must plan to meet the phase one limits of the
ETS in the 2005-2007 time period, the current supply could seriously limit the
maximum potential European finance of sustainable development supporting
CDMs in phase one.
Renewables projects in the pipeline could expand this supply. If all of these
projects are approved, renewable project would generate 15% of the total credits.
CER Pipeline % of CERs Generated Per Year (Excluding Registered Projects)
96
So far, only one small energy efficiency project has received certification.
The pipeline contains very few energy efficiency projects as well.
Ben Pearson has suggested several reasons why the CDM program has not
generated a large supply of renewable energy credits. 56 The main reason is that
renewable energy often costs more than other approaches to generating credits.
Consequently, CDM developers have favored projects that contribute little or
nothing to meeting sustainable development goals, but efficiently provide large
volumes of cheap credits.
Typically, these projects capture or destroy gases with high global warming
potential, such as methane and HFC-23. 57 Project developers understand that
buyers maximizing cost effectiveness will want the cheapest credits available, not
necessarily those that deliver the broadest and most important long-term
environmental, economic, and social benefits.
Energy efficiency projects often pay for themselves, but that means that
honest oversight will tend to make life difficult for energy efficiency projects.
Energy efficiency has terrific potential for cheap reductions in greenhouse gases.
But energy efficiency measures typically involve many low volume steps, each
generating a small amount of reductions in greenhouse gases indirectly, by
lessening demand for electricity generated by fossil fuels. This makes such
projects unattractive for prospective purchasers of credits. In addition, because
these projects often pay for themselves by generating reduced energy costs over
time, serious questions about whether a project is additional, and therefore
eligible to generate credits, should make it hard to get these projects approved.
Policy interventions, such as information programs to make people aware of the
opportunities for energy efficiency, taxes making carbon expensive, and
efficiency standards for cars, buildings, and appliances can help. But the CDM,
in the past, has generated project credits, not policy interventions. So, it is not
surprising that CDM developers have not done much with energy efficiency.
The Conference of the Parties meeting in Montreal in 2005, however,
attempted to increase the use of energy efficiency credits by authorizing credits
for efficiency projects forming part of a government program to increase
efficiency. 58 Assuring that such credits are truly additional will necessarily involve
a difficult inquiry into the motives of the policy-makers adopting energy efficiency
programs.
97
One would expect that renewable energy projects, while offering enormous
long term benefits, would present difficulties for developers seeking to quantify
reductions. Renewable energy projects do not directly reduce emissions, they add
energy with little or no added emissions. They reduce emissions indirectly, by
displacing more carbon intensive energy supply sources. Hence, estimating the
value of credits requires calculation of the amount of energy produced, the
associated emissions (if any), and the carbon emissions associated with the
energy sources displaced. While this is possible, especially with less innovative
projects that make a priori calculations of energy production reliable, it is more
complicated than calculating the value of credits from a project that simply
reduces the impacts of business as usual directly without starting down the path
of fundamental change. Again, trading, with its emphasis on a priori calculation
and low costs, does little to encourage renewable energy.
Non-compliance.
98
99
Conclusion
The goal of sustainable development is in some tension with the goal of short
term cost effectiveness. The sooner we face up to the tension between free
market liberalism and sustainable development, the better the chances for
effective climate change policy.
Endnotes
1
100
See WORKING GROUP III TO THE SECOND ASSESSMENT REPORT OF THE INTERGOVERNMENTAL
PANEL ON CLIMATE CHANGE, CLIMATE CHANGE 1995 ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL DIMENSIONS
OF CLIMATE CHANGE 241 (James P. Bruce et. al., eds., 1996) (noting that renewable
energy sources emit little carbon and that switching to renewables will reduce emissions).
Report of the Conference of the Parties on its Third Session, Kyoto Protocol to the UN
Framework Convention on Climate Change, 3rd Sess., pt. 2, Annex I, UN Doc.
FCCC/CP/1997/7 add.1, December 11, 1997, reprinted without certain technical
corrections in 37 I.L.M. 22 (1998) Art. II, 1(a)(i),(iv) [hereinafter Kyoto Protocol].
See Kyoto Protocol, supra note 3, Art. 12, Sec. 2 (describing achieving sustainable
development as part of the purpose of the clean development mechanism).
10
See, e.g., R. WISER ET. AL., LETTING THE SUN SHINE: AN EMPIRICAL EVALUATION OF
PHOTOVOLTAIC COST TRENDS IN CALIFORNIA (LBNL-59282, NREL/TP-620-39300 ) ii
(2006) (discussing a 25% decline in solar energy costs in California since 1998);
LESTER R. BROWN, PLAN B: RESCUING A PLANET UNDER STRESS AND A CIVILIZATION IN TROUBLE
158-59, 164 (2003) (discussing drastic decreases in wind and solar costs); Anthony
D. Owen, Renewable Energy: Externality Costs as Market Barriers, 34 Energy Policy
632, 634 (2006) (documenting sharp declines in the price of renewables between
1980 and 1995). Cf. MARK BOLLINGER & RYAN WISER, BALANCING COST AND RISK: THE
101
See generally Kysar, supra note 6, at 2114 (discussing the tendency to adapt
sustainability to fit the market liberalism framework).
12
13
See, Robert N. Stavins, Policy Instruments for Global Climate Change: How Can
Governments Address a Global Problem, 1997 U. CHI. LEGAL F. 293, 302-03; Robert
W. Hahn & Robert N. Stavins, Incentive- Based Environmental Regulation: A New Ear
for an Old Idea, 18 ECOLOGY L. Q. 1, 13 (1991); Bruce A. Ackerman & Richard B.
Stewart, Reforming Environmental Law: The Democratic Case for Market Incentives,
13 COLUM. J. ENVTL. L. 171, 183 (1988); Daniel J. Dudek & John Palmisano,
Emissions Trading: Why is this Thoroughbred Hobbled?, 13 COLUM. J. ENVTL. L. 217,
234-35 (1988).
14
See, e.g., David M. Driesen, Design, Trading, and Innovation, in MOVING TO MARKETS
IN ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION: LESSONS AFTER TWENTY YEARS OF EXPERIENCE (Jody
Freeman & Charles Kolstad eds. 2006) (forthcoming) [hereinafter, Driesen, Design];
Joel F. Bruneau, A Note On Permits, Standards, and Technological Innovation, 48
J. ENVTL. ECON. & MAN. 1192 (2004); Juan-Pablo Montero, Permits Standards, and
Technology Innovation, 44 J. ENVTL. ECON. &MAN. 23 (2002); Juan-Pablo Montero,
Market Structure and Environmental Innovation, 5 J. APPLIED ECON. 293 (2000); David
M. Driesen, Is Emissions Trading an Economic Incentive Program?: Replacing the
Command and Control/Economic Incentive Dichotomy, 55 WASH. & LEE L. REV. 289,
313-22, 325-38 (1998) [hereinafter, Driesen, Dichotomy]. See also David A.
Malueg, Emissions Trading Credit and the Incentive to Adopt New Abatement
Technology, 16 J. ENVTL. ECON. &MAN. 52 (1987); W.A. Magat, Pollution Control And
Technological Advance: A Dynamic Model of the Firm, 5 J. ENVTL. ECON. & MAN. 95 (1978).
15
16
A. DENNY ELLERMAN ET. AL.,MARKETS FOR CLEAN AIR: THE US ACID RAIN PROGRAM 130
(2000) (noting that the acid rain program did not produce greater reliance on
renewable energy).
17
See Margaret R. Taylor, Edward S. Rubin, and David A. Hounshell, Regulation as the
Mother of Innovation: The Case of SO2 Control, 27 LAW & POLY 348, 370 (2005).
Cf. David Popp, Pollution Control Innovations and the Clean Air Act of 1990, 22
102
J. POLY ANALYSIS &MGMT 641 (2003) (agreeing that command and control caused
more innovation than trading, but arguing that trading did better at encouraging
environmentally superior innovations).
18
19
See Adam B. Jaffe et. al., Environmental Policy and Technological Change, 22 ENVTL.
& RESOURCE ECON. 41, 51 (2002); Malueg, supra note 14, at 8-9 & n. 33.
20
See Malueg, supra note 14; Driesen, Dichotomy, supra note 14, at 334; DAVID
WALLACE, ENVIRONMENTAL POLICY AND INDUSTRIAL INNOVATION: STRATEGIES IN THE USA,
EUROPE, AND JAPAN 20 (1995) (explaining that the Malueg model casts doubt on the
claim that emissions trading necessarily spurs innovation); Chuhlo Jung et. al.,
Incentives for Advanced Pollution Abatement Technology at the Industry Level: An
Evaluation of Policy Alternatives, 30 J. ENVTL. ECON. & MAN. 95, 95 (1996)
(marketable permits may not provide greater incentives than standards, because
the incentive effects of marketable permits depend on whether firms are buyers or
sellers).
21
22
See Richard G. Newell et. al., The Induced Innovation Hypothesis and Energy-Saving
Technological Change, 114 Q. J. ECON. 941 (1999).
23
24
See Framework Convention, supra note 1, Art. 3, Sec. 3 (stating that measures to
combat climate change should be cost-effective).
25
See David M. Driesen, Free Lunch or Cheap Fix?: The Emissions Trading Idea and the
Climate Change Convention, 26 B.C. ENVTL. AFF. L. REV. 1, 44 (1998) (explaining this
point with a renewable energy example).
26
Cf. David M. Driesen, Markets are Not Magic, 20 ENVTL FORUM 19 (Nov.-Dec. 2003).
27
See Driesen, Dichotomy, supra note 14, at 324-25 (explaining why trading only
provides limited incentives for reductions).
28
See Council Directive 2003/87, 2003 O.J. (L 275) (EC) [hereinafter ETS Directive].
29
See Commission Proposal for a Directive of the European Parliament and Council
Establishing A Scheme for Greenhouse Gas Emission Allowance Trading Within the
Community and Amending Council Directive 96/61/EC, 2002 O.J. (C 075 E) 9.
30
See generally Brennan Van Dyke, Emissions Trading to Reduce Acid Deposition, 100
YALE L. J. 2707 (1991).
31
32
THE
AND
STRATEGY
103
33
34
35
SEE ILEX ENERGY CONSULTING, THE ENVIRONMENTAL EFFECTIVENESS OF THE EU ETS: ANALYSIS OF
CAPS: A FINAL REPORT TO WWF V-VI (2005).
36
See ETS Directive, supra note 28, Art. 3 (a), Art. 24.
37
38
39
40
Id., L 338/18.
41
Id.
42
43
44
Id. 338/19 (par. 6); Kyoto Protocol, supra note 3, Art. 6, Sec. 1(d).
45
46
See Decision 15/CP.7, Principles, nature and scope of the Mechanisms Pursuant to
Articles 6, 12, and 17, of the Kyoto Protocol, FCCC/CP/2001/13/Add.2, at 2
(2001).
47
See Linking Directive, supra note 9, 2 (adding Art. 11a to the 2003 Directive).
48
Id., 2(b)(6).
49
See E. Haites & S. Seres, Estimating Market Potential for the Clean Development
Mechanism: Review of Models and Lessons Learned, PCFPLUS REPORT 19 (2004).
50
51
Gernot Klepper & Sonja Peterson, Emissions Trading, CDM, JI, and More- The
Climate Change Strategy of the EU 11 (FEEM Working Paper No. 55.05, April
2005). This estimate might be off by 65 MtCO2e in either direction. Id.
52
See id.
53
FRANCK LECOCQ & KARAN CAPOOR, STATE AND TRENDS OF THE CARBON MARKET 2005, at 26
(2005), available at http://www.ieta.org/ieta/www/pages/getfile.php?docID=899.
54
Frank Lecocq, State and Trends of the Carbon Market 2005 (Executive Summary),
CARBON MARKET UPDATE 10, 11 (September, 2005) (explaining that the amount of
AAU from Russia and the Ukraine are a key uncertainty).
104
55
56
57
Id. at 12. For a critique of a major HFC-23 project see Newest Biggest Deal, DOWN
TO EARTH (November 15, 2005), available at http://www.downtoearth.org.in/cover.asp?
foldername=20051115&filename=anal&sid=1&sec_id=7 (last visited November 11,
2005). This Article estimates that HFC-23 projects account for 24% of all CERs sold.
58
59
See David M. Driesen & Shubha Ghosh, The Functions of Transaction Costs:
Rethinking Transaction Cost Minimization in a World of Friction, 47 ARIIZONA L. REV.
61, 92-98 (2005) (discussing the tension between the impetus to reduce transaction
costs to encourage trading and the need to preserve effective government oversight
to protect environmental quality from poor quality trades).
60
See id. at 93-94 (explaining why both buyers and sellers of pollution credits share
incentives to exaggerate the value of traded reductions).
61
62
Id. at 92-94.
5
Linking Community Forestry Projects in
India with International Carbon
Markets: Opportunities and Constraints
Rohit Jindal* and Shailesh Nagar**
The authors highlight the fact that India would benefit
tremendously through community forestry projects and the local
communities could accrue benefits by selling carbon sequestered
by these projects in Kyoto-based markets. However they find that
though India is eligible for conducting its business there is no
awareness among the public to take up such initiatives. In order
to prove that India has the potential to take up such projects he
conducted research in two prominent Non-Government
Organizations (NGOs) that have well established forestry
projects Seva Mandir and Foundation for Ecological Security.
They calculate the carbon sequestration potential for these two
NGOs, and identified the likely challenges and areas of
concern. The potential gains that the local communities may
accrue from sale of carbon credits. Despite all these efforts the
authors find that these projects are not taking off as expected,
*
**
Phd candidate Michiagn State University. Research Associate World Agroforestry Centre and Sokoine
University of Agriculture, Morogoro, Tanzania. E-mail: Jindalro@msu.edu
Senior Project Officer at Foundation for Ecological Security. E-mail: shailashnagar@gmail.com
106
due to delayed approval of land use. This is despite the fact that
there is huge demand in the market as the first commitment
period for mitigating emissions by the parties under Kyoto is
coming to an end by 2012. In such circumstances these projects
may need alternate avenues for selling carbon sequestration
credits, and one such viable market is the Chicago Climate
Exchange. CCX is the only largest carbon credit market that
takes up community forestry projects. Thus, India with all the
potential by joining hands with CCX may gain huge profits in
the carbon markets and also expand its supply base by linking
up with other member nations.
1. Introduction
Community forestry projects have long been implemented in India with an aim to
strengthen rural livelihoods by improving local natural resource base. Until now,
the major benefits from these projects were in the form of timber and NonTimber Forest Products (NTFPs) for the local communities. However, with the
ratification of the Kyoto Protocol 1 in 2005, there has been a growing expectation
that additional benefits could accrue by selling carbon sequestered by these
projects in Kyoto-based markets (Poffenberger et. al., 2001). Similarly, many
new forestry projects were initiated with the express objective of selling carbon
credits in international markets. Examples include TIST, Tamil Nadu 2 and Plan
Vivo based Women for Sustainable Development, Karnataka (FAO, 2004).
However, due to long delays in approval of land use sequestration projects, 3 the
Kyoto-based market for carbon sequestration credits hasnt really taken off (IISD,
2006). With the first commitment period under Kyoto ending in 2012, many of
these projects may need alternate avenues for selling carbon sequestration
credits. One viable market that has grown in recent years is the voluntary
emission reduction programs, particularly the Chicago Climate Exchange. 4
The Chicago Climate Exchange (CCX) was set up in 2003 to provide an
opportunity to business houses and other large entities to voluntarily reduce their
carbon emissions. Members can trade in carbon credits to fulfill their yearly
107
emission reduction targets. CCX has been growing rapidly; in 2005 alone, CCX
traded 1.43 million tons of carbon dioxide (tCO2) worth US$ 2.8 million, making
it the third largest carbon market in the world (Point Carbon, 2006). This
included trade in carbon sequestration credits from land use projects. Since the
two larger carbon markets European Union Emission Trading System and New
South Wales GHG Abatement Scheme are yet to trade in carbon sequestration
credits from forestry projects, CCX probably represents the single largest market
for such credits. This is a welcome opportunity for community forestry projects in
India which can potentially tap into this growing market for carbon credits.
Likewise, CCX may also gain from linking up with these projects and expanding
its supply base.
