Competition For Competitiveness
Competition For Competitiveness
Competition For Competitiveness
ISBN 978-90-9023150-1
All rights reserved. Save exceptions stated by law, no part of this publication may be
reproduced, stored in a retrieval system of any nature, or transmitted in any form or by any
means, electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording or otherwise, included a complete
or partial transcription, without the prior written permission of the author, application for
which should be addressed to the author.
VRIJE UNIVERSITEIT
ACADEMISCH PROEFSCHRIFT
ter verkrijging van de graad Doctor aan
de Vrije Universiteit Amsterdam,
op gezag van de rector magnificus
prof.dr. L.M. Bouter,
in het openbaar te verdedigen
ten overstaan van de promotiecommissie
van de faculteit der Sociale Wetenschappen
op donderdag 19 juni 2008 om 10.45 uur
in de aula van de universiteit,
De Boelelaan 1105
door
Angela Wigger
geboren te Luzern, Zwitserland
promotoren:
Thesis Committee:
Dr. M. Cini
Prof. dr. M.-L. Djelic
Prof. dr. L. Hooghe
Prof. dr. H. Kassim
Dr. L. McGowan
Prof. dr. J.Winter
Contents
Figures and Tables
viii
Index of Acronyms
ix
Acknowledgements
xii
Introduction
13
14
17
1.1
19
1.1.1
20
1.1.2
22
1.2
25
1.3
27
1.3.1
29
1.3.2
35
1.3.3
39
43
2.1
44
46
2.2
46
2.2.1
47
2.2.2
Article 86 and 87
49
2.2.3
2.3
49
51
2.3.1
51
2.3.2
2.3.3
2.4
2.5
2.5.1
61
2.5.2
62
65
2.5.3
68
2.5.4
72
2.7
56
2.6
53
74
74
76
2.7.1
76
77
2.7.3
79
2.7.4
2.8
80
84
87
2.8.2
90
2.8.3
95
ii
101
102
3.1
Monopolistic Capitalism
102
3.2
103
3.2.1
106
3.2.2
108
110
3.3
3.4
111
Post-War Germany
116
3.4.1
118
124
3.5.1
125
3.5.2
128
131
131
3.6.1
132
3.6.2
135
3.6.3
3.7
121
137
142
3.7.1
143
3.7.2
147
iii
151
154
4.1
4.2
155
161
162
164
4.3
168
4.4
169
4.5
171
172
4.6
172
175
178
182
4.8
4.9
183
185
187
189
190
192
iv
197
199
5.2
200
203
209
210
5.4
213
5.5
5.6
216
5.5.1
216
5.5.2
218
5.5.3
221
224
5.6.
225
5.6.2
5.6.3
De Havilland Merger
227
230
233
6.1
234
6.2
235
6.3
242
6.3.1
245
6.3.2
246
6.3.3
6.4
249
251
253
6.4.2
260
6.4.3
261
265
7.2
267
268
7.3
267
269
272
7.3.1
275
7.3.2
7.3.3
Men Report
278
280
7.4
7.5
283
286
286
290
vi
294
299
8.2
301
305
8.1.2
306
8.1.3
308
310
Competition Test
310
311
Cui Bono? The Driving Forces in the Reform Process and Their Agendas 313
8.3.1
Regulation 1/2003
313
8.3.2
317
8.3.3
8.3.4
321
8.4
323
326
331
332
339
References
343
Samenvatting
381
vii
Figure 1:
Figure 2:
47
of Regulation 17
58
Figure 3:
75
Table 1:
50
Table 2:
68
Table 3:
76
Table 4:
90
viii
Index of Acronyms
AAA
ABA
APEC
ASEAN
ASU
BASF
BDI
BEUC
CAG
CBI
CCBE
CDU
CEECs
CET
CFI
CFP
CFSP
CNPF
COPA
CSU
DG
DG IV
DG COMP
DIAC
DoJ
ECB
ECN
ECJ
ECSC
EEA
EEC
ix
EFTA
JHA
EMU
EP
European Parliament
ERP
ERT
ESA
ESCB
ETUC
EVV
FDI
FTC
FDP
GATT
GATS
GDP
HSR
IAA
IAEAA
IAR
IBA
ICC
ICI
ICN
ICPAC
ICT
IMF
ITO
JHA
LDC
M&As
MEP
MFN
Most-Favoured-Nation Treatment
MIT
MNCs
Multinational Corporations
MRA
NAFTA
NCAs
NIEO
NIS
NTA
NTBs
OECD
OFT
OPEC
PCA
PJCC
QMV
R&D
SMEs
SLC
TABD
TACD
TAED
TAFTA
TEC
TEU
TNCs
Transnational Companies
ToA
Treaty of Amsterdam
TRIMs
TRIPs
UEAPME
UCLA
UNCTAD
UNICE
WTO
WGTCP
VAT
xi
Acknowledgements
As it is often the case, the impetus for writing a Ph.D. thesis can be traced back to a Master
thesis, leaving still too many questions without a conclusive answer. Once I had finished
my thesis on The Vertical and Horizontal Dimensions of Multi-Level Governance in
European Competition Policy: The Role of Policy Networks in Competition Governance
in 2003, I was offered the opportunity to embark on a Ph.D. project at the Vrije
Universiteit in Amsterdam, and to make competition policy the central focus of my
research. The field has occupied my attention ever since, and is likely to continue to do so
for another while. Retrospectively, however, my very first encounter with competition
policy was anything but love at first sight. I could not be enkindled when I read my first
chapter on competition policy in a textbook on EU politics and governance. Even though I
was genuinely interested in political economy themes, the field of competition policy and
the many tedious technical details that come with it seemed utterly boring to me. It should
therefore not surprise that I initially hesitated when Henk Overbeek, then my Master thesis
supervisor, suggested investigating the recent developments in the field of EU competition
policy as a possible research topic. Having no alternatives ready at hand, I completed my
first share of reading with moderate interest. This changed when I realised that the
formulation of competition policy constitutes a profoundly political process, involving
many underlying conflicting stakes of societal groups. The fact that competition, and rules
controlling competition pertain on important questions regarding the distribution and
concentration of economic wealth, not only in domestic market settings, but also on a
global scale, awoke my interest. My affinity and fascination with competition laws and the
policy of enforcement have since then only been growing.
This dissertation could not have been written without the support of a number of people. I
would like to mention the most important ones. To begin with, I would like to thank my
two supervisors Henk Overbeek and Andreas Nlke. Henk, you have drawn my attention
to the topic of competition policy when I was still a graduate student. Without this stimulus
and your conviction that this was indeed a highly interesting research topic, this
dissertation would never have been written. Andreas, you were enthusiastic about this topic
from the very beginning when you embarked on the role of a supervisor at a later stage.
Writing a co-authored article together with you was a very enjoyable experience, which
xiii
In the same vein, I also would like to thank the other members and friends of the
Amsterdam Research Centre for Corporate Governance Regulation (ARCCGOR), Bastiaan
van Apeldoorn, Laura Horn, James Perry, and Arjan Vliegenthart, for the stimulating and
lively discussions, and regular advice and critical feedback on my work. I have learnt a lot
from you, and I am very grateful for that. In particular, I would like to thank Laura Horn.
Your persistent input into ARCCGOR, your enthusiasm and tenacity in organising
meetings, workshops, and conference panels were decisive for making ARCCGOR such a
success. On personal grounds, your sharp analytical mind, your humour, as well as your
encouragement and advice have been a precious source of inspiration and motivation for
me. Special thanks must also be given to Hubert Buch-Hansen. The unique insights of your
work, our conversations and joint projects have improved my work immensely, and made
me sharpen my argument. I look forward to continuing to work together with you in the
future. I am also very grateful to my former colleagues at the Department of Political
Science at the Vrije Universiteit more generally for the pleasant working environment, and
for contemplating on different approaches to social science. My then room mates and
friends, Tanja Aalberts and Gea Wijers, deserve special thanks for their support and
intellectual input. Furthermore, I would like to thank the broad range of colleagues who
provided me with valuable feedback and comments at various international conferences
and workshops, and anonymously refereerd reports on submitted manuscripts at academic
journals. I am also very grateful to all the experts working in the competition field who
have agreed to be interviewed for their enthusiasm, their detailed information on their daily
working practice, as well as for having forgotten the time during the interview.
xiv
Last but not least, I would like to give special thanks to my family and friends. Kees-Jan,
your love and patient support were indispensable during the course of this dissertation
project, particularly as you have always reminded me to relativise my work and take the
necessary distance. With all my heart, I am deeply grateful for that and more! I am also
immensely grateful to Maya. You have been a true friend in all those years. You have
continuously encouraged me and offered me hands-on support whenever I needed it. In the
last stages of this dissertation, your professional assistance was vital. Finally, I would like
to thank my parents Martin and Elisabeth Wigger for their continued understanding and
enduring support over many years, which allowed me to further my academic career. It is
to you that this dissertation is dedicated. Merci!
xv
In reality [] the aim of antitrust legislation has very little to do with consumers.
The protection of the interest of consumers (if this is the case) is a by-product (in
spite of claims to the contrary) rather than being the primary purpose of this
legislation. The protection of the interest of the tiny majority of the powerful is
smuggled into the collective consciousness as being the protection of the
overwhelming majority of the society.
Guglielmo Carchedi (2001: 136)
An open, competitive Single Market is Europes biggest asset, unique in the world.
Competition policy and effective enforcement will secure a level playing field so all
operators in the Single Market compete and win on merit alone. This is what generates
investment, efficiency, and innovation.
Neelie Kroes, EU Competition Commissioner (2006a)
Introduction
Competition policy constitutes one of the core policy areas of the European Union (EU). In
the Treaty of Rome of 1957, establishing the European Economic Community (EEC),
competition laws received a strong constitutional status, laying the legal basis for a system
ensuring that competition in the internal market is not distorted (Article 3(f)). The actual
competition provisions were included and stipulated in a section entitled Rules of
Competition, in the Articles 85-90. After the renumbering through the Treaty of
Amsterdam (ToA), they became Articles 81, 82 and 86 to 89, comprising four components
dealing with cartels and restrictive business practices (Article 85), abuse of dominant
position (86), public undertakings (90), and state aid (92). In the view of the Treaty
drafters, the inclusion of this market regulatory field to the supranational level served the
purpose of setting in motion the dynamics of the European economic integration project,
or, what in EU jargon was coined at a later stage as the creation of a level playing field.
Shortly after its inauguration, the European Commissions Directorate General (DG)
Competition (formerly DG IV) was entrusted with far-reaching investigatory and
decisional powers in the enforcement of competition laws. To date, there is no comparable
Community pillar policy, in which the Commission enjoys similar wide-ranging
competences, and in which the Council of the European Union and the European
Parliament have so little to say. The centralisation of competition control at supranational
Community level that is the enforcement of EC competition laws was pivotal to the
creation of market capitalism in the region, and paramount to the persistent continuity in
which the economic integration project advanced. By being genuinely focused on market
making, EC competition laws aimed at opening up Member States markets to foreign
competition, and removing obstacles to cross-border economic transactions imposed by
private market actors, as well as Member State governments. The right to compete in the
common market granted companies the right to freely access the domestic markets of other
Member States.
The dissertation employs a critical political economy perspective, with which it seeks to
grasp the transformation of EU competition laws and enforcement practices by relating it
to broader socioeconomic material and ideational changes. It departs from the notion that
law is frozen politics, and that the policy choices regarding the enforcement of laws are
driven by a complex interplay between influential sociopolitical forces, located in
particular macroeconomic realities, and adhering to particular ideas on how to organize the
market place. Reforms usually mark the end of certain ideological beliefs, and the
consolidation of new ideas that evolved in the time before the finalisation of the reform.
Competition policy is a genuinely multidisciplinary policy field, in which political,
economic, and legal thinking cannot be viewed independently from each other. Nor can
competition policy be viewed independently from economic realities. Although dominant
ideas (knowledge, norms, and convictions) are not always reducible to material factors, the
dissertation argues that the ascendancy of new ideas in EU competition policy needs to be
understood in the context of capitalist restructuring in Europe, unleashed by the process of
economic and political integration of markets in Europe, as well as increasingly on a global
scale. Based on a longitudinal analysis, the dissertation links the evolution of EC
competition policy in the late 1950s, and the subsequent development of the enforcement
practices in the 1960s, 1970s, and early 1980s to a structural shift of corporate orientation
from competition in national markets to competition in the single European market. In this
period, competition policy formed part of the institutional nexus of the post-War order of
embedded liberalism. The subsequent transformation starting in the mid-1980s, found its
origins in the disruption of the post-war social order, and the rise of neoliberalism. It was
accompanied by a shift in corporate orientation from competition in the common European
market to competition in the global market place. The dissertation argues that the direction
dissertation argues, moreover, that the transformation of the EU competition regime needs
to be placed in the context of underlying competitive tensions between the US as the EU as
major trading partners. This is particularly reflected in the transatlantic cohabitation in
setting the parameters of how cross-border competition questions should be addressed.
What initially had the shape of a friendly rivalry between EU and US competition
authorities, increasingly appeared as an organic unity. This is due to the fact that the past
competition reforms constitute considerable steps of convergence towards the US
competition regime, both in terms of content and in procedural enforcement rules.
Chapter 3 traces the historical evolution of the European competition model in the period
stretching from the early post-war years to the creation of the competition laws in
Germany, the inclusion of competition laws in the European Coal and Steel Community
(ECSC), and the EEC. It establishes the historical and political context in which laws on
competition were formulated and equipped with enforcement mechanisms, and explores
how the interplay of treaty drafters and the political opposition has given shape to the
particular outlook of EC competition model. Chapter 4 analyses and explains how EC
competition law enforcement has taken shape against the background of the broader
embedded liberalism bargain at Member State level in the period from 1958, the ECs
birth year, until 1985, the year in which the Single European Act (SEA) was adopted. It
argues that the Commission in its role of a supranational competition authority balanced its
decision-making against the broader macroeconomic goal of economic integration. EC
competition laws were enforced to pursue multiple goals, often in line with broader
industrial policy objectives, and occasionally social policy objectives, in order to cope with
the overall commitment to economic openness, both regionally and globally. Even though
competition policy was genuinely market opening, and thus, market making, it was also
rather defensive in character, displaying traces of a protectionist and neomercantilist
ideology that aimed at sheltering certain industries and companies from fierce outside
competitive pressures. In line with the progressive creation of a larger integrated regional
market that allowed companies to reap the benefits of economies of scale production,
competition laws were enforced as a means to foster the competitive strength of European
companies vis--vis the technologically more advanced and larger companies originating
from the US, and later from Japan. Enabling European competitors to compete was given
priority above the protection of the competitive process, which comprised a rather tolerant
stance towards mergers and acquisitions (M&As), and (cross-border) intercompany
agreements designed to pool R&D investments, and various forms of production,
distribution, or marketing joint ventures. Without loosing sight of the common market
project, Community level competition control sought to adjust the diminished capacity of
national governments to employ traditional protectionist measures. The dissertation argues
that the Commissions flexible market interventionist strategies were made possible by the
strong administrative nature of EC competition law enforcement of the ex ante public
control model.
recently, Microsofts abuse of its dominant market position. In reaction to the enhanced
exposure to multiple competition regimes, the executive branch of a selective group of
leading US and EU transnational corporations joined forces in their lobbying activities
before the EU institutions. Driven by the motive to expand the logic of the common market
to the transatlantic realm, they urged the EU and US competition authorities to streamline
their procedural approaches in competition law enforcement, and to harmonise their
interpretations of anticompetitive conduct in order to make competition rules more
coherent and predictable at both sides of the Atlantic. Chapter 6 examines the conclusion
of various bilateral cooperation agreements on competition matters between the EC/EU
and the US authorities, and links them to the broader neoliberal agenda. These bilateral
agreements were meant to facilitate commercial crossborder transactions. They sought to
establish an integrated transatlantic marketplace, undisturbed by regulatory and
administrative obstacles, and marked by a high degree of transparency.
10
meeting in 2003. Besides the deep-rooted US reluctance of having their powers further
constrained by a multilateral trading regime, the downfall of the multilateral trajectory
finds its origins also in the differences between the EU and US competition regimes. The
US authorities distrusted competition authorities of other WTO Members, including the
European Commission, to enforce competition laws in line with the free-market ideology.
As an alternative, the US authorities proclaimed the road of voluntary convergence as key
to streamline the application of competition laws on a global scale. Upon the initiatives of
US authorities and business interests, the International Competition Network (ICN) was
established as the central mechanism to proclaim convergence in competition matters
around the world. As a voluntary and informal forum, the US authorities occupy the
drivers seat, in tandem with the European Commission and transnational business
interests.
Chapter 8 focuses on the past competition policy reforms of the early 21st century, and
explains why the EU competition model has been so fundamentally transformed. It argues
that transnational business elites in the course of the 1990s identified the regime most
favourable to their interests. A range of features of the US competition regime was
considered more business-friendly, and eventually came to be preferred above that of the
EU. Regular public-private interactions on a case-by-case basis, and workshops,
conferences, position papers, as well as joint tripartite meetings involving also the US
competition authorities, resulted in what former Competition Commissioner Mario Monti
called a silent process of convergence towards US competition law and practices that went
on for a number of years and that recently intensified (Monti, 2001a). In addition to the
series of transatlantic bilateral cooperation agreements, the US and EU competition
authorities intensively cooperated in a joint EU-US Merger Working Group. Enforcement
procedures were streamlined and substantive issues in the review of mergers and
acquisitions were addressed. Subsequently, also the analysis of cartels and other restrictive
business practices moved to the centre of attention. The transatlantic cohabitation in
competition matters, backed up by a strategic elite alliance of representatives of large
transnational corporations, has given shape to what became labelled the modernisation, a
major step of convergence to the more marked-based, free competition orientated
competition regime of the US. By introducing a similar test to judge acts of economic
concentration like the US, the legal basis for inhibiting large transnational mergers was
removed, and efficiency arguments have become institutionally anchored. With the
11
abolition of the administrative ex ante public control model for judging commercial
intercompany agreements, similar to the US model, a private enforcement regime has come
in place, which based on a decentralisation mechanism reinforces private enforcement also
at national level. A more marketbased competition regime was established: one that panders
to the free flow of market forces in the allocation of resources, and significantly reduces the
protectionist scope for shielding corporations, or economic sectors, from outside
competition.
A range of journals dedicated to competition law offer a platform for debate and the evolution of new ideas.
Noteworthy in this regard are the Journal of Competition Law and Economics, the Journal of Industry,
Competition and Trade, the OECD Journal of Competition Law and Policy, World Competition, Antitrust
Bulletin and the Journal of Economic Perspectives. In addition, the textbook literature is copious and was
particularly on the increase in the 1990s. Worth mentioning on EU competition laws are the works of Sauter
(1998) Competition Law and Industrial Policy in the EU and Korah (1994) An Introductory Guide to EC
Competition Law and Practice, and Goyder (1998) EC Competition Law made it into the standard literature
on EU competition policy. Seminal is the book Law and Competition in Twentieth Century Europe:
Protecting Prometheus by David Gerber (1998) tracing the ordoliberal origins of EU competition policy and
comparing the competition regimes of EU Member States. Currently topping the list of bestsellers among the
audience of academics and practitioners in the field is Competition Policy: Theory and Practice by Motta
(2004), an economic account on game-theoretic modelling as it is applied in contemporary practice at both
sides of the Atlantic.
12
econometric tools for analysing markets, market shares, market efficiencies, consumer
welfare assessments, and distorting anticompetitive conduct. The branch of legal scholars
and economists drive the academic debate by inaugurating new legal questions, or
responding to judicial problems encountered in everyday competition law practice and
changing market situations. Their contributions often provide the intellectual context of
new ideas in competition matters (ibid). Legal and economic expert accounts, however,
tend to obscure, or downplay, the profoundly political nature of competition policy through
seemingly apolitical and static conceptualisations, and a preoccupation with complex legal
technicalities. Competition policy, however, is not a politically neutral regulatory field, and
political authorities do not naturally perceive problems and solutions in similar ways, and
subsequently arrive at the best and most effective institutional and regulatory solution to
a defined problem. Behind seemingly detailed judicial and technocratic issues of
competition laws and their enforcement lurk important political questions regarding the
distribution and concentration of economic power and wealth, not only in domestic market
situations, but also in an ever-more globalised world. Competition policy benefits some
groups and segments in society more than others, and different actors have different
interests in this policy area. Conceptions of competition policy denying or neglecting this
are political themselves, as they disguise the underlying conflicting interests regarding
content, form, and scope of public intervention in competition matters.
13
institutional and regulatory dimensions of this policy area (cf. Bulmer, 1994; Damro, 2002,
2006a, 2006b; Wilks, 2005; McGowan and Cini, 1999; McGowan, 2007a, 2007b; Bthe
and Swank, 2005; Bthe, 2007). Nonetheless, the overwhelming majority of existing
political science studies on EC competition policy fails to relate the developments in the
field to broader transformations in the way in which capitalism is regulated in Europe. EC
competition policy is often analysed as an isolated policy area. Such studies largely remain
at the descriptive surface of political processes, and predominantly pay attention to
producing knowledge on intra-institutional and judicial features, without further
contextualising this knowledge against broader socioeconomic and ideational changes (see
also Buch-Hansen and Wigger, 2007).
14
The Annual Competition Reports from 1995 onwards can be accessed at the Commissions webpage at:
http://europa.eu.int/comm/competition/annual_reports/. Earlier Annual Competition Reports, speeches by
Commissioners and high-ranking officials, as well as other documents by the Commission before 1995 are
accessible at the Historical Archives of the Commission in Brussels.
15
economists, and public officials, and business representatives, as well as the Annual
Competition Day organised jointly by the European Parliament and the European
Commission, provided a good opportunity to corroborate background knowledge about
ongoing policy discussions in the field.
16
Chapter 1
Introduction
Competition policy constitutes one of the most characteristic policy fields in the
organisation of modern capitalist economies. It comprises a regulatory area in which
politics, law, and economics intertwine in complex ways. Competition laws and their
enforcement typically pertain to the structure of market power and market integration.
They set the conditions of market concentration and market access and define the scope of
commercial freedom to conclude cooperative ventures for companies. Moreover, they
mark the distinction between the public and the private realm. Situated at the nexus of
trade, financial investment, industrial policy, contract law, and corporate governance
regulation, competition laws are genuinely public market interventionists. The terms
competition policy, competition law, and their enforcement are commonly used without
further delineating, in terms of scope and content, what is actually meant. In practice, much
of the terminology used in this field can give rise to confusion. In the US, the term
antitrust policy is used specifically to indicate the prohibition of cartels and other
restrictive business practices. In Europe and other parts in the world, the more generic
analogue competition policy is more common. The boundaries with other economic
policy fields are often blurred. The particular nomenclature and technical jargon of
umpteen experts and practitioners that dominate the literature in the field make it not an
easily accessible field to study. Moreover, apart from occasional high-profile cartel
prosecutions or disputed mergers, competition laws and their enforcement generally do not
attract broad political attention. This is mostly because the technicalities of competition
policy may seem unexciting and trivial at first glance. However, behind seemingly detailed
judicial and technocratic issues of laws and practices lurk important political questions
regarding the distribution and concentration of economic power, wealth, and social justice,
not only in domestic market situations, but also in an ever-more globalised world.
17
Competition policy can come in different shapes and sizes serve a broad range of
conflicting interests. It is generally anchored in a polity, the competition authority, which
forms part of the institutional architecture of the state. Depending on the degree of
institutional independence from government steering, the competition authority can be
equipped with more or less discretionary competences. Competition policy, in its broadest
sense, can strive to make entire economies more competitive, or focus on competition
between single enterprises. It can enable and constrain private market power, be more or
less market-interventionist, more or less business-friendly, or more or less free-market
orientated. The ambiguity of the nature of competition control constraining and enabling
market freedom at the same time makes competition authorities a lobbying target of rival
interests. On theoretical grounds, one can assume that a competition authority, similar to
other government bodies, is receptive to the lobbying activities. Different constituencies
have different stakes with regard to competition laws and their enforcement. Not all
constituencies are always aware of their stakes and hold explicit political positions. Neither
are all stakeholders mobilised and organised in the same degree.
This chapter argues that competition law enforcement needs to be understood as a product
of the prevailing economic and political thinking of the times (Gavil et al. 2002: 69), that
is both constituted by and constitutive to the structural power relations in a political
economy. In other words, it is a product of specific discursive and material practices. The
prevalent political and ideological discourses, enforcement philosophies, established
practices and procedural rules, and most notably, the political weight of certain social
forces seeking to influence the competition law enforcers, constitute elements that interact
in complex ways in a given market structure. The ideological outlook of these social forces
is not a priori fixed, but partly contingent upon their position and the position of others in a
given historical market structure. Dominant political discourses shape the broader political
climate and the wider socioeconomic governance regime, and affect social identities. The
social forces, which are directly involved and addressed in the governance of the
competitive process, i.e. the representatives of companies with operations in the common
market, can be expected to articulate their stakes in the most pronounced way.
The chapter starts with a few basic theoretical lines of thought with regard to the dynamics
of competition on the one hand, and the general nature of competition laws in capitalist
market economies on the other hand. It defines the parameters, adopted in this research, of
18
the concepts of competition and competition laws. Moreover, the chapter unveils, on
theoretical grounds, the interlinkages of ideological and interest-driven objectives of the
different constituencies. It embeds these actors and their interests within broader historical
macroeconomic structures and segues into theoretical questions with regard to how the
process of competition affects political, social, and economic life in the contemporary
context of globalisation.
There is probably no concept in all of economics that is at once more fundamental and
pervasive, yet less satisfactorily developed, than the concept of competition.
Paul McNulty (1968: 632)
Throughout this research, the terms enterprise, company, corporations, undertaking, or firm are
interchangeably applied.
19
In general, if any branch of trade, or any division of labour, be advantageous to the public,
the freer and more general the competition, it will always be the more so.
Adam Smith (1776: 420)
From the camp of classical economic thinkers, Adam Smith probably represents the most
prominent of all. He did not invent the concept of competition other economists
discussed competition in the economic literature well before him (cf. Rothbard, 1995;
McNulty, 1968). His work, however, attached considerable intellectual and ideological
significance to it. In the Wealth of Nations (1776), he generalised competition as a force
that drives the aggregate interaction of self-interested market players to higher standards
of wealth, a conception he captured with the renowned notion of the 'invisible hand:
He [the individual] generally, indeed, neither intends to promote the public interest, nor
knows how much he is promoting it. [] (H)e intends only his own gain, and he is in this,
as in many other cases, led by an invisible hand to promote an end which was no part of
his intention. (Smith, 1776: 572)
20
Although Smith mentioned the invisible hand only once throughout his work, it became
one of the central predications for his theories. Yet, as he did not offer a clear definition of
competition, academic disputes on whether competition indeed constituted the muchdiscussed invisible hand are ongoing. Rather than engaging with this discussion, it is
merely important here to illustrate how most of the dominant contemporary economic
theories depart from Smiths positive sum idea of competition, which assumes that free
competition is advantageous to the great body of the people (ibid: 623). According to
Smith, the rivalrous nature of free competition obliges every man to endeavour to execute
his work with a certain degree of exactness and animates the exertion of a few men of
extraordinary spirit and ambition (ibid: 963).
Contemporary neoclassical economic theories often build on the premise that the
aggregate endeavour in long-term survival and prosperity of individual corporations
moves the economy to higher levels of productive efficiency and technological
innovations, and increasing the power and capabilities of an economy (Gilpin, 2003: 18).
Yet, they deviate in their definition of what competition is. In the mindset of neoclassical
economists, the process of sorting out the efficient and the innovative from the inefficient
and the unprofitable results in perfect competition, a concept coined by Antoine A.
Cournot (1801-1877). Perfect competition refers to a theoretical, imaginary state of affairs
that is also sometimes referred to as pareto equilibrium. It embodies the result of a process
after which a plethora of discrete individual buyers and sellers has striven to maximise
their profits and utilities. This state of affairs entails the efficient allocation of resources,
and the efficient production and distribution of products benefiting the ultimate buyer, i.e.
the consumer. Perfect competition builds on the assumption that no buyer or seller has had
the power to influence the market conditions to his/her own benefit. Moreover, all buyers
and sellers have been in the fortunate position of having perfect information about the
costs and demand situation, and all have been free to enter and leave the marketplace. The
concept of perfect competition is generally juxtaposed with a monopoly situation in which
no competitors are left to compete, while the degree of competition is assumed to oscillate
between these opposing ends. Yet, as McNulty (1968: 642) rightly noticed, the utopian
situation of perfect competition actually refers to the absence of competition in quite as
complete a sense as does pure monopoly where no further competition within the industry
is possible. This is because perfect competition implies a situation in which no further
21
welfare increases are possible, neither for buyers of resources, sellers, nor the final
consumers.
Free competition brings out the inherent laws of capitalist production, in the shape of
external coercive laws having power over every individual capitalist.
22
intensified, the more capital owners would seek to beat down the price of labour, and/or
the more they would seek to improve the efficiency of the production process through
labour-saving innovations. Eventually, the command over abnormal quantities of unpaid
labour becomes a source of competitive strength (Marx, 1906, Part VI, Chapter 20).
Competition, thereby, is in essence about the extraction of surplus and the accumulation of
capital.
Competition does not only take place in markets, but also for markets, thus prompting a
process of commodification. Commodification indicates the subjugation of ever-more
segments of human existence and human interaction to the logics of the market and the
mechanism of price as a means of exchange. This ongoing process of commodification is
the direct result of the coercive nature exerted by competition. In order to expand market
shares and to be able to invest in more efficient production technologies, capital
accumulation becomes a necessity. Consequently, the competitive process leads to the
accumulation of capital into ever-fewer hands, and in its extreme form the oligopolisation
or monopolisation of product markets. To put it metaphorically, competition forces market
players to swim or to sink, and competition takes place only between the swimmers.
Smaller, weaker, or simply less successful competitors lose, and competition eventually
minimises. Monopolies the ultimate form of economic power concentration with no
competitors left concomitantly reveal the inherent contradictions of capitalist systems.
They constitute part of the reason why Marx prophesied that capitalism as an economic
system was destined to fail. However, Marxist theory did not take into account the
development of state-imposed competition laws in modern capitalist economies, which
seek to stabilise the competitive process and to combat monopolies. Thus, in a wider sense
competition laws secure the continuous reproduction of capitalist socioeconomic power
relations. They obviate what Marx expressed with the much-cited phrase capitalism
contains the seeds of its own destruction.
Marx notion with regard to the inborn contradictions of capitalist markets offers a good
starting point to add a critical note to the concepts of competition, and competition policy.
Contrary to the Adam Smith type (neo-) classical allusions that competition instigates
wealth, it is important to realise that, in reality, competition does not only produce
winners. According to Thurman Arnold, a US antitrust official in the 1940s, the
economic philosophy behind antitrust laws is a tough philosophy as competition means
23
that someone may go bankrupt. Competition laws do not contemplate a game in which
everyone who plays can win (in Kolasky, 2002b). Even though this is not to deny that
competition may indeed lead to increased levels of wealth, it is important to realise that
not everybody can profit equally from competition. The important question therefore is for
whom wealth increases: cui bono? As Sklar (1988: 88) pointed out, there is no such thing
as a politically innocent capitalist market. Competition touches upon important political
questions of income distribution. It erects a hierarchy of socioeconomic relations marked
by inequalities in wealth and power, which extend from the individual, groups or classes,
to geographical regions in the world. Moreover, competition constitutes a practice that is
inherent to capitalist free markets. It takes place among the owners of capital and labour
alike. In modern capitalist economies, competition has permeated various social spheres.
According to Bourdieu (1998), the logic of competition has extended to individuals
themselves. The individualisation of the wage relationship, individual performance
evaluations by means of salary increases and bonuses, and individual career paths are
examples thereof. As Bourdieu put it, individual wage labourers are held responsible for
their sales, their products, their branch, and their store as though they were independent
contractors (ibid).
Laws protecting competition keep capitalism alive by removing restraints that inhibit
competitors from competing. Consequently, competition law is both constitutive to and
constituted by capitalist market regimes. To use a metaphor again: if the process of
competition is the engine of capitalism, competition laws are the lubricating oil that
assures the functioning of the engine. The mere existence of laws that protect competition
entail a disclaimer with respect to the workings of unrestricted free-market logics. The
rule of law is constitutive to a capitalist system. Capitalist markets do not originate in law,
however. Once established the rise, the development, and the stability of the capitalist
order, be it laissez-faire capitalism or regulated capitalism, go hand in hand with the rise
of a legal order (Sklar, 1988: 87). The overarching purpose of competition laws is
therefore to ensure the endurance and stability of the capitalist mode of production by
forcing market actors to engage in a constant situation of rivalry. The next section further
elucidates the political nature of competition laws and their enforcement.
24
Antitrust will always be a product of the prevailing economic and political thinking of the
times. The ubiquitous influence of political and economic thought throughout antitrusts
history, combined with the longevity of some antitrust precedent, as well as the conflicting
ideologies [] guarantees that antitrust will continue to provide an arena for the clash of
contemporary ideas on governments and markets.
Gavil et al. (2002: 69)
Every cultural mode of thought has its own concepts of market, competition, economy in
general, property, collectivity of goods, trust and decency. Unless we understand, and
respect, these other modes of thought, we are not entitled to superimpose our concepts of
market and competition, and our understanding of economy, belonging and efficient
behaviour upon other, non-Western cultures. [] There are economic meta-concepts, and
meta-values, to be drawn from comparison, but they are not necessarily ours.
neither directly observable nor quantifiable, nor can everyone equally profit from the
alleged increase of economic welfare. One can only guess the overall impact of competition
policy based on counterfactual reasoning.
Similarly, those enforcing competition laws also tend to downplay the political nature of
competition laws by positing a taken-for-granted problem-solving understanding, mostly
to avoid the involvement of (other) government actors and uncalled-for stakeholders.
Former EU Competition Commissioner Mario Monti, for example, emphasised that
competition policy was a matter of law and economics, not politics and that unwarranted
political pressure weakened its effectiveness and undermined public confidence in the
combat of objectively harmful practices (European Union, 2001). Yet, competition policy
is not a politically neutral regulatory field in which political authorities naturally perceive
problems and solutions in similar ways, and crystallise the best and most effective
institutional and regulatory solution to a problem. The often-made trilogy of politics,
policy, and polity in the English language is also confusing as it separates policy from
politics, and thereby gives the impression that a policy is no longer politics. In the French
and German language, the political nature comes to the fore more clearly: competition
policy is steadfastly expressed in terms of la politique de la concurrence, or,
Wettbewerbspolitik, respectively. Conceptions of competition policy denying its inherent
political character are political themselves, as they disguise the underlying conflicting
interests regarding the scope and content of public intervention in competition matters. As
competition laws are located at the boundaries of the private and the public domain, they
represent the visible hand of the state. They determine the extent to which the organisation
of the economy is subject to state command and free-market processes. At the same time,
they protect market actors from unrestricted state power and arbitrary public market
intervention.
In order to analyse the political nature of competition policy, one needs to distinguish
between competition laws as they are designed, and as they are enforced. This dissertation
builds on the premise that law is frozen politics, and that competition law represents the
outcome of a political struggle. It touches upon the questions Lasswell (1956) posed as
who gets what, where, how, and when. There is no such a thing as the one and only
competition policy. The substantive content of competition laws either explicitly or
implicitly integrates political perceptions and values with regard to the organisation of the
26
27
28
Even if oligopolies are not always and not necessarily the most efficient enterprises, the
most efficient enterprises are usually oligopolies. [] Owing to their economic power,
oligopolies have their ways and means to get their interest defined by international
institutions as well. This process of representation is almost never immediate and
transparent. [] Yet, it is the oligopolistic sector that, directly or indirectly, dictates the
rules of the game.
Business can and does contribute to shaping competition policy. Any major policy initiative
is preceded by consultation.
Neelie Kroes, EU Competition Commissioner (2006c)
Large and small enterprises alike can adopt anticompetitive practices. Nonetheless,
companies have contradictory stakes with regard to the desirability of competition laws. In
29
essence, a policy of free competition fosters objectively the powerful economic units, that
is, the oligopolies (Carchedi, 2001: 126). The preservation of free competition is in the
interest of those determining the standards of competition for (usually) smaller, less
competitive companies, be it in terms of price, product innovation, advertising expenses,
or be it in terms of organisational or distributional logistics. Outcompeting weaker
companies works systematically to the advantage of economic survivors. The situation is
more delicate for corporations that have to face dominant corporations. The pace of
competition set by those able to compete may thwart their existence. Comparatively
weaker enterprises may use market-sharing or price-fixing cartel agreements and other
collusive practices to combine forces against dominant competitors. More competitive or
oligopolistic companies have a stake in the prohibition of these practices in order to
maintain their status quo. At the same time, the latter may also abuse a dominant position
and adopt anticompetitive practices to secure their position. Weaker companies then have
a stake in the protection from the anarchy of free-market play. It follows that competition
laws are zero-sum in nature: for some companies competition laws can function as a
constructive force, while imposing constraints on the economic freedom of others.
Alternatively, what constitutes a reduction of market freedom for one market player may
benefit another. The companies on the winning side, however, are those setting the pace of
competition for others, i.e. the dominant and mostly large companies. Concomitantly,
these companies are genuinely interested in the right to compete freely, undisturbed by
state interferences and privately erected market barriers by competitors, such as cartels. In
this vein, there is a conflict of interests between corporations from different sectors.
These interests are generally contingent upon a range of different factors, including the
degree of market openness and the broader macroeconomic market structure, the
integration of companies and/or business sectors in the world economy, and their trade
orientation. Companies with a strong focus on national market economies, mostly small
and medium-sized enterprises (SME), or companies that have to compete with cheaper
imports, i.e. import-competing enterprises and or sectors, are vulnerable to the exposure of
fierce outside competition (see also Van Apeldoorn, 2002). In addition to import-quota or
other measures, they are more likely to seek protectionist competition policies, rather than
competition policies that promote free competition and open economic borders (for trade
policies, see also Milner, 1988). A protectionist orientation in competition law
enforcement can take different forms. It can imply a less stringent interpretation of
30
competition laws by tolerating cartels and other restrictive business practices that lead to
reduced corporate rivalry, and hence a reduced need to compete with other (national)
competitors. It can also mean a discriminatory enforcement strategy, i.e. a beneficial
approach towards domestic corporations at the expense of foreign competitors, or towards
certain domestic economic sectors by granting state aid, tax reductions, or guaranteed
procurement. Whether or not import-competing companies voice their preferences with
regard to a protectionist competition policy depends on the degree of market openness and
their exposure to outside competition. Small and medium sized corporations with a
domestic focus constitute the most vulnerable of all. In contrast, companies focusing on
exporting their products to other markets seek free(r) competition, and hence more
stringent competition law enforcement. Although corporations with an export-orientation
may still prefer domestic barriers for foreign competitors as a way to secure their
competitive strength, they seek open markets abroad. Laws protecting free competition,
preferably at the multilateral stage, are in their interests as they inherently protect the right
to enter (geographically) new markets and to expand in scale and scope. It follows that the
more corporations are engaged in transnational transactions, the more likely it is that they
share a common interest in competition laws protecting the right to compete, regardless of
where they are headquartered and the sectors in which they operate. Free competition
offers a way to expand market shares and take advantage of the opportunities offered by
economic globalisation.
The term transnational corporation (TNC) juxtaposes the terms multinational corporation
(MNC) and international corporation. In the literature, the terms transnational,
multinational or international corporation are sometimes used interchangeably. While
international usually refers to relations between states, the term multinational corporation
(MNC) is often misleading, as it implies a corporation with multiple nationalities and
strong attachments to national economies. The term transnational, in contrast, specifies
actors, networks of actors, processes, and institutions established beyond national
boundaries. Those controlling transnational corporations are such actors. They act as if
national boundaries do not matter, or as Sklair (2001: 2) wrote, they do not derive their
power and authority from the state. Therefore, the term transnational corporations more
aptly captures that those representing these corporations are not dominated by nation
states economically, politically, or in terms of culture and ideology, regardless of the fact
31
these corporations as legal entities may have several nationalities and be composed of
subsidiaries which focus on national economies (ibid: 48).
The emergence of transnational corporations (TNCs) goes together with the phenomenon
of enhanced economic globalisation. Economic globalisation can best be conceptualised as
the dialectical dynamics between the expansion of market relations and the freedom of
capital to maximise its accumulation potential and the structural transformation of the
world economy by the pursuit of economic liberalism (Overbeek, 2002). The nature of
economic transactions was changed significantly by the steady course of worldwide trade
and capital liberalisation that accompanied the development of new technologies and
communication possibilities, as well as the improvement of transport. These changes
implied that vertical trade increasingly replaced traditional horizontal trade in finished
products. The different stages in the production and distribution chain were completed by
companies and subsidiaries located in different regions of the world. TNCs embrace these
structural transformations of the world economy. Despite the global scope and impact of
their activities, most of the large TNCs find their origin in a few advanced industrial
countries of the OECD, most notably the US, UK, Germany France and Japan, where they
also tend to have their headquarters (Goddard, 2003: 440).
TNCs are not only a product of economic globalisation, but also one of its driving forces.
They have a genuine interest in the right to free trade and access to new (cheap) labour
markets, markets for natural resources, as well as new product markets. The hierarchical
network organisation of affiliated companies allows TNCs exerting controlling power over
a national economy, and to exploit their bargaining leverage versus states, workers, local
competitors, and network affiliates (cf. Jones, 2000). It allows TNCs to reduce transactions
costs and to focus on high value-added activities, while passing on riskier or non-essential
activities, to subcontractors, who often fully depend on them. The vertical integration of
foreign affiliates into the hierarchical network structure allows TNCs to exploit
transferpricing opportunities at the expense of a host countrys tax revenue, as well as
competition. The broader ideology of neoliberalism suits the interests of those in control of
transnational enterprises. Neoliberalism can be defined as the politics constructed from the
individual, freedom of choice, the market society, laissez-faire, and minimal government
(Overbeek and Van der Pijl, 1993: 15). Neoliberal economic policies promote further
market liberalisation in terms of trade and financial services, and overall deregulation
32
33
Those in control of (large) TNCs seek to maintain cosy relations with political decisionmakers and influence the overall course of competition laws and their enforcement. The
structural power of transnational corporations is reinforced by their capability to exit
national economies and locate their production factories elsewhere, in particular in the
manufacturing sector. Against the backdrop of regulatory competition in the attraction of
foreign direct investment, political authorities are likely to be predisposed towards the
interests of more powerful corporations. Corporate lobbying in the field of competition
policy is a highly uneven process. Representatives of more powerful market players, mostly
TNCs, have a comparative advantage in communicating their interests. They generally
provide for the necessary financial and communicative capacities to hire contract lobbyists
to address decision-makers, rather than liaising with existing business interest organisations
first. Due to organisational difficulties, certain interest groups remain structurally excluded.
Labour and consumer organisations or environmental groups face greater organisational
costs when it comes to communicating their interests in competition laws and their
enforcement. They generally provide less information about the policy process and the
issues at stake, or are too heterogeneous in composition so that they are unable to formulate
common positions. This is particularly the case for consumers, but increasingly more so for
labour. Moreover, the interests of the two groups are not congruent: while labour
organisations may want to see a merger blocked because it leads to employment reductions,
consumers may welcome the synergy effects that result in lower prices or improved product
quality. Furthermore, due to confidentiality reasons, labour unions and consumer
organisations have hardly any access to pending competition cases, which structurally
places these groups at a disadvantage in getting themselves heard on a case-by-case basis.
The particular situation of EU competition law enforcement further enhances this. Those
directly subject to the EU competition authority, i.e. the European Commission, are
corporations engaged in transborder activities displaying a significant Community
dimension, hence, foremost but not exclusively (large) transnational corporations. The
34
centralisation of law and decision making at EU level provided corporate interests with a
welcome avenue to make their preferences heard and to transcend traditional business
lobbying associations. As Van Apeldoorn (2000: 4) notes, leaders of TNCs gather in elite
networks to reflect upon and discuss their medium and long term interests vis--vis the
state and other groups in society, and work out common political strategies on the basis of
which they seek to influence EU governance. In contrast, small and medium-sized
enterprises with a domestic focus generally fall under the jurisdictional authority of national
competition authorities. Even though they share a common interest in curbing the power of
the more dominant competitors, as a result of the institutional organisation, lobbying the
Commission does not seem self-evident.
35
In the literature, the Commission received a broad array of different labels, ranging from a
policy broker, a think tank, an integration catalyst, to a political and administrative hybrid
(cf. Nugent, 2001). Composed of officials recruited from Member State governments and
the private sector, the Commissions identity is difficult to pin down. Often, Commission
officials rotate (back) to the private sector again. To perceive it as a unitary actor is
misleading, even though decisions and policy initiatives are taken by the College of
Commissioners. Different DGs have different policy priorities, and different lobby groups
target the Commissions 6,500 officials involved in the policy process (cf. EU LobbyNet,
2007), which increases the likelihood of internal disputes. Commission officials interact
with a wide array of interest groups and lobbyists. Estimates suggest that the total number
of lobbyists in Brussels amount to more 15,000 and 20,000. Professional lobbyists
officially accredited at the EU amount to 13,000, compared to 25,500 lobbyists at the US
Congress (ibid). More than two-thirds represent business associations, individual
companies, sectoral groupings, or lobbying alliances from several companies established to
influence a specific legislation, i.e. actors who usually have the means to make their
preferences heard. To push forward their views, business associations formulate position
papers and commentaries serving the purpose of inducing broader policy or regulatory
changes, while individual representatives from the business community or their corporate
lawyers have a stake in influencing the Commissions decisions in the day-to-day
enforcement practice. Other actors that may seek to influence decision making or policy
ideas of Commission officials are labour and consumer organisations, environmental
pressure groups, Member State governments and competition authorities, as well as other
Commission Directorate Generals (DGs) and EU institutions.
Against the background of the massive presence of corporate lobby groups in Brussels, the
important question to be asked is, to what extent the Commissions DG Competition
polices the marketplace, and to what extent it acts as the incognito voice of management
boards. The critical reader will search the dominant existing literature of legal and
economic scholars in vain for a clear answer to that question. Arguably, the Commission,
as one of the most central EU institutions, may always be guided to some degree by
institutional self-interest and the wish for self-preservation. The expansion of Commission
competences into new areas of regulation increases the Commissions prestige and status
as a whole, or that of individual Commission officials. It follows that the Commission,
from an institutional point of view, is genuinely interested in the enhanced centralisation of
36
In order to grasp better the context in which a political authority, such as the Commission,
enforces competition laws, it is important to consider the underlying political discourses
that set the parameters in which public policies and political institutions are framed. The
Commission or the Commissions DG Competition forms a part of those social forces that
promote a shared understanding of how to address anticompetitive conduct and how to
interpret competition laws. Dominant political discourses can function as a cognitive filter
in which political identities are formed, interests articulated, and the political battles
carried out. They set the horizon of meaningful social practices and validate a particular
37
understanding of the past. Through interacting with business representatives, the legal
community, and other stakeholders, the Commission reflects and shapes such a discourse
and thereby contributes to a discourse gaining the interpretative upper hand. Whether or
not a discourse promoting certain ideas and policy solutions becomes dominant and thus
articulated by the Commission, is not an automatic, god-driven process, but spurred by
social forces with particular interests. Nonetheless, ideas cannot be simply reduced to
interests, nor can they be reified as existing prior to practice (Van Apeldoorn, 2002: 14).
This is not to give primacy to the power of political ideas above material interests. Rather,
a discourse may be embodied or internalised in social practices and become a material
force. Norman Fairclough (2003), interweaves the conceptual pairing of the material and
ideational into a complex and interdependent whole, at least in ontological terms. He
argues that there is a dialectic interaction between what he differentiates as the
constructive and the construal: the construal refers to the ideas and images promoted by
a discourse, and the constructive to the remodelling of such construals into social practices.
Moreover, although aspects of the social world such as social institutions are ultimately
socially constructed, once constructed they are realities, which affect and limit the
discursive construction of the social (Fairclough, 2003: 8).
Following from this, one can distinguish different phases or moments in the evolution of a
dominant discourse: a deconstructive, a constructive, and a consolidating phase. In the
deconstructive phase, articulators of the new political discourse problematise existing ideas
and views and promote new ones. Once these new ideas and views become dominant, they
are given shape by structural adjustments and the discourse enters a constructive phase. In
the consolidating phase, the discourse becomes commonsensical and deeply engrained in
institutional practices, and thus, reaches a state of hegemony above alternative discourses.
The identification of a dominant discourse surrounding EU competition policy helps to
acquire a more comprehensive understanding of the social and historical embeddedness of
particular conceptions about the institutional design, scope, and content of competition
laws and practices (cf. Overbeek, 1999 on the ascendancy of neoliberalism as a hegemonic
project).
38
We also applaud the work performed by national and international bar associations to
advance scholarship in the field [of competition policy]. [] We welcome commentary
from the academic community. And we are wise to consider carefully the perspectives
offered by business organisations and individual opinion leaders within the global business
community.
Charles James, Assistant Attorney General for the DoJ Antitrust Division (2001a)
Practitioners from the private sector and academia provide intimate knowledge on
competition laws and practices. They work on the same competition cases as public
(Commission) officials although often representing antagonistic positions when
defending or advising a corporate client. Professional linkages between private and public
competition experts produce distinct policy dynamics in which legal ends, legal criteria,
39
legal norms and legal participants pursue a policy that has its own logic (Wilks and
McGowan, 1996: 244). Public and private competition experts belong to the same
interpretative competition community. They gather at the same conferences and workshops
and develop shared legal practices. Thereby, they are socialised to speak, write and think
about competition law technicalities in the same idiosyncratic way (Slaughter, 2004: 253).
They wield a high degree of homogeneity and cohesion in norms and views, despite the
fact that they often bring forth competing legal interpretations (cf. Schepel and Wesseling,
1997). Exchanges of professional personnel from the public and private sectors are
common and many private professionals hold part-time tenures at universities. In that
sense, the legal competition community personifies the interweaving of market, state, and
academia (ibid: 182). Career paths in the sector of legal practitioners often depend on
academic prestige, and vice versa, practical experience feeds into doctrinal writings.
Universities provide for the intellectual infrastructure which creates a pool of well-trained
professionals (Monti, 2003b).
40
The marked presence of professional law companies is inherently linked to the European
integration processes on the one hand, and the growth of transnational corporations
engaging in economic transactions in different jurisdictions simultaneously on the other.
The enhanced pace of Community law production triggered by the Single European Act
(SEA) in the mid-1980s and the creation of the European Union in the early 1990s, created
new avenues for private professionals to offer their services to corporations operating in
the common market and beyond. Enhanced cross-border corporate activities created a huge
market for private competition practitioners to offer a broad range of new counselling
services to their clients. The overall structural corporate enmeshment through acts of
concentration and intercompany agreements, a development that in itself is the result of the
ongoing economic integration project, subjugated the compliance with competition laws to
a process of commodification. Corporations have to contract legal counselling from the
professional services market in order to comply with competition laws on the market of
professional services. An increase in economic cross-border transactions creates an
increase in the demand for legal advice. Furthermore, the large share of transatlantic
corporate transactions created an influx of US law firms into Europe. This stimulated the
creation of EU-based mega-law firms and alliances that are socially well connected to
Community institutions (Schepel and Wesseling, 1997: 182). In the EU, there are
currently about 100,000 judges and 450,000 lawyers (ibid: 187).
Private commercial, as well as academic competition experts, therefore, enjoy a quasimonopoly in terms of influencing legal discourses that eventually provide the broader
interpretation framework of Commission officials in the field of competition law
enforcement. They occupy an intermediary position between the public authorities and
private companies that have to comply with competition laws. In this position, they can be
assumed to embody largely the interests of their clients, i.e. private companies.
41
Chapter 2
Each model has its particular traits and leads to a different type of competition control.
Although not sharply etched, the EC/EU model (Part I) constitutes a counter-model to
that of the US (Part II). Both models fit into the wider socioeconomic perspectives of the
varieties of capitalism debate, notably the Rhenish or coordinated capitalism versus the
more market-based, liberal Anglo-Saxon variety. Moreover, both models are composed of
43
The EC/EU model is generally associated with economic fairness and public market
intervention, serving the purpose of creating an integrated common market (Sjostrom,
1998: 1). The US model, in contrast, tends to be associated with a laissez-faire approach
and fierce competition, giving primacy to market forces in the allocation of resources and
production factors (ibid). Accordingly, the EC/EU model would lead to a gentlemanlytype of competition, whereas the US model encouraged a more Darwinian-type of
competition (Monti, 2004e: 4). As will be demonstrated below, these differences manifest
themselves in the prosecution of economic concentrations, in particular monopoly conduct,
and the prosecution of cartels.
44
45
shares, product diversification, or reduced taxes. At the same time, M&As reduce the
number of competitors and create a situation of concentrated market power, which
eventually may lead to market dominance, or a monopoly position. This carries the risk of
foreclosing market access to newcomers or expelling competitors from the market. In a
situation of reduced competition, companies may ask higher prices in order to increase
revenues. Moreover, they may refrain from investing in product innovation, all to the
detriment of consumers. In addition, as concentration activities often generate
restructuring measures and the closure of duplicate divisions, they have an impact on the
internal employment structure, such as changes in the company board and reductions in
the overall employment.
46
enterprises, and 87 on state aid apply to the Member States. Of the remaining Articles,
Article 83 provides a basis for secondary legislation, Article 84 outlines conditions for
temporary enforcement, and Article 85 specifies the Commissions enforcement powers.
The substantive treaty articles were bound to general and abstract legislation, which left
ample room for interpretation. Over time, more detailed regulatory frameworks
complemented the substantive laws. This secondary legislation takes the form of
regulations, directives, and decisions. In addition, tertiary legislation in the form of case
law produced by the European courts, the European Court of Justice (ECJ), and from
1989 onwards also by the Court of First Instance (CFI) complemented the treaty
legislation. Given the strong constitutional character of the treaties, secondary and tertiary
legislation needs to be in accordance with the treaty articles. In addition, Notices and
Guidelines, as well as Best Practice Guidelines also provide a basis for the interpretation
of the laws and regulations.
Figure 1: The Three Pillars of EC/EU Competition Law
47
Article 82 prohibits any abuse by one or more enterprises of a dominant position within
the common market or in a substantial part of it in so far as it may affect trade between
Member States. This means that no company should distort competition by holding a
dominant position. Article 82 is sometimes also referred to as the EUs antimonopoly law.
This is slightly misleading because it is not prohibited to hold a dominant market position,
but rather to abuse such a position. In that sense, the European competition model does
not fight monopolies or oligopolies, even though Article 82 might give this impression.
Nonetheless, Article 82 reaches further than the antimonopoly law embedded in Section
Two of the US Sherman Act or the Clayton Act (see Part II), which prohibits attempts to
monopolise. Abusive dominant behaviour generally includes unilateral or bilateral
conduct that purports to disadvantage other market players. It can concern the application
of dissimilar conditions to equivalent transactions with other trading partners, such as
discriminatory purchases or prices or tied-selling agreements, i.e. the selling of a product
that is tied to another, but which the buyer does not want to purchase (McGowan, 1996:
14). Moreover, it can also concern the limitation of production in order to create scarcity
in a market, which in turn allows prices to be raised (ibid). The Commission and the
European Courts have interpreted the concept of an abuse of a dominant market position
differently at different times, partly because market dominance of a market player was
defined in relative terms with regard to other market players. In certain cases, a company
holding market shares between 20-40% was considered dominant. At the same time there
were rulings in which market shares of 50% and 60%, and occasionally even 80% were
still allowed (Schmitz, 2002: 558). As definitions on relevant product markets are
notoriously difficult to establish, the Commission has enjoyed much scope in the
interpretation of Article 82. Companies have sought to take advantage of this and to lobby
for favourable treatment. Nonetheless, market shares above 40% are generally considered
an indicator of dominance. US jurisprudence, in contrast, established market shares of
70% to indicate monopoly power (cf. Kim and Hutton, 2006). In other words, by
comparison, US antitrust law enforcement is far more tolerant towards large companies.
There is no equivalent of Article 82 in US law. Article 81 on the prohibition of cartels,
however, was formulated in the line of the US antitrust provisions. As will be illustrated in
the next section, that EC competition laws exceed the regulatory scope of those in the US
48
can also be seen from Article 87-89 (ex 92-94) on the control of state aid policies, which
in the US Federal context was never an issue at all.
49
turnover within a single Member State. The turnover thresholds provide for a one-stop
shop for mergers. This implies that the Commission enjoys exclusive control of
Community-dimension mergers. Multiple merger reviews by national competition
authorities (NCAs) were thereby ruled out. The Merger Regulation further entails
procedural requirements, deadlines, and hearing rights. It requires all companies involved
in a concentration meeting the turnover threshold criteria to notify their endeavours to the
Commission in advance.
Table 1: Sources of EU Competition Law
50
Most of the Southern Member States introduced competition laws in the mid-1980s,
generally after they joined the EC. Italy, however, as one of the founding EC Members,
constitutes an exception. Powerful industrial opposition could block the enactment of
competition laws until 1990 (Gerber, 1998: 406-410). When Italy adopted its competition
statute, the EC-level Article 81, with the exemption regime of Article 81(3), as well as
Article 82, and the merger law, together served as a template (ibid). Similarly, in the
French tradition of dirigisme and planification, competition laws had long played a
subordinate role. They barely had an identity before the mid-1980s: they were constituted
by a nameless collection of different sets of norms and sanctioning devices, which focused
foremost on price controls. Industrial policy, in contrast, occupied a central place.
Moreover, the French enforcement institutions for competition law were rather forceless.
Only after the 1986 reform did competition control achieve a higher standing in France.
German competition experts assisted their French colleagues in establishing a central and
independent enforcement institution, the Conseil de la Concurrence and with drafting new
legislation. As a result, the French and German legislations now look very similar (ibid:
404). However, the national competition regimes of the EC Member States are not entirely
51
identical.4 They vary in terms of: the regulatory scope and content of the laws, the
enforcement mechanisms, the degree of discretional autonomy enjoyed by the competition
authorities, the institutional resources invested, as well as the legal and economic
philosophies that underpin the enforcement practices.5 As a result of an enhanced pace of
economic integration over the past two decades, many national competition regimes have
adjusted to that of the EC (Gerber, 1998: 224; cf. Drahos, 2001).
The two-tier system of EC/EU and Member State competition law enforcement is similar
to the US Federal system, in which the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) and the
Department of Justice (DoJ) complement State-level antitrust statutes and enforcement
agencies. Depending on the scope of anticompetitive practices, either Community law or
Member State law is applied. The distribution of the enforcement powers follows the logic
that the best-placed authority should handle a competition complaint, as required by the
European subsidiarity principle outlined in Article 5 (TEC). The European Commission, as
a supranational competition authority, has exclusive powers over a range of areas.
Community law usually applies to anticompetitive conduct with a significant cross-border
dimension that is if trade and competition between the Member States is affected. In all
other cases, Member State law applies. Nevertheless, NCAs could apply parts of Article 81
and 82. Prior to 2004, they could not grant exemption as ruled under Article 81(3), which
provided little incentive to NCAs to cooperate with the Commission in the enforcement of
EC competition law (Jones and Levin, 2003: 13).
A detailed discussion on the heterogeneity of Member States competition regimes is beyond the remit of
this chapter. Instead, the focus is on a few general commonalities that allow for a summary, in broad terms,
of the European competition model.
5
For example, Greece adopted the first general competition law in 1977 as part of the preparatory program
for acquiring EC membership. Until far into the 1990s, competition law enforcement enjoyed only low
priority. Officials at the Greek competition authorities used to work only part-time.
52
53
powers. In fact, there is no comparable first pillar policy area, in which the Commission
enjoys similar wide-ranging powers. Whereas in other areas, the Commission usually sets
the agenda for the Council and the European Parliament on what to decide, in the field of
competition policy, it can act as an investigator, prosecutor, judge, jury, and executioner
in one, unless its decisions get challenged at the European Courts. Even though the
Commission takes important decisions as a collective in the College of Commissioners,
due to the technicalities that accompany competition law enforcement, it provides
considerable leeway in decision making. The Commissions DG Competition fulfils a key
leadership role in the daily enforcement of competition laws. It can investigate
anticompetitive conduct upon its own initiative (i.e. ex officio); it can take action based on
a complaint, or, on the ex ante notification regime. It can prosecute anticompetitive
conduct by stopping M&As, a commercial intercompany agreement, or a unilateral
corporate conduct. It can request modifications of a notified proposal, or even requiring
the break up of a conglomerate and force it to sell some of its divisions (Bannerman,
2002: 8). In the cases of non-compliance, it can sanction companies by the imposition of
fines up to 10% of a companys annual turnover. Even though the Commission has to
elucidate its decision, it does not need to give meticulous reasons for why it allowed or
prohibited a deal. Companies disagreeing with the Commissions decisions and
procedures can address the European Courts in Luxembourg, the CFI and the ECJ.
54
The issuance of regulations and directives build up cumulatively in number and scope
over time. It follows that the Commission could exert considerable influence on the future
course of competition law enforcement. The European Parliament, in particular its
Committee on Economic and Monetary Affairs, can try to exert influence by commenting
on the Commissions Annual Competition Policy Report. The Commission, however, is
not obliged to follow the EPs report, which renders parliamentary influence extremely
weak. Lobbyists, nonetheless, often target the Committees rapporteur, who scrutinises
the work of the Commission in competition matters (Wilks and McGowan, 1996: 240).
Furthermore, the Commission is not respond to voters preferences and electoral results.
The combination of these competences renders competition policy a unique field of
Commission power. As Competition Commissioner Frans Andriessen remarked, the
Commission is not dependent on the reluctance or inability of the Council of Ministers to
reach decisions on proposals, which it has put forward, and takes such decisions virtually
every week (Andriessen, 1983b: 5). The Commissions far-reaching discretionary
regulatory powers were further enhanced by the general and ambiguous notions within
which EC competition laws were framed, as well as the absence of a detailed analytical
framework specifying how competition laws should be enforced in practice. For example,
the notion if trade between the Member States is affected, which specifies which
anticompetitive conduct falls under Article 81 and 82, and hence, under the authority of
the Commission, provided the Commission, in principle, with a carte blanche in the
interpretation of competition laws, although it also needed to take into account the
possible interference of the Courts. On the one hand, this led to fierce criticism by
business as it rendered EC competition law enforcement highly ambiguous and uncertain.
On the other hand, the absence of a clear-cut, rule-driven enforcement also provided a
welcome avenue for corporate lobbying.
55
2.4 The Ex Ante Administrative Public Control Regime and the Possibility of
Exemptions for Commercial Intercompany Agreements
The EC/EU competition model entails an ex ante administrative public control regime,
which was designed to prevent, rather than to prosecute anticompetitive conduct. It builds
on a notification regime, according to which the parties give notice to a public authority
and ask permission prior to concluding a transaction. The notification procedure follows
the logic that everything not permitted is forbidden. Most European competition regimes
reveal this feature to some extent. Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, the
Netherlands, Norway, and Sweden can be subsumed in this category (Gerber, 1998: 173).
In the EC/EU competition model, notifications are required for all three pillars of
competition law, i.e. agreements falling under Article 81 (until the 2004 reform, see
Chapter 8), for planned mergers above a certain turnover threshold (since 1989, see
Chapter 5), as well as state aid projects intended by governments of the Member States.
Article 82 and 86 constitute an exception. In all other cases, companies, and in the case of
state aid, the Member State governments have to announce their plans to the College of
Commissioners. The Commissions DG Competition reviews the received notifications in
an administrative manner, which implies that most cases are settled, rather than litigated ex
post by courts (Harding and Joshua, 2003: 111). Once a transaction is notified, it is
automatically legally immune from prosecution by third parties. This renders the ex ante
notification and authorisation a benign, safe-haven procedure for companies. Although
there is no certainty with regard to the Commissions final decision on a notified case,
companies, as well as Member States in the case of state aid, can always ask the
Commission for permission without having anything to lose. As former Competition
Commissioner Frans Andriessen pointed out: business representatives would be better off
asking twice to avoid to go astray (1983c).
56
competition cases. Only in 5% of the cases did private actors take the initiative to bring an
action to court (Kemper, 2004: 9). Non-compliance with the notification regime or with the
decisions of the Commission was punished by declaring a transaction invalid or by
levying financial fines. Hard measures in the form of criminal sanctions enforced upon
individuals are absent at the EU, and in most Member States (Gerber, 1998: 175).
Individuals could be fined in Germany, Denmark, Greece, Spain, France, Ireland,
Luxembourg and Austria and in five of these countries, i.e. Germany, Austria, France,
Ireland, Luxembourg, individuals could even face imprisonment (Gauer, 2002: 11).
Nonetheless, criminal sanctions were seldom enforced.
Regulation 17 established the procedural framework for the application of Article 81 and
82 (TEU). As far as Article 81 is concerned, it introduced a system of notification for
commercial agreements falling under Article 81 (1). Companies meeting the Communitydimension turnover threshold had to notify all sorts of envisaged commercial intercompany
agreements and cooperative business practices to the Commission in advance (see Figure
2). Commercial intercompany agreements embrace all sorts of contracts other than fullblown mergers and acquisitions (M&As), although the boundaries between intercompany
agreements and mergers and acquisitions are often blurred. They can take place between
direct competitors (horizontal agreements) or companies involved in the different stages of
the production, distribution, or marketing process (vertical agreements). Examples are
production and R&D joint ventures, joint distribution, marketing and sales agreements,
(patent) licensing and franchising contracts, specialisation agreements, information
exchange and other cooperative activities. They can also integrate more structural longterm business objectives, or take the form of equity joint ventures, involve equity swaps or
minority holdings (Ullrich, 2003: 219).
Once notified, the Commission reviewed each case and controlled whether the intended
deal had the object or the effect of prevention, restriction or distortion of competition
within the common market as spelled out in Article 81(1). The Commission could either
prohibit or allow the deal, or grant exemptions. Based on Article 81(2), it could declare all
agreements prohibited by Article 81(1) null and void. Based on the conditions set out in
Article 81(3), it could grant exemptions on the basis of macroeconomic objectives.
