Agricultural Credit Management
Agricultural Credit Management
Agricultural Credit Management
When the country faced the problem of food shortages in the early sixties, agricultural
public policy aimed at increasing productivity and production of food grains to meet
this challenge. The cultivation of dwarf wheat and rice varieties which were highly
responsive to purchased inputs like fertilizers, agro-chemicals and irrigation required
capital at the farm level. Agricultural credit scenario was largely dominated by private
informal sources of credit i.e. professional money lenders and traders. The
participation of commercial banks was negligible in agricultural loans. Farmers level
of income was low and they were hesitant to use modern technology. Therefore,
agricultural credit policy aimed at increasing the flow of institutional credit at
reasonable rates of interest to agriculture sector. The cooperative credit structure was
strengthened by reorganizing and merging weak societies with strong societies. The
number of village level co-operative societies also increased. Presently, more than
The sources of agricultural finance are broadly classified into two categories:
(A) Non institutional Credit Agencies or informal sources, and
i) Traders and Commission Agents: Traders and commission agents advance loans to
agriculturists for productive purposes against their crop without completing legal
formalities. It often becomes obligatory for farmers to buy inputs and sell output
through them. They charge a very heavy rate of interest on the loan and a commission
on all the sales and purchases, making it exploitative in nature. It an important source
of finance in case of cash crops like cotton, tobacco and groundnut.
ii)Landlords: Mostly small farmers and tenants depend on landlords for meeting their
financial requirements.
iii)
institutional credit agencies, village money lenders still dominate the scene. Money
lenders are of two types- agriculturist money lenders who combine their money
lending job with farming and professional money lenders whose sole job is money
lending. A number of reasons have been attributed for the popularity of moneylenders
such as: (a) they meet demand for productive as well as unproductive requirement; (b)
they are easily approachable at odd hours; and (c) they require very low paper work
and advances are given against promissory notes or land. Money lenders charge a
very high rate of interest as they take advantage of the urgency of the situation. Over
the years a need for regulation of money lending has been felt. But lack of
institutional credit access to certain sections and areas had facilitated unhindered
operation of money lending. Cooperative credit and self-help groups can play a major
role in control of money lending.
calamities. The rate of interest is low. But it is not a major source of agricultural
finance.
ii)
back to 1904 when first Cooperative Credit Societies Act was passed by the
Government. The scope of the Act was restricted to establishment of primary credit
societies and non-credit societies were left out of its purview. The shortcomings of the
Act were rectified through passing another Act called Cooperative Societies Act 1912.
The Act gave provision for registration of all types of Cooperative Societies. This
made the emergence of rural cooperatives both in the credit and noncredit areas,
though with uneven spatial growth. In subsequent years a number of Committees
were appointed and recommendations implemented to improve the functioning of the
cooperatives.
Soon
after
the
independence,
the
Government
of
India
following
the
recommendations of All India Rural Credit Survey Committee (1951) felt that
cooperatives were the only alternative to promote agricultural credit and development
of rural areas. Accordingly, cooperatives received substantial help in the provision of
credit from Reserve Bank of India as a part of loan policy and large scale assistance
from Central and State Governments for their development and strengthening. Many
schemes involving subsidies and concessions for the weaker sections were routed
through cooperatives. As a result cooperative institutions registered a remarkable
growth in the post-independence India.
iii)
Commercial Banks:
Previously commercial banks (CBs) were confined only to urban areas serving mainly
to trade, commerce and industry. Their role in rural credit was meager i.e., 0.9 per
cent in 1951- 52 and 0.7 per cent in 1961-61. The insignificant participation of CBs in
rural lending was explained by the risky nature of agriculture due to its heavy
dependence on monsoon, unorganized nature and subsistence approach. A major
change took place in the form of nationalization of CBs in 1969 and CBs
were made
to play an active role in agricultural credit. At present, they are the largest source of
institutional credit to agriculture.
Box 5.1: Lead Bank Scheme
The National Credit Council (NCC) had appointed a Study Group in 1969 under the
Chairmanship of Prof. D. R. Gadgil to suggest an appropriate organizational
framework for effective implementation of social objectives. The Study Group
recommended an Area Approach for the development of financial structure through
intensive efforts. The same year, RBI appointed Nariman Committee to study this
recommendation. The Committee endorsed the views of the Study Group on Area
Approach and recommended the formulation of Lead Bank Scheme. The RBI
accepted the recommendation and Lead Bank Scheme came into force from 1969.
