HR-V1 Web
HR-V1 Web
HR-V1 Web
WORLD HAPPINESS
REPORT 2016 | VOLUME I
Update
Update
WORLD
HAPPINESS
REPORT
2016
Edited by John Helliwell, Richard Layard and Jeffrey Sachs
TABLE OF CONTENTS
1. Setting the Stage
50
Richard Layard
56
Jeffrey Sachs
The World Happiness Report was written by a group of independent experts acting in their personal capacities. Any views
expressed in this report do not necessarily reflect the views of any organization, agency or program of the United Nations.
Chapter 1
John F. Helliwell, Canadian Institute for Advanced Research and Vancouver School of Economics,
University of British Columbia
Richard Layard, Director, Well-Being Programme, Centre for Economic Performance,
London School of Economics and Political Science
Jeffrey D. Sachs, Director of the Earth Institute and the UN Sustainable Development Solutions
Network, Special Advisor to United Nations Secretary-General Ban Ki-moon on the Sustainable
Development Goals
W O R L D H A P P I N E S S R E P O R T 2 0 1 6 | U P D AT E
Introduction
The first World Happiness Report was published
in April 2012, in support of the High Level
Meeting at the United Nations on happiness and
well-being, chaired by the Prime Minister of
Bhutan. Since then we have come a long way.
Increasingly, happiness is considered to be the
proper measure of social progress and the goal
of public policy. This is the fourth World Happiness Report, and it is different in several respects
from its predecessors. These differences relate
to timing, content and geography.
In April 2015, we were already in the throes of
planning for the World Happiness Report 2017, on
the assumption that we would have, and need,
somewhere between 18 months and two years to
undertake the depth and range of research we
wanted to cover. However we were invited to
prepare a shorter report in 2016the World
Happiness Report 2016 Updatethat would be
released in Rome in March 2016, close to World
Happiness Day (March 20th). Twelve months
after that we plan to release World Happiness
Report 2017, with the usual broad range of
chapters based on global research, this time
including separate chapters focused on two large
global sub-populations, in China and Africa
respectively. Further plans include deeper
analysis of workplace happiness, and the happiness implications of immigration, refugees, and
transient populations.
Given the short time available since the launch of
World Happiness Report 2015, this Update has only
three chapters beyond this introduction, one
from each editor. Chapter 2, by John Helliwell,
Haifang Huang, and Shun Wang, contains our
primary rankings of and explanations for life
evaluations, significantly expanded this year to
include analysis of the inequality of well-being,
based on the distributions of happiness levels
within and among societies. Chapter 3, by Richard Layard, deals with the links between happiness and secular ethics. Chapter 4, by Jeffrey
Sachs, discusses the close connection between
W O R L D H A P P I N E S S R E P O R T 2 0 1 6 | U P D AT E
W O R L D H A P P I N E S S R E P O R T 2 0 1 6 | U P D AT E
Conclusion
In light of the limited time since the last report,
the 2016 Update is shorter than usual. This year,
as detailed in Chapter 2 of the Update, we
provide a fuller accounting of the distribution of
happiness among people within each country
and region. Just as happiness provides a broader
measure of well-being than separate accountings
of income, health status, and the quality of the
social context, we find that inequality of well-being provides a broader measure of inequality
than measures focusing on the distribution of
income and wealth. After documenting a general
rise in the inequality of happiness, we present
preliminary evidence that countries with more
equal distributions of well-being have higher
average life evaluations. This in turn invites
broader discussions about the policies that might
improve the levels and distribution of well-being
within and among countries.
We also present in Chapter 4 some preliminary
evidence that sustainable development is conducive to happiness. We find that happiness is
higher in countries closer to realizing the Sustainable Development Goals, as approved by the
nations of the world in September 2015.
Chapter 2
THE DISTRIBUTION
OF WORLD HAPPINESS
John F. Helliwell, Canadian Institute for Advanced Research and Vancouver School of Economics,
University of British Columbia
Haifang Huang, Department of Economics, University of Alberta
Shun Wang, KDI School of Public Policy and Management, Korea
The authors are grateful to the Canadian Institute for Advanced Research and the KDI School for research support, and to
the Gallup Organization for data access and assistance. In particular, several members of the Gallup staff helped in the
development of Technical Box 3. The author are also grateful for helpful advice and comments from Ed Diener, Curtis Eaton,
Carrie Exton, Leonard Goff, Carol Graham, Shawn Grover, Richard Layard, Guy Mayraz, Hugh Shiplett and Conal Smith.