Exemptions were justified as long as amongst others the intended deal promoted technical
or economic progress, or improved the production or distribution of goods, or as long as
57
it allowed consumers a fair share of the resulting benefit. Furthermore, the agreement
should not go beyond what is essential to attain those objectives and competition should
not be substantially eliminated (see Article 81(3) TEC). Article 9(1) of Regulation 17
stipulated that the Commission was the only instance that could authorise exemptions. The
Commission could grant individual exemptions to commercial agreements that in principle
were prohibited either on a case-by-case basis, or in the form of block exemptions. Block
exemption specified whole groups or categories of types or sector-specific agreements,
which were categorically freed from prosecution, i.e. not considered anticompetitive. They
took the form of regulations, which could be issued by the Commission, either without the
approval of the Council, or by the Council after a Commission proposal. Companies
disagreeing with the Commissions decision could file a complaint at the European courts
based on Article 230. Over time, the exemption regime came to cover a broad range of
agreements: vertical agreements, R&D agreements, specialisation and standardisation
agreements, servicing arrangements, technology transfer agreements, as well as specific
agreements in the motor vehicle distribution sector, the maritime and air transport sectors
and the insurance sector (Cini and McGowan, 1998: 98). It follows that, because of the
cumulative character of competition law enforcement, it became ever more tolerant
towards intercompany agreements over time.
Figure 2: The Centralised ex-ante Administrative Notification Regime of Regulation 17
58
(OJ C 368, 22.12.2001). Small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) anticipating the
conclusion of an intercompany agreement were usually excluded, because their actions
were assumed not to affect trade and competition within the Common Market. A company
is considered small or medium-sized if the annual turnover lies below 40 million, or if
the balance sheet is below 27 million, and if it employs a staff of no more than 250
people (Commission Recommendation of April 03 in OJ, 1996: 4).
The administrative ex ante public control model reflects an institutional artefact of the
more generic Rhenish or Continental European coordinated variety of capitalism (cf.
Wigger and Nlke, 2007).6 The Rhenish variety, or the coordinated market economy
model, is still the most widespread variant in the EU, not only because of the weight of the
German economy, but also because most of the old EU-15 (with the notable exception of
United Kingdom) fall into this variety (Hall and Soskice, 2001: 19). The central
characteristics of this variety are: a fairly balanced and consensual relationship between
labour and capital, strong employee involvement, a corporate governance regime of codetermination, a supporting role of the state, and the availability of patient capital provided
by major banks (Hausbanken), or internally generated funds. These features have been
conducive to a relatively long-term perspective with regard to the economic wellbeing of
firms. Stable ownership and control structures have provided companies with considerable
protection against hostile takeovers, which has particularly benefited SMEs, all factors
supportive to long-term investment strategies in human resource development, high skills,
and quality products.
The administrative ex ante public control model of the EU closely reflects the basic
institutions of the Rhenish model of capitalist organisation. It draws on the competition law
enforcement institutions of Germany, which constitutes a patent case of the Rhenish
model. The notification regime and the possibilities for exemptions created the necessary
flexibility in realising the Common Market. It provided the Commission with a market
interventionist tool to achieve the long-term goal of a balanced market structure. The basic
idea was to control the market and to withhold companies from engaging in harmful
anticompetitive practices. Whenever the Commission considered the overall benefits of an
anticompetitive conduct to be greater than its restraints on competition, it could allow a
deal, or declare entire categories of intercompany collaboration acceptable, or even
6
59
desirable. In other words, based on the notifications and their evaluations, the Commission
could distinguish between good or bad cartels and good or bad business practices.
The loosely defined conditions for exemptions provided ample scope for pursuing a multigoal approach in the enforcement of competition laws. It allowed for tailor-made decisions
with regard to industrial sectors or for sector-specific crisis management in times of
economic recession. This was the case in the 1970s, when the Commission allowed crisis
cartels and temporary government subsidies to rescue industrial sectors in recession, such
as coal and steel, sugar, the motor vehicle or shipbuilding industry (see Chapter 4).
Furthermore, the Commission could create incentives for corporate entities to share
economic risks in developing new products and technologies, engage in technological
transfers, and set product standards (Hall and Soskice, 2001: 17-21). This is exemplified by
the block exemption regulations for intercompany R&D cooperation (Regulation 418/85),
technology transfer (Regulation 240/96), specialisation (Regulation 417/85), and
standardisation (Horizontal Guidelines).
Rather than focusing on more narrowly defined competition effects, such as innovation,
efficiency, and lower prices for consumers, the Commission could enforce competition
laws as a macroeconomic market-interventionist tool. Referring to Article 3(1) (TEC),
which declares the strengthening of the competitiveness of the European industry a central
Community goal, it could focus on broader policy objectives in its decision making, such
as: favourable treatment of SMEs, employment and environmental considerations, broader
trade and industrial policy goals, as well as the more general promotion of market
integration and cohesion. The label cartel agreement did not apply as long as the
Commission sustained its decision with reference to an improvement of production and
distribution of goods, or technical or economic progress as ruled under Article 81(3). The
exemption regime thereby reflects the continuation of a tradition, which respected close
links of loyalty between suppliers and their customers, manufacturers and their
distributors, rather than the free play of competition (Goyder, 1998: 68). The exemption
regime introduced a legal possibility for excluding certain intercompany agreements from
competition, often for the sake of competition, or as Chapter 4 argues, also for the sake of a
neomercantilist strategy to make European corporations fit for competition in the world
market.
Placed in the broader historical context of capitalist development in Europe, the ex ante
public control model reflects the macroeconomic policy aspect of the broader embedded
60
liberalism bargain that lasted from postwar Europe to the late 1970s (see Chapter 4 for a
more detailed account). The overwhelmingly administrative character of the ex ante
notification authorisation practice, in combination with the generous exemption regime,
provided the European business community with a high degree of public support in the
pursuance of long-term strategies. The legal immunity from prosecution resulting from the
notification procedure provided companies with a safe-haven procedure in doing business.
It became a conventional practice to notify commercial agreements falling under Article
81, amounting to hundreds of cases per year (cf. Hwang, 2004). Moreover, the ex ante
notification regime also endowed companies with an avenue for lobbying. It could use the
vagueness of the legal devices to persuade the Commission to take a favourable decision in
their case. Usually, contacts between Commission officials and corporate managers
increased, particularly in the negotiation of exemptions.
As will be outlined in the next section, the ex ante public control model and in particular
the institutionalisation of a proactive powerful public market surveillance institution with
wide-ranging competencies, namely the Commission, reflects in many ways the legacy of
ordoliberals of the Freiburg School, who developed a theory of comprehensive
competition control in the 1930s.
2.5 Schools of Economic Thought: The Political Project of the Freiburg School
The introduction of competition laws in Germany, and later in the EEC, was informed by
the ideas of a group of scholars from the Freiburg University in Germany: the ordoliberals.
Their ideological positions and theories influenced a range of German politicians and
academics alike, who were involved in the building of economic institutions and the
formulation of policies in the postwar period. Although the overall influence on economic
regulatory policies that draws on the intellectual work of ordoliberals has waned since the
1960s, ordoliberal dogmas continued to have a remarkable stronghold in the field of EC
competition policy during the first decades of its existence (cf. Budzinski, 2003; Djelic,
1998; Gerber, 1998; Hlscher and Stephan, 2004; Monti, 2007: 79-82). References to
ordoliberal influence in the building of the EC/EU competition model often remain at the
margins in the competition policy literature, thus concealing the ordoliberal manifestation
in the evolution of supranational competition policy. Often, ordoliberals are merely
indicated as the Germans, who were obsessed with reproducing the German model and
61
the German virtues of competition policy at European level (Wilks and McGowan, 1995:
260). The parochial role of ordoliberal thinking in the history of EU competition policy
provided a philosophical framework for a balanced and flexible interventionist strategy in
the administration of anticompetitive conduct. The multi-goal and long-term orientation of
the ordoliberal understanding of competition created a strong role for a politically
independent competition authority in shaping the marketplace. Nonetheless, the regulatory
practice and policy formulation of EC competition law enforcement was far from a diligent
translation of the economic theory promoted by ordoliberals from the Freiburg School.
Had the founding fathers been taken seriously in the aftermath of the War, there would be
no large corporations in the Europe of today.
Franz Bhm and Walter Eucken also participated in the Freiburger Kreise, a resistance group of
intellectuals that became famous for their ideas on how to rebuild German society after the war (Gerber,
1998: 235).
8
Alexander Rstow and Wilhelm Rpke eventually left Germany, whereas Hans Grossmann-Drth had to go
to the Wehrmacht, where he died in 1944 (cf. Joerges, 2004).
7
62
Although the Freiburg scholars did not hold identical views, the endeavours of the
founding fathers of ordoliberalism, nonetheless, had a strong programmatic mission. They
signed the Ordo Manifesto of 1936 and entitled the first of their jointly edited volumes of
the series Ordnung der Wirtschaft: Our Task (Vanberg, 2004: 1). They launched an
academic journal called ORDO, which became the most important forum from the 1950s
onwards to promote their political views. Ordoliberals sought to make their ideas
accessible to a broader public by means of books, pamphlets, and newspaper articles. The
Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung in particular sympathised with ordoliberal ideas. For
example, Leonhard Miksch, an outspoken adherent of ordoliberalism, managed the
economic policy section and published many articles until the Nazis forbade the newspaper
in 1943. After the war, when the newspaper was re-established, ordoliberals occupied
central positions at the newspaper (Gerber, 1998: 258). This effective publishing strategy
allowed ordoliberals to approach both the intellectual and political elite, as well as the
wider public (cf. Commun, 2004).
What ordoliberals had in common was that they were all essentially market liberal in
orientation. They envisioned, however, a particular type of liberal market economy. As a
point of departure, they criticised the 19th century economic theorists that followed the
tradition of Adam Smiths laissez-faire market capitalism, which reduced the role of state
to a night-watchman function. Bhm noted in this respect, that even though a market free
from state intervention may be free, it is not ordered (Bhm, 1937: 107). Ordoliberals
anticipated bringing forth a more comprehensive view on society and markets, by
exceeding the scope of mere economics and law in their theories. They criticised the
neoclassical liberal tradition for perceiving the economic in isolation of the political and
the social (Gerber, 1998: 237). The narrow conceptions and the basic institutions
promoted by neoclassic liberalism, i.e. contractual freedom, private property and free trade,
as well as the self-regulatory forces of the free-market play, were not considered sufficient
to advance societal virtues such as honesty, incorruptibility, considerateness, selfdiscipline and fairness (Schller, 2005). The social, democratic principles, and humanist
values occupied a central place in their work. In the words of Eucken, everything is
socially important and social security and social justice should be the greatest concerns of
our time (in Schlecht, 1989: 303). Similarly, Rpke claimed not to decouple the freemarket economy from societal, political, and moral spheres, but to embed it in a frame of
economic and social policy, which beyond the market also protects the feeble, curbs the
63
self-indulgent, and curtails the negative spin-offs of economic power. A market economy,
in his view, was a necessary but not a sufficient prerequisite for a free, wealthy, just and
ordered society (in Borth et al., 1988: 218).
The more moderate economic liberalism promoted by the Freiburg School can be traced
back to the broader intellectual discourses of that time. The early work of ordoliberals
appeared in the Great Depression, a time of national protectionism, and a general
widespread discrediting of liberal ideas. John Maynard Keynes, for example, published one
of his first essays The End of Laissez-Faire (1926), and started to promote state-led
countercyclical demand management. At the same time, the critical ideas of the first
Frankfurt School on the political economy were thriving. Against this backdrop, Eucken
published a book on structural changes in the state and the crisis of capitalism, entitled
Staatliche Strukturwandlungen und die Krise des Kapitalismus (1932).
Ordoliberals expected the state to play a strong role and to act as guarantor of social justice
and human functioning of the market. They rejected the neoclassical, utilitarian view that
an aggregate of self-interested private market actors would act for the benefit of the society
as a whole simply by making use of their (economic) freedom. The strong emphasis on the
role of the state among its critics evoked the undertone of ordoliberalism favouring a
highly authoritarian state. Rather than an authoritarian state, ordoliberals advocated the
establishment of an economic constitution, which delineates the role of the state in the
marketplace on the basis of a strictly procedural and rule-oriented liberalism (Gerber,
1998: 237; Vanberg, 2004: 2). An economic constitution, from the ordoliberal point of
view, would complement the political constitution. It would form the basis upon which
fundamental economic institutional choices and substantive market principles could be
derived. This was necessary to guarantee what ordoliberals called an effective degree of
economic and political freedom that was morally justifiable (Gerber, 1998: 241).
According to Eucken, the distinction between form and process was essential: the nature
of state activity should influence the form of the economy, but not amount to state planning
and control of the economic process (Eucken, 1951: 95 in: Goldschmidt, 2004: 2). In his
understanding, the whole economy and its rules, both national and international, needed to
be consciously shaped and reshaped in the democratic process according to humane
principles (1950: 314). The notion of Interdependenz der Ordnungen, the interdependency
of orders, occupied a central place in ordoliberal theorising. In the holistic view of
64
ordoliberals, politics, the rule of law, the state administration, and churches, schools,
business and labour organisations, as well as the media, were all important ordering
institutions for society as an organic whole. Nonetheless, ordoliberals gave primacy to the
economic constitution as an ordering instance of the market, and to economic activity,
which was considered to form the central means by which society could be integrated.
Economic freedom would be a precondition for political freedom, and henceforth
democracy and the economic wellbeing of society as a whole.
Ordoliberals did not expect competition to evolve naturally. Only the careful cultivation of
the visible hand of the state would guarantee a continuously policed competition order
(Budzinski, 2003: 15). As there was no such thing as genuine economic behaviour,
ordoliberals reserved a crucial role for the interventionist arm of the state as the Hter der
Wettbewerbsordnung, the guardian of the competitive market order. All economic
behaviour, ordoliberals claimed, was shaped by political and legal decision making
(Gerber, 1998: 245). Therefore, a politically independent state institution, the competition
65
authority, was considered essential for competitive processes to take place. The
competition authority needed to be politically independent in order to avoid rent-seeking
market players inducing political leaders to go along with their preferences and change the
rules to their benefit. Bhm noted in this regard that a government is constantly faced with
a considerable temptation to meet the contradictory demands of pressure groups who, in
the pursuit of their narrow objectives ignore the common welfare of society (1989: 66).
The mandate of the competition authority, similarly to other state institutions, needed to be
constitutionally determined and subject to the rule of law of a modern Rechtsstaat. The
substantive content of competition laws needed to be formulated by the legislature and
made constitutionally amenable. In this vein, an independent and strong quasi-judicial
authority free from partisan influence would preserve the prerequisites for a balanced and
ordered market structure. The primary task of the competition authority was to establish
the proviso of vollstndiger Wettbewerb, complete competition, a notion that in the
ordoliberal ideal world refers to a state of affairs in which no corporate entity in a market
has the power to coerce the conduct of other firms (Eucken, 1938: Chapter III). Companies
needed to meet in the market as equals and economic exchange needed to take place on a
voluntary basis (Bhm, 1937: 105). A market order of equally matched market players was
deemed a prerequisite for the smooth running of competition. Competitive diversity
would benefit consumers, and the general wider society (Horton and Schmitz, 2002: 4).
Although ordoliberals agreed that complete competition was impossible to achieve in
reality, it should nevertheless constitute a normative reference point. This implied that
excessive private power in the form of monopolies and dominant market positions needed
to be prohibited. In the view of ordoliberals, economic power concentration was not an
indispensable element of a capitalist market economy, but the result of the reluctance of
the state to intervene in the market. According to Eucken, all relevant fields of economic
law, ranging from patent to corporate law, shareholder rights and liability schemes, tax and
trade policy, needed to be subordinated to the maintenance of minimised economic power
(Eucken, 1940 in: Vanberg, 2004: 14). This view also included the idea that shareholders
should not be allowed to hold shares in different companies, as this might lead to limited
competition (see De Long, 1990; Oswalt, 1996).
In the view of Eucken, the monopoly office was as indispensable as the highest court (in
Gerber, 1998: 254). Still, the competition authority should not directly engage with
66
Ordoliberals differed in their views about the stringency of competition. Ideally, an ordered
market economy was privilege-free and non-discriminatory. Nonetheless, as fierce
competition could be detrimental, ordoliberals considered certain forms of intercompany
collaboration acceptable (or even desirable). Although in principle Wilhelm Rpke (1994:
172) condemned cartels, he was nevertheless a proponent of allowing exceptions, in
particular if it served the rationalisation, specialisation, or diffusion of technology and
research. He particularly argued that competition should not become a guiding principle
for all spheres of societal organisation (1992: 191).
67
68
Political rhetoric and implementation practice, however, were not congruent. Erhard did
not envision a strong role for the state in redistributing welfare. His formula of social
market economy mainly served to appease the German population and its anticapitalist
conviction with the workings of a capitalist market economy. Rather than welfare benefits,
Erhard sought to realise prosperity for all through income increases and price reductions
(Berghahn, 1986: 205). In line with the Fordist perspective, borrowed from the US, he
believed that the rationalisation of the work process would lead to lower costs per unit and
to higher productivity rates, and consequently, to lower product prices and higher wages.
In Erhards Fordist welfare logic, sufficiently large corporations that were able to reap the
benefits of economies of scale needed to be created. He did not problematise large
corporations and monopoly positions in the market (see Chapter 3). Ordoliberals, in
contrast, feared that economic power concentrations in the form of large companies would
seek to gain political power, and to secure their status quo by the rule of law (Oswalt,
1995: 10). Erhard never considered himself as the executor of Euckens and Rpkes ideas,
69
Experts on German ordoliberalism debate the categorisation of Ludwig Erhard as an adherent to ordoliberal
philosophy. Whereas Goldschmidt (2004) is convinced that there is no doubt about Erhards affiliation with
ordoliberalism, Commun (2004) denies this.
70
The Walter Eucken Institute, founded by Ludwig Erhard in 1954 and sponsored by the
Commerzbank, is devoted foremost to the ideas of Friedrich August von Hayek, whose
ideas had already become influential in the late 1960s (Sddeutsche Zeitung 1994: 34).
Somewhat ironically, the Institute largely ignores his ideas. There is not a single
monograph of, or on Walter Eucken, whereas contributions from Hayek or on Hayeks
work are countless (TAZ, Tnnies, 2000: 14). The Institute left Euckens legacy of books
and unpublished work to his family, who founded the Walter-Eucken-Archive (Oswalt,
1995: 10). The subordinate position of Walter Eucken has also long been apparent in the
Institutes entry hall, which was up to recently decorated only with Hayeks portrait.
Euckens portrait now hangs there, but diagonally facing that of Hayek (ibid). Considering
that Eucken and Hayek were antagonistic colleagues, this is rather ironic. Even though
Hayek once worked at the Freiburg University, he and his disciples never supported the
ordoliberal idea of strong and proactive state institutions that would correct the workings
of the market by curbing economic power concentration (see for more Vanberg, 2002).
The Walter Eucken Institute, and also the Aktionsgemeinschaft Soziale Marktwirtschaft
form part of the elite networks and think tanks that are linked to the Mont Plerin Society,
a profoundly neoliberal think tank founded by Hayek in 1947 and named after the Swiss
mountain Mont Plerin. With a broad range of activities devoted to the spread and
development of Hayekian ideas, it encompasses a membership of approximately 500
individuals of high-ranking positions and an institutional machinery of more than 70 think
tanks around the world (Plehwe and Walpen, 1999: 4, see also Plehwe and Walpen, 2006).
The success of the Mont Plerin Society is revealed by the fact that since 1974 seven of its
members have received a Nobel Prize in Economic Sciences, an alternative prize modelled
on the official Nobel Prizes in the memory of Alfred Nobel and awarded by the Bank of
Sweden to outstanding contributions of economists. Notably, Hayek himself, in 1974
belonged to this group of Nobel Prize winners, next to Milton Friedman in 1976, George J.
Stigler in 1982, James M. Buchanan in 1986, Maurice Allais in 1988, Ronald H. Coase in
1991, as well as Gary S. Becker in 1992 (Plehwe and Walpen, 1999: 10).
The linkage between the Mont Plerin Society and the Nobel Prize awards in the discipline
of economics is no coincidence: the longstanding chair of the committee for this unofficial
Nobel Prize, Erik Lundberg, was a member of the Society himself (ibid). Most
importantly, many of these prize winners were highly influential in developing theories on
71
Traditionally, the Commissions DG for agriculture was headed by a French official, and the Internal
Market DG by a British official. Moreover, a Spanish official tends to preside over the DG Regional Policy
and an official from the Northern Member States the DG Environmental Policy (Hooghe and Nugent, 2002).
72
Generals and Assistants of the Director General were trained in German competition law.
Ernst Albrecht, for example, was Chef de Cabinet under Hans von der Grben from 19581967, and ascended to become Director General from 1967 to 1969. Manfred Caspari,
Director General, similarly was in office from 1980 to 1990, and his successors, ClausDieter Ehlermann, and Alexander Schaub, held this post from 1990 to 1995, and 1995 to
2002, respectively. Assistant Director General Gtz Drauz was appointed in 1999 and will
remain in office until 2009. Furthermore, Competition Commissioner Karel Van Miert
(1989-1994), a Belgian socialist, sympathised with ordoliberal ideas. He claimed to have
developed an interest in the writings of Ludwig Erhard very early on both privately and
professionally (Van Miert, 1998d: 1-2). In 1998, when he was awarded the Ludwig Erhard
Prize, he acknowledged that ordoliberalism had lost nothing of its relevance and that
again and again German politicians and competition specialists have taken a leading role
in the shaping and practical development of the European competition rules (1998d: 3).
The unwritten rule that every Director General needed to be a German started to lose its
hold with the arrival of the Prodi Commission (Kassim, 2003). With the imposition of
Philip Lowe from the UK as Director General for Competition in 2002, ordoliberal
influence was on the demise. He characterised the DG Competition as ideologically
divided in two camps, notably that of the Modernists and that of Jurassic Park. The
dinosaurs of the DG Competition, according to Lowe, were those still adhering to the
ordoliberal philosophy (Walbroeck, 2005).
To conclude, tracing and quantifying the continued influence of German ordoliberals over
time is an arduous task, particularly considering how ordoliberal ideas have changed over
the years. Discrepancies between theory and daily enforcement practice were
commonplace. Nonetheless, ordoliberal reflections continued to underlie the policy
mission of the DG in the 1960s, 1970s, and the early 1980s, a period in which EC
competition policy followed the broader embedded liberalism ideology (see Chapter 4).
73
74
Anticompetitive behaviour judged upon the rule of reason implies that anticipated harm
to trade is pondered against the benefits on a case-by-case basis. In addition, conduct
falling under the Sherman Act are assessd under the rule of reason. Article 7 prohibits acts
of concentrations only where they effect a substantive lessening competition, a notion
that brought forth the far-famed SLC-test in US merger control. The rule of reason
considerably increased the leeway of judges in interpreting the legality of market
concentrations. Moreover, it gave way to more lenient judgements. Antitrust cases required
an efficiency defence: as long as mergers and acquisitions resulted in more efficient
production and reduced costs, they could proceed. The mere size of a company, or the
existence of dominant market power, therefore, was not by definition considered an
offence. In practice, the rule of reason institutionalised an oligopolistic understanding of
competition (Peritz, 1996 in: Djelic and Kleiner, 2006: 289). Moreover, it implied that a
company was innocent until proven guilty. The differentiation between cartels as harmful
and company size as relatively harmless had important repercussions on the US market
structure. Mergers and acquisitions were legally accepted as the natural outcome of
successful competition and considered beneficial for achieving economies of scale. As the
formation of cartels was strictly ruled out in the US, companies choose to merge instead,
which resulted in particularly large companies. Until the end of the Second World War,
market structures in Europe, and most notably in Germany, were dominated by cartels as
the prevalent form of corporate organisation (see Chapter 3). Moreover, the European
model of ex ante notification and exemption procedure for commercial agreements implied
that, what in the US would fall into the category of cartels, were never completely ruled
out in Europe (see Part 1 of this chapter). In order to allow certain industries to deal with
chronic overcapacities, crisis cartels were sporadically permitted (see Chapter 4).
Figure 3: US Federal Antitrust Law
75
State-level antitrust enforcement can strongly deviate from that of the Federal authorities.
Harmonising antitrust law enforcement in the US, however, has never been an issue on the
political agenda (Calvani, 2003: 419). The authorities of the States have a reputation for
being more aggressive in the prosecution of anticompetitive conduct than their Federal
counterparts are. Moreover, they often seek to protect local companies from the
consequences of the anticompetitive behaviour of foreign companies. In particular during
76
the Reagan administration, State-level antitrust enforcement sought to redeem the lax
enforcement of the Federal authorities (Fox and Pitofsky, 1997: 243). As the next section
illustrates, in addition to the parallel enforcement of the State-level and Federal antitrust
authorities, two government agencies at Federal level are responsible for antitrust
enforcement.
77
and third, US Congress can co-define the course of enforcement by amending antitrust
statutes and other legislative measures. Thereby, the drafters of the Federal Trade
Commission Act sought to limit dominant partisan influence.
The bifurcated institutional division and the political influence overshadowing the
composition of the two agencies, resulted in a rather tense relationship between the DoJ
and the FTC (Gavil et al., 2002: 55; Fox, 1997: 341). The FTC often challenges the
practices of the DoJ. The political divisions are also manifested in the staff composition of
the two agencies: while the FTC was traditionally the preserve of economists, the DoJ
Antitrust Division is more comprised of lawyers (Peters, 1996: 59). Tensions emerge as
lawyers tend to be more conservative in their approach, balancing their arguments against
precedents and legal principles, while economists tend to be more willing to try out new
approaches and economic modelling (ibid). The DoJ and the FTC share the enforcement of
US antitrust law and fulfil similar tasks. Most notably, they both lack the authority to block
anticompetitive conduct and are merely equipped with investigatory powers. Courts, rather
than the two antitrust agencies, have the final say in the US. This renders US antitrust
enforcement a case-orientated endeavour in which the agencies have to litigate each case
before the courts. The public antitrust authorities find themselves on equal stance with
private actors who also enjoy the statutory right to prosecute antitrust violations before the
courts, a feature that is generally known as private enforcement. This why the US model is
also referred to as the court model, or the bifurcated judicial model (cf. Trebilcock and
Iacobucci, 2002).
The litigation powers of the FTC and DoJ differ. Generally, the DoJ is responsible for both
the Sherman and Clayton Act, and deals with the cases that require criminal sanctions.
Violations of the Sherman Act, i.e. horizontal cartels involving price fixing, bid rigging,
and market-sharing agreements, constitute so-called white collar crimes that can be
punished under US criminal law. As companies are considered to be legal fictions unable
to commit crimes, individuals are liable for antitrust breaches. Next to administrative or
civil sanctions in the form of an order to stop with a certain anticompetitive conduct, or in
the form of monetary fines, courts can jail individuals for up to three years (Chemtob,
2002: 199).11 This implies that cartel prosecution in the US can easily resemble a
11
In the 1990s, there were, on average, 35 individuals jailed for antitrust breaches, coupled with fines
averaging US$ 90,000 (Chemtob, 2002: 200). Over time, the fine maximum was increased several times: in
1974, Congress raised individual fines to US$ 100,000 and fines for companies to US$ 1 million in an
78
Hollywood-type feature film. The US antitrust authorities, for example, occasionally make
use of the FBI and investigation practices such as phone tapping and body wiring by
undercover agents (McGowan, 1996: 15). The FTC was primarily established for the
enforcement of the Clayton Act, and can only address those parts of the Sherman Act that
do not lead to criminal prosecution. To avoid the duplication of work, the agencies notify
cases to each other, and then decide which agency will conduct the investigations (Gavil et
al., 2002: 970). On an informal basis, the two agencies have divided cases on an economic
sector basis: while the DoJ specialises in the airline and telecommunication matters, the
FTC handles foremost the oil industry and pharmaceuticals (Litan and Shapiro, 2001: 12).
The fact that both agencies have to litigate anticompetitive conduct before the courts
results in a peculiar feature of the US antitrust model. As litigating a case before the courts
is a time-consuming and costly procedure, on average more than 80% of US government
cases are either abandoned or settled on a voluntary basis between the parties without a
court judgment, i.e. so-called consent decrees (Venit and Kolasky, 2000: 96). This has
resulted in a situation where since 1975, the US Supreme Court has not ruled in a
substantive merger case (Hwang, 2004: 133).
amendment of the Sherman Act (ibid: 197). In 1997, the maximum fines were increased once more to US$
350,000 and US$ 100 million respectively, and the famous vitamin cartel, Hoffman-La Roche, Ltd. was
punished with a fine of US$ 500 million (ibid).
79
the HSR (Davidow, 2002: 497).12 Thereby, all over the world, companies involved in a
merger have to determine whether or not they need to notify to the DoJ or the FTC, even if
there are no anticompetitive elements involved (Pitofsky, 2002: 56). As those companies
that are subject to antitrust enforcement also finance the lions share of the costs of the
Federal antitrust agencies, i.e. companies have to pay a filing fee of US$ 45,000 for each
transaction, companies not located in the US co-finance the operations of the US antitrust
authorities, something which eventually could turn to their disadvantage. In 2000, over
US$ 100 million and in 2001 US$ 86.3 million were collected under the HSR Act (ibid).
The reluctance to notify can lead to the imposition of fines. Notifying parties have to meet
the deadline of 25 working days before an agreement leading to a concentration will be
signed. In high-level cases, this deadline usually does not cause many problems, because
notifications tend to be preceded by informal triangular contacts not subject to a legal
deadline (Venit and Kolasky, 2000: 94). Meanwhile, other countries have also adopted
filing fees, such as Canada. In the EU, the notification regime is still free of charge,
although there are discussions on increasing the DG Competitions resources by
introducing a baseline fee of 30,000, adjustable to the size and complexity of the merger
(Bannerman, 2002: 11). So far, no decisions have been taken.
No other country has adopted an antitrust statute that contains equally broad substantive
provision and relies so heavily on a common law method of judicial interpretation to
implement them.
William Kovacic and Carl Shapiro of the US FTC and DoJ (2000: 58)
2.7.4 The Ex Post Court Model and the Anglo-Saxon Common Law Tradition
The US constitutes a leading example of an Anglo-Saxon common law scheme, which
underpins the institutional setup of the US antitrust authorities (cf. Boffa, 2004). This
means that US antitrust law enforcement is a case-orientated endeavour in which courts
constitute the ultimate resort for stopping anticompetitive conduct. The Sherman Act and
the Clayton Act are framed in vague and imprecise terms, embracing a simplicity virtually
unknown in modern legislative enactments (Gavil et al., 2002: 52). Initially, the rationale
12
In addition, the reform raised the notifying threshold in order to reduce the number of cases that fall under
the scrutiny of the FTC and the DoJ. Under the new rules, a transaction is judged if one parties has sales or
assets of at least US$ 100 million and the other at least US$ 10 million (Venit and Kolasky, 2000: 90).
80
was that too detailed laws would undermine the flexibility of the regulators that allows
them to adjust to different economic circumstances. In fact, there is no other competition
regime than the US in which antitrust rules have been formulated so broadly. Throughout
the past century, however, Federal judges produced lengthy judicial precedents that
interpreted, clarified, and refined US antitrust laws, rendering enforcement a highly
complex and specialist area.
As a direct consequence of the court model, anticompetitive conduct is prosecuted ex post.
The notion ex post derives from the Latin saying ex post facto, which refers to the situation
in which laws are enacted after the conduct has occurred. It is sometimes also categorised
as retrospective law. A central feature of the ex post court model is private enforcement,
entailing that private plaintiffs can bring antitrust breaches to the courts. Private antitrust
enforcement has a tradition of more than a century in the US. The Clayton Act of 1914
introduced a range of systemic features that made it particularly attractive for private actors
to initiate legal proceedings against corporations. The most prominent feature is the system
of treble damages according to which a successful plaintiff in the US can be awarded not
only the costs of suing (expert fees and attorneys fees), but up to three-times the damage
suffered from anticompetitive conducts. In terms of damage compensation, no other
national antitrust jurisdiction is as generous as that of the US. Even victims of
anticompetitive conduct from outside US territory may be awarded treble damages.
According to Section 16 of the Clayton Act any person, firm, corporation, or association
directly harmed in his or her business or property by unlawful conduct has the right to sue
before the US courts.
Other features that make it attractive to bring cases to the courts are class actions, which
allow plaintiffs to group together, sue collectively and share the costs of suing. Other proplaintiff rules are extensive discovery rights, the right to invoke a jury trial, as well as the
right of professional litigators to offer contingency fees, or to sell their legal services under
a no-cure-no-pay-condition. There are only a few restrictions to private antitrust
litigation, such as limitations to indirect purchasers who can only sue at some State courts,
but not at Federal court-level, or limitations concerning pass-on defences according to
which companies cannot forward damage claims to other companies. The US antitrust
model also entails a leniency scheme, which grants immunity from prosecution to those
who first confess to having participated in a collusive or other unlawful agreement. All of
81
these features constitute incentives for private actors to bring antitrust infringements to the
US courts, which has caused high levels of private enforcement throughout US antitrust
history. Litigation by the antitrust authorities merely constitutes a supplement to private
filings. Hitherto, more than 90% of all formal US antitrust actions were brought to the
courts by private litigators, or to put it differently: for every action pursued by the US
authorities before the courts, private actors pursue ten (Kemper, 2004: 9; Wils, 2003: 477;
Drn, 1996: 25). Over time, the level of private enforcement has increased. Whereas from
the early 1940s until the mid-1960s the ratio of private to government cases tended to be
6:1, from the mid-1960s to the late 1970s, private filings contrasted with public ones by a
significant 20:1. In the 1980s, as part of the influence of the Chicago School (see following
Section), private actions declined to a ratio of 10:1, which was due to the imposition of
higher burdens of proof for private plaintiffs and reduced options for receiving treble
damages (Gavil et al., 2002: 1000). Currently, class action filings in the US are ten times
as high as a decade ago. Even though the number of antitrust filings dropped by 10% from
2004 to 2005, private actions rose by 8,8% (McCarthy et al., 2005). In the first half of
2006, the number of private antitrust actions doubled (ibid), which indicates that even
private actors play an increasingly important role.
Private enforcement constitutes one of the most characteristic elements of the US antitrust
model, which has both its friends and foes. Proponents celebrate it as an additional check
and balance to the enforcement of the public agencies, which helps to remedy (potential)
laxness of public authorities and corruption, and to more generally increase the overall
level of antitrust enforcement. According to proponents, those who fall victim to
anticompetitive conduct which can be competitors, distributors and suppliers, as well as
consumers are likely to be more watchful than public agencies, and the double jeopardy
of public and private enforcers would create deterrence to antitrust violations. The
downside of the system of private enforcement is an excessive culture of litigation, in
which frivolous lawsuits are common. As the barriers for lawyers to certify class action are
very low, the net result of the US antitrust system is that a vast amount of private lawsuits
in the US are of a dubious nature.13 According to White House estimates, in the US, every
13
This can end up in bizarre outcomes, such as reported by credit cardholder Brian M. Carney, who was
awarded US$ 0.03 in the class action case Schwartz v. Citibank. He was not informed about the trial, nor was
he aware about having been treated unfairly, nor did he give his permission to sue the Citibank in his name
for late processing of payments. His lawyers, however, garnered US$ 9 million of the US$ 18 million
compensation payment (Carney, 2005). Customers of Citibank, henceforth, are now more likely to be
confronted with higher interest rates or the limitation of credits as a result of the awarded damage
payments.
82
two seconds a lawsuit is filed (Greenberg, 2003). The annual Stella Awards, although
rather a hoax than a serious contest, are symbolic for a litigation culture that has run out of
control. The Stella Awards honour the most outrageous and ridiculous lawsuits that are
brought to the US courts. The event was named after Stella Liebeck, the 79-year old
woman who in 1992 sued McDonalds for her burns after she spilled hot coffee on herself.
Mrs. Liebeck was awarded US $2.9 million as compensation for the damage suffered (see
for more www.stellaawards.com). Furthermore, private enforcement, in particular in the
US, tends to be biased towards plaintiffs. Private actors may first bring complaints to the
Federal antitrust institutions, which will provide them with necessary evidence for the
anticompetitive conduct, and then sue for damage compensation afterwards. In this way,
public enforcement by definition produces a multiplier effect: every public ruling triggers
further private lawsuits (Litan and Shapiro, 2001: 15). Since this can take place at both the
Federal and State courts, the US model, almost by definition, leads to a high number of
litigations. For this reason, the number of informal and voluntary settlements between
companies and public authorities tends to be high. Exorbitant damage payments may bring
corporations to a crisis, cause financial instability, hostile takeovers, or eventually
bankruptcy. This has created a situation in which US companies prefer to buy out plaintiffs
that threaten to litigate in order to avoid the vast costs of court trials and the risk of a
damaged reputation. US business representatives have repeatedly complained about the
easy access for private plaintiffs to the courts being a hidden tax on corporate America
(Litan and Shapiro, 2001: 15). In fact, in the end, this hidden tax is likely to be passed on
to employees and consumers, through lower wages, job cuts and higher prices. In addition
to the litigation risk, private enforcement increases judicial complexity for companies who
have to comply with the law. This is further enhanced by the fact that different judges
produce different interpretations of the same law. In short, the US business community is
interested in getting rid of the onerous elements of the US model, such as criminal
prosecution, class actions, and particularly the costly private treble damage action rule.
83
The ideas of economists and political philosophers, both when they are right and when
they are wrong, are more powerful than is commonly understood.
In order to stimulate the cross-fertilisation of the discipline of law and economics, special
antitrust departments at US universities were established. This was also the time when the
intellectual work of the Chicago School of Law and Economics at the University of
Chicago (hereinafter the Chicago School), started to gain influence. The Chicago School
incrementally changed antitrust discourse in the US, as well as wider political and
84
The early Chicago School emerged in a time when deconcentrationist views of the
Harvard School were dominant. Louis Brandeis from the Harvard School, a fervent
advocate of diluted market power, and author of The Curse of Bigness (1934), formed part
of Roosevelts team of political advisers. Under the influence of Brandeis, economic power
concentration was fiercely prosecuted as it was considered to have a negative impact on
industrial development and innovation (Hart, 2001: 4). The US encounter with the high
degree of industrial cartelisation in Nazi-Germany particularly stimulated US antitrust
enforcers to prosecute collusive practices, such as price fixing and market allocation, and
dominant positions, more vigorously and more stringently back home (Harding and
Joshua, 2003: 61-62).14 Structuralist approaches, i.e. approaches where the market
structure stood central, were dominant. Similarly to ordoliberalism, the emphasis of the
Harvard School scholars was to preserve a society of small, independent, decentralised
businesses and to keep economic power dispersed (Fox and Pitofsky, 1997: 236). For
example, the merger section of Clayton Act, which was barely applied in the past, was
amended with the Cellar-Kefauver Merger Act in 1950, which sought to protect the
interests of small and medium-sized business (ibid). In reaction to the antimonopoly
attitudes of the New Dealers, business representatives of larger combines pushed strongly
for more regulatory leeway in the formation of intercompany agreements instead. Chicago
scholars sympathised with these interests, and with the early work of Aaron Director on
antitrust issues in the late 1940s and early 1950s, the Chicago School started to challenge
the ideas of the Harvard School (Kovacic and Shapiro, 2000: 53). It only started to have
some impact on US Federal antitrust practices, however, from the late 1960s onwards, and
14
The focus of antitrust enforcement at that time was particularly directed against monopoly positions and
economic concentration. All economic concentrations with a combined market share above 20% were
deemed illegal (Mueller, 1997: 658). In addition, US trustbusters attacked international cartels involving US
companies like Allied Chemical, DuPont, Standard Oil, and General Motors (Wells, 2002: 59, 64).
Landmark cases were the Alcoa, short for US v. Aluminium Co. of America (1945), and the American
Tobacco (1946) decision. Nonetheless, under the New Deal, cartels were not categorically condemned. On
the contrary, government controlled industry-wide cartels were considered a means to steer economic
development (ibid: 35-37).
85
became dominant from the late 1970s on (cf. Gerber, 1998; Budzinski, 2003). In the
antitrust literature, the interwar period from the 1920s to the 1930s, is therefore sometimes
referred to as the first Chicago School, the 1960s and 1970s as the second, and the time
between the 1970s until today as the third Chicago School (Rutherford, 2003: 6).
Representatives of the Chicago School held coherent viewpoints and shared a commitment
to a broader political mission, which justifies speaking of a Chicago approach. As Gary
Becker, Chicago graduate and winner of the alternative Nobel Prize in 1992 described the
situation back in the 1950s:
There was a lot of self-confidence that we had the right answers and the rest of the
profession was wrong. We saw economic analysis as a powerful way to understand
behaviour, providing a lot of insight not only into the economy itself, but also how society
is organised. (Cited in Yergin and Stanislaw, 1998: 146)
86
The idea of perfect competition implied that the concept of market failure did not have any
meaning (Yergin and Stanislaw, 1998: 147). Chicago scholars put much emphasis on the
self-healing mechanisms of the market. Anticompetitive corporate behaviour was only
considered a temporary phenomenon, and hence, public market intervention was more
damaging in essence than anticompetitive conduct. Consequently, they attributed marginal
importance to competition control: structural market interventions should be the exception
and regulatory steering from the state should be restricted to a minimum necessary.
Cartels, however, should be prosecuted as they have clear negative effects on consumer
welfare in the short-term. With the single exception of cartels, the Chicago School showed
very little interest in busting anything else (Fox, 2003b: 91). Whereas most Chicago
87
scholars considered a certain degree of public market intervention necessary, the most
libertarian wing preferred no antitrust law at all (Fox, 2003b: 91). Even cartels would
eventually be self-destructive and wither at the expense of competition. Illustrative of this
is the view of the legendary Chicago scholar Milton Friedman, who considered antitrust
laws to be unduly intrusive, and to do far more harm than good. He suggested getting rid
of them (Friedman, 1999). In his view, corporate complaints about restrictive business
behaviour of dominant players were simply the cries of competitors, which sought
government protection from competition. Nonetheless, overall Chicago Scholars
considered cartels tantamount to corporate fraud against consumers and the supreme evil of
corporate market distortions.
The Chicago perspective on market behaviour was predominantly orientated on the shortterm, which implied that the market performance of individual companies constituted the
focal point of attention, rather than market structures of entire industries. Due to the
dynamics of competition, market structures were expected to recover themselves. For this
reason, there was no need for public policy to find structural solutions to regulate markets.
Chicago scholars propagated a permissive attitude towards size and dominant market
positions, as long as companies maintained competitive prices for consumers. Although the
market shares of a dominant market player could serve as an indicator of anticompetitive
conduct, they agreed that this should not be taken as conclusive evidence (Baker, 2003: 3).
Due to the workings of economies of scale and scope, greater economic concentration was
believed to bring greater efficiency effects. The product life cycle theory of Vernon (1966)
supported the view that the competitive game would eventually live on and monopolies
would vanish. Due to the high profit margins of new technologies, new products,
manufacturing processes, or business techniques, new competitors will enter the market
and undermine the monopoly windfall of the early starter, break it into an oligopoly, and
eventually, induce a situation of fierce competition in which economic power
concentration has dissolved. Therefore, merger restrictions of any sort were considered a
needless regulatory burden on companies. In the view of Milton Friedman, private
unregulated monopoly was the lesser of the evils when compared to government regulation
and ownership (in Yergin and Stanislaw, 1998: 148).
The whole raison dtre of competition was subordinated to the consumer welfare
paradigm. In the view of Bork, competition may be read as a shorthand expression, a term
88
of art, designating any state of affairs in which consumer welfare cannot be further
increased (Foer, 2004). Thus, the maximisation of the consumer surplus became
paramount in the assessment of anticompetitive conduct. Chicago scholars focused on
price reductions as the primary indicator and developed rigorous econometric models
based on neo-classical price theory (Fox, 1997: 340). Strongly behaviourist in nature, this
advocated an economic approach to legal analysis (Gavil et al., 2002: 63; cf. Posner,
1978; Slot, 2004: 445). The implication of this is that the use of price theories and price
modelling as a central reference point for determining anticompetitive conduct
quintessentially gives precedence to a microeconomic perspective and to short-termism.
The focus on prices limits the perspective to single company behaviour in relation to
consumers at a particular point in time and disregards macroeconomic issues like market
power concentration and market structure. The Chicagoan view therefore excludes broader
goals, such as the overall welfare of a society. It reduces societal interests to a generalised
view on consumers and corporate actors, and ignores the interests of other potential
stakeholders.
89
enforcement. Both parts of the US antitrust system, i.e. the short-term orientation and the
focus on the actual harm caused, rely on the critical notion that public market intervention
should be kept as limited as possible.
It follows from the litigation-orientated approach that there can be only one decisional
criterion upon which anticompetitive conduct is judged, otherwise the discretionary power
of the courts would exceed that of the political decision-makers, and the rule of law would
no longer be guaranteed. It should therefore be no surprise that the basic objectives of
competition policy and the mode of enforcement are closely intertwined. The Chicago
paradigm that came to dominate US antitrust enforcement further corroborated these
elements. The focus on efficiency gains, defined in terms of consumer welfare and
measured in terms of competitive prices, marginalised long-term market structure
concerns. Apart from overt monopolies, market concentration through mergers was not
considered a bad thing as long as prices remain competitive. Only collusive market
behaviour belonged in the category of anticompetitive practices. As a result thereof, longterm intercompany collaboration, which is meant to enhance the diffusion of technological
innovation, has no priority in the Anglo-Saxon variety of competition control.
Table 4: The Central Features of the US Competition Model
2.8.2 The Rise of the Chicago School in the 1970s and 1980s
Chicago scholars penetrated US antitrust thinking in the 1970s, at the zenith of Keynesian
ideas in the Western world. Richard Posner wrote his influential book Antitrust Law: An
Economic Perspective (1976) and Robert H. Bork wrote The Antitrust Paradox. A Policy
At War With Itself (1978). Although Keynesianism in the US never found a comparable
fertile ground to that of Europe, in the 1960s and early 1970s, the Supreme Court and the
Federal agencies balanced their decision making against wider social welfare objectives,
and were overtly hostile towards economic concentration. Commentators from the Chicago
School condemned the practice of dismantling larger companies in the 1970s as
90
unthinking zealotry and economic primitivism (Kovacic, 2003: 384; Kovacic and
Shapiro, 2000: 52; Fox, 2003b: 91). They fiercely criticised the authorities for punishing
normal business transactions like criminal acts. Under attack was the per se illegality of
non-price vertical restraints, such as exclusive deals and tie-in selling practices for business
entities with a dominant market position or a monopoly, i.e. those with a market share of
over 50% in the relevant product market or respectively a market share above 65%
(Murakami, 2002: 98). Chicago scholars deemed tie-in sales harmless as long as the buyer
was not forced to buy a tied product and as long as market access to competitors was
guaranteed. They were convinced that certain vertical restraints actually enhanced
efficiency, and thus competition. Most of the Chicagoan criticism was aimed at the
practice of condemning behaviour without proving its anticompetitive effect. In their view,
negative effects on competition needed to be substantiated and measured.
President Richard Nixon (1969-1974) appointed four antitrust judges to the US Supreme
Court who strongly sympathised with the free-market ideology and the permissive stance
towards conglomerate mergers of the Chicago School. The Supreme Courts decision in
the Sylvania case in 1977 (Continental T.V. Inc. v. GET Sylvania Inc) entered US antitrust
enforcement history as a turning point. The case concerned a particular form of vertical
price fixing. In line with narrow efficiency interpretations of the Chicago School, the Court
argued that the conduct was not anticompetitive, but rather conducive to competition
(Baker, 2003: 28). For the first time, it based its judgements on a comprehensive
economic analysis and set a precedent for enhancing consumer welfare as the only goal of
antitrust law (Ehricke, 2003: 115; Hwang, 2004:116). Thereby, references to broader social
and political goals within Federal Court rulings ended (Litan and Shapiro, 2001: 20). The
influence of the Chicago School celebrated its heyday under the presidency of Ronald
Reagan (1981-1989). What later was coined as Reagonomics, i.e. economic politics of
tax cuts, deregulation, monetarism, government retrenchment and free markets, was greatly
inspired by leading Chicago scholars. Reagan included Milton Friedman in his Economic
Policy Advisory Board, which was composed of a group of experts advising him from
outside the government during his tenure. In addition, the CATO Institute, headquartered
in Washington, D.C. and founded in 1977, also served as a platform for intellectual
breeding that advised the Reagan Administration. As one of the many sister think tanks of
the Mont Plerin Society, it held close ties to Milton Friedman and awards the Milton
91
Friedman Prize for Advancing Liberty (see for more information www.cato.org). In a
speech at the White House, Reagan declared:
Chicago school economics, supply-side economics, call it what you will I noticed that it
was even known as Reaganomics at one point until it started working all of it is fast
becoming orthodoxy. It's not just that Milton Friedman or Friedrich Von Hayek or George
Stigler have won Nobel prizes; other younger names, unheard of a few years ago, are now
also celebrated. (Reagan, 1987)
Under President Reagan, nearly all appointees to the DoJs Antirust Division came from
the Chicago School. William Baxter, who became the head of the Antitrust Division, was a
particularly zealous believer in the free- market idea (Wood and Anderson, 1993: 27).
Reagan also appointed a range of prominent Chicago scholars to the position of Antitrust
Attorneys at the different branches of the Federal Court. Richard Posner and Frank
Easterbrook held a seat in the Court of Appeals for the Seventh Circuit in 1981 and in
1985, respectively. Robert Bork was appointed to the Court of Appeals, yet his nomination
to the Supreme Court in 1987 failed due to blocked votes by the Senate. In addition, James
Miller became chair of the FTC and the first Chicago economist holding this position. The
influence of the Chicago scholars in the state apparatus was vital. The credo of free
markets, free from public regulatory intervention, planning, and public ownership,
prevailed. It evoked a period of antitrust retrenchment at Federal level. Antitrust
enforcement was not only reduced in scope, but also in the number of cases investigated:
from 1611 cases in 1977, by 1989 the number had declined to a mere 638 (Motta, 2004: 9).
The diminished scrutiny in antitrust analysis was accompanied by a significant reduction in
staff and resources during the 1980s. At the DoJ level, the number of lawyers was reduced
by 51% (from 422 to 254), and the number of economists by 11% (from 45-40) (Shepherd,
1991: 129). The overall budget dropped by 45% (ibid). Moreover, the number of private
antitrust suits also decreased: whereas during the 1960s private antitrust litigation
increased sevenfold, it amounted to 1,052 cases per year in the 1980s (Freyer, 2006: 148).
92
The relaxed merger controls in the Reagan era, combined with an overall deregulation of
corporate governance laws at that time, spawned the fourth big merger wave in US history,
which lasted from 1981 to 1989. There were more than a dozen mergers each day, which
mainly concerned larger companies acquiring smaller ones with the acquiring company
being, on average, ten times larger (Mueller, 1997: 656, 676). Market concentration
occurred in various sectors, but the changes in the banking industry were most farreaching: from the 1980s to the 1990s, more than 6,300 bank mergers were concluded in
the US, reducing the total number of banks by a third (Pryor, 2001: 315). In contrast, in the
1980s, price-fixing or market-sharing cartels falling under the per se prohibition rule were
prosecuted and also penalised more harshly (Litan and Shapiro, 2001: 18). Compared to
previous years, the number of incarcerated individuals increased significantly in the 1980s.
In the years between 1980 and 1984, 273 individuals spent a total of 1,008 months in jail
due to antitrust offences (Gallo et al., 2000: 129). The cases that were prosecuted almost
exclusively involved small enterprises (Kovacic, 1989: 173-206). Against the backdrop of
the fourth merger wave, smaller and medium-sized companies were particularly inclined to
conclude cartel-like agreements in order to be able to face the standards of competition set
by larger and more dominant players. In addition, small companies typically lacked the
necessary financial resources to employ professional legal counsellors for a successful
defence at the courts (Gallo et al., 2000: 119). The acme of the Chicago School took place
against the backdrop of worldwide economic downfall. With the collapse of the Bretton
Woods regime and the two subsequent oil crises of 1973 and 1979, US companies had to
back-pedal from their leading position in the world market. Competitors in Japan and
Western Europe, and Australia, increasingly posed a competitive challenge. Enhanced
mergers and acquisitions formed part of the US countervailing corporate strategy to face
93
foreign competition. The efficiency doctrine of the Chicago School and the highly
developed econometric modelling instruments served to legitimise public non-intervention
into US concentration activities. The strict prosecution of cartels, mainly concluded by
smaller competitors, matched the interest of larger corporations. In this sense, the
minimised antitrust enforcement of Chicago scholars represented an overt political effort to
strengthen domestic firms to compete in global markets.
15
Punches below the belt were common. In a speech before the American Bar Associations Section of
Antitrust Law in 1987, Senator Howard Metzenbaum, Chairman of the judiciary Subcommittee on Antitrust,
Monopoly and Business Rights, called the Reagan antirust leaders a garbage barge of ideologues (Pitofsky,
1996a).
94
2.8.3 The Continuation of the Chicago School in the US: Facts and Fiction
Although Chicago School doctrines have been fiercely criticised since the Reagan
Presidency, its premises have had an enduring impact on US antitrust enforcement. As
Chicago scholar Richard Posner declared:
Almost everyone professionally involved in antitrust today [] not only agrees that the
only goal of the antitrust laws should be to promote economic welfare, but also agrees on
the essential tenets of economic theory that should be used to determine the consistency of
specific business practices with that goal. Agrees, that is, that economic welfare should be
understood in terms of the economists concept of efficiency []. (In Foer, 2004)
Throughout the 1990s, the Chicago School continued to instigate academic discussions,
and Chicago scholars remain widely cited from 2000 onwards. For example, Robert H.
Bork generated renewed attention with his book The Tempting of America: The Political
Seduction of the Law in 1990. Commentators sometimes consider current times as the PostChicago School era, which started in the early 1990s (First, 2002: 183). The post-Chicago
blend fails to form a unified school (Schmidt and Rittaler, 1986: 11-2). Nonetheless, the
central neoclassical yardsticks of microeconomic price theory, efficiency, and consumer
welfare maximisation continue to be emphasised, albeit in a slightly less orthodox way
than by the Chicago scholars under the Reagan Administration. The vision that antitrust is
fundamentally about consumer interests, rather than wider social goals, such as
employment or the protection of SMEs, is commonly accepted in the US (Crandal and
Winston, 2005: 42-3). The actual enforcement practice of the Federal antitrust authorities
supports this. Up to the present day, monopolisation cases constitute a small fraction of the
overall investigations, which can be seen as a vestige of the Chicagoan permissive attitude
towards corporate size. On average, less than ten investigations a year concern monopoly
cases (cf. Hwang, 2004; Kovacic and Shapiro, 2000; First, 2002). In this regard, mergers
and acquisitions also continue to be subject to an overall diminished scrutiny (Hwang,
2004: 116). Similarly, most forms of unilateral action, even if conducted by monopolists,
tend to be considered harmless. Post-Chicago scholars, however, took a slightly more
interventionist stance, particularly with regard to challenging exclusionary and vertical
market conduct, such as tied-in selling, or predatory pricing (Foer, 2004). Therefore, to
date, no successor paradigm has replaced the dominance of Chicagoan thinking. In contrast
to the theory-minded first generation, post-Chicago scholars conducted greater empirical
research and collected evidence that was more factual. Econometric modelling became
95
The sustainability of the Chicagoan legacy is due to several factors. Up to the present day,
courts and generations of lawyers have continued to employ the views and analytical
concepts of the Chicago School (Gavil et al., 2002: 64). In fact, prominent scholars of the
Antitrust Division were elected as judges into the US Supreme Court. Richard Posner,
leading Chicago scholar and appointee to the Court of Appeals in 1981, became its chief
judge from 1993 to 2000, and more than half of the Federal judges participated at the
Chicago Trainee Program (ibid). Conservative, neoliberal foundations usually cover all
expenses of the two-week indoctrination of Chicago economics, which usually takes place
somewhere in the Caribbean (Lea, 1999). In these programmes, judges learn that antitrust
enforcement is wrong and that monopolies are good, something which is also emphasised
in the literature, supplied to judges afterwards (ibid). Thereby, Chicagoan theorems
continue to penetrate US antitrust jurisprudence. As a commentator put it, the Chicago
School remains a potent force as long as its adherents still sit on the Federal bench (Hart,
2001: 10). The voice of the judiciary is further enhanced by the case-by-case litigation
approach. Rulings by judges are not easily reversed. Once established, economic and
judicial concepts therefore tend to endure. They become part of a deeply engrained
philosophy, locked into the body of law that is constitutive for future antitrust rulings. The
Merger Guidelines, adopted under Reagan in 1982 and 1984 are an example of this. They
calibrated the scope and content of anticompetitive mergers to the economic concepts of
the Chicago paradigm and marked a considerable shift away from the more market
structure-inspired 1968 Guidelines (Mueller, 1996a: 236). Whereas the 1968 Guidelines
were based on statistical concentration levels as a focal point of determining
anticompetitive mergers, the Reagan Guidelines were biased towards efficiency gains,
rather than market size. In the 1992 revision of the Merger Guidelines, Chicagoan
influence was dominant again. The permissive attitude towards unilateral competitive
effects of mergers and the efficiency reasoning was not touched upon (Gavil et al., 2002:
68).
96
The Chicago views underwent a revival under the presidencies of Bush Senior and Junior,
which also made it difficult to attain changes in enforcement attitudes. Under George Bush
Senior, who already served as Vice President under Reagan, a slightly more activist
approach was adopted. However, in essence, little changed. The bias for corporate bigness
endured and mergers could be concluded unimpeded by the antitrust authorities (Mueller,
1993: 160). Under the maxim Back to the Future, his son, George W. Bush re-employed
many of the Chicago-brigades that already served during the Reagan administration in the
early 1980s, the epitome of the Chicago-School. Timothy Muris, Chairman of the FTC
since 2001, for example, was one of the main architects of Reagans antitrust agenda in the
1980s. He became famous for his laissez-faire view according to which not corporations,
but governments posed a threat to competition. In line with Chicago-style thinking, George
W. Bush defended the lenient stance of US antitrust authorities by saying that the
application of antitrust laws needs to be applied only where there were clear cases of pricefixing (Wolffe, 2000: 14).
The US antitrust laws are often assumed to be the strictest in the world (Taylor, 2006: 349;
Mueller, 1996b: 415). This is true for the 1960s and the early 1970s, which can be
classified as an overtly active period of antitrust enforcement. The overall enforcement
attitude of the US antitrust authorities under the Reagan Presidency, however, was lax. The
enforcement attitudes of the 1990s demonstrate that the norms established during the 1980s
persisted. Antitrust officials under the Clinton Administration (1993-2001) generally argue
that they tried to strike a pragmatic middle ground between the excessively active
enforcement in the 1960s and the minimalist laissez-faire enforcement of the 1980s
(Pitofsky, 1996b; Kovacic, 2003: 378). Leading officials of Clintons antitrust crew
criticised the way the Chicagoan efficiency dogma continued to be applied by the US
courts, i.e. Robert Pitofsky, FTC Chair from 1995 to 2001, Eleanor Fox, Assistant
Attorney General for Antitrust of the United States from 1997-2000, and Harry First, Law
Professor at the NYU. For example, in 1979 Pitofsky wrote an article entitled The
Political Content of Antitrust in which he stressed that political values, and not the
Chicagoan type of efficiency should be the benchmark of antitrust law enforcement
(Ullrich, 2003: 10). During the Clinton Presidency, and its ambition to walk the Third
Way, a more activist antitrust enforcement policy was adopted, the budgets of the FTC
and the DoJ were increased substantially, and experienced private attorneys were hired
(Crandal and Winston, 2005: 42). Compared to 1981, in the year 2000 the total antitrust
97
budget increased by more than a third (from US$ 107.7 million to US $ 146.9 million),
whereas the enforcement expenditures for controlling monopolies and mergers almost
doubled (from US$ 31,1 million in 1981 to US$ 57,2 million in 2000) (Kovacic, 2000). In
total, the Federal Government spends roughly US$ 150 million per year on antitrust
enforcement (Ehricke, 2003: 118). The enforcement focus shifted away from the shortterm Chicago views on actual price effects for consumers, to a more long-term orientation,
which took the future impact of economic transactions into account (Litan and Shapiro,
2001: 5).
The enhanced antitrust enforcement under Clinton, however, only holds if it is compared to
previous enforcement records. In total numbers, the FTC challenged 35 mergers in 1995,
the largest annual record since 1979 (Baker, 2003: 8). The DoJ Antitrust Divisions
involvement in analysing transnational corporations rose from 5% to 29% between 1993
and 1997 (Freyer, 2006: 151). Intervention mostly took place in cases of horizontal
mergers in relatively concentrated markets, such as the soft drink industry, of which
Federal Trade Commission v. Coca-Cola Company became a landmark case (cf. Pitofsky,
2000). Nonetheless, against the backdrop of a considerably increased merger activity from
the mid-1990s onwards, the absolute number of blocked concentration activities is
misleading. The financial market deregulation that started under Reagan and Bush
continued under the Clinton Administration, which facilitated both horizontal buyouts and
mergers and acquisitions. In 1995, 2800 mergers and joint ventures were filed, and there
were more than 4000 mergers per year in the period from 1998 to 2000 (Pryor, 2001: 312).
In less than 5% of the proposed transactions, the US antitrust authorities initiated more
detailed investigations (ibid: 3). Even though the public authorities challenged a few highprofile mergers between corporate giants and monopolies before the courts, such as
Microsoft, Intel, Visa and MasterCard, American Airlines and Toys-R-Us, the proportion
of litigated mergers was rather low (Litan and Shapiro, 2001: 12). Similarly to his
predecessors, the bottom line of antitrust enforcement under the Clinton Presidency was to
account more generously for mergers synergies in analysing competitive effects (Baker,
2003: 32). The view that antitrust enforcement was supposed to encourage efficiency in
order to serve consumer welfare also prevailed among Chicago School critics (Pitofsky,
1996a). When the Merger Guidelines underwent a reform in 1997, the Chicagoan
efficiency notion survived as the most central yardstick for assessing anticompetitive
conduct. In other words, since the 1980s the degree of industrial concentration through
98
mergers increased considerably in the US (Pryor, 2001: 317). Since the ascendancy of the
Chicago School, only a handful of the thousands of merger concluded per year are
prevented (Mueller, 1997: 680), while the vast majority of antitrust cases (about 1500
cases on an annual basis) was dismissed without further investigation (Lea, 1999). The
Post-Chicago era meant that interpretations were refined with highly sophisticated
analytical techniques and specific algorithms for the definition of markets and market
boundaries were developed, without touching, however, on the essence of the Chicago
theorems on efficiency gains.
99
Chapter 3
Going Back in History:
The Evolution of the European Model of Competition Control
Introduction
This chapter analyses the historical evolution of competition laws and practices in the US,
Germany, and henceforth in the European Community. On the basis of an analytical
narrative covering the time period of US military occupation in post-war Germany until the
adoption of the Treaty of Rome in 1957, it unravels the particular historical interest
configuration that brought competition laws and practices into the realm of European
integration. It subsequently embeds the evolution of competition laws in Germany, the
European Coal and Steel Community (ECSC), and eventually the European Economic
Community (EEC), in the context of the wider political economy at that time. First, it
reveals that competition laws formed part of the wider political project to establish a
market capitalist regime in Europe, an endeavour initially carried by a US coalition of
political and economic interests. However, the political and economic elite in Europe
subsequently endorsed it.
Going back in history reveals that strong US influence in the aftermath of the War was
crucial for why competition laws came to form the constitutional cornerstone in the
restructuring of the German economy and subsequently, in setting in motion the European
economic integration project. Second, the chapter argues that rather than a wholesale
Americanisation, the specific outlook of the competition law enforcement institutions
was shaped by the ideas and concepts of a small group of economic and legal theorists, the
German ordoliberals of the Freiburg University. Due to the prominence of the Freiburg
School on economic thought in Germany and its legal system, US antitrust discussions
never had a serious chance to become established in Germany (Fikentscher, 2003: 17). By
drawing on existing, but widely disregarded research and archival documents, the chapter
lays bare how this small group of intellectuals, under the patronage of the US Occupation
Forces, ascended from their enclave in Freiburg to restructure the German political
economy, and subsequently shaped the first supranational competition laws in European
Coal and Steel Community (ECSC) and the Rome Treaty. The close supervision of the US
authorities during the formative phase of the European integration project opened a
window of opportunity for ordoliberals. Third, the chapter demonstrates that by lobbying
101
the political decision-makers drafting the Treaties, national industrial elites blocked a
wholesale translation of ordoliberal ideas. Concomitantly, US political support of
ordoliberal influence in the institution-building process was critical in both Germany and
integrating Europe, but not all determining. National industry opposition could not prevent
the inclusion of competition laws, but influence the particularities of what previously was
identified as the European competition model a heuristic device to characterize the
institutional enforcement structure of EEC competition laws.
Most of the literature on European integration largely ignored the influence of ordoliberal
doctrines on the institution building process in the European Community. Only a limited
range of authors, mostly from the disciplines of economics and law, and foremost of
German origin, paid attention to the important role of Freiburg scholars (cf. Joerges, 2001;
Budzinski, 2003; Gerber, 1998; Gillingham, 2003). A possible explanation for the reason
why so many scholars outside Germany disregarded the ordoliberals is probably because
their work is almost exclusively in German. English translations or analyses recapitulating
their work were long hard to find. According to Joerges, the more complex explanation is
that political scientists do not take normative theories seriously enough (2004: 13). Here
it is argued that the particular normative ideas of the ordoliberals find their origin in the
opposition to the politico-economic structure of (totalitarian) monopolistic capitalism in
Germany.
102
In line with Marxist reasoning, Neumann (1942) ascribes the evolution of monopolistic
capitalism to the dynamics of competition against the backdrop of freedom of contract, free
trade, and free competition. The fiercer the competitive struggle, the more the exploitation
of economies of scale, expansion, and hence, capital accumulation for investments in new
technologies becomes crucial for economic survival. Thereby, competition turns into a
coercive force transforming classical small and medium-sized (family-owned) companies
into large-scale corporate entities able of eliminating economic risks and generating the
necessary investments. The process of ongoing economic power concentration and
centralisation culminates in an oligopolistic, monopolistic, cartel-dominated market
structure. After a period of consolidation, the corporate elite, running cartels, oligopolies,
monopolies, and the financing banks, forms a community of interest seeking to maximize
profits. Consequently, to secure economic power and the institutional prerequisites for
capital accumulation, carteleers and monopolists seek to influence the state machinery in
order to subordinate the masses to the policies of industrial empires (Neumann, 1942:
260). State-imposed protectionist policies, such as the establishment of tariff walls, help
cartels to gain additional profits. With reduced competition in the domestic market, prices
can be raised, and more surpluses extracted. Bukharin noted in this respect:
[] various spheres of the concentration and organisation process stimulate each other,
creating a very strong tendency towards transforming the entire national economy into
one gigantic combined enterprise under the tutelage of the financial kings and the
capitalist state, an enterprise which monopolises the national market []. (Chapter IV,
The Inner Structure of National Economics and the Tariff Policy, emphasis in the
original)
103
US antitrust enforcement. It is often considered if not the most powerful instrument for
economic policy in the United States, definitely the most characteristic (Letwin, 1981: 3).