As per this scheme a particular district is allotted to a specific bank which takes a lead
role in identifying the potential areas for banking and banking development and in
expanding credit facilities in the district. Functions of Lead Banks are:
(i)
(ii)
(iii)
(iv)
(v)
(vi)
Preparing district credit plans much ahead of the season with the help of
technical committee.
The lead bank is not a monopolist in banking business in the district but acts as a
consortium leader for coordinating the efforts of all financial institutions operating in
the district. By June 1992, all the districts of the country were covered under this
scheme.
iv)
Regional Rural Banks (RRBs): RRBs were set up in those regions where
Institution
1999-00
2000-01
2001-02
2002-03
2003-04
2004-05*
Cooperative Banks
18,363
20,801
23,604
24,296
26,959
24,471
Share (%)
40
39
38
34
31
28
3,172
4,219
4,854
5,467
7,581
9,176
Share (%)
11
Commercial Banks
24,733
27,807
33,587
41,047
52,441
52,038
Share (%)
53
53
54
58
60
61
Total
46,268
52,827
62,045
70,810
86,981
85,686
v)Micro financing: Micro financing through Self Help Groups (SHG) has assumed
prominence in recent years. SHG is group of rural poor who volunteer to organize
themselves into a group for eradication of poverty of the members. They agree to save
regularly and convert their savings into a common fund known as the Group corpus.
The members of the group agree to use this common fund and such other funds that
they may receive as a group through a common management.
By initially managing their own common fund for some time, SHG members not only
take care of the financing needs of each other, but develop their skills of financial
management and intermediation as well. Lending to members also enhances the
knowledge of SHG members in setting the interest rate and periodic loan installments,
recovering the loan, etc.
The SHG- bank linkages programme has emerged as the major micro-finance
programme in the country. NABARD has played a major role in development of
SHG-Bank linkages with involvement of Non Governmental Organizations (NGOs)
in the process. There are three models of SHG-bank linkages that have evolved over
time:
Model I. SHGs formed and financed by banks: In this model, the bank itself takes up
the work of forming and nurturing the groups, opening their bank accounts and
providing them with bank loans after satisfying itself as to their maturity to absorb
credit. In case the bank is also the programme implementing agency.
Model II. SHGs formed by NGOs and formal organizations but directly financed by
the banks: In this model, groups are formed by NGOs (in most cases) or by
government agencies. The groups are nurtured and trained by the agencies. The bank
then provides credit directly to the SHGs after observing their operations and maturity
to absorb credit. While the bank provides loans to the groups directly, the facilitating
agencies continue their interactions with the SHGs. Most linkage experiences begin
with this model, where NGOs play a major role. The model has also been popular
with and more acceptable to banks, since some of the difficult functions of social
dynamics are externalized. Around 75 percent of the total number of SHGs is
financed under this model.
Model III. SHGs financed by banks using NGOs and other agencies as financial
intermediaries: For various reasons, banks in some areas are not in a position even to
finance SHGs promoted and nurtured by other agencies. In such cases, the NGOs act
as both facilitators and microfinance intermediaries. First, they promote the groups,
nurture and train them and then they approach banks for bulk loans for on lending to
SHGs.
While 563 districts in all the States/UTs have been covered under this programme,
560 banks including 48 commercial banks, 196 RRBs and 316 cooperative banks
along with 3024 NGOs are now associated with this initiative. The number of SHGs
linked to the banks aggregated 1,276,035 as on December 30, 2004. Cumulative
disbursement of bank loan to these SHGs stood at Rs. 5,038 crore as on the same date.
Following the Raiffeisen Model, PACS came to existence after the enactment of
Cooperative Credit Societies Act 1904. PACS functions on the basis of cooperative
principles of voluntary participation, democratic control, limited area of operation and
limited liability. These societies work at the village level and are meant for the
farmers regarding provision of requisite short term and medium term loans. Supply of
agricultural inputs and other essential commodities is also taken up by these societies.
In addition to these PACS also helps in formulation and implementation of
agricultural development plans for the welfare of its members. The PACS are
associated with following functions:
(i)
They borrow adequate and timely funds from DCCBs and help the
members in financial matters;
(ii)
they attract local savings in the form of share capital and deposits from the
villagers, thereby inculcating the habit of thrift;
(iii)
(iv)
they make available fertilizers and insecticides etc. to the needy farmers;
(v)
(vi)
they associate with the programmes and plans meant for the socioeconomic development of the village;
(vii)
they are also involved in the marketing of farm produce on behalf of the
farmer-borrowers;
(viii)
(ix)
they supply certain consumer goods like rice, wheat, sugar, kerosene,
cloth etc. at fair prices.