W O R L D H A P P I N E S S R E P O R T 2 0 1 6 | U P D AT E
Introduction
It is now almost four years since the publication
of the first World Happiness Report (WHR) in
2012. Its central purpose was to survey the
scientific underpinnings of measuring and
understanding subjective well-being. Its main
content is as relevant today as it was then, and
remains available for those now coming to the
topic for the first time. The subsequent World
Happiness Report 2013 and World Happiness
Report 2015, issued at roughly 18 month intervals, updated and extended this background. To
make this World Happiness Report 2016 Update
accessible to those who are coming fresh to the
World Happiness Report series, we repeat enough
of the core analysis in this chapter, and its
several on-line appendices, to explain the meaning of the evidence we are reporting.
Chapter 2 in World Happiness Report 2015, the
Geography of World Happiness, started with a
global map, and continued with our attempts to
explain the levels and changes in average national life evaluations among countries around the
world. This year we shall still consider the
geographic distribution of life evaluations
among countries, while extending our analysis
to consider in more detail the inequality of
happiness how life evaluations are distributed
among individuals within countries and geographic regions.
In studying more deeply the distribution of
happiness within national and regional populations, we are extending the approach adopted in
Chapter 2 of the first World Happiness Report, in
which Figure 2.1 showed the global distribution
of life evaluations among the 11 response categories, with the worst possible life as a 0 and the
best possible life as a 10 (the Cantril ladder
question). The various parts of Figure 2.2 then
made the same allocation of responses for
respondents in nine global regions, weighting
the responses from different countries according
to each countrys population. In those figures we
combined all the data then available, for the
10
W O R L D H A P P I N E S S R E P O R T 2 0 1 6 | U P D AT E
The OECD (2013) Guidelines on Measuring Subjective Well-being, quotes in its introduction the
following definition and recommendation from
the earlier Commission on the Measurement of
Economic and Social Progress:
Subjective well-being encompasses three different aspects: cognitive evaluations of ones
life, positive emotions (joy, pride), and negative ones (pain, anger, worry). While these aspects of subjective well-being have different
determinants, in all cases these determinants
go well beyond peoples income and material
conditions... All these aspects of subjective
well-being should be measured separately to
derive a more comprehensive measure of peoples quality of life and to allow a better understanding of its determinants (including peoples objective conditions). National statistical
agencies should incorporate questions on subjective well-being in their standard surveys to
capture peoples life evaluations, hedonic experiences and life priorities.5
The OECD Guidelines go on to recommend a
core module of questions to be used by national
statistical agencies in their household surveys:
There are two elements to the core measures
module.
The first is a primary measure of life evaluation.
This represents the absolute minimum required to measure subjective well-being, and it
is recommended that all national statistical
agencies include this measure in one of their
annual household surveys.
11
12
answers? For this important question, no definitive answer was available until the European
Social Survey (ESS) asked the same respondents
satisfaction with life and happy with life
questions, wisely using the same 0 to 10 response scales. The answers showed that income
and other key variables all have the same effects
on the happy with life answers as on the
satisfied with life answers, so much so that
once again more powerful explanations come
from averaging the two answers.
Another previously common view was that
changes in life evaluations at the individual level
were largely transitory, returning to their baseline as people rapidly adapt to their circumstances. This view has been rejected by four independent lines of evidence. First, average life
evaluations differ significantly and systematically among countries, and these differences are
substantially explained by life circumstances.
This implies that rapid and complete adaptation
to different life circumstances does not take
place. Second, there is evidence of long-standing
trends in the life evaluations of sub-populations
within the same country, further demonstrating
that life evaluations can be changed within
policy-relevant time scales.13 Third, even though
individual-level partial adaptation to major life
events is a normal human response, there is
very strong evidence of continuing influence on
well-being from major disabilities and unemployment, among other life events.14 The case of
marriage is still under debate. Some recent
results using panel data from the UK have
suggested that people return to baseline levels of
life satisfaction several years after marriage, a
result that has been argued to support the more
general applicability of set points.15 However,
subsequent research using the same data has
shown that marriage does indeed have long-lasting well-being benefits, especially in protecting
the married from as large a decline in the
middle-age years that in many countries represent a low-point in life evaluations.16 Fourth, and
especially relevant in the global context, are
studies of migration showing migrants to have
W O R L D H A P P I N E S S R E P O R T 2 0 1 6 | U P D AT E
average levels and distributions of life evaluations that resemble those of other residents of
their new countries more than of comparable
residents in the countries from which they have
emigrated.17 This confirms that life evaluations
do depend on life circumstances, and are not
destined to return to baseline levels as required
by the set point hypothesis.
people see through the day-to-day and hour-tohour fluctuations, so that the answers they give
on weekdays and weekends do not differ.