However, most researchers and policy makers in India appear to be
unaware of CCX or of other voluntary programs that have come up in different
parts of the world. Review of recently published literature suggests there are
several studies in India that look at eligibility conditions for selling carbon credits
in Kyoto markets, but none that explores the same for CCX or for any other
voluntary market. What are the main requirements for selling carbon credits in
these markets? Do community forestry projects sequester enough carbon to sell
in these markets and what price schedules could they expect? Similarly, till date,
these voluntary markets have restricted their supply of carbon credits to certain
geographic regions. For example, CCX mainly meets its demand for carbon
sequestration credits from farmers in the US. With the increase in demand for
carbon credits, these markets will need to know more about potential suppliers
elsewhere. Who are these suppliers? How many carbon credits can they sell and
at what price? Do these suppliers have a long-term commitment to participate in
the carbon market?
This article attempts to answer some of these questions from the perspective
of community forestry projects in India. For preserving clarity in discussions and
with a view towards practical applicability, the article mainly considers the case
for selling carbon credits on the CCX. However, wherever necessary, the article
also considers broader issues and areas of concern. It is based on an extensive
research with two prominent Non-Government Organizations (NGOs) in India
that have well established forestry projects Seva Mandir and Foundation for
Ecological Security.
108
Research data were collected through field visits to selected project sites,
followed by open-ended discussions with community representatives, respective
NGO staff, and senior officials of the state Forest Department. Secondary data
sources consisted of recent reports on carbon markets, particularly CCX, and
details on relevant protocols for international carbon sequestration projects.
Carbon sequestration potential for the two NGOs was calculated on the basis of
their in-house monitoring studies and some recent literature on biomass
accumulation rates in India. Finally, critical challenges and areas of concern
were identified through a stakeholder workshop in Udaipur, India.
The rest of the article is organized as follows: the next Section provides
useful information on forestry interventions of the two NGOs. This is followed
by an estimation of annual carbon sequestration potential of these forestry
projects and a review additionality, leakage, permanence, and monitoring
issues to determine the relative feasibility of selling carbon sequestration credits
on CCX. Section four identifies potential gains for local communities from sale
of carbon credits. The article ends with a discussion on important areas of
concern such as food security and suggests some modifications in the present
set up of rules.
109
unable to fulfill local needs (Seva Mandir, 2006). Productivity is restored through
tree plantations and soil and water conservation measures. Seva Mandirs
forestry interventions that can earn carbon sequestration credits include:
i.
ii.
iii.
110
ii.
iii.
111
ii.
iii.
iv.
If the above rules are satisfied, the two forestry projects can potentially sell
carbon offsets through CCX on the basis of annual increase in the above-ground
living biomass. But first, an estimation of carbon sequestered by them.
112
projects are thus designated on the basis of their annual carbon sequestration
potential; projects that sequester less than 2000 tCO2 per annum as small,
between 2000 t CO2 and 12,500 tCO2 per annum as medium, and with more
than 12,500 t CO2 per annum as large forestation projects. Size determines
monitoring requirements for each project, as discussed below.
Detailed carbon analysis of the two projects was difficult due to time and
resource constraints; both NGOs covered large number of project sites that were
seldom contiguous. These sites varied with species mix, soil characteristics, mix of
planted versus natural regenerating trees, and eventual survival rates of the
trees. Although a high proportion of the project sites was believed to be
managed in a sustainable manner, working out the exact percentage required
an extensive survey in the area. Finally, the specific annual off take in the form of
grass harvests, fuelwood and other NTFPs was not known across different sites.
The present study therefore relied on recent estimates of biomass accumulations
in somewhat similar agro-ecological conditions in India, to arrive at mean values
of carbon sequestration for the two selected projects.
Poffenberger et. al., (2002) estimate that the above-ground mean annual
growth in degraded forests from protection and plantation was 3 tons C/ha
(carbon per hectare). 12 Similarly, Murali et. al., (2002) quote Seebauer (1992) to
report a national mean annual increment (MAI) of 3.6 tons C/ha for plantations.
Ashish et. al., (2006) arrive at a higher estimate of 5.24 tons C/ha for Rajasthan,
but their sample plots also include primary forests under protection, which tend
to add an upward skew to their calculations. In comparison, fewer estimates
were available for plantations on revenue or panchayat lands. A relevant study
was found to be conducted by FES itself, which reported an MAI of 1 tons C/ha
to 3 tons C/ha (Mondal et. al., 2005). Annual carbon sequestration is usually
taken as 0.5 times the MAI (Poffenberger et. al., 2002). By taking lower bounds
of the above estimates (to account for various uncertainties described above), the
present study estimates that the current carbon sequestration potential of all
forestry interventions taken together for Seva Mandir and FES is 16,421 tCO2 per
annum and 77,245 tCO2 per annum, respectively (see table 1 below; for details
see annex 1).
113
FES
Total
7,878
33,415
41,293
8,950
42,096
51,046
16,424
77,245
93,669
$65,697
$308,981
$374,678
114
115
116
As table 1 shows, the total financial value of carbon sequestration credits from
FES and Seva Mandirs forestry projects on CCX is $374,678 per annum.
Admittedly, not all of this financial value is immediately realizable, as the total
availability of carbon sequestration credits from the two projects (93,669
tCO2/annum) is much more than the current demand on CCX. In fact, only a small
percentage of these carbon credits may actually find buyers in international markets.
However, even small sales of carbon credits will generate additional incomes for
local communities, while creating opportunities for bigger sales in the future. These
incomes will be useful in extending local conservation efforts, in reducing livelihood
pressure on forests and can provide for sustenance needs of many poor families.
For example, FES is implementing Joint Forest Management program in
Chitravas and Rawach villages, in district Rajsam and (Rajasthan). Under this
program, the local community obtained an approval from the state forest
department to manage 276 ha of forestland. Since 2002, FES has helped the
community construct a stone fence around this forest and in planting more than
50,000 trees of indigenous species. These plantations are managed by the
village forest protection committee, which has banned all timber felling and
allows for only manual cutting of grass and for collection of dead and decaying
branches as firewood. The current carbon sequestration potential of this forestry
initiative is estimated to be 1,266.2 t CO2 per annum, with a financial value of
$5,064.8 per annum (or Rs.227,907 in the local currency). Discussions with
community representatives revealed that this is a significant amount of money. If
annual carbon payments were available to them, community members will have
an enhanced economic incentive to protect these plantations and in taking up
more conservation efforts. Since most farmers in the area were very poor, carbon
payments will also provide them with additional sources of income.
117
118
119
120
121
6. Conclusion
Seva Mandir and FES can potentially sell carbon sequestration credits on the
CCX and generate additional incomes for their local communities. Establishing a
relationship with CCX may in fact open avenues for carbon trading with other
international players. A viable strategy in this regard will be to start with simple
payment arrangements on small contiguous sites that are easy to monitor and
administer. Experience gained during these pilot projects may be handy in
expanding the scale of operations when international demand for carbon
sequestration credits rises further. Such performance-based payments may also
ensure that local communities have a long-term stake in conserving these
plantations.
On their part, the carbon markets will need to look at integrated role of
forests. Carbon payments can provide economic incentives to local communities
for conserving forests and other valuable natural resources. However, these
communities also depend on the same resources for their immediate sustenance
needs. Achieving a balance between these immediate needs and the long-term
priorities of the global society can truly promote sustainable solutions to global
warming.
122
Annex 1
Calculation of Current Annual Carbon Sequestration from
Forestry Interventions of Seva Mandir and FES, India
1.
2.
3.
Result from (2) is multiplied with 3.67 to get annual carbon sequestration in
terms of tCO2/ha.
4.
= 27,628 ha
= 77,245.3 tCO2/annum
= 7,163 ha
123
= 16,424.2 tCO2/annum
Acknowledgement
Acknowledgements to Michigan Agricultural Experiment Station for funding this study.
Thanks to the respective staff at FES and Seva Mandir for providing field support and
for participating in the brainstorming workshop at Udaipur. Authors also express
gratitude for villagers of Chitrwaas, Rawach, and Nayakheda for sharing their views on
implications of a carbon payment system. The opinions expressed here are those of
authors alone and do not necessarily represent views of respective organizations.
References
Aggarwal, A., R.S. Sharma, B. Suthar, and K. Kunwar. 2006. An ecological assessment of
greening of Aravali mountain through Joint Forest Management in Rajasthan, India.
International Journal of Environment and Sustainable Development. Vol.5 No.1, pp. 35-45.
FAO. 2004. A review of carbon sequestration projects. Food and Agriculture Organization
of the United Nations, Rome. AGL/MISC/37/2004.
FES. 2005. Annual Report 2004-05. Foundation for Ecological Security, Anand, India.
IISD. 2006. Chapter 2: Options for Fostering the Development Dividend, in Realizing the
Development Dividend: Making the CDM work for Developing Countries (Phase II).
International Institute for Sustainable Development. Draft Paper for the meeting of the Expert
Task Force of the IISD Development Dividend Project. Vancouver, March 27-28, 2006.
Jindal, R., B. Swallow, and J. Kerr. 2006. Status of carbon sequestration projects in Africa:
Potential benefits and challenges to scaling up. WP 26, World Agroforestry Centre, Nairobi.
Kerr, John, C. Foley, K. Chung, and R. Jindal. 2006 (in press). Sustainable Development in the
Clean Development Mechanism: Constraints and Opportunities. Journal of Sustainable Forestry.
Kerr, J., D. Marothia, K. Singh, C. Ramasamy, and W. Bentley (eds.). 1997. Natural
Resource Economics: Concepts and Applications to India. New Delhi: Oxford and IBH.
Mondal, D., S. Singh, and J.V. Dhameliya. 2005. Assessing the value of our forests:
Quantification and valuation of revegetation efforts. Paper submitted for the Fourth Biennial
Conference of the Indian Society for Ecological Economics (INSEE), Mumbai, June 3-4, 2005.
Murali, K.S., Indu K. Murthy, N.H. Ravindranath. 2002. Joint forest management in India and its
ecological impacts. Environmental Management and Health. Vol. 13, No. 5, 2002 pp. 512-528.
124
Poffenberger, M., E. DSilva, N.H. Ravindranath, U. Pingle, I. Murthy, and A. Tuttle. 2002.
The Clean Development Mechanism and village-based forest restoration. A case study from
Adilabad district, Andhra Pradesh, India. Community Forestry International, California, USA.
Poffenberger, M. (ed.), N.H. Ravindranath, D.N. Pandey, I.K. Murthy, R. Bist, and D. Jain.
2001. Communities & Climate Change: The Clean Development Mechanism and Villagebased forest restoration in central India. A case study from Harda Forest Division, Madhya
Pradesh, India. Community Forestry International and the Indian Institute of Forest
Management.
Point Carbon. 2006. Carbon 2006. Hasselknippe, H. and K. Roine eds. (www.pointcarbon.com)
Ravindranath, N.H., P.Sudha, and S. Rao. 2001. Forestry for sustainable biomass
production and carbon sequestration in India. Mitigation and adaptation strategies for
global change. 6: 233-256, 2001. Kluwer Academic Publishers, the Netherlands.
Rosa, H., S. Kandell, and L. Dimas. 2003. Compensation for Environmental Services and
Rural Communities: Lessons from the Americas and Key Issues for Strengthening
Community Strategies. PRISMA, El Salvador. (www.prisma.org.sv)
Seebauer, M. 1992. Review of Social Forestry Programs in India. GWB Gesselschaft fr
Walderhaltung und Waldbewirtschaftung GmbH, Michelstadt.
Seva Mandir. 2005. Annual Report: 2004-2005. Udaipur, India.
Seva Mandir. 2006. Seva Mandir: 5th Comprehensive Plan 2006-2009. Udaipur, India.
Smith, J., and S. Scherr. 2003. Capturing the Value of Forest Carbon for Local
Livelihoods. World Development. 31 (12), pp 2143 2160.
UNEP. 2004. CDM Information and Guidebook. Second edition. Edited by Myung- Kyoon
Lee. Contrbutors J. Fenhann, K. Halsnaes, R. Pacudan, and A. Olhoff. UNEP Riso Centre
on Energy, Climate and Sustainable Development, Riso National Laboratory, Denmark.
UNFCCC. 2003. Caring for Climate: A Guide to Climate Change Convention and the yoto
Protocol. United Nations Framework on Climate Change Convention (UNFCCC), Bonn,
Germany. (http://unfccc.int/resource/cfc-guide.pdf)
Endnotes
1
Kyoto Protocol was ratified in 2005 to reduce emission of greenhouse gases into the
atmosphere. Under its Clean Development Mechanism, developing countries can
sell carbon sequestered by their forests to industrialized countries as carbon credits
or carbon offsets. These are units of carbon dioxide that have been absorbed by
forests from the atmosphere (UNFCCC, 2003).
Called the LULUCF sector, i.e. land use, land use change and forestry.
125
Other examples include New South Wales Greenhouse gas Abatement Scheme in
Australia.
Apart from privately owned lands, there exist several kinds of common lands in
Indian villages. Prominent among these are revenue lands (owned by the
government revenue department), forestlands (owned by the state forest
department), and panchayat grazing lands (revenue department owns these lands,
but the village panchayats are the custodians). For more details on different property
regimes in India, see Kerr et. al., (1997).
CCX allows for trading in carbon sequestration credits from afforestation and
reforestation activities initiated only after 1990 on previously un-forested lands.
These are Gujarat, Rajasthan, Orissa, Madhya Pradesh, Andhra Pradesh, Karnataka
and Uttaranchal. More details on FES are available on www.fes.org.in
10
It is relevant to note that Seva Mandir too has a watershed development program,
much similar to FESs approach. However, the area covered under forestry subcomponent of Seva Mandirs watershed work is reported separately under different
forestry heads and is thus included in the above estimates.
11
12
13
14
In case of FES, this would cover different geographic regions that are far apart from
each other.
15
Acknowledgements to Esther Duflo at MIT for suggesting this innovative, yet costeffective means to verify additionality. If accepted, this methodology may help in
reducing transaction costs associated with carbon sequestration projects.
16
Indeed, the small holder tree plantation project (TIST), based in India and Tanzania
already uses hand help GPS to monitor their carbon plantations before selling
carbon credits in international markets. For more details see www.tist.org
17
Important to note that CCX already allows for trading in soil carbon, but it is
restricted to grasslands and conservation easements in US.
6
The Commerce Clause Meets
Environmental Protection: The
Compensatory Tax Doctrine as a
Defense of Potential Regional
Carbon Dioxide Regulation
Heddy Bolster*
On December 20, 2005 seven northeastern states announced an
agreement to implement the Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative
(RGGI), in an effort to reduce greenhouse gas pollution. In
doing so, those states formally committed to implementing the
first market-based regulatory program for carbon dioxide
emissions trading in the United States. When electricity suppliers
begin to import power from outside the regulated region in order
to avoid the constraints of the emissions cap, resulting in little or
no net decrease in overall emissions associated with the power
consumed inside the region the movement of emissions
associated with power consumed inside the region is called
leakage. The regulatory approaches available to RGGI to fight
the problem of leakage may be subject to attack as violations of
*
Professor of law, Boston College of law, USA. 262 Danforth St. Portland me 04102, USA.
E-mail: mail: hdb8@hayoo.com
2006 Boston College Law review. This article was originally published in Boston College Law Review,
Vol. 47 (737). Reprinted with permission.