DCCBs function as a link between the PACS and State Cooperative Banks (SCBs).
They are basically meant for meeting the credit requirement of PACS. They also
undertake banking business such as accepting deposits from public, collecting bills,
cheques, drafts etc. and providing credit to the needy persons. The area of operation
varies from taluka to district but in most of the states their operations are confined to
the taluka level. Membership of the DCCBs is open to individuals and societies
working in its area of operation. Marketing societies, consumer societies, farming
societies, urban banks and PACS are usually enrolled as members of this bank. The
specific functions of the bank are:
(i)
to supervise and inspect the activities of PACS and help the credit societies
run smoothly;
(ii)
to maintain close and constant contact and guide the primary societies and
provide leadership to them;
(iii)
(iv)
(v)
SCBs are at the apex of the cooperative credit organization present at the state
capitals. They perform the same functions for the DCCBs as the latter does for the
PACS. The membership comprises of DCCBs and individuals. Being at the apex
level, this bank mobilizes and deploys financial resources among the various sectors.
It finances and controls the working of the DCCBs in the state. It also serves as a link
between the RBI and DCCBs. The Specific functions of SCBs:
(i)
(ii)
(iii)
(iv)
(v)
(vi)
(vii)
(viii)
these banks coordinate their own policies with those of the cooperative
movement of the government.
The establishment of the Land Mortgage Bank (LMBs) on cooperative lines dates
back to the year 1920 in Punjab. Later during the period 1920-29, a number of LMBs
were established in the states of Punjab, Madras, Mysore, Assam and Bengal. After
that not much growth was observed in the number of LMBs till 1945. However,
during 1945-53 a rapid growth was observed in the number of these banks. During
this period only rich and affluent farmers derived benefits of these banks and small
and marginal farmers remained untouched of the developments. LMBs got massive
support from the RBI, SBI, LIC and Agricultural Refinance Corporation. As a result
LMBs had to reorient its lending policies in favour of marginal and small farmers.
LMBs were renamed as Land Development Banks (LDBs) in 1974. Primary LDBs
are generally organized to serve the farmers at Taluka level. Its specific functions are:
(i)
to provide long term finance to the needy farmers for the development of
land, increasing production and productivity of land;
(ii)
to provide long term loan for minor irrigation and for redemption of old
debts and purchase of land;
(iii)
(iv)
In many states PLDBs are federated into CLDBs. Branches of CLDBs, PLDBs and
individual entrepreneurs are the members of the CLDB. NABARD and LIC subscribe
for its debentures in large amounts. In fact, NABARD is the refinance agency of
CLDBs. It acts as a link between NABARD and the Government in long-term
business transactions. It supervises and guides the PLDBs. It inculcates the practice of
thrift among member banks by mobilizing savings and stimulating capital formation.
The CLDBs provides loans to member banks for the redemption of old debts,
improvement, reclamation and development of land, purchase of agricultural
machinery and equipment and development of minor irrigation.
LAMPS were organized for the first time in December 1971 on the lines of FSS on
the recommendation of Bawa team appointed by the Government of India to look into
the credit problems of tribal areas. According to its framed objectives, these societies
are expected to provide all types of credit including consumption credit through a
single window. Intensification and modernization of agriculture with appropriate
technical guidance and improving the marketing of agricultural and forest products in
the tribal areas, are their other objectives.
Membership and Area of Operation: All tribes can become members of this society
on voluntary basis. It can cover an area of a block to a taluka.
Sources of Capital: Share capital of members and state governments, entrance fee,
reserve fund, deposits collected from members and non-members and loans taken
from cooperative institutions, Government are the various sources of capital.
Farmers Service societies are registered cooperative bodies based on the principles of cooperation
The specific function of the FSS is:
iv)
v)
Area of operation: The societies have been launched in selected districts. Each
society has a jurisdiction of a block or a portion thereof. A district union of these
societies is there at the district level to suggest ways and means for improving and
organizing these societies for executing specific activities. The membership of these
societies is open to those who are eligible to get assistance under Small Farmers
Development Agency (SFDA) and Marginal and Small Farmers Development
Agency (MFAL) programmes. Others may be associate members without any voting
rights.