On the other hand, although life evaluations do
not vary by the day of week, they are much more
responsive than emotional reports to differences
in life circumstances. This is true whether the
comparison is among national averages20 or
among individuals.21
Furthermore, life evaluations vary more between
countries than do emotions. Thus almost
one-quarter of the global variation in life evaluations is among countries, compared to
three-quarters among individuals in the same
country. This one-quarter share for life evaluations is far more than for either positive affect
(7 percent) or negative affect (4 percent). This
difference is partly due to the role of income,
which plays a stronger role in life evaluations
than in emotions, and is also very unequally
spread among countries. For example, more
than 40 percent of the global variation among
household incomes is among nations rather
than among individuals within nations.22
These twin facts that life evaluations vary
much more than do emotions across countries,
and that these life evaluations are much more
fully explained by life circumstances than are
emotional reports provide for us a sufficient
reason for using life evaluations as our central
measure for making international comparisons.23 But there is more. To give a central role
to life evaluations does not mean we need to
either ignore or downplay the important information provided by experiential measures. On
the contrary, we see every reason to keep experiential measures of well-being, as well as measures of life purpose, as important elements in
our attempts to measure and understand subjective well-being. This is easy to achieve, at least in
principle, because our evidence continues to
suggest that experienced well-being and a sense
of life purpose are both important influences on
13
.25
.2
.15
.1
.05
World
10
W O R L D H A P P I N E S S R E P O R T 2 0 1 6 | U P D AT E
.35
Mean = 7.125
SD = 2.016
.3
.35
.25
.25
.2
.2
.15
.15
.1
.1
.05
Mean = 6.578
SD = 2.329
.3
.05
0
10
.35
.25
.2
.15
.15
.1
.1
.05
.05
2
10
Mean = 5.502
SD = 2.073
.3
.25
.2
.15
.15
.1
.1
.05
.05
4
.35
10
.25
.2
.15
.15
.1
.1
.05
.05
4
10
10
Mean = 4.999
SD = 2.452
.3
.2
.35
.25
10
Southeast Asia
Mean = 5.288
SD = 2.000
.3
Mean = 5.363
SD = 1.963
.3
.2
.35
.25
.35
Mean = 5.554
SD = 2.152
Western Europe
.3
.2
.35
.25
Mean = 6.575
SD = 1.944
.3
10
East Asia
10
.35
Mean = 4.589
SD = 2.087
.3
.35
.25
.25
.2
.2
.15
.15
.1
.1
.05
Mean = 4.370
SD = 2.115
.3
.05
0
South Asia
10
Sub-Saharan Africa
10
15
Table 2.1: Regressions to Explain Average Happiness across Countries (Pooled OLS)
Independent Variable
Log GDP per capita
Cantril Ladder
0.338
(0.059)***
Dependent Variable
Positive Affect Negative Affect
-0.002
0.011
(0.009)
(0.008)
Cantril Ladder
0.341
(0.058)***
Social support
2.334
(0.429)***
0.253
(0.052)***
-0.238
(0.046)***
1.768
(0.417)***
0.029
(0.008)***
0.0002
(0.001)
0.002
(0.001)*
0.028
(0.008)***
1.056
(0.319)***
0.328
(0.039)***
-0.089
(0.045)**
0.315
(0.316)
Generosity
0.820
(0.276)***
0.171
(0.032)***
-0.011
(0.030)
0.429
(0.277)
-0.579
(0.282)**
0.033
(0.030)
0.092
(0.025)***
-0.657
(0.271)**
Perceptions of corruption
Positive affect
2.297
(0.443)***
Negative affect
Year fixed effects
Number of countries
Number of observations
Adjusted R-squared
0.050
(0.506)
Included
156
1,118
0.741
Included
156
1,115
0.497
Included
156
1,117
0.226
Included
156
1,114
0.765
Notes: This is a pooled OLS regression for a tattered panel explaining annual national average Cantril ladder
responses from all available surveys from 2005 to 2015. See Technical Box 2 for detailed information about each
of the predictors. Coefficients are reported with robust standard errors clustered by country in parentheses.