Source: www.bc.edu
127
Introduction
On December 20, 2005, seven northeastern states signed an agreement to
implement the Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative (RGGI) in an effort to
reduce greenhouse gas pollution from power plants. 1 This agreement marked
the first formal commitment to implementing a market-based trading program
for carbon dioxide (CO2) emissions in the United States. 2 In March 2006,
Californias Environmental Protection Agency released a report summarizing the
emissions trading program options that the state was exploring for regulating
greenhouse gas emissions. 3 Both the RGGI agreement and the California report,
however, identify a particular concern regarding regional cap-and-trade
emissions programs that of leakage. 4
Leakage the movement of emissions from regulated to unregulated
regions to avoid caps on emissions can occur when a cap-and-trade scheme is
implemented on a state or regional, rather than national, level. 5 Electricity
128
suppliers begin to import power from outside the regulated region to avoid the
constraints of the emissions cap, resulting in little or no net decrease in overall
emissions associated with the power consumed inside the region. 6 To combat
this problem, the RGGI states and California could limit emissions associated
with energy imported into the region. 7 Because limiting interstate imports places
burdens on the trade of electricity, however, this approach may be subject to
attack under the Interstate Commerce Clause of the US Constitution. 8
This article explores the possibility of applying the concepts embodied in the
compensatory tax doctrine to defend a regulatory scheme that might be
employed to combat leakage, focusing on RGGI as the model scheme. 9 The
compensatory tax doctrine stands for the principle that even if a state regulation
burdens interstate commerce, it may survive constitutional scrutiny if it is a
compensatory tax designed merely to make interstate commerce bear a burden
already borne by intrastate commerce. 10 Any regulation the RGGI states adopt to
address leakage will necessarily impose burdens on interstate commerce
because they will have to limit, either directly or indirectly, electricity imports from
out of state. 11 This article argues that the RGGI states, and any reviewing court,
should draw on compensatory tax doctrine principles in crafting, and supporting,
a regulation that imposes burdens on imported electricity. 12
Part I of this article provides an introduction to the RGGI program and the
particular problem of leakage. 13 Part II introduces the potential legal challenges
to the program based on the Commerce Clause of the US Constitution, and
explores the compensatory tax doctrine as developed by the US Supreme
Court. 14 Part III analyzes the application of Commerce Clause jurisprudence and
the compensatory tax doctrine to the alternatives that RGGI may use to combat
the problem of leakage and evaluates the likely success of those options. 15 Part
III concludes that although the compensatory tax doctrine may not be directly
applicable to the regulation of emissions leakage, the legal principles it
embodies should be used to uphold the regulation. 16 In addition, if RGGI can
overcome the legal and political obstacles in its path, it may serve as an effective
experiment in the regulation of CO2 emissions and eventually could be a
template for a national regulatory program aimed at slowing global warming. 17
129
130
allowances increases, the market price for allowances also will increase. 33 Dirtier
facilities then face the choice of either reducing emissions or purchasing
allowances because the net emissions from the region cannot exceed the cap. 34
This approach gives facilities flexibility not available to them under traditional
command and control regulations; each facility can design its own compliance
strategy based on economic efficiency and adjust its strategy over time in
response to changes in technology and the market. 35 In fact, the federal
government used a cap-and-trade program to regulate the emissions that cause
acid rain largely because of the flexibility the approach offers. 36
Because the federal government has not implemented a national regulatory
program for CO2 emissions, the northeastern states, through RGGI, may act
without fear of preemption by existing federal law. 37 This does not mean,
however, that RGGI lacks legal obstacles. 38 For example, although each state
has the individual authority to regulate CO2 emissions, each must determine how
to fit that regulation within its state regulatory framework. 39 Some states can
adopt the RGGI regulations through the rulemaking authority vested in their
respective state agencies, while others require enabling legislation to give effect
to the RGGI rules. 40 Once the cap-and-trade regulations have been adopted,
each RGGI state will monitor and enforce those rules. 41 That enforcement may
raise additional challenges in particular, the problem of leakage. 42
131
132
region. 62 The LSEs would engage in the same market for allowances with
electricity generators and make operating choices based on economic efficiency.63
This regulatory scheme would likely face challenges based on the Interstate
Commerce Clause of the US Constitution, however, because the regulation
imposed on LSEs would place restrictions only on imported electricity. 64 Electricity
generators outside the RGGI region wishing to sell into the region at lower prices
likely will challenge the regulation as a violation of the dormant Commerce
Clause, which prohibits any state from enacting regulations that discriminate
against (or place burdens on) interstate commerce. 65 The RGGI states should
thoroughly consider potential Commerce Clause challenges before implementing
a cap-and-trade program on electricity imported by LSEs to stem leakage. 66
133
balancing test. 74 This test examines whether: (1) the law effectuates a legitimate
local purpose, (2) the burden imposed on interstate commerce is not clearly
excessive in relation to the putative local benefits, and (3) there are alternative
means for promoting the local purpose as well without discriminating against
interstate commerce. 75 Where, however, the state regulation is discriminatory,
meaning that it provides differential treatment of in-state and out-of-state
interests, it is virtually per se invalid. 76 The regulations proponent will only
overcome the per se rule of invalidity if it can show that the regulation advances
a legitimate local purpose that cannot be adequately served by reasonable
nondiscriminatory alternatives. 77 Facial discrimination by itself may be a fatal
defect, and invokes the strictest scrutiny of any purported legitimate local purpose
and of the absence of nondiscriminatory alternatives. 78
The hybrid regulatory approach described above could be challenged as a
facially discriminatory regulation because the regulation covering LSEs only
regulates emissions associated with imported electricity and therefore expressly
treats in-state and out-of-state interests differently. 79 The LSE regulation imposes
burdens on electricity crossing state lines only. 80 Therefore it burdens out-of-state
generators wishing to sell into the RGGI region, but does not itself impose the
same burdens on in-state generators. 81 Thus, the regulation would most likely be
subject to strict scrutiny under the dormant Commerce Clause. 82
134
tax on all liquor imported into the state equal to the tax imposed on all liquor
distilled within the state. 87 The Supreme Court stated that the tax on imported
liquor was merely a complementary provision necessary to make the tax equal
on all liquors sold in the state. 88 Therefore, the Court held that this was not an
attempt to regulate commerce, but an appropriate and legitimate exercise of the
states taxing power. 89
Since Hinson, the Court has more clearly defined and significantly limited
the compensatory tax doctrine through a line of cases beginning in 1937 with
Henneford v. Silas Mason and culminating in the decision of Fulton Corp. v.
Faulkner in 1996. 90 Modern application of the compensatory tax doctrine
involves a three-part test set out in 1994 in Oregon Waste Systems v. Department
of Environmental Quality of the State of Oregon and refined in Fulton Corp. 91
The three conditions necessary for a valid compensatory tax are: (1) a state must
identify the intrastate burden for which the state is attempting to compensate; (2)
the tax on interstate commerce must be shown roughly to approximate but not
to exceed the amount of the tax on intrastate commerce; and (3) the events on
which the interstate and intrastate taxes are imposed must be substantially
equivalent that is, they must be substantially similar in substance to serve as
mutually exclusive proxies for each other. 92 Given the relatively short life and
limited application of the formalized three-part test, it is necessary to examine
earlier cases, which address each of the prongs only implicitly, to analyze the
compensatory tax doctrine fully. 93
135
136
As an initial matter, the Court addressed the State of Louisianas claim that
the taxable uses within the state broke the flow of commerce and were wholly
local events, subject to state regulation. 112 The Court rejected this reasoning,
stating that gas crossing a state line at any stage of its movement to the ultimate
consumer was in interstate commerce during the entire journey from the
wellhead to the consumer, even though interrupted by certain events within a
particular state. 113
Finding the tax scheme facially discriminatory towards interstate commerce,
the Court set out to determine whether it could be upheld as a compensatory tax
under Silas Mason. 114 The Court held that the compensatory tax doctrine requires
identification of the burden for which the state is attempting to compensate. 115
Louisiana claimed that it was attempting to compensate for the burden of the
severance tax on local production of natural gas. 116 The Court rejected this
argument, stating that although Louisiana has an interest in protecting its natural
resources and therefore could impose a severance tax on domestic producers, it
had no comparable sovereign interest in being compensated for the severance of
resources from land outside its boundaries. 117 Therefore, the first-use tax could
not have been designed to meet the same ends as the severance tax it could
not have been designed to protect Louisianas natural resources. 118 The Court
said that the use of gas and severance of gas could not be considered
substantially equivalent events, reasoning implicitly that because the burden of
the two taxes fell on differently described taxpayers (in-state producers and outof-state consumers) and did not meet the same ends, the taxes were not
functionally equivalent. 119 The Court differentiated these circumstances from the
case of sales and use taxes, where a state attempts to ensure uniform treatment
of goods to be consumed in the state by imposing taxes on substantially similar
events occurring wholly within the state. 120
The Court concluded that the common thread running through the cases
upholding compensatory taxes was equality of treatment between local and
interstate commerce. 121 Because the pattern of credits and exemptions principally
burdened gas moving out of state, the tax was not a valid compensatory tax. 122
137
138
within Oregon. 134 The Oregon-based company regularly shipped waste from
neighboring Washington into Oregon for disposal. 135 The Oregon Supreme
Court upheld the surcharge as a compensatory fee with an express nexus to
actual costs incurred by state and local governments associated with disposing of
the waste. 136 The US Supreme Court reversed and invalidated the surcharge. 137
The Court held that because the rule was facially discriminatory, it was per
se invalid unless it advanced a legitimate local purpose that could not be
adequately served by reasonable nondiscriminatory alternatives. 138 The Court
began by recognizing the settled principle that interstate commerce may be
made to pay its way and that [i]t was not the purpose of the commerce clause
to relieve those engaged in interstate commerce from their just share of state . . .
burdens. 139 The Court noted that since Hinson v. Lott in 1869 the compensatory
tax doctrine had been used to express these principles, while also ensuring that
no state exacts more than a just share from interstate commerce, which is a
central purpose of the Commerce Clause. 140
The Court set out the first and second prongs of the compensatory tax
analysis requiring the state to (1) identify the intrastate burden for which the state
is attempting to compensate and (2) show that the burden on interstate
commerce roughly approximated, but did not exceed, the burden on intrastate
commerce. 141 Applying these two requirements, the Court held that Oregons
failure to identify a specific compensating charge on intrastate commerce equal
to or exceeding the surcharge was fatal to its claim. 142 Oregon claimed that the
surcharge compensated for general taxes paid by Oregon residents who
disposed of in-state waste. 143 The Court rejected this claim because it was
impossible to determine which portion of the general taxes were attributable to
the disposal of waste, and therefore the Court could not determine whether the
two burdens were roughly equivalent. 144 Accordingly, the state failed the first two
prongs of the analysis. 145
The Court further stated that even if it were possible to calculate the portion
of the general taxes that contributed to an intrastate burden roughly equivalent to
the interstate burden, the surcharge would still be invalid because the general tax
and the surcharge were not imposed on substantially equivalent events. 146 Thus,
the surcharge also violated the third prong of the analysis. 147 Under the
equivalent events analysis, the Court reasoned that earning income and
139
disposing of waste were even less equivalent than wholesale and manufacturing,
which were found not to be substantially equivalent in Armco. 148 The court
reasoned implicitly that the two taxes were not designed to meet the same ends,
because income taxes cover far more than disposal of waste and the two could
not be functionally equivalent to each other. 149 Moreover, the fact that
Oregon-based shippers of out-of-state waste were charged the surcharge and
income tax refuted the argument that the events were substantially (or
functionally) equivalent. 150 The Court noted that the prototypical example of
substantially equivalent events is the sale and use of articles within the state and
that the only compensatory taxes upheld had been use taxes on products
purchased out of state. 151 The Court refused to weigh comparative burdens
imposed on dissimilar events. 152
140
To meet its burden under the first prong, North Carolina argued that the
taxable percentage deduction (i.e. the tax on out-of-state stock interests)
compensated for the burden of the general corporate income tax paid by
corporations doing business in North Carolina. 160 The Court rejected this
argument, holding that in addition to merely identifying the intrastate burden for
which it seeks to compensate, the state must also show that the intrastate tax
serves some purpose for which the state may otherwise impose a burden on
interstate commerce. 161 The Court held that because North Carolina had no
general sovereign interest in taxing income earned out of state, it would fail the
first prong of the analysis unless the state could identify some instate activity or
benefit to justify the compensatory tax. 162 North Carolina attempted to cure this
deficiency by pointing out that the out-of state corporations benefited from the
use of the states capital markets without paying corporate income tax and that
the intangible tax compensated for this loss. 163 The Court declined to create a
precedent that would allow the imposition of a tax on entities involved in
interstate commerce any time they happened to use facilities supported by
general state tax funds. 164
Under the second prong of the analysis, the Court in Fulton addressed the
problem of interstate burdens that are imposed as a compensatory measure for
generally defined intrastate burdens. 165 The second prong requires that the
burden on interstate commerce be shown roughly to approximate, but not
exceed, the amount of the burden on intrastate commerce. 166 North Carolina
justified the intangibles tax and corresponding taxable percentage deduction as a
measure for maintenance of the capital market for the shares of both foreign
and domestic corporations. 167 The Court noted that the tax for which the state
purported to compensate was a general corporate income tax that paid for a
wide range of things, including construction and maintenance of a transportation
network, institutions to educate a workforce, and local fire and police
protection. 168 The state could not say what percentage of that general tax was
allocated to support the capital market and whether that proportion was greater
or smaller than the one imposed on interstate commerce by the intangibles
tax. 169 The Court emphasized the point made in Oregon Waste, namely that it is
generally unwilling to make the complex quantitative assessments required by the
compensatory tax doctrine when general forms of taxation are involved. 170 The
Court confirmed its unwillingness to permit discriminatory taxes on interstate
141
142
stock price of corporations doing business outside the state would reflect the
impact of the incidence tax because North Carolina investors make up a small
portion of the national market. 184 Thus, the economic incidence of that tax would
fall on the resident shareholder. 185 The Court noted that the objective of the
equivalent event requirement is to enable in-state and out-of-state businesses
to compete on equal footing. 186 The combination of the two tax schemes violated
this objective because the actual incidence of the intangibles tax fell squarely on
the shareholder and thus encouraged North Carolina investors to favor
investment in corporations doing business within the state. 187 The Court stated
that the compensatory tax doctrine is fundamentally concerned with equalizing
competition between in-staters and out-of-staters. 188 The Court cautioned,
however, that the difficulty in comparing the economic incidence of allegedly
complementary tax schemes on different taxpayers and different transactions
leads to the conclusion that courts will be unable to evaluate equivalency outside
the context of traditional sales/use taxes. 189
143
nondiscriminatory means. 197 The RGGI states should therefore argue for the
expansion of compensatory tax doctrine principles to cover important state and
regional environmental regulations such as the RGGI program. 198
A regulatory approach that adequately addresses leakage may require a
second regulation imposing a cap on the emissions associated with electricity
imported into the region by LSEs. 199 This regulation would be passed after the
implementation of the first cap on domestic electricity generators and only if it
was determined that leakage was undermining the goals of the program. 200 If
the RGGI states decide to use this hybrid regulatory approach to address
leakage, they should employ the compensatory tax doctrine to defend the
scheme by arguing that the regulation of imported electricity is necessary to
further a legitimate local purpose and that the combination of the two
regulations is nondiscriminatory in effect. 201 The purpose of the initial emissions
regulation imposed on generators is to reduce CO2 emissions associated with instate electricity consumption in order to protect the states interests in public
health and welfare and preservation of natural resources. 202 The regulation of