In 1914, the Clayton Act complemented the Sherman Act. Together with the Sherman Act,
they constitute the Magna Charta of free enterprise. They were the political result of a
broad-based popular protest movement against the concentration of economic power in a
period of monopolistic capitalism.
The Sherman Act was adopted in the context of rapid industrialisation in the late 19th
century US. Markets grew in size, the subsequent extension of railroads facilitated
transportation, and new technologies increased industrial productivity and communication.
When the economic depression of 1883 hit the economy, demand stagnated and industries
engaged in overproduction. Competition intensified. Against the backdrop of the open
world economy at that time, this was even more so the case. In the period between 18701914 cross-border trade and investment was greater than at the end of the 20th century,
relative to the world population at the time. Cross-border trade grew 3.4% per annum and
its value was 33% of total world output (Hirst and Thomson, 1999: 21-22). In response to
tightened competition, giant trusts emerged a sort of vesting shareholdings or holding
companies of several legally independent companies in a particular industry (Goyder,
1998: 4; Djelic, 2002: 241). The term trusts derives from the certificates issued to the
trustees of these inter-firm networks. The participating companies remained independent
legal units, while combining their endeavours in a larger unit. In contrast to the much more
loosely organised price cartels, trusts institutionalised cooperation on a more permanent
basis. Trusts controlled operating and investment decisions, fixed prices, imposed output
limitations, and allocated local and regional markets. Thrusts eradicated competitors,
coerced suppliers and distributors, and dictated high prices for customers. They wielded
monopolistic control over entire industries, such as steel, cattle, cordage, cottonseed oil,
lead, oil, sugar, tobacco, whiskey, and linseed oil (Djelic, 2002: 241).
104
financiers that controlled these trusts also enjoyed monopoly power over new technologies,
in particular that of railroads and telegraphs (Wells, 2002: 28). They were located at the
financial centres in New York, Boston, Philadelphia, and Baltimore and sometimes even
London. Most notably, they held close ties with the political elite (ibid). Farmers and small
companies, but eventually also the wider society, struck by poverty, and unable to compete
with the prices of the large trusts, came to protest against the practices of large trusts,
which culminated in the formation of an antitrust movement demanding an antitrust
legislation. The issue of antitrust control made its way into public consciousness to an
extent that was probably never seen again. Bankers were often the target of the popular
antitrust movement as their decisions often turned against smaller shareholders (Fennema,
1982: 4). Commentator Timberg embedded the broad-based resentment of the little man
against economic power concentration of large trusts in the particular historical
constellation that characterised the American way of life: farmers and small town
entrepreneurs were all ambitious, mobile, optimistic, speculative, anti-authoritarian,
egalitarian, and competitive (2003). At the heart of the antitrust debate was the question
about the role of the state in relation to the emerging corporate market order and the power
of large companies. The central issue at stake was the extent to which private companies
were to be granted the right to organise the market by themselves, and to what extent the
state authorities should intervene, as well how large companies should grow. In 1890,
Senator John Sherman drafted a law to prohibit large trusts. Section 1 prohibited every
contract, combination in the form of trust or otherwise, or conspiracy that restrained
interstate or foreign trade. Section 2 forbade attempts to monopolise. In his speech before
Congress, Sherman argued that early trusts were governed only by selfishness:
If anything is wrong, this is wrong. If we will not endure a king as a political power, we
should not endure a king over the production, transportation, and sale of any of the
necessaries of life. If we would not submit to an emperor, we should not submit to an
autocrat of trade. (Statement of Senator Sherman (1890) in Bork, 1966)
In the years to come, the driving forces of the antitrust movement, i.e. the strong farmer
lobbies and small entrepreneurs, also pushed for antitrust laws at the level of the States. In
1899, almost all states located in or near the Mississippi Valley adopted antitrust laws.
Boudreaux and DiLorenzo (1993: 82) ascribe this to the fact that the powerful farm lobbies
from the Midwestern agricultural states attempted to thwart competition from the large
centralised meat or wheat processing industries of the cities. Today, the term trusts is
105
rarely used anymore. Instead, the more general amalgam cartel has become more
widespread. Nevertheless, the word antitrust endured among US practitioners and
academics specifically to refer to the fight against cartels and restrictive business practices,
whereas in Europe and the rest of the world, the more generic analogue competition
policy became more widespread.
The enactment of the Clayton Act took place against the political backdrop of an upcoming
protectionism in the world economy, in which national government blocked cross-border
trade flows by imposing tariff walls as high as 40% (Scholte, 2001: 522). In the time of
economic crisis in the US, antitrust sentiments revived and socialist ideas prospered
(Zweynert, 2004: 11). Under the Presidency of Theodore Roosevelt (1901-1909), antitrust
106
enforcement became steadily more stringent. Large corporations came under attack and
public market intervention culminated in the administration of prices (ibid). Increasingly,
the Sherman Act was considered an insufficient legal basis to tackle economic power
concentration and the accumulation of capital into ever fewer hands. In 1914, under the
tenure of President Woodrow Wilson (1913-21), US Congress adopted the Clayton Act.
Section 7 regulated large companies and mergers that substantially lessen competition
and that tend to create a monopoly. It prohibited exclusive agreements and tied-selling
agreements, i.e. the practice of linking the selling of one product to another (cf. Fox and
Pitofsky, 1997; Litan and Shapiro, 2001). Moreover, it also prohibited three types of
interlocks between boards of directors: between banks, between directly competing firms,
and between railroads and their potential suppliers (Fennema, 1982: 20). In addition to the
new antimonopoly legislation, in the same year the Federal Trade Commission Act was
adopted to prohibit unfair methods of competition in or affecting commerce, and unfair or
deceptive acts or practices in or affecting commerce. It erected the Federal Trade
Commission (FTC) next to the Antitrust Division of the Justice Department (DoJ) as a
second independent administrative body to enforce the new law.
The Clayton Act expanded the regulatory scope of antitrust control. Similar to the Sherman
Act, it entailed provisions to protect the interests of smaller and less powerful companies.
However, broadly formulated notions such as substantially lessening competition lacked
a clear definition (see also Chapter 2). In essence, the Clayton Act did not inhibit
companies from growing in size, but rather attempted to control concentrations in the
context of the existing market structure. Whether or not a merger created a dominant
position was irrelevant as long as it did not substantially lessen competition. In other
words, even though the Clayton Act was established to curb the economic power of large
enterprises, it did not prohibit economic concentration. The judiciary enjoyed far-reaching
room for interpreting the Clayton Act. The US Supreme Court subsequently used the
Clayton Act in the favour of large industries (cf. Mueller, 1997). In the years immediately
after the First World War, the US experienced an economic boom, which resulted in an
enhanced liquidity of capital markets and gave companies the possibility to acquire other
companies by means of debt creation. The investment banking industry was fundamental
in the financing of concentration activities. It was both the trigger factor for the second
merger wave, and eventually also for its halt, when the increasingly high returns on
investors slowed down the economy (Gaughan, 2002: 28-30). Also the level of
107
lines,
enhanced
mechanisation,
meticulous
managerial
control,
and
organisational hierarchies. The resulting efficiency gains, which led to higher wages and
improved living standards for workers, were in turn expected to increase demand for the
goods produced for the mass consumer markets. Typically, Fordist companies were
characterised by a high vertical integration in which a few dominant firms assembled the
108
finished products from their manufacturing subsidiaries (cf. Knudsen, 1996). High levels
of vertical integration freed companies from their dependence to suppliers and distributors
and allowed for centralised managerial control.
The enforcement of antitrust laws constituted one of the supportive regulatory frameworks
that facilitated the Fordist production model. The tolerant attitude towards economic
concentration and centralisation buttressed the diktat of efficiency in the production
process. Under the guidance of Thurman Arnold, the DoJs Antitrust Division did not
problematise company size, but industrial inefficiency, particularly if efficiency gains were
not passed on to the consumers (Wells, 2002: 41). Thereby, the purpose of antitrust control
was to force companies to be efficient in their production. The number of antitrust
officials at the DoJ and the cases scrutinised in the late 1930s increased considerably from
58 to 200 and from 11 to 92 (Wells, 2002: 40). The emphasis on corporate efficiency
brought Arnold and his antitrust crew into battle with labour unions, which feared
increased unemployment (ibid: 41). However, political opposition to the new Fordist
course in antitrust control soon vanished. Large-scale mass production provided cheaper
consumption products, such as cars, washing machines, radios, vacuum cleaners, and
refrigerators that became available to broader segments of society, and this subsequently
weakened support for labour organisations. Strange to say, but in 1940, the DoJ even
attacked labour unions on the basis of anticompetitive practices of organised labour
(Wells, 2002: 55). The weakness of labour organisations contrasted sharply with the
strength of business.
109
amendment of the Sherman Act in order to allow the integration and coordination of
business efforts (ibid: 54) an euphemistical demand for abolishing the Sherman Act and
thus allowing cartel-like agreements. Yet, cartels were still perceived to be too
controversial (ibid: 85). Nevertheless, as private industry was crucial to the US defence
machinery, antitrust enforcers turned a blind eye on cartel behaviour during the War.
Examples of US companies engaging in international market sharing cooperative
agreements with foreign competitors are General Electric, DuPont, Allied Chemicals,
Standard Oil, and Imperial Chemical Industries (ICI), which had a strong stake in cartel
ties with the German IG Farben, as it invested heavily in a process to produce oil from
coal (Wells, 2002: 46, 75-6).
The following sections demonstrate that the emergence of large-size companies in the US
and their intimate relationship with US government was not only crucial for the hegemonic
economic and political role played by the US after the Second War, but also for the export
of US-type antitrust laws to Europe.
110
enacted the Sherman Act. Due to the dissolution of the legislature, however, these laws
failed to pass the legislative process (Gerber, 1998: 7).16 According to Fennema (1982: 3)
one of the reasons for the absence of a popular antitrust movement was that socialist forces
were rather unconcerned about the trustification of industries and banks. The prevalent
view was that cartels and alike only had to be socialised to function perfectly in a
socialist planning system (ibid).
16
See also Harding and Joshua (2003) for a more detailed account on the early attempts to establish
competition laws in other European countries.
17
Medieval guilds, the Hanseatic League of Northern Europe allying merchants and the economies of entire
cities with specific trade privileges, as well as the trading monopolies of the English East India Company
(1600), the Dutch Vereenigde Oost-Indische Compagnie (1602) and the French Compagnie des Indes
Orientales (1664) would today account for a cartel-like institutions (cf. Harding and Joshua, 2003).
111
The German Reichsgericht ruled that the existing cartel agreement was valid, and that the
freedom of contract exceded the freedom to compete, and in a wider sense, the freedom of
each company to establish a business where it wanted (Deringer, 2003).
In Europe, the pinnacle of cartel activity was concentrated in Germany, where monopoly
capitalism forged ahead with feverish rapidity (Bukharin, 1929, see Chapter IV). The
German industrialisation process was relatively late and concentrated foremost on the
capital intensive, large-scale heavy industries of steal, iron, and coal. Similar to the US,
railway construction constituted one of the leading industrial sectors, facilitating
communication and reducing transportation costs for other industries. Close connections to
banks and other financial investors providing patient capital were established, a particular
feature that later developed into the system of Hausbanken, or Grossbanken, the universal
bank system of the Rhenish variety of capitalism (cf. Gerschenkron, 1962). The evolution
of large cartels in Germany parallels the drastic political and institutional transformation
accompanying the German state building process and the subsequent imperial expansion.
The unification of German kingdoms into the German Reich in 1871 created new avenues
for burgeoning entrepreneurs to enter the marketplace, which led to a boom in the
establishment of new enterprises. The enhanced competition raised uncertainty among
established market players, a development that was further intensified by the economic
downturn of 1873-79. The number of cartels steadily increased and encompassed virtually
every sector of the German industry (Djelic, 2002: 8). Cartels and enhanced concentrations
emerged in the time of the Second Industrial Revolution lasting from 1870 to 1913, in
which the chemical and electrical industries also expanded. Banks often acted as the
entrepreneurs of mergers and cartels, in order to rationalise the industrial structure and to
increase profitability (Edwards and Ogilvie, 1996: 430). Representatives of banks occupied
central positions in the supervisory boards of so-called joint stock companies, which
proliferated from the 1880s onwards: from 2,143 in 1886 to 5,486 in 1913 (ibid: 428). The
powerful industrial networks, which in Germany were called Kartelle, Konzerne, or
Interessen Gemeinschaften (IGs) (cf. Djelic, 2002), lasted from the turn of the 19th century
until the decartelisation by the Allied Forces after 1945. Tentative statistical data reveals
that the number of cartels rose from four in 1865, to eight in 1875, to 90 in 1885, to 210 in
1890 (Harding and Joshua, 2003: 66). As part of the liberal trade regime at that time, many
of these cartels exhibited a strong transnational dimension, transgressing national borders.
According to an analysis by Schrter (1996), in 1897 there were about 40 cross-border
112
cartels with German companies involved. At the time of the Second World War, more than
40% of world trade was controlled by cartels (Fear, 2006: 15). In 1905, roughly 400 cartels
existed, including about 12,000 companies in Germany alone (Schrter, 1996). Five years
later, the number had almost doubled (ibid). Cartel formation in Germany, but also in the
rest of Europe, had its heyday in the 1920s and 1930s, the interwar period. Germany was
confronted with horrendous reparation payments, which, combined with the financial
instability of the early 1920s, the shattered public finances of the politically weak
governments of the Weimar Republic (1919-1933), and the worldwide Great Depression of
1929 resulted in hyperinflation (Borth et al., 1986: 167-8). Social disruptions, economic
chaos, mass unemployment, and the pauperisation of large parts of society marked the
political climate. Against this backdrop, cartels prospered. In 1930, cartel activity in
Germany reached a peak with 2,100 cartels (Fear, 2006: 11).
The German Mittelstand, consisting of smaller retailers, wholesalers and artisans, formed
an opposing force to the large cartels and monopolies. The opposition never amounted to
an antitrust movement similar to that in the US (see Part I of this chapter). Notably thirty
years after the enactment of the Sherman Act in the US, in 1923, Germany adopted a
decree against abuses of economic power, the Verordnung gegen den Missbrauch
wirtschaftlicher Machtstellung, which sought to counterbalance cartels and cartel-like
organisations that surfaced in the time of rising interwar inflation (Harding and Joshua,
2003: 73). Gustav Stresemann emerged as its major proponent. He was a representative of
the Mittelstand and the Reichsverband Deutscher Konsumerverein, a consumer
organisation, (ibid). However, the view that cartels were an important stabilising factor for
the Germany economy was so dominant that the law did not prohibit cartels, but rather
made them subject to the surveillance of the state institutions (Deringer, 2003). This first
German encounter with some sort of competition law was only short-lived. The law was
abolished again as part of the broad-based hostility towards liberal markets which arose
during the worldwide economic depression following the New York Stock Market crash on
24 and 29 October 1929 (see for more details Djelic, 2002). Nonetheless, Germanys
ephemeral experience triggered a political discussion on the introduction of competition
laws in the 1920s and 1930s in other countries, albeit without concrete political results
(Gerber, 1998: 7).
113
Cartels played a pivotal role in the rise of the fascist regime of National Socialism in
Germany, and vice versa: the regime sponsored the emergence of cartels and monopolies.
The enmeshment of the totalitarian state within the corporate elite exemplifies totalitarian
monopoly capitalism (Neumann, 1942). Totalitarian monopolist capitalism stands for the
particular historical junction in which a monopolistic economy combinations with the
command economy of the totalitarian state. With the advent of the National Socialists, a
law was enacted in July 1933 declaring the formation of big industrial cartels compulsory.
A cartel tribunal, a sort of cartel supervisory institution within the Ministry of Economic
Affairs was erected to supervise cartels (cf. Feldenkirchen, 1992; Djelic, 2002: 13). With
the adoption of Grings Four Year Plan in 1936, the integration of cartels and monopolies
into the totalitarian state apparatus intensified further. Mergers were promoted by means of
fiscal incentives, which resulted in a considerable degree of economic concentration in the
1930s (Feldenkirchen, 1992). Also a range of other measures added to the economic
concentration, such as complex forms of patent rights, interlocking directorates, proxy
voting, plurality votes, exchange of shares, and pooling of profits. This led to the erection
of economic combinations not surpassed in any country, not even the United States
(Neumann, 1942: 288). Rather than nationalising German industries, as would be the case
in a command economy, the Nazi government, in the interest of the corporate elite
supported a regime of corporate self-governance. The CEOs of the most powerful
companies administered the cartels in an autocratic style (ibid: 270). Thereby, the
centralised Nazi state apparatus could communicate with centralised cartels and
monopolies (ibid). By awarding contracts of guaranteed procurement, the Nazi government
helped the corporate elite to secure economic profits. In turn, it provided the Nazis with the
indispensable production of military equipment and financial, hence, political, support. The
symbiotic relationship between the state machinery and the capitalist elite entailed also the
distribution of Jewish industries or industries of annexed territories to the corporate elite
(ibid).
The most powerful cartels were formed in the capital intensive heavy industries, such as
coal and iron, and chemicals where the homogeneity of products facilitated the
specification of quotas and prices (Landes, 1969: 245). The coal and steel syndicates
constituted the core of the German war machinery. The highly vertically integrated
Vereinigte Stahlwerke was probably the largest mining and steel company, producing more
crude steel than any other steel company in Europe. It was founded in 1926 by August
114
Thyssen and later split into two conglomerates, led by the sons Fritz and Herbert Thyssen.
Fritz Thyssen was involved in financing the National Socialist German Workers Party.
Later he titled his memoirs I paid Hitler (1941). Cartel regimes, such as IG Farben,
which at the Nuremberg Trials in 1947 was dismantled into Hoechst, Bayer, and BASF
(Badische Anilin- und Sodafabriken), also played a crucial role under the Nazi regime.
Apart from its help in planning the war, it profited from forced labour camps, unrestrained
experimentation on camp prisoners, as well as from supplying Auschwitz and other
concentration camps with chemicals such as the notorious Cyclone B.
During the Third Reich, closed market structures eliminated competition from outside.
However, within Germany, the carteleers found themselves in a relentless struggle for
supply, production, and sales quotas (Neumann, 1942: 291). The consolidation of the
totalitarian monopolistic capitalism marginalised the position of the German Mittelstand.
This was particularly pronounced in the case of joint stock companies functioning as
financial centres and capital funds for member companies. Joint stock companies
institutionally centralised economic power: the board of directors of the largest firms took
important decisions. In need of capital, small and medium-sized companies formed the
majority of stockholders, and thereby often came to co-finance the expansion of the large
ones (Neumann, 1942: 281). To give an example, the Rhenish-Westphalian Coal Syndicate
also operated as a joint stock company (Fear, 2006: 4). It encompassed more than 67 firms
and employed more than 500 people solely to run the cartel (Djelic, 2002: 12). In addition,
banks participated in the economic expansion of the large industrial combinations.
However, with enhanced competition among banks, they did not fully control large cartels
and monopolies (Harding and Joshua, 2003: 66; Resch, 2005: 3). Concentrations in the
banking sectors brought consortia of several large banks onto a supervisory board, which
reduced their collective ability to influence the course of the company (Edwards and
Ogilvie, 1996: 440). Moreover, with the growing size of industrial companies and the high
profitability, no single bank was large enough to finance further expansion, which also
limited the influence of financial capital on the supervisory boards (ibid).
After the Second World War, Germany was the first country to establish a broad based
competition regime in Europe. Although the UK had already adopted the Monopolies and
Restrictive Practices Control and Enquiry Act in 1948, it was only between 1965 and
1980s that more all-encompassing competition laws were adopted (cf. Eyre and Lodge,
115
2000). The next section illustrates that Germanys second encounter with competition laws
was more enduring. The establishment of competition laws in Germany forms part of the
heritage of US Occupation Forces during the economic and political restructuring after the
Second World War. The German experience was of vital importance for the evolution of
competition laws in the European Community, and subsequently also in other European
states in the late 1950s and 1960s.
Only a few months later, at the Potsdam Conference in July, the heads of the US, British
and Soviet occupation zones agreed upon a US initiative to dismantle the cartel-dense
German economy at the earliest practicable date (Article 12 of the Potsdam Treaty in
Feldenkirchen, 1992: 261). The military governor of the US zone, General Lucius D. Clay,
was a key figure in determining the course in this regard and included the following goal
into his four-D programme: denazification, demilitarisation, democratisation, and hence,
decartelisation (Freyer, 2006: 247).
The staff of the US Decartelisation and Deconcentration Branch was drawn directly from
the US Justice Departements Antitrust Division. Initially, it could do little more than study
the situation as it occupied only the Southern states of Bavaria, Hesse, and BadenWrttemburg, which were not heavily industrialised (Wells, 2002: 148). The British
occupied the Ruhr Valley, the industrial heart of Germany where more capital-intensive
companies were based. When the US zone fused with the British zone in 1947 the US
Occupation Forces could take the lead in the economic and political reconstruction of
116
Western Germany and impose a statute on antitrust.18 Cartels and cartel-like agreements,
such as syndicates, trusts and other monopolist arrangements were declared unlawful
(Djelic and Kleiner, 2003: 4). Additional legislations restricting the combination of
commercial and investment banking were introduced to disentangle corporate finance from
the productive sector (Wells, 2002: 153). Subsequently, more than 1,000 cartel agreements
were dissolved, including IG Farben and Vereinigte Stahlwerke. IG Farben constituted the
worlds largest chemical company and held close ties with the Nazi Regime. At the
Nuremberg Tribunal in 1947, the managers of the IG Farben were sentenced for crimes
against humanity for the exploitation of foreign slave labourers (Freyer, 2006: 249).
Ironically, many sectors of the US industry formed part of the large international industrial
cartels in which also German corporations, supporting the fascist regime, participated.
After the four years of Allied occupation, the German economy was far from
deconcentrated, in marked contrast to the successful breakdown of big German industrial
cartels. Several reasons account for this. On the one hand, the chief executives of large
German companies fiercely opposed the deconcentration efforts of the Allied Forces, and
this considerably slowed down the endeavour.19 On the other hand, the US Decartelisation
and Deconcentration Branch suffered from internal divisions. The Decartelisation Unit,
most notably composed of zealous lawyers, was convinced of the necessity to break the
German industry up into small pieces. It even sought to establish more stringent rules than
that of the US in order to set a precedent which would have an impact both at home, as
well as in the rest of Europe (Wells, 2002: 147). The Deconcentration Unit, which was
composed of economists, executed its task with less vigour, and eventually shelved the
deconcentration activities altogether (Freyer, 2006: 259; Wells, 2002: 261). Notably, under
US antitrust law and enforcement practice, large corporations were not per se evil, and
thus, the need to deconcentrate the German industry was considered less important. As one
of the Deconcentration Unit noted:
18
The UK and France were also involved in the decartelisation project of particularly concentrated industries,
such as coal and steel production, banking, motion pictures, and chemicals. Yet, in the absence of antitrust
laws in these countries, the implementation by these occupation forces was markedly less severe than the
approach taken in the US zone. The British did not share the same aversion to cartels as the US Occupation
Forces. The French, on the contrary, did not prohibit cartels as such. Instead, action could be taken only if an
anticompetitive effect could be examined (Harding and Joshua, 2003: 87; Wells, 2002: 147).
19
Exemplary is the blackmailing power exerted by two managers of the Metallgesellschaft, who announced
their deep concern to the military government about maintaining friendly relations with the their competitor
British Metal with regard to other companies in the markets (Freyer, 2006: 250).
117
In any approach to the German people on the subject of decartelisation, I think that we
should honestly stress that we have no intent or desire to pulverize German industry; that
our purpose here is not to permit the rest of the nations of the world the benefits of largescale production. (In Feldman, 2006)
The intention was to focus on the largest firms only, including companies like Henschel &
Sohn, Robert Bosch, Siemens & Halske, and Metallgesellschaft (Wells, 2002: 155).
Eventually, Bosch and Siemens underwent only a marginal restructuring. The Big Three
of the banking sector, the Deutsche Bank, the Drezener Bank and the Commerzbank, which
controlled the financial system of Germany and held large stocks of leading German
companies, were divided only into nine, rather than thirteen different banks as initially
envisaged (Berghahn, 1986: 110).
The political elite of the US Occupation Forces, most notably Lucius D. Clay and his
successor John J. McCloy, the head of the European Recovery Programme (ERP), the
forerunner of what became the Marshall Plan, held close connections with US business and
certain German industrialists (cf. Link, 1978; Van der Pijl, 1984). In 1946-1947, Clay
invited US business representatives to travel through the Western zones in order to gain a
first hand impression on the state of the West German economy and to establish close ties
with their German counterparts (Berghahn, 1986: 82-3). In a Report on Germany in 1947,
US business representatives suggested reinstating the board members and directors of
118
German companies to their posts (ibid). Their requests had the desired effect. Exemplary
are the cases of Krupp and the chief executive mangers of IG Farben. In 1951, McCloy
released Krupp from prison and reversed the confiscation of his property, deeming the
prior judgment to be 'repugnant to American concepts of justice' (Van der Pijl, 1984: 174).
In 1952, he also released the IG Farben chief executive mangers from prison, who
regained their high-ranking positions in the German industry (cf. Heall, 2005). The US
corporate elite had a strong interest in the creation of free market access for their
technologically far more advanced and more competitive US companies. In particular,
Fordist-type, export-orientated companies producing cheap mass consumer goods were
seeking new consumer markets in post-war Europe to offset their products and expand in
size. The financial loans of the Marshall Plan supplied the necessary purchasing power for
innovating production into Western Europe, and hence the first important step in exporting
American accumulation conditions (Van der Pijl, 1984: 184). By exporting the US
economic model and industrial culture to Germany, the German industrial system was
meant to be integrated into the US dominated world economy. Eventually, the rest of
Europe would follow the German vanguard and buttress the system of market capitalism
against communism.
This pressure was a reaction to the German industry representatives, who sought to
reinstall cartels in the aftermath of the War. They were convinced that cartels help to create
technological progress and economic stability, and to curb labour radicalism and class
conflicts (Freyer, 2006: 247). Or as Carl Duisburg, Chairman and Director of IG Farben,
noted industrial combinations were the consequence of the necessity to economize (in
Harding and Joshua, 2003: 42). In particular, Germanys (heavy) industry, confronted with
119
enormous devastation after the War, had no sympathy for the US project of outlawing
cartels and opening up their markets to foreign competition. The Bundesverband der
Deutschen Industrie (BDI), the Federal Association of German Industry, encompassing 39
business associations counting more than 100,000 member companies, started an
aggressive propaganda campaign together with the Ruhr industrial elite against the
establishment of an antitrust regime (Djelic, 1998: 231). The connections between the
industry oligarchs and the state officials were highly personalised and the lobbying attitude
rather rude (Berghahn, 1986: 189-190). The enduring opposition of the industrial elite, as
well as of the German Mittelstand, implied that the US industrial culture could not be
exported as quickly as had been envisaged. Only in the 1960s did the first structural
industrial changes become visible (Berghahn, 1986: 259). Nonetheless, the US banking
system did not gain a foothold in Germany and the great universal banks were
reconstructed (Feldman, 2006: 8). The cooperative industrial relations were re-established,
and co-determination became the central mechanism within German corporate governance
regimes. In other words Germany established different a kind of capitalism to the liberal
market economy model of the Anglo-Saxon world, notably, what came to be known as the
Rhenish or coordinated capitalism (cf. Albert, 1993; Hall and Soskice, 2001; Crouch and
Streeck, 1997).
The broader political context also contributed to this. In the aftermath of the war, political
sentiments were overly hostile towards ideas of free market capitalism and the concept of
free competition. The attractiveness of unbridled economic liberalism propagated by the
US authorities seemed to be losing the battle against the socialist solutions offered by the
Marxist-inspired Social Democratic Party (SPD) and the Christian-inspired socialism
based in Roman Catholic regions (CSU) (Gerber, 1998: 257). According to Zweynert
(2004: 16), the deep rooted aversion to economic liberalism was founded on a strong
holistic conviction that society and economy should form an organic whole. The
introduction of US-style market capitalism was anticipated to run counter to this view.
According to Blum, the question was less about choosing between capitalism and
socialism, but how socialism should be organised (Blum, 1969: 26-37 in Zweynert, 2004:
16). Also in other European countries, the free market ideas promoted by the US did not
find a fertile ground. In France, an era of tatist capitalism made its entry, marked by
planification and state dirigisme, as well as strong elite alliances between government and
corporate interests. In the United Kingdom, the Labour Government nationalised its heavy
120
industries of coal and steel in 1949 and strongly sympathised with government planning
with regard to gas, electricity, transport and telecommunications (Resch, 2005: 15).20
121
Cartels and (Djelic and Kleiner, 2003: 7). Their aim was to create a worldwide open door
for US exports and investment. The US delegates built in the loophole that, in any cases in
which the ITO failed to intervene, the US could enforce its own laws instead (ibid: 118).
The ITO was never ratified. The Soviets did not participate in the talks and several
European countries expressed their opposition to the Draft Charters that addressed cartels
and inter-governmental commodity agreements (ibid: 120). Rather than joining the US
liberal project, developing countries instead planned to steer domestic industrialisation and
to adopt protective measures such as import restrictions and subsidies to domestic
manufacturing industries (ibid: 121). In the end, US Congress also refused to ratify. The
ITO would have implied the delegation of a considerable amount of decision making
power in the field of trade, investment, and competition to the multilateral level. In
particular, the Republicans surfaced as staunch opponents, but also investors and US
business successfully lobbied against the Havana Charter.
Initially, the impetus for enacting multilateral rules on competition was based on the wish
for unhindered market access of US companies to European markets, in particular with an
eye to breaking down the economic power of large concerns and cartels that had supported
the fascist regimes in Germany, as well as in Italy and in Japan. Moreover, US companies
also had an interest in liberalising market access to the (former) colonial empires of France
and the UK, whose companies enjoyed privileged access (Wells, 2002: 119). However, in
the end US corporate interests feared that the ITO entailed too much room for public
market intervention as it was shaped according to the ideas of John Maynard Keynes, one
of the leading delegates from the UK (Aaronson, 1996: 3). Keynes suggested including
provisions for intergovernmental commodity accords to regulate production in sectors with
extensive surpluses, to control national commodities buffer stocks in order to stabilise
prices to the benefit of both consumers and producers, and to promote consumption
increases in national markets (Wells, 2002: 119). As the Keynesian countercyclical
demand management could have imposed production and investment constraints on
business, corporate actors lobbied against the proposal. In particular the 1919 established,
Paris-based International Chamber of Commerce (ICC), one of the most comprehensive
business fora committed to economic liberalisation, protested against the fact that
governments had the permission to conclude agreements that were forbidden for private
actors (ibid: 124). Instead of the more ambitious and wide-ranging ITO, the less
122
controversial General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) was adopted in 1948. As
part of the Bretton Woods regime, or what commonly is referred to as the Washington
Consensus, the GATT complemented the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the
World Bank, which served to provide US capital with an integrated international circuit of
financial flows. Despite the initial interim character of the GATT, it endured for more than
40 years, until it was incorporated in the World Trade Organisation (WTO) in 1995. It
contained a set of rules on the reduction of state imposed customs tariffs that were
originally proposed as a part of the ITO. Rules on cartels and private market restraints
were not included in the GATT and the idea of establishing a multilateral agreement on
competition rules reached a stalemate.
In the meantime, the US authorities exerted political pressure on the other Allies to adopt
antitrust laws (Freyer, 2006: 248). The US government used the provision of military aid,
and reconstruction loans with the later Marshall Plan, as political leverage. The UK in
particular, suffering from a considerable payment deficit, depended on Washingtons
commitment not to seek repayment for received military aid (Wells, 2002: 109). Already
in 1941, the US and the UK adopted a Mutual Aid Agreement entailing a commitment to
support each other politically and to pool their efforts in international economic affairs
(Keenwood and Loughead, 1999: 237). In response to relentless US pressure, the UK
adopted the Monopolies and Restrictive Practices Control and Enquiry Act in 1948. As
Gerber (1998: 214) pointed out, the adoption of competition laws was a convenient and
relatively cost-free means of demonstrating a spirit of cooperation with the US. The
export of competition laws to other countries formed part of the liberal trade order
promoted by the US government, which established the long-lasting US economic and
political hegemony. It served the purpose of facilitating US corporate expansion into
geographically new markets without the imposition of 'discriminatory tax and labour laws,
as well as the constant threat of expropriation in Europe (Van der Pijl, 1984: 144).
Germany constituted the centre of gravity of US efforts. As the next section demonstrates,
US pressure was crucial for the adoption of competition laws in Germany. However, even
though the competition laws of the US continued to be operational until the establishment
of the West German Republic in 1949, they did not last.
123
[] there is a tendency to argue that the US brought us free competition. [However] the
Freiburg School, which had already developed a concept of free competition and free
market economy during the Third Reich, and Professor Bhm in particular, was actively
involved in advising on the law against restrictions of competition.
Heinrich Kronstein, a Jewish German lawyer who fled to the US and, while in exile,
became responsible for the prosecution of international cartels at the US Antitrust
Division, drew the attention of the US Occupation Forces a small group of legal and
economic theorists from the University of Freiburg, the ordoliberals (see Chapter 2). Their
political colour perfectly matched the outspoken liberal goals and the denazification
standards of the US. With the political support of the US, a range of eminent ordoliberals
successfully ascended from their enclave in Freiburg. They took over ranking leadership
positions and the role of academic consultants in the economic policy planning of post-war
West Germany. Walter Eucken gave a range of advisory opinions to the Allied Forces on
the organisation of the economic transition in 1946 and 1947 and Franz Bhm became a
Member of the Bundestag during 1951-1961. In the years before, he closely cooperated
with the Bavarian authorities. Thereby, ordoliberals exerted considerable influence on the
shaping of the competition laws and the accordant institution-building process in Germany.
Due to ordoliberal influence, Germany did not adopt a competition regime exactly
resembling that of the US, despite the US effort to proselytize the German competition
124
model towards that of the US (Gerber, 1998: 177; Slot, 2004: 443). However, neither did
the ordoliberal proposals materialize in the way ordoliberals had initially envisaged them.
Fierce industrial opposition not only protracted the adoption of competition laws, but also
led to a watered down legislation.
Parts of the German ministerial bureaucracy, the US Occupation Forces, and the industrial
elite of the Ruhr and the BDI immediately boycotted the proposal. Industry representatives
in particular considered the way in which the draft proposal problematised economic
power concentration far too radical. Disputes emerged also with the US authorities (Freyer,
2006: 254). Despite the shared conviction on establishing a liberal market economy in
Germany, ordoliberals did not represent mainstream US economic thinking, which
propagated human salvation through free market play and which did not see evil in large
corporations. Ordoliberals fiercely criticised the piecemeal approach of the US Antitrust
Faction of the US interim military government towards economic deconcentration and
accused it of supporting the monopoly practices of business people with a Nazi
background (ibid). In his role as an economic advisor to the US Occupation Forces,
125
Faced with the sword of Damocles of the US authorities and the Marshall Plan funds,
Ludwig Erhard, heading the Ministry of Economic Affairs strongly favoured the
establishment of competition laws. Repeatedly, he emphasised that controlled competition
should constitute the motor of economic growth after the War (cf. Erhard, 1957). However,
in marked contrast to the Josten Draft, he envisaged the imposition of a similar competition
regime as that in the US. Although he did not have an intimate knowledge of US antitrust
laws and practices, he sympathised with a strict ban on cartels in combination with mild
merger control regulations (Berghahn, 1986: 158, 167, 289). Erhard opposed the farreaching deconcentration of the German economy. Instead, similar to the spirit of
Americas economic policy, he sympathised with the idea of stimulating large enterprises
to be able to compete in the world market (ibid: 159). After the political failure of the
Josten Draft, Erhard committed an ad hoc commission to come up with competition laws
in 1953. The enactment of a strict regime prohibiting cartels and other restrictive business
practices should take place quickly as otherwise the resurrection of industrial cartels could
not be stopped anymore. Erhard had a hard time defending his position in favour of
antitrust rules to the BDI, as well as to the ministries of Agriculture, Transport and
Finance, who pushed for a less prohibitive approach to cartels and for completely
abandoning the idea of a law for controlling mergers (Eyre and Lodge, 2000: 66).
Corporate actors denounced the Ministry of Economic Affairs to be merely an instrument
for the US Occupation Force to weaken or even destroy the German economy (Djelic,
1998: 231).
126
The opposition of large industrialists and their associations could not block the adoption of
competition laws banning cartels in Germany. However, it was effective in delaying the
legislative process until 1957, when the Gesetz gegen Wettbewerbsbeschrnkungen, the
Restriction of Competition Act, and the enforcement institutions were adopted. The
ordoliberal project dramatically failed to control economic concentrations through mergers.
The adoption of mergers laws tumbled over political and industrial opposition. From the
US Occupation Forces, industry representatives learned that large companies and
oligopolies were necessary to achieve economies of scale. They considered German
enterprises not yet large enough to be able to compete. By keeping close ties with the
CDU, the BDI and its ally, the Deutscher Industrie- und Handelstag (DIHT), successfully
blocked the introduction of laws that could constrain economic concentration (Drahos,
2001: 245). The ordoliberals in the Josten Committee lacked the political power and the
necessary support to include rules on mergers in the new competition regime. Thereby, the
German industry rapidly re-concentrated again. Exemplary are the companies Hoechst,
Bayer, and BASF resulting from the deconcentrated IG Farben. Today, each of these
companies is about twenty times larger than IG Farben. Organised in the Verband der
Chemischen Industrie, the Chemical Industry Association, these companies systematically
invested in the careers of political leaders, such as Helmut Kohl who worked as a lobbyist
for the Association between 1959 and 1969, in order to secure their political influence
further (cf. Heall, 2005).
127
The ordoliberals involved in the drafting process strongly opposed the US antitrust
enforcement practice that relied so heavily on courts and on private enforcement allowing
private litigators to bring breaches of competition law to the courts (Freyer, 2006: 248).
Instead, they preferred a system governed by administrators who constantly supervise the
marketplace.22 As a result thereof, German competition laws received a strong
constitutional status, embedded in public administrative law. This reflects the ordoliberal
idea of a stable framework of principles for the distribution of power, not only between the
state and the market, but also within state institutions. The Bundeskartellamt, the Federal
Cartel Office, the cartel offices of the Lnder were shaped as (supposedly) politically
independent agencies with far-reaching administrative and discretionary powers to control
and to prosecute anticompetitive conduct. Additionally, in 1973 when Germany adopted
merger control laws, the Monopolkommission, the Federal Monopoly Commission, was
erected to monitor economic concentration and entrusted with an advisory task. To ensure
a certain degree of checks and balances and transparency, following the US model (see
Chapter 2), the Ministry of Economic Affairs was authorised to supervise the
Bundeskartellamt. The physical distance between the government located in Bonn and the
22
As will be demonstrated in Chapter 9, the political resistance of German authorities against the
introduction of private enforcement at EU level more than 40 years later is rooted in the legal and economic
history of the post-war period. From the very beginning of a competition law tradition, these sentiments
endured.
128
The traces of corporate lobbying became manifest in the fact that the proposal for a merger
control regime was dropped from the agenda and cartel law came to include the possibility
of a more flexible interpretation. Although cartels and vertical agreements were outlawed
on a per se basis like the US model, the Bundeskartellamt was given much leeway in
granting exemptions to the existing law, based on the rule of reason. On the basis of an
exemption regime, the Bundeskartellamt was empowered to temporarily authorise
rationalisation cartels, i.e. intercompany agreements promoting technological progress,
and structural crisis cartels preventing the loss of business due to a temporary decline in
demand (Buxbaum, 2006: 6). In addition, the competition laws excluded export cartels.
This implied that an administrative institutional body could discriminate between harmful
and harmless cartels. In other words, the cartel authority in every sense of the word was an
authority that could authorise cartels. This particular in-built authoritative leeway can be
seen as the result of a political compromise between those favouring a free market
economy with free competition, and those favouring the traditional cartel approach in line
with the interests of German industry. The possibility for exemptions constitutes an
institutional remainder of the longstanding cartel tradition in Germany as it provides a
legal escape to cutthroat competition. From the perspective of the German industry
representatives, cartel formation was believed to evoke rationalisation, standardisation and
specialisation in European industries all features considered important for the
implementation of economies of scale and mass-production techniques (ibid). Cartels and
other forms of collective corporate agreements were seen as functional equivalents to the
large corporations that could be found in the US (Djelic, 1998: 232). Thus, the possibility
After the German reunification and the relocation of the government to Berlin, the Bundeskartellamt
moved to Bonn in order to keep the much-cherished independence of the competition authority from
governmental influence. Probably nowhere else in Western Europe was the importance of the rule of law and
the separation of political power implemented with such vigour. What from the perspective of outsiders is
sometimes sardonically perceived as Deutsche Grndlichkeit originates in the traumatic experiences under a
totalitarian regime.
23
129
130
The next part demonstrates that the combination of US interests, industry opposition, and
ordoliberal experts was not only dominant in the socioeconomic institution building of
post-war West Germany, but also of crucial importance during the formative phases of the
European Coal and Steel Community (ECSC).
3.6 The European Coal and Steel Community A Clever Cover for a Gigantic
European Cartel?
When the European Coal and Steel Community (ECSC) was established in 1951 in Paris,
the governments of the six founding Member States of France, Germany, Italy, and the
Benelux agreed to include competition laws. However, fierce political battles preceded this
decision. Similar to Germany, the driving forces pushing in favour of competition laws
were composed of a combination of transatlantic political and industrial elites, and German
ordoliberals, who played a pivotal role in shaping the competition laws and in building up
the procedural and institutional framework necessary for the enforcement.
131
When Robert Schuman, the French Foreign Minister, brought forth the plan for the ECSC,
rules on competition were not included. The draft text of the Paris Treaty was composed
during the few months between summer and fall of 1950 and was dominated by a semiprivate group headed by Jean Monnet, head of the French Commissariat du Plan, the
Planning Commission, and later the first President of the High Authority. At that time,
France did not have competition laws. Given Monnets political career in the field of
economic planification, he did not have a clear vision on competition laws (Hoeren, 1999:
410). As a matter of fact, the French negotiators initially envisaged price regulations where
prices would be fixed by national governments and producers associations (Witschke,
2001: 7). With the historical experience of the devastating German invasion in mind,
French industry representatives and politicians initially favoured a particularly hard line
against the German steel and coal mining industries. They were vertically integrated,
which implied that German steel companies enjoyed privileged access to coal. For the
French, decoupling the German steel production from the ownership of coal mines, or then
132
its privileged access, was considered highly important for securing the economic survival
of the less competitive French steel industry, which so strongly relied on access to the
precious Ruhr coal resources (Karagiannis, 2004: 12-13). When the US Occupation Forces
executed its deconcentration efforts with less vigour (see previous sections), French
business associations were overtly concerned about Germanys rapid economic
recuperation. Moreover, German corporations enjoyed a vast resource of highly qualified
people a resource France could not compete with (Gehler and Grben, 2002: 20).
Regulated prices and controlled market access were therefore in the interests of the French
industry association Conseil National du Patronat Franais (CNPF). It even imposed a
Commission for German Affairs, whose chief official kept close contact with Robert
Schuman (Karagiannis, 2004: 12-13).
The prospect of European supranational price controls within the framework of the ECSC
raised immediate concerns in the US. When US Secretary of State, Dean Acheson was
confronted with the draft treaty on 7 May 1950, he noted that the ECSC was 'a clever cover
for a gigantic European cartel for coal and steel producers (Acheson, 1969: 383-384). He
threatened that without the inclusion of antitrust articles in the Treaty, the US government
could not support in good faith that the general idea is a single market characterised by
competition (in Witschke, 2001: 17). Moreover, he noted that the cartel question with
regard to the ECSC would have greatest effect on public opinion particular in the US
(ibid). Concerned about market access, US business associations shared this view. In a
telegram to Schuman, they put much emphasis on the necessity of establishing a regime in
which competition would be safeguarded (Berghahn, 1986: 134-5). The concerns of US
business and government alike took shape in the context of the beginning of the Korean
War in June 1950. The creation of an economically strong Western bloc vis--vis the
Communist bloc received a new dimension: European industries should support the US
with the necessary raw materials in the production of military equipment. The increased
US demand for steel, due to their involvement in the Korean War, raised prices, and
henceforth increased the power of European heavy industry (Berghahn, 1986: 136).
Both French and German heavy industry came to hold the view that European unification
in the coal and steel sectors should take place via national cartels which would privately
administer themselves on the basis of an international framework, rather than through a
centralised, supranational organ such as the proposed High Authority (ibid: 131-2). With
133
the prospect of supranational competition laws addressing all national coal and steel
industries alike, the French industry representatives joined forces with the German BDI.
The French steel industry did not seek a wholesale prohibition of horizontal cartel
agreements, but merely the vertical disentanglement of the German steel and coal mining
industry. This German-French rapprochement resulted in a joint resolution against the
inclusion of competition laws in the ECSC and in favour of protecting the European
tradition of national and international cartels (Karagiannis, 2004: 17). Old cartel ties across
the French and German borders were revived (Berghahn, 1986: 114). Protests also came
from Belgium, in particular from the Socit General de Belgique, a major Belgian bank
involved in coal and steel industries, and from the Netherlands .(Witschke, 2001: 14).
In reaction to these developments, the US authorities strongly pressured for the inclusion
of competition laws into the ECSC. The rules initially designed for the deconcentration of
the German economy were also to be applied to the industries of the other Member States.
They did not only want to tackle large industry cartels in Germany, but bring the entire
European cartel tradition to a halt. Any form of producer price agreements should be ruled
out (Buxbaum, 2006: 8). US-style competition laws were considered indispensable for the
US project to export their vision of economic freedom in order to establish the same
Fordist-type consumer market in Europe, and secure market access to resources for its
industries. Moreover, the creation of a strong Western European bloc should inhibit the
Communists from gaining political ground. Similar to Germany, the US government
intended to decartelise the French economy and to enact competition legislation modelled
after the Sherman Act. The US government was concerned about France nationalising its
coal industry and imposing partial governmental control on its steel industry (Freyer, 2006:
271-272). The practice of nationalising coal mines and steel industries formed part of a
broader strategy on a worldwide basis to allow marginal industries to survive at public
expense (Schmitt, 1964: 103). The situation was similar in Italy, where a state holding
company controlled half of the steel industry and in the Netherlands, where the state held
shares in the most significant steel firm (ibid: 104). As the introduction of national
competition laws in post-war France was highly contested, US officials, as a part of the
Marshall Plans Technical Assistance programme invited a team of French experts to the
US in order to train them in US antitrust law and enforcement. Back in France the group of
experts concluded that an easy transplantation of US laws to the French scene was
unlikely due to the different economic and legal conditions (Pederson, 1996: 269). The
134
US meddling with French economic policy raised considerable opposition from large parts
of the state administration, as well as the French business community, and the French
Communists, albeit for different reasons. The protests of French industrialists towards
competition policy were particularly entrenched. The US endeavour to direct France
towards market capitalism included the strategy of inviting French manufactures on study
trips to the US, as well as holding numerous seminars and meetings in which the virtues of
free competition and US-style capitalism stood central (ibid: 268-271). The US teaching
endeavours did not book the expected success, mainly because the old guard of highranking management officials stayed at home, and these were the very ones involved in
cartel practices, and controlling the powerful trade associations or the US Chamber of
Commerce (ibid). The US courting of French industrial interest could not change the
prevalent view that price fixing and market allocation cartels were necessary for stifling
economic growth and stability.
24
Robert Bowie served as a policy advocate in the Truman, Eisenhower, Kennedy, Johnson and Carter
administration during the Cold War. John J. McCloy, who is reported to have been the unofficial 'Chairman
135
the Schuman Plan in Paris led to a replica of the legal provisions that he previously
designed for Germany. These draft provisions were reviewed by the US government in
Washington and by George Ball, another close friend of Monnet, and also a private
antitrust lawyer with close ties to Washington and New York (Gerber, 1998: 338;
McFadzean, 2003: 56).
Under the political pressure from the US government and its technical assistance, Monnet
took a leading role in drafting competition law provisions. In addition, the French Ministry
of Foreign Affairs supported the introduction of competition laws, which by then were also
appositely called Lex Ruhr. In order to generate the necessary business support for
competition laws, Monnet even mobilised countervailing forces, such as the
manufacturing industry as a leverage for the growing power of the heavy industries
(Berghahn, 1986: 131-2). The manufacturing industry was traditionally less cartelised and
more easily convinced about the endorsement of the principle of competition into the
European integration project. In order to avoid giving the signatories the impression that
US interests controlled the process, US influence was deliberately disguised: the provisions
were re-written in a European idiom by Maurice Lagrange, a member of the French
Conseil dtat and one of the first Advocate Generals of the European Court of Justice
(Harding and Joshua, 2003: 95). US representatives did apparently not surface during the
treaty negotiations in order to achieve a quick consensus. For example, George Ball wrote
in his memoirs that he used to take the back door during the negotiations phase just in
case Europeans arrived (Gerber, 1998: 338). Nevertheless, the extent of the US influence
on the establishment of the ECSC and competition law in particular is a much-contested
issue. According to Gerber (1998) there is little outspoken evidence that US politicians
directly pressured for the incorporation of competition law provisions. Yet, it cannot be
denied that US experts assisted in the drafting phase of ECSC competition laws. The
pressure of the US authorities were also of a monetary nature. In a loan of US$ 100 million
to the ECSC, the US authorities imposed the condition that the money would be used in a
manner consistent with the operations of a common market free from national barriers and
private obstruction to competition (Report by the Department of State, March 16, 1955 in
Wells, 2002: 202).
of the Establishment and a patron and close friend of Bowie, also introduced Bowie into the transnational
elite of the US and European classe politique, academia and business (cf. McFadzean, 2003).
136
The Franco-American unison, most notably represented by Monnet and McCloy and his
antitrust experts Bowie and Ball, eventually pressured for a breakthrough on competition
laws, which was achieved on 14 March 1951 (Hoeren, 1999: 412-3). Only a few days later,
on 19 March 1951, the ECSC Treaty was signed. Monnet recalled later that the Treaty
would never have been signed but for McCloys support (in Djelic, 2002: 26). The
competition laws were formulated in Article 65 and Article 66, and constituted one of the
Treatys most important parts. Article 65 prohibited agreements that aimed at preventing,
restricting, or distorting the normal operation of competition (i.e. the cartel law). Article 66
laid down rules for controlling transactions leading to a concentration, such as mergers and
acquisitions, and the prohibition of restrictive business practices, such as the abuse of a
dominant position. The striking resemblance of the formulations in the cartel prohibition
(Article 65) and the merger law (the first part of Article 66) with the US provisions signals
strong US presence. Political pressure from the US in favour of establishing competition
laws epitomize the rising hegemonic weight in orchestrating the political economy of
Western Europe towards market capitalism hegemony understood in the Gramscian
sense of a dominant ideology, permeating cultural, economic, and political layers of
society. The cartel and merger laws of the ECSC undoubtedly drew on US experience with
the Sherman Act of 1890; they do not, however, exactly mirror the US blueprint.
137
The controversies between the French and German delegations centred on whether ECSC
competition law should follow the prohibition or the abuse principle. These led to two
different systems with important repercussions on the stringency with which competition
laws would be enforced. The French proposal entailed a per se prohibition on cartels,
which, following the US antitrust model, implied that all cartels and other restrictive
business practices would be categorically declared illegal. In contrast, the German proposal
followed the abuse principle, according to which cartel practices and alike would be legal
in principle and only be prosecuted in the case of abuse. The German preference for a more
lenient approach to cartels was imbued by the presence of strong industrial interests
favouring the continuation of a cartelised economy. During the negotiations, Hallstein and
his team were surrounded by a group of experienced and cartel-minded industrialists,
among whom was Max Boden, the director general of AEG electrics, as well as Max C.
Mller, who headed the Vereinigte Stahlwerke and held first class connections to the steel
industry (Berghahn, 1986: 120-1).
The coal and steel industry felt cornered by foreign (French) competitors. Ludwig Erhard
also campaigned for the more lenient German proposal. In a letter to Adenauer on 11
December 1950, Erhard tried to convince him to adapt the treaty text to the better-qualified
German draft on ECSC competition law. As not every cartel was per se evil, he considered
the US and French suggestions for prohibiting cartels to be inept for Germany (in Hoeren,
1999: 414). Although Hallstein held the view that cartels, even under the strictest
supervision of the state remained highly suspect, he eventually drafted Article 66
according to the German model (Freyer, 2006: 274). The law reserved a strong role for the
High Authority, which, as one of the ECSCs principal institutions, next to the Council
representing the Member governments and the European Court of Justice (ECJ), was
declared responsible for administering and applying competition laws. Designed almost
simultaneously with the Bundeskartellamt in Germany, and similar to the German model,
the High Authority was entrusted with far-reaching discretionary powers to differentiate
between harmful and harmless commercial agreements. In times of economic crisis, it
could exempt horizontal cartel agreements from existing law. It could impose production
quotas (Article 58) and specify conditions of sales. Presumptively, due to the influence of
the French delegations, it could also fix price margins (Article 61). All these far-reaching
market interventionist powers were designed to serve to increase the productivity or the
distribution of products.
138
In addition, Article 66 also came to prohibit the abuse of a dominant position, a legal
device that finds no equivalent in the US antitrust legislation where only intentions to
monopolise are ruled out. The abuse of dominance prohibition draws on the ordoliberal
distrust of bigness, i.e. in order to allow a vast range of competitors to compete on equal
terms, companies should not grow too big. Walter Hallstein thereby attempted to include a
commitment to social market economy in the new legislation. Article 66 also empowered
the High Authority to intervene in already existing dominant positions of both private and
public enterprises. It could block a transaction or require the breaking up of a company if
prices were affected, the production or the marketing restrained, or the maintenance of
effective competition in a substantial part of the market impaired. As only the High
Authority could enforce the law, it virtually enjoyed unlimited discretionary powers to
structure the market. Private actors could appeal to the European Court of Justice (ECJ),
although, direct private lawsuits similar to the private enforcement regime of the US were
forbidden (Gerber, 1998: 341). The inclusion of these provisions demonstrates that the
German treaty drafters preferred a strong state authority to the mechanism of free
competition as a market ordering force.
The cartel provisions drafted by the US lawyer Robert Bowie in Germany were directly
translated to the Schuman Plan. He drafted most of Article 66 (Freyer, 2006: 274).
However, here Hallstein and his team of ordoliberals and industry representatives also
made an enduring imprint. This was reflected in the enforcement procedure, according to
which concentrations needed to be authorised by the High Authority prior to its completion
through a system of notification. Again, the High Authority enjoyed plenty of scope for
interpretation as it could outlaw unreasonable concentrations that might evade
competition. Given the far reaching powers of the High Authority, it should not come as a
surprise that the leaders of the business communities also fiercely opposed the
incorporation of competition laws as a central pillar of the ECSC (Djelic and Kleiner,
2003). However, their opposition could not block the inclusion of competition provisions
for the following reason: government representatives were reported not to have informed
the industry representatives about the state of affairs of the negotiations until it was too late
for them to formulate a common position and to effectively lobby for it (Bthe and Swank,
2005: 28). Similarly, for industry groups like the BDI it was to late to intervene as they
expected the negotiations to be unsuccessful on this issue anyway (Gehler and Grben,
2002: 12, 21).
139
Yet, industry opposition was still successful in swinging the provisional treaty text in its
favour. The burden of proof came to lie with the High Authority: only if it could
successfully prove that a merger would lead to a situation in which the new combination
can control prices and distribution channels, it could prohibit it (ibid: 15). German
industries pressured for the inclusion of a non-discrimination clause, according to which
the High Authority had to take into account the different economic positions of other
companies when assessing mergers, taking the size of the largest company as point of
reference (Witschke, 2001: 16). Thereby, the German industry had less to fear with regard
to the reconcentration of the coal and steel industry and could move towards an
oligopolistic market structure. Although the French industries were not directly involved in
the French delegation of politically experienced top civil servants, they stayed in regular
contact during the preparatory stages of the drafting process (Berghahn, 1986: 128-9).
Their influence led to the inclusion of a notion that concentrations concluded prior to the
ECSC ratification would not be subject to the High Authority. This meant that the bulk of
concentration activity in France did not fall under the merger rules (Haas, 1958: 153).
Nevertheless, the French steel industry, in particular was very discontent with the result. It
did not want to ask prior permission from a supranational authority for envisaged mergers
or producer agreements. Moreover, it had much to fear from competition laws, as strong
cross-participation between companies and inter-locking directorates constituted the order
of the day (Witschke, 2001: 14-17, 27).
When confronted with the institutional outlook of the ECSC competition laws, the
enthusiasm of the US government for European integration dampened. US concern was
instigated by the far-reaching powers entrusted upon the High Authority, including the
possibility to set price margins and to allow cartel agreements. When the US reviews of
the draft text arrived from Washington, Monnet, Bowie and Hallstein had already
completed their work (Freyer, 2006: 273). To recapitulate, the same US antitrust experts
who drafted the competition rules in the aftermath of Nazi-Germany co-authored the cartel
and merger law of the ECSC Treaty. The differences in a large part of the substance of the
laws are negligible. However, the US influence was not all determining. The institutional
design of the enforcement mechanisms and the responsibilities attributed to the High
Authority came to look very distinct from that of the Federal antitrust agencies of the US.
At a lower level of abstraction, the combination of the ordoliberal weight in the drafting
phase and the opposition of the industrial elite were arbitrative. Once the ECSC
140
competition laws were established, US influence vanished. In the years to come, the
competition law provisions of the ECSC were hardly enforced. Despite its wide-ranging
powers, the High Authority was anxious to keep the goodwill of the industrialists who
forcefully opposed the anti-cartel and merger provisions. The joint endeavours by industry
representatives from the ECSC Member States can be hold accountable for this. In a
declaration in 1951, the Council of the Federation of European Industries, the first
transnational organisation, encompassing the main employers associations from France,
Belgium, the Netherlands and Germany, protested that the High Authority would become
too powerful in combating cartel behaviour and intervening in economic concentrations
(Witschke, 2001: 14). In addition, national governments also opposed the enforcement of
competition laws. Ludwig Erhard the German Minister of Economics contested the
inclusion of supranational merger laws from the start (Hoeren, 1999: 412-3).
As a result, of the more than eighty registered syndicates only three were dissolved, none
of them being important, and of the more than 59 concentrations falling under Article 66 of
the ECSC none was prohibited (ibid: 19; for details see also Schmitt, 1964). In other
words, the High Authority took a friendly view of mergers (Berghahn, 1986: 282). It
failed to set up a coherent and transparent enforcement policy for Article 66. In any case,
mere size was not considered a problem. Thus, the German industries deconcentrated
rapidly. Under the consent of the High Authority, many of the thirteen independent
successor companies of the deconcentrated Vereinigte Stahlwerke rapidly re-concentrated
and re-established their links with the coal sector and merged again (Witschke, 2001: 3). In
addition, the German steel producers Mannesmann and Hoesch re-concentrated by
restoring vertical integration with down and upstream companies, including coal
producing companies (ibid: 19). Similarly, the High Authority took a reluctant stance
towards dismantling the German coal syndicate Deutscher Kohleverkauf, which succeeded
the Ruhr syndicate (Resch, 2005: 16). French industry was also actively engaged in
concentration activities. In 1954, a French consortium, supported by government loans,
took over the biggest West German coal mine, the Harpener Bergbau AG (Witschke,
2001: 21).
141
the ECSC, Austria and the Netherlands enacted their first competition laws in 1951, while
France adopted some sort of embryonic competition laws in 1953, and Belgium and
Denmark in 1960. Yet, in response to received loans from the Marshall Plan the adoption
of competition laws initially reflected a mere formality to please the US (Gerber, 2003: 8,
171). To illustrate this with anecdotal evidence, when James Rahl, a US law professor,
paid a visit to Denmark in the 1960s, he noted that the competition authority consisted of a
director and a secretary only (ibid). In spite of the initial difficulties for competition laws
and practices in early integrating Europe, the competition idea was meant to endure, even
without direct involvement of US interests. As the next section demonstrates, when
drafting the Rome Treaty a few years later, the European political elite already had
engendered the idea of competition as the centrifugal dynamic of economic integration.
The German experience with competition laws, and the inclusion of competition laws into
the ECSC treaty was crucial for the enactment of competition laws in the EEC. The EEC
did not only embrace the institutional structure of the ECSC, but also used the competition
142
laws of the Paris Treaty, i.e. Article 65 and 66, as a template. The basic idea was that the
rules designed for the coal and steel industries should be applied to other economic sectors,
too. The idea was that discrimination among corporations on grounds of nationality should
be outlawed and free market access guaranteed to all enterprises. Committed ordoliberals
from Germany contributed to the nascent phase of EEC Treaty legislation and the
subsequent institution building. They evolved as particularly enthusiastic proponents of
European market integration and competition across borders. Again, Walter Hallstein was
the principal negotiator on behalf of the German government. He also became the first
President of the European Commission, which he headed for nine years. In his writings and
speeches during the formation period of the EEC and during his Presidency, he referred
extensively to ordoliberal concepts (Gerber, 1998: 263). The German Hans Von der
Grben (1907-2005), a lawyer by origin and an outspoken adherent of ordoliberal ideas
became the first Commissioner for Competition Policy in the newly established Directorate
General (DG) IV, which he presided over during the first two terms from 1958 to 1962 and
from 1963 to 1967. He was also called Jean Monnet of Germany, as he drafted much of
the Spaak Report, the basic document for the Rome Treaty. He played a pivotal role in the
drafting phase of competition laws into the Treaty of Rome. Von der Grben and Walter
Hallstein were not only friends in private life, but also shared the ordoliberal view that
political integration was to be achieved foremost through establishing a common market
(cf. Von der Grben, 1965b; Gehler and Grben, 2002: 8). Their marked presence in the
negotiations, in the run up to the EEC, explains why the Rome Treaty came to embody the
programmatic idea of an economic constitution in which competition plays the primary
structuring device for societal welfare in an integrated Europe.
143
based market economy with competition laws as the centrepiece steering economic
integration. Jean Monnet also attended the negotiation phase as an independent advisor. In
line with his economic planning background, he suggested a common market that would
be steered by a strong economic planning authority. While the Italians were inclined by
the French option, the representatives from Benelux supported the German proposal,
which secured ordoliberals the necessary leverage power. This was particularly the case
with respect to the negotiations on competition laws.
Similar to the ECSC negotiations, disputes between the French and the German delegates
flared up with regard to the detailed outlook of the competition laws and the enforcement
competences entrusted upon the competition authority. Again, the choice between the
prohibition and the abuse system gave reason for controversy. Compared to the positions
taken on competition laws in the formative phase of the ECSC, however, the French and
the German delegates changed camps. This time the German government vehemently
postulated a prohibition system for all cooperative agreements that affect trade in the
common market, whereas the French government sympathised with the abuse system
(Hoeren, 1999: 414). In line with the ECSC competition laws, however, both governments
agreed on incorporating possibilities for granting exemptions.
The German option of a general prohibition rule with the possibility of granting
exemptions implied an authorisation system that required an ex ante notification of all
intercompany agreements. Following the ordoliberal spirit of a continuously policed
competition order, a strong competition authority should take over the task of reviewing
these notifications and of taking decisions independent of governmental influence. The
French delegates proposed an abuse system according to which only predefined abuses of
business would be subject to legal control. Rather than installing a mechanism of prior
notification controlling for all business agreements, an abuse system implies an ex post
abuse control. Only detected abuses would be subject to jurisdictional control. The abuse
system tends to more lenient. Consequently, France envisioned a supranational
competition authority with limited powers. Notably, it should merely coordinate the
different national competition laws and make them compatible (Warlouzet, 2005: 66).
Given these controversies, the French delegates opposed the German proposal to include
provisions on the precise application of these laws. Rather than fully-fledged laws and
144
procedures, it proclaimed the view that only a declaration of intent should be included into
the treaty.25
The reasons why the French and German delegates reversed roles lays in the changed
situation of their national industries. During the formative phase of the ECSC, the French
Ministry of Economics, which maintained strong ties with the French industry, supported
the French delegates. Why they favoured the inclusion of competition laws was primarily
due to the geopolitical goal of weakening the German coal and steel industry and creating
market access for the French industries to these resources. Once competition laws were
applied to all industries in all Member States in the same way, the French preference for
the blanket per se prohibition of cartel agreements was no longer supported. A more
tolerant competition regime, allowing for cooperative intercompany agreements, would
allow French industries to face foreign competition better. In the vein of national
planification, national competition authorities should take over the bulk of competition
control, while the European Commission should be merely entrusted with coordinating
and harmonising national approaches (Warlouzet, 2005). The German delegates, however,
feared that the more protectionist Member States, such as France and Italy, would
foreclose their national markets to German competitors (Warlouzet, 2005: 66-67). The
imposition of strong competition laws at EEC level would prevent this.
Eventually, after many draft texts, and with the political support of the Dutch and the
Belgians, the German delegate Von der Grben succeeded in imposing an administrative
ex ante notification control regime with possibilities for exemptions drawing on the
prohibition principle (see Chapter 2). As he noted at a later stage, the proposal was taken
up as he designed it (Gehler and Grben, 2002: 18-19). Although he was not a party
member of the Christian Democratic Union (CDU), he was backed up by Ludwig Erhard,
who was a staunch supporter of the inclusion of cartel laws into the EEC. He could make
use of the assistance of advisory committees composed of members of the German
competition authority (Gehler and Grben, 2002: 56). The in-built possibilities for
exemption mirror the ordoliberal emphasis on establishing a strong public authority that
can balance its decision making in a flexible way against wider policy concerns. Von der
Grben (1966a: 4) elucidated the introduction of the exemption regime with the argument
that the Commission should hold multiple objectives rather than just one, implying that the
25
See for a more detailed account Hoeren (1999), Von der Grben (1982), and Narjes (2004).
145
Although the Rome Treaty prioritised competition policy more than the ECSC Treaty,
eventually, the competition law provisions were only partially transferred to the new
treaty. As Cini and McGowan (1998: 17) noted, the EEC competition laws represented a
much watered-down version of those of the ECSC rules. Like the German competition
regime, merger laws were excluded. Industry representatives, but also government
institutions opposed the inclusion of merger laws. The German Ministry of Economics, in
particular, considered merger laws a discriminating measure against its industry
(Witschke, 2001: 6). However, during the formation of the EEC competition laws, the
presence of industry representatives was less marked. Primarily, the creation of a common
market was in the interests of large corporations as it provided new opportunities to
expand and to achieve economies of scale. In addition, the reluctance of the High
Authority to enforce Article 56 and 66 of the ECSC gave the impression that there was
little to fear. So far, Ruhr giants had not been hindered in their process of reconcentration.