***, **, and * indicate significance at the 1, 5 and 10 percent levels respectively.
16
W O R L D H A P P I N E S S R E P O R T 2 0 1 6 | U P D AT E
Technical Box 2: Detailed information about each of the predictors in Table 2.1
17
ment the Aristotelian presumption that sustained positive emotions are important supports
for a good life.28 The most striking feature is the
extent to which the results buttress a finding in
psychology, that the existence of positive emotions matters much more than the absence of
negative ones. Positive affect has a large and
highly significant impact in the final equation of
Table 2.1, while negative affect has none.
Each of these bars is divided into seven segments, showing our research efforts to find
possible sources for the ladder levels. The first
six sub-bars show how much each of the six key
variables is calculated to contribute to that
countrys ladder score, relative to that in a
hypothetical country called Dystopia, so named
because it has values equal to the worlds
lowest national averages for 2013-2015 for each
of the six key variables used in Table 2.1. We
use Dystopia as a benchmark against which to
compare each other countrys performance in
terms of each of the six factors. This choice of
benchmark permits every real country to have a
non-negative contribution from each of the six
factors. We calculate, based on estimates in
Table 2.1, a 20132015 ladder score in Dystopia
to have been 2.33 on the 10-point scale. The
final sub-bar is the sum of two components: the
calculated average 2013-2015 life evaluation in
Dystopia (=2.33) and each countrys own prediction error, which measures the extent to which
life evaluations are higher or lower than predicted by our equation in the first column of
Table 2.1. The residuals are as likely to be
negative as positive.29
18
W O R L D H A P P I N E S S R E P O R T 2 0 1 6 | U P D AT E
ence of healthy life expectancy on life evaluations. The width of these different sub-bars then
shows, country-by-country, how much each of
the six variables is estimated to contribute to
explaining the international ladder differences.
These calculations are illustrative rather than
conclusive, for several reasons. First, the selection of candidate variables was restricted by
what is available for all these countries. Traditional variables like GDP per capita and healthy
life expectancy are widely available. But measures of the quality of the social context, which
have been shown in experiments and national
surveys to have strong links to life evaluations,
have not been sufficiently surveyed in the
Gallup or other global polls, or otherwise measured in statistics available for all countries.
Even with this limited choice, we find that four
variables covering different aspects of the social
and institutional context having someone to
count on, generosity, freedom to make life
choices and absence of corruption are together responsible for 50 percent of the average
differences between each countrys predicted
ladder score and that in Dystopia in the 20132015 period. As shown in Table 13 of the Statistical Appendix, the average country has a 20132015 ladder score that is 3.05 points above the
Dystopia ladder score of 2.33. Of the 3.05 points,
the largest single part (31 percent) comes from
GDP per capita, followed by social support (26
percent) and healthy life expectancy (18 percent), and then by freedom (12 percent), generosity (8 percent) and corruption (5 percent).30
Our limited choice means that the variables we
use may be taking credit properly due to other
better variables, or to un-measurable other
factors. There are also likely to be vicious or
virtuous circles, with two-way linkages among
the variables. For example, there is much evidence that those who have happier lives are
likely to live longer, to be most trusting, more
cooperative, and generally better able to meet
lifes demands.31 This will feed back to influence
health, GDP, generosity, corruption, and the
sense of freedom. Finally, some of the variables
19
20
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.
9.
10.
11.
12.
13.
14.
15.
16.
17.
18.
19.
20.
21.
22.
23.
24.
25.
26.
27.
28.
29.
30.
31.
32.
33.
34.
35.
36.
37.
38.
39.
40.
41.
42.
43.
44.
45.
46.
47.
48.
49.
50.
51.
52.
53.