Sponsorship: The lead bank of the district generally sponsors the FSS in financial
matters
Capital Structure: The various sources for funds are: share capital, loans, funds
contributed by commercial banks, cooperative societies, subsidies from SFDA and
MFAL and commissions accrued to the society through supply of essential inputs and
interest on advances. Share capital is contributed by its members, lead bank and the
State Government.
Management: The number of the members of the Board of Directors varies from 9 to
13 depending upon the size of the society. One full-time managing director is deputed
by the lead bank. Five directors will be elected from the members of the society of
which three are from small and marginal categories and two from other farmers. The
remaining directors are representatives of financial institutions. Block Development
Office, Department of Agriculture and Cooperative societies.
The establishment of Regional Rural Banks (RRBs) has been a landmark in the
history of rural banking. Till 1968, the official policy was in favour of developing
cooperative credit system. In 1969, All India Rural Credit Review Committee found
that over large parts of the country small farmers had been lacking access to
cooperative credit. Further, the quantum of credit from the cooperative system was
too little to meet the credit requirements of agriculture. In 1969 a major effort was
made to improve rural credit delivery system through nationalization of 14
commercial banks which emphasized on opening of rural branches. But rural branches
of commercial banks (CBs) proved to be a source of channelizing savings from rural
areas to urban areas. They also lacked trained personnel to handle rural issues and
acted more as a competitor to the cooperative credit system rather than supplementing
it. As CBs worked more for profit earning, they failed to include the disadvantaged
sections of the society in their banking domain.
RRBs were expected to play a vital role in mobilizing the savings of the small and
marginal farmers, artisans, agricultural laborers and small entrepreneurs and inculcate
banking habit among the rural people. These institutions were also expected to plug
the gap created in extending the credit to rural areas by largely urban-oriented
commercial banks and the rural cooperatives, which have close contact with rural
areas but fall short in terms of funds.
a. Objectives
2. Jurisdiction: The operational area to be covered by each RRB varies from one
to two districts for efficient functioning. The number of branches in the area
covered by each RRB may range from 50 to 60 keeping in view the
operational and financial efficiency. Each branch of a RRB is expected to
4. Share Capital: The authorized share capital of a RRB has been fixed at Rs 1
Crore and issued capital at Rs 25 lakhs. This is contributed by the Central
Government, State Government and the sponsoring Bank in the ratio of 50, 15
and 35, respectively. On the recommendation of working group of 1986, the
Government has increased the authorized capital to Rs 5 Crores and issued
capital to Rs 1 Crore to improve their viability.
5. Functions: The main functions of RRBs are to grant loans and advances
particularly to small and marginal farmers, agricultural laborers, cooperative
societies, artisans and small entrepreneurs within its operational area. They
extend other banking facilities also such as issuing of drafts, collection of
cheques etc. They also play a vital role in the rural developmental programmes
of the Government.
6. Rate of Interest: The rate of interest on the loans charged is the same as
collected by PACS. They have been allowed to offer 0.50 per cent higher
interest on deposits than offered by CBs.
i)
b. RRBs are allowed to pay 0.5 per cent higher interest rate to its depositors
over the interest rates paid by CBs;
c. Cash Reserve Requirement (CRR) of 3 per cent to be maintained with RBI
as against 10 per cent by CBs;
d. They are allowed to draw refinance from NABARD to the extent of 50 per
cent or more depending upon the type of advance of the eligible outstanding
loans at a concessional interest rate of 7 per cent per annum; and
e. The RRBs are registered as insured banks with Deposit Insurance and Credit
Guarantee Corporation of India (DICGC). All deposits up to 30,000 in each
bank are accordingly insured with the DICGC thus providing protection to
the depositors.
c. Performance of RRBs
However, in period following this report RRBs made impressive strides on various
business indicators. For instance, deposits of RRBs have grown by 18 times and
advances by 13 times between 1980 and 1990. Between 1990 and 2004, deposits and
advances grew by 14 times and 7 times, respectively (Table 2). Between the year
2000 and 2004, loans disbursed by RRBs more than doubled reflecting the efforts
taken by the banks to improve credit flow to the rural sector. The average per branch
advances also increased from Rs.25 lakh in March 1990 to Rs.154 lakh in March
2003. When one considers the deployment of credit relative to the mobilization of
resources, the credit-deposit (C-D) ratio of RRBs were more than 100 per cent during
the first decade of their operations up to 1987. Though the C-D ratio subsequently
became lower, of late, it has shown an improvement and went up from around 39 per
cent in March 2000 to 44.5 per cent in March 2004.