Consequently, the representatives of large companies, among which the Ruhr industry, but
also business associations such as the BDI, were not worried about competition laws any
more (Karagiannis, 2004: 24-25; see also Buch-Hansen forthcoming).
Despite the absence of merger laws, no other EEC policy field was so eminently inspired
by the imperatives of ordoliberal thinking as competition policy. As Joerges (2004: 16)
pointed out, the rationale of the ordoliberal economic constitution appeared particularly
appropriate for legitimising the economic orientation of the integration project. The
inclusion of competition laws in the founding Rome Treaty gave competition laws a
strong constitutional status. Secondary legislation of the EEC or the Member States could
not overrule the competition laws. In the view of Von der Grben, ordered competition,
rather than central planning should provide the key steering instrument for economic
integration (1962: 16). All other socioeconomic policies should be brought in line with
competition policy, in particular those meant to guarantee price stability and other policies
preventing economic fluctuations (ibid, 1963: 7-8). However, both the system of market
146
economy and ordered competition, were not objectives in themselves, but merely served
as an instrument to achieve broader socio-political ideals (ibid: 2). In line with the broader
macroeconomic view of establishing a common market, the EEC competition provisions
were formulated in vague and ambiguous terms, including notions such as violating
Community-interest or if trade between the Member States is affected all concepts
that leave ample room for interpretation. The ordoliberal notion of combating the abuse of
dominant positions endured. It was included in the Rome Treaty as Article 82. Additional
rules addressing governmental restraints on public and private enterprises were also
included. Based on Article 86 (TEC) the Commission could take action against a Member
State in cases of special, or exclusive rights granted to companies and state monopolies.
Section 3 stipulated the right of the Commission to bind the Member States by directives
without the prior approval of the Council of Ministers. Although Article 86 was not used
very often prior to the 1980s as its interventionist nature was considered too controversial
(ibid: 18), it granted the Commission an extraordinary right to intervene in the public
sector of the Member States. Similarly, Article 87 to 89 on the prohibition of subsidies by
national or sub-national authorities, constitute a pillar of central importance, which has
neither a complement in the ECSC, nor in the US antitrust regime.
147
Due to the opposition of the French government, in the run up to the EEC, to equipping the
Commission with further enforcement powers, no procedural enforcement rules could be
included in the Rome Treaty. Three years later, this issue ended up on the negotiation table
again. This time it received the necessary French support. Why the French government
voted in favour of Regulation 17 was due to a package deal. In exchange for the goodwill
of the German government for the generous Common Agriculture Policy (CAP),
Regulation 17 was adopted on 14 January only shortly after the difficult CAP
negotiations were concluded (Warlouzet, 2005: 67). Not unimportant with regard to the
French approval, was the fact that a broad range of economic sectors was constitutionally
exempted from the EEC competition laws: the agricultural sector (falling under the CAP),
the defence industry, the transport sector, and nuclear energy (Neven et al., 1998: 5). The
coal and steel sector continued to be regulated separately under the ECSC until it was fully
incorporated into the EC Treaty in 2002.
The adoption of Regulation 17 was vital for the development of the EC competition model.
It spelled out the powers of the European Commission and granted it considerable
executive powers. Owing to Regulation 17, the Commission was entitled to act as a
supranational competition authority, i.e. investigator, prosecutor, judge, jury, and
executioner altogether. The Commission could investigate competition cases, either on its
own initiative or on the request of a Member State, a third state, business, or consumers. It
held the right to access to all relevant documentation of the company under investigation,
26
Arved Deringer contributed not only to the further development of European competition law, but also to
the drafting of competition laws in countless countries (Deringer, 2003), a tradition that has been taken up
by other competition law experts at Freshfields Bruckhaus Deringer. More than forty years after Regulation
17, he still held the ordoliberal view that concentrated market power in the form of monopolies constitutes
the biggest threat to a competitive economy (ibid).
148
search this documentation unannounced (i.e. dawn raids), interrogate employees, and
sanction anticompetitive conduct with up to 10% of the companys annual turnover. It
allowed the Commission to intervene in the competition control of the Member States,
both with regard to private and public companies, and most notably, Regulation 17 allowed
the Commission to formulate its policy without the Council and the European Parliament
having a say, which has been crucial for setting the tone for further competence expansion
of the Commission.
To conclude, this chapter has identified the subsequent adoption of competition laws in
Europe in the aftermath of the Second World War, as part of a broader project of US
corporate and political interest in incorporating Western European countries into a
capitalist world economy. Competition laws served the purpose of creating market access
to (US) newcomers in the domestic home markets. Whereas the imposition of competition
laws in both German and the ECSC took place against the backdrop of strong US presence,
in the EEC the treaty drafters had adopted the idea of competition laws without direct US
involvement or help. As Van Apeldoorn et al. (2003: 39) noted, even though the
transatlantic link fundamentally influenced European integration, European integration is
not simply subject to or determined by American control. After the ECSC, European
integration developed as a relatively autonomous project. In the field of competition law,
US corporate and political pressure joined forces with a particular liberal minded group of
academics, the ordoliberals. Rather than a wholesale Americanisation, the particular
configuration of influential adherents of ordoliberal thinking and enduring industry
opposition gave shape to what previously was identified as the European competition
model. The ordoliberal Hans Von der Grben, who became the first Competition
Commissioner, can be held responsible for the ultimate inclusion of rules on competition
as one of the core constitutional founding principles of the Treaty of Rome. Arved
Deringer, also an adherent of ordoliberal ideas and a lawyer from the private sector, further
developed the subsequent regulatory procedures for implementing these laws. The
ordoliberal paradigm gave primacy to market structure over individual market
performance. Creating and maintaining a balanced ideal-type market structure, rather than
competition by all means, constitutes one of the central contributions of the ordoliberals
in the drafting phase. It formed the basis for multi-goal and long-term orientation, which
until the 1980s, shaped the views and conceptions of the European Commission's
149
Directorate General of Competition on ways to enforce competition laws (cf. Gerber, 1998;
Joerges, 2001; Budzinski, 2003; Schmitz, 2002).
150
Chapter 4
pressures from larger and technologically more advanced US companies, which tried to
gain a foothold in the newly created EC market. Corporations in Europe generally did not
meet the standards of their US competitors, which tended to be larger in size and far more
vertically integrated. In Europe, a similar homogeneous market situation to the US, with,
therefore, similar scope conditions allowing European corporations to reap the benefits of
economies of scale and other advantages, was absent. As a countervailing strategy, EC
Member States gave primacy to the creation of national champions who were able to
compete in the world economy. At EC level, the Commission sought to thwart the practice
in which governments picked their national winners, by stimulating Eurochampions
instead. It adopted a pro-economic concentration stance and actively motivated European
business to conclude intercompany agreements, in particular across Member State borders,
in order to catalyse European integration. In addition, spurring technological innovation as
a source of economic growth and competitive strength received central attention. In the
US, the institutionalisation of research on technological innovation at US universities
directly fed into corporate success. A similar institutionalisation of R&D was absent in
Europe; however, the Commission particularly stimulated intercompany cooperation in this
field. In the economic crisis years of the 1970s, the liberal embeddedness of competition
control was substantiated in the toleration of so-called structural crisis cartels, or
emergency cartels as they were sometimes also called. Industries in despair turned to the
Commission, who, based on the ex ante authorisation and exemption regime, sought to
alleviate economic recession problems. In the context of ongoing trade liberalisation
through the General Agreement of Trade and Tariffs (GATT), EC Member State
governments embraced new protectionist strategies to cushion national industries against
the competitive pressures of the opening world economy.
The Commission never lost focus on the market integration project. At a time of political
stalemate in the economic integration process, the approach was twofold. On the one hand,
it sought to dismantle internal market barriers and open up domestic markets through
competition law enforcement. On the other hand, in line with Member State and corporate
interests, it gave preferential treatment to certain industrial sectors facing competitive
pressures from mostly US companies, and increasingly also from Japanese companies.
Ordoliberal-inspired tenets of fair competition informed competition law enforcement
practices at the Commissions competition division, although in a much diluted form of the
views promoted by ordoliberal thinkers in the 1930s. The maxim of curbing economic
152
power concentration one of the centrepieces of ordoliberal doctrine did not materialise.
On the contrary, boosting economic size almost became an obsession. The ordoliberal ideal
of a balanced common market structure translated into special support for SMEs instead.
Small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) were largely excluded from complying with
EC laws. This chapter argues that the interplay of the Commission and European industry
representatives was crucial for the chosen course. Against the backdrop of competitive
pressures from abroad, industry also increasingly pushed for protectionist competition
rulings at EC level. The institutional peculiarities of the EC competition regime facilitated
the neomercantilist approach. The possibility for exempting certain business conducts,
either on a case-by-case basis, or categorically through block exemption regulations,
provided a welcome avenue for corporate actors to lobby for business-friendly treatments.
In order to fortify European players in the world market, the Commission adopted a
flexible and lenient enforcement strategy.
The breakdown of the Bretton Woods regime in August 1971 is generally taken as a critical
historical moment, ending the post-war regime of embedded liberalism (Ruggie, 1982).
However, in the field of EC competition law enforcement, embedded liberalism ideology
endured until the early 1980s. The advent of neoliberal ideas in the 1980s evoked a period
of transition that endured until the 1990s. According to Overbeek (1999), in the
ascendancy of neoliberalism as a hegemonic project there are three moments to identify. In
the early 1980s, neoliberalism evolved foremost as a deconstructive project, in which
previous enforcement practices were heavily criticised. In parallel, established protectionist
enforcement practices endured, in particular in economic areas facing difficulties to
compete. Only gradually did the neoliberalisation of EC competition law enforcement
make its inroads (see also Chapter 5). Structural changes in the global economy formed the
background against which neoliberal policy discourses nestled within the EC. With the
enhanced presence of large European companies in the global market, global competition
increased. In response, US-based competitors further diversified their production and
expanded around the world, which again triggered similar corporate strategies in Europe.
Vested business interests, mostly originating in the US, sought to enhance their global
competitiveness through the promotion of deregulation of capital markets and further
liberalisation of trade. What started in the US increasingly captured European business
elites, who started a vigorous political campaign at the Commission in the 1980s and
153
1990s, requesting the endorsement of neoliberal policies which open up markets and free
capital investment (Cox and Skidmore-Hess, 1999).
The weight of the institutional positioning of the Council in the Community structure left
the Commission with little scope for playing a prominent and proactive role in competition
law enforcement. The Franco-German rapprochement, personified by the flamboyant
personages of Charles De Gaulle and Konrad Adenauer, and the negotiations of the
Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) overshadowed Community politics. Moreover, a
range of ambitious proposals by Walter Hallstein, President of the Commission, provoked
154
the famous empty chair crisis in which President Charles De Gaulle, together with other
French representatives were absent from Council meetings from 30 June 1965 until 29
January 1966, until the conclusion of the Luxembourg Compromise. Hallstein and his
German staff surfaced as enthusiastic Federalists. As convinced ordoliberals, they held
holistic conceptions of market regulation and supported a market order governed at
supranational level. Hallstein wanted to implement the following changes: to expand the
Commissions powers, to introducing qualified majority voting (QMV) at Council level, to
create an independent source of Community finance and to revise the budget for CAP, as
well as to create a political union. After the French protests over the delegation of more
powers to the Brussels bureaucracy, Hallsteins ideas were put on ice for more than twenty
years until Jacques Delors, also a staunch Federalist, became President of the Commission
in 1985. Von der Grben later noted that Delors only continued what the ordoliberals had
started (Gehler and Grben, 2002: 53).
4.1 The American Challenge and the Creation of Embedded National Champions
Competition law enforcement in the 1960s was informed by the international political
context of the liberal post-war economic and financial Bretton Woods system erected by
the US. The Dillon and Kennedy GATT Round of the late 1950s and early 1960s reduced
tariffs to trade, which generated a period of expansion of the world economy, marked by
high levels of trade and capital flows. From the 1960s to the early 1970s, the worlds
manufacturing output doubled and trade in manufactured products trebled (Overbeek and
Van der Pijl, 1993: 5). Economically, politically, and culturally, the US evolved as the new
hegemon, also referred to as Pax Americana. The economic power of large US companies
was based on their dominance in the market for high-value goods and superiority in the
155
In contrast, European companies were much smaller. The European marketplace was
highly fragmented along national borders even after the creation of the EC. The different
national regulatory regimes reduced opportunities for economies of scale and scope
production. Cultural-linguistic barriers, but also the institutional landscape of varying
regulatory settings of the Member States, imposed structural constraints on the growth of
corporations. Mergers and acquisitions were relatively seldom. With the gradual opening
of national market barriers, the EC member governments sought to establish analogous
market conditions to that of the US. The European integration project always constituted a
political response to the challenges posed by the US market. It was subordinated to the
creation of the basic prerequisites that allow market players to compete. As Commissioner
Walter Hallstein noted, the goal of the transformation of the market relations in the
European Community as a whole was to build a new giant big enough in a world of giant
powers (in Freyer, 2006: 282). The project took shape through the subsequent abolition of
trade-related quotas and tariffs among the six Member States and the establishment of a
customs union that came into force on 1 July 1968, earlier than initially agreed in the
Treaty of Rome. The customs union entailed a Common External Tariff (CET) and a joint
foreign trade policy. In combination with the elimination of trade barriers under the GATT
regime, and the stepwise liberalisation of capital controls in the early 1960s, European
companies were confronted with enhanced competitive pressures, and subsequently
addressed their national governments for protectionist measures.
156
The depreciation of the US dollar and the stable exchange rates secured by the Bretton
Woods regime led to enhanced capital investments by US corporations in Europe. In 1960,
almost 60% of all FDI originated from the US (Overbeek, 1999: 243). US companies were
taking over European companies on a broad scale from the mid-1960s onwards, which led
to increased levels of market concentration. According to a sample analysis of the
Commission in 1971, in the time from 1966 to 1970, the acquisition of holdings and the
establishment of subsidiaries, as well as bilateral operations increased by a factor 3.5, often
involving non-Member State companies, most notably from the US, followed by British
and Swiss companies (European Commission, 1972: 171-77; 1973b: 30). The expansion of
US companies into Europe brought with it a critical shift in functional differentiation from
the level of country and sector to the level of product and firm (Ruggie, 1982: 401). Two
thirds of the increase in world trade from 1955 to 1973 was due to transatlantic trade flows.
The bulk was constituted by the intra-industry and intra-firm trade, which marks a
fundamental difference to the era prior to 1914, in which the levels of intercontinental
trade were overwhelmingly intersectoral (ibid: 400).
The dominant presence of the large US companies displayed the competitive disadvantage
of the relatively smaller, domestic corporations of the European Member States. In the
information technology sector and the emerging computer industry, in particular US
companies were leading (Sauter, 1997: 81). Through mergers and acquisitions, a range of
157
European companies, such as Philips or Siemens, were transformed into virtual trading
companies for US or Japanese producers (Hager, 1987: 59). This evoked the picture of a
growing submergence of so-called national champions in US economic hegemony. This
picture prevailed mainly in France, where politicians feared that US transnationals would
be a Trojan horse undermining French economic sovereignty (Gill and Law, 1989: 485).
The French Socialist and journalist, J. J. Servan-Schreiber, captured the phenomenon of
offensive US capital investment in the EC in his bestselling book of 1967 Le defi
amricain, the American challenge, in which he sought to raise awareness about the
comparative advantage of giant US companies seizing power in Europe. In addition to
technical advancement and innovation potential, he observed unmatched dynamism and
managerial organisation. He quoted a US businessperson saying:
The Treaty of Rome is the sweetest deal ever to come out of Europe. This is what brought
us here. Were happy to be here. We are making money. And we are going to make a lot
more [] Prospects in commerce and industry are better for us here than they are in the
United States. (1967: 22, own translation)
Against the background of progressive trade liberalisation within the GATT, and economic
integration within the Community, national governments could no longer apply
conventional protectionist measures. High tariff walls and import restrictions as a way of
insulating national companies from foreign competition were not a viable option anymore.
A range of European governments embraced the concerns of domestic industry
representatives about their lagging competitiveness, the growing technological gap, and the
drastically reduced production cycles. They opted for the strategy of creating national
champions, both in the private and public sector. They adopted far-reaching industrial
policies meant to boost the growth of national champions and industries considered
strategic. These measures generally included protectionist non-tariff policies, such as
guaranteed preferential public procurement contracts, tax rebates for some industries,
158
national standard setting, and the stimulation of mergers among national companies, as
well as (research) subsidies and investment in technical education (Sauter, 1997: 81;
Ruigrok and Van Tulder, 1995: 106). Moreover, national governments adopted proactive
programmes to encourage concentration activities among domestic corporations as a
catalyst for technological advancement. Corporate size was deemed vital in achieving
global competitiveness and in gaining market shares in the world market. For example, in
1968, the British Prime Minister Wilson announced the intention to fundamentally rethink
British hostility to monopolies and to restructure British industries on a scale and at a
speed such as we have not seen in this century (Adams and Brock, 1990: 177). The
enhanced mergers and acquisitions in Europe that followed brought forth an unprecedented
industrial restructuring during the 1960s. Between 1960 to 1969, more than 5,635
companies were absorbed through concentration activities, compared to 5,486 during the
decades of 1900 to 1959 (Cox and Watson, 1995: 308). A journalist observed that there
was
[] a fascination with gigantism, a mania for mergers, call it what you will, but Europe's
leading businessmen are infected with it. They are merging companies with such haste and
sweep that no label seems quite adequate. (Siekman, 1970: 95)
State aid also became an increasingly common instrument (Commission 1972: 16).
Thereby, national champions were embedded in a tolerant and protective national
context, regardless of the discriminatory impact against SMEs, as well as against
competitors from abroad. In addition to the pro-concentration stance and protectionist nontariff barriers, the strategy of embedded liberalism also entailed Keynesian monetary and
fiscal strategies to spur economic demand, complemented by welfare benefits for
individuals. The French government was particularly proactive in stimulating national
champions. In the post-war capitalist regime of dirigisme and planification, the French
corporate elite held close ties with the political elite. In line with the quests of French big
business, the government adopted protectionist and state-led industrial policies. In the era
of De Gaulle (1958-1969), nationalist sentiments moved to the fore in reaction to the first
steps of European integration. The goal to reinforce a competitive position for French
industry was formally spelled out in the Fifth Plan of the French planification economy,
covering the years of 1966-1970 (cf. Cinquime Plan de dveloppement conomique et
social in: Hayward, 1995: 4). The French government planned to strengthen a limited
number of large scale corporations through massive capital infusions and government159
The US inflow of capital through mergers and acquisitions brought with it a technology
transfer, as well as a transfer of production methods, increasingly industrial organisation,
and corporate governance methods. A similar transfer of organisational techniques was
imported from Japanese companies. Therefore, a range of European companies in hightechnology industries preferred piecemeal alliances with an economically superior US
partner to merging with enterprises from another Member States (Hayward, 1995: 5). The
alliance between Olivetti and AT&T and the collaborative venture of Unidata in the
computer production sector are exemplary in this respect. The joint venture Unidata, which
initially involved the European companies Siemens, CIT, and Philips, is particularly
illustrative. The project failed only after three years due to a decision by the French
government to draw up a transatlantic alliance between its national champion CIT and
Honeywell-Bull (ibid).
Against this overtly protectionist national context in the 1960s, the Commission applied
the supranational EC competition laws as a market integrationist tool meant to break down
intra-EC barriers, although, in a manner consistent with the overall bolstering of European
companies against competition from abroad. It pursued policies meant to stabilise the
adjustment process of companies faced with the competitive threat of ongoing trade
liberalisation. The Commissions Director General for Competition justified economic
concentration by saying:
It would be absurd [] to prevent the creation of an enterprise, which would dominate the
market of a small country, when such an enterprise would need its size to be competitive on
the export markets. (In Fennema, 1982: 61)
160
Three years later, the Council assured the European business community, that cooperation
was not banned by the Treaty in any case in which the position of enterprises concerned, as
a whole, is too weak to cause an appreciable limitation of competition in the common
market (Council, 1968: 465). The Commission emulated the concern of the Council about
the settlement of excessively large, financially and commercially powerful firms from the
US prompted by a wish to dominate (Von der Grben, 1965a: 3, 15-16). However, as the
guardian of the treaties, the Commission sought to supersede the Member States attempts
to create national champions. Instead, the Commission sought to create large European
corporations, so-called Eurochampions, in order to improve overall competitiveness of the
European economy vis--vis that of the US or Japan. The creation of the common market
should provide for the necessary economies of scale and expansion opportunities,
analogous to the large US market that brought forth corporate giants. Although the EC was
not actively involved in directly financing Eurochampions, based on a selective
competition law enforcement strategy, the Commission adopted an overtly lenient
approach towards cartels and economic concentrations between European enterprises.
Moreover, it promoted the creation of an appropriate fiscal and legal framework for
European business (Sauter, 1997: 75). By adopting a straightforward pro-industrial
cooperation and pro-concentration stance, the Commission applied EC competition laws as
a vehicle to make the European business community able to compete. It did therefore not
161
deviate from EC industrial policy, which strove for the same goal. In the spirit of economic
integration, the Commission generally considered cooperative agreements among
corporations that transcended national borders beneficial for market unity. This led,
amongst others, to enduring and successful cross-border alliances (certain critics would
call these alliances government-sponsored production cartels). Illustrative examples were
Concorde and Airbus, the European Space Agency (ESA), or the Train Grande Vitesse
(TGV). The development and production of the supersonic passenger aircraft Concorde
was a joint project negotiated by the French and British government (Dinan, 1999: 392).
The collaborative endeavour ended in 2003 after a major crash due to technical mistakes in
2000 in Paris. The industrial collaboration within the consortium Airbus came to
encompass the governmental support of France, Britain (until 1968), the Netherlands, and
Spain (ibid). As a range of national armies and government-controlled airline companies
were the main customers, the consortium was always state-sponsored in one way or
another.
The Commission based its pro-cooperation and pro-concentration stance on the issuance of
block exemption regulations. The next section introduces the importance of the acquisition
of this new enforcement tool in terms of the discretionary authority of the Commission on
the one hand, and for corporate lobbying on the other hand.
162
Nonetheless, the notification impasse of the early 1960s led to a much more far-reaching
decision. Rather than reviewing each notified case individually, the Commission suggested
that the Council adopted the possibility of block exemption regulations. Such block
exemption regulations would categorically exclude whole groups of intercompany
agreements from the notification requirements that fall under the loosely defined
conditions spelled out in Article 81(3) (TEC) (see Chapter 2). In March 1965, the Council
enacted the first block exemption regulation, which excluded certain vertical agreements
from Article 81 (cf. Council Regulation No. 19/65). As the number of notifications
remained high, only two years later in March 1967, the Council delegated the Commission
the power to issue its own block exemption regulations. This move was crucial as it opened
up the gate for enhanced discretionary powers on behalf of the Commission. It meant that
the Commission could enact its own legislation, which excluded whole classes of
commercial intercompany agreements from prosecution in addition to exempting
intercompany agreements on a case-by-case basis. Thereby, the Commission could not
only investigate and prosecute anticompetitive conduct, but also codify existing
competition laws further, and hence, steer its competition policy in the desired direction.
As will be demonstrated throughout this dissertation, with the legislative tool of block
exemption regulation, the Commission was in a position to significantly affect the course
of competition law enforcement in the coming decades and conduct a real policy in this
field. The Council ratified the Regulation merely to create administrative convenience for
the Commission and could not foresee the future impact of the far-reaching competences
entrusted upon the Commission in the 1960s. Warlouzet (2006: 6) suggests that the
163
Commission mobilised the still inexperienced national civil servants in competition matters
through a range meetings. Even there was never a consensus on technical questions, once
the Commission made the issuance of block exemption regulations a Council agenda point,
it claimed to have reached an agreement with the national civil servants on the Regulation.
Under the exemption regime of Article 81(3) and a series of notices issued during the
1960s, the Commission allowed a broad range of commercial intercompany agreements as
a part of its strategy to create embedded Eurochampions. As the next section
demonstrates, initially, the business community was not convinced of the Commissions
goodwill.
27
In the aftermath of the adoption of Regulation 17, German industry representatives protested to Chancellor
Konrad Adenauer against the reappointment of von der Grben as a Competition Commissioner in 1962
(Gehler and Grben, 2002: 47). To speed up the process, von der Grben was offered the running of the
Konjunkturinstitut in Berlin instead a prestigious position, which he however rejected. He later said about
his office as a Competition Commissioner that it had a strong political meaning, which displeased certain
people in Germany (ibid).
164
The possibilities for exemption from Article 81(1) provided a welcome avenue for
corporate lobbying in favour of a lenient and protectionist decision making that would
remedy lagging international competitiveness. In the end, the EC business community was
rather pleased with the benevolent measures aimed at improving the overall
competitiveness of European industries (Dinan, 1999: 393). As the notification regime
provided companies with provisional validity and immunity from fines until the
notifications were evaluated and the decisions taken, most of the cases were generally
settled in an administrative, business-friendly manner. At least, until 1970, no fines were
imposed. The Commission adopted a favourable stance towards commercial intercompany
agreements. However, it did not artificially stimulate cooperative agreements between
companies, but remained passive, leaving the decision to cooperate to the entrepreneurs
(Von der Grben, 1963: 6). In line with the ordoliberal standpoint, the Commissions DG
IV did not intervene in market processes, but confined its role to shaping a favourable
economic framework. In this vein, companies could proceed with the scheduled agreement
in more than 85% of the cases (i.e. cases that were closed by formal decisions in the time
from 1964 to 1970).
The Commission allowed the vast majority of the deals, either by negatively clearing the
cases (i.e. allowing them straight away), or by granting exemptions under Article 81(3).
Almost a third of all cases received exemption. Eventually, less than 15% of the cases
infringed Article 81 and Article 82 (TEC).28 In the context of the presumed American
technological challenge, it considered commercial agreements between companies in hightechnology industries to be harmless to competition, in particular if they involved the
exchange of experience, R&D contracts, cooperation in fields such as accounting and
credits, joint statistics or market research. In addition, agreements regarding the joint use of
production and storage facilities, partnerships in the purchase of resources, as well as
common selling and repair arrangements were also excluded from prosecution. In 1967,
the Commission adopted a block exemption that was particularly far-reaching in this
regard. Regulation 67/67 exempted bilateral agreements on exclusive selling and exclusive
purchasing as long as the participating companies belonged to at least two Member States
(Commission 1972: 99). The regulation officially authorised cartel-like cross-border
agreements. The Commission adopted the Regulation to boost cross-border commercial
28
The percentages are based on calculation retrieved from all official decisions on the notified agreements
referring to Article 81 and Article 82, published at
http://europa.eu.int/comm/competition/antitrust/cases/older_antitrust_cases.html.
165
interdependencies in order to further the economic integration project and to enhance the
competitiveness of European industries. The expiry date of the Regulation was set for 31
December 1972. However, three weeks before expiry, the Commission extended the
validity for another ten years through the adoption of Regulation 2591 (European
Commission, 1973b: 19). Regulation 2591 included further specifications intended to
facilitate the specialisation of products, and limited the exemption to companies with a
market share that did exceed 10% in their national home market, in order to warrant a
sufficient degree of competition in the respective geographical markets (ibid, 1972: 21).
In order to make the exemption process more transparent and to reduce the number of
notifications, the Commission specified eight categories of cooperation activities that did
not fall under the prohibition of Article 81(1) in a Notice on Cooperation published in
1968. What commentators interpreted as an attempt by the Commission to reduce the
administrative burden (cf. Bright, 1996), formed part of the Commissions pro-industrial
cooperation policy. In the same way, a range of concrete economic policies were
formulated in the Colonna Report of 1969, a programming statement on how to strengthen
the competitive position of corporations in the Community, to achieve a reasonable degree
of technological independence from the US, and to facilitate the creation of European
champions (see for more details Sauter, 1997: 71). In the face of the resistence of the
Member State governments, the Commission did not tackle state aid granted to private
companies, or the preferential treatment of state-owned companies, although prohibited
under EC law, and ignored Articles 86 and 87 in the 1960s (Cini and McGowan, 1998: 22).
Like the proactive cooperation and pro-state aid policy, the Commission encouraged
economic concentration throughout the 1960s. Again, it considered mergers in technology
sectors with a high R&D intensity, particularly important, and again, it did not actively
order concentrations, but left the decision to entrepreneurs. The Commission held the view
that it was the task of industrialists to instigate concentrations by mergers and acquisitions,
and the task of the authorities to facilitate them (Adams and Brock, 1990: 177). Von der
Grben noted that the need of the age for companies was to form larger groups and that
artificial and psychological obstacles to mergers needed to be removed (Von der Grben,
1965a: 4, 13). The Commissions reluctance to apply Article 82, prohibiting the abuse of a
dominant position indirectly, led to the situation where no large corporations resulting
from mergers and acquisitions were prosecuted.
166
Following the holistic ordoliberal perception that competition control formed one of the
several regulatory fields responsible for creating order, von der Grben emphasised that
competition policy was inseparable from overall economic policy-making and called for an
approximation of legislation (cf. Von der Grben, 1969). He considered the different
national corporate tax burdens and taxation for merging companies a major distortion for
the healthy functioning of competition. In this vein, von der Grben proposed to harmonise
corporate turnover tax regimes and of the law governing companies or partnerships with
limited liability, and especially joint stock companies (ibid: 12). The Commissions procooperation and pro-concentration policy of the 1960s was not informed by ordoliberal
ideas, despite the presence of adherents of ordoliberal ideas at the DG IV. The Commission
adopted a tolerant approach towards market size, although, the Freiburg scholars of the
1930s considered it important to curb the concentration of economic power (see Chapter
2). Competition Commissioner von der Grben was aware of the conflict between market
concentration and the ordoliberal goal of developing a balanced market structure. In Ordo,
the academic journal of the ordoliberals, he justified the Commissions policy course by
arguing that the state of science and statistical evidence could not yet sufficiently indicate
when market concentration was harmful (Von der Grben, 1963: 5-6). Elsewhere, he noted
that it was impossible to generalise about the optimum size of companies, but there was
definitely a limit for amalgamated firms to gain market power (ibid, 1966a: 7; 1965a: 12,
17). However, in general, economic concentrations, he continued, formed a constructive
and positive part of the competition policy (ibid, 1966a: 6).
The presence of devotees of the ordoliberal paradigm in the Commission endured. With the
establishment of the Rey Commission (1967-1971), von der Grben took over the
Directorate General Regional Policy in 1967. Maan Sassen, his successor from the
Netherlands, reassumed most of his personnel and assured the continuation of the von der
Grbens course. A range of background studies drafted in the early years became
influential in the formulation of later policy priorities (Cini and McGowan, 1998: 22).
Moreover, von der Grbens Chef de cabinet, Ernst Albrecht, a Christian Democrat from
Germany and fervent adherent of ordoliberal ideas, became Director General under Sassen
(ibid).
167
168
169
4). Thereby, the Court backed up the Commission in interpreting Article 81 as a solid legal
tool to tackle private restraints that constitute a direct or indirect threat to the market
integration project. The latter element was important, in so far as the common market
provided the decisional criterion for blocking an agreement, and not competition as such
(Sauter, 1997: 119). Whether or not vertical agreements were outlawed required a rule of
reason (see Chapter 2). Only those agreements that distort trade flows across Member
State borders, including export and import restrictions, were considered illegal in the
1960s. The Grundig-Consten ruling became a landmark case. It signalled to the European
industries that they could no longer ignore the Commission as a supranational competition
authority. Moreover, it illustrates the important role played by the ECJ as a principal
integration force at a time in which the process seemed to be stagnating.
Until very recently, the Commissions harsh stance towards vertical intercompany
agreements constitutes one of the most notorious fields of controversies (Gerber, 2003:
175). In particular, antitrust experts of the US criticised the Commissions approach,
because the US approach towards vertical agreements was always much more lenient. This
was further enhanced by the fact that horizontal producer cartels, the sharp end of
competition policy, remained largely untouched by the Commission until far into the
1970s (Harding and Joshua, 2003: 110; Berghahn, 1986: 471). Horizontal cartels could
operate with impunity (Goyder, 1998: 70). In response to the enhanced economic
concentration at that time, the formation of cartel-like cooperation agreements gradually
weakened as larger combines were less dependent on reducing competition (Berghahn,
1986: 282). Nonetheless, the Commission did not hinder Europes industrial elite in its
traditional approach of forming cartels. Only in 1969, the Commission started to prosecute
horizontal cartel agreements based on Article 81 infringements. The Quinine and the
Dyestuffs cases are exemplary in this regard. Both cases concerned export cartels, so-called
gentlemans agreements that purported to protect national product markets. Moreover,
both agreements entailed price fixing elements. The Quinine case is particularly
interesting, as the case only attracted the Commissions attention after the US antitrust
authorities took legal actions and imposed fines. The cartel, which dated back to 1913,
concerned an agreement between French, German, and Dutch producers on the cinchona
bark, the base material for quinine used in the production of malaria medicines. They fixed
prices, allocated markets, and stabilised the supply. When the prices for the raw material
for the production of malaria medicines increased, in response to the increased demand for
170
Like the large unified market of the US, European economic integration should provide a
platform for Eurochampions to exploit economies of scale and scope. Competition policy
in the 1960s was subordinated to this goal. It was employed to open up national markets
and create access to competitors. Against the backdrop of lagging competitiveness of
European corporations, the Commission adopted a pro-cooperation and pro-concentration
171
stance in order to strengthen Eurochampions who were able to face competition from their
larger counterparts in the US, and increasingly also from Japan, where companies had
successfully adopted the logics of Fordist production culture of cheap mass products. At
the same time, SMEs received a preferential treatment through generous exemption
regulations freeing them from compliance with EC competition laws.
172
financial flows, new possibilities for speculation on foreign exchange markets were
created, i.e. the type of monetary transactions the Bretton Woods regime had previously
sought to constrain. As one of the direct spin offs of the speculative behaviour after the
collapse of Bretton Woods, economic concentrations through mergers and acquisitions
activity increased considerably in the early 1970s (Oster, 1999: 223). From 1974 to 1975,
share acquisitions sharply increased, amounting to a growth rate of 49% (European
Commission, 1977: 150-152). The number of non-Community firms involved in share
acquisition rose from 9% in 1974 to 24% in 1975. US capital owners, in particular,
acquired EC based companies, of which many sought to make quick profits from
undervalued assets (Dawkins, 1987b: 2). Also the US economy underwent a rapid
concentration. In 1972, the largest 200 corporations held 60% of the manufacturing assets
in the US (Freyer, 2006: 137). Thereby, US companies continued to be the largest and the
most technologically advanced in the world. To illustrate this: in 1969, the US company
Standard Oil was double the size of Royal Dutch Shell, General Motors was seven times
larger than the German company Volkswagen, and Chrysler twice as large as Volkswagen
(Mueller, 1993: 159). Similarly, General Electrics was double the size of Philips, and US
Steel was double the size of British Steel (ibid).
The decision by OPEC to increase oil prices precipitated a situation of stagflation in 197374. European economies were in severe crisis, facing unemployment, worsening inflation
rates, and overall balance of payments disequilibria. The economic recession and
insecurity culminated in a climate of new protectionism at Member State level. European
industrialists facing economic decline turned to their national governments to offset the
effects of foreign competition. The creation of a favourable macroeconomic environment
that stimulates investment was deemed crucial for overcoming the overall economic
malaise in Europe. As the imposition of higher import duties, as a means to curtail the
inflow of competing goods, was not a viable option, protectionist market interventionist
industrial policies of a non-tariff nature were employed. They generally included quotas,
voluntary export restraints, state aid, a broad range of supportive export-promoting and
import-controlling measures (cf. Kahler, 1985). However, occasionally this went as far as
the control of wages, prices, credits and imports, to the wholesale direct subsidisation of
loss-making industries (Sauter, 1997: 77). The spirit of the GATT Kennedy Round of the
1960s, devoted to keeping economic frontiers open, seemed to have been reversed. In line
with Keynesian full employment macroeconomic policies, new protectionism formed the
173
The Commission redefined its role as the guardian against the development of
protectionists tendencies
174
the 1970s, the Commission assured that it will not lose sight of the social and human
factors involved, which may justify aid beyond what is required by strictly economic
reasoning (ibid).
The key word in the enforcement of EC competition law throughout the 1970s was
flexibility, which was declared more important than a dogmatic approach (cf.
European Commission, 1977: 9). The Commission steadfastly defined its overarching
maxims with concepts such as equality of opportunity and fairness, notions that reflect the
ordoliberal ideal of complete competition in which market players compete on equal
terms. In the Ninth Annual Report on Competition in 1980, the Commission announced
that it would preserve a situation of equality of opportunity in the internal market by
helping certain industries to adapt to new economic circumstances and by supporting an
industrial policy which promotes the necessary restructuring (ibid, 1980: 10). Moreover,
in line with the full-employment policies and the Keynesian-inspired demand management
at the Member State level, the ideal of equal opportunity was also formulated in terms of a
necessity to take into consideration the legitimate interests of workers, users and
consumers (ibid). The next section illustrates that these broader policy goals were
manifested in a lenient stance towards cooperative intercompany agreements and state aid.
175
cartels as they were sometimes also called (ibid, 1981a). Old industries of steel,
shipbuilding, chemistry, and textiles, as well as the sugar industry, gratefully took
advantage of the permissive attitude of the Commission. Rather than outcompeting each
other, competitors could engage in joint ventures and make use of production quotas, in
order to deal with disparities between production capacities and actual demand (i.e. chronic
excess production), as well as with prices that did not cover production costs. Reduced
competition in the short-run would, according to expectations, spur the recovery of the
affected industries, and ultimately benefit the competitiveness of the European economy in
the long run. The Commission argued that the decisions made in this context did not
easily fit into a general pattern, since each case needed to be treated according to its
particular characteristics (ibid, 1972: 25).
The notification and exemption regime provided a convenient and flexible tool to deal with
the pressing problems of the European economy. The Commission qualified a large
number of notified agreements as individual exemptions ruled by Article 81(3), or
permitted them right away. It allowed structural crisis cartels, and agreements designed to
spur innovation, particularly if they concerned R&D support and cooperation or a transfer
of technology. Similarly, also employment considerations were used to justify crisis
cartels. This approach was further reinforced by an ECJ ruling in the case of Metro SBGrossmrkte GmbH & Co. KG v. Commission in 1977. The ECJ ruled that Article 81(3)
exemptions to intercompany agreements could be granted when they had a beneficial
impact on employment, particularly in times of unfavourable market conditions (Monti,
2007: 96). The Commission, however, warned the business community that these
temporary protectionist measures could not be taken as a commitment to similar
protectionist measures in the future (cf. European Commission, 1977). Nonetheless, a
range of these crisis cartels endured until the restructuring initiatives of the mid-1980s, in
which the Commission took the role of assisting companies to undertake restructuring
measures (see the next part of this chapter). In its Twelfth Annual Report in 1982, the
Commission continued to publish informal conditions for the exemption of crisis cartels
under Article 81(3). Particularly companies suffering from structural overcapacity, without
prospect of improvement in the medium-term, and confronted with the risk of social
dislocation, qualified for the establishment of crisis cartels (cf. European Commission,
1982). Only in a few instances did it order the termination of an agreement, and only a few
companies appealed the decision before the court, i.e. the Belgian Wallpaper case (Papier
176
Peints) in 1974, the Cement case (VCH) in 1972 and the Belgian Tobacco case
(FEDETAB) in 1978 (see for more on these cases Harding and Joshua: 119-120).
In addition to the toleration of crisis cartels, the Commission sought to encourage the
competitiveness of European corporations in a more structural way. In a joint conference
on Industry and Society in the EC in Venice in 1972, industry representatives and
Commission officials proposed special measures for high technology industries and
industries facing crisis conditions, which eventually were included in a Memorandum on
Technological and Industry Policy in 1973 (Sauter, 1997: 74). European industry
representatives complained about being trapped in a vicious circle of lagging
competitiveness. The presumed technological challenge of US and Japanese competitors
resulted in ever-shorter product life cycles, and hence, shorter time to regain R&D
expenditures. European corporations faced difficulties in amortising their product
development costs through products sales only in the EC. As the European market was still
rather fragmented and the possibilities for reaping the benefits of economies of scale
177
limited, they requested further economic integration. Moreover, expansion into third
country markets increasingly became a prerequisite for economic survival and success.
Whereas Member State governments sustained the export of indigenous producers through
state funded R&D projects, guaranteed procurement, and export subsidies, the
Commissions DG IV took a proactive stance towards joint corporate investments in R&D
instead. It considered strategic alliances in R&D-intensive, high value-added sectors
necessary to pool technological know-how and to avoid duplicating innovative research
(European Commission, 1981a: 13). Thus, as part of a broader neomercantilist strategy, the
stimulation of technological innovation reached a central position on the Commissions
agenda to build up the competitiveness of Eurochampions in the world.
178
In the absence of proper EC merger laws, the famous Continental Can decision in 1972 is
illustrative of how the Commission applied Article 82 instead. In the first decade of EC
competition law enforcement, Article 82 was deliberately not applied, in order to
strengthen European companies against foreign competitors (see previous part of this
Chapter). The Commissions sudden distrust in bigness, however, was directed foremost
towards non-community companies. In the Continental Can case, the Commission sought
to avoid that a leading US company in the production of metal containers would take over
the Dutch packaging company TDV, an economically weaker European competitor. Prior
to this, Continental Can already acquired the German firm SLW, also a producer of
containers and related products. The Commission banned the planned takeover under
Article 82 and argued that the acquisition constituted an abuse of its already dominant
market position in both the Benelux and in Germany.
179
The timing of the Commissions expansionist drift, with regard to controlling mergers, was
no coincidence. When the merger law of West Germany, the Fusionsgesetz, had already
passed the preparatory stages it was adopted in 1973 the Commission sought to seize
the opportunity and to reinvigorate the merger discussion at EC level. The Commission
emphasised that a piecemeal emergence of national merger rules was not sufficient. In
particular, after the conclusion of a bilateral free trade agreement of the EC with the
Member governments of the European Free Trade Area (EFTA) in 1972, EC competition
rules underwent a geographical expansion, which strengthened the overall position of the
DG IV as a supranational competition authority. Although the Commission could not
directly prosecute anticompetitive conduct in the EFTA, it participated in the joint
surveillance committee, which provided it with an opportunity to ask the respective
national authority in charge to take action against observed anticompetitive conduct. Prior
180
to drafting the proposal for a pan-European merger law, the Commission sought to
generate political support and increase its leverage power vis--vis the Council, by
consulting an impressive range of national and international business organisations, as well
as a few labour and consumer organisations (see for a complete overview
European Commission, 1974: 38).
The lack of Council support for more Commission competences fits into the overall
landscape of the integration deadlock of the 1970s and early 1980s. In other words, the
Commission explored the limits of its institutional competences and found them. Even
though the merger wave of the late 1960s and early 1970s did not endure, the Commission
put much effort into keeping the merger regulation proposal on the negotiation table.
Rather than problematising mergers, it started to adopt a more favourable stance towards
mergers again. In its Third Annual Competition Report in 1974, it argued:
[There is a] desire and need of Community firms to adapt constantly to the new scale of
their markets and to improve their competitiveness on the world market. Many mergers, as
a result of the structure of the markets in which they occur, in no way lessen competition
but, on the contrary, can increase it. (European Commission, 1974: 28)
181
182
183
large export-orientated corporations were more globally orientated and interested in the
free movement of goods, services, and capital on a global scale. Transnational corporations
with a global focus surfaced as staunch supporters of the completion of the common
market, guaranteeing free market access and free movement of goods, services, capital, and
people. They became active in the promotion of the neoliberal discourse of free markets. A
new tide of protectionism in Europe could trigger similar reactions elsewhere and inhibit
market access for Community products and the purchase of raw materials. This could
negatively affect net industrial exporters and transnationally operating corporations with
extensive intra-firm trade flows.
This part argues that the DG Competition, which by then was still called DG IV,
increasingly embraced the neoliberal tone in the enforcement of EC competition laws in
the 1980s. In the presence of political counterforces, the process of ideological
transformation did not take place overnight and radically break with the enforcement
philosophies of the past two decades. The economic crisis of the 1970s was not yet
overcome. The proponents of a neoliberal course did not drown out the protectionist
corporate interests of the neomercantilists within the Community. Requests for
protectionist measures even underwent an upswing with the rise of M&As and strategic
alliances, enhanced FDI flows, and the presence of ever fiercer competition from Japanese
and corporations from South East Asia. Adherents of neomercantilist strategies sought to
cure the situation in the adoption of investment stimulation measures aimed at fostering the
competitiveness of European companies, a strategy in favour of European regionalism with
a protectionist edge (Ruigrok and Van Tulder, 1995: 128-130). When drawing on the
different phases in the ascendancy of neoliberalism as a hegemonic project by Overbeek
(1999: 248-249), it can be argued that neoliberalism in the early 1980s evolved as a
deconstructive moment, in which neoliberal reasoning gradually made its inroads, and a
significant share of high-level politicians subsequently endorsed the new ideology.
However, the strength of the neoliberal orientation only started to reveal its impact from
the mid-1980s onwards. Therefore, the enforcement of EC competition law in the early
1980s formed part of a transition period.
184
To date the Mont Plerin Society is committed to the goal of promoting neoliberal ideas entailing
according to its own saying the redefinition of the functions of the state so as to distinguish more clearly
between the totalitarian and the liberal order (Mont Plerin Society, 2005).
185
Report of 1986, the Commission announced the protecion of SMEs against powerful
competitors, including transnational companies by enforcing Article 82 and the banning of
abusive dominant positions. It argued that abusive market power by a few should not
undermine the rights of the many (European Commission, 1987). This policy manifested
itself in the prosecution of the charging of abnormally low prices intended to squeeze out
small competitors and against refusals to supply products essential to the activity of SMEs
(European Commission, 1988: 29). The continuity of competition law enforcement can be
ascribed to the economic recession of the 1970s, which continued into the early 1980s. The
prospects for recovery remained gloomy. According to the Annual Economic Report for
1982 and 1983, national economies were still suffering from heavy public sector debts,
zero-growth rates, overall high interest rates, inflation and mounting rates of
unemployment. In 1982 there were about 11,5 million people unemployed in the EC, about
half of which were young people, an overall increase of 17% compared to 1981
(Andriessen, 1982a: 1).
Nonetheless, a more stringent enforcement philosophy gradually made its inroads. The
Commission announced its intention to act with more firmness, especially in times of
recession when companies in particular were inclined to cartelise (ibid, 1981a: 2). While it
still considered state aid, in certain cases, perfectly legitimate, in others it was compared to
woodworms eating away the carcass of the ship of integration (ibid, 1982b: 6). The
Commission endorsed neoliberal reasoning in a range of restructuring measures, in which
the tolerant approach of the 1970s was increasingly tightened. Industries facing prolonged
economic downturn were despicably called sunset industries or lame ducks. The crisis
cartels and branch-wide agreements that previously were meant to shelter indigenous
companies from foreign competition were increasingly phrased as anomalies and as
examples of a frozen economy (ibid). Rather than crisis cartels, the Commissions DG IV
actively encouraged and monitored restructuring plans. Based on industrial
rationalisation programmes, the Commission sought to ensure that the healing process
was not delayed or obstructed (European Commission, 1981b). In practice, these
programmes often implied the downsizing of employment and the strict prohibition of
price and market sharing agreements.
The new rigours in the enforcement of competition laws were first felt in the ailing
European steel industry. Under the alleged reason of revitalising the industry, the
186
strong presence of US and Japanese companies evoked the picture of an industrial and
economic infeudation of Europe (Gibb, 1986: 17).
The pressures were successful insofar as the Commission adopted a range of block
exemption regulations to counter the lagging technological competitiveness in the early
1980s. Yet, investments in new technologies and science remained a private affair.
Nonetheless, by means of exemption, the Commission provided for a supportive regulatory
framework for intercompany collaboration. The block exemptions concerned R&D
cooperation agreements, patent licences, as well as an enlargement of the existing block
exemption regulation on specialisation and exclusive distribution agreements. The latter, in
particular, aimed at enabling small and medium-sized companies to achieve economics of
scale, by allowing them to concentrate their production and form joint ventures. The green
card for SMEs to cooperate was extended and the suppleness of the Commission
continued (Andriessen, 1981b: 11). Commissioner Andriessen (1984:11) elucidated at the
Internationalen Kartelkonferenz in Berlin in 1984 that cooperation prevented the
duplication of research and hence the squandering of resources, which could give a
substantial boost to integration in the Community. He further noted that cross-frontier
cooperative schemes bring economies of scale and assure sales in all the countries
concerned, which pulls countries out of the fragmentation of markets (ibid). Business
representatives of import-competing sectors advised the Commission to grasp the nettle
and apply cooperation schemes to genuinely European companies only, those having their
headquarters in European countries and with their profits remaining in Europe, rather than
to transnational corporations from the US trying to convince European governments of
their Europeanness (Butler, 1986: 17). As one representative postulated
The US Government knows which are American companies. We know which are European.
[] (Our companies) have to forget that they are long-standing rivals and remember the
danger of hanging separately if they do not stand together. They have to make deals under
which they produce complementary products and buy them from each other. They have to
form joint venture companies to produce hardware and, indeed, whole IT systems. They
have to find ways of pooling their marketing efforts, either for particular products or by
region. [] Ways of thinking must be changed in the European Commission, in
governments, in boardrooms and in middle-management. (Ibid)
188
189
concluded strategic alliances with competing companies, such as with the market leaders in
the production of semiconductors and telecommunication equipment suppliers, Intel and
Mittel, did not raise concerns. In the face of Japanese competition, US antitrust authorities
supported their national champion by adopting an utmost lenient stance.
The Commission took a different view to its US counterparts and was willing to assert its
view to enforce antitrust law in a way the US might not (Fikentscher, 2003: 24). IBM
fiercely protested against the allegations and started a massive lobbying campaign in
Brussels. It eventually challenged the Commission's decision at the ECJ in 1981. The
accusation against IBM also raised concerns among US authorities about protectionist
tendencies at the Commission. In response to political pressure from the US, the
Commission eventually suspended its proceedings against IBM, in August 1984 and
comforted US authorities and corporations with the promise that the EC would ensure a
non-discriminatory treatment of all corporations operating inside the common market
(Andriessen, 1981a: 5). In return, the IBM made (minor) concessions in a settlement
agreement and proposed, in good faith, to provide competitors with a technical description
that was sufficient to enable a competent professional skilled in the art to attach a product
of his design to an IBM System/370 product (FT, 1984: 2). Moreover, IBM demonstrated
its willingness to cooperate in Esprit, the programme designed by the EC to boost the
development of the European electronics industry. John Opel, CEO of IBM said about the
settlement: This undertaking satisfies the Commission's desires and puts the matter behind
us, without requiring us to make significant changes in how we do business". (Cheesright
and De Jonquieres, 1984) Thereby, IBM kept the right to safeguard the information about
the inner workings of its machines. Competitors believed, however, that this continued to
enhance the dominance of the IBM's technical standards worldwide (FT, 1984: 2). The
Commission warned the company that it might start up the legal processes at any time
again. In fact, it did so right after the settlement to check whether IBM had withheld the
source code of software packages.
190
of the best protected sectors in Europe. Member States shielded their national champions
from the logics of open competition. From the 1980s onwards, European producers faced
increased competition from car manufacturers in the US, Japan, and later Korea. In the
battle for supremacy in the Western European car market, they had difficulties in
competing with the much cheaper imports. Member State safeguarded their indigenous car
producers by imposing entry barriers for mostly Japanese importers. Exemplary are the
Italian and French governments, which concluded bilateral agreements with Japan
entailing a restriction on Japanese imports to their domestic car markets of 1% and 3%
respectively (Seidenfuss and Kathawala, 2005). In response to the intense lobbying of
national car producers and Member State governments, the Commission endorsed the view
that the car sector needed special protection. It made use of the legislative powers derived
from Regulation 17 (see Chapter 2), and adopted the Block Exemption Regulation 123/85
in 1985. The Regulation was limited to ten years and exempted exclusive distribution
regimes of European car manufacturers with their car dealers from Article 81(1). Thereby,
the EC level officially formalised national protectionist practices (Akbar, 2003: 4). The
block exemption was established under the pretext of warranting quality services.
However, in essence, car manufacturers could install exclusive and separate dealer
distribution systems in order to reduce the exposure of brand names, and hence (foreign)
competition. Japanese manufacturers such as Nissan and Toyota fiercely opposed the
protectionists and discriminatory block exemption regulation. However, after they invested
in their own exclusive distribution networks in Europe, the companies supported the
continuation of the regulation in 1994 similar to their European producers (see Chapter 5).
Only smaller car manufacturers, such as Honda, Mitsubishi, and Mazda, which lacked a
similar distribution network, opposed its continuation (Ruigrok and Van Tulder, 1995:
278).
191
The Commission kept a close eye on the US competition administration, but still clearly
distanced itself from the US laissez-faire approach in antitrust matters. Compared to the
US, the Commission adopted a more activist approach. Consequently, business
192
With the enhanced presence of true European transnational companies from the 1970s
onwards, the European Round Table of Industrialists (ERT) appeared on the political stage
of the EC. Leading CEOs of transnational corporations, Wisse Dekker of Philips, Pehr
Gyllenhammer of Volvo, and Umberto Agnelli of Fiat joined forces with another forty
CEOs of leading transnational corporations, the so-called captains of European industry,
and launched the ERT in 1983. The ERT became one of the major driving forces of the
institutionalisation of neoliberal policies within the EC. The emergence of the ERT
reflected the rise of transnational corporations in developed countries that started in the
1960s. The number of TNCs increased from 7,000 at the end of the 1960s to 40,000 at the
end of the 1990s (Djelic and Kleiner, 2006: 293). Sales of foreign affiliates increased from
US $ 3 trillion in 1980s to US $ 14 trillion today, exceeding the level of world trade (ibid).
As a transnational elite forum of mostly European transnational corporations, the ERT held
privileged access points to the Commission, in particular to the DGs for trade, internal
market, and competition. The high-level elite character of the ERT seemed sufficient to
establish a dialogue with the Commission and national politicians and to set the agenda for
future economic integration in Europe (Van Apeldoorn, 2002). As Wilks and McGowan
(1996: 242) sketched, Fiat wields more influence than many Italian ministries, Philips
writes the briefs with which Dutch officials negotiate, and no Commission official will
refuse to see the representatives of Daimler Benz. In fact, as a member of the ERT
193
reported, the Commission was extremely open to the business community, which implied
that whenever necessary, businessmen had access to Commissioners (in CEO, 2000).
Initially, the ERT did not advocate a radical neoliberal laissez-faire stance. In the mid1980s, the ERT directed the bulk of its attention towards formulating policy solutions that
bolster the competitiveness of European companies. According to Van Apeldoorn (2002),
import-competing companies with a focus on the European market dominated the ERT,
which favoured a Europrotectionist stance: a borderless, integrated common market that
served as a homebase to reach the scale necessary to resist the pressures from nonEuropean competitors, mostly from the US and Japan (ERT, 1983). The concern that
international competitors were developing a lead over Europe in certain new technologies
stood central (ibid). In 1984, the ERT set up Euroventures, a pan-European venture capital
organisation largely funded by the ERT member companies, which had the purpose of
stimulating Europes position as an independent source of innovation in a world
dominated by the US and Japan (Batchelor, 1988: 9). The target groups for the corporate
venture were small and medium-sized corporations. The Euroventures project generally
ended with ERT companies taking over smaller companies in order to control innovative
ideas and products, which they lacked the time to develop themselves (ibid). The ERT
gradually started to promote more globalist views in the late 1980s. In search of ever-larger
and ever-freer markets on a worldwide scale, the export-orientated corporations of the ERT
mostly, resolutely required to speed up neoliberal reforms and to create an uttermost
business-friendly climate unhindered by public interferences and regulatory barriers (see
Chapter 5). For this purpose, the ERT closely cooperated with other corporate lobby
groups, such as AmCham and UNICE. They exchanged a lot of information, had joint
meetings, and even published joint papers in order to strategically reinforce and
supplement each others' positions (in CEO, 1999a). As a general strategy, the
collaboration was kept rather non-transparent, as it was more effective not to say
everything together, but to have different people telling the institutions more or less the
same thing (ibid).
The ERT took a leading role in advocating a new course in the enforcement of EC
competition laws from very early on. It established its own competition division, the
working group on competition policy, which over the years regularly responded to
Commission proposals, Green Papers, as well as initiating new policy proposals in its
194
position papers. At the European Management Forum Symposium at Davos in 1983, Wisse
Dekker, later chairman of the ERT (from 1988-1992), suggested the fundamental rewriting
of the ECs competition rules (Andriessen, 1983a: 2). The Commission should reconsider
the basis upon which it took decisions and to relax the stringency of competition rules
(ibid). The quest for a relaxation of stringency concerned only interpretations with regard
to the Commissions interpretation of dominant positions and vertical agreements, i.e.
issues related to corporate size and market shares. The ERT clearly favoured the removal
of anticompetitive practices, such as price fixing and market allocation cartels as well as
state aid, to certain industries, in other words, all practices that led to fragmented markets
and that directly inhibited their market access. Moreover, the free marketers highlighted
the link between competition rules and international trading relations. They urged the
Commission to seek greater consistency in the application of competition laws in order to
facilitate the emergence of transnational industrial structures that allow them to compete
on a world wide scale (ERT, 1983).
This early attempt by the ERT to influence the future course of competition laws was
successful insofar that the Commissions DG IV introduced a new post, called conseillerauditeur, which would make sure that the Commission heard a company's defence. The
post was entrusted with the task to guarantee fairness and balance in the investigative
process of anticompetitive conduct and to directly advise the staff on the restrictive
practices and abuse of dominant market positions. Thereby, business representatives were
provided with an avenue to express their interests. Roland Mussard was appointed and
thereby, for the first time an economist entered the DG IVs bastion of legal staff. In an
interview, former Competition Commissioner Andriessen validated this move by arguing
that the previous administrations had operated in an ivory tower without understanding the
needs of business (Andriessen, 2006). To remedy the situation, Andriessen cooperated
intensively with business associations, such as UNICE and the EVV, as well as with the
legal community.30 Concomitantly, new guidelines were introduced for making the
enforcement of the rules more predictable for corporations.
In conclusion, in the early 1980s, the room for protectionist measures subsequently
narrowed, marking the end of an era characterised by an easygoing attitude towards
30
The speeches held by Commission officials at antitrust law conferences provide evidence. For example the
conference of the American Bar Association on 6 November in 1981, the International Antitrust Law
Conference in Oxford 16 September in 1983, and the Conference of the International Bar Association on 27
January in Brussels.
195
196
Chapter 5
Introduction
From the mid-1980s onwards, the ECs project of creating an ever-closer Union
consecrated by the Single European Act (SEA) took shape in an ever more self-confident
and more proactive manner. The neoliberal tenet promoted in the early 1980s, as a counter
project to embedded liberalism and to neomercantilist, protectionist ideas, increasingly
gained the discursive upper hand. Neoliberalism became the general articulating ideology
involving a wide-ranging array of concrete policy positions, which, in essence, promoted
the superiority of free market forces and competition-driven mechanisms above stateregulated social and economic organisation. Academia echoed the prevailing neoliberal
tenor. Academic pundits like Francis Fukuyama (1992) proclaimed The End of History, in
which the victory of liberal democracy and neoliberal economic principles were praised as
constituting the end point of mankinds ideological evolution and the final form of
human government (1992: xiii).31 In Europe, the deregulation of the market and the
removal of 300 non-tariff trade barriers (NTBs) were the central mechanisms put in place
to achieve the single market goal. Often, deregulation took shape as re-regulation at the
supranational level, as freer markets tend to require more rules (cf. Vogel, 1996). By
abolishing domestic market barriers, the SEA embodied a course of negative integration,
31
This triggered a range of academic bestsellers. Samuel P. Huntington announced that primary conflicts will
take place between civilisations rather than political ideologies, a statement which he further worked out in
his book The Clash of Civilizations and the Remaking of World Order (1996). In his view in the post-Cold
War world, the most important distinctions among peoples are not ideological, political, or economic, but
cultural (1996: 21). In Jihad vs. McWorld (1992), Benjamin R. Barber took a similar stance by prophesising
that despite the thwarting impact of Jihad symbolising Islamic and tribal fundamentalism, Western
democracy and liberal market capitalism will eventually endure as the prevailing forms of societal
organisation.
197
rather than positive integration in the form of a comprehensive formulation of marketcreating policies a trend had already started with the famous ruling of the ECJ in the
Cassis de Dijon case in 1979. The constructive moment of neoliberalism found its
expression in the accomplishment of the Maastricht Treaty of 1991 establishing the
European Union (EU). The enshrinement of the four freedoms of movement transformed
the EU in a businesspersons Europe. Neoliberal ideas served as the predominant
ideological framework, which led to the Economic and Monetary Union (EMU) decision
for a common currency, giving primacy to the economic doctrine of monetarism. The
European System of Central Banks (ESCB) pushed national central banking towards the
maintenance of price stability. The establishment of the European Central Bank (ECB) in
1998, the ESCBs core institution, enshrined the supremacy of monetarism in the form of
institutional independence, which reached an extent unparalleled to that of any other
central bank. The Convergence Criteria of the Maastricht Treaty put a tight straitjacket on
Member States fiscal policies, which rendered Keynesian-orientated macroeconomic
steering of aggregate demand and full employment a precarious endeavour.
One of the key agenda setters for the SEA was the corporate elite organised in the
European Round Table of Industrialists (ERT). In a series of reports, reform proposals,
position papers, and newspaper interviews, it voiced its discontent with EC institutions and
their failure to keep pace with the liberalisation which has transformed the global
economy over the past 10 years (Maucher in: FT, 1996f: 16). The Commission was utterly
receptive to the ERTs initiatives. Boosted by deepening integration and confident in
making use of its powers, the Commission surfaced as a major protagonist in orchestrating
the neoliberal organisation of the common market. The salience of the Commission as a
pivotal political actor grew with the increase of its workload. As the guardian of the
treaties, it kept close track of the progress of the single market project and did not shy
away from reproaching national governments for their lax implementation of EU rules. It
proclaimed that the common market should become synonymous with rationalised
production and stronger competition (European Commission, 1988: 14).
The political momentum of the SEA, and the creation of the EU, spurred the salience of
competition law enforcement as a mechanism to dismantling intra-European market
barriers. As a commentator remarked competition policy is an idea whose time has come
(Jenny, 1998: 8). Neoliberal reasoning expanded in EC competition law enforcement. The
198
This chapter analyses in two parts the enforcement of competition law in the ascendancy of
neoliberal ideas. It identifies and explains the political motives of the driving interest
constellation that supported a neoliberal approach in competition control and traces the
political struggle with opposing forces. The first part addresses developments after the
SEA in 1985, and the second part after the Maastricht Treaty in 1993.
Part I: From 1985 Onwards Neoliberal Wind in the Sails of European Integration
Under Jacques Delors, president of the Commission twice in the years 1985-1988 and
1989-1995, the idea of an ever closer union received new impetus. With the
Commissions White Paper to the European Council on Completion of the Internal Market
of 14 June 1985, European integration was put back on track. It declared the ambitious
goal of finalising the single market by 1992. The subsequent adoption of the Single
European Act (SEA) in 1986 renewed constitutional status to the economic foundation of
the Rome Treaty. Whereas the SEA was biased towards an overall trend of less state at all
levels (Van Apeldoorn, 2002: 81), rather than a laissez-faire attitude towards the freemarket mechanisms, the Commission adopted an activist, and interventionist role in the
field of competition policy ambitiously fighting market-distorting behaviour, both in the
private and public realm. Neoliberal in nature, competition policy was subordinated to the
sole purpose of re-establishing competition as a major regulatory instrument to warrant a
genuinely free-market economy. The incumbency of two committed free-marketeers from
199
the Anglo-Saxon Member States, Ireland and the UK in the DG IV, Peter Sutherland
(1984-1989) and Sir Leon Brittan (1989-1992), was crucial in this regard. Margaret
Thatcher, who was keen to influence the allocation of British Commissioners to portfolios
closest to her heart, sent off her cabinet minister Sir Leon Brittan, who was located at the
neoliberal wing of the Conservative Party. Under the sheer evangelism of Sutherland and
Brittan (Wilks and McGowan, 1996: 164), the Commission was self-assured in making use
of its powers. Regulation 17 was applied to its full potential against agreements that
hampered European integration. Under the new Anglo-Saxon Commissioners, the DG IV
engaged in the fierce prosecution of cartels. The previously dormant prohibition of state
aid and the prohibition of the abuse of a dominant position were implemented with
enhanced vigour. Similarly, for the first time, the Commission made use of the possibility
to issue directions demanding the privatisation of national monopolies. Moreover, with the
adoption of the Merger Regulation in 1989, the Commission acquired a new instrument to
intervene in the common market structure. Overall, the Commissions activism led to more
than 8,000 decisions a year in the early 1990s (FT, 1992f: 15).
Anecdotal evidence suggests that his fellow Commissioners ascribed Sutherlands pugnacious negotiation
style to the fact that he was a committed rugby player who had broken his nose several times. His tactics
were similar to running a rugby game: opening the game aggressively to shock and exhaust opponents in
order to tie them in a more strategic approach later (FT, Dawkins, 1987a: 18).
200
take the form of straightforward grants and tax reductions, soft loans, equity participations
or public procurement guarantees.
Under Competition Commissioner Sutherland, the toleration of state aid was declared
incompatible with the single market and perceived as a Member State trade barrier that
distorted competition more than before and ran counter to the objectives for 1992 (ibid,
1988: 15). By specifying the conditions for state aid, the Commission narrowed the leeway
for public market interventions, and thereby acquired an enhanced grip on the course of the
Member States national industrial policies. The Commissions shift from a permissive to a
prohibitive stance did not comprise state aid in all industries equally. For example, in the
shipbuilding industry, state aid schemes were developed that would eventually phase out
government subsidies in the long run. As the industry faced fierce competition from
cheaper imports from Japan and South Korea, whose governments also subsidised their
shipyards, the restructuring of the sector was made conditional on the adoption of a fairer
pricing policy of Japan and Korea (FT, 1989b). The Commission thereby delayed the
reduction and eventual elimination of state aid in the shipbuilding sector until other
countries stopped subsidising the sector. Whereas the shipbuilding sector was spared from
having to compete more vigorously, the aviation sector underwent a stricter approach. The
Commission scrutinised the bilateral cooperation agreements between different airline
companies and in 1986 and 1987 charged as many as thirteen airlines of anticompetitive
conduct, a measure that indirectly also addressed government subsidy of national airlines
(Dimitrakopoulos, 2004: 114).
201
steadily declined after it had reached a peak in 1982 (European Commission, 1987: 17-18).