Denmark (7.526)
Switzerland (7.509)
Iceland (7.501)
Norway (7.498)
Finland (7.413)
Canada (7.404)
Netherlands (7.339)
New Zealand (7.334)
Australia (7.313)
Sweden (7.291)
Israel (7.267)
Austria (7.119)
United States (7.104)
Costa Rica (7.087)
Puerto Rico (7.039)
Germany (6.994)
Brazil (6.952)
Belgium (6.929)
Ireland (6.907)
Luxembourg (6.871)
Mexico (6.778)
Singapore (6.739)
United Kingdom (6.725)
Chile (6.705)
Panama (6.701)
Argentina (6.650)
Czech Republic (6.596)
United Arab Emirates (6.573)
Uruguay (6.545)
Malta (6.488)
Colombia (6.481)
France (6.478)
Thailand (6.474)
Saudi Arabia (6.379)
Taiwan (6.379)
Qatar (6.375)
Spain (6.361)
Algeria (6.355)
Guatemala (6.324)
Suriname (6.269)
Kuwait (6.239)
Bahrain (6.218)
Trinidad and Tobago (6.168)
Venezuela (6.084)
Slovakia (6.078)
El Salvador (6.068)
Malaysia (6.005)
Nicaragua (5.992)
Uzbekistan (5.987)
Italy (5.977)
Ecuador (5.976)
Belize (5.956)
Japan (5.921)
0
W O R L D H A P P I N E S S R E P O R T 2 0 1 6 | U P D AT E
21
22
W O R L D H A P P I N E S S R E P O R T 2 0 1 6 | U P D AT E
23
W O R L D H A P P I N E S S R E P O R T 2 0 1 6 | U P D AT E
Nicaragua (1.285)
Sierra Leone (1.028)
Ecuador (0.966)
Moldova (0.959)
Latvia (0.872)
Chile (0.826)
Slovakia (0.814)
Uruguay (0.804)
Uzbekistan (0.755)
Russia (0.738)
Peru (0.730)
Azerbaijan (0.642)
Zimbabwe (0.639)
Thailand (0.631)
Macedonia (0.627)
El Salvador (0.572)
Georgia (0.561)
Paraguay (0.536)
China (0.525)
Kyrgyzstan (0.515)
Germany (0.486)
Brazil (0.474)
Tajikistan (0.474)
Argentina (0.457)
Puerto Rico (0.446)
Serbia (0.426)
Philippines (0.425)
Cameroon (0.413)
Colombia (0.399)
Zambia (0.381)
Bulgaria (0.373)
Trinidad and Tobago (0.336)
Bolivia (0.322)
Kazakhstan (0.322)
Palestinian Territories (0.321)
Romania (0.310)
Mongolia (0.298)
Kosovo (0.298)
South Korea (0.295)
Indonesia (0.295)
Haiti (0.274)
Bosnia and Herzegovina (0.263)
-1.5
-1.2
-0.9
-0.6
-0.3
0.0
0.3
0.6
0.9
1.2
25
-1.2
-0.9
26
-0.6
-0.3
0.0
0.3
0.6
0.9
1.2
W O R L D H A P P I N E S S R E P O R T 2 0 1 6 | U P D AT E
-1.2
-0.9
-0.6
-0.3
0.0
0.3
0.6
0.9
1.2
-1.5 -1.2 -0.9 -0.6 -0.3 0.0 0.3 0.6 0.9 1.2
27
28
then the crisis may even lead to higher subjective well-being, in part by giving people a chance
to work together towards good purpose, and to
realize and appreciate the strength of their
mutual social support; and in part because the
crisis will be better handled and the underlying
social capital improved in use.
For this argument to be convincing requires
examples on both sides of the ledger. It is one
thing to show cases where the happiness losses
were very big and where the erosion of the social
fabric appeared to be a part of the story. But what
examples are there on the other side? With
respect to the post-2007 economic crisis, the
best examples of happiness maintenance in the
face of large external shocks are Ireland and
especially Iceland. Both suffered decimation of
their banking systems as extreme as anywhere,
and yet have suffered incommensurately small
happiness losses. In the Icelandic case, the
post-shock recovery in life evaluations has been
great enough to put Iceland third in the global
rankings for 2013-2015. That there is a continuing high degree of social support in both countries is indicated by the fact that of all the countries surveyed by the Gallup World Poll, the
percentage of people who report that they have
someone to count on in times of crisis is exceptionally high in Iceland and Ireland.39
If the social context is important for happiness-supporting resilience under crisis, it is
likely to be equally applicable for non-economic
crises. There is now research showing that levels
of trust and social capital in the Fukushima
region of Japan were sufficient that the Great
East Japan Earthquake of 2011 actually led to
increased trust and happiness in the region.40
The happiness effects of crisis response may
also be mediated through generosity triggered
by a large natural disaster, with the additional
generosity adding to happiness.41
What can be learned by using the six-variable
explanation of Table 2.1 to explain happiness
W O R L D H A P P I N E S S R E P O R T 2 0 1 6 | U P D AT E
29
30
W O R L D H A P P I N E S S R E P O R T 2 0 1 6 | U P D AT E
31
1.