1980
1985
1990
1995
2000
2004
No. of RRBs
85
188
196
196
196
196
Capital
21
46
91
166
1959
2221
Deposits
222
1315
4023
11141
32226
56295
Advances
262
1405
3384
5987
12427
25038
Interest Earned
NA
NA
480
1158
3938
5535
Total Income
NA
NA
53
1230
4145
6231
Operating Profit
NA
NA
12
-280
524
1044
TABLE5.3: Direct Institutional Credit For Agriculture And Allied Activities Total (Short-Term And Long-Term)
(Rs. crore)
Loan Issued
Year
Coop.
S.G.
SCBs
RRBs
Loan Outstanding
Total
Coop.
SCBs
RRBs
(2 to 5)
Total
(7 to 9)
10
1972-73
958
177
21
1156
1837
342
2179
1980-81
2479
153
1496
168
4296
4821
3541
273
8635
1990-91
4819
359
4676
335
10188
10531
17032
1753
29316
2000-01
27295
487
16440
3966
48187
46135
38270
7249
91654
2009-10
58787
160690
26499
245976
64045
256119
37367
357531
2010-11
74938
34640
76480
46282
I.
Genesis
Prior to independence, long term credit requirement for agriculture were met by
money lenders and to a small extent by state governments. Considering this, All India
Rural Credit Survey Committee (1951) and Committee on Cooperative Credit (1960)
emphasized the need for arrangements for long-term finance for investment in
agriculture and suggested the establishment of an institution at the apex level. The
Standing Advisory Committee of RBI on Agriculture Credit had also supported the
recommendations. Consequent to their recommendations, Parliament through an Act
of 1963 provided for the establishment of Agriculture Refinance Corporation (ARC)
form July 1, 1963. It was basically a refinancing agency, meant for promotion and
development of agriculture through long-term financial assistance. Considering its
developmental and promotional role, it was renamed as Agricultural Refinance and
Development Corporation (ARDC). Ever since its inception, it financed term finance
which included medium term and long term loans for major agricultural development
projects, which were so far neglected by existing financial institutions.
ARDC could not make much headway in the field of direct financing and delivery of
rural credit against the massive credit demand for rural development. Its role to meet
the challenges in integrated rural credit through institution building, training, research,
policy making, planning and providing expertise in the diverse disciplines of finance
was inadequate and insufficient. As a result many committees and commissions viz.
Banking Commission (1972), National Commission on Agriculture (1976) and
Committee to Review Arrangements for Institutional Credit for Agriculture and Rural
Development (CRAFICARD) in 1979 under the chairmanship of B. Shivaraman,
former member of planning Commission recommended the setting up of a National
Level Institution called National Bank for Agricultural and Rural Development
(NABARD) for providing all types of production and investment credit for agriculture
and rural development. In pursuance to their recommendations, NABARD came into
existence in July 1982. The erstwhile ARDC, the Agricultural Credit Department
(ACD) and Rural Planning and Credit Cell (RPCC) of RBI were merged with
NABARD.
II.
Objectives
As an apex refinancing institution NABARD purveys all types of credit needed for
the farm sector and rural development. It is also vested with the responsibility of
promoting and integrating rural development activities through refinance. The bank is
also providing direct credit to an institution or agency or an individual subject to the
approval of the Central Government. It has close links with RBI for guidance and
assistance in financial matters. As an effective catalytic agent for rural development
and in formulation of appropriate rural development plans and policy, its role is
remarkable.
III.
i)
Functions
ii)
iii)
It provides short term credit to state cooperative banks, RRBs, and any
other financial institution notified by RBI for a period not exceeding 18
months by way of refinance for agricultural operations, marketing of crops
and marketing and distribution of agricultural inputs.
iv)
v)
vi)
vii)
viii)
ix)
It coordinates and monitors all agricultural and rural lending activities with
a view to tie up with extension and planned development activities in rural
areas; and
x)
IV.
Management
are appointed by the Central Government in consultation with the Reserve Bank of
India (RBI).
V.
Sources of Funds
Authorized share capital of NABARD is Rs 500 crores and issues and paid up capital
is Rs 100 crores. NABARD accrues additional funds from borrowings from the
Government of India and any institution approved by the Government of India, issue
and sale of bonds i.e. Rural Infrastructural Development Bond, borrowings from RBI,
deposits from State Governments and local authorities and gifts and grants received.