When Commissioner Sir Leon Brittan, who later became Lord Brittan of Spennithorne,
succeeded Commissioner Sutherland, the vigorous prosecution of state aid continued with
even more scrutiny (cf. Smith, 1998; Cini, 2001). Similarly to Sutherland, Brittan came
from a Member State (the UK), which had already privatised national monopolies in the
early 1980s. Under his tenure, the French and British car manufacturers Renault and Rover
even had to pay back their national subsidies to their governments.
In addition to state aid, the Commission also started to tackle state monopolies under
Article 82 (TEC) prohibiting the abuse of market dominance. The DG IV endorsed
directives under Article 86(3) (TEC), a hitherto virtually unused law, which allowed the
Commission to issue directives in the field of public enterprises and state monopolies
without the approval of the Council of Ministers. By means of so-called privatisation
directives in the utility sectors, such as telecommunication networks, the aviation sector,
rail transport, postal services, electricity, natural gas and water, the Commission entered a
field, which used to be the prerequisite of the Member States (Pollack, 1998: 230-1;
Nugent et al., 2001: 251). Commissioner Sutherland fully realised that this was as close as
you can get to touching the nerve of national sovereignty (FT, 1987a: 18). The
Commission defended the view that state monopolies, similar to state aid, rendered whole
industrial sectors inefficient (ibid). By the application of Article 90, the Commission
steadfastly opened up previously closed sectors to competition. In order to sell the new
strategy to the Member States and their constituencies, the Commission published
estimates on the link between privatisation, generally referred to as liberalisation, and the
creation of new jobs. In the telecommunication sector alone, up to 500,000 new jobs were
expected by 2000, rising to 1.3 million by 2005 (Van Miert, 1998c: 4). However, while the
privatisation of the telecommunication sector proceeded rapidly, in sectors that were more
sensitive, such as electricity, the Commission was less successful. Here, enduring Member
State opposition slowed down the privatisation efforts.
202
formal decision (European Commission, 1987: 15). The fines imposed on those breaching
EC competition laws reached previously unparalleled levels. For example, a price-fixing
and market-sharing cartel involving 15 chemical companies was fined 60 million ecu in
1986 (ibid). Moreover, the era of structural crisis cartels was over. Exemptions to
commercial intercompany agreements were only given if there was strong evidence that
the agreement furthered technical progress and benefited economic integration across
borders. This implied that exemptions were confined to intercompany cooperation in the
field of R&D, the transfer of technologies, and innovation. Similarly, franchising
agreements received the Commissions straightforward permission, as they were
considered market making by nature, rather than market distorting. In particular,
distribution networks were considered of great importance for the further integration of the
common market (ibid). In 1983, the Commission permitted more than 83,000 cross-border
franchising agreements (cf. European Commission, 1988). In order to exclude franchising
contracts categorically from the obligation of notification, a block exemption regulation
was adopted in 1988, blacklisting and whitelisting certain categories of franchising (ibid).
The Commission applied a comparable rationale in the block exemption regulation with
regard to joint ventures between companies that control less than 25% of a product market.
Thereby, smaller competitors would be able to grow bigger. The Commission wanted to
encourage cross-border joint ventures (The Economist, 1987: 65). This policy was
exemplified in a joint manufacturing company set up by AEI and Reyroll Parson, which,
despite its monopolistic position, received exemption in 1988, based on the Commissions
arguments that its product innovations would benefit consumers (Carchedi, 2001: 128).
203
situations only after they were created. With pan-European merger control, it could now
intervene beforehand to prevent companies from building up dominant position by means
of mergers.
Shortly after the adoption of the SEA, cross-border mergers with a Community-dimension
became more frequent and geographically more extensive, involving heavy stock market
activity. Viewed over time there were: 115 European cross-border mergers in 1982-83, 208
in 1984-85, 498 in 1988-89, and 622 in 1989-90 (Tsoukalis, 1993: 103). In West Germany
alone, the number of mergers amounted to 802 in 1986. Although most of the mergers
notified at the Bundeskartellamt in 1985 and 1986 concerned acquisitions of small and
medium-sized enterprises, the biggest merger ever in the German history so far occurred in
this period, i.e. the merger between Daimler-Benz and AEG (FT, Hermann, 1987: 8).
Enhanced economic concentration and a temporary decline in US economic power, partly
due to the stock market collapse in 1987, brought a comparative advantage to European
companies vis--vis their US competitors (Freyer, 2006: 290).
The Commission took the enhanced merger activity and the adoption of the SEA as an
occasion to relaunch the merger control regulation once more. In 1988, Peter Sutherland
revised the much-cherished proposal of 1973 into a fully-fledged Merger Control
Regulation. The draft proposal would have transferred exclusive competences to the
Commission to control all mergers above a dual turnover threshold: 1) the combined
annual turnover of the two companies must exceed ecu 1 billion; 2) the turnover of the
smaller of the two companies must exceed ecu 50 million. Only concentrations with more
than 75% of their combined sales in a single member state would be excluded from the
Commission power and fall under the control of the national competition authority.
Moreover, similarly to Regulation 17, it included a notification regime for mergers. After
reviewing the notification, the Commission could accept the merger, prohibit it, or impose
conditions, such as the divestiture of specific assets. Similarly to the previous attempts at a
pan-European merger control, Sutherlands proposal also faced considerable opposition
from both the business community and the Member State governments. The solid coalition
between the corporate interests represented in the ERT, UNICE and the Commission
explains why the Council adopted the Merger Regulation No. 4064/89 on 21 December
1989. Competition Commissioner Brittan celebrated the occasion as 'a historic
breakthrough in the creation of a single market' (FT, 1989c).
204
As the adoption of the Regulation required unanimity by the Council, each Member State
could insist on its own amendments. Commissioner Sutherland warned the Council that if
it did not come up with adequate agreement by the autumn, the Commission would
simply start to review mergers under existing competition law (Dawkins, 1987b: 2). To
demonstrate the seriousness of his warning, the Commission started to investigate the
planned merger between Fiat and Alfa Romeo, and applied Article 81 to the Philip Morris
case (ibid). The appeal by Philip Morris at the ECJ became an important landmark case. In
1987, the ECJ ruled that Article 81, prohibiting cartels and other anticompetitive business
practices, could also apply to agreements between two or more companies that allowed
one of the companies to obtain legal or de facto control over the other. With this proactive
ruling, the ECJ provided the Commission with a backdoor route to deal with mergers
(Pollack, 1998: 233-234). The Commission started to apply Article 81 to a range of high
profile mergers such as the takeover of British Caledonian by British Airways and banned
the takeover of Irish Distillers by GC and C Brands (Gillingham, 2003: 251). This move
caused a climate of legal uncertainty for companies with intentions to merge and
companies voluntarily started to notify their planned mergers to the Commission.
205
Both the ERT and UNICE were closely involved in the drafting of a new version of the
regulation. The ERT started to press for the creation of a level-playing field that
committed companies to one merger regime only, a metaphor borrowed from the language
of team sports, which entered the Eurojargon in the late 1980s. It became synonymous with
the creation of free play for market forces unhindered by public authorities. This resulted
in the inclusion of a one-stop-shop rule for mergers, implying that once the Commission
opens up a case, no other Member State authority could intervene. Moreover, it implied
that the companies involved did not have to notify to any of the EC or EEA jurisdictions
any more. The one-stop-shop rule created the desired legal certainty, and henceforth, a
significant reduction in the negative externalities that came forth from the multijurisdictional overlap that emerges with merger notifications to five or six different
competition authorities of EC Member States. In a declaration, UNICE further emphasised
that merger control should be exercised on the basis of pre-defined, objective, economic
and legal criteria that genuinely facilitate cross-border mergers within the common market
(European Commission, 1988: 25). In response to business concerns, a tight timetable was
imposed on the Commission. The investigation phase should take no longer than one
month, after which it could ban or clear a merger (phase one), or then decide to assess the
situation with greater scrutiny for another four months, after which time it had to come up
with a final verdict (phase two). Compared to the 1973 proposal, where the Commission
envisaged an investigation time of a year, the new Regulation catered to the business
community with wished-for speedy procedures.
In order to generate the necessary leverage power, the Commission also sought intensive
contacts with the national business associations to assure their support (European
Commission, 1988: 26). It contacted the Conseil National du Patronat Franais (CNPF),
the representatives of the West Germany industry, the Bundesverband der Industrie (BDI)
and the Confederation of British Industry (CBI) (ibid). In addition, the Commission asked
the legal community to review and comment on the draft proposal. Most notably, the
involvement of the Consultative Committee of the Bars and Law Societies (CCBE) was
crucial in the preparatory phase (ibid). Of the 120 responses to the Commissions Green
Paper that were made public on its website, the legal community was far more active in
submitting its opinion than individual companies and business associations. When the
Council negotiations started, European industry representatives started to feel bypassed
and feared that the Ministers were moving the proposal into a direction that it would not
206
agree with. Eventually, the national and transnational business organisations lobbied
intensively, at national level, in favour of the introduction of pan-European merger rules
(Pollack, 1998: 232). For example, the CBI feared that the Council would eventually settle
on a watery text, which failed to include the one-stop shop for companies contemplating
significant cross-border acquisitions or mergers. It urged the Member Governments to stick
to the Commissions original proposal (Directorate General in the CBI in: FT, 1989e).
German business associations also started a lobbying campaign, at government level, in
favour of the new regulation and the one-stop-shop principle, as they could thereby escape
the vigilance of the Bundeskartellamt. More generally, the pro-free market Financial Times
strongly favoured the introduction of the Merger Regulation. The positions of the FT and
Sir Leon Brittan hardly differed: this can be ascribed to the fact that Sir Leons influential
brother, Sir Samuel, worked as an economics commentator at this influential newspaper
(Gillingham, 2003: 252).33
In the end, both the Commission and the business community had to make concessions.
The draft regulation went through several changes in order to accommodate the 12
Member States. The German and British governments, in particular, both of countries with
established antitrust authorities, consistently opposed the expansion of the Commissions
powers. In contrast, the Belgium government, which enjoyed much less power to control
mergers, strongly favoured the Commission having a larger say in the merger area. The
turnover thresholds that required the Commissions involvement caused a major point of
disagreement. The Council adopted the regulation only after these thresholds were raised
considerably. Yet opinions diverged extensively. While the UK and Germany wanted to
raise the turnover threshold to ten billion ecu, Belgium favoured a threshold less than two
billion ecu (Kellaway, 1989). The final Merger Regulation stipulated that the Commission
had exclusive competence over deals involving companies with a combined worldwide
turnover of what today is equivalent to 5 billion, or then each with more than 250
million in sales in Europe, unless they each realised more than two thirds of their European
turnover in one and the same country (Article 1). The Member States would handle all
mergers below this turnover threshold. In an interview with the Financial Times, Wolfgang
Kartte, the president of the Bundeskartellamt and adherent of ordoliberal ideas, explained
that the German government only eventually agreed with the regulation because it was
The Financial Times celebrated Sutherlands and Brittans success in transforming competition policy into
a positive force for creating and policing the emerging single market and portrayed the previous DG IV as
dry legal theory not grounded in market realities (FT, 1992d: 22).
33
207
convinced that the number of cases for the EC Commission would be kept within
reasonable limits. Yet, the Bundeskartellamt was overtly concerned that the Commission
would gain too much power in the merger field. However, it thought it unrealistic that the
Commission would become a leading competition authority in merger control, due to the
constraints of personnel at the Commissions DG IV. At that time, the Bundeskartellamt
employed 230 people, which is about twice as many as the DG IV (FT, Fisher, 1989: 3).
Furthermore, in the perception of ordoliberals at the German Bundeskartellamt, the DG IV
suffered, in critical cases, from the high politicisation of merger control and lacked
political independence. Whether or not a merger was considered to lead to a dominant
market position was not decided by the DG IV, but by the College of Commissioners, and
all 17 Commissioners could exert political influence in their vote (Kartte, 1990 in: Wilks
and McGowan: 265). Due to German intervention, a so-called German clause came to be
included in Article 9 of the Regulation, which provided national competition authorities
with the right to ask permission to intervene in a Community-level merger that fell under
the exclusive competences of the Commission. The German authorities reminded the
Commission of the principle of subsidiarity to guide the competence allocation (Wilks and
McGowan, 1995: 266). Although the word subsidiarity was not mentioned, the German
delegates succeeded to include their postulation. In hindsight, the Commission was
reluctant to give away its newly acquired powers and rejected four of the first five requests
of the Bundeskartellamt right away, i.e. in the merger of Varta-Bosch, Siemens-Phillips,
Alcatel-AEG, and Mannesmann-Hoesch (ibid), which it sought to block, although without
success.
The Member States were split into two camps in the discussion centred on the inclusion of
strict competition criteria for the assessment versus industrial and social concerns. While
the British and the German government favoured strictly competition-oriented criteria in
the assessment of mergers, the French urged the inclusion of social and industrial policies.
The final version resembled more the British and German position, which laid emphasis on
the strict application of competition rules. However, French opposition managed to build in
a loophole. Article 2(1) stipulates that the Commission can also balance its decisions
against the development of technical and economic progress provided that it is to
consumers' advantage and does not form an obstacle to competition. Nonetheless, the
central measure of the Merger Regulation was the dominance test enshrined in Article
2(2). Accordingly, the yardstick for prohibition was formed by whether or not the
208
209
The geographical scope of EC competition rules expanded substantially with the fourth
enlargement of Austria, Finland, and Sweden, and the creation of the European Economic
Area (EEA) with Norway, Iceland, and Liechtenstein in 1992. Moreover, in response to
heightened prominence of cross-border competition cases and the resulting complaints by
TNCs on the heightened transaction costs, the Commission engaged in a series of bilateral
agreements with competition agencies from non-EU states, of which the transatlantic
cooperation agreements evolved into the most far-reaching of all (see Chapter 6). In the
spirit of optimism of the 1990s, the Commission evolved as a powerful pro-market
orientated force on a global scale. Commission embarked on its most ambitious endeavour:
crafting a common understanding of the competition principles around the world, by
establishing a multilateral competition agreement in the WTO setting as a means to break
down barriers that affect cross-border trade (see Chapter 7). As the next section
demonstrates, all these developments are inherently linked to the competition for
competitiveness discourse that is in the interests of the corporate elite in charge of
transnational corporations.
210
institutional features, it considered Europe not attractive enough to attract foreign direct
investment flows. It argued that profit margins and the return on capital were 40% lower in
Europe compared to Japan and the US (FT, 1995c: 3). The ERT identified high tax levels,
high social costs on industry, and high energy costs as reasons for this difference. Whereas
European tax levels of 46% of GDP were argued to compare to 31% in the US and 34% in
Japan and energy costs to be 30% higher, social costs on industry stemming from the
contracts between social partners and from environmental legislation were declared
exorbitant (FT, 1994b: 2). The ERTs criticism sometimes went even a step further and
addressed the European attitude in its totality.34
The ERT discursively linked the imperative of generating higher economic growth,
prosperity, and competitiveness, with EU competition policy. It declared that unfettered
competition was the backbone of spurring economic growth. It suggested a whole string of
neoliberal measures, such as a broad-based deregulation of the market for goods, services,
and capital flexibility, improved education and training, as well as the rolling back of the
public sector and its entrenched bureaucracy (Maucher in: FT, 1996f: 16). It pushed for
the
liberalisation
and
privatisation
of
allegedly
high-cost
national
energy,
34
The ERT complained about the social attitudes of the European management model, which it saw as losing
out in terms of flexibility and economic effectiveness. Nestl Chairman Helmut Maucher declared the
mentality of Europe to be one of a dying society and dominated by hedonism, narcissism and the
unwillingness to take risks (in FT, 1996f: 16). In the centre of the ERTs criticism were, in particular, the
lack of a vigorous risk-taking attitude originating from a tradition of semi-regulated markets, the lack of a
teamwork culture, and a worldview that seeks to adapt to every new country and culture with a tailor-made
treatment (Bloom et al., 1994).
211
targets that allowed for a regular assessment of European competitiveness against that of
the US and Japan (cf. ERT, 1996a).
The ERT pushed for the reformation of competition law procedures and principles. It in
particular suggested to the Commission to be a priori more ready to define the world
market as the relevant geographical market when assessing mergers and to examine
barriers to entry from a worldwide perspective (ERT, 2000). Moreover, it suggested
interpreting competition in a way that is more in line with economic analysis, including a
more economics-based assessment and the adoption of new economic concepts, such as
the theory of contestable markets and efficiency considerations (Jenny, 2000: 21). In other
words, the transnational business elite of the ERT envisaged a Darwinian logic of the
survival of the fittest, building on a notion of market justice according to which
anticompetitive practices were considered unfair to others. Eventually, the number of
those winning from the removal of private market barriers and enhanced exposure to
market competition was expected to offset the damage suffered by those losing from it. A
range of Commission officials embodied this fierce neoliberal tone of the transnational
corporate elite and suggested major reforms. Competition Commissioners Brittan and his
predecessor Sutherland are cases in point. Under their tenures, the DG Competition, and its
Merger Task Force (MTF) in particular, held an open-door policy towards business
representatives. It strongly encouraged companies and their legal advisors to discuss their
proposals 'early and often' (FT, 1992c: 10). According to a study by Neven et al. (1998) on
the contact between company representatives and Commission officials, only a small share
(13%) proceeded by written or phone contact (Neven et al., 1998: 137). The vast majority
met with high-level staff, i.e. the Head of the Unit (78,4%) and the Director (55.4%) of the
different units within DG Competition (ibid: 138). In fact the larger the company, the more
high-level the contact was. In the run up to formal decisions in competition cases, personto-person contact became more frequent (ibid: 137-8). In addition to regular case-by-case
contact, the elite network of the ERT also succeeded in influencing the course of EU
competition policy more generally.
212
I very much believe in competition, but not as a religion. You must observe a proper
balance. [] You can't just look at your competition textbook and say: That has to be No,
and that's it.
Karel van Miert, Former Competition Commissioner (FT, 1993: 29)
213
Bundeskartellamt had a stark interest in reviving the more moderate liberal approach of the
German ordoliberal tradition at the DG IV. Bangemann, lawyer by origin and former
German Economics Minister (1984-1988), as well as Member of the European Parliament
(MEP) from 1973 to 1984, sympathised with ordoliberal ideas and an active European
industrial policy (cf. FT, 1992a). The endeavours to reinstall a German at DG IV failed
and the Council appointed Thatcherite Brittan to the post. Bangemann became
Commissioner for Industry and Internal Market from 1989 to 1999. Commissioner Brittan
subsequently replaced the remaining ordoliberal top-grade competition officials from
Germany with disciples of the neoliberal ideology. For example, Manfred Caspari started
his career in DG IV as Chef de Cabinet under Commissioner Hans von der Grben in
1963. After a few other high-ranging posts in the DG Internal Market, he became Director
General of Competition in 1981. When he had to leave the Commission in 1989, the
leading international newspaper The Financial Times reporting on this change of
personnel, wrote that the private fiefdom of Germany had came to an end (FT, 1989d).
The views of Brittan and his new staff at the DG IV clashed on a regular basis with the DG
III of Industrial Policy. In an interview in The Financial Times, Bangemann said that he
was very angry about academics in the DG IV, mostly lawyers by profession, who have no
idea of the reality of economic life (FT, 1992a). Also officials from the Regional Policy
DG regularly complained about the views held by competition officials (cf. Menon and
Hayward, 1996; Wishlade, 1993). The neoliberal hardliners were nicknamed ayatollahs
or gurus, as a way to refer to their arrogance and unshakable faith in their beliefs in the
rationality of the market (Guerrera, 2002b).
At the end of Commissioner Brittans tenure in December 1992, the French, Italian, and
Spanish governments lobbied in favour of reshuffling the competition portfolio. What
these governments had in common was a total reluctance to liberalise national monopolies
in sensitive sectors, such as energy and telecommunication services and infrastructures. In
France, above all, neoliberal ideas did not nestle easily. In the French tradition of tatisme
and dirigisme, political and corporate elites revealed a deep mistrust towards the
functioning free-market mechanisms. With the view that there was nothing wrong with
hedging large nationalised industrial sectors, the French government refused to liberalise
its large state-owned sectors or to cut down on state aid to their national champions. In the
few privatisation projects undertaken in France until the early 1990s, the control of either
the state or state-controlled banks endured (FT, 1993g: 58). This led to a highly tense
214
relationship between the French government and the DG Competition under the leadership
of the Anglo-Saxon Commissioners Sutherland and Brittan. Consequently, the socialist
government of Francois Mitterrand urged the Council to appoint a Commissioner that was
more inclined to a French-style industrial approach. The request to change direction in the
field of competition control achieved heightened prominence with the French government
announcement to hold a referendum on the Maastricht Treaty in 1992, shortly after the
Danish No in the same year. Aware of the fact that a French Competition Commissioner
would probably face difficulties in generating sufficient political backing by the other
Member governments, such as those of the Anglo-Saxon countries and Germany, the
French government endorsed Karel van Miert as the appropriate candidate for the post.
Karel van Miert was a Flemish socialist and served as Commissioner of the DG Transport
and Environment Policy from 1989 to 1993. Member States cherished the hope that van
Miert would shelve the plans to liberalise the national monopolies in sectors such as
energy, telecommunication, and postal services. Publicly controlled and/or publicly owned
France Telecom, EDF, and Gaz de France, and also Air France therefore supported the
imposition of van Miert as Competition Commissioner (Van Miert, 2000: 48, 56).
Moreover, Van Mierts partisan roots, and his commitment to redirect EU competition law
enforcement towards more social and industrial policy objectives, rendered him a close
ally of President Delors, and hence, assured him of French support.
With the appointment of the Flemish Commissioner Karel van Miert to the competition
portfolio, counter-hegemonic forces to the neoliberal project temporarily thrived. Van
Miert rearticulated the long-standing ordoliberal discourse, which had prevailed for so
long at the DG Competition and which seemed to have vanished with the neoliberal
enforcement practice that started with the Commissioner Sutherland and Brittan. In an
interview, van Miert declared that from a philosophical point of view, he will choose for a
different attitude on how to cope with the rules (FT, 1993g: 12). Rather than a stringent
competition-only focus and efficient production as the sole guiding principle, he
announced that he would broaden the scope of competition policy in line with the
German ordoliberal approach and adjust competition policy to economic, political, social,
and environmental goals by looking at the whole picture (FT, 1993d: 1; 1993g: 12). He
underlined the ordoliberal view that competition laws served to safeguard a pluralistic
democracy, which could not survive a strong concentration of economic power (in Jebsen
and Stevens, 1996). He emphasised that a strong pro-market interventionist stance, rather
215
than less state intervention, was needed to enhance industrial competitiveness (in FT,
1993d: 1). The state should especially continue to play a role in big infrastructure
programmes where private investors do not want to invest (FT, 1994d: 2). Also in the
accession negotiations with the candidate Member States, Van Miert employed a more
moderate tone than his predecessors did. He steadfastly applied ordoliberal reasoning and
argued that talking the language of Erhard-style social market economy made it easier to
convince the candidate Member States of the value of having competition laws than the
language of the Chicago School (Van Miert, 1998d: 2). Nevertheless, over time, the oldstyle socialist as The Financial Times used to call van Miert started to adopt more
free-market oriented, neoliberal views. In his previous office, he had navigated EU
transport policy towards enhanced liberalisation and open competition, and thus,
demonstrated a willingness to tackle government-run industries. Enforcement records only
offer a partial picture and are not entirely conclusive as an indicator for the type of
reasoning applied in the enforcement of competition laws. However, when placed side by
side, the record of merger and state aid cases from van Mierts tenure in 1993 seems
equally stringent to that of Brittan in 1992: the ratios were 58:60 for mergers and 435:502
for state aid, respectively (FT, 1994e: 2).
The following section addresses the political conflicts underpinning the Commissions
stringency with which it enforced EU competition laws. It demonstrates how the interests
of the transnational corporate elite took shape and how their policy requests were gradually
implemented. For this purpose, it is necessary to understand the structural context that
transformed the common market situation and how these informed the interests of large
transnational corporations with regard to competition policy.
216
In the past, mergers were characterised by larger companies eating smaller ones. The late
1990s were rolled over by a wave of mergers of similar-sized companies, including
successful global players and touching on virtually every industry. This is generally
counted as the fifth big wave of mergers in history (cf. Carrol, 2002; Gaughan, 2002: 2356), and it exemplified significant transnational dimensions. Notable are the mega-mergers
between Vodafone and Airtouch-Mannesmann, and the AOL-Time Warner merger in 2000,
which concerned respective transactions of US$ 190 and 166 billion, which compares to
the GDP of a middle-sized industrial country like Portugal, with about US$ 120 billion
(Budzinski, 2002: 2). The (hostile) takeover of Mannesmann by Vodafone entered merger
history as the biggest merger ever. TNCs grew in number and displayed a high degree of
economic power concentration. Today, the aggregate annual income of the largest TNCs
surpasses the level of GDP of most countries in the world. Although TNCs differ in many
respects, the sectors in which they operate are generally limited to the world economys
most dynamic sectors, including electronic products, chemicals, automobiles, drugs,
machinery and banking and telecommunications (Went, 2002: 100). More than 70% of all
M&As involved companies of the same industrial sector, i.e. horizontal mergers, but also
vertical concentrations involving companies along the production chain were also on the
217
increase (UNCTAD, 2000: 10). The food industry displayed a particular high level of
M&A activity, i.e. in with transnational corporations such as Unilever, Nestl or BSN
growing ever larger (Gillingham, 2003: 453). After the 2000 peak, concentration activity
slowed down slightly. Yet, levels of concentration activity stayed comparatively high. The
bursting of the dot.com bubble was held responsible for the slowdown. However, one is
tempted to argue that after the high tide of M&A activity, the takeover market did not
leave much to acquire. In addition to obvious concentration developments resulting from
M&As, various forms of commercial intercompany agreements and strategic alliances,
such as partnerships, joint ventures, business consortia and alike proliferated too (Goddard,
2003: 438). The degree of corporate enmeshment remains opaque. Most intercompany
agreements and intra-company trade lines are not public, and fall under the confidentiality
of the involved companies. Such forms of economic integration are more commonplace
than M&As and highly complex in nature. Furthermore, TNCs are marked by high rates of
intra-firm trade. Estimates suggest that the first couple of thousands of TNCs make up for
half of the total aggregate global trade flows, whereas one third is generally assumed to be
linked to intra-firm trade only (Vernon, 1998: 10).
218
euro. Whereas, in the early 1990s, most concentrations took place between countries with
a geographical or cultural proximity, i.e. between the UK and Ireland, the Scandinavian
countries, Germany and the Netherlands, Spain, Portugal, and France, or France, Belgium
and Germany (Martinez Torre-Enciso and Bilbao Garcia, 1996), with the introduction of
the euro and enhanced market integration, this played less of a role. Another development,
which should not be underestimated, is the fact that competition in the common market
increased, which forced many industries to restructure their production and seek synergy
effects, such as economies of scale and scope, through mergers. On top of that, the
phenomenon of intensified concentration activity in the form of merger waves often
triggers a self-perpetuating mechanism: the more economic power becomes concentrated,
the more onerous it becomes for smaller competitors to keep up, and the more the option
of a merger becomes the only viable solution left for corporate survival. Jumping on the
merger bandwagon can become a necessity to avoid so-called fire sales, i.e. cheap
acquisitions of companies in dire straights. Moreover, in the climate of merger waves,
CEOs also try increasingly daring and complex transaction combinations (Draghi, 2003:
10-11). Shockwaves created by enhanced concentrations may eventually result in the
oligopolisation or monopolisation of market power at the expense of competition and
market diversity.
With the increase of cross-border merger activity in Europe, similarly to the 1960s, the
share of mergers revealing a transatlantic dimension was significant. In the race for market
dominance, US companies tried to get a foothold in the common market not only by
mergers and acquisitions, but also by the conclusion of different forms of cooperative
intercompany arrangements, such as alliances, joint ventures, distribution and supplier
agreements, cross licensing of intellectual property, and franchising. As illustrated in
previous chapters, since the 1960s the influx of US companies into European markets had
constituted an ongoing phenomenon. However, with the rapid pace of European
integration in the early 1990s, the expansion of US corporations into Europe achieved new
dimensions. In 1990, US investment in Europe accounted for half the total earnings of US
companies, which held assets of more than US$ 175 billion in Europe close to half the
total of US overseas foreign direct investment at that time (The Economist, 1990: 23). In
1994, more than a third of all mergers involved a company from across the Atlantic (36%
and US$ 21.8 in value) (Martinez Torre-Enciso and Bilbao Garcia, 1996: 7). Of the 1950
notifications of large transnational mergers reviewed by the Commission during the period
219
from 1990 to 2002, 435 transactions involved at least one US company (Schaub, 2002b:
3). In 1999, for the first time, the number of concentrations in the EU exceeded that in the
US, which indicated that large-scale M&A activity was no longer confined to the US
market only. Moreover, the increased number of merger cases at the Commissions desk
prompted a revitalised judicial activism, which contributed to the complexity and the
subsequent refinement of the merger control procedure.
The fundamental changes in the corporate governance regimes and enhanced stock market
activity since the 1980s constitute another important aspect in the emergence of the 1990s
merger wave (cf. Holmstrom and Kaplan, 2001). The progressive importance of stock
market capitalisation as means for corporate finance in addition to, or instead of,
traditional bank loans, facilitated a growing market of corporate control. Companies
were bought and sold like other commodities, epitomising the commodification of
corporate control (cf. Hpner and Jackson, 2001; Horn, 2004). Mergers and acquisitions
provided a welcome opportunity to fast track such market consolidation and control
tangible and intangible assets. Monetary indicators, such as shareholder value
maximisation, surplus value, and after tax yields became primary corporate objectives and
takeover decisions became ever more disciplined by the influence of capital markets (cf.
Ltz, 2000). The increased presence of hedge funds and private equity funds further
enhanced the primacy of shareholders in both concentration and deconcentration
activities. In this regard, it is worth mentioning that the use of M&As for generating rapid
liquidity did not lead to the anticipated positive results in terms of real economic effects
such as profits and productivity (UNCTAD, 2000: 12).
Traditionally, the strong shareholder value culture of the Anglo-Saxon world involved
higher levels of M&A activity. On the Continent, especially in coordinated market
economies, such as Germany, hostile takeover bids used to be relatively seldom. More
protective corporate government regimes account for this, such as large block holders and
relatively limited rights for minority shareholders, as well as lower rates of return (cf.
Hassel and Beyer, 2001). Moreover, in a system in which Hausbanken form stable sources
of long-term funds for industries, the market for corporate control tends to be much
weaker. What used to be a prerequisite of the Anglo-Saxon variety of capitalism,
however, increasingly transferred to the coordinated market economies of the Continent.
Financial investment institutions seeking short-term capital gains in the equity market
220
were increasingly involved in leveraged buyouts and predatory bidding for shares. Today
M&A activity strongly correlates with booming stock markets, with the bulk of it taking
place against the background of raising stock prices signalling higher than normal profits
(Mueller, 1997: 664). This picture is confirmed by UNCTAD statistics: in the time
between 1980 to 1999 less than 3% of the total number of cross-border M&As can be
classified as true mergers, if defined in terms of a mutual consent of executive directors.
The vast majority of transactions were acquisitions, either by purchasing the majority of
shares or assets of a corporation. A third of all acquisitions in this time period were full
acquisitions (UNCTAD, 2000: 10). Minority acquisition accounted for a fifth in
developed and a third in developing countries. In 5% of the total value of M&A activity,
the acquisitions were of a hostile nature (ibid), i.e. shareholders acquiring the stocks of a
company against the wish of company boards.
The bulk of takeover activity in Europe was concentrated in the UK and displayed a strong
transatlantic dimension. In 1994, a third of all merger activity in Europe involved British
companies: it concerned 854 of a total of 2,933 deals with a corresponding volume of US$
32.3 billion of a total of US$ 103,8 billion (Martinez Torre-Enciso and Bilbao Garcia,
1996: 281; Ietto-Gillies et al., 2000). The strong presence of US financial investors in the
City provided not only the necessary mobile capital, but also introduced new financial
products for lending, leasing, hedging and stripping (Gillingham, 2003: 453-454). The
assets of US companies in the UK alone equal that invested in Asian, Latin American, and
Middle Eastern countries combined. The corporate governance regime of the UK rendered
companies much more vulnerable to predatory takeovers, creating a situation in which
British companies ended up being taken-over by foreign capital, while they themselves
could not easily expand elsewhere in Europe. As rumour has it, alongside entrenched lack
of sympathy, particularly the aggressive takeovers by French nationalised companies
proved especially irritating to the British (FT, 1991b: 14).
221
mergers a year. There were 72 cases in 1997, and by 1999, the number had reached almost
300. Enforcement statistics reveal that the Commission was overtly permissive towards
market concentration and predisposed towards the expansionary interests of large market
players. From 1990 to 1992, the Commission hardly ever came across an anticompetitive
merger. Of the 136 notifications that were filed at the Commissions Merger Task Force,
more than 100 planned mergers were permitted after one month of investigation (phase
one). Ten of the notified mergers underwent a more detailed four month lasting
investigation (phase two). Eventually, two were permitted, six permitted after concessions
were made to modify the proposal, while the other cases were withdrawn during the
process. In 1994, the Commission only scrutinised six mergers in detail from a total
number of 95. When assessing the enforcement practice over a longer period, the approach
remained lenient. Of the 3558 merger cases that the Commission decided upon in the time
from 21 September 1990 to 31 December 2007 (excluding the 110 merger that have
withdrawn in both phase one and phase two), only 20 have been prohibited (European
Commission, 2007). More than 95% of all merges were directly approved, and of the 5%
of the cases that required further investigation, only 1% were eventually prohibited (ibid).
More than 90% of the cases were settled within one month after notification (see also
Resch, 2005: 19).
Neither the neoliberal Commissioner Brittan, nor the old-style socialist Commissioner
van Miert problematised the concentration of economic power through mergers and
acquisitions. Brittan held the view that competition policy should be devoted to consumer
interests only a view that he disseminated in more than 400 speeches delivered during his
four years in office (Gillingham, 2003: 252). In his opinion, as long as a merger was
beneficial to consumers (in terms of expected lower prices), there was no reason to block
it. Similarly, van Miert was firmly convinced that the EU had to accept the trend for more
mergers (Van Miert, 1999). In fact, when comparing the DG Competitions decision
records under Brittan and Van Miert, there were roughly as many positive and negative
decisions under both Commissioners (FT, 1994e: 2).
The Commission was generally highly receptive to the interests of CEOs and chairpersons
of large transnational corporations. Eventually, they preferred a ruling by the Commission
over that of national competition authorities, as it provided a convenient escape from a
more stringent Member State jurisdiction. According to a company lawyer from Allen &
222
Overy's Brussels' office, many lawyers tried to present so-called borderline mergers in a
way that the deal would pass the required turnover threshold needed for a Commission
ruling (FT, 1993i: 15).35 The business community in particular welcomed the fast and
efficient clearance procedures of the Commission. The maxim speed is our friend time
is our enemy was best matched with the centralised merger control regime. The
Commission took most of its decisions within one month (Phase 1). According to a study
conducted by the Centre for Economic Policy Research (CEPR) called Merger in
Daylight, business preferred the Commissions quick procedures, and its flexibility and
willingness to accommodate, as most national competition regimes were under no
obligation to stick to clear deadlines. Similarly, corporate lawyers preferred the
Commission, as it published reasoned decisions, which provided some guidance with
regard to the scope of what counted as anticompetitive and what not.
In line with requests of transnational business, the Commission sought to facilitate crossborder mergers. In a review on the success of the Merger Regulation in 1993, it
suggested lowering turnover thresholds that determine the Commissions responsibility on
cross-border mergers (FT, 1993c: 3). The Commission adopted a similar strategy to that of
the introduction of the Merger Regulation in order to convince the Council of its
endeavour (see Part 1 of this Chapter). It consulted almost 300 companies and a range of
EC industry associations, such as the ERT, UNICE, and national business organisations to
gain political support (ibid). Consumer organisations and labour unions did not voice their
opinion. The response was wholly enthusiastic. The German BDI particularly supported
the idea. In this manner, corporations could evade the firm rulings of the
Bundeskartellamt, which, in a survey, had been rated as the toughest domestic policeman
in terms of merger decisions (Neven et al., 1993b). Ironically, the Commissions DG
Competition anticipated that it would be tougher than the competition authorities of the
Member States (The Economist, 1997: 25).
National governments and competition authorities, however, fiercely opposed ceding more
powers to the Commission in merger control. The well-established competition authorities
of Germany, the UK, and France announced that their Member Governments would vote
against Commission proposals that aimed at lowering turnover thresholds by referring to
35
Several other sources confirm the picture that the number of borderline cases was high (The Economist,
1993: 124). The actual number is unknown though, as talks that adjust so-called borderline cases to a ruling
by the Commission took place behind closed doors.
223
the subsidiarity principle (FT, 1993b: 2). The German Bundeskartellamt, the stronghold of
ordoliberals in competition matters, fiercely criticised the Commissions soft on mergers
approach (FT, 1995a: 14). In the past, it had attempted to retrieve merger cases of national
significance from the Commissions authority, although without much success. The
Commission largely ignored what came to be termed the German clause in the Merger
Regulation (see Chapter 4). Nevertheless, it repeatedly sought to revive the issue of
lowering turnover thresholds for a Community ruling. Only three years later, in 1995,
Competition Commissioner Karel van Miert picked up the subject again in the
Commission's Annual Report on Competition Policy. In response to corporate pressure,
the Commission issued a Green Paper on the review of the Merger Regulation in January
1996, proposing to lower the turnover thresholds to ecu 2 billion for mergers on a
worldwide basis and 100 million for mergers involving at least two of those companies in
the Community (European Commission, 1996a). The Meger Regulation was eventually
reformed in 2004 (see Chapter 8).
The appointment of Commissioner van Miert to the competition portfolio received plaudits
from those sectors seeking protectionist measures and those penalised for anticompetitive
conduct by his predecessors. Van Miert warned the European business community: If you
think I'm a sort of anti-Sir Leon, forget it (FT, 1993l: 3). Nonetheless, he assured
protection to certain industries confronted with fierce outside competition. This concerned
mostly the car and electronics sector, which faced competition from Japan and Korea, and
224
Nonetheless, the industries confronted with enhanced (outside) competition and thus
seeking neomercantilist and protectionist policy measures were increasingly losing ground
to those holding more neoliberal conceptions of open competition. The examples of the
European car sector, the De Havilland merger, and the steel sector illustrate the high-level
politics involved in the exposure of previously protected sectors, or sectors dominated by
national champions, to enhanced competition.
225
The Commission was receptive to the demands of the car industry and adopted the Block
Exemption Regulation 1475/95, for a limited period, until the end of 1999. The idea was
that the car industry, in the meantime, would undertake restructuring measures to adjust to
a more competitive situation after the expiry date of the Regulation. What might give the
impression of a rather generous protectionists exemption regulation that postponed the
opening of the Community market to Japanese, Korean, and US car imports until the end
of the century, was a halfway house towards more open competition. The regulation
required car manufacturers to supply any dealer demanding a vehicle with a foreign
specification at local prices. In addition, independent service garages would have the right
to gain easier access to the manufacturers technical information. Thereby, the Commission
hoped to destroy one of Europes most restrictive market division regimes and to provide
unofficial traders with market access, giving them the possibility to undermine the prices
of the established networks of car manufacturers and dealers.
Opposition to the inclusion of this notion came from both manufacturers and distributors.
Car manufacturers had an interest in reduced inter-brand competition and did not want car
dealers to be engaged in multiple franchising contracts, selling more brands under the same
roof. Car distributors, who derived their commercial existence from exclusive contracts
with manufacturers were reluctant to cede their territorial monopolies to competitors and
give up their stable position. At the same time, the car distributors camp was not unified in
its stance, because becoming more independent from producers also offered new chances.
Exclusive distribution agreements with car manufacturers often imposed a repressive
regime on them, such as a prohibition on selling cars to foreigners, due to different pricing
tactics in the different Member States. If car distributors did so anyway, manufacturers
might reduce the premium or dissolve contracts (Van Miert, 2000: 63).
The Bureau Europen des Unions de Consommateurs (Beuc) lobbied against the
prolongation of the 1985 block exemption regulation and urged the Commission to open
up the market completely. The director of Beuc compared the fact that consumers could
not make cross-border purchases of cars to 'an unmitigated disaster for consumers' (FT,
1994a: 17). The abolition of the exclusive distribution regime was considered essential in
increasing consumer choice across Europe. Consumers eventually succeeded in 2002,
when Regulation 1400/2002 imposed the same competition rules on the car sector as in
other industrial areas. Car manufacturers could no longer impede liberalisation. Two years
226
prior to its enactment, the Commission actively consulted consumer associations, dealers,
independent importers and repairers, spare-part producers, firms that sell through the
Internet and all the motor vehicles manufacturers and asked for their input (Akbar, 2003:
12). In response to enhanced competitive pressure resulting from the new regulation, the
car manufacturing industry underwent an industrial restructuring by mergers and
acquisitions. Examples are the high-level mergers between Daimler and Chrysler, Rover
and BMW, and the growing amount of shares in Fiat held by General Motors.
5.6.2 The End of Industrial Policy: The Banning of the De Havilland Merger
In a range of mergers, competitors and national competition authorities complained about
the Commissions lenient stance with regard to dominant market positions. Examples of
large mergers that raised controversies are: in 1991 Varta-Bosch (car batteries), Tetra PakAlfa Laval (food packaging), Alcatel-Telettra (telecommunications); in 1992 NestlPerrier (food and beverages), Mannesman-Hoesch (steel tubing and instruments); in 1993
the stainless steel tubes joint venture between Mannesman, Vallourcee and Ilva; in 1994
Mercedes Benz-Kssbohrer (busses) and Procter and Gamble-Schickendanz (hygiene
227
products). Competitors feared that the newly created combinations led to market
dominance, which would eventually push them out of the market. The De Havilland
merger became an important landmark case.
In the four years during which the Merger Regulation was in force, the De Havilland case
was the first industrial concentration the Commission blocked. The case is symbolic for
marking the end of the Commissions tolerance towards Member State industrial strategies
that aimed at creating national champions. The Canadian aircraft manufacturer De
Havilland was a daughter company of the giant US aircraft manufacturer Boeing, which
was no longer interested in the regional turbo-propeller commuter aircraft market and thus,
put the company on sale. The consortium ATR, involving the French company
Aerospatiale and the Italian state aerospace group Alenia, supported by the French
government, proposed a bid to take over De Havilland. The joint endeavour would have
made them market leaders (FT, 1991d). The bid formed an attempt to survive the
economic slump in the regional turbo-propeller commuter aircraft market which resulted
from the end of the Cold War and reduced military spending (FT, 1991a). In September
1991, the Commission blocked the takeover for reasons of market dominance that
eventually would deter newcomers. It expected the concentration would lead to a market
share of 67% in the sector commuter aircraft of 20 to 70 seats (ibid). Thereby, it sought to
maintain competition among European players in each sectoral segment. The ruling
entailed a resignation of active neomercantilist industrial policy. The companies, as well as
the French and Italian government, lobbied the Commission to reconsider its decision, as
the merger would have created a Eurochampion (FT, 1991d). European competitors, such
as British Aerospace lobbied against the merger. Yet, the intentions were similar to those
of the Franco-Italian alliance, as the company sought to create a consortium similar to
Airbus together with Aerospatiale, the Deutsche Aerospace, Casa of Spain, and the
Dutch Fokker.
The merger raised controversies among the College of Commissioners, who had to give its
blessing to the DG IV decision as a collective. The Commission was split into a
neomercantilist camp and a neoliberal camp. The neomercantilist Commissioners were
located foremost in the DG responsible for Industrial Policy, and the neoliberal
Commissioners in the DG Internal Market and Competition. The Industrial Policy
Commissioner Martin Bangemann, as well as the Commissions President Jacques Delors,
228
fiercely criticised their colleagues from the DG Competition for downplaying industrial
and employment reasoning in their assessment. Bannermann denounced the competition
officials as ayatollahs and gurus that adopted an over-legalistic approach in competition
matters. In the past, an active industrial policy and competition policy had complemented
each other. Primacy had been given to the creation of Eurochampions able to compete on a
global scale (see Chapter 4). The De Havilland ban broke with this tradition. The camp in
favour of a proactive industrial policy was too weak. Competition Commissioner Sir Leon
Brittan eventually changed a lot of minds in the Commission (FT, 1991a). The
Commissions neoliberals all went along with Brittan, while others were simply giving
way to the Commissioner in charge. Delors abstained from the vote and the swing vote
of Commissioner Manuel Marin was traded for Brittans support of the reorganisation of
the European fishing fleet (Ross, 1995: 178). At a later stage, Commissioner van Miert
(1998c: 4-6) emphasised that the concept of national champions was dead and that
industrial intervention was an old-fashioned policy. Not to expose companies to full
competition, in his view, was a false economy (ibid).
The repercussions of the De Havilland case went further than this. The Commissions ban
also came as a shock to those fearing a turnaround in the Commissions lenient
enforcement policy towards mergers. The European transnational business elite reacted
with a sense of outrage, proclaiming that the ruling was based on rigidly defined maximum
permissible market shares. As industrial competition primarily came from large dominant
players mainly from the US, elite networks, such as the ERT, promoted large European
players that could punch their weight in a globalised economy (ERT, 2004). The
dominance of the new combination was restricted to the European market. On the world
market, it had to survive alongside larger competitors, such as the Canadian Bombardier
and the Brazilian Embraer. After the Commissions blocking, Bombardier took over De
Havilland, which eventually set an even harsher pace of competition for European players.
Thereby, the ban in the De Havilland merger became symbolic for EC competition policy,
inhibiting an approach that allowed European industries to catch up with their (US)
competitors. The ERT demanded the adaptation of competition laws to allow European
players to achieve economies of scale and operate on the world market. It urged the
Commission to view the world market as the relevant market by which to judge a merger
(ibid).
229
The Commission, however, insisted with genuine toughness on the closure of steel plants
of both the private and state-owned sector, a remedy that followed the rhetoric of a stepby-step restructuring the industry. The liberalisation process should take place stepwise.
By the end of 1995, the closure programmes were scheduled to be finished. In the short
run, the industry was committed to cutting capacity to 30 million tons, which corresponds
to a quarter of the total EU steel production. In return the Commission offered to
contribute to the closing costs with a budget of ecu 900 Million (FT, 1993e: 36). The
Commissions stance was highly disputed by Member State governments who sought to
protect their industries from capacity cuts and the loss of state aid, such as those of Italy,
Spain, and Germany. Steelworkers in Taranto, Southern Italy demonstrated against the
proposed closures, and the Italian Industry Minister, Paolo Savona, announced that it
would challenge the Commission before the European Court of Justice (FT, 1993h: 2). The
The Italian industry federation, Federacciai, estimated that the plan to restructure privately-owned steel
industry would cost more than a quarter of the 25,000 jobs in the private sector (FT, 1994c: 2).
36
230
Commission feared that concessions to the steel sector would make governments require
the right to subsidise other national sectors in crisis and eventually undermine the whole
idea of a single market driven by the neoliberal idea of unfettered competition. In the end,
the political pressure of the state-owned steel industries in Italy, Spain, and Germany was
successful, insofar as far as the restructuring plans were conducted in a less radical manner
than previously envisaged by Commission. State aid was permitted as a temporary rescue
in return for negotiated capacity cuts. Moreover, temporary antidumping duties were
imposed on cheap imports from Eastern Europe to protect the EC steel industry (FT,
1993j: 5). In 1994, the Commission launched a proposal to abandon quotas on steel
imports from Slovakia and the Czech Republic, although without success.
In conclusion, from the mid-1980s onwards, the accelerated pace of the creation of the
common market and the advent of neoliberal ideas informing policy decisions increased
competition in the EU. The ongoing liberalisation on a global scale, and the growing
presence of competitors in previously state-protected industries further enhanced
competitive pressure. To cope with the new situation, corporations strong enough to
compete, mostly large transnationally operating corporations and/or corporations in the
export sector, came to favour free competition. Free competition meant free from privately
imposed market barriers such as cartels and other restrictive behaviour, and free from
public intervention privileging certain economic sectors or corporations over others by
protectionist measures. The creation of the common market and subsequently the
liberalising global economy enlarged the scale for competition. Globally competing
corporations pushed for a tolerant stance towards mergers and acquisitions, and hence,
towards economic power concentration at EU level. In contrast, corporations unable to
stand up to fierce outside competition gradually lost their influence. Pushing for
protectionist measures at both the Member State and EU level was no longer an option.
The centralisation of competition policy at the Commission was crucial in this regard. It
provided a platform for a private-public alliance favouring open competition and
stringently enforced competition laws. The neoliberal tenet was set. After van Mierts
interlude at the DG Competition, the staunch neoliberal course surfaced again with the
tenure of Mario Monti and his successor Neelie Kroes as Competition Commissioners,
leaving little room for a macroeconomic and pro-industrial policy competition vision.
231
Chapter 6
Mutual acknowledgement of different, but equally effective systems, will also be necessary.
We shall all have to compromise on something [].
Introduction
In the course of the 1990s, the EU and the US authorities concluded a range of bilateral
cooperation agreements in the field of competition policy. This chapter outlines the
background that led to the first and second transatlantic agreements and explains why
transatlantic cooperation in competition matters has evolved into the intensive working
relationship we witness today. It identifies the joint interests of the transatlantic business
elite as the major driving forces. The same forces that lobbied for the creation of a
transatlantic marketplace, also sought to abolish transatlantic regulatory barriers, which
had evolved from different approaches in the field of competition control. This chapter
argues that the interests of the transatlantic business community were predicated on the
structural economic integration across the Atlantic. Enhanced cross-border concentration
activities of the 1990s brought the growing risk of jurisdictional overlaps to the fore, and
concomitantly, negative externalities of economic transactions. Apart from administrative
burdens for transnational business, the problematic of extraterritorial application of
competition law started to form a regulatory obstacle for corporations in the transatlantic
realm. This constitutes part of the reason why transatlantic cooperation in competition
matters emerged and, in a wider sense, is also indicative of a transformed transatlantic
power (im)balance. Previously, US competition authorities had never shied away from
applying their competition laws on an extraterritorial basis. Alongside the course of
European integration, the Commission, as a supranational competition authority,
233
emancipated and acquired additional decision making powers. With the right to control
mergers, the Commission received more media coverage and became more visible to the
outside world. Notably, the involvement of giant transnational corporations brought its
activities into the public attention spotlight. In addition, the incumbency of a new
generation of powerful Competition Commissioners meant that the US competition
officials could no longer ignore their European counterparts. They had to curb the
application of US competition laws outside US territory.
234
USA in Washington with a division covering the antitrust issues.37 The agreements
encompassed the whole spectrum of competition control, but they were most advanced in
the mergers field. Cooperation in competition matters takes place quietly and largely goes
unnoticed by the wider public. Exceptions are the merger between McDonnell-Douglas
and GE-Honeywell, which almost caused a trade war. According to the adage there is no
cooperation without conflict, the next sections embed the subsequent cooperation
agreements in the broader context of political conflict, and identify the particular interest
constellation that lobbied for these agreements.
It is difficult to overstate the effect the TABD has had on trade liberalisation [...] in fact
virtually every-opening move undertaken by the United States and the EU in the last
couple of years has been suggested by the TABD. [] The idea was simple: to identify
those barriers to trade or opportunities for liberalisation on which both business
communities (in Europe and in the United States) could agree as targets for government
action. We should put the business 'horse' before the government 'cart'.
This [TABD] process is not a fifth wheel. It has become part and parcel of the entire
transatlantic agenda.
No one would have quite imagined the degree to which the TABD has influenced
government decision-making on both sides of the Atlantic. It has become deeply enmeshed
and embedded in to the US government decision-making process on a wide range of
regulatory, trade and commercial issues. It is regularly cited and it is part of the ongoing
discussion between the EU and the US.
The US Mission to the European Union is the biggest mission by a government in Brussels, staffed by
more than 50 diplomatic deputies specialised in different issue areas. See for more at:
http://useu.usmission.gov.
235
Baker, US Secretary of State, announced that the United States and the European
Community should consider working together to achieve, whether in a treaty or some
other form, a significantly strengthened set of institutional and consultative links (in
Piening, 1997: 108). This proposal led to the Transatlantic Declaration, signed on 20
November in 1990 in Paris, in which the US and EU agreed on a framework for regular
and intensive consultation (see for more Piening, 1997). The decision to foster the
institutional glue across the Atlantic finds its roots in enhanced US scepticism on
establishing economic, monetary, and political union. Similar to the adoption of the ECSC
in 1951 and the Treaty of Rome in 1957, the prospect of a Fortress Europe in which US
corporations would be disadvantaged raised concerns across the Atlantic. The stalemate in
the closing phases of the 1990 Uruguay Round, looming trade wars on bananas, beef, and
biotechnological products, but also past experiences with protectionism and state aid
supporting domestic industries in Europe, fuelled these concerns.
236
The TABD was established with the great support of ERT (Van Apeldoorn, 2002: 111).
The ERT had a major stake in a transatlantic pendant attuned to its lobbying efforts that
were directed at the creation of a barrier free transatlantic market (TABD, 2005; 2007).
Many members of the ERT were also members of the TABD, such as the CEOs from Asea
Brown Boveri, Bayer, Bertelsmann, Ericsson, ICI, Olivetti, Pirelli, Philips, Siemens,
BASF, Solvay, and Unilever (CEO, 1999c). Influential TABD members from the US
included Boeing, Enron, Federal Express, Ford, IBM, Motorola, Nokia, Pfizer, Procter &
Gamble, Time Warner, Westinghouse, and Xerox (cf. Green-Cowles, 2001; Graf, 2000). As
Reinhard Quick, the TABD's Global Issues Manager, noted: We work together, we
consult with each other. The ERT is part of the TABD network. (In CEO, 1999a) Through
237
the TABD, transnational business interests could influence the governance of the
transatlantic realm and soon evolved as the most crucial and most powerful political forces
in setting the political agenda. As the TABDs co-chair Michael Treschow stated, the
TABD was not a lobby group, but an invited advisor (CEO, 2001). Five subject-specific
working groups sought to generate a broad-based consensus in 15 key areas of concern.
Right from the start competition policy constituted one of these key areas. Additional areas
covered were: standards certification, issues regarding the WTO, export controls, customs
issues and trade liberalisation, information technology and intellectual property,
government procurement, taxes, investment and R&D, transportation, international
business practices, small and medium-sized enterprises, and product liability. The type of
regulatory regime envisaged by representatives of transnational corporations was
straightforward and utterly neoliberal in character. As Jrme Monod, European co-chair
of the TABD, stressed:
The underlying premise is that the market itself has the capacity to come up with pragmatic
positions, on the assumption that business leaders are better able to establish a dialogue
among themselves than are governments and administrations. (In CEO, 1999c)
The creation of a free trade zone in the transatlantic marketplace and the right to compete
freely in each others markets constituted the primary objectives. In this vein, the TABD
lobbied for a deregulation of excessive domestic laws and regulations which hampered
corporate competitiveness, and suggested instead a more business-driven and marketorientated approach (FT, 1995b: 2). It demanded the abolition of double regulatory
requirements, discriminatory regulations, and non-tariff trade barriers (NTBs) and
suggested harmonising regulatory matters step-by-step. It advised harmonising corporate
governance standards, corporate and VAT taxes, and abolishing the withholding of taxes
on intercompany royalty and interest payments. In fields such as Internet commerce, it
urged governments to leave issues to private self-regulation (ibid, 1998f: 12).
Furthermore, it recommended the adoption of Mutual Recognition Agreements (MRA) on
testing and certification standards (ibid, 1996b: 6).
On both sides of the Atlantic, the political elite supported the TABDs requests. The
meetings took place largely behind closed doors. The privileged access of transatlantic
elite business interests to political decision-makers led to an extraordinary symbiotic
relationship, in which the interests of corporate and political elite were enmeshed into one
238
effective power block marked by consensus on many important issues (in CEO, 1999c).
Former Competition Commissioner Brittan confirmed, in a letter to the TABD Chair, his
full personal support for the TABD process and well as on the continuing cooperation of
his officials (ibid). In addition to frequent informal contacts, TABD interlocutors
monitored internal working documents of the Commission, and issued replies and followups (European Commission, 2006c). Stephen Johnston, TABD Director noted in this
respect that each of the TABD issue groups had a Commission contact point in order to
ensure ongoing cooperation and a structured dialogue. He observed that the Commission
was cooperative, helping business by giving them the information that they needed,
eventually, however, it was business that made recommendations (in CEO, 1999c).
The TABDs stark influence is revealed in the proposal to create a Transatlantic Free
Trade Agreement (TAFTA) brought forth by Sir Leon Brittan in 1995, which would form a
transatlantic analogue to the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) established
in January 1994. His ambitious proposal for a transatlantic economic space of free trade
failed to generate the necessary support of the EU Member governments and the US
government (The Economist, 1995: 49). In particular, the French government fiercely
criticised the free rein given to Commissioner Brittan in promoting free trade areas
between the EU and third countries, despite the fact that agricultural production was
excluded in the proposal. As a result thereof, the negotiations reached a stalemate and the
TAFTA proposal never materialised. Nonetheless, US President Clinton and Commission
President Santer adopted the New Transatlantic Agenda (NTA) in December 1995, a
follow-up agreement to the Transatlantic Declaration of 1990. The NTAs Action Plan
did not include a free trade zone, although it did entail a framework for the progressive
reduction and eventual elimination of barriers that hinder the flow of goods, services, and
capital. The NTAs purpose was to bring the two economic superpowers closer to a free
trade zone. In this regard, it constituted a significant milestone, although Commissioner
Brittan condemned the surrogate solution as slow and producing only limited results
(The Irish Times, 1995: 11). The NTA provided a welcome platform for the TABD to
voice corporate interests. Eventually, the NTA included more than 60% of the
recommendations issued by the TABD in Seville (FT, 1996g: 6). Moreover, less visible is
the fact that the TABD also succeeded in cancelling, delaying, or watering down businessconstraining environmental and consumer-protectionist regulations in the transatlantic
realm (Holt, 2000). Thousands of alterglobalists and civil society movements regularly
239
demonstrated at TABD meetings against the ongoing liberalisation of trade and financial
markets (FT, 1996g: 6), as well as against the fact that the TABD could influence the
direction of economic decision making by evading parliamentary control. TABD members
were largely unimpressed by the protestors. According to TABD Chair Monod, the
remarkable success rate justifies the institution's existence all by itself (in CEO, 1999c).
Or, as EU Trade Commissioner Pascal Lamy remarked, it was more important to find
new ways of getting across the benefits of freer trade, rather than engaging with the
concerns raised by the demonstrators (Alden, 2000: 10).
Not only alterglobalists protested against the political influence of the TABD, but also
standing national industry associations, as well as the UNICE in Brussels. As the TABD
bypassed other industrial associations at the national and EU level, as well as national
governments, the relationship with other businesses was tense. AmChams chairman
Russell reckoned that European TNCs tended to be very much their natural allies in
marked contrast to those parts of European industry that are tied very much to the local
economies (in CEO, 1999a). These tensions find their origin in the fact that corporations,
either with an intra-EU or national focus, or smaller or import-competing corporations, did
not necessarily share the neoliberal oriented free-market focus of transnational
corporations.
The TABD was the joint endeavour of a selective group of the transnational business elite.
It excluded the greater variety of other business interests. Illustrative in this regard is the
TABDs inaugural conference. While the large share of national business associations were
not included, only CEOs equipped with red cards could make themselves heard during the
inaugural conference. Lower-ranking officials and government representatives were
assigned blue cards, which merely granted observer status with no right to speak (Graf,
2000). Existing business associations in Europe felt overlooked and challenged. The
European Union of Craftsmen and Small and Medium-Sized Enterprises (UEAPME), for
example, repeatedly complained about denied access to powerful groups that influence EU
policy-making (Carchedi, 2001: 125). The De Minimis rule (see Chapter 2 and 4) excluded
most SMEs from the direct authority of the Commission, which implied that they
traditionally had no reason to direct their lobbying activities at the supranational level. A
study by Neven et. al (1998: 139) shows that SMEs and their associations indeed contacted
national competition authorities more frequently, as they were more sensitive to their
240
interests. However, with the prominent presence and influence of transnational business
interests at the Commission, they also tried to make themselves heard at EU level.
Similarly, officials from the German industry association, the BDI, noted that if member
companies of the TABD took such visible interest in a specific topic, industrial
organisations, such as the BDI should be alarmed (cited in Green-Cowles, 2000b: 172).
Furthermore, many leading European business leaders organised in UNICE, as well as in
the ERT, also did not share the enthusiasm about the TABD (Woolcock, 1996: 175). The
TABDs prominent US label caused a certain degree of discomfort among ERT Members.
Horst Langer, CEO of Siemens noted that many CEOs already had effective channels for
direct contacts with government circles in Brussels and Washington. Given the great
differences among business associations across the Atlantic, they did not need the TABD
(Graf, 2000).
Aware of these tensions, both the TABD and ERT sought to incorporate existing European
business associations, such as UNICE and small and medium-sized enterprises, into the
political agenda. The unifying purpose was to accommodate the broader interests of
industry within the EU, as well as to draw on the knowledge and organisational structure of
specialised working groups. The TABD let the UEAPME participate in its informal
framework of political contacts (see for more UEAPME, 2007). Also the ERT sought to
build closer links with SMEs as a way to generate broader support and accelerate political
change (cf. Servan-Schreiber, 1967). Moreover, in order to avoid the picture that European
corporations were controlled by their US counterparts, the ERT, rather than the TABD
communicated high-profile policy initiatives to the Commission (in CEO, 1999a).
Nonetheless, the scruples of European business about the invasion of US capital as first
described in Schreibers best-selling book Le dfi amricain (1967) increasingly vanished
throughout the 1990s (Van Apeldoorn, 2002: 112). Transnational business elites spoke
with one voice to those in charge of the regulatory decision making. Gradually, European
corporations also started to adopt US-style lobbying practices as a result thereof (Van
Miert, 1999). The success of the TABD generated a few organisational clones in other
areas, such as the Transatlantic Consumer Dialogue (TACD) and the Transatlantic
Environmental Dialogue (TAED). Moreover, the TABD-concept was used as an inspiration
for the establishment of the Global Business Dialogue (GBD), which, in addition to CEOs
from US and EU based corporations, also involves CEOs from Japan and Australia, as well
as business associations of the OECD regions.
241
The transatlantic pact of unified corporate forces allowed for a maximisation of political
pressure on US and EU institutions. According to Stuart Eizenstat, US Under-Secretary of
International Trade, when both business communities agree that a particular action is in
the interest of both sides, it is much easier for governments to act and to act quickly
(Aroon, 1998). The first transatlantic competition agreement needs to be seen against the
backdrop of broader transatlantic economic cooperation. Even though it pre-dates the
establishment of the TABD, transatlantic corporate forces urged the EU and US authorities
to cooperate in competition matters and to streamline the investigation process.
Corporations operating in the transatlantic marketplace had a direct stake in reducing the
costs and uncertainty when their competition case involved authorities at both sides of the
Atlantic. As the next section demonstrates, transatlantic business interests were crucial in
setting up the first transatlantic competition agreement.
The good news is that over the past decade we have achieved a remarkable record of
cooperation and convergence. Despite our different legal traditions and cultures, and
despite substantial differences in the language of our governing laws, we have been able to
work together to develop generally coherent and largely consistent competition policies,
built on sound economic foundations, directed at a common goal: to promote consumer
welfare through competition.
William J. Kolasky, Assistant Attorney General at the Federal Trade Commission (2002a: 1)
242
generally non-binding and applied as a mild form of unilateral conflict prevention.38 In the
particular field of competition law, traditional comity finds its origin in a series of nonbinding OECD recommendations that were issued from the 1960s onwards (OECD, 1967,
with revision in 1973, 1979, 1986, 1995). Prior to its inclusion in the transatlantic
competition agreement, the principle of negative comity was hardly applied. The primary
purpose of the negative comity principle was to avoid regulatory conflicts in competition
matters, or, according to the Commission (1994a: 72), the possibility or impact of
differences between the parties in the application of their competition laws. Eventually,
the cooperation and coordination endeavour had the goal of harmonising the different
approaches of the Commission and the US authorities, and hence facilitating economic
transactions across the Atlantic. In addition to cooperation on a case-by-case basis, the
signatories scheduled discussions, on general matters a propos the future course of
competition policy, on a twice-a-year basis. The 1991 transatlantic competition agreement
thereby came to form the prelude of a slow but steady process of convergence in which
the EU incorporated decisive elements of the more market-based, US competition model
(see Chapter 8).
The impetus for regulatory cooperation in the course of the 1990s is linked to the
enhanced pace of transatlantic concentration activities since the 1980s, such as mergers,
alliances, joint ventures, and other types of intercompany agreements. With the emergence
of a transatlantic market for corporate control, regulatory barriers in the field of
competition control increasingly formed an obstacle for transatlantic business
transactions. Corporate representatives repeatedly complained about the delays and lack of
transparency in rulings and, therefore, the uncertainty created by parallel competition
investigations. Michael Treschow, CEO of Electrolux, called the process horrendous as
in many cases the businesses of merging companies were essentially frozen for a year or
more, until both competition authorities reached a decision (Alden, 2001: 10). Waiting for
decisions pushed up the costs of M&As, which, according to James Schiro, CEO of Price
Waterhouse Coopers, was detrimental to value creation (ibid). The Commission took
these complaints seriously and repeatedly emphasised the need to synchronise and
coordinate regulatory barriers, such as: the differences in the investigation procedures and
38
There is no general binding definition of traditional comity. According to the Black's Law Dictionary
(1997), traditional comity can entail the recognition that one sovereignty allows within its territory the
legislative, executive, or judicial actor of another sovereignty having due regard to rights of its own
citizens. It can imply that courts of one state or jurisdiction will give effect to laws and judicial decisions of
another state or jurisdiction, not as a matter of obligation, but out of deference and mutual respect (ibid).
243
the information requirements, the applied definitions, the time schedules, and the remedies
(Van Miert, 1997). The 1991 transatlantic competition agreement was therefore
instrumental in opening up the transatlantic market space by eliminating regulatory
constraints for business. In a wider sense, the agreement served the purpose of facilitating
free competition and free market access undisturbed by public market intervention.