imported electricity through LSEs is a compensatory measure designed simply to
make interstate commerce bear a burden already borne by intrastate
commerce. 203 In other words, the combination of the two regulations merely
levels the playing field across all electricity generators serving the region. 204
Because the LSE regulation is necessary to effectuate the purpose of the initial
regulation, the combination of the two does not have a discriminatory effect, and
is therefore a legitimate compensatory tax or burden on interstate
commerce. 205
144
145
and Fulton Corp. v. Faulkner, the Court held that the state must identify an
in-state activity or benefit to justify the compensatory levy, a task that neither of
the states could do. 220 The RGGI states, on the other hand, may be able to
overcome the sovereign interest argument by showing that the regulation of
emissions associated with imported electricity is necessary to carry out the
purposes of the in-state regulation, and that the two regulations are designed to
meet the same end. 221 The RGGI states should argue that the combination of the
two regulations serves the legitimate local interest of protecting the natural
resources and the health and welfare of their citizens, and that a regulatory
scheme that places some burden on interstate commerce is necessary to
effectuate that purpose. 222 If the states cannot regulate emissions from imported
electricity, then the regulation of domestic emissions will not be effective. 223 This
argument thus directly addresses the requirement set out in Louisiana that the two
regulations be designed to meet the same end, because both regulations are
ultimately designed to protect the states public health and natural resources. 224
Based on this reasoning, the RGGI states could persuade a court that the
regulation satisfies the first prong of the compensatory tax doctrine. 225
146
states should set the initial cap on emissions for the region at a level that includes
the emissions associated with historic imports on the same basis as historic
in-region generation. 232 Under the second regulation, LSEs should receive
allowance allocations on the same basis that generators are given allowances. 233
Any inequality in the method by which allowances are distributed to LSEs for their
imports as compared to domestic generators could lead a court to detect
economic protectionism. 234 The RGGI states must be able to show that the
allocation of allowances to imported electricity under the second regulatory
measure is nondiscriminatory because it is based on the same historic baseline
as the allocation of allowances to domestic generators. 235
Also critical to the defense of the regulation on imported electricity will be
the method by which actual emissions associated with imported electricity and
domestic generator emissions will be measured. 236 If the methods used are not
the same, then the states will run a greater risk of having the regulation of
imported electricity struck down, because the court will not be able to weigh the
burdens quantitatively. 237 For example, if the states use actual emission rates for
instate generators because they are able to inspect those plants, but use assumed
rates based on megawatt-hour output for imported electricity because they are
unable to inspect out-of-state plants, a court could find that either the burdens
were not equivalent or that it was too cumbersome to attempt to weigh them. 238
For this reason, RGGI should use a common system of assigning CO2 attributes
to electricity for both generators and LSEs. 239
Both the allocation of allowances and measurement of emissions will likely
raise the sort of difficult quantitative questions that the Supreme Court has
continually used to strike down compensatory regulations. 240 For example, in
Armco, Inc. v. Hardesty, the state attempted to impose a wholesale interstate tax
to compensate for a manufacturing intrastate tax. 241 The Court complained that
it could not determine what part of the manufacturing tax was attributable to
manufacturing and what part to sales and therefore it struck down the burden on
interstate commerce, even though the burden on intrastate activities was
arguably the greater of the two. 242 To survive the second prong of the analysis,
the RGGI states must ensure that the accounting of allowances and emissions
reveals the actual burdens imposed and that the burden on interstate commerce
is no greater than the burden on intrastate commerce. 243
147
148
contrast, the burdens of the two regulations here fall on similarly described
entities, those serving a states electricity market and ultimately consumers within
the state, and therefore the two burdens are functionally equivalent. 255
As sensible as this argument seems, the fact remains that the Supreme
Court has continuously refused to acknowledge any expansion of the
compensatory tax doctrine beyond the sales and use tax category since its 1937
decision in Silas Mason. 256 For example, in Armco the Court held that
manufacturing and wholesale are not substantially similar events, reasoning that
the taxes imposed on the two were not functionally equivalent to each other. 257
The Court in Fulton stated: Hinson does not alter our conclusion today that
Courts will ordinarily be unable to evaluate the economic equivalence of
allegedly complementary tax schemes that go beyond traditional sales/use
taxes. 258 It appears that the Court is largely unwilling to open the door to
allowing facially discriminatory regulations as alleged compensatory regulations
outside sales and use taxes because the quantitative evaluations required to
determine whether the burdens are equivalent are too cumbersome. 259 The
principles embodied in the doctrine, however, are still of value to the RGGI states
because they may form the foundation of an argument for upholding the
regulation. 260
For one, there is a critical distinction between the hybrid approach to
regulating emissions and each of the allegedly compensatory taxes that the
Court has struck down since Silas Mason. 261 In every other case the Court has
found that the combination of regulations either did in effect, or had the potential
to, favor domestic interests over out-of-staters. 262 By contrast, here it is assumed
that the RGGI states will design a combination of regulations that do not favor
domestically generated electricity over imported electricity. 263 In Louisiana, the
combined effect of the imposed tax and tax credit scheme was to burden only
gas traveling out of state; therefore, the tax was invalidated. 264 In Fulton, the
regulations had the effect of encouraging North Carolinians to invest in domestic
rather than out-of-state companies. 265 By contrast, as was the case in Silas
Mason, the RGGI regulations would have the effect of burdening all electricity
consumed in the state equally and therefore should be upheld. 266
It is also worth considering the words of the Court in Armco when evaluating
the manufacturing and wholesale taxes. 267 The Court noted that because no
exception existed in the regulation for imported goods already subject to
149
manufacturing tax in another state, the combination of the two regulations could
have the effect of favoring domestic goods. 268 If out-of-state generators are
subject to emissions caps in their home states, then the LSE regulation will not
further burden them because they will already be producing clean electricity and
the regulation will not run into the Armco problem. 269 Before implementing a
hybrid approach, however, the RGGI states must consider whether the regulation
on imported electricity requires some exceptions. 270 For example, the regulation
should account for other potential burdens associated with CO2 emissions that
are not imposed in the RGGI region but could be imposed in other states, such
as CO2 emissions taxes. 271 Taking this issue into account as well as the Courts
approach to compensatory taxes, the RGGI states may be able to avoid
invalidation of future attempts to address leakage. 272
Conclusion
The ultimate solution to the problem of leakage is to implement a nationwide
regulatory program for greenhouse gas emissions. Until that time, state
regulators must do their best to combat global warming by implementing
regional programs and to prevent leakage. If RGGI is committed to a supply-side
regulatory scheme, there are several factors that should be considered before
implementing a regulation that covers imported electricity through LSEs. In order
to meet the requirements of the compensatory tax doctrine, the RGGI states must
be able to show with absolute certainty that the combined effect of the
regulations is to impose equal burdens on electricity to be consumed within the
state that the burden on interstate commerce is no greater than the burden on
intrastate commerce.
The initial carbon dioxide emissions cap should be set at levels that include
emissions associated with historic imports as well as historic in-state generation,
to avoid difficult accounting of allowances in the second phase of the program.
The RGGI states must also determine how to allocate allowances associated with
historic imports during the phase of the program that only subjects in-state
generators to regulation. The allocation of allowances must not favor in-state
electricity generators.
The RGGI states must also determine how carbon emission attributes of
imported electricity should be measured. The method used should be the same
150
Endnotes
1
151
and lower atmosphere to warm more than they otherwise would. See C.C. LEE,
Dictionary of Environmental Legal Terms 284 (1st ed. 1996); Environmental
Protection Agency, Terms of Environment: Glossary, Abbreviations, and Acronyms,
http://www.epa.gov/OCEPAterms/gterms.html (last visited Aug. 29, 2006).
Seven states are participating in the RGGI program: Connecticut, Delaware, Maine,
New Hampshire, New Jersey, New York, and Vermont. See RGGI MoU, supra, at 1,
67. The Memorandum of Understanding also contains an explicit provision
allowing Massachusetts and Rhode Island to become signatories at any time prior to
January 1, 2008, under certain conditions. See id. at 8.
2
See RGGI MoU, supra note 1, at 12; Envt Ne., The Regional Greenhouse Gas
Initiative: An Overview of the RGGI Program and its Importance 3 (2005)
[hereinafter Envt Ne. Overview], http://www.env-ne.org/Program%20Fact%20Sheets/
ENE_RGGI_Background.pdf. Market-based regulatory programs are commonly
referred to as cap-and-trade programs. See infra note 23 and accompanying text.
These programs implement an aggregate cap on allowable emissions in a region
through government regulation. See infra note 25 and accompanying text. The cap
is then distributed to polluters in the form of allowances. See infra note 26 and
accompanying text. Each polluter must own enough allowances to cover its own
emissions, but polluters are allowed to buy and sell allowances among each other.
See infra notes 2732 and accompanying text.
See generally Cap and Trade Subgroup, Cal. Climate Action Team, Cap and Trade
Program Design Options (2006) [hereinafter California Report], available at http://
www.climatechange.ca.gov/climate_action_team/reports/2006-03-27_CAP_AND_TRADE.
PDF. The Cap and Trade Subgroups report was appended to the Climate Action
Teams more general report evaluating the impact of climate change on California
and the options available to the state, which was presented to the California
legislature and Governor Arnold Schwarzenegger. See Cal. Climate Action Team,
Cal. Envtl. Prot. Agency, Climate Action Team Report to Governor Schwarzenegger
and the Legislature 5 (2006), available at http://www.climatechange.ca.gov/
climate_action_team/reports/2006-04-03_FINAL_CAT_REPORT.PDF; see also Climate
Action Team Reports to the Governor and Legislature, http://www.climatechange.
ca.gov/climate_action_team/reports/index.html (last visited Sept. 16, 2006) (listing
the Climate Action Teams reports and appendices). On August 30, 2006,
Californias leaders announced an agreement to enact legislation that would place
sharp limits on carbon dioxide emissions within the state. See Felicity Barringer,
Officials Reach California Deal to Cut Emissions, N.Y. Times, Aug. 30, 2006, at A1.
See California Report, supra note 3, at 22; RGGI MoU, supra note 1, at 9.
See id.
152
See Richard Cowart, Another Option for Power Sector Carbon Cap and Trade
Systems Allocating to Load 34 (Regulatory Assistance Project, 2004),
http://www.rggi.org/docs/allocating_to_load.pdf; see also California Report, supra
note 3, at 2122.
See infra notes 18272 and accompanying text. The arguments in this Note could
also be applied to the regulatory scheme that California is currently adopting. See
supra note 3.
10
See Fulton Corp., v. Faulkner, 516 US 325, 331 (1996) (quoting Assoc. Indus. of
Mo. v. Lohman, 511 US 641, 647 (1994)); see also Walter Hellerstein,
Complimentary Taxes as a Defense to Unconstitutional State Tax Discrimination, 39
Tax Law. 405, 406 (1986) (examining compensatory tax doctrine jurisprudence).
11
12
13
14
15
16
Id.
17
18
19
See Eileen Claussen, An Effective Approach to Climate Change, Science, Oct. 29,
2004, at 816; Joint Science Academies Statement: Global Response to Climate
Change 1 ( June 7, 2005), http://nationalacademies.org/onpi/06072005.pdf.
Carbon dioxide is the most abundant anthropogenic greenhouse gas in the world.
Envt Ne. Overview, supra note 2, at 1. It is released into the atmosphere when
carbon-based fuel is burned. See id. In 1780, the level of CO2 in the earths
atmosphere was approximately 280 parts per million (ppm) and had been for at
least 6000 years. See Elizabeth Kolbert, The Climate of Man III: What Can Be Done?,
The New Yorker, May 9, 2005, at 54. As the industrial age took hold, CO2
concentrations began to rise slowly at first and then more rapidly. See id. By the
1970s, the CO2 concentration in the atmosphere was approximately 330 ppm and
in 2000 it reached 369 ppm. Id.; see also Lester R. Brown, Growing . . . Growing . . .
Gone?, Mother Earth News, Dec.Jan. 2004, at 70, available at http://www.
153
motherearthnews.com/Nature_and_Environment/2003_December_January/Growing___
Growing___Gone_.
20
See Elizabeth Kolbert, The Climate of Man II: The Curse of Akkad, The New Yorker,
May 2, 2005, at 69. This predicted increase in temperature is based on model
predictions that show that if we continue to produce greenhouse gases at the rates
necessary to meet increasing demand, atmospheric CO2 will reach 500 ppm
around the middle of this century. Id. There is evidence that CO2 concentrations in
the earths atmosphere were that high about fifty million years ago when crocodiles
lived in Colorado and ocean levels were three hundred feet higher than they are
today, putting much of todays inhabited land underwater. Kolbert, supra note 19, at 54.
21
See generally Peter Schwartz & Doug Randall, An Abrupt Climate Change Scenario
and Its Implications for United States National Security (2003), available at
http://www.environmentaldefense.org/documents/3566_AbruptClimateChange.pdf.
This report, commissioned by the US Department of Defense, identified these and
other consequences as the possible and even likely results of an abrupt climate
change event that could be caused by the collapse of the Atlantic conveyor as a
result of global warming. See id. at 13; see also RGGI MoU, supra note 1, at 1.
22
See M.J. Bradley & Associates, Momentum Builds in the US Whats Filling the
Federal Vacuum on Climate Change?, Envtl. Energy Insights, Apr.May 2005, at 14.
Through the Kyoto Protocol, most of the countries in the world, including the United
Kingdom, the European Union nations, and Russia, have committed to reducing
greenhouse gas emissions to at least 5% below 1990 levels by 2012. See Kyoto
Protocol to the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change, Dec. 10,
1997, 37 I.L.M. 22 (1998); United Nations Framework Convention on Climate
Change, Kyoto Protocol: Status of Ratification, http://unfccc.int/files/essential_
background/kyoto_protocol/application/pdf/kpstats.pdf (last visited Aug. 31, 2006).
On January 1, 2005, the European Union launched a capand-trade program
covering CO2 emissions from large industrial polluters that will eventually cover
twenty-five countries with a target of reducing CO2 emissions to 8% below 1990
levels by 2012. European Commn, EU Action Against Climate Change 3 (2005),
http://ec.europa.eu/environment/climat/pdf/emission_trading2_en.pdf; see also
Joseph A. Kruger & William A. Pizer, Greenhouse Gas Trading in Europe: The New
Grand Policy Experiment, Envt, Oct. 2004, at 823 (analyzing the European Union
emissions trading system). Individual states, including New Hampshire,
Massachusetts, California, Oregon, and Washington, have made commitments to
reducing greenhouse gases. See M.J. Bradley & Associates, supra, at 23. Mayors
from 132 US cities have taken the Kyoto pledge of 7% reductions below 1990 levels
by 2012, and fifty of the worlds largest cities signed onto greenhouse gas emission
reductions of 25% by 2030 at the UN World Environment Day conference held in
June 2005. Id. at 34. Additionally, in 2003, various institutional investors
representing $2.7 trillion worth of assets formed the Investor Network on Climate
Risk to examine the risks of climate change to their portfolios. Id. at 1. The group
154
24
See Envt Ne. Overview, supra note 2, at 2. To ensure compliance with the cap, the
RGGI states will develop a method of enforcement that may be imposed on the
regulated facilities. See Model Rule XX-6.5 (Regl Greenhouse Gas Initiative 2006),
http://www.rggi.org/docs/model_rule_8_15_06.pdf (setting out a model compliance
scheme).
25
See Envt Ne. Overview, supra note 2, at 2; Office of Air and Radiation, US Envtl.
Prot. Agency, Tools of the Trade: A Guide to Designing and Operating a Cap and
Trade Program for Pollution Control 1-2 (2003) [hereinafter EPA Guide], available at
http://www.epa.gov/airmarkets/international/tools.pdf.
26
See Envt Ne. Overview, supra note 2, at 2; EPA Guide, supra note 25, at 1-2.
27
Id.
28
Memorandum from the RGGI Staff Working Group to RGGI Agency Heads 2
(Aug. 24, 2005) [hereinafter RGGI Staff Memorandum], http://www.rggi.org/
docs/rggi_pro posal_8_24_05.pdf.
29
See id.; see also RGGI MoU, supra note 1, at 2. If Massachusetts and Rhode Island
join the program, the cap will be increased to approximately 150 million tons. See
RGGI MoU, supra note 1, at 8.
30
31
32
See id. Cap-and-trade is a workable solution in the case of CO2 because CO2 is a
uniform pollutant; it has the same atmospheric impact regardless of where the
source is located. See Envt Ne. Overview, supra note 2, at 2. By contrast, localized
pollutants such as mercury and particulate matter directly impact the health of the
local communities and ecosystems surrounding the emission source. Id. This
localized impact raises concerns over the creation of hotspots of pollution and
related social and environmental justice issues. See EPA Guide, supra note 25, at 22. Therefore, for localized pollutants it is usually necessary to implement site-specific
command-and-control regulation, which does not allow the flexibility of cap-andtrade programs. See id.
33
34
See id. at 1-2 to -3. Dirtier facilities that exceed the emissions cap may be subject to
additional penalties. See supra note 24.
155
35
See EPA Guide, supra note 25, at 1-2. In addition to investing in non-emitting forms
of energy generation such as wind and solar energy, regulated facilities will have an
incentive to improve end-use efficiency, transition to cleaner fossil fuels, invest in
more efficient generation and transmission technology, and even utilize carbon
capture and sequestration techniques to offset their emissions if it is economically
efficient to do so. See id. at 1-3; see also California Report, supra note 3, at 24.