VI.
Performance of NABARD
In the last two decades of its existence NABARD has taken many initiatives to meet
the credit requirement for the development of agriculture and rural areas. The
Government has established Rural Infrastructural Development Fund within
NABARD from April 1995. The fund will provide loans to State Governments and
State Owned Corporations for completing on-going projects relating to medium and
minor irrigation, soil conservation, watershed management and other forms and rural
infrastructure. NABARD has also implemented a Partnership Model of linking of
self-help groups to CBs along with involvement of a NGO. The model has been
largely successful in delivering financial services to rural poor. NABARD has also
introduced a rehabilitation programme for the weak DCCBs and SCBs.
Table 5.4: National Bank for Agriculture and Rural Development - Financial
Assistance
(Rs. crore)
Year
No. of
Total Financial
NABARD's
Schemes
Assistance
Commitment
Sanctioned
Sanctioned
Disbursements
1976-77
4487
1713
1465
815
1980-81
16574
4629
3860
2223
1990-91
89513
23164
18299
14310
2000-01
121097
71241
56032
50882
(724)
(7096)
(6415)
(6158)
130595
156706
135773
130173
(3)
(12308)
(12009)
(12009)
130598
171444
149259
143659
(3)
(14738)
(13486)
(13486)
2009-10
2010-11
Agricultural Finance Corporation (AFC) was incorporated on April 10, 1968 by the
Indian Banks Association in order to provide advisory services to commercial banks
in matters related to financing agriculture. Basically, AFC is a consortium of
commercial banks established under the Indian Companies Act 1956 to provide
The
Corporation
has
two
distinct
institutions/organizations/individuals
roles:
involving
financing
agricultural
the
individual
development
and
units.
The
promotional
role
included
(a)commercialization
and
In recent years AFC has assumed only consultancy roles extending project
consultancy services to banks, Central/State Governments, NABARD, cooperatives,
private sector and international funding agencies. It also undertakes surveys and
research studies including, socio-economic, market, baseline, concurrent and impact
evaluation surveys, credit demand studies, farm management studies, MIS studies and
resource management studies both at national and international levels
Agricultural credit system in the country is faced with many problems, which restrict
its outreach to different areas and sections of farming classes as well as
hindering its
growth and contribution towards agricultural growth to the optimum level. These
problems can be discussed under following heads:
(i)
Two issues are involved in agricultural lending in India. The banking sector has to
cater a very large number of small borrowers spread over a very large area. Secondly,
size of the loan is very small. The small and marginal farmers constitute more than 80
per cent of the farmers and some of the areas are remotely located. Catering to their
requirements of farmers of such areas becomes very difficult and costly. From
borrowers point of view, access to intuitional credit especially for small, resource
poor and illiterate farmers gets inhibited as the procedural and documentation
requirements are cumbersome, time consuming and increase the cost of borrowing for
the farmers. On the other hand, access to non-institutional credit is regarded to be very
simple where transaction cost is negligible and involve no procedural complications.
Empirical studies show that transaction cost in case of non-institutional loans was
negligible whereas it ranged from 3 to 5 per cent in case of CBs, 1.4 to 3 per cent in
case of cooperatives and more than 8 per cent in case of RRBs.
(ii)
Loan Overdue
Gujarat,
Karnataka, Maharashtra, Rajasthan, Madhya Pradesh and Uttar Pradesh. The recovery
performance is poor in eastern and north-eastern states except West Bengal. There is
one good feature that where the use of institutional credit was higher, the recovery
performance was also better.
(iii)
(iv)
The small and marginal farmers constitute 80 per cent of operational holdings and
cultivate around 36 per cent of area in India. Their number is expected to grow in
future due to subdivision of holdings and lack of employment opportunities in the
non-farm sector. Due to their small holding they are disadvantageously placed with
respect to access to technology, credit and other institutional supports. The
information on distribution of institutional agricultural credit shows that their
access
to credit to meet their short term and long term capital requirements has not improved
over the years.