The 1991 EU-US Competition Cooperation Agreement is also illustrative of the role of
the Commission and the European Court of Justice (ECJ) as major pro-free market forces,
which embodied the concerns of transnational corporations in the creation of a
transatlantic marketplace. The autonomous role of the Commission in concluding a
competition agreement caused considerable political turmoil among Member States. The
Commission entered the agreement with the US government without the political consent
of the Council of Ministers. In December 1991, the French government, supported by
Spain and the Netherlands, challenged the legality of the Commissions competence to
sign such a formal international agreement with a foreign government before the ECJ. In
the US, no such disputes emerged as US law solved the competence question more
swiftly: the 1991 agreement accounted as a binding international executive agreement,
which, however, cannot override domestic law since the US Senate did not ratify it
(Janow, 2000: 30). In defence, the Commission claimed that the agreement was of a
purely administrative nature. It emphasised that it could negotiate and conclude
agreements without the approval of the Council as long as this did not lead to an increase
in the Communitys budget, basing its argument on Article 101 of the Euroatom Treaty.
By virtue of the 1969 Vienna Convention (Article 46), which rules that an international
agreement concluded by an authority that was not manifestly incompetent binds the state
for which it acts, the Commission asserted that the agreement would remain valid in
international law.
In August 1994, the ECJ ruled in France v. Commission (see for details Case C-327/91,
ECR 1-3641) that the Commission indeed acted ultra vires and exceeded the scope of its
discretionary authority (see also Damro, 2002, 133-135; Cini and McGowan, 1998:
202). Nonetheless, the ECJ still supported the argument put forward by the Commission
as it did not declare the 1991 cooperation agreement void. It somewhat vaguely ruled that
the agreement produced a legal effect without, however, further specifying what kind of
legal effect. Moreover, it ruled that the Council of Ministers still had to approve the
244
agreement. Nevertheless, the Council of Ministers officially signed the same agreement on
April 10 in 1995. Thereby, the document was declared retrospectively valid, from the
initial signing date onwards (Commission, 1994a: 72-73). The ruling of the ECJ thereby
not only supported the Commissions attempt to expand its executive powers in
competition matters, but also the quest of transatlantic business interests to facilitate
economic transactions.
245
launched their activities as if they were one single entity, while remaining legally
autonomous (ibid, 1998e: 5). In their joint attempt to open up the aviation market to
competition, the US authorities wanted to go much further and pushed for a full-blown
liberalisation. They suggested concluding a separate bilateral Open Skies Agreement
allowing airlines to fly every route in the EU and US markets. EU Member States
considered such an agreement to be to the advantage of US carriers only and successfully
opposed the agreement until April 2007, when EU and US authorities signed the Open
Skies Agreement nonetheless. When the agreement takes effect in March 2008, the aviation
market will be fully liberalised.
Transatlantic cooperation on competition control, and hence, its impact with regard to the
further liberalisation of the transatlantic marketplace, generally took place without raising
the awareness of the wider public. The risk of conflicting views became more prominent in
the second half of the 1990s. The number of mergers across the Atlantic was on the
increase and the magnitude, in terms of combined turnovers, unmatched. The Boeing
McDonnell Douglas merger, the General Electric Honeywell merger, as well as the
Microsoft controversy led to heavy disputes between the EU and US competition
authorities despite the initial successes of the existing 1991 cooperation agreement.
246
the massive amount of documents submitted to support the deal the paper load was
reported to be the most extensive in US merger review history (Boeder, 2000: 141). In a
written decision, the FTC argued that the deal would not negatively affect consumers,
who in this case were purchasers of aircrafts. The Commission received the notification a
bit later in February, 1997. Although the companies had no major manufacturing facilities
in Europe, the high level of sales in Europe demanded that the companies also notify the
planned merger to the Commission. After the four week long phase one of the EU
notification procedure, the Commission announced that it would start the much-feared
investigation phase two, which required more in-depth analysis and hearings during the
next four months. On July 4, the Advisory Committee of the Commission suggested
blocking the deal.
The different rulings of the US and the EU competition officials generated an expansive
and detailed analysis by commentators (cf. Lvque and Shelanski, 2003; Johnson and
Turner, 2000). The political repercussions on the transatlantic cooperation in competition
matters, however, lacked similar coverage. The Commissions plan to ban infuriated not
only the companies involved in the merger, but also the US government. The stakes were
high, as the merger not only concerned a concentration between two direct competitors in
the market for commercial civil aircraft manufactures, but it would also create a synergy in
the US defence sector. As the major purchasers of defence products, the US government
had a vital interest in the merger. With McDonnell Douglas facing tremendous financial
difficulties, and potential bidders from Asia already expressing their interest in a takeover
(Van Miert, 2000: 269), the US government, under President Clinton, wanted to avoid a
foreign company interfering with US defence interests. The US authorities portrayed the
Commissions plan to ban as an attempt to protect the already heavily state-subsidised
French, German, British and Spanish Airbus Consortium, which in Europe was hailed as
the most successful case of post-war European economic cooperation (Boeder, 2000).
Airbus was the only serious competitor to Boeing in the market for large jet engines.
The Commissions line of reasoning was that the Boeing-Airbus duopoly already reflected
a case of immense concentration and that the combined worldwide market share of more
than 70% provided enough reason to prohibit the deal. The Commission was particularly
concerned about the possibility that Boeing would abuse its dominant position in the future
and inhibit market entry for newcomers. According to van Miert (1997), the deal would
247
create an incumbent with enough market power to stifle competition and foreclose
potential entry. Moreover, with the US government as a major purchaser of defence
products from the new combination, the Commission argued that the companys privileged
access to publicly funded R&D projects would further enhance this dominant position, and
hence, increase their bargaining power vis--vis suppliers (Van Miert, 1998e: 10). From
the viewpoint of the Commission, the merged companies would be able to conclude
exclusive agreements along the production chain that could evolve into a snowball that is
very hard to stop (ibid). The Commissions argument is inherently linked to the
differences in market structures across the Atlantic. Prior to the announcement of the
Boeing and McDonnell Douglas merger, the US defence-related industry was undergoing
a rapid restructuring in a wave of large-scale mergers, i.e. Lockheed-Martin Marietta,
Northrop-Grumman,
McDonnell
Douglas-Hughes
Helicopters,
Raytheon-Hughes
Lockheed Martin-Northrop
Despite initial opposition, the Commission eventually allowed the deal, due to political
pressure from the US government. Insiders argued that the deal was made possible due to
dubious political trade offs between US and EU officials (Bannerman, 2002: 44). The
negotiations were reported to have been nerve-wracking. The case also caused internal
divisions in the Commission, as a reaction to which Karel van Miert even threatened to
resign (Van Miert, 2000). The threat of a trade war emerged in the picture. US Vice
President Al Gore warned the Commission that the administration would take whatever
action is appropriate to prevent the EU from impeding the merger (in FT, 1997: 1). The
US authorities threatened to limit flights between the US and France, to impose a tax on
European airplanes sold in the US, as well as to file an official protest with the WTO
(Boeder, 2000: 143). Tit for tat negotiations involving high-level government
interference eventually resulted in an agreement. Despite the fact that the international
press provoked heated debates on both sides of the Atlantic, it remains obscure whether the
concessions made by the companies alone constitute the actual tradeoff. Boeing promised
248
not to abuse its dominance in the world market and agreed to modify the terms of the
merger. It agreed to offer competitors the use of any government-funded patent as well as
the technicalities and know-how related to such a patent, on a licence-basis. Moreover, it
committed itself to reporting to the Commission annually for the following ten years, on
the development of publicly funded, non-classified aircraft projects.
The reproaches made by competition officials on both sides of the Atlantic were harsh.
The Commission was accused of megalomania, harming important US defence interests
(Van Miert, 2000: 10). In particular, The Financial Times attacked van Miert for his
delusions of grandeur and for lacking diplomatic flair. The Commission, in turn, sought to
revise the image of being the junior partner of the US. As Frdric Jenny, a French
commentator remarked:
I hope what Europeans have done, written and said over the last 40 years has done enough
to persuade our American friends that the antitrust world is at least bipolar. It may not
have been until the Boeing-Mc Donnell Douglas merger case last year that some people
[] realised just how true this is. (Jenny, 1998: 7)
As no government alone could have achieved similar concessions to those achieved by the
Commission, the Commission left the battle in a position of increased political credibility
from the point of view of the EU Member States (Schaub, 1998). Despite the fundamental
dispute in the Boeing-McDonnell Douglas merger, it called the cooperation with the US
authorities a success story.
249
[The Boeing merger] graphically demonstrated, even the US and the EU, which agree
entirely on the importance of sound antitrust enforcement, diverge significantly in our
application of merger enforcement and related monopoly rules. (Joel Klein in FT, 1998e:
20)
250
was established. Several joint subgroups, involving staff members of both agencies, were
given the task of looking into the various procedural and substantive aspects of merger
control and identifying the scope for convergence of analysis and methodology (cf. US
Mission, 1999; FTC, 2002). The Working Group specifically had the task to ease tensions
and take necessary precautions to avoid future conflicts, such as aligning legal standards
that guide the respective merger control regimes, defining best practices, and reconciling
the different approaches of the EU and the US (ibid). What started with cooperation was
gradually replaced by a call for more convergence.
At a later stage, US competition officials downplayed the political turmoil of the BoeingMcDonnell Douglas dispute as an incidental bump on the road the road towards
convergence (Pitofsky, 2000). As will be illustrated in the next section, the GE-Honeywell
controversy in 2001 proved that the road remained bumpy in the aftermath of the BoeingMcDonnell Douglas merger. Yet, with the conclusion of a second bilateral cooperation
agreement, a further step was taken to avoid conflicting decisions in the future.
The centrepiece of the TABD's power is clearly the symbiosis, which has been built with
(parts of) the European Commission a unique and disturbing example of an international
corporate-state alliance. (CEO, 1999c)
the TABD advocated the EU and the US authorities to make use of the positive comity
procedures in antitrust enforcement, and to focus thereby on mergers and acquisitions in
particular (TABD, 1995: Section II.10 and II.12). Only two years later, the TABD worked
out a draft proposal on positive comity that would form the basis of a closer EU-US
cooperation (TABD, 1997: 6). On 4 June in 1998, the Commission and the US government
concluded the Positive Comity Agreement (PCA) in Washington, which formed part of the
Joint US-EU Action Plan that was established in parallel to the New Transatlantic Agenda
(NTA). The PCA allowed the signatories to request the other party to begin investigations
in cases outside its jurisdictional reach, but which still affected its important interests. It
entailed a mutual commitment to act promptly, responsibly, and diligently in examining
allegations at issue and not to act unilaterally in cases falling under the other partys
jurisdiction, unless all means provided by positive comity were exhausted (Pitofsky,
1998).
The underpinning rationale behind the specific reference to positive comity was to
facilitate communication with the competition authorities and to reduce the level of
friction that can arise from different rulings in cross-border enforcement situations. Similar
to the one-stop-shop rule in the EU Merger Regulation (see Chapter 4), positive comity
should channel competition cases with a transatlantic dimension to only one competition
authority (Van Miert, 1998b: 2). As Draghi (2003: 10-11), Vice Chairman of Goldman
Sachs International, explicated the negative externalities resulting from multijurisdictional overlap in merger review constituted a significant transaction risk. With
positive comity, inconsistent rulings could be eliminated and the review procedure and
decision making considerably accelerated. Yet, the inclusion of positive comity reached
further than the problem of multi-jurisdictional overlaps. As the next section illustrates, it
also sought to curb the extraterritorial application of competition laws.
252
As the Community has never formally claimed territorial jurisdiction as extensive as that which is
claimed by the US, this situation was viewed as an imbalance in our bilateral relations and an
obstacle to any further deepening of these relations. For this reason we have decided to negotiate a
strengthening of the positive comity instrument.
253
of March 1996 are probably the most well known examples of US extraterritorialism.39
Yet, also within the field of competition law, the US record stands out. The earliest
extraterritoriality case in competition matters concerned American Banana accusing
United Fruit for having intented to monopolise the banana trade in Costa Rica before the
US Supreme Court in 1909 the American Banana Co. v. United Fruit Co. (Gavil et al.,
2002: 934). The Supreme Court ruled that the Sherman Act does not address acts
committed outside of US territory. This changed in 1945 with the legendary Alcoa case,
short for United States v. Aluminium Co., which led to the Effects Doctrine, a document
that gave the exercise of US extraterritorial jurisdiction a statutory basis. Accordingly,
foreign business conduct, which has an effect on US import commerce, falls within the
application of the Sherman Act. In other words, the Effects Doctrine entitled US
jurisdictions to prosecute market conduct by non-nationals that had a significant effect on
consumers or markets in the US, such as price fixing cartels, organised outside US
territory and selling their products in the US. The extent to which US authorities made use
of the Effects Doctrine varied over time. While the competition authorities under the
Reagan administration were less belligerent in the extraterritorial enforcement of
competition law (Hwang, 2004: 117), from the 1990s to the turn of the century, the US
practice of extraterritorial application increased considerably, and in addition, also became
a rather lucrative business. From 1996 to 1997, the US DoJ prosecuted more than 50
companies for international cartel activities and obtained fines of more than US$ 1.9
billion, and it also imprisoned about 20 senior executives for cartel activities (Kolasky,
2002a: 1). In 1997 alone, US courts imposed fines amounting to a total of US$ 200 million
in criminal antitrust cases, all involving international cartels (FT, 1998e: 20). In 1998,
more than 30 criminal cartel investigations were pending, involving companies based in
more than 20 countries (ibid). A third of all cases involved foreign defendants, compared
to 1% in 1991 (ibid, 1998d).
The US practice of extraterritoriality generated fierce controversies and evoked the picture
of a hegemonic gesture of aggressive unilateralism (Gavil et al., 2002: 935). The EU and a
The DAmato Act was officially titled Iran and Libya Sanctions Act 1996, and the Helms-Burton Act,
named after the US Senator Jesse James and Dan Burton, the Cuban Liberty and Democratic Solidarity
(Libertad) Act 1996. Both were designed to foster the US economic embargo against Iran, Libya, and Cuba,
and meant to prosecute any foreign citizen, company, or government involved in business transactions with
these countries. In the case of non-compliance, the punishment ranged from the confiscation of the property
of companies in the US, to the banning of company directors and their families from entry into the US, even
if there was little demonstrable effect of their actions within US territory (Dixon and McCorquodale, 2003:
285; Lane, 2000: 280).
39
254
40
Canada is exemplary in this respect, but also Germany, the UK, and Switzerland adopted a rule that limits
the effect of US judgements (Freyer, 2006: 128). German law addresses the issue in section 328 of the Civil
Procedure Laws, ruling that a foreign judgment may be denied if it would lead to a result that is
irreconcilable with material principles of German law, especially if recognition is irreconcilable with
constitutional rights (Buxbaum, 2006: 12). The German courts in particular referred to this provision to
deny recognition of the practice of multiple damages awards in antitrust cases (ibid).
255
merger 2001 (see following section in this Chapter). Particularly illustrative is the merger
between the South Korean electronics manufacturer Samsung and the US computer
manufacturer AST Research Incorporated. The Commission fined the two companies for
not having complied with the notification requirement of the EU Merger Regulation
(European Voice, 1998). The merger did not have a damaging effect on competition in the
computer market and the Commission would have cleared the merger anyway. However,
as the companies did not ask prior permission from the Commission, the fine demonstrated
merely an act of symbolic power meant to communicate to the transnational business
community that it could not ignore the Commission as a competition authority and that
extraterritoriality rulings were no longer exclusively a US hobby. Yet, the legal grounds
for the Commissions extraterritoriality were highly insecure. There were no provisions in
the treaties on the jurisdictional reach of EU competition laws, and court rulings so far
interpreted the extraterritoriality question inconsistently, i.e. there were no explicit
decisions regarding Article 82 or merger cases (Monti, 2002a: 71).
In 1999, the European Court of First Instance (CFI) played a significant role in providing
a legal basis for the extraterritorial application of EU competition law. Its judgment in the
Gencor-Lonrho case constituted a landmark decision in this regard. Briefly, the
Commission prohibited a merger between the mineral mining companies Gencor from
South Africa and Lonrho from the UK. Both companies operated outside Communityborders and had no assets in the EU. The Commission blocked the merger, regardless of
the fact that the South African competition gave its permission. It argued that the new
combination caused a dominant position in the world market for platinum and that it
affected trade between the EU Member States. When the companies appealed at the CFI
(i.e. Gencor Ltd vs Commission), it ruled that the Commission was authorised to block the
deal because it was foreseeable that the proposed concentration will have an immediate
and substantial effect in the Community. The Commission very much welcomed the
newfound clarity (Monti, 2003: 72). One could say that the ruling equipped the
Commission with its own Effects Doctrine. Similarly to the US, it could now prosecute
anticompetitive conduct, irrespective of the companies national origin, as long as it had a
major effect on the common market of the EU. In contrast to the US Effects Doctrine,
which was extended to conduct restraining trade with the US Foreign Trade Improvements
Act in 1982, the Commission maintained that the EU version was less sweeping as it did
not cover adverse effects on European exports markets (Monti, 2003: 72).
256
257
to keep each other mutually informed. In addition, competition officials attended each
others staff meetings. Part and parcel of the cooperation endeavour as envisaged by the
business community was to arrive at a process of substantive and procedural convergence
in order to reduce the negative externalities involved in complying with different
jurisdictions, and hence, to reduce the costs inherent to cross-border transactions more
generally. As far as substantive convergence was concerned, CEOs observed that the
Commission de facto did have a more conservative approach to merger review (Draghi,
2003). They noticed an ever-toughening stance by the EU Merger Task Force in the late
1990s. The Commission blocked concentration transactions with increased frequency
(ibid). Therefore, corporations had a stake in bringing the EU model of merger control
closer in line with US practice.
258
of mergers where business had a greater incentive to cooperate with the competition
authorities, and to allow joint EU-US interviews in order to speed up the review procedure
and receive consistent rulings. Exemplary cases in which reciprocal consultation
procedures and coordinated enforcement were applied are Daimler Benz-Chrysler (1998),
British Petroleum-Amoco (1998), Deutsche Bank-Bankers Trust (1999), and Ford-Volvo
(1999), WorldCom-MCI, and MCI-WorldCom-Sprint cases (FT, 1998a: 3).
The Commission wanted to enter a cooperation agreement with the US authorities that
went much further in terms of the exchange of confidential information (Monti, 2002a:
78). This would facilitate the Commissions combat of cartels. In contrast to the
Commission, the US DoJ and US FTC are, by law, entitled to conclude agreements
containing such provisions. The International Antitrust Enforcement Act (IAEAA) that
came into force in 1994, and the Antitrust Enforcement Guidelines for International
Operations issued in the same year, formed the basis of so-called second generation
agreements. In the US, cartels constitute a major crime against consumers and are per se
prohibited, and prosecuted under criminal law (see Chapter 2). For this reason, the US
competition authorities possess extensive powers to detect cartels, including the
entitlement to exchange confidential information by law. Transnational corporations
generally seek to avoid US criminal sanctions, the treble damage compensation rule, but
also private enforcement and class actions (see Chapter 2). In the EU, where cartel
prosecution is traditionally less firmly rooted, breaches can only be sanctioned based on
fines. Upon the initiative of the US, in the 1998 OECD Recommendation devoted to
combating hard-core cartels, Member States were encouraged to conclude agreements on
the exchange of confidential information (OECD, 1998). The US authorities entered the
most far-reaching bilateral competition agreement with Australia, which was due to
Australias particular strong confidentiality laws (Calvani, 2004: 6). To date, fierce
lobbying of business associations constitutes the reason why there is no transatlantic
IAEAA-type agreement. Company directors in Europe (and elsewhere) in particular fear
exposure to the US jurisdiction in cartel matters. For corporate actors, the inclusion of a
provision allowing the exchange of confidential information may lead to more hazards
than benefits. Rather than a second-generation agreement that would also make it possible
to cooperate more extensively in the prosecution of cartels, only a non-binding
Administrative Arrangements on Attendance (AAA) was concluded with the US authorities
in 1999.
259
The US authorities proclaimed that sound economic analysis would help to disentangle
trade aspects from competition matters. Substantial efforts were made to streamline
economic thinking across the Atlantic. Over time, Commission officials adopted this view.
Illustrative of this is the declaration by Alexander Schaub, Director General of
Competition, that successful cooperation depends upon rigorous economic analyses based
upon strictly legal rules (Schaub, 1998). Moreover, trade policy issues should not become
entwined with competition issues (ibid). As will be argued in Chapter 8, in the course of a
260
series of reforms, the European competition regime was institutionally transformed and
came to incorporate a broad range of key substantive features from the US competition
model and procedures, such as streamlining the timing of the merger review process. The
DG Competition employed more economists, and fine-tuned microeconometric modelling
replaced the previous, macroeconomic deliberate approach.
261
server operating systems. The Commission fined Microsoft 497 million for abusing its
market power in the EU after five years of investigations the largest antitrust fine ever
imposed by the Commission (but unlikely to hurt Microsoft with US $ 54 billion cash flow
at its disposition) (Smith in Dombey and Waters, 2004). When Microsoft appealed at the
Court of First Instance (CFI), it ruled in December 2004 that Microsoft violated the EU
objective of guaranteeing equal opportunity in market integration when bundling its
Media Player with the Windows Operating System. It ordered that Microsoft had to
disclose complete and accurate specifications for the protocols necessary for its
competitors server products to be able to talk on equal footing with Windows software.
This implied a code removal, which, according to Brad Smith, Microsofts General
Counsel, constitutes the broadest compulsory licensing of intellectual property right since
the EU was founded 50 years ago (Litan and Shapiro, 2001: 55).
Although the DoJ had attacked Microsoft on similar grounds in 1998, US government
officials were furious about the Commissions decision to challenge Microsoft based on
monopoly accusations, which considerably increased tensions in the transatlantic
relationship. Microsoft, which is estimated to spend more than US$ 6 million a year on
lobbying activities in Washington alone, lobbied the US government extensively,
demanding that it increase political pressure in order to convince the Commission, at that
time headed by Mario Monti, to withdraw the case (Pitschner, 2004). US Senator Bill Frist,
a Republican, accused the Commission of threatening the vitality of Americas IT
industry, which touches upon American jobs, American consumers and the American
economy (Hart, 2001: 10). Again, the leverage of US-EU trade disputes emerged into the
picture. In 2002, the Commission and the US antitrust authorities agreed to conduct a joint
investigation procedure (Helmore, 2004). As inconsistent rulings by the EU and the US
authorities could have created uncertainty and higher transaction costs, Microsoft gave its
consent for the transatlantic cooperation endeavour. However, while the US authorities
reached a comprehensive settlement with Microsoft in 2002, the Commission did not. It
continued to prosecute Microsoft for having abused its dominance by tying the Windows
Media Player to Windows, and in 2006 it imposed another fine of 280,5 million on
Microsoft for failing to comply with the 2004 decision. Thereby, the Commission went
against a prior decision of the US authorities and neglected the positive comity agreement.
Microsoft appealed again at the CFI, which supported the Commissions ruling on 17
September 2007, after nine years of arduous investigations. The company agreed to
262
comply with the ruling of the CFI and announced to take concrete steps to provide
competitors with the demanded access to its technology. In the view of US antitrust
authorities, the approach taken by the EU reconfirmed the view that it attempts to protect
competitors, rather than competition (see previous sections). Thomas Barnett, head of the
DoJs Antitrust Division, reacted on the ruling by saying that it had unfortunate
consequences of harming consumers by chilling innovatrion and discouraging competition
(in FT, 2007: 8). According to the Chicagoan single goal orientation of efficiency gains,
and hence, consumer welfare, that is prevailing in the US, competition policy should not
protect smaller companies from competition by larger companies.
The McDonnell Douglas merger, the GE-Honeywell merger, and the Microsoft case are
illustrative for the political limits of bilateral cooperation in competition matters across the
Atlantic. These high-profile cases brought the differences in approaches to the fore, and
increased tensions between the EU and the US competition authorities. Consequently, the
European Commission put much effort in the conclusion of multilateral competition
agreement, as the next chapter demonstrates.
263
Chapter 7
The Politics of the Multilateral Trajectory:
The Convergence Crusade of EU and US Competition Authorities
The greatest long-term challenge in terms of convergence will be the task of managing
the worldwide proliferation of antitrust regimes. Many of these regimes are very new, and
we both the EU and US need to be advocating that competition policy should be used to
foster competition, and not as a protectionist instrument, as an instrument of old-fashioned
industrial policy, as an instrument of social policy, or whatever.
Alexander Schaub, Director-General for Competition at the European Commission (2002a: 12)
Introduction
Competition policy gathered political momentum in the 1990s when it reached the global
agenda. In the road-levelling process towards the formalisation of a binding multilateral
agreement on competition within the institutional setting of the World Trade Organisation
(WTO), the European Commission positioned itself at the fore. A sequence of staunch
proponents of the neoliberal free-market ideology at the DG Competition campaigned to
establish a comprehensive competition culture on a global scale. What started with the
energetic Commissioners Peter Sutherland and Thatcherite Sir Leon Brittan (1989-1995),
continued with Karel van Miert (1995-1999) and Mario Monti (1999-2004). By means of
the multilateral trajectory, the Commissions DG Competition sought to transpose the
subsequent subordination of EU competition policy to neoliberal ideas onto a global level.
The idea of establishing multilateral competition rules at the WTO was formed in the
context of the larger geopolitical transformations of the early 1990s and the finalisation of
the Uruguay Round, two important historical circumstances that fostered belief in opening
up markets to competition and removing barriers to trade. Alongside the subsequent
reduction of government imposed tariff and non-tariff barriers, so-called 'private barriers to
trade' were identified as the most important problem needing to be solved.
The impetus found its origins in the quest of the same transnational business elite that
demanded enhanced transatlantic cooperation in competition matters (see Chapter 6).
Against the backdrop of the breathtaking pace in which structural economic developments
made it easier for companies to transnationalise and engage concentration activities and
265
other kinds of commercial intercompany transactions, private market barriers and state aid
measures for domestic companies inhibited free-market access for TNCs and the
possibilities of expansion into new product and labour markets. Moreover, the growing
number of domestic competition regimes around the world, particularly the adoption of
merger controlling laws, enhanced the problems resulting from multi-jurisdictional
overlaps, and hence imposed additional transaction costs on TNCs. As a broad-scale
harmonisation of national competition laws was not a viable option, hopes were cherished
that, by the establishment of WTO competition rules, national laws and review procedures
would at least converge. The transnational business elite, most of whom had their
headquarters in the OECD world, found a committed ally in the Commissions DG
Competition for exporting the free-market logic to the global realm. The initiatives for a
multilateral agreement began to take shape in 1996 when competition was declared one of
the Singapore Issues at the Singapore Ministerial Conference of the WTO, together with
three other market-making policy issues, such as trade and investment, transparency in
government procurement and trade facilitation. The subsequent proliferation of non-tariff
related issue-linkages, so-called trade and issues within the WTO meant the
conclusion of an agreement on competition rules appeared to be within striking distance. In
September 2003 at the Cancn Ministerial Conference of the WTO, however, the project
of multilateralising competition rules experienced an embarrassing downturn. Due to fierce
opposition from the US authorities, and a number of developing countries, albeit for
different reasons, the idea of a binding global competition agreement was abandoned.
This chapter explains why the EU proposal arrived at the WTO, which social forces
supported this process and their reasons for doing so. Established accounts explaining the
Commissions multilateral endeavours tend to suggest that competition regulators desired
convergence of competition laws as a means to increase international cooperation in areas
under their discretionary authority (Damro, 2006b: 869). In contrast to this view, this
chapter demonstrates that the reason why the Commission sought to craft a common
understanding on competition principles around the world needs to be understood in the
context of transnationally operating companies seeking worldwide market access for
goods, services, and capital. Commission officials embraced the desire of TNCs to
institutionalise free competition as a means of ensuring the right to compete, and hence,
the right to access new markets. This chapter starts with a brief walk through the history of
attempts to multilateralise rules on competition. There were many initiatives for the
266
267
the remaining barriers seemed tangible, including barriers to free competition. Moreover,
the larger geopolitical transformations, caused by the breakdown of the Soviet Regime in
the early 1990s, fostered the belief that the logics of free competition were to be
orchestrated in the multilateral realm. In the early 1990s, a group of foremost German
academics and practitioners located in Munich submitted the Draft International Antitrust
Code (DIAC) to the GATT Member States.
The DIAC proposal received careful thought in the Marrakech Agreement on the
establishment of what later became the World Trade Organisation (WTO). However, it did
not create the necessary enthusiasm within the international community. Much of the
criticism pointed to the DIACs far-reaching regulatory approach and the strict cartel
268
With the solid support of their business communities, our governments can speed up on
international negotiations.
7.2 The Transnational Business Elite Setting the Agenda for a Multilateral
Competition Agreement
The transnational business community had a stake in reducing negative policy externalities
arising from cross-border transactions not only in the transatlantic realm, but also on a
global scale. Priority agenda points were: the harmonisation or convergence of the
different national procedures in the clearance of mergers and acquisitions, and the creation
of free-market access through the institutionalisation of competition laws on a global scale.
The interest in harmonisation or convergence is inherently linked to the fact that
competition regimes proliferated around the globe, and multijurisdictional overlaps
became more common. In 1989, only 31 countries had competition laws, of which 20 were
situated in the industrialised OECD world and 11 in the developing world (Schoneveld,
2003: 434). Today, there are nearly a hundred states that have adopted competition laws
and about 70 countries require a pre-merger notification. According to estimates, in 2010
there will be 110 countries with some sort of a competition regime (Gavil et al., 2002: 59).
More than 60% of all competition regimes were introduced during the 1990s, mostly by
developing countries, and another 20 countries are still in the process of adopting
competition laws (ICPAC, 2000: 33 in Damro, 2004: 12). Competition regimes emerged
269
foremost in South American countries, marking a wide gap with most African countries
(except for Zambia, Gabon, and South Africa) and much of Asia. South American and
Caribbean countries even went as far as to establish regional cooperation agreements on
competition, i.e. Mercosur, the Andean Community, and the Caribbean Community and
Common Market, in short, Caricom (cf. Lee and Morand, 2003).
270
The TABD, the ERT, UNICE and AmCham, as well as the ICC constituted the choir of
transnational corporate interests. The ICC, involving more than 7,000 member companies
and business associations from over 130 countries, including law firms and other
professional service companies, evolved into a triumphant lobbyist for global economic
deregulation in fora such as the WTO, the G8, the OECD, as well as UNCTAD (cf. Carrol
and Carson, 2006). In 1994 at the ERT Summit in Essen, Germany, ERT members urged
the political leaders of the EU, among which the Commission, to consider a more outward
focus on EU competition policy. Holding exceptionally privileged access points to the
European Commission, it set the agenda, together with the TABD. Together, they
articulated their wish for more consistency in global economic transactions and to extend
the coverage of the WTO to additional relevant areas, such as competition policy in order
to address structural impediments to market access which foreign investors might come
across (ERT, 1996b; TABD, 1996). They demanded that the EU and the US authorities
take the lead and to make joint efforts within the WTO to harmonise strong and effective
competition laws (TABD, 1995: Section II.13 and II.14). As free trade and free
competition were both deeply entangled areas of economic regulation, they advocated the
establishment of a WTO committee on trade and competition policy at the Singapore
Ministerial Conference (Business Law Europe, 1996). The transnational business elite
were motivated by the fact that, in addition to conventional tariff barriers to free trade,
barriers that impeded free competition created an obstacle to corporate expansion and thus
the achievement of a competitive market position. It wanted to expand onto a worldwide
scale what in Eurojargon was formulated as creating a level playing field. The process of
market liberalisation in Europe should not take shape in isolation, but be fortified by an
energetic commitment to a free-market environment by the rest of the world in order to
allow free-market access to natural resources and new geographical product markets. In a
report, the ERT spelled out its claim as follows:
The world economy is the proving ground. Industry wants a strong Europe in a growing
world economy, which cannot be achieved by building a fortress closed against our
neighbours. The largest companies of the European Round Table operate on a global scale
and can clearly identify the causes of declining competitiveness. [] Industry [...] expects
more open access to world markets, in return for giving our competitors better access to
the Single Market in Europe. (ERT, 1993: 10, 14)
271
The transnational business community had a stark interest in the removal of cartels and
private restrictive practices in domestic market settings. Even though tariff barriers were
low, transnational business representatives regularly complained about the closed Japanese
and Korean markets (The Economist, 1994: 55). For example, in Japan, foreign producers
were restricted from entering Japanese markets by an extensive quota system, tariffs, and
special technical and administrative import requirements (Ruigrok and Van Tulder, 1995:
42). In addition, lax enforcement of competition laws, biased regulation in the banking
and insurance sector, biased production, distribution and retailing networks, and other
restrictive private practices were also identified as major barriers to entering the Japanese
market (FT, 1993k: 2). Similarly, it urged the abolition of protectionist policies promoting
national champions, or policies that used the cloak of patriotism or national security to
prevent overseas investment (Draghi, 2003: 10-11). In addition to the removal of
regulatory and private market barriers, the transnational business community also had a
strong interest in significantly eliminating the potential for conflicts arising from
extraterritorial competition law enforcement. The TABD urged the US and EU
governments to cooperate closely with the private sector in order to arrive at the most
constructive approach in the promotion of a better understanding of the relationship
between competition policy and the issues significant market access in the WTO (TABD,
1996). It also reminded the US and the EU authorities to work closely with the private
sector in order to develop the most constructive approach to this issue (TABD, 1996: 7).
Even though the US Department of Commerce established and nurtured the TABD in
collaboration with the Commission (see Chapter 6), over time the TABDs alliance with
the Commission became much stronger, and the TABD even located its office near the
Commissions headquarters in Brussels. The Commission stressed the TABDs role in
setting priorities in the EUs WTO agenda (CEO, 1999c). As the next section illustrates,
the Commission took the transnational business elites demands to multilateralise
competition policy seriously.
7.3 A Role to Play by the European Commission: Taking the Initiative in the 1990s
The developments in the 1990s demonstrated that competition policy became one of the
EUs most formidable international powers (Damro, 2006b: 868). Commissioner Brittans
opening speech at the Cartel Conference of 19 June in 1990 hosted by the
272
The fall of the Berlin Wall, and the expansion of market capitalism in the CEECs, led to a
missionary wave of activities in which the European Commission actively sought to export
its competition laws into new regions of the world. Similarly, in the run-up to the North
American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA), US antitrust officials from the DoJ and the
FTC targeted their efforts at bringing the competition regimes of Canada and Mexico more
in line with the US model. Assisted by the competition task force of the American Bar
Association (ABA), the US competition authorities also sent out antitrust specialists to
abroad for longer periods of time to exert substantial influence in building up competition
regimes from scratch around the world. Together, the EU and US competition authorities
were involved in building up nearly 100 competition jurisdictions in emerging markets
273
worldwide (Gavil et al., 2002: 4; Djelic and Kleiner, 2003: 8). In the early 1990s, the
Commissions focus was primarly on training officials from candidate countries awaiting
EU accession. Through various cooperation or association agreements, the Commission
expanded its global reach and provided technical assistance in newly emerging competition
regimes in North African, the Baltic and Mediterranean countries, Latin and Central
American, and Asian countries (Gerber, 2002: 134). The Commission organised
conferences and held seminars promoting competition policy as the centrepiece of a
smooth functioning of a capitalist market in modern societies, and outlining basic
economic concepts and theories on the workings of free and open markets (Ehlermann,
1995). Financed by the PHARE programme, it trained competition practioners and
organised the exchange of staff. In the Europe Agreements, the existence of competition
laws and effective enforcement were made one of the core preconditions for candidate
countries awaiting EU accession, together with the restoration of private ownership, the
introduction of company laws, rules on bankruptcy and liquidation of companies, the
liberalisation of prices, trade and FDI (Commission, 1995a). The Commission claimed that
the EU competition regime provided a useful model for the accession countries and
demanded an approximation of the national competition laws of the CEECs to the EC law
(ibid).
274
European model was preferred because of its more egalitarian competition standards and
the greater concern for the protection of small and medium-sized companies, as well as the
flexibility in achieving both economical, political, social goals that go beyond achieving
greater efficiency (Jenny, 2002: 297).
7.3.1 Substantiating the Initiative: The 1995 Karel van Miert Report
In June 1994, Commissioner Karel van Miert assigned a group of Wise Men with the
mandate to come up with a possible framework for a multilateral agreement on
competition. The subsequent Wise Men Report of July 1995, or Karel van Miert Report
as it was also called, was officially titled Competition Policy in the New Trade Order:
Strengthening International Cooperation and Rules (European Commission, 1995a). Wise
Men groups became a common mechanism for drafting policy innovations in the EU
setting. Van Mierts group was constituted foremost by the staff of the DG Competition,
among whom was senior-level staff such as Director-General Claus-Dieter Ehlermann
(1990-1995) and Assistant Director General Jean-Franois Pons (1994-2002). In order to
keep up the appearance of an independent expert report, it was emphasised that the Wise
Men group was independent (European Commission, 1996b). It entailed the usual
disclaimer that this report represented the views of the group of experts and did not bind
the Commission (ibid: 1,22). Three independent experts joined Van Mierts Wise Men.
Among the external experts were Ulrich Immenga from the Munich Group, which had
come up with the DIAC proposal, Frdric Jenny, Professor of Economics and member of
the French competition authority, as well as Ernst-Ulrich Petersmann, Professor of
Economics at the University of St. Gallen, Switzerland (ibid: 23). Similarly to the Munich
275
Group, the strong German (ordoliberal) representation in the Wise Men Group was
notable.43
Van Miert realised that at this stage a worldwide and independent competition agency in
the form of a World Competition Authority (WCA) was not feasible (FT, 1993k: 2). The
signatories of a multilateral agreement would not accept such far-reaching constraints on
national sovereignty. Van Miert therefore emphasised the establishment of minimum
competition rules in the first place. The Wise Men proposal served as a blueprint for the
EU to take the lead in setting competition rules on the agenda at the WTO's Ministerial
Conference in Singapore in December 1996. Together with his predecessor Brittan, van
Miert modified the 25-page long Wise Men Report and presented it to the Council (see
Brittan and Van Miert, 1996). Rather than a full-scale harmonisation of competition rules,
the Commission advised to strengthen international cooperation between competition
authorities and a first harmonisation of certain national rules and procedures (ibid: 3,
emphasis added). It recommended a gradual construction of a plurilateral agreement on a
set of jointly determined competition rules (ibid: 12-15). The signatories would initially
only include the worlds major trading partners and then expand in membership in a tierlike fashion. At a later stage, the founding members would decide upon an institutional
framework for a new international body to conciliate and arbitrate in the event of disputes
and differences (ibid: 10).44
In addition to the German Claus-Dieter Ehlermann, Ulrich Immenga and Ernst-Ulrich Petersmann were
heavyweights in competition matters, looking back on an extensive record of work experience in competition
authorities and international fora. Mr. Petersmann studied economics among others at the University of
Freiburg, the ordoliberal core. He later worked as Consultant Legal Adviser from 1990 onwards in the
GATT/WTO Secretariat and participated or chaired six GATT/WTO dispute settlement panels.
44
The report identified the following countries as the potential signatories: US, Canada, Australia and New
Zealand, EU and the countries of the EEA and CEECs, Japan and other Asian industrialised countries such
as Hong Kong, Singapore, and Taiwan, as well as the most advanced Latin American countries
(European Commission, 1995b: 15-16).
276
Brittan made this idea more explicit. They promoted the WTO as the most appropriate
forum as it included a system of transparency and surveillance through notification
requirements and monitoring provisions (Brittan and Van Miert, 1996). In addition to the
first phase of the plurilateral trajectory, the Commission advised deepening the existing
bilateral competition agreements. This meant the Commission continuing on its path,
particularly by increasing technical assistance in the establishment of competition laws and
procedures in the CEECS, the Newly Independent States (NIS), and Russia.
The recommendations of the Wise Men Report were essentially European in nature, in
terms of both substance and form. Like the historical evolution of the EU, the plurilateral
competition agreement should have a domino effect and progressively expand its
coverage in terms of member states, substance, and surveillance competences of the
international body (ibid: 22). At the same time, the report sought to avoid cumbersome
processes for coming to terms with signatories. Those sharing an interest in proceeding
with a competition agreement could do so, while others were free to opt out (ibid: 22).
Thereby, single signatories could not block multilateral decision making, a notion that
draws directly on the EUs experience with integration. Concerning the substance of the
rules, the report was quite straightforward. Although a few passages referred to
consensus and jointly determined principles, it suggested shaping the common
competition rules on existing EC laws and enforcement procedures. More specifically,
dominant market positions were to be ruled according to a regime similar to that of
Article 82 (TEC) (ibid: 17).
277
7.3.2 The Unimpaired Market Access Rationale of the Wise Men Report
The rationales outlined in the report for why a multilateral agreement was necessary,
reflect the core interests of TNCs. In line with the transnational business elite, it declared
the phenomenon of multijurisdictional overlap a pressing problem that constituted a major
barrier to the expansion of trade and investment and highlighted the high transaction costs
and increasing uncertainties suffered by companies operating on a transnational scale. It
spelled out that also lax or non-enforcement of competition law worked as a barrier. In
addition, the report identified potential conflicts as a major obstacle, which may emerge
from the practice of extraterritorial competition law enforcement. Thereby, it explicitly
referred to the US practice of imposing its own competition laws on an extraterritorial
basis as a highly distorting gesture. Furthermore, it problematised the absence or weak
competition law enforcement practices of developing countries, which after the further
liberalisation of trade found themselves exposed to increased anticompetitive practices and
interference by other countries enforcing their laws extraterritorially (European
Commission, 1995b: 3-4).
278
The issues not taken up in the report also reflect the compelling influence of the
transnational business community. There was no mentioning of limiting corporate
concentration by a merger control regime on a global scale. This is remarkable as
Commissioner van Miert once noted that the increasing concentration in certain industries
posed a threat to the idea of free markets and thus formed one of the central reasons for a
multilateral agreement on competition. He said: "One of the dangers ahead of us is that we
will end up with private monopolies or companies with dominant monopolies worldwide."
(Van Miert in FT, 1998i: 4) Aware of the fact that attacking corporate size in the WTO
framework was not a feasible option, he estimated that negotiations on monopolies and
vertical restraints would take longer, while an international agreement could easily be
reached in the field of horizontal restrictions, such as: price and output fixing, market
sharing, bid rigging and export cartels (Van Miert, 1998c: 20). The head of the German
Bundeskartellamt, an adherent of ordoliberal ideas, also suggested building an
international body that would control large-scale cross-border mergers. With the mergers
between Deutsche Bank and the US Bankers Trust, and Daimler-Benz and Chrysler in
mind, he warned that some mergers were too big for national bodies and also also a size
too big for European merger control authorities (FT, 1998b: 3). The issue of
concentration, however, remained unmentioned in the report. At a later stage, van Miert
called the report prudent and pragmatic, which indicates that he might have envisaged
going much further (Van Miert, 1998a: 6).
279
trade balance. Furthermore, they can prohibit foreigners from controlling strategic
industries, such as coastal shipping lines, oil pipelines, domestic airlines, or broadcasting
networks (The Economist, 1996: 80). In the course of the 1990s, a range of governments
concluded bilateral investment treaties to facilitate foreign corporate activities. For
example, in 1994 OECD countries concluded nearly 600 bilateral investment treaties with
developing countries (The Economist, 1994: 55). A multilateral investment agreement at
the WTO, according to transnational corporations, would lead to one common
denominator in the rules regulating market access for foreign investors, and hence,
facilitate mergers and acquisitions. This becomes particularly apparent when taking into
account that FDI flows mainly proceed by mergers and acquisitions. In terms of value, the
ratio of mergers and acquisitions of FDI in the 1990s amounted to 80%, and occasionally
even 90% (cf. UNCTAD, 2000).
The Commissions efforts took shape in an ideological climate in which neoliberal market
views were dominant. Therefore, the incorporation of competition rules within the remit of
the WTO need to be understood as an attempt to consolidate the idea of global free
markets, trade liberalisation, and worldwide economic integration. In that sense, the
expansionary drifts of the Commission epitomise a further phase of construction in the
280
The overall subordination of competition policy to open markets and the guarantee of
legal certainty, consistency, predictability, and an absence of regulatory arbitrariness
represent the stark interests of transnational corporations. In fact, the Commission received
direct instructions from the transnational business community. The TABD issued an
Implementation Table in 1998 with recommendations on how to proceed in the WTO and
the Commission assured its full support to the recommendations of the TABD. It
concluded that nearly all WTO items identified by the TABD have been taken up (TABD
Implementation Table 1998: Working Document by the Commission Services, referred to
in: CEO, 1999c).
The Commission internalised the requests of the transnational business elite and portrayed
divergence or inconsistent competition law enforcement as a burden to international
commerce and global competition (Pitofsky, 1998). Therefore, the rationale for a
281
References to equal opportunities served the purpose of justifying the free-market access
objective. For the sake of competition, governments should treat foreign competitors on
the same terms as domestic market players. However, small and medium-sized enterprises
face difficulties living up to the competition standards set by large and powerful TNCs.
Ignorant of this fact, the Commission sided with the interests of TNCs. According to
Helmut Maucher, CEO of Nestl and former ERT and ICC president, local industry
should not be scared of TNCs moving in newly-opened markets it might be tough at
first, but later they will be stronger and more competitive (in CEO, 1998a).
The reason why the idea for a multilateral competition agreement initially found a
sympathetic ear at the WTO headquarters was the particular configuration of successive
Competition Commissioners holding important strategic positions in both the industry and
international organisations. Competition Commissioner Sir Leon Brittan was a committed
neoliberal who not only set a new course for the Commissions endeavours, but also
engineered his own career. After heading the DG Competition, he took over the newly
established external trade portfolio and became chiefly responsible for the GATT/WTO
negotiations. As Trade Commissioner, he continued to proclaim the necessity of
introducing a multilateral agreement on competition laws and for subjecting such laws to a
sanctioning mechanism (The Economist, 1998a: 14).45 Brittans immediate predecessor,
Commissioner Sutherland (1985-1989), after his tenure took over the position of the
45
After his ten-year tenure at the European Commission (1989-1999), he job hopped to the investment
bank UBS Warburg, where he became vice-chairman. In addition, he worked as a consultant on competition
policy, especially on mergers and state aid, as well as on WTO issues and market access issues at the private
law company Herbert Smith, and at Unilever, where he became Advising Director. Since 2001, Brittan works
as chairman of the LOTIS Committee of International Financial Services London (IFSL), a lobby group
representing the British financial sector (Hoedeman, 2002).
282
GATT/WTO Director-General (1993-1995), from where he backed up the proposal for the
conclusion of a multilateral competition agreement (FT, 1998i: 4). The successive DGs
under Karel van Miert and Mario Monti, adopted the idea of establishing a multilateral
agreement on competition rules. Moreover, Claus-Dieter Ehlermann, who contributed to
the drafting of the Wise Men Report in 1995, was transferred to the WTOs Appellate
Body in Geneva in December 1995, where he worked until 2001, where he became chair
in the last year of his mandate before he switched to a private law company. Therefore, the
particular configuration of former Commissioners in strategic posts not only facilitated the
political momentum to set competition policy on the WTO agenda, but also contributed to
the particular enmeshment between corporate and political elites.
The prospects for a multilateral agreement on a common set of principles for national
competition policies looked gloomy from the outset. The Member States could not agree
which components of competition control should be discussed (FT, 1996d: 6). The
proposal for setting up an international framework for competition rules, however, was not
the thorniest issue on the agenda. Nonetheless, controversies loomed large. US scepticism
and the opposition of a few developing countries eventually led to a rather weak mandate
for the Working Group, which merely entailed to study issues raised by Members relating
to the interaction between trade and competition policy, including anticompetitive
practices, in order to identify any areas that may merit further consideration in the WTO
framework (WTO, 1996). The EU received considerable political backing from the
Japanese government. Prior to that, the Commission organised joint seminars with
European and Japanese competition authorities, lawyers, and academics (FT, 1993e: 36).
283
The US on the contrary, blamed the EU and Japan for distracting attention away from the
liberalisation of trade in agricultural products. The reduction of tariffs and non-tariff
barriers to trade in the agricultural sectors constituted one of the most pressing agenda
points of the US, and other leading exporters of agricultural products, such as Australia,
Brazil, and Canada. The EU negotiators, however, insisted on what in Eurolingo came to
be termed ABA, an acronym for anything but agriculture, a stance broadly supported
by other WTO Members with a highly protected agricultural sector, such as Japan,
Norway, South Korea and Switzerland (The Economist, 1999). The overwhelmingly profree market attitude in the Council of Ministers bolstered the free marketeers at the
Commission. In particular, the broad political backing of the Northern EU Member States
for an aggressive EU approach in launching the preparations for a new trade
liberalisation round at the WTO Ministerial Conference in Singapore in December 1996.
After an informal meeting of EU trade ministers in Dublin in September 1996,
Commissioner Brittan declared:
There was a clear orientation on the part of ministers that Europe should take a positive
forward line, that Europe should take the lead. It seems to me a very fundamental
watershed that we have passed today. (In FT, 1996a: 6).
A series of reports and conferences followed, in which the Commission tried to persuade
the Council, the international community of competition authorities, legal experts, and
private practitioners of the need for a multilateral agreement on competition rules. At the
Annual Conference of the Fordham Law Institute in 1997, one of the most prominent
platforms where leading experts and competition practitioners discuss the future course of
competition policy, van Miert announced that the EU will play a full part in persuading
the Members States of the WTO of the merits of a framework for competition rules. He
suggested a core of common principles, positive comity provisions as a positive
alternative to the extraterritorial application of competition rules, and a dispute settlement
mechanism for clearly specified circumstances (Van Miert, 1997).
The Commissions rationale for taking a proactive role advocating a global competition
regime extended much further than this. It is novel that, in the global political history of
the post-war world, this time the major protagonist taking the lead in further configuring
the free-market system was of European origin. The US authorities, the founding fathers of
the Bretton Woods institutions, seemed to have resigned as active proponents of
284
As a result of far-reaching disagreements, the Working Groups first report in 1998 lacked
the necessary vigour to substantiate serious negotiations (WTO, 1998). In 1999, at the
WTO Summit in Seattle in November 1999 Commissioner Mario Monti strongly
advocated expanding the mandate of the Working Group on Trade and Competition to go
beyond the stage of studying the interaction between trade and competition policy. This,
however did not prove to be successful (Monti, 2002a: 81). In addition, the TABD,
especially US business, became more sceptical about the success of negotiations over
competition policy in the WTO (CEO, 1999b). In order to avoid a stalemate, the
Commission tempered its proposal considerably. Whereas it had initially envisaged a
detailed and binding competition agreement subject to the WTOs dispute settlement
mechanism, the emphasis shifted to reaching a voluntary WTO agreement on common
basic principles for national competition authorities, which were intended as a means to
strengthen the stance of competition authorities in domestic settings around the globe. At
the subsequent Ministerial Conference in Doha, Qatar, in November 2001, the competition
agreement was declared a long-term objective.
Consistent lobbying by the Commission accounts for the reason why the competition issue
had not yet been dropped. Nothing had been decided yet, except that multilateral rules on
competition had been made a long-term objective and that the negotiations on the
Singapore Issues were postponed until the Fifth Ministerial Conference at Cancn,
Mexico, during 11-14 September 2003. In its final report, the WTOs Competition
Working Group recommended merely some loosely defined core principles. It entailed
stipulations on the transparency of rules and regulations and a provision on non-
285
286
Presidency could not generate the necessary support of US Congress for the trade and
liberalisation projects. Clinton even tried to prolong the fast-track authority that Congress
granted for the Uruguay Round of the GATT negotiations, which would have obligated US
Congress to approve or reject trade agreements without any further amendments. He did
not get the support of Congress for his quest. Rather than a comprehensive commitment to
multilateralism, the US authorities nevertheless wanted to raise awareness about the
necessity of establishing a culture of competition control and more procedural and
substantive consistency. According to Joel Klein, US Assistant Attorney General for
Antitrust of the DoJ:
What is needed is to develop an international culture of sound antitrust enforcement, built
on the basis of shared experience, bilateral co-operation and technical assistance to
countries just starting down this road. (In FT, 1998e: 20)
US officials did not share the EUs enthusiasm for the WTO as the principal coordinating
body, even though the Commission tried to convince its US colleagues of WTO
competition rules on several occasions (FT, 1993k: 2). US opposition was deeply rooted,
due to a combination of reasons. Primarily, the US hegemonic approach in enforcing its
own competition laws extraterritorially did not immediately create a pressing need to
conclude a multilateral agreement (see Chapter 6). As a commentator remarked, the US
competition regime has long been the only show in town (Jenny, 1998: 7), and US
officials held the view that global competition laws were to be defined in Washington and
in Washington only. Cooperation and coordination in competition matters should take
place under the leadership of the Department of Justice as they were the folks who should
take the lead (Pitofsky, 2002: 59). Moreover, convergence by law would be an aspiration,
it was just not going to happen (ibid: 58). The US system was considered simply the best
and most effective (Drn and Wilks, 1996: 308).46 As Joel Klein explained to his
European colleagues:
Looking-glass, looking-glass, on the wall, who in this Land is the fairest of all? In a survey carried out by
the Global Competition Review (see www.globalcompetitionreview.com), a specialist journal, on behalf of
the DoJ and the FTC, thousands of competition lawyers and economists rated antitrust enforcement in 25
countries. In a report published in July 2002, they identified the US authorities as the only five star
authorities in the world, well ahead of their counterparts in the EU. The US agencies were the most
sophisticated in the world (Guerrera, 2002a), while the European Commission was positioned third with the
Italian and the Australian enforcers, after Germany, the UK and France. The lack of a business-orientated
career on the Commissions staff was the reason for the relatively low ranking. The report noted that the
Commission can therefore be particularly frustrating to deal with (ibid). In 2003, the Global Competition
Review issued a new survey based on more than 500 questionnaires from business groups, legal departments,
and the competition authorities themselves. This time the Commission was identified as one of the best of the
46
287
If you want a perfect solution, there is only one perfect solution, one that I havent been
able to persuade anybody to adopt, and that is to let the United States Department of
Justice do global enforcement! [] (I)t would be terribly efficient. [] And my friends at
the Federal Trade Commission, Im sure would be the first people to support this idea.
(Klein, 2002: 338)
The different competition law enforcement practices across the Atlantic spurred US
reservations in this regard. The Boeing-McDonnell Douglas, the GE-Honeywell, and the
Microsoft controversies reinforced US scepticism (see Chapter 6), but Frances overly
supportive industrial policy also raised concerns. The recurring US critique was that the
EU competition regime was outlined in order to protect competitors, rather than
competition (Fox, 2003a). If these differences were to be played out on a global scale,
trade relations were expected to be further politicised. US competition authorities had a
world, although still below that of the US, Germany, and the UK. Respondents declared that the
Commissions work was 99% sound (Dombey, 2003a). The US regime was declared better at economics and
less instinctively interventionist (ibid).
288
marked interest in keeping competition control uncontaminated from trade issues (cf. Drn
and Wilks, 1996; Varney, 1996; Schoneveld, 2003). After all, the argument was,
competition issues were deemed too complex to allow interference from trade authorities.
As WTO rules did not directly address company behaviour, but rather Member State
administrations instead, the risk of an international body interfering with the rulings would
have damaged the reputation of a longstanding pundit in trust-busting such as the US (FT,
1998h: 4). In particular, the prospect of having to cope with the diplomatic style of career
diplomats at the WTOs permanent missions in Geneva was out of the question for an
agency that had previously been used to a hegemonic approach in competition matters
(Schoneveld, 2003: 465). On systemic grounds, the US model of private enforcement in
antitrust matters (see Chapter 2) would have implied that US courts had to deal with
private lawsuits referring to WTO rules. As private parties do not have access to the
WTOs dispute settlement mechanism, this scenario was rather realistic. Therefore, US
authorities did not want to lose control over the future direction of competition law
enforcement and politicise competition cases by having an international body ruling
against the decisions of the Federal competition authorities. As numerous other cases
demonstrate, this fits into the broader picture of US aversion to multilateral agreements.47
Similarly, even when the US government delegated powers to the WTO, it always ensured
that US Federal law would enjoy supremacy over WTO agreements. For example, the US
Uruguay Round Agreements Act stipulated that no provision inconsistent with any law of
the Unites States shall have effect (Section 102 (a) (1)).
The US authorities announced they could not agree on a multilateral regime until there was
more convergence in enforcement of existing national laws and more experience was
gained in cooperative enforcement efforts between national authorities (Pitofsky, 1995).
Political resistance to a centralised multilateral competition agreement within the WTOs
setting also came from a range of developing countries, although for different reasons.
Examples are: International Criminal Court (ICC) (2002), Kyoto Protocol (1997), Mine Ban Treaty
(1997), Comprehensive Test Ban Treaty (1996), Rio Pact on Biodiversity (1992), Protocol Against Child
Soldiers (1989), proposed Protocol (verification regime) Biological Weapons Convention (1975) and the
ABM Protocol (1972).
47
289
7.5.2 The Neoliberal Bias Revisited: Opposition from the Developing World
At the WTO negotiations in Cancn, more than 70 WTO Members from the developing
world fiercely opposed the Singapore Issues, i.e. trade and investment, trade and
competition, transparency in government procurement, and trade facilitation. The
Ministerial Conference collapsed after only four days and the EU had to drop the proposal
for a multilateral competition agreement. The reason why competition issues had survived
the previous Doha Round can be ascribed to the inclusion of provisions on technical
assistance to developing countries in the core principles (Lee, 2005: 23). A few African
countries brought forth a paper, called the Kenyan paper, outlining their unwillingness to
negotiate on the Singapore Issues in August 2003. They noted that the benefits of
negotiating a multilateral framework for each of these issues were not evident to them
and that many developing countries, which were already grappling with the
implementation of existing WTO rules, had scarce resources to meaningfully negotiate
these issues (WTO, 2003a). Even though the developing world did not form a monolithic
block with regard to the Singapore Issues, a range of other developing countries joined the
position of the African countries. In addition to the fact that competition rules were not a
priority agenda point, a common critique was that the inclusion of a WTO competition
agreement constituted a Trojan Horse for further importing market liberalisation and was
thereby an instrument of neo-colonialism from the Western world. The non-discrimination
clause included in the final report of the Singapore Competition Working Group gave rise
to concerns as it disproportionally benefited large transnational corporate interests.
290
rules, the Singapore Working Group on Trade and Investment included provisions such as
the of right of establishment by foreigners through FDI and national treatment, which
would have equipped foreign companies with the same rights and duties as national
companies.
The
non-discrimination
clause
would
have
provided
transnational
corporations, which overwhelmingly originate in the wealthy OECD world, with their
desired level-playing field. Free-market access to valuable natural resources, new products
and cheap labour markets, as well as new markets for corporate control through mergers
and acquisitions, would have allowed transnationally-operating corporations to
consolidate their position further in the world market. The draft proposal at the WTO
ignored the fact that free competition and free investment triggered structural inequalities
in economic power between companies in the developed and developing world.
Companies in developing countries do not have similar access to capital, marketing and
distribution networks, or general expertise. Dominant new competitors can oust smaller
indigenous competitors out of the domestic market and extinguish competition in the end.
The prospects for sustainable economic development eventually worsen, and the prospects
for these companies to compete globally become few and far between.
The non-discrimination clause also raised opposition from the Korean government, which
sought to negotiate exemption rules, particularly considering many of the industrialised
WTO Members already had long-standing exemption regimes in place (WTO WGTCP,
2002a). The Thai government advocated a special and differential treatment of the core
principles of competition policy for developing countries (WTO WGTCP, 2003), and the
Indian government called for differential treatment of domestic companies with regard to
the large transnational corporations (WTO WGTCP, 2002b). In addition, a range of WTO
Members feared that even though the competition agreement had a plurilateral character,
at a later stage those not signing could be confronted with coercive pressure to comply
anyway, either by other Member governments or by investors (World Development
Movement, 2003). Rather than discussing competition policy within the WTO, a range of
developing countries suggested UNCTAD, which was generally more open towards the
interests of developing countries, as a more appropriate forum for discussing competition
rules (FT, 1996e: 6).
That the WTO proposal of core competition principles entailed a political bias in favour of
creating market access for transnational corporations, was also reflected in the issues
291
deliberately excluded from the agenda, such as the prosecution of export cartels and
antidumping practices. A range of developing countries announced that they would not
support the inclusion of competition rules unless they included a discussion on the
prohibition of antidumping policy, which was mostly applied by industrialised countries
to restrict cheap imports (FT, 1998h: 4). WTO rules allowed Member governments to
impose duties on imports sold below the price of the home market or the costs of
production (Artis and Finger, 1993; Marceau, 1995). Proponents of antidumping rules
typically argue that cheap imports flooding national markets eventually reduce
competition, as they undercut prices of domestic producers and drive them out of the
market, and hence, provide the new foreign company with a possibility to raise its prices
again and earn back the losses from dumping products below the normal price. Critics, in
sharp contrast, hold that antidumping rules are simply a guise for market protectionism,
which fences off import competition and market access. In fact, after the completion of
the Uruguay Round, when import duties or quotas were no real option anymore,
antidumping rules had to do the job instead. Antidumping practices have become a
popular way of complaining about the unfairness of foreigners for an industry seeking
protection from imports, particularly as the categorisation of a practice as dumping is
always based on arbitrary decisions and as comparisons between prices across borders are
difficult to establish (Finger, 1993: 3). Often it is sufficient if a competing import
company demonstrates the dumping damage, based on decreasing sales and the rising
imports of a foreign competitor. Developing countries were particularly concerned about
large transnational corporations profiting from antidumping rules (Hoekman and Holmes,
1999: 878).
The WTO antidumping rules were shaped according to those of the US (The Economist,
1998b: 75). This is no surprise as the practice of antidumping had long been a US habit.
The US has an extensive record closely followed by the EU, of successful antidumping
cases. From 1980 to 1997, 80% of all antidumping claims of US origin were successful,
compared to 71% of EU origin (The Economist, 1998b: 75). Especially the US
government, supported by influential business lobby groups, took a rather favourable
stance towards antidumping lawsuits (FT, 1998c: 4; 1998g: 44). It even speeded up
antidumping suit procedures and maintained that rules on antidumping were unrelated to
competition control (ibid). Antidumping provisions were particularly common in the
textiles sector, where they fulfilled the function of a protective shield against cheap
292
Chinese imports, or in the steel sector where their purpose was to curb imports from
countries such as Brazil, Russia, and also Japan (The Economist, 1998b: 75). In the EU,
antidumping rules led to the epithet Fortress Europe. In order to keep the European
cotton bleaching industry alive, the EU levies a duty on bleached cotton imports (ibid).
Similarly, in order to sustain EU based rice mills, it levies import duties on certain types
of processed rice as part of its antidumping rules. The omnipresent practice of
antidumping explains why both the EU and US authorities refused to include the issue in
the remit of the WTO Working Group on the Interaction of Trade and Competition. Their
reluctance to drop antidumping rules explains why the discussions on WTO competition
rules already faced a severe deadlock in the preparation phase.
The European Commission, and its delegation to the Singapore Working Group, tried to
convince the opponents of the beneficial aspects of a WTO competition agreement, and
actively lobbied a number of developing countries in favour of the envisaged WTO
competition agreement. Therefore, the Commission adopted a competition for economic
development reasoning. Next to integrating developing countries into a rules-based world
economy and enhancing the capacity of domestic competition authorities to enforce
competition rules against large (foreign) companies (Monti, 2003b), it would help to
prevent consumers in developing economies falling victim to cartels, monopoly abuses,
and the creation of new monopolies through mergers (Anderson and Jenny, 2005: 2).
Moreover, it assured that the WTO agreement would include cooperation modalities that
were sufficiently flexible to address the needs of countries at different stages in the
development (Monti, 2001c). To achieve this, Commissioner Mario Monti emphasised the
necessity to strive to achieve a maximum of convergence and consensus on fundamental
issues such as the substance and economics of competition policy, the enforcement
priorities, and best practices (ibid). As the next section demonstrates, the new avenue
chosen to achieve these objectives was the International Competition Network (ICN).
293
(T)he EU has a real influence on the shape of antitrust policy more globally, an influence
which is exemplified by the leading role we have played in putting competition policy high
on the global agenda, including in various multilateral fora such as the OECD, the WTO,
and more recently in a new multilateral forum dedicated to competition policy: the ICN.
294
that of the WTO (ibid). The ICPAC was dissolved again in June 2000 after the creation of
the ICN was agreed. 48
The US authorities presented their alternative to the WTO trajectory to the European
Commission in the same year. In his speech Time for a Global Competitive Initiative?, US
Assistant Attorney General Joel Klein urged the Commission that it was time to develop a
common language and to adopt a microeconomics-based competition enforcement, even if
they could not achieve pure convergence (Klein, 2000). This competition culture was to
be broadened beyond the established players to a global scale by creating a venue where
antitrust officials, business, academics, economic and legal experts can discuss matters of
competition law. The transnational business elite welcomed the proposal with enthusiasm.
The ERT reminded the competition authorities that the priority agenda point was to
harmonise the different national procedures and to reduce the administrative and financial
burdens in the clearance of mergers and acquisitions (ERT, 2002a). Commissioner Mario
Monti assured the support of the DG Competition for the US initiative, although he also
expressed his disappointment that the US suggested a Global Competition Initiative
without the establishment of a multilateral competition law framework at the WTO level
(Monti, 2002a: 82). Nonetheless, after the downfall of the Cancn Ministerial Conference,
the Commission promoted the ICN as the main vehicle to advance a process of
convergence in competition matters on a global scale.
The flexibility of the ICNs network structure remedied the US tie anxiety to a more
constraining rule system, such as the WTO. The recommendations issued by the several
working groups are non-binding and informal in nature. The voluntary and non-binding
character should not surprise, as the Antitrust Division of the US DoJ and the FTC sit at
the drivers seat in bringing more consistency and convergence among national and
supranational jurisdictional agencies in the world. The European Commission soon joined
forces with the US authorities, sharing the seat of the pater familias at the head of the
global competition family table. To date, nearly all national and regional competition
authorities of the world take part in the ICNs 'best practices machinery. The number of
participating national competition authorities increased from 14 at the time of the ICNs
creation to 60 at the time of its first conference in Naples in 2002, to more than 90 today.
The ICN was designed for both developed and developing countries to share practical
48
More details on the history of the ICN can be found at: www.internationalcompetitionnetwork.org.
295
problems in handling competition issues, and to adapt the proposed standards and
procedures of competition control through mutual policy-learning. Nonetheless, a process
of convergence in competition laws and practices presupposes an identifiable common
reference point, a target towards which systemic, legal, or regulatory devices are moving.
The standards promoted by the ICN are unequivocally predisposed towards those of the
US authorities and the European Commission, who form part of the ICNs steering group
responsible for identifying projects and work plans. The ICN constitutes the perfect means
for the diffusion of common norms and procedural standards, for raising awareness on
certain problem definitions and solutions, and to socialise more peripheral competition
authorities socialised in one global competition culture (Gerber, 2002: 123). The message
of the ICN is simple: there is little room for different interpretations by national
competition authorities to tackle questions of competition. Although the ICN officially
declared that it would seek to establish consensus through persuasion and deliberation, it
allows powerful members to exert significant political pressure on less powerful members
to adopt the agreed set of rules, practices, or systems. As Commissioner Monti (2004c)
pointed out, competition authorities and legislators had to move decisively forward with
the implementation of the agreed ICN standards. Anomalies, he continued, would be
eliminated by through persuasion and other appropriate means (ibid).