32
0.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
W O R L D H A P P I N E S S R E P O R T 2 0 1 6 | U P D AT E
Bhutan (1.294)
Comoros (1.385)
Netherlands (1.397)
Singapore (1.538)
Iceland (1.569)
Luxembourg (1.574)
Switzerland (1.583)
Senegal (1.598)
Afghanistan (1.598)
Finland (1.598)
Vietnam (1.599)
Mauritania (1.600)
Rwanda (1.601)
Sweden (1.604)
Madagascar (1.616)
Congo (Kinshasa) (1.619)
Belgium (1.647)
New Zealand (1.649)
Azerbaijan (1.649)
Tajikistan (1.656)
Myanmar (1.661)
Denmark (1.674)
Norway (1.677)
Israel (1.685)
Laos (1.696)
Indonesia (1.702)
Mongolia (1.705)
Niger (1.705)
Canada (1.726)
Australia (1.756)
Benin (1.757)
Guinea (1.794)
Kyrgyzstan (1.798)
Ireland (1.801)
Thailand (1.803)
Germany (1.805)
Austria (1.819)
France (1.845)
Somaliland region (1.848)
Lithuania (1.848)
Moldova (1.850)
Hong Kong (1.854)
Chad (1.855)
Latvia (1.862)
Turkmenistan (1.874)
United Kingdom (1.875)
Algeria (1.877)
Taiwan (1.878)
Ethiopia (1.884)
Japan (1.884)
Estonia (1.888)
Spain (1.899)
33
0.0
0.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
3.5
34
0.0
0.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
3.5
W O R L D H A P P I N E S S R E P O R T 2 0 1 6 | U P D AT E
35
0.0
0.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
3.5
1.
6. World (0.123)
7.
36
0.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
W O R L D H A P P I N E S S R E P O R T 2 0 1 6 | U P D AT E
Figure 2.7: Changes in Standard Deviation of Happiness from 2005-2011 to 2012-2015 (Part 1)
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.
9.
10.
11.
12.
13.
14.
15.
16.
17.
18.
19.
20.
21.
22.
23.
24.
25.
26.
27.
28.
29.
30.
31.
32.
33.
34.
35.
36.
37.
38.
39.
40.
41.
42.
43.
44.
45.
46.
47.
48.
49.
50.
Pakistan (-0.425)
Iceland (-0.376)
Malta (-0.232)
Afghanistan (-0.221)
Dominican Republic (-0.201)
Chile (-0.182)
Paraguay (-0.178)
Israel (-0.156)
Azerbaijan (-0.153)
Puerto Rico (-0.138)
Comoros (-0.124)
Lithuania (-0.113)
Moldova (-0.106)
Taiwan (-0.096)
Peru (-0.090)
Colombia (-0.072)
Spain (-0.071)
Mauritania (-0.068)
Slovenia (-0.060)
Croatia (-0.053)
Japan (-0.052)
Congo (Kinshasa) (-0.046)
Luxembourg (-0.045)
Nicaragua (-0.043)
New Zealand (-0.043)
Poland (-0.042)
Hong Kong (-0.041)
Mexico (-0.037)
Germany (-0.034)
Lebanon (-0.031)
Botswana (-0.030)
Argentina (-0.025)
Somaliland region (-0.024)
Ukraine (-0.023)
Brazil (-0.020)
Switzerland (-0.017)
Hungary (-0.015)
Sweden (-0.014)
Ireland (-0.001)
Rwanda (0.001)
Palestinian Territories (0.004)
United Kingdom (0.004)
Mauritius (0.007)
South Korea (0.011)
Turkey (0.013)
Slovakia (0.017)
Canada (0.017)
Trinidad and Tobago (0.019)
Czech Republic (0.020)
Mongolia (0.024)
37
0.0
0.5
1.0
1.5
Figure 2.7: Changes in Standard Deviation of Happiness from 2005-2011 to 2012-2015 (Part 2)
51. Angola (0.025)
52. Russia (0.029)
53. Norway (0.030)
54. Italy (0.034)
55. Ecuador (0.034)
56. Egypt (0.035)
57. Thailand (0.043)
58. Singapore (0.050)
59. Australia (0.052)
60. Austria (0.053)
61. Gabon (0.057)
62. Georgia (0.059)
63. Guinea (0.059)
64. Uruguay (0.059)
65. Senegal (0.061)
66. Yemen (0.064)
67. Finland (0.070)
68. Belarus (0.072)
69. Latvia (0.076)