36
See 42 U.S.C. 7651(b) (2000) (aiming to reduce emissions of sulfur dioxide and
nitrogen oxide through an emissions allocation and transfer system); see also
California Report, supra note 3, at 1112 (noting the success of the federal
governments acid rain reduction program). The largest-scale use of the cap-andtrade model in the United States to date is the federal governments acid rain
program under Title IV of the Clean Air Act, but the model has also been used in
regional programs. See 42 U.S.C. 7651 (2000); California Report, supra note 3,
at 1115. Two regional programs, the Northeast NOx Budget Program and the
Regional Clean Air Incentives Program (RECLAIM), used a cap-and-trade
emissions program to regulate ozone and smog, respectively, with varying degrees
of scope and success. See California Report, supra note 3, at 1314.
37
See Envt Ne. Overview, supra note 2, at 3. This statement assumes that RGGI does
not attempt to regulate electricity transmission or wholesale transactions per se that
are regulated by the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission under the Federal
Power Act. See 16 U.S.C. 824 (2000); see also Note, Foreign Affairs Preemption
and State Regulation of Greenhouse Gas Emissions, 119 Harv. L. Rev. 1877, 1878
(2006) (arguing that state regulation of greenhouse gases should not be preempted
by the federal foreign affairs power).
38
See Peter Glaser, Troutman Sanders LLP, Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative: A
Contrarian Perspective, Presentation to the American Bar Associations Environment,
Energy and Resources Section 23 (Jan. 26, 2006), http://www.abanet.org/environ/
committees/renewableenergy/teleconarchives/012606/1-26-06GlaserPPT.PPT (contending
that the RGGI states face Compact Clause and Commerce Clause hurdles and
questioning whether the states have the political will to regulate CO2 if legislation is
required).
39
40
See id.
41
See id.
42
See id. at 9.
43
156
of emissions from sources within the program to sources outside the program as a
potential problem facing non-national programs).
44
See RGGI MoU, supra note 1, at 2; Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative, About
RGGI, http://www.rggi.org/about.htm (last visited Aug. 23, 2006); supra notes 23
27 and accompanying text.
45
46
See California Report, supra note 3, at 2223; Cowart, supra note 7, at 5. The
program cap will cover all in-region fossil fuel-fired electricity-generating units
having a rated capacity equal to or greater than twenty-five megawatts. See RGGI
MoU, supra note 1, at 2. The program may be expanded in the future to include
other sources of greenhouse gas emissions and greenhouse gases other than CO2.
See Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative, About RGGI, http://www.rggi.org/
about.htm (last visited Aug. 23, 2006).
47
48
49
Id.
50
Id.
51
Id.
52
Id.
53
54
See id. at 9.
55
Id.
56
See California Report, supra note 3, at 2224; Cowart, supra note 7, at 5. For
example, California is exploring a variation of the cap-and-trade approach referred
to as allocation-to-load. California Report, supra note 3, at 21. Under this approach
emission allowances are allocated to electricity providers, or LSEs, rather than to
electricity generators. Id. Each LSE must hold allowances equal to the emissions
created by the electricity it distributes to consumers. Id. Under a complete allocationto-load program, the regulated LSE must hold allowances for all emissions
associated with the electricity it sells to consumers, regardless of where the producing
generator is located, and the cap applies to total emissions associated with all
electricity consumed in the state. Id. In this way, imported energy, as well as
domestic energy, is accounted for in the cap. See California Report, supra note 3,
at 2123; Cowart, supra note 7, at 5.
57
Cf. California Report, supra note 3, at 2123 (discussing the possibility of regulating
CO2 emissions through LSEs, rather than generators). This Note does not address
157
the question of whether individual states have the authority to regulate the emissions
associated with imported power purchased by regulated LSEs. See id. (discussing
existing regulatory authority and additional authority that would require legislative
action to regulate all LSEs in California). This question depends heavily on statespecific legal issues. See id.; see also RGGI MoU, supra note 1, at 7.
58
59
See California Report, supra note 3, at 2123; Cowart, supra note 7, at 5. The
current proposed cap for the total RGGI region approximately 120 million short
tons is based on the average emissions of the highest three years between 2000
and 2004 for each state. See RGGI MoU, supra note 1, at 2; RGGI Staff
Memorandum, supra note 28, at 2. Generators and LSEs alike would receive
allowances on this same historic basis. See California Report, supra note 3, at 2123;
Cowart, supra note 7, at 5.
60
61
See California Report, supra note 3, at 21. The assignment of CO2 attributes to
imported electricity for the purposes of measuring emissions associated with
consumption in the state is a complicated issue that is not addressed in this Note.
See id. at 23. Several methods are available. See id. Before choosing a method, the
regulating community must consider the impact that each method could have on the
legal analysis presented herein. See id.
62
63
See id.
64
See US Const. Art. I, 8, cl. 3; Or. Waste Sys., Inc., v. Dept of Envtl. Quality, 511
US 93, 99 (1994) (holding that state laws placing burdens on interstate commerce
are subject to challenge based on the Commerce Clause of the US Constitution);
Robert B. McKinstry, Jr., Laboratories for Local Solutions for Global Problems: State,
Local and Private Leadership in Developing Strategies to Mitigate the Causes and
Effects of Climate Change, 12 Penn St. Envtl. L. Rev. 15, 67 (2004) (noting potential
Commerce Clause challenges to state and regional regulatory programs).
65
See US Const. Art. I, 8, cl. 3; Or. Waste, 511 US at 99; McKinstry, supra note 64,
at 67.
66
See infra notes 190272 and accompanying text; see also Kirsten H. Engel, The
Dormant Commerce Clause Threat to Market-Based Environmental Regulation: The
Case of Electricity Deregulation, 26 Ecology L.Q. 243, 25052 (1999) (noting the
Commerce Clause objections to market-based environmental regulation and
arguing that such regulation should be upheld based on the logic of the market
participant exception and because it promotes economic efficiency and interstate
harmony, and is not motivated by economic protectionism).
158
67
68
See Fulton Corp., v. Faulkner, 516 US 325, 330 (1996); Or. Waste Sys., Inc., v.
Dept of Envtl. Quality, 511 US 93, 9899 (1994).
69
70
Fulton, 516 US at 330 (quoting Assoc. Indus. of Mo. v. Lohman, 511 US 641, 647
(1994)).
71
72
73
See Fulton, 516 US at 331; Or. Waste, 511 US at 99; Hughes, 441 US at 336.
74
75
See id.
76
77
See Or. Waste, 511 US at 10001 (quoting New Energy Co., of Ind. v. Limbach,
486 US 269, 278 (1988)); Hughes, 441 US at 336; see also Maine v. Taylor, 477
US 131, 151 52 (1986) (upholding a facially discriminatory law banning the
importation of out-of-state bait fish into Maine because the fish were subject to
parasites completely foreign to Maine baitfish and could jeopardize the health of the
Maine fish population, and no nondiscriminatory alternatives existed).
78
See Or. Waste, 511 US at 99; Hughes, 441 US at 337; see also Justin M. Nesbit,
Note, Commerce Clause Implications of Massachusetts Attempt to Limit the
Importation of Dirty Power in the Looming Competitive Retail Market for Electricity
Generation, 38 B.C. L. Rev. 811, 842 (1997) (concluding that an outright ban on
imported power would likely be invalidated under the Commerce Clause but that a
surcharge on sales of dirty electricity could pass the Pike balancing test).
79
80
See supra notes 5666 and accompanying text; see also Armco, Inc., v. Hardesty,
467 US 638, 644 (1984) (finding that wholesale tax imposed only on imported
goods burdened interstate commerce).
81
82
83
84
85
159
86
87
Id. at 150.
88
Id. at 153.
89
Id.
90
See Fulton, 516 US at 332. See generally Henneford v. Silas Mason Co., 300 US
577 (1937).
91
92
93
94
95
96
Id. at 58081.
97
Id. at 579.
98
Id.
99
160
161
162
163
193 See New State Ice Co., v. Liebmann, 285 US 262, 311 (1932) (Brandeis, J.,
dissenting) (There must be power in the states and the nation to remould, through
experimentation, our economic practices and institutions to meet changing social
and economic needs.); see also McKinstry, supra note 64, at 1516 (noting that
although states serve as laboratories for environmental policy change and often
serve as a template for federal action, they face unique challenges).
194 See M.J. Bradley & Associates, supra note 22, at 2; supra notes 18, 1822 and
accompanying text. In addition, if California adopts a different program for
reduction of CO2 emissions from that adopted by RGGI, the impact of the two
programs on the national regulated community could be significant and force
federal action. See M.J. Bradley & Associates, supra note 22, at 2; supra notes 18,
1822 and accompanying text.
195 See supra notes 190194 and accompanying text.
196 See supra note 107 and accompanying text.
197 See 511 US 93, 102 (1994).
198 See id; supra notes 190194 and accompanying text.
199 See supra notes 5763 and accompanying text.
200 Id.
201 See Fulton Corp., v. Faulkner, 516 US 325, 342 (1996). There is an obvious
distinction between a tax and a regulation limiting CO2 emissions. See supra note
107 and accompanying text. The emissions cap does, however, ultimately impose
burdens on generators of electricity that wish to participate in interstate commerce
with the RGGI states. See supra notes 5766 and accompanying text. This burden on
electricity crossing regional borders is analogous to the burden imposed by the
traditional taxes considered under the compensatory tax doctrine. See supra notes
5766 and accompanying text.
202 See RGGI MoU, supra note 1, at 1; Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative, About
RGGI, http://www.rggi.org/about.htm (last visited Aug. 23, 2006).
203 See Assoc. Indus. of Mo. v. Lohman, 511 US 641, 647 (1994).
204 See supra notes 4363, 99102 and accompanying text.
205 See Fulton, 516 US at 33031; Or. Waste, 511 US at 99. One weakness of this
argument is the availability of the total allocation-to-load regulatory option, which a
court could deem to be a reasonable, less discriminatory alternative. See supra note
56. Although this regulation could still be subject to a Commerce Clause challenge
because it places burdens on interstate commerce of electricity, it likely would not
face the strict scrutiny test imposed on facially discriminatory regulations like the
regulation that RGGI is now considering. See supra notes 7377 and accompanying
164
text. Rather, a court would likely find that it regulates evenhandedly with only
incidental effects on interstate commerce because it does not differentiate between
in-state and out-of-state interests. See California Report, supra note 3, at 23 (noting
that the total allocation-to-load approach generally treats in-state and out-of-state
interests equally); supra notes 7377 and accompanying text. A strong case could be
made that a single load-based emissions cap that included both domestic and
imported energy would pass the Pike balancing test because: (1) it would effectuate
a legitimate local purpose that of reducing greenhouse gases; (2) the burden
imposed on interstate commerce would not be clearly excessive in relation to the
putative local benefits; and (3) there are no alternative means for promoting the
local purpose as well without discriminating against interstate commerce. See Pike v.
Bruce Church, Inc., 397 US 137, 142 (1970).
206 See Fulton, 516 US at 331; Or. Waste, 511 US at 99; Hughes v. Oklahoma, 441 US
322, 336 (1979).
207 See Fulton, 516 US at 333 (finding a statute that burdens interstate commerce but
not intrastate commerce to be facially discriminatory); Or. Waste, 511 US at 100
(stating that a law that taxes interstate activities more heavily is facially
discriminatory); supra notes 5663 and accompanying text; see also Kirsten H.
Engel, Mitigating Global Climate Change in the United States: A Regional Approach,
14 N.Y.U. Envtl. L.J. 54, 7778 (2005) (concluding that an outright ban on
importation of electricity would be a facially discriminatory Commerce Clause
violation unless it was expressly authorized by Congress).
208 See supra notes 7392 and accompanying text.
209 Id.
210 See supra notes 8392 and accompanying text.
211 See Fulton, 516 US at 332; Or. Waste, 511 US at 103.
212 See Fulton, 516 US at 337 (expressing suspicion that the reason given for imposing
an allegedly compensatory tax was illusory).
213 See Maryland v. Louisiana, 451 US 725, 759 (1981); see also Fulton, 516 US at
334 (holding that North Carolina could not impose a tax on foreign corporations
compensating for the burden of income tax on domestic corporations because North
Carolina had no sovereign interest in taxing the income of a foreign corporation).
214 See RGGI MoU, supra note 1, at 1.
215 See Louisiana, 451 US at 759; cf. Massachusetts v. EPA, 415 F.3d 50, 5456 (D.C.
Cir. 2005), cert. granted, 126 S. Ct. 2960 (2006). In Massachusetts v. EPA, Judge
Randolph, writing for a three-judge panel of the US Court of Appeals for the District
of Columbia Circuit, assumed without deciding that a state has standing to bring an
action based on the generalized grievance of harms associated with global
165
warming. 415 F.3d at 5456. Judge Sentelle, dissenting in part but concurring in the
judgment, stated that the state did not have standing because it did not assert a
specific harm associated with CO2 emissions. Id. at 59 60 (Sentelle, J., dissenting
in part but concurring in the judgment). Judge Tatel, dissenting, stated that the state
did have standing, in part because it had successfully shown injury caused by global
warming. Id. at 64 (Tatel, J., dissenting).
216 See Louisiana, 451 US at 759.
217 See id.
218 See id.
219 See id. at 759; supra notes 4363 and accompanying text.
220 See Fulton, 516 US at 334; Louisiana, 451 US at 759.
221 See Or. Waste, 511 US at 99; Louisiana, 451 US at 759.
222 See Maine v. Taylor, 477 US 131, 15152 (1986) (upholding a facially
discriminatory law banning the importation of out-of-state bait fish into Maine
because the fish were subject to parasites completely foreign to Maine baitfish and
could jeopardize the health of the Maine fish population, and no nondiscriminatory
alternatives existed).
223 See supra notes 4352 and accompanying text.
224 See Louisiana, 451 US at 759.
225 See supra notes 211224 and accompanying text.
226 See supra notes 141145, 165171 and accompanying text.
227 See Fulton, 516 US at 338; Or. Waste, 511 US at 10405; supra notes 141145,
165 171 and accompanying text.
228 See Armco, Inc., v. Hardesty, 467 US 638, 643 (1984) (striking down an allegedly
compensatory tax, in part because the court could not determine which part of the
tax was meant to be compensatory); California Report, supra note 3, at 21, 23
(discussing the current lack of a robust emissions-tracking system for LSEs); see also
Fulton, 516 US at 338; Or. Waste, 511 US at 10405.
229 See Or. Waste, 511 US at 106 (citing Wyoming v. Oklahoma, 502 US 437, 454
(1992) and New Energy Co., of Ind. v. Limbach, 486 US 269, 275 (1988));
Henneford v. Silas Mason, 300 US 577, 586 (1937).
230 See Or. Waste, 511 US at 106; Silas Mason, 300 US at 586.
231 See California Report, supra note 3, at 2123. Because the initial phase of the
program will only regulate in-region generators, the RGGI states must determine
how to allocate the allowances associated with historic imports so as to avoid
166
allocation problems later in the event that the regulation of imported electricity is
required. See id. If the RGGI states allocate the entire cap of allowances including
those associated with historic imports to generators during the initial phase of the
program and leakage becomes a problem, then there will be the serious issue of
reallocating those allowances associated with historic imports to the newly regulated
LSEs. See id.; cf. Armco, 467 US at 645 (rejecting an allegedly compensatory tax in
part because it was unclear which part of the tax was intended to be compensatory).
232 See California Report, supra note 3, at 2223; Cowart, supra note 7, at 5.
233 Id.
234 See Fulton, 516 US at 338; Or. Waste, 511 US at 10405.
235 Id.
236 Id..
237 See Fulton, 516 US at 342; Or. Waste, 511 US at 105; Armco, 467 US at 643.
238 See Armco, 467 US at 643 (striking down an allegedly compensatory tax in part
because the court could not determine what portion of the tax compensated for the
in-state burden); California Report, supra note 3, at 23 (noting the various difficulties
associated with tracking emissions).
239 See Fulton, 516 US at 342; Or. Waste, 511 US at 105; Armco, 467 US at 643.
There is currently not a robust tracking system for LSEs to monitor emissions
associated with electricity they deliver to customers. See California Report, supra note 3,
at 23. Options for developing a tracking system include relying on average
emissions and requiring power contracts to include emissions data for electricity
delivered. Id.
240 See supra notes 129, 142144, 168171 and accompanying text.
241 See 467 US at 643.
242 See Armco, 467 US at 643; see also Or. Waste, 511 US at 10405 (refusing to
engage in the type of quantitative assessments that the compensatory tax doctrine
requires). 243 See Silas Mason, 300 US at 584; see also Fulton, 516 US at 342; Or.