The power of the US-EU tandem is further enhanced by the ICNs ultra-light
organisational structure: the ICN does not have formal decision making rules, a permanent
secretariat, a letterbox, or a bank account (Monti, 2002a). The ICN provides the powerful
competition authorities with the necessary flexibility to steer the future course of the ICN
with greater ease. Through regular gatherings and an annual conference, the dissemination
of working group reports, and surveillance through implementation reports on member
countries, the ICNs framework allows the proactive agencies to exert peer pressure and to
coerce competition authorities to adopt the ICN norms into their legal systems, and thereby
fasten up the process of convergence. Most notably, the informal organisational structure
allows private business representatives to play an important role side-by-side with the
competition authorities. The ICN maintains close contact with and seeks input from
international organisations, such as the OECD, WTO, and UNCTAD (cf. Nederlandse
Mededingingsautoriteit, 2007). The Commission was rather overt in this respect and
announced that it would actively seek advice and contributions form the private sector and
from the legal professions and individual members of the academic community (Schaub,
296
2002b). Similarly, the US authorities believe that the private sector has an important role
to play in the ICN, not as members but as partners (Government, 2002). Excluded from
the list were labour organisations. In 2006, the ICN even established a subgroup on
Business Outreach, which actively seeks contact with business organisations in order to
benefit from their knowledge, experience, and insights and to understand business realities
(Barnett, 2006). It maintains close contact with and seeks input from international
organisations,
such
as
the
OECD,
WTO,
and
UNCTAD
(cf.
Nederlandse
Initially, in line with the interests of the transnational business community, the ICN
primarily targeted the area of merger control in the multijurisdictional context. Meanwhile,
working groups on cartel investigation and prosecution, as well as on unilateral conduct
were established. Three working groups alone were established on merger related issues.
The dominant position of the chief socialisers became visible through the ICN working
group structure. Members of the US authorities and the Commission chaired most of the
working groups that aimed streamlining investigative procedures in the assessment of
mergers. They headed the subgroups focusing on Notifications and Procedures and
Investigative Techniques, as well as the ICNs Advocacy Working Group, and its
subgroups on Capacity Building and Competition Policy Implementation, which were
given the task to promote a culture of competition in developing countries. For example,
the Notifications and Procedures subgroup issued seven recommended practices for
merger notification procedures, a rather detailed guide on adopting a merger notification
regime. As Commissioner Monti (2004c) explained, the convergence endeavour in the
merger area entirely served the purpose of making compliance for companies with
multijurisdictional merger review much less burdensome.
The ICN constitutes a palpable example of how the processes of regulatory convergence in
the field of competition laws are not driven by inexorable and mechanical laws of the
market. Rather, an alliance of public authorities and private business, seeking to establish
an intellectual consensus on how to address competition questions around the world,
orchestrated the convergence endeavour. The central practices underpinning the allegedly
297
The next chapter illustrates that the European competition model, alongside the bilateral
and multilateral cooperation trajectory, underwent a process of convergence towards the
more free market-oriented competition model of the US.
298
Chapter 8
Introduction
From the mid-1990s onwards, the EU competition regime underwent a series of reforms.
The most recent and the most incremental changes came into force on May 1 2004,
coinciding with the accession of ten new Member States. The reform fundamentally
transforms the EU competition model, both in terms of an impact on substance and
enforcement procedures. What has been commonly termed the modernisation (European
Commission, 1999), came in the form of a package deal consisting of both substantive and
procedural features, which according to former Competition Commissioner Mario Monti
(2004b) comprised a revolution in the way competition rules are enforced in the European
Union. The reform represents a major step towards convergence with the US model of
competition law enforcement. According to Monti (2004a), if there was ever a gap
between both systems, it disappeared on 1 May 2004. Two regulatory changes were
crucial in this regard. First, the replacement of the more than forty year-old Regulation 17
with Regulation 1/2003 essentially altered the way in which anticompetitive conduct, such
as cartels and other restrictive business practices, were prosecuted in the EU. The longstanding centralised administrative ex ante notification regime for commercial
intercompany agreements was abolished, and replaced with a decentralised ex post private
enforcement regime. Second, the Merger Regulation 4064/89 was replaced by the Merger
Regulation 139/2004, which entailed a revision of the substantive measurement used for
the assessment of mergers. Furthermore, it allocated more investigatory powers to the
Commission.
49
This chapter draws on Wigger (2007) and Wigger and Nlke (2007).
299
This chapter argues that the new regime consolidates the developments that started in the
1990s, notably the incorporation of a more neoliberal focus in the enforcement of EU
competition laws through the adoption of a more market-based approach similar to that of
the US, which entails a predisposition towards fiercer and freer competition. The
institutional anchoring of the use of microeconomic theories reinforces this trend. Crucial
in this regard, is the use of ever-more sophisticated econometric techniques in modelling
anticompetitive conduct, as well as a general inclination, on the part of the Commission, to
base its decision making on corporate efficiency and consumer welfare. The reform is
intrinsically linked to the process of bilateral and multilateral cooperation between the US
competition authorities and the European Commission (see Chapter 6 and Chapter 7), a
cooperation that finds its origins in the relentless quests of the transnational business elite
for enhanced global convergence in the application of competition laws. In line with the
interests of transnationally operating business, the reform seeks to remedy the engrained
tensions, which surfaced between the European and the US models throughout the 1990s.
Moreover, by introducing private enforcement (see Chapter 2), the main burden of antitrust
enforcement shifted to the private sector: the enforcement of EU competition laws will be
increasingly determined by how proactive market actors are in litigating observed
anticompetitive behaviour before the EU or national courts. Thereby, the business
community cannot rely anymore on the sanction-free notification procedure, but has to
assess by itself whether a planned economic transaction infringes the law or not. According
to the Commission, companies will thereby take EU competition rules more seriously
(Monti, 2001a). The mere threat of private litigation will cause sufficient deterrence,
inducing companies to comply better with European competition law (Monti, 2004d; see
also Kroes, 2005a).
The reform seeks in many ways to enhance levels of private enforcement in the EU. The
launch of a Green Paper in December 2005, proposing the introduction of new judicial
tools, such as damage compensation, seeks to render private actions more worthwhile for
claimants. This chapter first examines the combined impact of the newly introduced
Regulation 1/2003, and the enhanced emphasis on neoclassical microeconomic theories
and econometric modelling. Second, it analyses the new decisional grounds in the
assessment of mergers and acquisitions under Regulation 139/2004. Furthermore, by
paying close attention to the question of cui bono, this chapter reconstructs the interest
constellation, against the backdrop of the structural conditions, which enabled it to inform
300
this process of neoliberal restructuring. The transnational business elite and the private
practitioners are identified as the major driving forces in the reform process. In addition, it
demonstrates that the enhanced possibilities for litigation in competition matters also play
into the hands of a more shareholder value-orientated market economy. It highlights that a
diffuse group of shareholders lobbied for class action litigation and criminal sanctions,
alongside the competition reform. The reform, it will be argued, opens up a window of
opportunity for groups of shareholders to increase their voice options, vis--vis
management boards, in order to redistribute controlling powers in their favour. In
conclusion, the chapter underscores the contradictions in the interest motives of the
different transnational forces seeking enhanced market-based regulatory solutions.
We can confidently say that we share the same goals and pursue the same results on both
sides of the Atlantic: namely, to ensure effective competition between enterprises, by
conducting a competition policy which is based on sound economics and which has the
protection of consumers as its primary concern.
For Article 82 there was never a notification regime. See also Chapter 2.
301
less on market supervision and intervention by public authorities. It means that companies
are increasingly exposed to the risk of being litigated by other market actors, a jeopardy
that, so far, has constituted a relatively alien feature in EU antitrust control. This reflects a
retrenchment of the Commission and the end of the long-standing ordoliberal tradition of
administrative and supervisory market control for commercial intercompany agreements.
According to a speech by Competition Commissioner Mario Monti at the ordoliberal
headquarter Freiburg University, the Freiburg School and its basic concepts, to which
many policy choices can be traced back, has made a major contribution to shaping the
post-war economy and what sometimes is called the European Model (Monti, 2000a: 1).
However, in the presence of strikingly modern ideas, the whole of the competition law
framework needed to be overhauled in order to ensure more efficient enforcement of the
European competition rules (ibid).
The reform seeks to boost the level of private enforcement in the EU, which reflects a
major step towards convergence with the Anglo-Saxon antitrust model, in particular
towards that of the US. The process of convergence constitutes mostly a one-sided
phenomenon, in which the EU adopted crucial features of the US model of competition
control. The Federal antitrust authorities, the Department of Justice (DoJ) and the Federal
Trade Commission (FTC), never played as similarly comforting role as the Commission,
nor was there an equivalent of the EU notification regime for commercial intercompany
agreements in the US. Although private entities always played an important role in the
enforcement of EU antitrust law, they tended to inform the Commission, rather than to
litigate. The Commission received, on average, more than 100 private complaints per year
(Paulis and Smijter, 2005b: 12), while private litigators in less than 5% of the cases invoked
a claim at the European courts (Kemper, 2004: 9). The ex ante notification regime provided
little ground for private actors to bring legal actions to the courts: once the Commission
cleared a case or granted exemption, companies enjoyed legal immunity from further
prosecution, leaving claimants with the only option of challenging the Commissions
decision at court level. Positing a case at the Commissions desk was far more appealing as
claimants would have needed to collect the relevant evidence and prove that a certain
business conduct infringed the law, as well as cover the alleged costs of suing (Pirrung,
2004: 97). Alerting the Commission on competition law infringements was easier for
claimants than initiating the litigation themselves. In addition, most of the legal features
that make it attractive to initiate legal proceedings against corporations in the US were
302
absent in the EU system. Successful plaintiffs in Europe were not awarded three times the
damage suffered, on top of the costs of suing, nor was there a possibility for class actions in
which several plaintiffs group together and sue collectively (see Chapter 2). Moreover, nowin-no-fee or contingency fees, offered by most US law companies, according to which
professional litigators representing the plaintiffs in court make their profit dependent on the
monetary award, were prohibited in most European legal systems. Therefore, the absence of
these judicial tools, together with the fact that national jurisdictions could not apply the
whole of Article 81, rendered the legal landscape of the EU a rather hostile environment for
private enforcement, which is why, in the European setting, a claimants culture with
exorbitant compensation payments, similar to that of the US, was a rather alien feature.
Even though the 2004 reform did not directly touch upon further legal modifications, the
current discussion on a range of legal instruments for private plaintiffs is likely to render
the reform a stepping-stone in a much broader process of enhanced convergence towards
the US model. In particular, the creation of stronger incentives for private litigation has
achieved high agenda status in the current discussions. Competition Commissioner Kroes
(2005d) was quite overt in this respect when saying that the comprehensive enforcement
of the competition rules was not yet complete not enough use was made of the courts. In
December 2005, the Commission presented its ideas on how to 'increase the scope for
private enforcement, in a Green Paper promoting the introduction of Damages Actions
for Breach of the EC Antitrust Rules (European Commission, 2005b). As a point of
departure, it was noted that the current situation of damage claims for competition law
infringements in the EU-25 presented a picture of total underdevelopment and
astonishing diversity (ibid).
Whether a facilitated damage relief system was desirable at all did not form part of the
Commissions 36 options specifying its implementation. Furthermore, jurisprudence by the
European Court of Justice (ECJ) already laid the basis for damage compensation. In the
seminal Courage vs. Crehan decision of September 20 in 2001, it ruled that any
individual injured from an agreement in violation of Article 81(1) must be able to obtain
compensation for the economic losses suffered (Gerven, 2005: 2; cf. Reich, 2005). So far,
only three Member States have a damage claim statutory, although, in principle, twelve
allow such claims (McDavid, 2005). Since 1962, there have been only 12 competition
cases where damages payments were awarded (ibid). As the rulings of the ECJ produce a
303
direct effect, individuals can also evoke these rulings before national courts. The ECJ
thereby played a proactive role, with regard to creating a legal basis for damage actions in
national settings. It concluded from the Crehan case that the existence of litigation right
strengthens the working of the Community competition rules and that actions for
damages before the national courts could make a significant contribution to the
maintenance of effective competition in the Community (in Schoneveld, 2003: 440). Also
the Commission believes that once a system of damage relief is introduced at Member
State level, private parties will bring more actions to the courts (Monti, 2004d). Moreover,
the gradual rise in private lawsuits and facilitated court access is expected to increase the
overall level of enforcement and render it at least as effective as in the US, if not more so
(Philip Lowe in Dombey, 2004).
Somewhat ironically, US enforcers have much critique on their own system (Wils, 2003).
Even though US authorities have traditionally put much effort into narrowing the distance
between the European and the US antitrust model, these efforts were never directed at
promoting the US system of private enforcement (Davidow, 2002: 493). Timothy Muris
(2004), chairperson of the US FTC, noted that private enforcement, particularly in
combination with the US class action system, carried enormous costs, as lawyers usually
left the battle as winners, leaving little direct benefits for consumers. On the contrary,
consumers were even faced with indirect costs as damage payments imposed on companies
were eventually incorporated in the price of consumer goods. In response to pressure by
the US business community to reduce competition law enforcement in the US, the Bush
Administration even sought to forbid certain litigation practices at Federal court level in
the hope to curtail a claimants culture that has run out of control. It proposed a Bill in
February 2005 that aimed to scale down the scope and the frequency of class actions
before the US courts. The Democrats eventually opposed the bill, as it would have led to a
massive dismissal of claims by Federal judges, and culminated in an attack on consumer
rights. The next section highlights why private enforcement unequivocally stimulates a
more market-based competition regime.
304
Markets, not politicians, are best placed to allocate resources efficiently. Markets, not
politicians, are best placed to identify the companies and technologies of the future.
Markets, not politicians, are what at the end of the day will generate the wealth we need to
maintain our way of life, based on our shared social and environmental values.
305
Consumer welfare is now well established as the standard the Commission applies when
assessing mergers and infringements of Articles 81 and 82. Our aim is simple: to protect
competition in the market as a means of enhancing consumer welfare and ensuring an
efficient allocation of resources.
Neelie Kroes, EU Competition Commissioner (2005c)
306
One of my main objectives upon taking office [] has been to increase the emphasis on
sound economics in the application of the EC antitrust rules, in particular to those
concerning different types of agreements between companies [].
Similarly to the US model, a post called the Chief Competition Economist was
established, which had the mission to scrutinise the Commissions antitrust investigations
with a fresh pair of eyes and independent economic viewpoints (Monti, 2002b).
Accompanied by an entourage of experienced economists called the Economic Advisory
Group, the Chief Economist had the task of guiding the regular staff of lawyers, on a caseby-case basis, in all fields of competition control and advising on the future development
of competition policy (Rller, 2005: 6). In addition to the increase in the number of
competition officers trained in economics, a range of indicators lay bare that the kind of
competition economics that has made its entry is grounded in neoclassical
microeconomics, analytically premised on methodological individualism, and originally
derives from the neoliberal free-market ideology. The new creed of economists maintains
strong transatlantic contacts, which indicates that the substance of economic theories is
likely to be streamlined with that prevailing in the US. Bilateral meetings on past case
work and economic methodology with economists working at the FTC and the DoJ take
place on a regular basis (Rller, 2005: 6). In this vein, it seems no coincidence that
Professor Lars-Hendrik Rller, who was appointed Chief Competition Economist in July
2003, was educated in competition economics in the US. James Rill, former US Deputy
Attorney General for Antitrust remarked on the reform that it was as close at it could get
to the US-style without copying the whole caboodle (Rill, 2003). Although differences in
the legal instruments remain, the Commission is increasingly using the same
microeconomic analytical tools as the US (Schaub, 2002a: 3). Monti heralded the silent
process of convergence as the most important success story in the transatlantic
relationship and argued that EU competition policy is now clearly grounded in sound
microeconomics (Monti, 2004d). Furthermore, he observed:
[] (w)e share a common fundamental vision of the role and limitations of public
intervention. [] We are both grappling with the same evolving economic realities and are
both exposed to the same evolution in economic thinking. (Monti, 2004a)
This common fundamental vision entails that the ultimate purpose of public intervention
in the marketplace is restricted to safeguarding price competition and efficiency
307
improvements at company level. The particular emphasis on economic efficiency and the
declaration of consumer welfare (measured in the form of price reductions) indicates that
macroeconomic-orientated visions, inspired by ordoliberal economic thinking, are
definitely over. The use of price theories and price modelling as a central reference point in
the assessment of economic efficiency, quintessentially give precedence to a short-term
microeconomic perspective. The central focus on price limits the perspective to single
company behaviour in relation to consumers, and disregards macroeconomic issues like
market power concentration and market structure. In other words, the scope for a multigoal
strategy, such as protectionist and neomercantilist decision making, has narrowed
considerably. That consumer welfare arguments have increased in importance is revealed
in the creation of a new post within the Commission's DG Competition called Consumer
Liaison Officer in December 2003. The new institution has the task of ensuring a
permanent dialogue with European consumers and alerting consumer groups to
competition cases where their input might be useful (European Commission, 2003).
jurisdictions, with thousands of tribunals, will have to set their own yardsticks for
infringements, and evaluate the soundness of technically complex empirical material used
in accusations and court defences. In the absence of specialised competition courts,
ordinary judges will have to award damage compensation and impose fines. In the
Member States where competition law infringements are prosecuted under criminal law,
national judges will have to imprison CEOs for their unlawful activities. The chances for
deviant interpretations are very high, and the legal forum shopping for claimants may
become common. Because EU competition laws are formulated in loose and imprecise
terms, due process of law, according to established rules and principles, will be difficult to
maintain. National courts expect so-called borderline cases to become rather frequent,
which is part of the reason why the devolution of competences to national courts led to
many controversies. The microeconomisation of competition law enforcement becomes
all-pervasive with the possibility of private enforcement in a decentralised enforcement
regime. The growing body of judge-made case law, and the fact that future claimants may
rely upon legal precedents, has the potential effect that certain economic data-gathering
methods will be immured as the standard for decision making.
To recapitulate, whereas before, a public authority could balance the decision making in
competition cases against broader political macroeconomic goals, in a regime of private
enforcement, individual claimants are more likely to be driven by (pecuniary) self-interest
when invoking a claim against allegedly anticompetitive behaviour. National judges
similarly proceed on a case-by-case basis without taking into account market structures
within the wider political economy. In combination with the trend towards a more
microeconomics-based assessment, the new regime preludes a political bias towards
narrower and more short-term conceptions of competition.
309
(T)he competition systems in Europe and the US have more similarities than differences.
And, most importantly, enforcers on both sides of the Atlantic are firmly headed in the
same direction, with policies which increasingly go hand-in-hand. And there is so much we
can achieve by consulting and co-operating with each other and by continuing to
recognise that listening to our stakeholders and benefiting from their experiences is
important too.
8.2 The Reform of the EU Merger Regulation A Step Towards Convergence with
the US Model
In addition to Regulation 1/2003, the pan-European Merger Regulation of 1989 also
underwent a major reform. Regulation 139/2004 came into force on May 1 2004, in
combination with new Merger Guidelines designed to provide corporations with a
preliminary indicator of anticompetitive mergers. Similarly to Regulation 1/2003, the new
merger regulation reveals a paradigm change towards a more US-style and more
microeconomics-based merger control. As Commissioner Monti pointed out, a European
competition lawyer who picks up the US Federal Merger Guidelines will be struck by how
much common ground is shared between the US and EU approaches to merger analysis
(Monti, 2004a).
310
criterion in the examination of mergers was more in line with the ordoliberal imperative to
constrain dominant economic power concentrations, as well as the desire to protect the
German Mittelstand, the SMEs sector. As Ulf Bge (2003), President of the
Bundeskartellamt, put it Why should a dominant company pass efficiency advantages on
to the consumer if it is no longer forced to do so by competition? After all, by definition
monopolies imply a situation in which competition is absent. The Bundeskartellamt
declared that it would not apply the same test as the Commission, and eventually also the
European Courts, applied. Instead, it would stick to the old Dominance Test. How long the
German resistance endures remains to be seen, particularly as the new regulation equipped
the Commission with a coercive instrument in bringing more consistency into merger
assessments by Member State competition authorities. Based on Article 21 of the new
Merger Regulation, the Commission can impose binding decisions on the legitimacy and
proportionality of state measures that adversely affect mergers. The exceptions are
mergers affecting public security. The Commission thereby gained new controlling
powers in countering allegedly undue protectionist Member States interventions in
mergers. It can streamline competition law enforcement in the long term. This reduces the
relevance of national competition laws as independent sources of law. Competition
Commissioner Kroes (2006d) warned that it would intervene in each and every attempt by
national governments to block takeovers that fall within the Commissions exclusive
competence. To date, the Commission has not hesitated to make use of its powers, which
can be seen by its reaction to the recent upsurge of protectionist attempts by Member
States to impose barriers on cross-border mergers. The Commission challenged the
Spanish government before the ECJ when CNE, Spains national energy commission,
sought to frustrate the 27 billion takeover of Spanish Endesa by the German E.ON, one
of the worlds largest private energy companies, through the imposition of 19 conditions
(Kroes, 2007a).
The next section addresses the questions of who is benefiting from the transformation of
the European competition regime, who has been driving the reform, and why.
312
8.3 Cui Bono? The Driving Forces in the Reform Process and Their Agendas
8.3.1 The Mixed Emotions of Corporate Europe with Regulation 1/2003
Management boards of large transnational corporations emerged as the most fervent critics
of EU competition law enforcement. They were in favour of modernising the application
of the EC antitrust rules (UNICE, 1995; 2001, 2002). A recurring point of criticism was
that EU competition law enforcement was vague, inconsistent, complex, and nonobjective, and that corporations were exposed to the arbitrariness of competition
authorities. Driven by a genuine interest in lifting regulatory barriers that hamper the free
flow of capital accumulation, i.e. the creation of a so-called level playing field, the
notification procedure was deemed too time-consuming and bureaucratically cumbersome,
particularly as the Commission faced a backlog of more than 1000 unprocessed cases
(European Parliament, 1999: 10). The Commissions workload was expected to increase
by another 40% through the expansion of the EU with ten new Member States (Guerrera,
2003). As intercompany agreements were often concluded for short periods, business
representatives wanted rapid decisions. Even though, in order to speed up the decision
making process, the Commission concluded voluntary settlements with companies (Paulis
and Smijter, 2005: 11), the administrative burden of notification was still there. To wait for
clearance from the Commission produced extra regulatory transaction costs and always ran
the risk of a blocking decision. Removing this burdensome, administrative straightjacket
increased the leeway in making use of the freedom of contract. Companies could engage in
all types of commercial agreements without being immediately controlled by the
Commissions interventionist arm.
The corporate elite of the ERT repeatedly criticised the Commissions far-reaching powers
that, themselves, were not subject to judicial control (ERT, 2001b: 3). It had a stake in a
generous and encouraging environment when concluding investment-sharing R&D
partnerships and other intercompany agreements, particularly in the field of new
technology, which was characterised by increasingly shorter periods of amortisation (ERT,
2002a). Moreover, CEOs of large transnational corporations considered the systemic
tension between the Anglo-Saxon conception of market capitalism and the EU conception
of a coordinated market economy an obstacle (Waverman et al., 1997: 414). Similar
approaches between the EU and the US would make economic life a lot easier. As the US
system was more favourable to their interests, members of the ERT encouraged the
313
The macroeconomic context explains why transnational corporate elites lobbied for the
modernisation of the enforcement regime for Article 81. Like mergers, the conclusion of
intercompany agreements had increased considerably over the past 40 years. Estimates
suggest that companies from the OECD world are responsible for 82% of all strategic
alliances concluded worldwide (Ullrich, 2003: 210-211). In the 1990s, the total number of
strategic partnerships, including joint ventures, underwent a growth unparalleled in history:
from 1,050 in 1989, to 4,000 in 1990, with a temporal peak of 9,000 in 1995, and 8,660 in
2000 (ibid). In the 1990s, about half of all strategic partnerships involving European
companies exhibited a transatlantic dimension, whereas only a quarter concerned pure
intra-European deals (ibid: 211-12). In the competition literature, this phenomenon was
captured with the buzzwords coopetition or networked competition(ibid: 220). For
corporations, the conclusion of such intercompany agreements constituted a source of
competitive strength to compete on a global scale. Consequently, corporations have a stake
in removing regulatory barriers inhibiting or complicating commercial cooperation
agreements. Similarly to cross-border mergers, a rigid reviewing process imposed extra
transaction costs and, where multiple jurisdictions were involved, the probability of
jurisdictional conflicts increased. Through the abolition of the ex ante notification regime,
such corporate cross-connections could proceed largely unchecked. As contractual
intercompany agreements generally fall under the confidentiality of the corporations, the
web of corporate linkages becomes ever-more indiscernible to the wider public. At least,
no market concentration indices can capture the global corporate entanglement anymore.
Thus, the facilitation of corporate enmeshment, through commercial agreements,
stimulates the global fragmentation of the production process and the resulting global
division of labour. In other words, the removal of public control hides actual market
concentration and blurs the boundaries between inter-firm and intra-firm trade further, all
aspects that play into the hands of transnational corporations seeking to improve their
competitive strength in the global economy.
Under the previous regime, similarly to EU merger control regime, market share thresholds
determined whether an intercompany agreement required scrutiny by the Commission. For
example, a market share of 30% for vertical agreements was considered less harmful than a
314
The Commission had already taken an overtly tolerant approach and allowed most of the
commercial intercompany agreements in the past few years. Based on the generous block
exemption regime under the new regime, different types of investment sharing R&D
partnerships, specialisation, and distribution agreements were cumulatively excluded from
the category of anticompetitive behaviour. In order to be on the safe side, the ERT lobbied
nonetheless in favour of a further extension of provisions that formally exclude vertical
agreements from prosecution. As a result, the reform broadened the conditional provisions
for granting group exemptions under Article 81(3) (Ullrich, 2003: 216). Nevertheless, the
Commissions codification of the interpretation of Article 81 implies that there is little
room for national competition authorities to exempt certain agreements on a more flexible
basis. In other words, the discretionary power to safeguard agreements as enjoyed by the
Commission under the previous regime has been phased out (see also Monti, 2007: 498).
The situation parallels the case of hardcore horizontal cartel agreements falling under
Article 81(1), such as price agreements, output fixing, and market sharing between direct
competitors. The Commission has adopted a guideline approach similar to US practice,
which allows corporations to orientate themselves on the boundaries of legal and illegal
behaviour. In terms of content, the Guidelines on Horizontal Agreements were streamlined
with that of the FTC and the DoJ published in 2000, providing companies at both sides of
the Atlantic with the same regime.
315
greater involvement of groups, like consumers and employees, risks diverting the
attention from the competition focus of the Commissions analysis and increases both
uncertainty and delay (ERT, 2001b: 4). With the focus on competition only, which
builds on short-term orientated econometric evidence, more diffuse societal interests are
unlikely to be included in the assessment of a case. Additionally, it may provide managers
with an avenue for less stringent enforcement. Concepts such as dynamic efficiency
improvements leave ample room for gerrymandering the decision making in the desired
direction. Prior definitions of relevant product markets, or the distinctions of one product
vis--vis another, can be used for moulding evidence to support a particular claim.
Moreover, as a commentator argued, estimates on the future impact on competition in an
econometric model are based on defined confidence intervals, which are tantamount to an
intuitive judgment in deciding whether a test has passed or not (Dobbs, 2002: 3).
Nevertheless, the support of Corporate Europe for Regulation 1/2003 was not
straightforward. Emotions were mixed and certain elements of the reform were fiercely
criticised (Berggren, 2005). The administratively burdensome, but secure, notification
regime also had its proponents, particularly among UNICE, which comprises the whole
range of European companies, including SMEs. It argued that the complexity of the rules
required extensive expert advice and substantial management time (UNICE, 1999;
2001). This contrasts with Commissioner Montis argument that the Commissions role
was not to give comfort, and that after forty years of experience, the application of
European competition law should be sufficiently clear to business (Monti, 2004d).
Elsewhere he compared the notification procedure to parking a car in a town: citizens
must know where to park a car and shouldnt have to go to the police station to check first
(ibid). The fact that antitrust law enforcement is far more complex than Montis car
parking allegory, partially explains the discontent within the business community with the
new regime, particularly when considering that the fines imposed on cartel cases exceed
those of traffic offences! Also among the select group of TNCs represented in the ERT, the
formal safe-haven regime constituted a much cherished good, as long as speedy and
straightforward processing was guaranteed (ERT, 2002a). Judicial advocacy by corporate
lawyers could not provide the desired legal certainty in the competitive environment
created by ever-shorter amortisation periods for new technology products or so was the
argument. In marked contrast to the enthusiasm of business representatives for a more
microeconomics-based approach, the new risk of litigation and the exposure to
316
compensation payments alarmed business associations (i.e. UNICE, 2006; DIHK, 2006;
HDE, 2006; VCI, 2006). The reason is obvious: potential fines, damage compensation
payments, and the costs of defence can be detrimental for companies (cf. Bizjak and Coles,
1995). Although the 2004 antitrust reform does not immediately lead to a US-style
litigation culture, CEOs from the European business community were very much aware of
this scenario. US business leaders, represented by the US Chamber of Commerce, alerted
their European colleagues to the downside of an excessive litigation culture. With the
asbestos cases in mind, which cost more than 70,000 jobs, they warned in particular of the
introduction of class actions and the emergence of high-priced trial lawyers in Europe (cf.
Donohue, 2003).
Another problematic issue was that the new regime of decentralised private enforcement,
which allows private litigants to bring breaches of EU antitrust law also to national courts,
was deemed to accentuate inconsistency, a lack of transparency, and unpredictability by
transnational business representatives (cf. UNICE, 1999; ERT, 2002a). In a range of
position papers during the preparatory stages of the reform, business organisations sought
to limit the exposure of companies to private lawsuits and urged the Commission to build
in legal safety measures, such as ex ante reasoned opinions on a case by competition
authorities and national jurisdictions. The issuance of such advices would come close to
the reintroduction of the notification regime. In response, the Commission promised
merely the occasional provision of general guidance letters, which it would publish on its
website. Only in genuine cases of uncertainty, will it grant case-specific informal
guidance (cf. Recital 38 of Regulation 1/2003). Business associations deeply regretted the
Commissions loose commitment and pleaded for more guidance, particularly in cases of
commercial agreements that are ancillary to, or involve a financial risk, capital
investment, or an effect on shareholder value (UNICE, 2001b: 5; ERT, 2002a).
317
an attempt to monopolise (see Chapter 2). The EUs elastic notions, such as the abuse of
power or the abuse of dominance, were considered disturbingly vague (Gerber, 1998;
174). In the EU, market dominance of a company traditionally provided reason enough to
intervene, regardless of whether prices remained competitive. Conglomerate mergers, in
particular, were seen as a threat to competition, because the merged entity could leverage
its market power with the effect or object to foreclose one or several market players from
effective competition (Monti, 2001b). In the US context, competition officials buried
similar conglomerate merger theories with the ascendancy of the Chicago School. In the
EU, however, the maintenance of a high degree of competition in the common market
long enjoyed priority over other criteria in the assessment of anticompetitive conduct, such
as consumer welfare protection and efficiency gains (ibid). As a general rule, the
Commission applied the logic that a high degree of competition, inter alia, required a large
number of competitors. Thus, too dominant market players could pose a threat to the
broader project of market integration to which competition laws were subordinated.
The transnational business elite, however, criticised the Commissions way of taking
narrowly defined market shares as a focal point of analysis as imprecise (ERT, 2002a). It
preferred the approach of the US authorities towards large, dominant corporations, which
was more lenient and only considered the real impact of M&As and commercial practices
by focusing on efficiency improvements, such as lower prices or better quality products for
consumers. Therefore, the ERT urged the Commission to introduce a more economicsbased interpretation and to give priority to efficiency and consistency similarly to the
US model (ibid). By virtue of their Chicago School trainings, US competition officials had
more faith in the workings of free markets, implying that market dominance was generally
conceived as a source of competitive strength, rather than a hazard to free competition.
Moreover, representatives of transnationally operating companies, in alliance with US
competition experts, considered the Commissions approach to be biased towards
European players by giving undue weight to competitor arguments (Pitofsky, 2000;
Draghi, 2003). Underpinning this criticism was the fear that EU industrial policy would
interfere with the merger enforcement. As Kolasky (2002c), Attorney General of the US
DoJ, put it, the EU competition policy, designed to maintain fragmented markets or
protect small business, was misguided.
318
The criticism on the divergent approaches in merger control across the Atlantic endured for
more than a decade. After the 1991 Transatlantic Bilateral Agreement, EU and US
competition officials stayed in regular contact (see Chapter 6 and 7). In workshops, US
officials shared their experiences with the Commissions Merger Task Force in the
investigation and analysis of mergers (Pitofsky, 2000). When the Commission issued
Merger Guidelines in 1997 on how to measure market power and define relevant markets,
the US Merger Guidelines of 1982, which were slightly amended in 1992 and 1997, served
as a template (Pitofsky, 1998; Gavil et al., 2002: 967). In October 1999, a joint EU-US
Merger Working Group was established and given the mandate to: seek more consistency
in the respective approaches, come up with best practices in the analysis of mergers, and
identify the scope of further procedural and substantive convergence across the ocean
(European Commission, 2002b). Nonetheless, the complaints about the merger control
developments in the EU by US business interests and antitrust authorities persisted.
According to Mario Draghi (2003), Vice Chairman of Goldman Sachs, despite the
extensive and positive cooperative working relationship on merger review and the steps of
convergence, antitrust review for transatlantic transactions remains a significant
transaction risk. A series of divergent rulings by the Commission in high-profile cases
between US companies indicated that interpretations of the harmfulness of oligopolistic
dominance differed substantially. In particular, the Boeing-McDonnell Douglas merger and
the GE-Honeywell merger constituted the reason why the transnational business elite
lobbied to reform the EU Merger Regulation (see Chapter 6).
The pressure to reform the EUs merger control regime also increased when the Court of
First Instance (CFI) annulled the Commissions decisions in the mergers between Airtours
and Firstchoice in 1999, Schneider and Legrand in 2002, and Tetra and Laval-Sidel in
2002. The Commissions prohibitions in the Schneider-Legrand and Tetra Laval-Sidel
merger cases were particularly important. The cases involved French companies in the
electricity distribution equipment sector and the liquid food-packaging sector, respectively.
The Commission ruled, in both cases, that the mergers would lead to a situation of market
dominance, eliminating competition in the future, and vetoed the deals. When the
companies appealed to the CFI, it deemed the Commissions supporting economic
evidence insufficient, and its economic logic unconvincing, and thus overruled the
Commissions blocking verdict. The ruling was therefore a major critique on the
Commissions expertise and competence in the review of mergers and other cooperative
319
ventures. After these embarrassing court defeats, Commissioner Monti announced some
reforms. He assured his critics that the Commission was not against mergers that create
more efficient firms, even if competitors might suffer from increased standards of
competition (Monti, 2001d). Moreover, consumer welfare was not just a goal, but the
goal of competition policy (ibid). The US authorities applauded Montis leadership in
encouraging more convergence, but remained suspicious, as it remained to be seen whether
the Commission would not only talk the talk but walk the walk (in Guerrera and Hill,
2002). As the 2004 reform demonstrates, the Commission matched its actions to the words.
More economists, nurtured in US-style econometric analysis, were hired (see earlier
section in this Chapter), which greatly increased the awareness of Commission officials
on efficiency-based reasoning in their practice (Jenny, 2000: 22). Alternative decisional
grounds were portrayed as misguided or not mindful enough of market forces (ibid).
The reliance on sound economic foundations in the decision making was meant to bring
comfort on the robustness of the decisions to the business community (Lowe, 2003). A
large part of this comfort, however, can be ascribed to the fact that since 2002 the
Commission had permitted most of the merger transactions, regardless of the resulting
dominant market position (e.g. exemplary is the merger between BASF, Eurodiol and
Pantochim, see Fuchs, 2003: 226). The number of M&As, and in particular large crossborder mergers, also remained high after the merger wave of the late 1990s (see Chapter
5). In terms of the combined value of deals concluded, the year 2006 exceeded the
previous peak year of 2000. Of the ten largest worldwide deals ever, eight took place in
2006 (i.e. AT&T-BellSouth, E.on-Endesa, Sueze-Gaz de France, Mittal Stell-Arcelor). Low
interest rates for lending money and the event of private equity companies attracting
private investors to fund M&As provoked the upsurge of market concentration. The
Commission took a highly positive stance on cross-border merger activity and considered,
what it termed corporate restructuring, to be a normal response to globalisation.
Commissioner Kroes (2006e) noted, in this respect, that he was pleased that industries in
the Internal Market were able to restructure corporate ownership in order to meet the
global challenges posed by competition. The Commissions positive clearance decisions
provide further evidence: in 2006, over 360 mergers were permitted, and the year 2007 will
probably even beat this record (ibid, 2007c). Transnational business representatives tend to
be equally pleased. With regard to economic concentrations, the EU merger regime
converged towards the more tolerant approach of the US system, while the advantages of
320
the EU system remain intact, such as: the one-stop-shop rule for large, cross-border
mergers; tight deadlines; speedy procedures, and transparency (Draghi, 2003). Moreover,
the new Merger Regulation seeks to harmonise the decisional grounds among Member
State merger control by allowing the Commission to overrule decisions that run against its
policy. National authorities can no longer interfere in cross-border mergers based on
protectionist motivations.
The next section addresses private antitrust enforcement in terms of its potential impact on
the corporate power balance of management vis--vis shareholders.
Commissioner Kroes presented the enhanced antitrust litigation possibilities as a right for
consumers and individual businesses in Europe who have lost out as a result of the
anticompetitive behaviour of others (Kroes, 2006b). The generalisation that only either
consumers or competitors have an interest in rectifying abusive corporate behaviour
downplays the existence of other stakeholders, such as labour and environmentalists.
Diffuse groups such as labour, consumers, and individual businesses, however, face high
321
administrative costs when organising claims against corporate fraud. On the other hand,
another category of plaintiffs, namely shareholders, particularly institutional investors, and
hedge funds prioritising short-term profits, is more likely to make use of the facilitated
antitrust litigation possibilities. As the reform explicitly hinges upon enhanced private
antitrust litigation, the so-called voice options for shareholders increase (cf. Hirschman,
1970). At first glance, the modernisation and shareholder activism in antitrust litigation
may not appear related. In addition to legal actions against accounting manipulation, or
security fraud in cases of inaccurate disclosure of information, a wide range of other events
can account for legal actions induced by shareholders, such as: breaches of contract, patent
infringements, product failures, bankruptcy issues, slander, marketing, distribution and
franchise disputes and notably, also antitrust violations (cf. Bizjak and Coles, 1995). As a
rule of thumb, the more regulatory fields become subject to private enforcement, the more
rent-seeking private investor groups are provided with new windows of opportunity to alter
the corporate power balance in their favour and pursue corporate governance goals.
Challenging mismanagement and fraudulent behaviour of CEOs at the courts may serve as
a means to veto inauspicious decisions by CEOs, to intervene in the decision making in the
cases of share value loss, to alter the composition of the management, or to conduct hostile
takeover bids by litigating target companies. Shareholder activism in antitrust matters may
expose management boards to new risks regarding long-term investment strategies and, in
the worst-case bankruptcy, which makes for easy prey for hostile takeovers. The
institutional anchoring of short-term performance indicators in antitrust assessments
provides additional ground for litigation. Even the mere threat of suing may discipline
company boards to deliver higher returns on investment in the short-run.
322
different interests: whereas, for instance, certain hedge funds may follow an aggressive
strategy of short-term profit maximisation, (investment) banks, insurance companies, and
(certain) pension funds may be more inclined to secure more long-term investment.
Moreover, the interests of the shareholders of one company are not equivalent to those of
another company. The reason seems obvious. The exposure of a company to high damage
compensation payments and, in the worst-case, even bankruptcy or hostile takeovers,
eventually renders economic life more precarious for all stakeholders involved, including
shareholders.
In view of the current proposals for facilitated shareholder litigation in the EU Member
States, one is tempted to conclude that those shareholders opting for the Anglo-Saxon
litigation practice find themselves on the winning side. While Sweden and the UK have
already introduced the possibility for class action lawsuits in general, the German
government specifically included a range of measures that facilitate private actions in its
seventh amendment of competition law. As a part of the attempt to make Germany a global
financial centre with a stock market as a viable avenue for investment, two government
proposals were launched on 14 March in 2005 including a bill on shareholder class actions
and a bill on shareholder derivative lawsuits (Kamar, 2005: 17-18). Similarly, in Italy
shareholder rights have been strengthened and made conceptually reminiscent of US
corporate legislation to attract US investors (ibid: 22). In Finland, the Netherlands, and
France, the issue of facilitated shareholder litigation has also reached agenda status. For
instance in France, President Chirac instructed his government to put forward initiatives
for the introduction of class actions against abusive market practices an incremental
move that fits into the political landscape of the competition law overhaul.
323
legal services landscape in the EU demonstrates that the phenomenon of law companies
with a specialisation in antitrust issues is no longer a phenomenon restricted to the AngloSaxon type of capitalism (see also Chapter 1).
Since the 1990s, countless professional service companies, or law companies, with everexpanding numbers of lawyers and economists have established offices throughout Europe.
They emerged in the 1950s and 1960s in reaction to the expansion of US management
ideas in Europe (Djelic, 1998). Their number rapidly increased in the 1980s and the 1990s
(cf. Kelemen and Sibbitt, 2004; Kelemen, 2007). Many of these law companies originated
from across the Atlantic and from the UK, and sought to gain a foothold in the thriving
market of professional services in Europe. The dominant presence of US law companies in
Europe can be ascribed to two factors: on the one hand, worldwide liberalisation processes
required governments to open up national and regional markets for legal services. On the
other hand, enhanced liberalisation and cross-border economic transactions also spurred
the demand for legal services (see also Keleman, 2004: 111). The influx of US law
companies brought US legal practices and forms of organisation into Europe, such as
multijurisdictional litigation and lobbying services (ibid). Against the backdrop of the Bush
Administrations anti-litigation stance, a new flow of US law companies expanded into
Europe. As an US antitrust lawyer observed, some firms think Brussels will be the next
Washington (cited in: Henning, 2003).
Large Continental European law companies are also on the increase. Faced by the
particular competitive dynamics created by the mere size and global presence of US law
companies, implied that European law companies had to restructure along the lines of US
law companies. Through mergers and acquisitions, as well as corporate alliances, they
have organised themselves into larger units, similar to the US mega-law companies
(Kelemen, 2007: 7). The booming consultancy market in competition matters in Europe
forms part of the reason why. In France, the legal services market grew by 44% between
2000 and 2004, and is expected to grow another 41% by 2009. In Germany, the legal
service market grew by 20% in the time period (ibid: 8). A study reveals that about 80% of
the companies involved in a competition case turned to law companies for legal and
economic consultants, as well as professional lobbyists (Neven et al. 1998: 136). In
notification cases, 83,3% of companies made use of external legal advice. In cases where
there has been a prohibition decision, 53% of the companies consult economists as a last
324
sort resort defence (ibid: 136-138). On average, professional services account for 6% of
companies costs, at times increasing to 9% (Dombey, 2003b).
The workload of professional service companies increases not only with every new merger
wave, but also with the introduction of private enforcement in the EU. The US experience
with private enforcement best depicts the motivational grounds for the involvement of
private antitrust counsellors in defining the course of European competition law: it simply
earns their bread and butter (Calvani, 2004: 18). Legal experts already played a
significant counselling role under the previous notification procedure. The introduction of
private enforcement, however, increases corporate demand for judicial advocacy. It
provides a flourishing source of income for law companies specialised in competition
questions. As well as navigating companies through legal actions with specialised litigators
and more general judicial advocacy, professional services companies can offer tailor-made
compliance programmes for companies who have to assess themselves with regard to
Article 81-type agreements. In addition, the demand for specific market analyses and
economic modelling also increases, as well as targeted lobbying activities at the EU and
national regulatory authorities. It follows that law companies have a primary stake in open,
but rules-based markets, in which they can offer a combination of legal and advisory
services to other corporations. Moreover, fees will be higher, the more competition
regimes diverge, and the less standardised the problem (Morgan, 2005).
Professional service companies took the lead in the detailed formulation of possible
avenues to introduce enhanced private litigation in the EU. A comparative study conducted
by Ashurst, a transnational law company specialised in EC competition law, provided the
intellectual basis for the Commissions Green Paper on Damage Actions. In addition to a
detailed account on the possibilities for damage actions in the EU, it covered a wide range
of other litigation-related measures, such as the introduction of class actions (cf.
Waelbroeck et al., 2004). The legal community, including representatives from across the
Atlantic, contributed a vast number of detailed responses to the Commissions Green
Paper, which were overtly mild-mannered, if not wholeheartedly positive (cf. European
Commission, 2006a). Large law companies have an interest in creating similar market
conditions in the European litigation sector to the US.51 Organised as integrated networks
of individual partner agencies in different regions of the world, they do not only have
51
According to a ranking by The American Lawyer based on annual turnovers, US law companies
dominate the list of 100 global law companies (see for more http://www.thelawyer.com/global100/).
325
transnational corporations as their clients, but they have transnationalised themselves. They
are no longer restricted to domestic markets and clients, but comprise multijurisdictional
counselling related to cross-border transactions with licensed lawyers in different national
settings. With offices mainly in London, Brussels, and Frankfurt, they form part of a wider
and diffuse expert community surrounding the DG Competition. A dense fabric of
professional linkages marks their relationship. Law companies provide a vast source of
recruitment for competition law specialists, which again seek to inspire the future
development of competition policy. As Gerber (1998: xiv) noted, experts significantly
influence competition decisions in ways that are important and concealed. Similarly,
Enriques (2005: 44-45) argues that lawyers and legal scholars constitute an important
lobbying force in the production of EU law. Often, the Commission also contracts law
companies to prepare comparative studies on selected aspects of national laws, and to
make specific suggestions on policy-making as the Ashurst study demonstrates. While the
business community in Europe is expected to monitor itself and its competitors, with the
support of consultancy from professional law companies, the Commission embarked on its
own agenda, as the next section illustrates.
326
327
that competition in the common market was not distorted and that Articles 81 and 82 of the
EC Treaty are applied effectively and uniformly throughout the community. In this sense,
both the decentralisation and the establishment of the ECN, serve the purpose of
consolidating a culture of competition in the common market, as well as creating an
increased commitment, on the part of NCAs, to more stringently ensure the workings of
free competition. In an EU with heterogeneously structured national jurisdictions, distinct
procedural practices may also raise the potential for conflict. Aware of this, the
Commission financed specific competition law training schemes for more than 700
national judges in 2005 in order to streamline the jurisdictional enforcement (Kroes,
2005d), which constitutes an opening move to diminishing the significance of national
competition laws and clearing the way for EU competition law.
Rather than making itself obsolete, the Commission hopes to refocus its staff resources on
cracking down more vigorously on cartels at global level, leaving smaller cases to private
trustbusters and national jurisdictions. To this purpose, Regulation 1/2003 considerably
increased the Commissions investigative and sanctioning powers: it can conduct dawn
raids more easily than before and take oral statements from witnesses of cartel practices. In
addition to imposing fines that amount to 10% of a companys annual turnover, it can now
also impose fines for procedural breaches and require periodic penalty payments. The
incentive to patrol the globe for hard-core cartels needs to be placed in the context of the
free market ideology, which underpins the transformation. Accordingly, the removal of
privately erected barriers would guarantee the free flow of market forces. The Commission
thereby follows the example of the US authorities, which celebrated the golden age of
cartel prosecution by dissolving a range of high-level price-fixing cases in the late 1990s.
They levied the highest fines ever and imprisoned a range of CEOs (Litan and Shapiro,
2001: 27). In the absence of a world competition authority, the Commission has tried to
expand the EUs powers beyond its borders and fight transnational cartels in duopoly with
the US agencies. Similar to the US authorities, it drastically increased the size of fines
imposed on companies involved in cartels. Compared to the ridiculously light fines of
1969 with ECU 500.000 fine, and of 1983 with ECU 1.250.000, in 1986, fines reached
ECU 58 million (McGowan, 1007b: 6). More recently, the fines levied upon carteleers
reached new hights. Topping the list of the largest fines ever is the 480 million fine
levied on ThyssenKrupp in 2007.
328
The EU competition law reform was intended to convey a world class regulatory system
(European Commission, 2002a). The impetus, however, reaches further than mere prestige
and competence seeking on the part of a regulatory body that long suffered from the image
of being the junior partner of the US agencies. The reform constitutes a case in point that
seeks to foster the project of an ever-closer Union by deepening neoliberal market
integration. It took root against the background of the reinvigorated discourse surrounding
the Lisbon Agenda of 2000, aimed at making the EU the most dynamic knowledge-based
and competitive economy by 2010, and in a wider sense, aimed at outperforming the US
economy and the rest of the world. According to the dominant neoliberal view, this is best
achieved by downsizing Brussels regulatory jungle, which is also conform to the
interests of the executive boards of transnational corporations. With the privatisation and
decentralisation of important aspects of EU competition law enforcement, the reform
seems to deviate no longer from this prevailing tenet.
329
The competition laws and policies of different countries should closely resemble one
another and be as universal as the applicability of micro-economic analysis.
Frdric Jenny, Chairman of the OECD Competition Law and Policy Committee (2000: 23)
Conclusion:
The Politics of the Transformation of the EU Competition Regime
The dissertation argues that EC/EU competition policy, in content, scope, as well as form,
has undergone a profound transformation since its enactment in the Treaty of Rome in
1957, and that this transformation needs to be understood against the background of
broader ideational and socioeconomic changes in the history of the European integration
project. The transformation of what has been identified here as the European competition
model (see Chapter 2), started in the mid-1980s. Neoliberal ideas increasingly gained a
foothold in Europe, affecting EU economic policymaking, including competition policy.
Throughout the 1990s, neoliberalism subsequently was established as the dominant
ideology in the daily enforcement practice of the European Commissions DG
Competition. In the early 21st century, a fundamental overhaul of the EU competition
regime institutionally anchored the neoliberal orientation. Backed up by sophisticated
econometric modelling in the assessment of anticompetitive conduct, the reform
consolidated a narrow competition only focus, and the use of microeconomic reasoning.
of
production
and
ownership
structures.
Processes
of
transnationalisation, most notably the detachment of national ownership structures and the
(re-)location of production, fundamentally changed the interests and preferences of large
corporations. In addition, enhanced market integration in Europe, and across the Atlantic,
as well as the subsequent removal of global barriers to trade and capital, contributed to this
process. The increased confrontation between transnationally operating corporations and
different competition regulatory regimes evoked a shared interest among transnational
corporations in more transparency and legal certainty regarding their economic
331
When competition laws became one of the core constitutional principles of the founding
Treaty of Rome in 1957, establishing the European Economic Community (EEC),
European Treaty-drafters had internalised the language of market competition, and
considered competition laws important for the economic integration project. The reason
why the EC competition model looked different to its US counterpart can be ascribed to
the enduring opposition of powerful industry representatives in Europe, and to some
extend the particular ordoliberal ideas of the so-called Freiburg School (see Chapter 2 and
3). Ordoliberalism promoted an ordered and balanced market structure, in which equally
332
matched competitors, mostly small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs), would engage
in competition with each other. According to this paradigm, it was the task of strong state
authorities to foster competition by actively curbing the emergence of excessive economic
concentration, and dissolving anticompetitive corporate agreements. The concentration of
economic power in the form of oligopolies and monopolies, as well as cartels, was
believed to undermine the advantages offered by a free market economy, and in the end
democracy, as concentrated economic power would also eventually seek political power.
The EC competition law enforcement institutions and practices were to some extent
inspired by ordoliberal ideas. Remnants of the ordoliberal ideology can be found
throughout the 1960s, 1970s, and occasionally also in the early 1980s (see Chapter 4). The
European Commission, however, never adopted a strict interpretation of ordoliberal ideas.
This was to some extent due to the institutional positioning of the Council in the
Community structure. In the 1960s, in particular, there was little scope for the rather
inexperienced Commission officials to play a prominent and proactive role in competition
law enforcement, despite the powerful powers entrusted upon the Commission by
Regulation 17.
In the era of embedded liberalism, stretching from the 1950s to the late 1970s, and partly to
the early 1980s (see Chapter 3 and 4), EC competition laws were enforced in a flexible
market interventionist manner, displaying protectionist and neomercantilist traits. Rather
than adopting a strict competition focus, the Commission adjusted its decision making to
what in the preamble of the Rome Treaty was identified as balanced trade and fair
competition. A range of developments had a major impact on content, form, and scope of
EC competition policy in this time. Ongoing trade liberalisation within GATT made it
increasingly difficult for EC Member States to erect conventional protectionist barriers to
insulate national industries from foreign competitive pressures. This led to the adoption of
new protectionist measures at Member State level, which were directed at national
industries and national champions, considered strategic both in the private and public
sector. Protectionist non-tariff policies formed part of a countervailing strategy to boost
economic growth and the ability of European corporations to face competition with the
often larger, and technologically more advanced US companies. Various forms of state aid
were granted, such as guaranteed preferential public procurement contracts, tax rebates for
some industries, (research) subsidies, and investment in technical education, but also
national standard setting, and the stimulation of mergers and acquisitions among national
333
companies. In the 1960s and 1970s, EC competition laws were enforced in a consistent
manner with the dominant embedded liberalism bargain at national level. In line with
Member State and corporate interests, the Commission did not vigorously challenge
national state aid, leaving the provisions prohibiting state aid largely unenforced. The
protection of the competitive process was frequently subordinated to broader,
macroeconomic industrial policy goals, also allowing public interest and employment
considerations to be taken into account. EC competition law enforcement thereby formed a
political response to the challenges posed by the much larger and more homogeneous US
market. The Commission was overtly responsive to the interests of European industries
seeking to catch up with the much stronger US economy, and adopted a supportive stance
towards European companies. The gradual incorporation of national markets into one
common market in Europe was intended to create the basic prerequisites that would allow
sufficiently large (nationally based) corporations to reap the benefits of economies of scale
production, and to expand in size. Without loosing sight of the European integration
project, the Commission sought to synthesise the removal of internal barriers to trade and
competition with the adoption of a rather lenient attitude towards mergers and acquisitions
(M&As). It actively stimulated (cross-border) intercompany alliances, designed to pool
R&D investments, and various forms of production, distribution, or marketing joint
ventures. Thereby, it sought to thwart the practice in which governments picked their
national winners, and actively stimulated strong Eurochampions instead, able to face the
presumed American challenge. The absence of merger control laws in the Treaty of
Rome was constitutive in this regard. At the same time, in most cases, SMEs were
exempted from the necessity to comply with EC competition laws, which provided them in
practice with a carte blanche to engage in various types of corporate alliances.
In the years of economic crisis starting in the 1970s, EC competition law enforcement was
subordinated to a broad-based crisis management, which aimed at rescuing various
European industries in decline. The Commission gave preferential treatment to certain
industrial sectors by (temporarily) exempting so-called structural crisis cartels from the
necessity to compete, which engendered not only the preservation of companies, but also
of jobs. Once it became clear in the late 1970s and early 1980s that attempts to solve the
enduring economic crisis were not successful, neoliberalism, as a counter project to
embedded liberalism, increasingly gained the discursive upper hand among political and
corporate elites in many European countries (see Chapter 5). The Commission, in
334
The renewed emphasis on competition as a central market organising mechanism was not
simply bound up with what is commonly referred to as the rationale of economic
globalisation, but rather induced by social and political forces at the EC level. European
business elites, heading large transnationally operating corporations, started a vigorous
political campaign at the Commission in the 1980s and 1990s. Most notably, the European
Round Table of Industrialists (ERT) requested the endorsement of concrete neoliberal
policy positions at EC level. In addition to overall claims for more deregulation, it
advocated the completion of the common market project. It considered the common market
to be not half as open as that of the US, and hence a severe handicap for the development
of economic growth. In search of new lucrative prospects of corporate expansion, the ERT
promoted the liberalisation and privatisation of state-owned key utility and infrastructure
sectors. In response, the Commissions DG Competition endorsed so-called privatisation
directives under Article 90(3), a previously unused legal provision allowing the
Commission to issue directives in the field of public enterprises and state monopolies,
without the approval of the Council of Ministers. Similarly, in a joint effort with UNICE
and its national member business associations, the ERT successfully pushed for the
introduction of a pan-European merger regulation, which was adopted in 1989. Entrusting
the Commission with exclusionary powers to vet large mergers and acquisitions meeting a
defined turnover threshold meant that companies could bypass the often stricter Member
335
State merger regulations. Rather than prohibiting economic concentrations, the centralised
merger control regime was designed to facilitate (cross-border) mergers. Against the
background of the enhanced pace of economic integration, enacted by the 1992programme, and the neoliberal deregulation and liberalisation more generally, the number
of cross-border mergers sharply increased, leading to a profound restructuring of the
common market. The Merger Regulation resulted in significant concentrations of
transnational capital: since its enactment, the Commission approved more than 95% of all
notified mergers. It should therefore not come as a surprise that transnational corporations
were among the strongest supporters of the EU merger control regime.
The amalgamation of neoliberalism into the European integration project was constitutive
to the spread of neoliberal ideas elsewhere in the world, in particular as the EU took an
active role in setting the conditions for open and competitive markets, not only within
Europe, but since the 1990s also on a global scale. The Commissions DG Competition
evolved as one of the chief socialisers, who sought to craft a common understanding on
competition policy as a tool for the successful management of economic policies around
the world. It has played a major role in launching global initiatives, aimed at establishing a
336
multilateral agreement on competition control within the WTO (see Chapter 7). Even
though such an agreement did not materialise, due to the stark opposition of the US and a
range of developing countries, these activities indicate that the Commission seeks to play a
vital role in the promotion of global convergence of competition laws. Instead of a binding
WTO agreement on competition, the non-binding and more informal International
Competition Network (ICN) has been established. It was declared the chief mechanism for
achieving global convergence of competition laws and practices. Currently, both the US
competition authorities and the Commission take a leading role in defining regulatory
standards and so-called best practices for competition authorities around the world.
Moreover, the Commission engaged unilaterally in a range of advocacy activities. It has
started a dialogue on competition issues with developing countries and is providing
material and immaterial aid for building up competition authorities, as well opportunities
for the exchange of personnel activities that are generally referred to as technical
assistance and capacity-building.
Corporate pressures and repeated critique on the lack of transparency and legal certainty of
the Commissions still rather flexible decision making, eventually led to a fundamental
overhaul of the EU competition regime in 2004 (see Chapter 8). The permeation of
neoliberal ideas in the enforcement of competition laws entered a phase of consolidation,
breaking definitely with the broadly defined macroeconomic industrial and social policy
objectives that dominated competition policy in the era of embedded liberalism. Against
the background of the broader neoliberal restructuring of the common market project since
the mid-1980s, the transformed EU competition regime exposes competition law
enforcement to market mechanisms and introduces a more microeconomic reasoning in the
assessment of anticompetitive conduct. Through the abolition of the administrative public
control model, and the concomitant decentralisation of Article 81 and 82, the
administrative barriers posed by the necessity to notify intended cooperative agreements
with other companies to the Commission were removed. This enhanced the freedom of
companies to engage in various types of corporate alliances. The reform rested upon the
view that less regulation is better regulation and marketbased solutions are superior to the
interventionist arm of a public authority. This strengthens the power of transnationally
operating corporations not only in the realm of the common market, but also on a global
scale. The primacy of enforcement has shifted to the proactivity of private parties who are
expected to bring observed antitrust breaches to the national courts. Private enforcement,
337
338
339
In addition, it is also necessary to take into account the structural power balance between
transnational corporations, domestic governments, labour, and small and medium-sized
domestic companies. This balance of power has shifted considerably in favour of
transnationally operating companies. With the emergence of transnational corporations
operating on a global scale, the common distinction of European companies versus foreign
companies has become increasingly problematic. Nonetheless, the overwhelmingly large
share of transnational corporations finds its origin in the Western, industrialised part of the
world. Transnational corporations generate combined annual turnovers that often exceed
the GDP of developing countries. It is generally assumed that more than 40% of global
trade consists of intra-firm trade flows, which implies that prices for goods and services are
not determined by markets, but by transnational corporations. Internal transfer price
mechanisms, the maximisation of economies of scale and scope, the ability to reduce
market risks through outsourcing production, as well as the ability to generate large sums
of capital, combined with the overall leverage power vis--vis governments, labour, and
competitors, all these factors constitute sources of comparative advantage unmatched by
small and medium-sized companies. Transnational corporations, as the central sources of
foreign direct investment, enjoy considerable structural bargaining power vis--vis their
host countries governments, labour, corporate affiliates, and local competitors, which
340
allows them to influence market rules to their advantage. Free competition, and the right to
freely access new markets, contributes to the very mechanism perpetuating socioeconomic
inequality and power imbalances on the global market place. The standards of competition
are set by those able to compete. The nature of global competition is rather oligopolistic. In
order to expand market shares and to be able to invest in more efficient production
technologies, capital accumulation constitutes a necessity for economic survival in a
globally competitive environment. This has crucial repercussions for the overall structure
of the global economy, in particular regarding the prospects for economic development by
the structurally disadvantaged South. Seen from the contemporary worldwide distribution
of accumulated wealth, that is the fundamental gap between North and South, competition
erects a hierarchy of socioeconomic relations marked by inequalities in wealth and power,
which extends from the individual, groups, or classes, to geographical regions in the world.
Competition therefore is not exclusively the domain of companies competing with each
other in the form of innovative products sold for low prices to consumers in the global
market place. Cities, states, and entire geographical regions compete to attract business
investments, work, and hence, social welfare.
The transformation of the EU competition regime reaches further than the realm of the EU,
or the transatlantic market place. This becomes particularly apparent with regard to the
Commissions involvement in the International Competition Network (ICN), which seeks
to establish global convergence of competition laws and practices. The endorsement of the
neoliberal free market philosophy at Commission-level implies that neoliberal ideas
regarding competition policy will be promoted by the Commission also on a global scale.
Convergence in a field such as competition policy is not simply the result of globalisation
processes, or independent, unilateral governmental decisions, or decisions by state
agencies, to reorientate their regulatory competition regime into the direction of another.
Rather, convergence, if it can be observed, is the result of a political practice. In this case,
dominant players, such as the US and EU competition authorities, promote a particular
vision of competition laws and practices. Convergence is not in the primary interest of
public institutions. Those pressing for more convergence of competition laws and
enforcement are transnationally operating companies engaged in various cross-border
business transactions. The proliferation of competition regimes around the world in the
1990s increased not only the transaction costs emerging from the phenomenon of
multijurisdictional overlap, it also fuelled corporate concerns about the possibility that
341
342
References
Aaronson, S.A. (1996), Trade and the American Dream, Kentucky, USA: University Press
of Kentucky.
Acheson, D. (1969), Present at the Creation. My Years in the State Department, 1987,
New York: Norton.
Adams, W. and J.W. Brock (1990), 'Mergers and Economic Performance: The Experience
Abroad', Review of Industrial Organization 5(2).
Akbar, Y. (2003), 'Slip Sliding Away? The ChangingPolitics of European Car
Distribution', Business and Politics 5(2), pp. 175-192.
Albert, M. (1993), Capitalism Against Capitalism, London: Whurr Publishers.
Alden, E. (2000), 'Protests Make a Mark on World Trade Leaders', Financial Times,
International Economy, 20 November, Cincinnati, p. 10.
Alden, E. (2001), 'Corporate Chiefs Call For Cheaper Antitrust Process', Financial Times,
International Economy, 17 May, p. 10.
Allen, T. (2005), 'Interest in Class Action Grows Outside the U.S.' Securities Litigation
Watch, 14 June, available at:
https://slw.issproxy.com/securities_litigation_blo/2005/06/the_state_of_fo.html,
02.01. 2008.
Alexander, C.R. (1999), 'On the Nature of the Reputational Penalty for Corporate Crime',
Journal of Law and Economics 42(1), pp. 489-526.
Alves, P. and M. Abrantes Pires (2000), 'Globalization and Labour Control in One Auto
Plant in Portugal: The Case Of Autoeuropa', paper for the International Workshop
on Lean Production and Labour Force in the Car Industry. The Forms of
Implementation of an Epoch-Making Model, 25-27 March, University of Calabria.
Anderson, R. and F. Jenny (2005), 'Competition Policy, Economic Development and the
Role of a Possible Multilateral Framework on Competition Policy: Insights from
the WTO Working Group on Trade and Competition Policy. Chapter 4', in: E.
Medalla (ed.), Competition Policy in East Asia, UK: Routledge, pp. 61-85.
Anderson, R.D. and P. Holmes (2002), 'Competition Policy and the Future of the
Multilateral Trading System', University at Sussex at Brighton, Discussion Papers
in Economics (84).
Andriessen, F. (1981a), 'Antitrust in the International Sphere. Antitrust an Endangered
Species?' Speech held before the American Bar Association's National Institute on
Antitrust, November 6, Washington. Brussels: Historical Archives of the European
Commission.
Andriessen, F. (1981b), 'Het Mededingingsbeleid in de jaren 80', Speech at the Algemene
Ledenvergadering van de Raad voor het Filiaal -en Grootwinkelbedrijf, 29
September, Brussels: Archives of the European Commission.
Andriessen, F. (1982a), 'Antitrust Law in the EEC, Principle Features and Trends', speech
at the American Chamber of Commerce', 26 November, Brussels: Archives of the
European Commission.
Andriessen, F. (1982b), 'Speech to the Groupe des Presidents des Grandes Entreprises
Europeennes', Ludwigshafen. Brussels: Archives of the European Commission.
Andriessen, F. (1983a), 'Developments in the Competition Policy of the EEC', speech at
the International Political Science Association, at the London School of Economics,
25-26 February, Brussels: Archives of the European Commission.
Andriessen, F. (1983b), 'The Role of Antitrust in the Face of Economic Recession. State
Aids in the EEC, 16 September', speech at the Second Oxford International
Antitrust Law Conference, Oxford. Brussels: Archives of the European
Commission.
343
344
345
Brittan, L. (1996), 'Investment Liberalisation: A New Issue for WTO. Europe and the
Challenge of Global Economy', speech at the Confederation of British Industry
(CBI) Conference, 11 November, Harrogate.
Brittan, L. and K. van Miert (1996), 'Towards an International Framework of Competition
Rules. Communication to the Council',Brussels: European Commission, available
at http://europe.eu.int/comm/competition/international/com284.html, 02.01.2008.