70. France (0.080)
71. Indonesia (0.089)
72. Benin (0.093)
73. Bolivia (0.094)
74. Belgium (0.095)
75. Costa Rica (0.096)
76. Estonia (0.099)
77. Macedonia (0.107)
78. El Salvador (0.111)
79. Turkmenistan (0.111)
80. Honduras (0.112)
81. Romania (0.113)
82. China (0.119)
83. Netherlands (0.122)
84. Sri Lanka (0.127)
85. Bulgaria (0.134)
86. Vietnam (0.135)
87. Tajikistan (0.136)
88. United States (0.142)
89. Kazakhstan (0.145)
90. United Arab Emirates (0.148)
91. Zimbabwe (0.148)
92. Greece (0.155)
93. Bangladesh (0.159)
94. Bahrain (0.167)
95. Serbia (0.168)
96. Nigeria (0.177)
97. South Africa (0.181)
98. Bosnia and Herzegovina (0.185)
99. Uganda (0.186)
100. Venezuela (0.188)
38
0.0
0.5
1.0
1.5
W O R L D H A P P I N E S S R E P O R T 2 0 1 6 | U P D AT E
Figure 2.7: Changes in Standard Deviation of Happiness from 2005-2011 to 2012-2015 (Part 3)
101. Armenia (0.192)
102. Denmark (0.193)
103. Kyrgyzstan (0.195)
104. Ghana (0.198)
105. Madagascar (0.198)
106. Algeria (0.226)
107. Panama (0.230)
108. India (0.231)
109. Montenegro (0.254)
110. Niger (0.256)
111. Portugal (0.257)
112. Togo (0.259)
113. Jordan (0.271)
114. Qatar (0.273)
115. Uzbekistan (0.277)
116. Chad (0.287)
117. Kosovo (0.288)
118. Mali (0.291)
119. Cyprus (0.311)
120. Philippines (0.324)
121. Syria (0.326)
122. Nepal (0.347)
123. Morocco (0.359)
124. Iran (0.370)
125. Sudan (0.377)
126. Haiti (0.393)
127. Tunisia (0.401)
128. Tanzania (0.409)
129. Belize (0.415)
130. Malawi (0.429)
131. Malaysia (0.430)
132. Kenya (0.436)
133. Guatemala (0.438)
134. Saudi Arabia (0.447)
135. Burkina Faso (0.451)
136. Cameroon (0.466)
137. Ivory Coast (0.510)
138. Albania (0.550)
139. Kuwait (0.577)
140. Zambia (0.580)
141. Jamaica (0.600)
142. Burundi (0.616)
143. Laos (0.635)
144. Congo (Brazzaville) (0.709)
145. Cambodia (0.791)
146. Sierra Leone (0.913)
147. Iraq (0.963)
148. Namibia (1.218)
149. Liberia (1.341)
39
0.0
0.3
0.5
0.6
0.9
1.0
1.2
1.5
1.5
40
W O R L D H A P P I N E S S R E P O R T 2 0 1 6 | U P D AT E
41
1 D
iener, Lucas, & Oishi (2016) estimate the number of new
scientific articles on subjective well-being to have grown by
about two orders of magnitude in the past 25 years, from
about 130 per year in 1980 to almost 15,000 in 2014.
12 S
ee, for an example using individual-level data,
Kahneman & Deaton (2010), and for national-average data
Table 2.1 of Helliwell, Huang, & Wang (2015, p. 22) or
Table 2.1 of this chapter.
2 S
ee OECD (2013).
13 B
arrington-Leigh (2013) documents a significant upward
trend in life satisfaction in Qubec, compared to the rest
of Canada, of a size accumulating over 25 years to an
amount equivalent to more than a trebling of mean
household income.
42
W O R L D H A P P I N E S S R E P O R T 2 0 1 6 | U P D AT E
43
37 T
here are thus, as shown in Table 15 of the Statistical
Appendix, 31 countries that are in the 2013-2015 ladder
rankings of Figure 2.2 but without changes shown in
Figure 2.3. These countries for which changes are missing
include some of the 10 lowest ranking countries in Figure
2.2. Several of these countries might well have been
shown among the 10 major losers had their earlier data
been available.