Waste, 511 US at 105; Armco, 467 US at 643.
243
244 See Fulton, 516 US at 33233.
245 See id.
246 See supra notes 114122 and accompanying text.
247 Id.
167
7
Balancing Cost and Emissions
Certainty: An Allowance Reserve for
Cap-and-Trade
Brian C. Murray,* Richard G. Newell** and William A. Pizer***
On efficiency grounds, the economics community has to date
tended to emphasize price-based policies to address climate
change such as taxes or a "safety-valve" price ceiling for
cap-and-trade while environmental advocates have sought a
more clear quantitative limit on emissions. This paper presents a
simple modification to the idea of a safety valve: a quantitative
limit that we call the allowance reserve. Importantly, this idea
may bridge the gap between competing interests and potentially
improve efficiency relative to tax or other price-based policies.
The last point highlights the deficiencies in several previous
studies of price and quantity controls for climate change that do
not adequately capture the dynamic opportunities within a
cap-and-trade system for allowance banking, borrowing, and
intertemporal arbitrage in response to unfolding information.
*
Director for Economic Analysis, Nicholas Institute, and Research Professor, Nicholas School of the
Environment, Duke University. 1616 p st. NW Washington, D.C. 20036. E-mail: forester@rff.org.
** The Gendell Associate Professor of Energy and Environmental Economics, Nicholas School of the
Environment, Duke University- Research Associate at the National Bureau of Economic Research.
E-mail: bcmurray@duke.edu
*** Senior Fellow at Resources for the Future. E-mail: billy.pizer@gmail.com
2008 Resources for the Future. This article was originally published in Resources for Future Discussion
Paper No. 08-24. Reprinted with permission.
Source: www.nber.org.
169
Introduction
The economic debate over using taxes versus cap-and-trade to control pollution
emissions revolves around the relative merits of using prices versus quantities as
the policy instrument. A cap-and-trade system fixes the quantity of emissions
allowed but leaves the market price of emissions rights uncertain. In contrast, a
tax fixes the price of emissions at the tax rate but leaves the quantity of emissions
uncertain. This trade-off raises essential questions for policy design: which form
of uncertainty is a greater burden to society? What can be done to minimize that
burden or maximize net benefits? A sizable economics literature has addressed
these questions, dating back to Weitzman (1974) and others.
Taxes and cap-and-trade are, in some sense, extreme examples of the
alternative market based approaches that are available to correct an emissions
externality. The government stipulates that emitters must obtain the right to
emit. These rights (typically called allowances or permits) are either supplied
with infinite elasticity at a fixed price (the tax) or with zero elasticity at a fixed
supply (the cap). A key alternative initially suggested by Roberts and Spence
(1976) and later developed in the context of climate policy by Pizer (2002) is
the idea of a safety valve, in which a cap-and-trade system is coupled with a
price ceiling at which additional allowances can be purchased (in excess of the
cap). So long as the allowance price is below the safety-valve price, this hybrid
system acts like cap-and-trade, with emissions fixed but the price left to adjust.
When the safety-valve price is reached, however, this system behaves like a tax,
fixing the price but leaving emissions to adjust. Given the importance attached by
many stakeholders and policymakers to containing the costs of any US climate
policy, this approach has received considerable attention in the US debate over
climate change regulation (e.g., Samuelsohn 2008), and has come to be known
as the cost-containment issue (Pizer and Tatsutani 2008).
Cap-and-trade with a safety valve represents one of many possible
mechanisms that lie between the two extremes of a pure price or a pure quantity
instrument. It offers a more malleable supply curve for emissions allowances,
containing both vertical and flat segments. This paper discusses a second
mechanism that includes features of both price and quantity instruments. We
believe this approach, which we call an allowance reserve, is particularly
170
promising. The basic idea goes one step beyond the safety valve: while the safety
valve stipulates that an unlimited number of allowances be made available at the
specified safety-valve price, the allowance reserve stipulates both a ceiling price
at which cost relief is provided and a maximum number of allowances to be
issued in exercising that relief. Much like a safety-valve mechanism can mimic
either a pure price or pure quantity control, depending on how the cap and
safety valve price are set, an allowance reserve can mimic a pure price, pure
quantity, or safety-valve approach, depending on how the ceiling price and
volume are set.
Three motivations underlie our interest in this mechanism. The first two are
largely practical in nature, while the third hints at a new twist on the conditions
underlying optimality, in contrast to the traditional prices versus quantities
perspective. The first motivation is simple: as we describe below, the safety valve
represents a special case of the allowance reserve where the volume of available
allowances is very large or unlimited. Thus, an allowance reserve has the
capacity to do as well if not better than the safety valve in terms of matching
public interest described below as a blend of economic efficiency and political
feasibility. That is, political economy conditions suggest that public interest may
be better served with an allowance reserve because it is more likely to sustain a
coalition that will enable welfare-enhancing policy to be enacted.
Second, the reserve mechanism addresses one problem with a safety valve.
Although most cap-and-trade programs permit allowance banking, which can
help equilibrate present value prices across different time periods and increase
dynamic efficiency, allowance banking coupled with a safety valve creates a
dynamic problem. Suppose the cap needs to be tightened and as a result the
safety-valve price is expected to increase dramatically at some point in the future.
With an ordinary safety valve, an expectation of much higher prices in the future
would lead rational firms to buy as many allowances as possible at the current,
low safety-valve price in order to save them for use later when prices are high.
Absent a mechanism to limit such purchases, they could effectively overwhelm
efforts to tighten the future cap, thereby undermining long-term environmental
policy goals. An allowance reserve would address this potential problem by
placing an upper limit on the available number of extra allowances.
171
172
foresight necessary for such optimality, the allowance reserve may be a useful
way to help move market outcomes in the correct direction. We end with a
discussion of the remaining issues that surround practical implementation of the
allowance reserve, including establishing the ceiling price, reserve size, and
release mechanisms. We present conclusions in the final section.
173
cap-and-trade with a price floor and ceiling. This approach generates three types
of outcomes depending on the realized demand: (1) when demand is low, the
price is set by the floor, and the quantity of allowances is below the cap; (2)
when demand is moderate, the quantity of allowances is determined by the cap,
and the price is somewhere between the floor and ceiling; and (3) when demand
is high, the price is set by the ceiling, and emissions are above the cap. 2
Depending on the choice of design parameters (i.e., cap, floor, ceiling), the
policy also has the ability to mimic either a tax (if the price ceiling or cap level is
sufficiently low) or pure cap-and-trade (if the floor is low and the ceiling high).
Owing partly to the previously mentioned authors emphasis on price-based
policies and partly to the politics of wanting to have both certainty about prices
and stringent emissions limits, there has been a significant emphasis on policy
with a relatively low, stringent cap level and low price ceiling. This approach,
where the price ceiling is referred to as a safety valve, has garnered
considerable attention and political support over the past five years as climate
policy proposals have made their way to Congress (Samuelsohn 2008). The price
floor, though it has received less attention in the federal policy debate, is being
implemented in the Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative cap-and-trade program
in the Northeastern US states.
Representing the allowance reserve idea requires only a slight adjustment to
the Roberts and Spence (1976) supply schedule (see the right panel of Appendix
Figure 2). The price ceiling that previously allowed an unlimited volume of
allowances to be purchased now also has a quantitative limit, which is the
allowance reserve. Basically, we have simply added another kink in the
allowance supply schedule and made it more flexible in its ability to balance
price and quantity goals. Indeed, the first-best policy would be to specify an
allowance supply schedule that mimicked the marginal damages from higher
emissions. In this sense, the allowance reserve offers a well-defined improvement
over the alternative policies developed so far, each of which remains a special
case. In essence, the reserve can be deployed in a way that reflects something
closer to the increasing marginal social cost of emissions.
When implemented, all market-based policies require us to identify a group
of regulated entities whose direct emissions or embodied emissions (for upstream
regulation of fuels) are measured and reported on a regular basis, typically
174
annually. Under a tax policy, those entities are then required to pay a specified
tax ($/ton) applied to the measured amount of emissions. Under cap-and-trade,
they are required to acquire and surrender allowances.
A key feature in virtually all proposed greenhouse gas cap-and-trade
programs is banking, under which unused allowances in one year can be used in
subsequent years. With banking, there can be an incentive to reduce emissions
early particularly during a gradual phasedown of emissions targets and it is
not necessary for the market to meet the target exactly each year. If that were the
case, there would be a danger that requiring emissions to match the number of
allowances exactly would result in either too few allowances causing the price
to skyrocket or too many allowances causing the price to plummet. The former
occurred in the California NOx RECLAIM market; the latter occurred in Phase I of
the EU Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS) for greenhouse gases. Both systems
significantly restricted banking and borrowing across compliance periods. In the
EU ETS, the main culprit was that banking was not allowed between Phase I (preKyoto) and Phase II (Kyoto). That, combined with a generous allocation,
eventually led to an excess supply of allowances and drove the price to zero at
the end of Phase I. In contrast, systems that have allowed banking (and possibly
borrowing) have tended to have much smoother price behavior as the price at
the end of one period tends to match the price at the beginning of the next due
to allowance fungibility across periods and market arbitrage.
What about more complex policies? The price floor in the Roberts and
Spence (1976) hybrid policy could be implemented in two ways. If the allowances
associated with the cap are all distributed for free, the only alternative is for the
government to agree to buy any allowances that regulated entities are willing to
sell at the specified floor price. If, however, some of the allowances are
auctioned, the price floor could be implemented by specifying a minimum price
in the auction. In this way, allowances only enter the market if the price meets or
exceeds the floor; otherwise, less than the full volume of allowances are sold.
The price ceiling, or safety valve, could be implemented by having the
government agree to sell additional allowances at the specified ceiling price.
However, there has been a wrinkle in such legislative proposals (e.g., S. 1766 in
the 110th Congress, the BingamanSpecter bill); that is, unlike ordinary
175
allowances, these additional allowances are not bankable and must be used in
the year they are released. This places an implicit limit on the volume of safetyvalve allowances that might be sold in any year, namely the total volume of
emissions for that year. Thus, under such proposals, one could in principle use
safety-valve allowances to meet all of ones current-year emissions obligations
and bank ordinary allowances for the future. Another wrinkle in the safety-valve
provision of S. 1766 is that the safety valve is only available during one month
each year, while firms are doing final balancing of their emissions and allowance
holdings. This avoids a potential run on the safety valve while Congress might be
debating whether to raise the level or remove the safety valve altogether in the
future a debate that would hopefully be completed during the eleven-month
period when the safety valve is unavailable. We return to this issue below, as it is
not obvious that such a sequence of events is likely.
The allowance reserve takes the price ceiling idea a step further. As just
described, an unlimited nonbankable safety-valve could allow the release of up
to one years worth of emissions at any one time. The allowance reserve,
however, could limit the use of this safety valve to a significantly smaller amount.
The appropriate size of the reserve will ultimately depend on the stringency of the
cap, the ceiling price, and the degree of remaining price volatility that is
acceptable. A reserve of perhaps ten to twenty percent of the annual cap would
reflect the range of emissions reductions sought by many current proposals over
the first decade, coupled with varying assumptions about the price ceiling. The
issue of how to choose the reserve size is further addressed later in this article.
This raises an important question: how does the government allocate the
extra allowances from a reserve if demand exceeds reserve supply at the ceiling
price? There are several ways to do this. These are outlined in detail below, but
perhaps the most compelling is analogous to the price-floor approach, but
instead auctions the reserve allowances with a minimum price that is equal to the
ceiling price (versus the floor price). The result would be: (1) no sales, (2) sales
less than the limit, at the ceiling price, or (3) sales equal to the limit, at or above
the ceiling price. Thus, the allowance reserve does not guarantee the ceiling price
in the same way as an explicit price ceiling or safety valve. On the other hand, as
discussed in the next section, it has several practical and theoretical advantages.
176
177
amended version of the Americas Climate Security Act (S. 3036) in 2008, which
included the allowance reserve idea (Eilperin and Mufson 2008). In this way, a
simple interpretation of the allowance reserve that its additional flexibility can
better represent public interest may be the most relevant argument when
public interest includes not just economic views of optimality but also the
perspective of key stakeholders. In other words, one very practical advantage of
the allowance reserve idea is that it may be able to bridge differences between
environmental advocates seeking a cap on emissions and industrial interests
concerned about costs, in much the same way that some viewed the safety valve
more than a decade ago (Kopp et. al., 1997). Operating under the presumption
that failure to enact a climate policy at all would lower social welfare, all else
equal, a design element such as an allowance reserve that can break an
impasse, can enhance overall efficiency relative to the status quo.
178
All of this points to a potential problem with the ordinary safety valve when it
is coupled with banking and evolving expectations of stricter targets. Under these
circumstances, as firms and individuals become convinced that future prices will
be well above the current safety valve, they will want to make use of the safety
valve as much as possible, acquiring emissions allowances cheaply now that will
quickly become more valuable in the future. Or, if safety valve allowances cannot
be banked, will allow regulated entities to preserve more valuable ordinary
allowances for the future. That is, even without the ability to bank safety-valve
allowances, there is a real possibility of accumulating multiple years worth of
allowances if people become convinced of the impending change many years in
advance. The SO2 trading program, for example, saw more than a years worth
of allowances accumulated early in the program without a safety valve, owing to
the relatively easy targets from 1995 through 1999 and anticipation of stricter
targets legislated for 2000.
The accumulation of a large bank of allowances perhaps more than an
entire years worth of allowances poses two related problems. The first is
superficial: from an appearance standpoint, people may see a run on the safety
valve, and a large accumulation of allowances from it, as a systemic failure. The
second is related, but more substantive: a particularly large bank could begin to
thwart efforts to cut emissions in the future. This is not an issue in the SO2
program because emissions reductions are relatively large compared with
historic emissions fifty percent in the 1990 amendments, starting in 2000, and
fifty percent again in 2010 under the Clean Air Interstate Rule. One years worth
of banked allowances would be used up in two years following a fifty percent cut
(were facilities to try avoiding their fifty percent cut in emissions). In contrast, CO2
emissions reductions are anticipated to occur more slowly as entirely new
technologies cutting across many sectors must be brought into use. A relatively
tough target might mean a ten to twenty percent reduction from baseline within
the first decade, in which case a bank on the order of one year of allowances
could delay such a change for five to ten years without reducing emissions. We
emphasize only that this could (but not necessarily would) be a problem because,
even in the worst case, the tougher target could be designed with the bank in
mind, in much the same way that programs with offset credits from uncapped
sources often seek a tougher target than would be practical if those offset
opportunities did not exist. Further, there is little evidence concerning how large
179
of an allowance bank firms might accumulate (it could, in fact, be much larger
than one years worth of allowances), how fast they might spend it down, and in
turn how much this might affect any future tightening of the cap.
The allowance reserve tackles both potential problems head on by simply
limiting the volume of extra allowances entering the market and therefore
limiting the potential for these extra allowances to contribute to an excessively
large bank. As noted above, existing legislative proposals for a safety valve limit
the released volume to the annual emissions level. With emissions reductions of
perhaps ten to twenty percent per decade, this seems far more than is necessary
to deal with anything except the desire to bank. In this case, an annual allowance
reserve limit of about ten to twenty percent of the cap should be sufficient to
address short-term uncertainty while leaving longer-term expectations free to
drive near-term prices.
180
181
the resolution of cost uncertainty in period 1 are equal to the tax which was set
in period 0. Firms will not match their marginal costs to the expected period 2
marginal costs (updated with new information on both costs and mitigation
benefits in period 1) because there is no incentive to do so. Specifically, there is
no ability to shift compliance obligations from the period with high (expected,
discounted) costs to the one with low (expected, discounted) costs in a tax-based
system. The emissions outcome in the first period would therefore not generally
satisfy the previously mentioned efficiency condition because expectations about
period 2 marginal costs will have changed between periods 0 and 1, but no
responsive action will be taken by the affected parties.
This type of result is inherent in the classic Weitzman framework where
policies are fixed prior to uncertainty being revealed. Neither a price nor (a
nonbankable) quantity policy is optimal ex post because neither exactly matches
realized (or updated expectations about) marginal costs and marginal benefits.