There are some disquieting features of lending to small borrowers. The number of
small borrower accounts in case of commercial banks has come down over time
indicating shifting of their focus to large borrowers. The rate of growth in agricultural
advances to small and marginal farmers (less than 2 ha) by scheduled commercial
banks in the 1990s has come down as compared to other farm size categories due to
which their share declined from 54 percent in TE 1993 to 51 per cent in total
agricultural credit in TE 2002. The All India Debt and Investment Survey (AIDIS)
showed that rural households with assets less than Rs 20,000 had access to
institutional loans for their credit needs only up to 35 to 37 per cent while the share of
non-institutional agencies in the outstanding debt was as high as 52 to 62 per cent. In
case of higher asset households, 70 per cent of the outstanding debt came from
institutional sources. Therefore, in spite of strong network of rural branches and
strong emphasis on target lending under poverty alleviation programmes, creating
self-employment opportunities, etc, a large number of rural poor remain outside the
fold of formal banking system for their credit needs. The important factors impeding
the access of disadvantaged sections to institutional credit are higher transaction costs
due to large numbers and small borrowings, higher risk cost, complicated procedures
and large documentation required, inability of small borrowers to provide tangible
collaterals, non-availability of tenancy agreements, loan waivers affecting recovery
performance, poor risk mitigation mechanism for farmers in the wake of natural
calamities and crop failure and mind set of bankers against small loans viewing them
as unprofitable.
(v)
Indebtedness of Indian farmers has a long history. The Deccan Riots Commission of
1875 reported that one third of the occupants of government land were under debt.
The Famine Commission of 1880 reported that one third of the land holders of the
country were under deep debt and another one third were also under debt but in
position to redeem it. The Famine Commission of 1901 estimated that more than 80
per cent of farmers were under debt. The Great Depression of 1929-30 also worsened
the debt situation. The problem of indebtedness of Indian farmers in the postindependent India continues (Table 5.5) with varying degrees. After 1981,
indebtedness has shown an increasing trend over the years with 57.2 per cent of
cultivators indebted in 2003. According to the 50th round of the National Sample
Survey Organization (NSSO) in 2005, if farmers engaged in allied agricultural
activities (going by principal source of income) are added to the cultivators then the
proportion of indebted farmers at all India level is 48.6 per cent. Deceleration in
agricultural growth in the 1990s is regarded as one of the most important factors
responsible for increasing indebtedness.
There is a wide variation in the number and proportion of indebted farmers across the
states and union territories (UTs) of India. At all India-level 48.6 per cent of the total
farmers are reported to be indebted. The incidence of indebtedness is the highest in
Andhra Pradesh (82.0) percent followed by Tamil Nadu (74.5 per cent), Punjab (65.4
per cent), Karnataka (61.6 per cent) and Maharashtra (54.8 per cent). The states of
Haryana, Rajasthan, Gujarat, Madhya Pradesh and west Bengal and group of UTs
have reported indebtedness among the farmers to the extent of 50-53 per cent. The
states of Meghalaya (4.1 per cent), Arunachal Pradesh (5.9 per cent) and Uttaranchal
(7.2 per cent) have reported very low incidence of indebtedness among farmers The
rest of the states have reported indebtedness in the range of 18.1 per cent in Assam to
49.2 per cent in Tripura. The states with high level of agricultural development are
reported to be home of a higher proportion of indebted farmers. The outstanding debt
also varies considerably according to the amount across states and farm sizes.
Table 5.5: Indebtedness among Cultivators in India
Year
1971
46.1
1981
22.3
1991
25.9
2003
57.2
The states with high level of agricultural development and with commercial farming
report high level of per farmer debt. Crop failure due to droughts/floods, pest attacks
and use of spurious insecticides and productive loans also add to high incidence of
indebtedness.
The prevalence of informal loans generates interlinked transactions in the market. The
farmers borrowing from informal sources generally use their crop as collateral and
commit to sell the output to the lender. The loans are also used to acquire modern
inputs like herbicides, insecticides, seeds, fertilizers and also consumer goods from
the lenders. In some of the cases farmers buy inputs as well as sell output via lenders.
The interlinked transactions take place because lenders are engaged in marketing of
agricultural inputs, consumer goods and agricultural output along with money
lending. The professional money lenders/commission agents charge high interest rates
generally between 18-36 per cent per annum and also exploit the farmers in supply of
inputs and marketing of agricultural output. This has negative implications for
agricultural development and cripples the farmers capacity to return loans and come
out of debt trap.
Farmers suicide in India has been reported regularly for period of a decade and half.
The states of Andhra Pradesh , Karnataka, Maharashtra, Kerala and Punjab are the
major states where such incidents have been experienced. The emergence of this
phenomenon has also become a subject of debate among the scholars, social
organizations and policy makers. Studies have shown that mainly economic and in
scattered cases non-economic factors have been responsible for farmers suicide.