Brmmelmeyer, C. (2000), 'Interactive Regulation: A Plea for a Reform of International
Antitrust Law', The European Legal Forum (E) 3-2000/01, pp. 192-9.
Buch-Hansen, H. and Wigger, A. (2007), Revisiting 50 Years of Market-Making: The
Neoliberal Transformation of EC Competition Policy. Paper presented at the panel
The Marketisation of European Economic Policies - A Critical Encounter, at the
British International Studies Association (BISA) Annual Conference 2007, 17 - 19
December, University of Cambridge.
Buch-Hansen, H. (forthcoming), 'Rethinking the Evolution of European Merger Control. A
Critical Political Economy Perspective', Copenhagen Business School PhD Series,
Copenhagen, Denmark.
Budzinski, O. (2002), 'The International Competition Network and Its Governance of
Cross-Border Mergers. An Analysis from the Perspective of New Institutional
Economics', paper for 2nd CSI-Conference on 'International Institutions and
Multinational Enterprises - Global Players, Global Markets'. Innsbruck, 20th - 22nd
November 2002.
Budzinski, O. (2003), 'Pluralism of Competition Policy Paradigms and the Call for
Regulatory Diversity', Volkswirtschaftliche Beitrge Universitt Marburg, 14.
Bulmer, S. (1994), Institutions and Policy Change in the European Union: The Case of
Merger Control, Public Administration, 72 (Autumn), pp. 423-444.
Bukharin, N.I. (1929), Imperialism and World Economy: Marxists Internet Archive 2001,
available at
http://www.marxists.org/archive/bukharin/works/1917/imperial/index.htm,
02.01.2008.
Business Law Europe (1996), 'TABD Progress Report', 31 May.
Bthe, T. and G.T. Swank (2005), 'The Politics of Antitrust and Merger Review in the
European Union: Institutional Change and Decisions from Messina to 2004', paper
for Research Seminar of the Institute for Global and International Studies, 8
December Elliott School of International Studies, George Washington University,
available
at
http://www2.gwu.edu/~igis/Buthe%20Swank%20paper.pdf,
14.05.2006.
Bthe, T. (2007), The Politics of Competition in the European Union: The First 50 Years,
in S. Meunier & K.R. McNamara (eds) The State of the European Union, Vol.8,
Oxford/New York: Oxford University Press.
Butler, M. (1986), 'How Europe Can Fight The Multinationals', Financial Times, 5
January, London, p. 17.
Buxbaum, H.L. (2006), 'German Legal Culture and the Globalization of Competition Law:
A Historical Perspective on the Expansion of Private Antitrust Enforcement.
Article 10 in Issues in Legal Scholarship', German Legal Culture and the
Globalization of Competition Law, available at
http://www.bepress.com/ils/iss9/art10, 14.05.2006.
Calvani, T. (2003), 'Devolution and Convergence in Competition Enforcement', European
Competition Law Review (ECLR), 24(9).
Calvani, T. (2004), 'Conflict, Cooperation & Convergence in International Competition',
paper for the 90th Anniversary Symposium of the Federal Trade Commission.
346
347
Cini, M. and F. McGowan (1998), Competition Policy in the European Union, New York:
St. Martins Press.
Commun, P. (2004), 'Erhards Behkehrung zum Ordoliberalismus: Die grundlegende
Bedeutung des wirtschaftspolitischen Diskurses in Umbruchszeiten', Freiburg
Discussion Papers on Constitutional Economics (4).
Council (1963), European Yearbook / Annuaire Europen, Volume 11, 1963 Council of
Europe, Brussels: Martinus Nijhoff Publishers.
Council (1965), European Yearbook/Annuaire Europen, Volume 13, 1965, Council of
Europe, Brussels: Martinus Nijhoff Publishers.
Council (1968), European Yearbook/Annuaire Europen, Volume 16, 1968, Council of
Europe, Brussels: Martinus Nijhoff Publishers.
Cowen, R. (2006), 'Chapter Fourteen: Cartels, and Various Metal Cans of Worms',
Genealogy Website, available at
http://www.geology.ucdavis.edu/~cowen/~GEL115/115CH14aluminum.html,
13.06.2007.
Cox, A. and G. Watson (1995), 'The European Community and the Restructuring of
Europe's National Champions. From National to European Champions in Western
Europe', in: J. Hayward (ed.), Industrial Enterprise and European Integration,
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Cox, R.W. (1981), 'Social Forces, States and World Orders: Beyond International
Relations Theory', Millennium: Journal of International Studies 10(2), pp. 126-155.
Cox, R.W. (1996), 'Social Forces, States, and World Orders: Beyond International
Relations Theory', in: R.W. Cox (ed.), Approaches to World Order, Cambridge:
Cambridge Univerisity Press.
Cox, R.W. and D. Skidmore-Hess (1999), US Politics and the Global Economy. Corporate
Power, Conservative Shift, London: Lynne Rienner Publishers.
Craig, P. and G. De Burca (1998), EU Law. Text, Cases, and Materials, Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
Crandal, R.W. and C. Winston (2005), 'Does Antitrust Policy Improve Consumer Welfare?
Assessing the Evidence', Chapter 2, in: C. Robinson (ed.), Governments,
Competition and Utility Regulation, London Business School, The Institute of
Economic Affairs, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing Limited.
Crouch, C. (2000), 'Introduction: The Political and institutional Deficits of European
Monetary Union', in: C. Crouch (ed.), After the Euro: Shaping Institutions for
Governance in the Wake of European Monetary Union, Oxford: Oxford University
Press.
Crouch, C. and W. Streeck (eds)(1997), Political Economy of Modern Capitalism.
Mapping Convergence and Diversity, London: Sage.
Damro, D.C. (2002), 'Economic Internationalization and Competition Policy. International
and Domestic Sources of Transatlantic Cooperation', Graduate Faculty of Arts and
Sciences,
Pittsburgh:
University
of
Pittsburgh,
available
at:
http://etd.library.pitt.edu:80/ETD/available/etd-11222002-081019/, 17.11.2003.
Damro, D.C. (2004), 'International Competition Policy: Bilateral and Multilateral Efforts at
Dispute Prevention', in: B. Hocking and S. McGuire (eds), Trade Politics,
Routledge.
Damro, C. (2006a), 'Transatlantic Competition Policy: Domestic and International Sources
of EU-US Cooperation', European Journal of International Relations 12(2), pp.
171196.
Damro, C. (2006b), 'The New Trade Politics and EU Competition Policy: Shopping for
Convergence and Co-operation', Journal of European Public Policy 13(6), pp. 867886.
348
349
http://www.staff.ncl.ac.uk/i.m.dobbs/Files/market%20definition%20general%20cas
e.pdf, 02.01.2008.
Dombey, D. (2003a), 'EU Competition Authorities Put Among Top of the Class', Financial
Times, International Economy, June 17, Brussels.
Dombey, D. (2003b), 'Monti Focuses on Lawyers and Architects', Financial Times, 28
October, Brussels.
Dombey, D. (2004), 'EU Antitrust Reforms Will See Rulings Decentralized: The Balance
of Competition Power is Set to Shift Dramatically When the European Union
Enlarges Next Month', Financial Times, 24 April, London, p.7.
Dombey, D. and R. Waters (2004), 'Relations Shattered', Financial Times, The Microsoft
Verdict, 25 March, London, p. 28.
Donohue, T.J. (2003), 'Legal Reform Press Conference of the U.S. Chamber of
Commerce', 18 September, available at
http://www.uschamber.com/press/speeches/2003/030918tjd_legalreform.htm,
02.01.2008.
Drn, G.B. (1996), 'Comparative Competition Policy: Boundaries and Levels of Political
Analysis. Chapter 2', in: B.G. Drn and S. Wilks (eds), Comparative Competition
Policy. National Institutions in a Global Market, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Drn, G.B. and S. Wilks (1996), Comparative Competition Policy. National Institutions in
a Global Market, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Draghi, M. (2003), 'US-EU Regulatory Convergence Capital Markets Issues Vice
Chairman, Goldman Sachs International', speech at the Second Mmeeting of the
Transatlantic Strategy Groups, 12-14 February, Miami, Center for Applied Policy
Research, Munich, and Bertelsmann Foundation, Guetersloh, available at
http://www.cap.uni-muenchen.de/download/2003/2003_Miami_Draghi.pdf,
02.01.2008.
Drahos, M. (2001), 'Convergence of Competition Laws and Policies in the European
Community. Germany, Austria and the Netherlands', Amsterdam: University of
Amsterdam.
Edwards, J. and S. Ogilvie (1996), 'The Universal Banks and German Industrialization: A
Reappraisal ', Economic History Review New Series 49(3), pp. 427-446.
Ehricke, U. (2003), 'Comments', in: J. Drexl (ed), The Future of Transnational Antitrust From Comparative to Common Competition Law, Berne: Staempfli Publishers Ltd.
Eickhof, N. and K. Isele (2005), 'Eine Politkonomische Analyse des Einflusses
wettbewerspolitischer Leitbilder auf die Europische Fusionskontrolle',
Volkswirtschaftliche Diskussionsbeitrge, Potsdam: Universitt Potsdam.
Eizenstat, S.E. (2003), 'Testimony of Subcommittee on European Affairs Committee on
Foreign Relations US Senate, October 16'.
Ellis, W. (1983), 'Grim Warning on EEC Information Technology', Financial Times,
World Trade News, February 25, p. 5.
Enriques, L. (2005), 'EC Company Law Directives and Regulations: How Trivial Are
They?' European Corporate Governance Institute (ECGI) Working Paper Series in
Law 39 (May).
Erhard, L. (1957), Wohlstand fr Alle, Dsseldorf: Econ.
ERT (1983), 'Part 2: Foundations for the Future of European Industry. Memorandum to EC
Commissioner E. Davignon, 17-19 June', paper for EEC Summit Meeting,
Stuttgart, available at http://www.ert.be/doc/0055.pdf, 02.01.2008.
ERT (1993), 'Beating the Crisis. A Charter for Europe's Industrial Future', Brussels:
European
Round
Table
of
Industrialists,
available
at
http://www.ert.be/doc/0129.pdf, 02.01.2008.
350
351
352
European Commission (2004), 'Communication from the Commission to the Council and
the European Parliament. The EU Approach to the Millenium Round: Summary',
available at
http://trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2006/december/tradoc_111111.pdf,
02.01.2008.
European Commission (2005a), 'The Future Of EU Car Industry: Stakeholders Have Their
Say'Brussels, available at
http://europa.eu.int/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference=IP/05/480&format=H
TML&aged=0&language=EN&guiLanguage=en, 02.01.2008.
European Commission (2005b), 'Green Paper 'Damages Actions for Breach of the EC
Antitrust Rules', available at
http://europa.eu.int/comm/competition/antitrust/others/actions_for_damages/gp_en.
pdf, 15.09.2006.
European Commission (2006a), 'Comments on the Green Paper on Damages Actions for
Breach of the EC Antitrust Rules', available at
http://ec.europa.eu/comm/competition/antitrust/others/actions_for_damages/gp_con
tributions.html, 15.09.2007.
European Commission (2006b), 'Contributions Received in Response to the Public
Consultation on the 'Modernization Package', available at
http://ec.europa.eu/comm/competition/antitrust/legislation/procedural_rules/comme
nts/, 02.01.2008.
European Commission (2006c), 'The Trans-Atlantic Business Dialogue (TABD):
Entrepreneurial Diplomacy. Between EU and US Business And Governments',
available at
http://ec.europa.eu/enterprise/enterprise_policy/business_dialogues/tabd/thetabd.ht
m, 02.01.2008.
European Commission (2007): European Merger Control - Council Regulation 139/2004 Statistics. 21 September 1990 to 31 December 2007, available at
http://ec.europa.eu/comm/competition/mergers/statistics.pdf, 02.01.2008.
European Community (1962), 'Council Regulation (EEC) No 17. First Regulation
Implementing Articles 85 and 86 of the Treaty', Official Journal 13 (21.02).
European Parliament (1999), 'Report on the Commission White Paper on Modernisation of
the Rules Implementing Articles 85 and 86 of the EC Treaty', COM, available at
http://www.futureofeurope.parlament.gv.at/sides/getDoc.do?pubRef=//EP//NONSGML+REPORT+A5-1999-0069+0+DOC+PDF+V0//EN, 03.01.2008.
European Union (2001), 'Monti Dismisses Criticism of GE/Honeywell Merger Review,
Deplores Politicization of the Case', Press Release IP/01/855.
European Union (2003), 'Glossary ', available at
http://ec.europa.eu/comm/competition/general_info/c_en.html#23, 02.01.2008.
European Voice (1998), 'News in Brief', available at http://www.europeanvoice.com/archive/issue.asp?id=110, 18.12.2006.
Eyre, S. and M. Lodge (2000), 'National Tunes and a European Melody? Competition Law
Reform in the UK and Germany ', Journal of European Public Policy 7(1), pp. 6379.
Fairclough, N. (2003), 'Semiotic Aspects of Social Transformation and Learning', in: R.
Rogers (ed.), New Directions in Critical Discourse Analysis: Semiotic Aspects of
Social Transformation and Learning, Erlbaum.
Fear, J. (2006), 'Cartels and Competition: Neither Markets nor Hierarchies', Working Paper
Harvard Business School 07 (11).
Federal Trade Commission (FTC) (2002), 'US-EU Merger Working Group: Best Practices
on Cooperation in Merger Investigations', available at
353
http://www.ftc.gov/opa/2002/10/mergerbestpractices.htm, 02.01.2008.
Feldenkirchen, W. (1992), 'Competition Policy in Germany', Business and Economic
History 21.
Feldman, G.D. (2006), 'The Post-1945 American Challenge to European Enterprise, 2125 August ', paper for the XIV International Economic History Congress Helsinki,
Finland, available at http://www.helsinki.fi/iehc2006/papers1/Feldman.pdf,
01.01.2008.
Fennema, M. (1982), International Networks of Banks and Industry The Hague: Martinus
Nijhoff Publishers.
Fikentscher, W. (2002), 'A Transnational Antitrust Converntion and the Recent European
Antirtust Proposals: Exercises in Economic Anthropology', in: C.A. Jones and M.
Matsushita (eds), Competition Policy in the Global Trading System, The
Netherlands: Kluwer Law International, pp. 341-386.
Fikentscher, W. and U. Immenga (eds) (1995), Draft International Antitrust Code:
kommentierter Entwurf eines internationalen Wettbewerbsrechts mit ergnzenden
Beitrgen, Baden-Baden: Nomos.
Finger, J.M. (1993), 'Antidumping Is Where the Action Is', Chapter 1 in: N.T. Artis and
J.M. Finger (eds), Antidumping: How It Works and Who Gets Hurt, Michigan:
University of Michigan Press.
First, H. (2002), 'Antitrust Goals: Theories of Antitrust in the United States and Japan',
Chapter 10 in: C. Jones and M. Matsushita (eds), Competition Policy in the Global
Trading System - Perspectives from the EU, Japan and the USA, Kluwer Academic
Publishers.
Fisher, A. (1989), 'Overseas News Merger Policy Talks Please German Cartel-Busters',
Financial Times, 1992 The European Market, 9 January, p. 3.
Foer, B. (2004), 'American Antitrust Institute', Holiday Review of Antitrust Books,
available at: http://www.antitrustinstitute.org/recent2/357.cfm, 09.07.2007.
Fox, E.M. (1997), 'US and EU Competition Law: A Comparison. Chapter 10', in: E.M.
Graham and Richardson. J.D. (eds), Global Competition Policy, Washington, D.C.:
Institute for International Economics.
Fox, E.M. (2003a), 'We Protect Competition, You Protect Competitors', World
Competition 26(2), pp. 149-165.
Fox, E.M. (2003b), 'What is Harm to Competition? Antitrust, Exclusionary Practices, and
the Elusive Notion of Anticompetitive Practices, and the Elusive Notion of
Anticompetitive Effect', in: J. Drexl (ed.), The Future of Transnational Antitrust From Comparative to Common Competition Law, Berne: Staempfli Publishers Ltd.
Fox, E.M. and R. Pitofsky (1997), 'United States', in: E.M. Graham and J.D. Richardson
(eds), Global Competition Policy, Washington, D.C.: Institute for International
Economics.
Freyer, T. (2006), Antitrust and Global Capitalism, 1930-2004, Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Friedman, M. (1962), 'Capitalism and Freedom', Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Friedman, M. (1999), 'The Business Community's Suicidal Impulse', CATO Policy Report
21(2).
FT (1982), 'Self Defence', Financial Times, Men&Matter, 27 July, Brussels, p. 14.
FT (1983), 'Car Producers Condemn EEC Move on Prices', Financial Times, by K.
Gooding, 24 October, p. 1.
FT (1984), 'Something for Everyone in Brussels' IBM Settlement', Financial Times, G. de
Jonquie'res, 3 August, p. 2.
FT (1989a), 'Brussels Flexes Its Muscles To Take a Swing At State Subsidies', Financial
Times, Overseas News by L. Kellaway, p. 6.
354
355
FT (1993k), 'Van Miert Calls for GATT Rules on Business Barriers', Financial Times, by
A. Hill, 9 October, p. 2.
FT (1993l), 'Van Miert Warns Energy Utilities', Financial Times, by A. Hill, 5 February,
Brussels, p. 3.
FT (1994a), 'The Battle for the Forecourt: European Carmakers Fear the Consequences if
their Exclusive Dealer Networks are Reformed', Financial Times, by K. Done, 16
September, p. 17.
FT (1994b), 'EU Industry Concerned at Competition: Round Table Seeks to Stop Drain of
Jobs to US, Asia', Financial Times, by L. Barber, 25 November, Brussels, p. 2.
FT (1994c), 'Restructuring Puts Thousands of Jobs at Risk, Financial Times, by A. Hill, 16
June, Brussels, p. 2.
FT (1994d), 'Socialist Redoubles Efforts on Behalf of Free Market: Paul Betts Talks to
Competition Commissioner Karel Van Miert', Financial Times, Monday Interview
by P. Betts, 13 June, Brussels, p. 2.
FT (1994e), 'Van Miert Equal to the Competition Despite Defeat: Andrew Hill Examines
the Policy Significance of the Go-Ahead Given to a Controversial Steel-Tube Joint
Venture', Financial Times, 27 January, p. 2.
FT (1995a), 'A Case for A Cartel Body', Financial Times, by C.D. Ehlermann, 7 March, p.
14.
FT (1995b), 'EU to Push for Greater Ties With US: Sir Leon Seeks to Overcome FrenchLed Resistance', Financial Times, World Trade News by L. Barber, 2 June,
Brussels, p. 4.
FT (1995c), 'Push to Break Europe Jobless Trend', Financial Times, by C. Southey, 21
June, Brussels, p. 3.
FT (1996a), 'Brittan Sets Tough Line for WTO', Financial Times, by G. de Jonquie'res, 20
September, p. 6.
FT (1996b), 'EU Closer on Telecoms and IT Accord', Financial Times, by N. Dunne, News
International, 11 November, Chicago, p. 6.
FT (1996c), 'EU Embraces the Cause of Free Trade: Brussels Advocates Liberalisation
with Convert's Passion', Financial Times, G. de by Jonquie'res, 6 August, p. 5.
FT (1996d), 'It's a Funny Old World Trade Organisation: Guy de Jonquie'res Reflects on
the Interminable Haggling at the Singapore Ministerial Meeting', Financial Times,
World Trade, 12 December, p. 6.
FT (1996e), 'Thorny 'New Issues' Set to Dominate Debate', Financial Times, World Trade,
9 December, p. 6.
FT (1996f), 'The Threat from Without: The FT Interview Helmut Maucher. Nestle's
Chairman Tells Lionel Barber Europe Must Become More Competitive', Financial
Times, Comment & Analysis, Brussels, p. 16.
FT (1996g), 'US, EU Closer on Telecoms and IT Accord', Financial Times, by N. Dunne,
News International, 11 November, Chicago, p. 6.
FT (1997), 'Boeing Warns of Trade War if Merger is Blocked', Financial Times, by M.
Skapinker, and E. Tucker,
14 May, Brussels, p. 1.
FT (1998a), 'EU and US in Antitrust Deal', Financial Time, by S. Iskandar, 5 June,
Brussels, p. 3.
FT (1998b), 'German Cartel Chief Calls for New World Body', Financial Times, New
Digest, 26 November, Bonn, p. 3.
FT (1998c), 'Moves Afoot to Clarify WTO's Role on Competition: Broad Participation in
Talks Starting Today Reflects Issue's Importance in Buttressing Market Principles',
Financial Times, by G. de Jonquie'res, 27 July, p. 4.
356
FT (1998e), 'No Monopoly on Antitrust: Personal View. Joel Klein: It would Be Premature
for the WTO to Seek to Enforce Global Competition Rules', Financial Times,
Comment & Analysis by. J. Klein, 13 February, p. 20.
FT (1998f), 'Tensions Rise Between Governments and the World of Business', Financial
Times, Survey by N. Moran, 1 April, Brussels, p.12.
FT (1998g), 'UK Chess Clash', Financial Times, Guide to the Week, 27 July, Brussels, p.
44.
FT (1998h), 'Uncharted, and Troubled, Waters', Financial Times, Survey - World Trade
System by G. de Jonquie'res, 18 May, Brussels, p. 4.
FT (1998i), 'Van Miert Calls for Competition Rules Accord', Financial Times, by G. de
Jonquie'res, 31 January, Davos Summit, p. 4.
FT (2007), 'Kroes Round on Critics of Antitrust Ruling', Financial Times, World News by
T. Buck, 20 September, Brussels, p. 8
Fuchs, A. (2003), 'Collaboration Among Competitors and the Concept of Restraint of
Competition. Comments on Hanns Ullrich', in: J. Drexl (ed.), The Future of
Transnational Antitrust - From Comparative to Common Competition Law, Berne:
Staempfli Publishers Ltd.
Fukuyama, F. (1992), The End of History and the Last Man, London: Hamish Hamilton.
Gande, A. and C.M. Lewis (2005), 'Shareholder Initiated Class Action Lawsuits:
Shareholder Wealth Effects and Industry Spillovers', Working Paper, Nashville:
Owen Graduate School of Management, Vanderbilt University, available at
http://www.sauder.ubc.ca/faculty/divisions/finance/conference2005/papers/CraigLe
wis-class_action_July2005.pdf, 14.09.2006.
Gallo, J.C., K. Dau-Schmidt, J.L. Craycraft and C.J. Parker (2000), 'Department of Justice
Antitrust Enforcement, 1955-1997: An Empirical Study', Review of Industrial
Organization 17, pp. 75-133.
Gauer, C. (2002), 'Does the Effectiveness of the EU Network of Competition Authorities
Require a Certain Degree of Harmonization of National Procedures and Sanctions?'
in: C.D. Ehlermann and I. Atanasiu (eds), European Competition Law Annual
2002. Constructing the EU Network of Competition Authorities, EUI RSCAS
European Competition Law Annual Series, Vol. 7, Oregon: Hart Publishing.
Gaughan, P.A. (2002), Mergers, Acquisitions, and Corporate Restructurings, New York:
John Wiley & Sons, Inc.
Gavil, A.I., W.E. Kovacic and J.B. Baker (2002), Antitrust Law in Perspective: Cases,
Concepts and Problems in Competition Policy, American Casebook Series, New
York: Thomson West.
Gehler, M. and H. von der Grben (2002), 'Europische Integration aus historischer
Erfahrung: ein Zeitzeugengesprch mit Michael Gehler/Hans von der Grben',
Zentrum fr Europische Integrationsforschung (ZEI) Discussion Paper, Bonn:
Rheinische Friedrich-Wilhelms-Universitt.
Geradin, D. and D. Henry (2003), 'The EC Fining Policy for Violations of Competition
Law: An Empirical Review of the Commission Decisional Practice and the
Community Courts Judgments', The Global Competition Law Centre Working
Papers Series 03(5).
Gerber, D.J. (1998), Law and Competition in Twentieth Century Europe: Protecting
Prometheus, 2003, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Gerber, D.J. (2002), 'The U.S. - European Conflict Over the Globalization of Antitrust
Law: A Legal Experience Perspective', New England Law Review 34(1).
Gerschenkron, A. (1962), Economic Backwardedness in Historical Perspective: A Bock of
Essays Cambridge and Massachusettes: Belknap Press.
357
Gerven, van W. (2005), 'Private Enforcement of EC Competition Rules', paper for the Joint
EU Commission/IBA Conference on Antitrust Reform in Europe: A Year in
Practice, Brussels, 10-11 March.
Gibb, J. M. (1986), 'A Catalyst in Europe', Financial Times, 19 February, London, p. 17.
Giersch, H. (1985), 'Eurosclerosis', Kiel Discussion Papers (112).
Gill, S.R. and D. Law (1989), 'Global Hegemony and the Structural Power of Capital',
International Studies Quarterly 33(4), pp. 475-499.
Gillingham, J. (2003), European Integration, 1950-2003: Superstate Or New Market
Economy?, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Gilpin, R. (2003), 'The Nature of Political Economy', Chapter 1 in: C.R. Goddard, P.
Cronin and K.C. Dash (eds), International Political Economy. State Market
Relations in a Changing Global Order, 2nd edition, UK: Palgrave McMillan.
Goddard, C.R. (2003), 'Defining the Transnational Cooperation in the Era of
Globalization', Chapter 25 in: C.R. Goddard, P. Cronin and K.C. Dash (eds),
International Political Economy. State Market Relations in a Changing Global
Order, 2nd edition, UK: Palgrave McMillan.
Goldschmidt, N. (2004), 'Alfred Mller-Armack and Ludwig Erhard: Social Market
Liberalism', Freiburg Discussion Papers on Constitutional Economics (12).
Goyder, D.G. (1998), EC Competition Law, 3rd edition, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Goyder, D.G. (2003), EC Competition Law, 4th edition, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Graf, D. (2000), 'Die Grndung des Transatatlantic Business Dialogue und die
Revitalisierung der EU-US-Beziehungen', Zrich: University of Zurich, available at
http://www.nadir.org/nadir/initiativ/agp/free/tabd/tabd_gruendung.htm#n14,
02.01.2008.
Green-Cowles, M. (1994), 'The Politics of Big Business in the European Community:
Setting the Agenda for a New Europe', Washington DC: American University
Green-Cowles, M. (2000a), 'Private Firms and US-EU Policymaking: The Transatlantic
Business Dialogue', in: E. Philippart and P. Winand (eds), Policy-Making in the
US-EU Relationship, Manchester: Manchester University Press.
Green-Cowles, M. (2000b), 'The Transatlantic Business-Dialogue and Domestic Business
Government Relations', in: M. Green-Cowles, T. Risse and J.A. Caporaso (eds),
Transforming Europe: Europeanization and Domestic Change, London: Cornell
University Press.
Green-Cowles, M. (2001), 'The Transatlantic Business Dialogue: Transforming the New
Transatlantic Dialogue', in: M.A. Pollack and G.C. Shaffer (eds), Transatlantic
Governance in a Global Economy, Rowman and Littlefield.
Greenberg, M.R. (2003), 'Fixing the Legal System - CEO Agenda 2004 - Litigious Climate
Hurts Economy', The Chief Executive, (December), BNET Research Centre,
avaialable at
http://findarticles.com/p/articles/mi_m4070/is_194/ai_111737866, 02.01.2008.
Griffin, J.P. (2000), 'What Business People Want From A World Antitrust Code', New
England Law Review 34(1), pp. 39-45.
Grben, H. von der (1963), 'Wettbewerb und Programmierung als Instrument der
Wirtschaftspolitik im Gemeinsamen Markt', Vortrag vor der List-Gesellschaft in
Frankfurt am Main, 8 June, Brussels: Historical Archives of the European
Commission.
Grossekettler, H. (1996), 'Franz Bhm as a Pioneering Champion of an Economic Theory
of Legislative Science', European Journal of Law and Economics 3, pp. 309-329
Grossmann-Drth, H. (1933), Selbstgeschaffenes Recht der Wirtschaft und staatliches
Recht, Tbingen: Walter Eucken Institut/Mohr Siebeck.
358
359
360
http://www.iccwbo.org/home/statements_rules/statements/1999/icpac_confidential
_info.asp, 02.01.2008.
ICN (2006), 'Business Outreach by ICN members: Challenges and Case Studies ', available
at
http://www.internationalcompetitionnetwork.org/media/library/conference_5th_cap
etown_2006/business_report.pdf, 02.01.2008.
Ietto-Gillies, G., M. Meschi and R. Simonetti (2000), 'Cross-Border Mergers and
Acquisitions: Patterns in the EU and Effects', paper for the Technology, Economic
Integration and Social Cohesion -Programm, sponsored by the European
Commission,
available
at
http://www.merit.unimaas.nl/tser/teis021.pdf,
19.18.2006.
James, C.A. (2001a), 'Reconciling Divergent Enforcement Policies: Where Do We Go
from Here?', address by the Assistant Attorney General - Antitrust Division US
Department of Justice, at the 28th Annual Conference on International Law and
Policy, Fordham Corporate Law Institute, New York, October 25, available at
http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/speeches/9395.pdf, 14.09.2006.
James, C.A. (2001b), 'International Antitrust in the 21st Century: Cooperation and
Convergence', paper for the OECD Global Forum on Competition, October 17,
available at www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/seeches/9330, 14.09.2006.
Janow, M.E. (2000), 'Transatlantic Cooperation on Competition Policy', in: Simon J.
Evenett, A. Lehmann and B. Steil (eds), Antitrust Goes Global. What Future for
Transatlantic Cooperation?, Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press.
Janow, M.E. (2003), 'What Role for Competition Policy in the WTO', in: A. Appleton
(ed.), The Next Trade Round, Dordrecht, The Netherlands: Kluwer Publication.
Jebsen, P. and R. Stevens (1996), 'Assumptions, Goals, and Dominant Undertakings: The
Regulation of Competition Under Article 86 of the European Union', Antitrust Law
Journal 64, p. 443.
Jenny, F. (1998), 'Proposed Answers to Professor Jenny's Questions', paper for the
Antitrust And Trade Policy - Round Table, Fordham Corporate Law Institute, New
York, 22-23 October.
Jenny, F. (2000), 'Competition Law and Policy. Achievements and Failures From an
Economic Perspective', Chapter 2 in: E. Hope (ed.), Competition Policy Analysis,
UK: Routledge.
Jenny, F. (2003), 'Competition Law and Policy: Global Governance Issues', World
Competition 26(4), pp. 609-624.
Joerges, C. (2001), 'Symposium: Mountain or Molehill? A Critical Appraisal of the
Commission White Paper on Governance: Economic Order - Technical Realization
- The Hour of the Executive: Some Legal Historical Observations on the
Commission White Paper on European Governance', Jean Monnet Working Paper.
6.
Joerges, C. (2004), 'What is left of the European Economic Constitution? A Melancholic
Eulogy', paper for the International Workshop on the 'European Union as a Model
for the Development of Mercosur? Transnational Orders between Economical
Efficiency and Political Legitimacy', Fundao Getlio Vargas, So Paulo,
September 27-29, available at
http://www.edesp.edu.br/files/eventos/papers/Paper%20-%20Joerges.pdf,
11.09.2005.
Johnson, D. and C. Turner (2000), European Business: Policy Challenges for the New
Commercial Environment, USA and Canada: Routledge.
361
362
Klein, J. (2000), 'Time for a Global Competitive Initiative?' paper for the EC Merger
Control 10th Anniversary Conference, Assistant Attorney General Antitrust
Division US DoJ, Brussels, September 14, available at
http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/speeches/6486.htm, 02.01.2008.
Klein, J. (2002), 'Expanding Our Web of Bilateral Agreements', in: C.A. Jones and M.
Matsushita (eds), Competition in the Global Trading System, Dordrecht, The
Netherlands: Kluwer Law International, pp. 335-340.
Knudsen, D.C. (1996), The Transition to Flexibility: Dordrecht, The Netherlands: Kluwer
Academic Publishers.
Kolasky, W.J. (2002a), 'US and EU Competition Policy. Cartels, Mergers and Beyond',
New York: Antitrust Division U.S. Department of Justice, available at
www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/speeches/9848.pdf, 16.09.2002.
Kolasky, W.J. (2002b), 'Comparative Merger Control Analysis: Six Guiding Principles For
Antitrust Agencies - New And Old ', paper for the International Bar Association
Conference on Competition Law and Policy in a Global Context, 18 March, Cape
Town, South Africa, available at:
http://149.101.1.32/atr/public/speeches/10845.htm, 02.01.2008.
Kolasky, W.J. (2002c), 'Global Competition: Prospects for Convergence and Cooperation',
paper for the American Bar Association Fall Forum, 07 November, Washington,
D.C.,
available
at
http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/speeches/200446.htm,
02.01.2008.
Korah, V. (1994), An Introductory Guide to EC Competition Law and Practice, Oxford:
Hart Publishing.
Kovacic, W.E. (2000), 'The Microsoft Case: Its Implications for Network Industries', paper
for the Thirteenth Annual Advanced Workshop in Regulation and Competition, July
5-7, Monterey, Calif.
Kovacic, W.E. (2003), 'The Modern Evolution of US Competition Policy Enforcement
Norms', Antitrust Law Journal 71(2).
Kovacic, W.E. (1989), 'Failed Expectations: The Troubled Past and Uncertain Future of
the Sherman Act as a Tool for Deconcentration', Iowa Law Review (74), pp. 11051150.
Kovacic, W.E. and C. Shapiro (2000), 'Antitrust Policy: A Century of Economic and Legal
Thinking', Journal of Economic Perspectives 14(1), pp. 43-60.
Kroes, N. (2005a), 'Building a Competitive Europe Competition Policy and the Relaunch
of the Lisbon Strategy,' speech 5/78 at a Conference at the Bocconi University,
Milan, February 7, available at
http://europa.eu.int/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference=SPEECH/05/78&form
at=HTML&aged=0&language=EN&guiLanguage=en, 02.01.2008.
Kroes, N. (2005b), 'Effective Competition Policy - A key Tool for Delivering the Lisbon
Strategy', speech 05/73 at EMAC Open Meeting of Coordinators, Brussels,
February 2, available at
http://europa.eu/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference=SPEECH/05/73&format=
HTML&aged=0&language=EN&guiLanguage=en, 02.01.2008.
Kroes, N. (2005c), 'Speech at the European Consumer and Competition Day', 15
September, London.
Kroes, N. (2005d), 'Taking Competition Seriously Anti-Trust Reform in Europe', speech
05/157, available at
http://europa.eu.int/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference=SPEECH/05/157&for
mat=HTML&aged=0&language=EN&guiLanguage=en, 02.01.2008.
363
Kroes, N. (2006a), 'Competition Policy in a Lisbon Context - The State of Play', speech
06/439 before the German Bundestag - Europaausschuss, 6 July, Berlin, available
at
http://europa.eu/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference=SPEECH/06/439&format
=HTML&aged=0&language=EN&guiLanguage=en, 02.01.2008.
Kroes, N. (2006b), 'Actions for Damages', available at
http://ec.europa.eu/comm/competition/antitrust/others/actions_for_damages/index_
en.html, 14.09.2006.
Kroes, N. (2006c), 'Interview ', European Business Forum 25, available at
http://www.ebfonline.com, 02.01.2008.
Kroes, N. (2006d), 'Background on Topical Issues', paper the for Japan National Press
Club, 07 March, available at http://jpn.cec.eu.int/home/news_en_newsobj1605.php,
12.05.2007.
Kroes, N. (2006e), 'Industrial Policy and Competition Law & Policy', speech 06/499, at the
Fordham University School of Law, 14 September, New York City, available at
http://europa.eu/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference=SPEECH/06/499&format
=HTML&aged=0&language=EN&guiLanguage=en, 02.01.2008.
Kroes, N. (2007a), 'European Competition Policy Facing a Renaissance of Protectionism Which Strategy For The Future?', speech 07/301 at the St. Gallen International
Competition Law Forum, 11 May, St. Gallen, Switzerland, available at
http://europa.eu/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference=SPEECH/07/301&format
=HTML&aged=0&language=EN&guiLanguage=en, 02.01.2008.
Kroes, N. (2007b), 'Developments in Anti-Trust Policy in the EU and the US', speech
06/494 at The C. Peter McColough Series on International Economics, The Council
on Foreign Relations, 15 September New York, available at
http://europa.eu/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference=SPEECH/06/494&format
=HTML&aged=0&language=EN&guiLanguage=en, 02.01.2008.
Kroes, N. (2007c), 'European Competition Policy in a Changing World and Globalised
Economy: Fundamentals, New Objectives And Challenges Ahead', speech 07/364
at the GCLC College of Europe Conference '50 years of EC Competition Law', 5
June, Brussels, available at
http://europa.eu/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference=SPEECH/07/364&format
=HTML&aged=1&language=EN&guiLanguage=en, 02.01.2008.
Landes, D.S. (1969), The Unbound Prometheus: Technological Change and Industrial
Development in Western Europe from 1750 to the Present, Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Lane, R. (2000), EC Competition Law, Harlow, UK: Longman.
Lasswell, H. (1956), Politics: Who Gets What When and How, 1995, New York: Peter
Smith Co.
Lea, G. (1999), 'What the heck is the Chicago School?', The Register, 22nd November,
available at
http://www.theregister.co.uk/1999/11/22/what_the_heck/, 02.01.2008.
League of Nations (2006), 'Photo Archives', Geneva: Palais de Nations, available at
http://www.indiana.edu/~league/index.htm, 25.12.2007.
Lee, J.S. (2005), 'Towards a Development-Oriented Multilateral Framework on
Competition Policy', Bepress Legal Series (785).
Lee, M. and C. Morand (2003), 'Competition Policy in the WTO and FTAA: A Trojan
Horse for International Trade Negotiations?' Canadian Centre for Policy
Alternatives, available at
http://www.policyalternatives.ca/publications/competition-policy.pdf, 25.02.2004.
364
Letwin, W. (1981), Law and Economic Policy in America: The Evolution of the Sherman
Antitrust Act, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Lvque, F. and H. Shelanski (2003), Merger Remedies in American and European Union
Competition Law, United Kingdom: Edward Elgar Publishing Limited.
Link, W. (1978), Deutsche und amerikanische Gewerkschaften und Geschftsleute, 19451975. Eine Studie ber transnationale Beziehungen, Dsseldorf: Droste.
Litan, R.E. and C. Shapiro (2001), 'Antitrust Policy and the Clinton Administration',
Massachusetts: Harvard University, Center for Business and Government, John F.
Kennedy School of Government.
Lowe, P. (2003), 'Interview', 25 September, Web Newscaster Europolitix, available at
http://ec.europa.eu/comm/competition/speeches/index_2003.html, 02.01.2008.
Ltz, S. (2000), 'From Managed to Market Capitalism? German Finance in Transition',
MPIfG Discussion Papers (2).
MacFarquhar, L. (2001), 'The Bench Burner. An Interview with Richard Posner', The New
Yorker,
10
December,
New
York,
available
at
http://www.igreens.org.uk/richard_posner.htm, 02.01.2008.
Manow, P. (2001), 'Ordoliberalismus als komenische Ordnungstheologie', Leviathan 29,
pp. 179-198.
Marceau, G.Z. (1995), Anti-Dumping and Anti-Trust Issues in Free-Trade Areas: Issues in
Free Trade Areas, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Martinez Torre-Enciso, I. and J. Bilbao Garcia (1996), 'Mergers and Acquisition Trends in
Europe', International Advances in Economic Research 2(3).
Marx, K. (1847), Wage Labour and Capital. Chapter 9: 'Effect of Capitalist Competition
on the Capitalist Class the Middle Class and the Working Class', online version of
the Marx/Engels Internet Archive, available at
http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1847/wage-labour/ch09.htm,
02.01.2008.
Marx, K. (1906), Capital: A Critique of Political Economy, Vol. I. Chicago: Charles H.
Kerr and Co.
McCarthy, E., A. Maltas, M. Bay and J. Ruiz-Calzado (2005), 'Litigation Culture versus
Enforcement Culture a Comparison of US and EU Plaintiff Recovery Actions in
Antitrust Cases', The Antitrust Review of the Americas 2007, A Global Competition
Review, special report, available at
http://www.lw.com/upload/pubContent/_pdf/pub1675_1.pdf, 02.01.2008.
McDavid, J.L. (2005), 'Enhancing Private Enforcement of EC Competition Rules', paper
for the Joint EU Commission/IBA Conference 'On Antitrust Reform in Europe: A
Year in Practice', Brussels, 10-11 March.
McDonald, K. M. (1995), The Sociology of the Professions, London: Sage.
McFadzean, A. (2003), 'The Bigger Picture: Biography and/or History? Robert Bowie',
Australasian Journal of American Studies, pp. 41-63.
McGowan, L. (1996), 'Unmasking a Federal Agency: The European Commissions Control
of Competition Policy', European Business Review 96(5), pp. 13-26.
McGowan, L. and M. Cini (1999), 'Discretion and Politicization in EU Competition
Policy: The Case of Merger Control', Governance 12(2), pp. 175-200.
McGowan, L. (2007a), Theorising European Integration: Revisiting Neo-Functionalism
and Testing its Suitability for Explaining the Development of EC Competition
Policy?, European Integration Online Papers 11(3).
McGowan, L. (2007b), In Search of Theoretical Explanations: Reflections on the
European Commissions Fifty Year War Against Cartels, paper presented at the
International Conference on European Competition Policy 1930-2005, Paris, 14-15
September 2007.
365
366
http://europa.eu/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference=SPEECH/01/328&format
=HTML&aged=0&language=EN&guiLanguage=en, 02.01.2008.
Monti, M. (2002a), 'Cooperation Between Competition Authorities. A Vision for the
Future', in: C. Jones and M. Matsushita (eds), Competition Policy in the Global
Trading System, The Hague: Kluwer Law International.
Monti, M. (2002b), 'Merger Control in the European Union. A Radical Reform', speech
02/545 at the European Commission/IBA Conference on EU Merger Control,
Brussels,
7
November
2002,
available
at
http://europa.eu.int/comm/competition/speeches, 02.01.2008.
Monti, M. (2003a), 'EU Competition Policy After May 2004', speech at the Fordham
Annual Conference on International Antitrust Law and Policy, October 24, New
York, available at http://www.eurunion.org/news/speeches/2003/031024mm.htm,
02.01.2008.
Monti, M. (2003b), 'Introductory Remarks for the ICN Capacity Building and Competition
Policy Implementation Working Group', speech 03/323 at the Second ICN Annual
Conference, Medrida, Mexico,23-25 June, available at
http://europa.eu/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference=SPEECH/03/323&format
=HTML&aged=0&language=EN&guiLanguage=en, 02.01.2008.
Monti, M. (2004a), 'Convergence in EU-US Antitrust Policy Regarding Mergers and
Acquisitions: An EU Perspective', speech 04/107 at the UCLA Law First Annual
Institute on US an EU Antitrust Aspects of Mergers and Acquisitions, Los Angeles,
28 February, available at
http://europa.eu/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference=SPEECH/04/107&format
=HTML&aged=1&language=EN&guiLanguage=en, 02.01.2008.
Monti, M. (2004b), 'The EU Gets New Competition Powers for the 21st Century',
Competition Policy Newsletter Special Edition.
Monti, M. (2004c), 'International Antitrust A Personal Perspective', speech 04/449 at the
Fordham Corporate Law Institute, New York, 7 October 2004, available at
http://europa.eu.int/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference=SPEECH/04/449&for
mat=HTML&aged=0&language=EN&guiLanguage=en, 02.01.2008.
Monti, M. (2004d), 'Private Litigation as a Key Complement to Public Enforcement of
Competition Rules and the First Conclusions on the Implementation of the New
Merger Regulation', speech 04/403 at the 8th IBA Annual Competition Conference,
Fiesole, 14 September, available at
http://europa.eu.int/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference=SPEECH/04/403&for
mat=HTML&aged=0&language=EN&guiLanguage=en, 01.02.2008.
Monti, M. (2001d), 'Merger Control: Issues Highlighted in the Context of the
GE/Honeywell Merger', speech 01/340 at the Taylor's Hall London on 'The Future
for Competition Policy in the European Union Merchant' available at
http://europa.eu/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference=SPEECH/01/340&format
=HTML&aged=0&language=EN&guiLanguage=en, 02.01.2008.
Monti, M. (2003c), 'The New Shape of European Competition Policy', speech at the
Inaugural Symposium of the Competition Policy Research Center 'How Should
Competition Policy Transform Itself ?', 20 November, Tokyo available at
http://www.jftc.go.jp/cprc/sympo/2003sympo/agenda25.pdf, 02.01.2008.
Monti, M. (2004e), 'Comments by Mario Monti to Hew Pate, Assistant Attorney General,
US Department of Justice', at the Antitrust in a Transatlantic Context, 7 June,
Brussels, available at
http://ec.europa.eu/comm/competition/speeches/text/sp2004_005_en.pdf,
02.01.2008.
Monti, G. (2007): EC Competition Law. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
367
368
369
Peterson, J., M. Green-Cowles and Y. Devuyst (1995), 'US Lobbying and Influence on the
Internal Market ', paper for the Biannual Conference of the European Community
Studies Association, 11-14 May Charleston, South Carolina, available at
http://aei.pitt.edu/7003/01/peterson_john.pdf, 02.01.2008.
Piening, C. (1997), Global Europe: The European Union in World Affairs, London: Lynne
Rienner.
Pirrung, M. (2004), 'EU Enlargement Towards Cartel Paradise? An Economic Analysis of
the Reform of European Competition Law', Erasmus Law and Economics Review,
February 2004 (1), pp. 77-109.
Pitofsky, R. (1995), 'International Antitrust: An FTC Perspective', speech at the Fordham
Corporate Law Institute 22nd Annual Conference on International Antitrust Law &
Policy at the Fordham University Law School, New York City, 26 October.
Pitofsky, R. (1996a), 'An Antitrust Progress Report for the FTC: Past, Present and Future',
speech at the 1996 Antitrust Conference, Business Development Associates Inc.,
Washington, D.C., 4 March.
Pitofsky, R. (1996b), 'FTC Staff Report on Competition Policy: Six Months After', speech
at the American Bar Association Section of Antitrust Law' Conference on The
Changing Nature of Competition - Legal and Policy Implications, Washington,
D.C., 7 November.
Pitofsky, R. (1998), 'Competition Policy in a Global Economy - Today And Tomorrow',
speech at the European Institute's 8th Annual Transatlantic Seminar on Trade and
Investment, Washington, D.C., 4 November.
Pitofsky, R. (2000), 'EU and U.S. Approaches to International Mergers-Views from the
U.S. Federal Trade Commission', speech at the EC Merger Control 10th
Anniversary Conference of the International Bar Association, 14-15 September
2000, Metropole Hotel, Brussels.
Pitofsky, R. (2002), 'Antitrust Cooperation, Global Trade, and US Competition Policy', in:
C.A. Jones and M. Matsushita (eds), Competition Policy in the Global Trading
System, The Netherlands: Kluwer Law International, pp. 53-60.
Pitschner, S. (2004), 'The Role of Interest Groups in the Arena of Global Antitrust and
their Relevance for the Occurrence of Conflicts', ECON Paper, Institute for
International Economic Studies: University of Stockholm.
Plehwe, D. and B. Walpen (1999), 'Wissenschaftliche und wissenschaftspolitische
Produktionsweisen im Neoliberalismus. Beitrge der Mont Plerin Society und
marktradikaler Think Tanks zur Hegemoniegewinnung und -erhaltung', Zeitschrift
fr kritische Sozialwissenschaft 29(115).
Plehwe, D. and B. Walpen (2006), 'Between Network and Complex Organisation. The
Making of Neoliberal Knowledge and Hegemony', in: D.Plehwe, B.Walpen and G.
Neunhffer (eds), Neoliberal Hegemony. A Global Critique, Routledge/Ripe
Studies in Global Political Economy, New York: Routledge.
Polanyi, K. (1944), The Great Transformation, 2nd edition, Boston: Beacon Press.
Pollack, M. A. (1998), 'The Engines of Integration? Supranational Autonomy and
Influence in the European Union', in: Wayne Sandholtz and Alec Stone Sweet
(eds), European Integration and Supranational Governance, Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
Pond, E. (2002), The Rebirth of Europe, Washington: Brookings Institution Press.
Posner, R. (1978), Antitrust law: An Economic Perspective, 1997, Chicago: University of
Chicago Press.
Pryor, F.L. (2001), 'New Trends in US Industrial Concentration', Review of Industrial
Organization 18, pp. 301-326.
370
Reagan, R. (1987), 'Remarks at a White House Briefing for Members of the Deficit
Reduction
Coalition',
10
July,
available
at
http://www.reagan.utexas.edu/archives/speeches/1987/071087a.htm,02.01.2008.
Reich, N. (2005), 'The 'Courage' Doctrine: Encourage or Discouraging Compensation for
Antitrust Injuries?' Common Market Law Review 42, pp. 35-66.
Renfurm, J. (2005), 'Nederland, de EU en de Helms-Burtonact. Een Nederlandse en
Europese visie op de Amerikaanse sanctiewetgeving tegen Cuba', available at
http://www.geschiedenis.nl/index.php?option=com_content&task=view&id=219&I
temid=16&limit=1&limitstart=8, 02.01.2008.
Resch, A. (2005), 'Phases of Competition Policy in Europe', Paper of the Institute of
European Studies (050401).
Rhodes, M. and van B. Apeldoorn (1998), 'Capital Unbound? The Transformation of
European Corporate Governance', Journal of European Public Policy 5(3), pp. 406427.
Rill, J. (2003), 'Overhaul Merger Regime May Not Come Up Smelling Roses', European
Voice 9(39), Brussels.
Rller, L.H. (2005), 'Using Economic Analysis to Strengthen Competition Policy
Enforcement in Europe', Chief Competition Economists at the European
Commission, 21 March, Brussels.
Rller, L.H. and H.W. Friederiszick (2005), 'konomische Analyse in der EU
Wettbewerbspolitik', Brussels: European Commission.
Rpke, W. (1992), The Social Crisis of Our Time, New Brunswick, N.J.: Transaction.
Rpke, W. (1994), Economics of a Free Society, Grove City, PA: Libertarian Press.
Ross, G. (1995), Jacques Delors and European Integration, New York: Oxford University
Press.
Rothbard, M.N. (1995), Economic Thought Before Adam Smith: An Austrian Perspective
on the History of Economic Thought, Brookfield: Edward Elgar.
Roy, J. (1997), 'The Helms-Burton Law: Development, Consequences, and Legacy for
Inter-American and European-US Relations', Journal of Interamerican Studies and
World Affairs 39(3), pp. 77-108.
Roy, J. (2000), Cuba, the United States, and the Helms-Burton Doctrine: International
Relations, Florida: University Press of Florida.
Ruggie, J. (1982), 'International Regimes, Transactions, and Change: Embedded
Liberalism in the Postwar Economic Order', International Organization 36(2), pp.
379-415.
Ruigrok, W. and R. Van Tulder (1995), The Logic of International Restructuring, London:
Routledge.
Rutherford, M. (2003), 'Chicago Economics and Institutionalism', Draft, May, University
of Victoria.
Sachse, T. (2006), 'Extraterritorial Application of Competition Laws in the US and the
European Union', Briefing Paper, CUTS Centre for Competition, Investment &
Economic
Regulation,
available
at
http://www.cutsinternational.org/pdf/Extraterritorial_4-2006.pdf, 02.01.2008.
Sauter, W. (1997), Competition Law and Industrial Policy in the EU, Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
Scharpf, F. W. (2002), 'The European Social Model: Coping with the Challenges of
Diversity', Journal of Common Market Studies 40(4), pp. 645-670.
Schaub, A. (1998), 'International Cooperation in Antitrust Matters: Making the Point in the
Wake of the Boeing/MDD Proceedings', EC Competition Policy Newsletter
1998(1).
371
372
Between the Japanese Car Manufacturers and the European Union', European
Business Review 17(3), pp. 217-223.
Servan-Schreiber, J.J. (1967), Le dfi amricain, Paris: Livre de Poche.
Shapiro, M. and A. Stone (1994), 'The New Constitutional Politics of Europe',
Comparative Political Studies 26(4), pp. 397-420.
Shaw, M.N. (2003), International Law, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Shepherd, W.G. (1991), Public Policies Toward Business, Homewood: Irwin.
Sherwood, B. and N. Tait (2005), 'Class Actions Across the Atlantic Group Litigation',
Financial Times, London, June 16, p. 14.
Siekman, P. (1970), 'Europe's Love Affair With Bigness', Fortune, pp. 94-95.
Sjostrom, W. (1998), 'Competition Law in the European Union and the United States', in
New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and the Law, Macmillan.
Skitol, R.A. (2007), 'What Should We Call the 'New Antitrust'? The New School Of
Antitrust Law', San Francisco Economic Roundtable, 29 May, San Francisco,
available at
http://www.antitrustinstitute.org/Archives/188.ashx, 02.01.2008.
Sklair, L. (2001), The Transnational Capitalist Class, Malden, Massachusetts: Blackwell
Publishing.
Sklar, M.J. (1988), The Corporate Reconstruction of American Capitalism, 1890-1916.
The Market, the Law, and Politics, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Slaughter, A.M. (2004), New World Order, Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Slot, P.J. (2004), 'A View From the Mountain: 40 Years of Developments in EC
Competition Law', Common Market Law Review 41, pp. 443-473.
Smith, A. (1776), The Wealth of Nations, 2003, New York: Bantam Classics.
Smith, M. P. A. (1998), 'Autonomy by the Rules: The European Commission and the
Development of State Aid Policy', Journal of Common Market Studies 36(1).
Stigler, G. J. (1957), 'Perfect Competition, Historically Contemplated', Journal of Political
Economy 65 (February).
Streeck, W. and P.C. Schmitter (1985), 'Community, Market, State-and Associations? The
Prospective Contribution of Interest Governance to Social Order', European
Sociological Review 1(2).
SZ (1994), 'Das umstrittene Erbe Walter Euckens', Sddeutsche Zeitung, p. 34.
Tabaksblat, M. (2000), 'How to Achieve What Was Set Out in Lisbon', speech of the
Chairman of the European Round Table of Industrialists (ERT), at the European
Business Summit, June 10, available at http://www.ert.be/doc/0096.pdf,
02.01.2008.
TABD (1995), 'Transatlantic Business Dialogue: Overall Conclusions', available at
http://static.tabd.com/manilaGems/1995SevilleCEOReport.pdf, 02.01.2008.
TABD (1996), 'The Chicago Declaration', 9 November, available at
http://static.tabd.com/manilaGems/1996ChicagoCEOReport.pdf, 02.01.2008.
TABD (1997), 'TABD Priorities for the Mid-Year Summit', Brussels: Transatlantic
Business Dialogue, available at
http://www.tabd.com/ceo_reports, 02.01.2008.
TABD (2005), 'TABD Davos Declaration of 2005', available at
http://static.tabd.com/manilaGems/TABDDavosDeclarationFINAL.pdf,
02.01.2008.
TABD (2006), 'Towards a Barrier-Free Transatlantic Market. Report and
Recommendations to the 2006 EU-US Summit Leaders', available at
http://static.tabd.com/manilaGems/TABDreport14March07FINAL.pdf, 02.01.2008.
373
374
Underhill, G.R.D. (2003), 'States, Markets, and Governance for Emerging Market
Economies: Private Interests, the Public Good and the Legitimacy of the
Development Process', International Affairs 79(4), pp. 755-781.
UNICE (1995), 'Modernizing EU Competition Policy: Refocusing the Scope and
Administration of Article 85', UNICE Discussion Paper, Brussels.
UNICE (1999), 'UNICE Comments, Executive Summary on the Modernization of EC
Competition Law', Position Paper, Brussels.
UNICE (2001), 'UNICE Comments on the Modernization of EC Competition Law.
Proposal for a Council Regulation Implementing Articles 81 and 82 of the Treaty.
Com (2000) 582 Final', Position Paper, Brussels.
UNICE (2002), 'UNICE Supplementary Comments on the Modernization of EC
Competition Law. Proposal for a Council Regulation Implementing Articles 81 and
82 of the Treaty. Status: 26 July 2002', Position Paper, Brussels.
UNICE (2006), 'Comments on Green Paper 'Damages Actions for Breach of the EC
Antitrust',
Executive
Summary,
Brussels,
available
at
http://ec.europa.eu/comm/competition/antitrust/others/actions_for_damages/045.pd
f, 03.08.2007.
UNO (1948), 'Havana Charter: Final Act and Related Documents of the United Nations
Conference On Trade And Employment', Lake Success, New York.
US Mission (1999), 'Transatlantic Economic Partnership Report of the Top Steering
Group', paper for Meeting of the Trade And Economic Ministers at the US-EU
Summit,
December
17,
available
at
http://www.useu.be/Categories/Antitrust/May1702USEUAntitrustCooperationKola
sky.html, 25.06.2005.
US Government (2002), 'Competition Policy and Deregulation Group Merida', Submission
of the United States United States' Perspectives on the International Competition
Network, available at
http://www.apeccp.org.tw/doc/Workshop/w2002/008.htm, 02.01.2008.
Van der Pijl, K. (1984), The Making of an Atlantic Ruling Class, London: Verso.
Van Miert, K. (1997), 'International Cooperation in the Field of Competition; A View from
the EC', paper for the 24th Annual Conference, Fordham Corporate Law Institute,
New York, October 16, available at
http://ec.europa.eu/comm/competition/speeches/text/sp1997_073_en.html,
02.01.2008.
Van Miert, K. (1998a), 'What Does a Level Playing Field Mean in the Global Economy?',
speech at the World Economic Forum (WEF), Davos, Switzerland, 30 January,
available at
http://ec.europa.eu/comm/competition/speeches/text/sp1998_031_en.html,
02.01.2008.
Van Miert, K. (1998b), 'Globalization of Competition. The Need for Global Governance',
speech at the Vrije Universiteit Brussel, 25 March, available at
http://ec.europa.eu/comm/competition/speeches/text/sp1998_052_en.html,
02.01.2008.
Van Miert, K. (1998c), 'European Competition Policy', paper for Management Policy
Council,
Brussels
De
Warande,
May
6,
available
at
http://ec.europa.eu/comm/competition/speeches/text/sp1998_053_en.html,
02.01.2008.
Van Miert, K. (1998d), 'The Future of European Competition Policy', paper for Ludwig
Erhard Prize Award, Bonn, Germany, 17 September, available at
http://europa.eu.int/comm/competition/speeches/text/sp1998_042_en.html,
02.01.2008.
375
376
377
378
http://www.commerce.nic.in/trade/international_trade_papers_nextDetail.asp?id=3
2, 02.01.2008.
WTO WGTCP (2003), 'Communication from Thailand to the Working Group on the
Interaction of Trade and Competition Policy', WT/WGTCP/W/213, 26 September,
available at:
http://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/comp_e/wgtcp_docs_e.htm, 02.01.2008.
Yergin, D. and J. Stanislaw (1998), Commanding Heights: The Battle for the World
Economy, New York: Simon and Schuster.
Zweynert, J. (2004), 'Shared Mental Models, Catch-up Development and Economic
Policy-Making: The Case of Germany after World War II and Its Significance for
Contemporary Russia', Hamburgisches Welt-Wirtschafts-Archiv (HWWA)
Discussion Papers 288.
379
Samenvatting
Het beleid over de mededinging behoort tot de centrale beleidsterreinen van de Europese
Unie (EU). Het wordt in essentie door politieke belangen bepaald. Bovendien heeft de
inrichting van het mededingingsbeleid cruciale gevolgen voor de mate van economische
concentratie, de werkgelegenheid, en de verdeling van de welvaart. Deze gevolgen
beperken zich niet tot Europa, maar zijn ook voelbaar op mondiaal niveau, hetgeen het
intrinsiek politieke karakter verder versterkt. Toch zijn er maar weinig politicologen, die
zich met dit beleidsgebied bezig houden. Het mededingingsbeleid wordt voornamelijk
bestudeerd door juristen en economen, die meestal een zeer technocratische en zeer
specifieke invalshoek hanteren, zonder expliciet aandacht te besteden aan politieke
factoren.
381
Het mededingingsbeleid bleef lange tijd voorbehouden aan het Amerikaanse kapitalisme.
De invloed van Amerikaanse belangen in het naoorlogse Europa was dan ook beslissend
voor het opnemen van mededingingswetgeving in het verdrag van de Europese
Gemeenschap voor Kolen en Staal (EGKS) in 1951. Met de plaatsing van het
mededingingsbeleid op supranationaal niveau werd beoogd de staatsgesteunde nationale
marktordes van kartels en monopolies in strategische industrien, zoals de kolen- en
staalindustrie, te ontmantelen, en de markttoegang voor nieuwkomers (in eerste instantie
vooral Amerikaanse bedrijven) te waarborgen. Toen in 1957 de Europese Economische
Gemeenschap (EEG) werd opgericht, hadden de opstellers van het verdrag zich de taal van
marktconcurrentie inmiddels zo eigen gemaakt dat de concurrentiegedachte n van de
kernprincipes van de economische integratie werd. De EG mededingingswetgeving diende
een stapsgewijze opening van nationale markten voor de concurrentie vanuit andere
lidstaten mogelijk te maken om zo de vorming van de gemeenschappelijke binnenmarkt te
bevorderen.
Kenmerkend voor het beleid in de periode vanaf de jaren zestig tot het begin van de jaren
tachtig
was
dat
het
mededingingsbeleid
onderdeel
vormde
van
een
actieve
In de tijd van het embedded liberalism werd het EG mededingingsbeleid regelmatig als
een compenserende strategie ingezet om Europese bedrijven klaar te stomen voor de
concurrentie met de technologisch vaak geavanceerdere Amerikaanse bedrijven. Met de
toenemende handelsliberalisering binnen het GATT werd het voor nationale lidstaten
steeds moeilijker om conventionele protectionistische marktbarrires op te richten. Dit
werd verholpen door andere, niet op tarieven gebaseerde, beschermende maatregelen toe te
passen. Nationale overheden gaven bijvoorbeeld steun aan nationale ondernemingen in de
382
vorm van subsidie, een voorkeursbehandeling bij openbare aanbestedingen, het geven van
fiscale voordelen, en het plegen van publieke investeringen in het technische onderwijs,
waar nationale bedrijven direct van profiteerden. De Europese Commissie was in haar
beleid ontvankelijk voor de belangen van de Europese industrien uit de verschillende
lidstaten en liet de steun door nationale regeringen aan nationale bedrijven toe. Met name
het koesteren van nationale kampioenen werd door de Commissie als toezichthoudend
orgaan getolereerd en niet direct als concurrentievervalsend gezien. Desalniettemin
probeerde de Commissie, met het oog op de vorming van de gemeenschappelijke
binnenmarkt in haar eigen de bevordering van de vorming van Europese kampioenen
boven de vorming van nationale kampioenen te stellen. De Commissie stimuleerde
grensoverschrijdende fusies en samenwerkingsverbanden tussen nationale ondernemingen,
met name samenwerking op het gebied van onderzoek en ontwikkeling. Fusies werden
indirect bevorderd door de afwezigheid van controlerende regelgeving met betrekking tot
fusies in het Verdrag van Rome: het Verdrag stelde geen grenzen aan de mate van
economische concentratie. Bovendien was de werking van de bestaande regelgeving van
Artikel 82 van het EG-Verdrag, beperkt tot een verbod op het misbruiken van een
economische machtspositie door ondernemingen voorzover dat een ongunstige invloed had
op de handel tussen de EG-lidstaten. Het hebben van een economische machtspositie an
sich werd niet gezien als een bedreiging voor concurrentie. De geleidelijke integratie van
nationale markten in n gemeenschappelijke markt door het verwijderen van steeds meer
van de bestaande handelsbelemmeringen had bovendien tot doel de benodigde
schaalvergroting te creren teneinde de vorming van Europese kampioenen te bevorderen.
De handhaving van de EG concurrentiewetgeving vormde daardoor een politieke reactie
op de uitdagingen die kwam van de veel grotere en meer homogene markt van de VS.
in
het
licht
van
Europees
crisisbeheer:
noodlijdende
383
Toen in de late jaren zeventig en de vroege jaren tachtig steeds duidelijker werd dat de
pogingen om de economische crisis op te lossen niet succesvol waren, maakten neoliberale
ideen hun intrede onder de politieke en economische elites als een reactie op het
compromis van embedded liberalism. De Commissie omarmde neoliberale ideen, en
nam een voortrekkersrol in door de versnelde marktintegratie op de Europese agenda te
zetten. Aanvankelijk manifesteerde zich de neoliberale koers als een deconstructief project.
De macro-economische visie gericht op het steunen van bepaalde industrile
bedrijfstakken, alsmede het in acht nemen van sociale overwegingen over werkgelegenheid
werden meer en meer als niet legitiem beschouwd. Door de aanwezigheid van politieke
krachten
tegen
deze
neoliberale
koers
werden
de
neonmercantilistische
en
neoliberale
orintatie,
waarin
harde
concurrentie
en
vrije
marktwerking centraal kwamen te staan. Het verbod op het geven van overheidssteun, op
de vorming van kartels en ander restrictief gedrag van ondernemingen, werd in
toenemende mate stringenter nageleefd. Stringente toepassing resulteerde ook in de
privatisering van overheidsmonopolies en -bedrijven, die nu ook aan concurrentie
384
onderhevig werden. In deze constructieve fase werd harde concurrentie gezien als het
centrale mechanisme achter de organisatie van de gemeenschappelijke markt.
meer
dan
95%
van
alle
aangemelde
fusies
goedgekeurd.
Deze
Mede door de druk van grote, op wereldschaal concurrerende bedrijven werd in 2004 voor
een meer marktgeorinteerd regime gekozen met als gevolg dat priv-actoren meer ruimte
kregen om de rol van markt sturende autoriteit voor zich op te eisen en dat economische
385
concentratie als een noodzaak voor concurrentie op de wereldmarkt wordt gezien. Het
mededingingsbeleid heeft niet alleen een verschuiving van nationale markten, naar een
gemeenschappelijke interne markt teweeggebracht maar wordt daarnaast sinds een paar
jaar steeds meer ingezet als een instrument voor het openen van nationale markten op
wereldschaal. De redenen voor deze transformatie liggen deels in de transnationalisatie van
productie- en eigendomstructuren van grote bedrijven. Door de (re-) lokalisatie van
productie is de aard van de belangen van grote transnationale ondernemingen
fundamenteel veranderd. Ondernemersorganisaties, zoals de ERT, UNICE en de
vertegenwoordiging van Amerikaanse transnationale ondernemingen in Europa (AmCham),
maar ook de Trans Atlantic Business Dialogue (TABD) waren bijzonder invloedrijk in de
besluitvormingsprocessen rondom een herziening van het bestaande mededingingsregime.
386
387