Both instruments are generally inefficient in such a setting, so the issue becomes
one of choosing the instrument with the lowest deadweight loss. Even when
period 1 brings about expected changes in period 2 tax rates, there is virtually no
incentive to deviate from the otherwise standard behavior setting period 1
marginal costs equal to the fixedin- period-0 tax. The only possible incentive to
deviate arises if changed expectations about future tax rates affects investment in
long-lived emissions abatement capital that would be subject to the future tax.
182
183
Neither policy transmits any new information about benefits or future targets. In
contrast, in the dynamic cap-and-trade setting that is relevant here, firms do
have an incentive to adjust under the quantity policy in response to both new cost
and new benefit information because of adjusted expectations about future
targets and marginal costs. While both policies can eventually be adjusted to
achieve the desired target, the dynamic cap-and-trade policy provides a
mechanism for firms to respond during the first period, when policy is fixed,
while the tax does not.
All of this suggests that for a cumulative emissions problem like greenhouse
gases, a capand- trade program with sufficient banking and borrowing can in
principle deliver a better outcome than taxing emissions. This conclusion has
been recognized to some degree for some time (Jacoby and Ellerman 2003).
Extending prior research on optimal banking and borrowing (Rubin 1996, Kling
and Rubin 1997) to a stochastic instrument choice context, Newell et. al., (2005)
rigorously showed how intertemporal banking and borrowing would allow firms
to smooth abatement costs across time, thereby offsetting the traditional
disadvantage of cap-andtrade relative to taxes. They also suggested several
practical mechanisms for implementing such an approach, including an
allowance reserve. What is new here, we believe, is that this is the first time
conventional economics has suggested cap-and-trade can be better than taxbased approaches based on Weitzman-like efficiency grounds, with appropriate
dynamic modifications. The key, as discussed above, is that most previous
analyses have either ignored or underappreciated both the evolution of
information and the dynamic nature of policymaking that are core features of a
long-term problem like climate change as well as the common feature of
banking in most trading programs.
184
that not only is the period 1 cap important; so are expectations (in period 0) of
future marginal costs and allowance prices in period 2, which also depend on
future targets and benefits. The ceiling price in the allowance reserve mechanism
is one way the government can signal an initial expectation about the correct
current and future prices.
A third and important reason for considering an allowance reserve is the
concern that borrowing a key mechanism for dealing with unexpectedly high
costs in the short-term may not work as we have assumed. Borrowing may not
be implemented or it may be constrained in ways that limit its usefulness. To
date, market-based policies have included only limited borrowing mechanisms.
For example, the corporate average fuel economy (CAFE) program for light-duty
vehicles allows a firm to undercomply in a given model year if it repays the
borrowed credits within the subsequent three model years. Meanwhile, there are
examples of exceptionally high prices early in a borrowing-constrained cap-andtrade program as market participants anticipated or experienced a shortage of
allowances. These include both the NOx State Implementation Plan (SIP) Call in
the United States and the EU ETS. In the context of an emissions phasedown of
the type discussed for greenhouse gas policy, a well-designed allowance reserve
would change the market dynamics so that high prices tap the reserve and alter
the market from tending to borrow allowances in the short term to either meeting
demand or potentially banking allowances.
Implementation Issues
We turn next to a number of important practical issues surrounding the
implementation of an allowance reserve. Most immediate are determining the
appropriate ceiling price at which the reserve can be drawn down and the size of
the reserve. Additional issues include whether the reserve expands or attempts to
maintain the cumulative cap, how reserve allowances are introduced to the
market, and whether the reserve design parameters would be managed by an
executive board or decided through legislation.
185
186
187
188
cumulative cap defines the aspirational target of the policy if the reserve is never
tapped and the price remains below the ceiling price. The upper end of the
range, defined by the cumulative effect of tapping the reserve, reflects the
maximum allowable cumulative emissions. Based on the earlier discussion of
how one would set the size of the reserve, this should be sufficient to maintain the
ceiling price unless future expectations drive prices higher.
Just as the approach of system-wide borrowing from future allocations may
make more sense if there is strong societal commitment to a specific cumulative
cap (and a willingness to accept the cost consequences), the cap-range approach
may make more sense if there is strong societal commitment to maintaining
incremental costs below the ceiling price (and a willingness to accept the
emissions consequences). Of course, in either case the long-term cap will
undoubtedly be adjusted in the future; the main issue here is how the
specification of a default cumulative cap (be it larger or smaller) may affect
future expectations and indeed future action. Both approaches address shortterm constraints with an appropriately chosen ceiling price and reserve size.
However, the future borrowing approach, which maintains a predetermined
cumulative cap, may create higher future price expectations and induce more
mitigation than the range approach with the same aspirational cap. On the other
hand, the caps are not exogenous to the choice of design; a range approach
where the aspirational cap is significantly more aggressive than the cap under
the future borrowing approach could create even higher price expectations.
189
190
would be exercised. In the event that allowance prices exceeded the ceiling
(strike) price level, options holders would begin to exercise their option rights, but
would stop once prices fell back below the ceiling price level. One substantive
difference with the reserve auction discussed above is the timing of the allocation
of reserve allowances or options for reserve allowances, with the allocation of
options most likely occurring sooner. Whether this would be an advantage or
disadvantage requires further analysis. Another difference is that under the
option approach, the difference between the market and ceiling price if there is
one goes to the option holder, and options could be either auctioned or
allocated for free. This feature suggests that options could be allocated in a way
to help ensure that legislation passes, but can also create wasteful rent-seeking
behavior.
191
versus containing costs. However, there are a variety of differences (Pizer and
Tatsutani 2008), and this remains an active area of discussion.
Conclusions
While much of the debate in the literature on the economics of climate change
regulation has focused on comparing pure price and pure quantity mechanisms
i.e., taxes versus cap-andtrade these policies are increasingly being viewed as
too extreme to meet both practical and political needs. This article has presented
recent and perhaps provocative new arguments suggesting that a sufficiently
flexible cap-and-trade system can in theory do at least as well as and potentially
better than a tax (despite previous literature pointing the other direction).
However, it is unlikely that the required flexibility to borrow allowances from the
future and the associated requirement for rational expectations in dynamic
allowance markets would be ensured in practice. All of this recommends a hybrid
mechanism. Roberts and Spence (1976) first suggested the idea of a cap-andtrade system with both a floor and ceiling price. We have taken their idea one
step further and suggest that the ceiling price could come with a quantitative
limit: what we call the allowance reserve.
We have argued that the allowance reserve addresses certain shortcomings
of the Roberts and Spence idea, including the need for more flexibility in the
elements of policy design to balance competing political interests. It also solves a
possibly thorny technical problem that arises when the Roberts and Spence idea
is applied in a dynamic world that includes banking and a need to update
policies which has the potential to lead to a run on the price ceiling. But
perhaps most fundamentally, it supports the idea of a flexible cap-and-trade
system that seeks to achieve an intertemporal optimum.
A number of additional details remain to be resolved, most notably setting
the ceiling price and reserve size and how an allowance reserve would be
institutionalized. Other issues tend to be primarily cosmetic or of a more general
nature applicable to any market-based policy. In summary, the allowance
reserve may help solve several previously insurmountable challenges in the
current debate over climate policy design. This paper demonstrates that the
notion of capand- trade with an allowance reserve is more than simply a political
solution. Rather given the considerable uncertainties we face now over the costs
192
Note: CAIR: Clean Air Interstate Rule; FIP: Federal Implementation Plan.
193
Technical Appendix
Consider an effort to seek: min C1 (q1)+C2 (Q q1) where qt is the emissions each
period t, Q is the ultimate cumulative emissions goal (unknown until period 2),
C1 is the cost of emissions level q1(which, unknown until period t, is positive if qt is
below some baseline level and zero otherwise), and the cost functions include
adjustment for discounting to the present.
Given the ultimate resolution of uncertainty in period 2, we know costs in
period 2 are C2 (Qq1) and it would therefore be optimal to choose q1 such that
C1 (q1) = C2 (Q q1) With the information available when q1 has to be chosen,
the best practical outcome would be C1 (q1) = E1 [C2 (Q q1)], where E1 reflects
the expectation formed in period 1 about the costs and target set in period 2.
An optimizing government setting a period 1 tax, t1, in period 0 would
choose t1 = E0 [C1(q1)] where q1 satisfies E0 [C1(q1)] = E0 [C2 (Q q1)], thereby
minimizing expected costs as seen in period 0. Firms would then choose to emit
q1 such that t1 = C1(q1), given the resolution of cost uncertainty in period 1. This
outcome for q1 would not generally satisfy the efficiency condition, C1 (q1) = E1
[C2 (Q q1)] because E1 [C2 (Q q1)] will not generally equal E0 [C2 (Q q1)] =
t1 = C1 (q1) under the tax.
Now imagine the government instead sets a cap q1 in period 0 and a
second period cap q 2 to deliver the ultimate objective Q = q 1 + q 2. Note that
with second period cap q 2, if firms have banked q 1 q1 at the end of period 1,
in period 2 emissions would be Q q1 and marginal costs would be C2 (Q q1).
In this setting, a cost-minimizing firm would choose q1 such that C1 (q1) = E1 [C2
(Q q1)] regardless of the first period cap.
194
Appendix
Figure 1: Emissions and Price Outcomes under Cap-and-Trade versus Emissions Fee/Tax
195
Anda, Jason Grumet, Suzanne Leonard, Tim Profeta, Nicole St. Clair, Robert
Stavins, Tracy Terry, an anonymous referee, and participants at the Resources for
the Future workshop, Managing Costs in a US GHG Trading Program, (Pizer
and Tatsutani 2008) for their insights and suggestions on this issue.
References
Argus Media. 2008. Markets Slowed by CAIR Concerns. Argus Air Daily, May 30, 15 (104).
Eilperin, Juliet, and Steven Mufson. 2008. Climate Bill Underlines Obstacles to Capping
Greenhouse Gases. Washington Post, June 1, A12.
Energy Information Administration (EIA). 2008. Energy Market and Economic Impacts of
S. 2191, the LiebermanWarner Climate Security Act of 2007. April. Report
SR/OIAF/2008-01. Washington, DC: EIA.
Hoel, Michael, and Larry Karp. 2002. Taxes versus Quotas for a Stock Pollutant. Resource
and Energy Economics 24: 367384.
Jacoby, H.J., and A.D. Ellerman. 2003. The Safety Valve and Climate Policy. Energy Policy
32(4): 481491.
Kerr, Suzi and Richard G. Newell. 2003. Policy-Induced Technology Adoption: Evidence
from the U.S, Lead Phasedown. Journal of Industrial Economics 51(3):271-343.
Kling, C., and J. Rubin. 1997. Bankable Permits for the Control of Environmental
Pollution. Journal of Public Economics 64(1): 10115.
Kolstad, C.D. 1996. Learning and Stock Effects in Environmental Regulation: The Case of
Greenhouse Gas Emissions. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 31(1):
118.
Kopp, Raymond, Richard Morgenstern, and William Pizer. 1997. Something for Everyone:
A Climate Policy that Both Environmentalists and Industry Can Live With.Weathervane.
Washington, DC: Resources for the Future. http://www.weathervane.rff.org/Something
ForEveryone.pdf.
Murray, Brian, and Martin Ross. 2007. The LiebermanWarner Americas Climate Security
Act: A Preliminary Assessment of Potential Economic Impacts. Policy Brief NI PB 0704.
Durham, NC: Nicholas Institute for Environmental Policy Solutions, Duke University.
Newell, Richard G., and William A. Pizer. 2003. Regulating Stock Externalities under
Uncertainty. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 45: 416432.
Newell, Richard G., William A. Pizer, and Jiangfeng Zhang. 2005. Managing Permit
Markets to Stabilize Prices. Environmental and Resource Economics 31: 133157.
Paltsev, Sergey, John M. Reilly, Henry D. Jacoby, Angelo C. Gurgel, Gilbert E. Metcalf,
Andrei P. Sokolov, and Jennifer F. Holak. 2007. Assessment of US Cap-and-Trade
Proposals. Report 146. Cambridge, MA: MIT Joint Program on the Science and Policy of
Global Change.
196
Pizer, William A. 2002. Combining Price and Quantity Controls to Mitigate Global
Climate Change. Journal of Public Economics 85(3): 409434.
Pizer, William A. and Marika Tatsutani. 2008. Managing Costs in a US Greenhouse Gas
Trading Program: A Workshop Summary. Discussion paper 08-23. Washington, DC:
Resources for the Future.
Roberts, M.J., and M. Spence. 1976. Effluent Charges and Licenses under Uncertainty.
Journal of Public Economics 5(34): 193208.
Rubin, J.D. 1996. A Model of Intertemporal Emission Trading, Banking, and Borrowing.
Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 31: 269286.
Samuelsohn, Darren. 2008. Behind Safety Valve Debate Resides 30+ Years of History.
ClimateWire, March 11.
US Environmental Protection Agency. 2005. Rule to Reduce Interstate Transport of Fine
Particulate Matter and Ozone (Clean Air Interstate Rule); Revisions to Acid Rain Program;
Revisions to the NOX SIP Call. Federal Register 70(91): 2516225405.
US Environmental Protection Agency. 2008. EPA Analysis of the LiebermanWarner
Climate Security Act of 2008: S. 2191 in 110th Congress. http://www.epa.gov/
climatechange/downloads/s2191_EPA_Analysis.pdf.
Unold, Wolfram, and Till Requate. 2001. Pollution Control by Options Trading. Economics
Letters 73: 353358.
Weitzman, Martin L. 1974. Prices vs. Quantities. Review of Economic Studies 41(4): 477491.
Endnotes
1
These two allowance supply approaches are shown in Appendix Figure 1 along with
two alternative outcomes for emissions demand.
197
above the safety valve price. Assuming the safety valve price is set appropriately,
however, this is desirable because environmental policies should not, from an
economic perspective, seek to promote technology at any cost. Rather policies
should induce an efficient amount of innovation and adoption, consistent with
societal willingness to pay (Kerr and Newell 2003).
4
If the execution date is not constrained in this way, it would create a very important
difference: the effective annual reserve could accumulate over time if options
accumulate, unexercised, year- after- year. If options can be executed well before the
true-up period, reserve allowances could enter the system based on early
expectations of high prices which, by the time the true up period arrives, have been
revised.
8
Greenhouse Gas Emissions Charges
and Credits on Agricultural Land:
What can a Model Tell Us?
Joanna Hendy,* Suzi Kerr** and Troy Baisden***
Using the simulation model Land Use in Rural New Zealand
version 1 climate (LURNZv1-climate), we simulate the effects
of an agricultural land-use emissions charge and a reward for
native forest and scrub regeneration. Our results are preliminary
and at this stage should be considered illustrative. We find that,
on its own, an agricultural emissions charge based on solely on
land use would be disruptive and may not be very effective in
reducing emissions. In addition, we find that including an
additional policy that rewards regenerating forest and scrub
without a similar reward for plantation forestry might negatively
impact on plantation forestry, increasing emissions growth in the
short-run. We are currently developing a second version of
LURNZ-climate, which will be more robust and thus lend more
weight to our future results.
*
**
199
1. Introduction
Policies designed to mitigate greenhouse gas emissions through the Kyoto
Protocol have the potential to create political firestorms. In 2003, the government
proposed the ill-fated fart tax this small research levy ignited a damaging
political firestorm despite representing a charge of only 25 cents per tonne
carbon dioxide equivalent. This levy pales in comparison to the price of
European Union Allowances, which have exceeded NZ$50 per tonne in March
and April 2006 before falling back dramatically. Was the outrage all hot air? We
use the simulation model Land Use in Rural New Zealand climate (LURNZ
climate) to explore the impacts of high emissions charges (NZ$50 per tonne) on
productive land uses including dairying, sheep and beef agriculture, and forestry.
The results demonstrate the potential connections between greenhouse gas
mitigation policies across sectors. We examine the large economic and
potentially quite small emissions impacts that could result from exposing
agriculture to the international emissions price. We also examine the land use
and emissions implications of proposed policies that would give landowners
emissions credits for regenerating indigenous forest and scrub. In the absence of
a parallel policy for production forestry, the results are surprising and potentially
disappointing for proponents of biodiversity.