Among economic factors, the failure of crop (mainly cotton) and failure of investment
in bore wells are responsible for involvement of farmers in debt trap. Stagnant
agricultural yields among Punjab farmers have been found to a cause of their stress. In
the wake of limited access to institutional credit, the small farmers are forced to
borrow from non-institutional sources. At times they rotate credit from noninstitutional to institutional sources and vice versa leading to their exploitation by
multiple agencies. There are a large number of factors which operate simultaneously
and cause unbearable distress to the farmer. The resource poor farmers in all the
major states reporting suicides constitute the largest proportion of suicide victims.
Thus it can be concluded that farmers suicides are more common in states which are
forerunner of commercial agriculture. They are Andhra Pradesh, Karnataka, Keral ,
Maharashtra and Punjab. These are the states which show high proportion of the
farmers under outstanding debt. With the exception of Kerala and Maharashtra, these
are the states where farmers dependence on informal sources of credit is very high.
In majority of the cases, the suicide victim farmers have used loans for investment in
agriculture and they belong to the category of small and marginal farmers. The
resource poor farmers suicides indicate that there is breakdown of the community
sense and social support mechanism in areas of highly commercialized and
competitive agriculture.
Broadly speaking, there are three major issues before the rural financial institutions
which need attention for making the agriculture sector make a significant contribution
to the economic growth of the country (1) The quantum of flow of institutional
credit to agriculture has to be increased; (2) The access to formal credit for the rural
poor and disadvantaged and agriculturally less developed regions has to be improved;
and (3) the economic viability of rural banking system has to be ensured over time.
The credit delivery system has been found wanting with respect to meeting adequately
credit requirements of high-tech and high-value agriculture, value addition,
processing and marketing activities of the farmers. Apart from crop sub-sector, the
financing of activities like animal husbandry, fisheries, agricultural services will
require vast credit support. New loan products such as pledge financing, marketing
credit, loan against warehouse receipts, export credit and venture capital for
agricultural entrepreneurship shall have to be promoted to meet the challenges posed
by globalization. The present credit delivery system only emphasizes production
credit. Thus the imbalance between production and post-production credit needs to be
rectified.
Secondly, the outreach of formal agricultural credit is not adequate to rural poor,
small and marginal farmers and agriculturally less developed areas. Linking of selfhelp groups (SHGs) with financial institutions with the help of non-governmental
organization (NGOs) has yielded positive results in the form of asset creation,
increased income and greater employment for these disadvantaged sections of the
society. Such successful examples of forming SHGs encouraging them to save and
provide micro-finance have to be replicated. The consumption requirements of the
poor s need to be integrated with production requirements. Crop insurance
programmes need to be more effective for taking care of risks arising out of crop
failure. Tenants lack access to credit because tenancy agreement is not in written
form. If the land-lease market is made free, it would help such farmers in procuring
formal credit.
Finally, the cost of borrowings to the farmers is also an important issue affecting the
flow of credit to agriculture sector. The rate of interest to agriculture has been recently
brought down to 9 per cent for loans less than Rs 50,000 and 10.5-12.5 per cent on
loans above Rs 50,000. The cost of credit from cooperative institutions is still high
because at every tier of the three tier structure some costs and margins are added and
secondly, cooperatives offer higher interests on deposits. The NABARD has amended
its 1981 act to provide refinance directly to DCCBs. Yet the transaction cost is high,
which need to be reduced by introducing new products like group lending,
to
support
the
process
of
agricultural
diversification
and
responsible for advising the Central Government on Mahatama Gandhi NREGArelated matters, and for monitoring and evaluating the implementation of the Act. It
will prepare Annual Reports on the implementation of Mahatama Gandhi NREGA for
submission to Parliament.
Organizational Structure Diagram at various levels namely State, directorate,
region, district, block etc
The Panchayats at district, intermediate and village levels are the principal authorities
for planning and implementation of the Schemes made under this Act. Key stake
holders are:- wage seekers, Gram Sabha, PRIs specially the Gram Panchayats,
Programme Officer at the block level, District programme Coordinator, State
Governments and Ministry of Rural Development.
Expectations from the public for enhancing the effectiveness and efficiency
To be aware of their rights enshrined under the Act and actively exercise them
Arrangements and methods made for seeking public participation /contribution
Awareness generation through intensive IEC activities using electronic media, print,
press advertisements, workshops, outdoor through DAVP
and interpersonal