2. About LURNZ-climate
To examine the impacts of devolving Kyoto credits and liabilities for emissions
and sinks to land owners, economists at Motu Economic and Public Policy
Research, and scientists at institutes including Landcare Research, AgResearch,
Scion/Ensis (Forest Research), and NIWA have combined their efforts to develop
LURNZ-climate. Based on economics and natural science, LURNZ-climate is a
computer model that simulates the effect of climate change related government
policies on rural land use in New Zealand. LURNZ-climate predicts land-use
change at a fine spatial scale over the whole country, producing dynamic paths
of rural land-use change and maps of rural land use across New Zealand. In
addition, LURNZ-climate calculates the greenhouse gas implications of land-use
change. With the development of LURNZ-climate, New Zealand now has the
capacity to empirically investigate the potential impacts of policies designed to
alter land-use decisions, including policies such as a charge to farmers in
proportion to the amount of methane and nitrous oxide their livestock emit and a
reward for regenerating indigenous forest and scrub.
200
201
detail in Kerr and Hendy (2006). LURNZv1 uses these estimated relationships to
predict short run land-use adjustment to economic shocks and long run
equilibrium land use at the national level. LURNZv1 then uses spatial algorithms
to map predicted changes across New Zealand, based on the assumption that,
in response to an economic shock, it is marginal land that will change land use
first. LURNZv1 is explained in more detail in Hendy, Kerr, and Baisden (2006).
The greenhouse gas module in LURNZv1-climate includes functions that
project land-use related greenhouse gas emissions per unit of economic activity.
The functions are simple; are based on readily available data and strong
science; are consistent with the national inventory in 2002; evolve so that implied
net emissions approximately match past inventory totals (1990-2002); and can
be linked easily to a variety of models so they can be used in simulations.
Combined with simple projections of the intensity of land-use for each land-use
type, the greenhouse gas module calculates emissions associated with one
hectare of each land use. This is explained in more detail in Hendy and Kerr
(2005) and Hendy and Kerr (2006). Finally, combining the predictions of landuse change with the projections of land-use emissions per hectare, LURNZv1climate calculates the emissions implications of land-use change.
For the remainder of this Article we discuss results produced from LURNZv1climate. Given that the relationships driving the land-use responses in LURNZv1climate are still under development, the underlying mechanisms of the model will
be examined further before results can be considered robust in terms of timing or
magnitude. Thus, the results presented should be taken as qualitative illustrations
of issues arising from the modelled policies.
202
gas emissions (Brown and Plume, 2004). Therefore, reducing land-use emissions
could significantly help New Zealand to meet its target and contribute efficiently
to controlling greenhouse gases. A potential policy to help encourage emission
reductions would be to charge farmers in proportion to the amount of emissions
that their animal production produces. This would lead farmers to reduce area in
livestock and particularly in dairy, reduce stocking rates and, if possible, change
farm management to reduce emissions per animal. Current methane and nitrous
oxide monitoring technology makes accurate animal or farm-scale monitoring of
emissions impossible. The proposed policy related payments only to livestock
numbers, which can be monitored. Because of current limitations in LURNZ, we
model an even simpler policy where the government simply charges farmers in
proportion to their land area in each land use, and assumes that each farm
emits an average amount per hectare. This is a less flexible policy because
farmers cannot change their stocking rates in response to the charge. We
therefore underestimate the size of the likely response to a charge based on
livestock numbers.
If dairy farmers were charged $50 for every tonne of carbon dioxide
equivalent emitted in 2002, based on average values, their income would
decrease 60 cents for each kilogram of milk solids that they produced. On
average in 2002, farmers received $5.31 per kilogram of milk solids, so this
charge would have equated to an 11% reduction in revenue. If sheep/beef
farmers were charged the same amount per tonne of carbon dioxide equivalent,
they would pay 85 cents for every kilogram of combined meat and wool,
equivalent to a 22% reduction in revenue. The impact of these revenue
reductions can be measured against net profits, which were $126,469 for dairy
farms and $113,303 for sheep/beef farms when averaged over the last five
years (New Zealand. Ministry of Agriculture and Forestry, 2001-2005a and
2001-2005b). This charge would have reduced net profits by $48,693 for the
average dairy farm and $38,116 for the average sheep/beef farm. These
impacts would directly lower land values and hence farmer wealth.
The charge would also affect people other than farmers, as the indirect
effects would spread out through the economy. Farmers, who would have to pay
the huge cost, would likely reduce their spending. This would negatively affect
their communities, in particular including laying off farm workers or lowering
203
their wages. Farm workers in return would reduce their own expenditure. Thus,
the effects of the charge would flow on through the economy. Sin et. al., (2004)
found that the areas likely to be hardest hit by an emissions charge would be
Gore and MacKenzie in the South Island, and Taihape, Waipukurau, Te Kuiti and
Dannevirke in the North Island. The effect on the economy as a whole may not
be large after an initial period of adjustment if the revenue from the charge were
recycled into other tax cuts, but the transfers of income between people and the
dislocation in some communities would be significant.
In response to such a policy, some marginal land is likely to change to a
lower emitting land use. If, for example, sheep/beef farming on a parcel of
marginal land is no longer profitable, the land is likely to enter plantation
forestry or a state, which we refer to as regenerating forest and scrub, in which
no economic activity is discernable. It is also likely that some land will move from
dairy to sheep/beef (or not convert to dairy as soon if dairy prices and
conversions continue to be high). For example, facing such a charge, farms
considering converting to dairy would find that the difference between their
current returns in sheep/beef farming and the returns they could potentially earn
in dairy would be reduced. This is because dairy farming has higher emissions
per hectare than sheep/beef farming so they face a higher charge. For some
farms on the margin for conversion to dairy, this effect might be large enough to
make sheep/beef more profitable than dairy, and so these farms might choose
not to convert and thereby reduce New Zealands total emissions. In all cases,
the resulting land-use changes will result in lower emitting land use, achieving
the goal of the policy. However, the costs to enterprises and rural economies
may be sufficiently large that the policy is not currently justified, relative to other
policies that would induce emissions reductions in other sectors.
To examine the impact of a NZ$50 per tonne of carbon dioxide equivalent
charge on New Zealand agriculture, we ask, how big would the corresponding
emissions reductions be? To answer this, we first need to know what would have
happened if no policy was introduced. To tell us this, we simulate a reference
case scenario. The reference case gives us a line against which we can measure
the effectiveness of the policy, allowing us to observe the magnitude of the policy
effect and discern whether the policy is achieving its intended result.
204
For our reference case, we project changes in land use and emissions from
2003 to 2012, using Ministry of Agriculture and Forestry forecasts of commodity
prices and assuming that both the interest rate and the area of non-rural land
are constant. Based on this scenario, LURNZv1 projects that by 2012 dairy area
will expand by 1.2% (18,000ha), sheep/beef area will contract by 2.8%
(199,000ha), plantation forestry will expand by 17.4% (273,000ha), and
regenerating forest and scrub will contract by 5.5% (92,000ha) compared to
2002. The solid line in the figure shows the corresponding agricultural emissions
for the reference case over the period. The emissions are calculated as total
methane and nitrous oxide emissions from dairy, sheep, and beef livestock, and
fertiliser use, net of carbon dioxide removed by plantation forests and
regenerating indigenous forest and scrub.
To find out how much the charge would reduce emissions, we model the
charge as a reduction in the commodity price that farmers receive, assuming that
farmers will respond to the charge in the same way as a commodity price shock.
From 2003 onwards, we reduce the commodity prices relative to those we used
in the reference case by the equivalent of 60 cents for milk solids and 85 cents
205
for meat and wool; these reductions correspond to a charge of $50 per tonne of
carbon dioxide equivalent. We expect that, when compared to the reference
case, dairy would expand less, sheep/beef would contract more, plantation
forests would expand more, and regenerating forest and scrub would contract
less. As a result, we expect that the rise in emissions would be reduced and
indeed this is the case. The dashed line in the figure shows net emissions
associated with this scenario.
We find that dairy area contracts by 1% with the policy, whereas in the
reference case it expanded by 1.2%. Sheep/beef area contracts by 0.3
percentage points more than in the reference case, plantation forestry stays
about the same, and regenerating forest and scrub contracts by 3.8 percentage
points less than in the reference case. The land-use change caused by the policy
reduces the annual growth rate in emissions during 2003 2012 from about 0.5
million tonnes of carbon dioxide equivalent per year in the reference case to
about 0.4 million tonnes of carbon dioxide equivalent per year.
The lower emissions rate from a charge based on land use equates to a 6%
relative reduction in emissions over the first commitment period. This is a small
reduction for a large emissions price. The result therefore suggests that an
emissions tax levied on agriculture will result in relatively small reductions in
emissions, relative to reductions in the profitability of farming that are likely to
flow through the economy. Thus, a policy levying an emissions charge on
agriculture based on emissions per hectare remains a relatively poor policy
option, presuming that significant impacts on land values rural workers and rural
communities cannot be addressed. It is possible however, that the current model
underestimates the magnitude of change that could be achieved through slightly
more targeted policies. A more sophisticated policy, such as a policy where the
government monitored livestock numbers and fertiliser use within each land use,
could give more dimensions along which farmers could reduce their emissions.
206
207
regenerating forest and scrub remove much less carbon dioxide from the
atmosphere than young plantation forests. This is a short-term problem; in the
long run, removals by naturally regenerating vegetation surpass those by
plantation forestry. However, this effect would actually make meeting our
obligations for the first Kyoto commitment period more difficult.
This result suggests that the PFSI has the potential to achieve a perverse
result during 20082012, by actually making New Zealands net position under
the Kyoto Protocol worse. Rather than suggesting that the PFSI is poor policy, this
result emphasizes that even policies with the potential to produce multiple
environmental benefits such as the PFSI must be considered as part of an overall
picture. In this case, the PFSI would be enhanced if plantation forestry were
rewarded for carbon sequestration as well. Our preliminary results suggest that
the government should consider also rewarding plantation forestry particularly if
they want short-term emission gains.
Similarly, the impacts of levying a charge on land use related emissions
from agriculture would ideally be examined in the context of carbon charges or
emissions trading in the fossil fuel sector. This is not possible with any current
model.
5. Summary
These illustrative simulations demonstrate that LURNZv1-climate is a useful tool
for analysing potential greenhouse gas mitigation policies intended to reward or
tax emissions resulting from land use activities. Our first simulation indicates that
an agricultural emissions charge based simply on land use would be highly
disruptive and may not be very effective in reducing emissions. Our second
simulation shows that the inclusion of a reward for regenerating forest and scrub
without a similar reward for plantation forestry might negatively impact on
plantation forestry, increasing emissions growth in the short-run. This
demonstrates the potential for policies to have unintended, and potentially
perverse impacts when policies are not aligned across sectors.
The model results illustrate the importance of careful empirical analysis of
potential policies, and emphasize the need for tools such as LURNZ that are
applicable to New Zealands unique situation. The results presented here are
208
preliminary in that they illustrate the probable scale and direction of policy
impacts but the exact size of those impacts may not be robust. We are currently
developing a second version of LURNZ-climate, which will be much more robust,
and thus lend more weight to our future results.
Finally, when developing LURNZv1-climate we used publicly available data
whenever it was available. We did this to support our aim of making both
LURNZ-climate and the LURNZ-climate database freely available for research
purposes whenever possible. We hope others will use our data and model to
explore these issues further. For more information, please visit www.motu.org.nz/
land_use_nz.htm.
Acknowledgements
This research is part of Motus Land Use, Climate Change and Kyoto research
programme, which is carried out in collaboration with Landcare Research and
others. This research programme is funded by a grant from the Foundation for
Research, Science and Technology. We would like to thank participants of Motus
Land Use, Climate Change and Kyoto: Human dimensions research to guide
New Zealand policy research workshops between 2002 and 2005, for their
input into the development of the fundamental project, which this report relies
on. Any remaining errors or omissions are the responsibility of the authors.
References
Brown, Len and Helen Plume. 2004. New Zealands Greenhouse Gas Inventory 1990
2002: The National Inventory Report and Common Reporting Format Tables, National
Inventory Report, New Zealand Climate Change Office, Wellington.
Hall, Graeme M. J. 2001. Mitigating an Organizations Future Net Carbon Emissions by
Native Forest Restoration, Ecological Applications, 11:6, pp. 1622-33.
Hendy, Joanna and Suzi Kerr. 2005. Greenhouse Gas Emissions Factor Module: Land
Use in Rural New Zealand-Climate Version 1, Motu Working Paper 05-10, Motu
Economic and Public Policy Research, Wellington, NZ.
Hendy, Joanna and Suzi Kerr. 2006. Land Use Intensity Module: Land Use in Rural New
Zealand-Climate Version 1, Draft Motu Working Paper, Motu Economic and Public Policy
Research, Wellington, NZ.
Hendy, Joanna; Suzi Kerr and Troy Baisden. 2006. The Land Use in Rural New Zealand
(LURNZ) Model: Version 1 Model Description, Draft Motu Working Paper, Motu Economic
and Public Policy Research, Wellington, NZ.
209
Kerr, Suzi and Joanna Hendy. 2006. Drivers of Rural Land Use in New Zealand:
Estimates from National Data, Draft Motu Working Paper, Motu Economic and Public
Policy Research, Wellington, NZ.
New Zealand. Ministry of Agriculture and Forestry. 2001-2005a. Dairy Monitoring
Report, MAF Policy, Ministry of Agriculture and Forestry, Wellington.
New Zealand. Ministry of Agriculture and Forestry. 2001-2005b. Sheep and Beef
Monitoring Report, MAF Policy, Ministry of Agriculture and Forestry, Wellington.
Sin, Isabelle; Emma Brunton, Joanna Hendy and Suzi Kerr. 2005. The Likely Regional
Impacts of an Agricultural Emissions Policy in New Zealand: Preliminary Analysis, Motu
Working Paper 05-08, Motu Economic and Public Policy Research, Wellington, NZ.
Trotter, Craig M.; Kevin R. Tate, Neal A. Scott, Jacqueline A. Townsend, R. Hugh Wilde,
Suzanne M. Lambie, Mike Marden and Ted Pinkney. 2005. Afforestation/Reforestation of
New Zealand Marginal Pasture Lands by Indigenous Shrublands: the Potential for Kyoto
Forest Sinks, Annals of Forest Science, 62:8, pp. 865-71.
List of Cases
Armco, Inc., v. Hardesty, 467 US 638, 644 (1984).
Assoc. Indus. of Mo. v. Lohman, 511 US 641, 647 (1994).
Fulton Corp., v. Faulkner, 516 US 325, 331 (1996).
Henneford v. Silas Mason Co., 300 US 577 (1937).
Hughes v. Oklahoma, 441 US 322, 32526 (1979).
Maine v. Taylor, 477 US 131, 15152 (1986).
Maryland v. Louisiana, 451 US 725, 760 (1981).
New Energy Co., of Ind. v. Limbach, 486 US 269, 278 (1988).
New State Ice Co., v. Liebmann, 285 US 262, 311 (1932).
Or. Waste Sys., Inc., v. Dept of Envtl. Quality, 511 US 93, 9899 (1994).
Index
A
Animating, 87
Malleable, 170
Articulates, 87
Maneuvre, 67
Combustion, 8, 9, 17
Congruence, 89
Counterfactual, 15, 35
Discernable, 204
Plummet, 175
Dubious, 51, 67
Exogenously, 186
Putative, 133
Firestorms, 200
Ramifications, 40
G
Grazing Lands, 109, 110
H
Hazards, 15, 88
I
Intertemporal Arbitrage, 169
L
Landfill, 37, 41
S
Sequestration, 9, 107, 111, 116, 121, 208
Seriatim., 15
Simulation, 198, 200, 208
Skepticism, 4
Spearheading, 43
T
Throughput, 88
212
Unpalatable, 188
Wastelands, 110
Vulnerable, 61
Yearnings, 5
Snap Shot
There is enormous pressure for framing a comprehensive international regulatory framework to deal with
key issues like leakage, permanence, boundary issues and allocation of liabilities in CCS technology.
This book provides contemporary attempts of various developed Nations in successfully implementing CDM
sequestrisation schemes and Joint Implementation projects It would be of great use to the students, research
scholars, faculty in Environmental Law, Environmental science, entrepreneurs, corporate entities, regulatory
authorities, policy makers, CDM and joint implementation project developers.