53 S
ee United Nations (2013, Figure 2.1). If the national Gini
coefficients are weighted by national population, the
global measure has been declining continuously, mainly
through the impact of China. Still using population
weights, but excluding China, the global average peaked
in 2010 (just as did the unweighted average) and fell more
rapidly than the unweighted average to a level that was
nonetheless slightly higher in 2010 than it was in 1980.
54 S
ee the World Bank data portal http://data.worldbank.
org/indicator/SI.POV.GINI?order=wbapi_data_value_2010+wbapi_data_value+wbapi_data_value-last&sort=asc&page=1.
60 S
ee Helliwell & Wang (2011).
45 T
he World Bank (2014) has emphasized the measurement and eradication of extreme poverty.
61 S
ee Goff et al. (2016), Table 6.
46 S
ee Keeley (2015) for a survey of recent OECD data and
research on inequality.
47 S
ee Atkinson (2015), Atkinson & Bourguignon (2014),
Deaton (2013), Piketty (2014), Stiglitz (2013, 2015), and
Wilkinson and Pickett (2009). For an earlier review from
a sociological perspective, see Neckerman & Torche
(2007).
48 S
ee, e.g. Marmot, Ryff, Bumpass, Shipley, & Marks
(1997).
49 S
ee Roemer & Trannoy (2013) for a theoretical survey, and
Putnam (2015) for data documenting declining equality
of opportunity in the United States. For a survey of
research on intergenerational mobility, see Corak (2013).
44
55 T
his is because it is almost impossible to compare price
levels when there is very little overlap in the products
consumed to sustain standards of living in different
countries. See Deaton (2010).
62 T
he negative effect of well-being inequality becomes
significant only when regional dummy variables are also
included, as also found by Goff et al. (2016). That paper
includes income and regional dummy variables for all
regions, but none of the other variables used in Table 2.1.
We find that the only necessary regional variable is for
Latin America, which has inexplicably high life evaluations (i.e. most countries have actual ladder values above
those predicted by the equation of Table 2.1) and also
unusually high inequality of subjective well-being. The
coefficient on well-being inequality rises if the variables
for freedom and social support are removed, showing that
these are in part the likely routes via which well-being
inequality reduces well-being. If the Latin American
countries are compared with each other, people are
nonetheless happier in those countries with more equal
distributions of well-being, consistent with earlier
findings by Graham & Felton (2006).
W O R L D H A P P I N E S S R E P O R T 2 0 1 6 | U P D AT E
63 W
e test two different measures of income inequality in
our Table 2.1 equation. The first is from the World Bank,
the same source used by Goff et al. (2016), and it shows
for us, as it generally did for them, no significant negative
effect, whether or not the inequality of well-being is also
included in the equation. The second measure, as
described in the Statistical Appendix, is based on Gini
coefficients constructed from the incomes reported by
individual respondents to the Gallup World Poll. That
variable attracts a significant negative coefficient whether
or not subjective well-being inequality is included, and it
is stronger than the subjective well-being inequality when
the two measures are both included, as shown in Table 10
of the Statistical Appendix.
64 See Table 10 of the Statistical Appendix.
65 W
e use the standard deviation as our preferred measure
of well-being inequality, following Kalmijn & Veenhoven
(2005) and Goff et al (2016). See also Delhey & Kohler
(2011) and Veenhoven (2012). Since we are anxious to
avoid mechanical negative correlation between average
well-being and our measure of inequality, the standard
deviation is a more conservative choice than the coefficient of variation, which is the standard deviation divided
by the mean, and the Gini, which mimics the coefficient
of variation very closely.
66 The 95 percent confidence intervals for standard
deviations and changes in standard deviations are all
estimated by bootstrapping methods (1,000 times).
67 T
he cross-sectional correlation between the average
ladder for 2013-2015 and the standard deviations of
within-country ladder scores is -0.25.
68 I f the Gallup World Poll questions relating to corruption,
freedom and social support had been asked on a 0 to 10
scale, rather than as either 0 or 1, we might have been
able to see if the inequality of life evaluations was based
on some combination of the inequalities of the main
supporting variables.
69 Figure 2.4 in the first World Happiness Report shows the
2005-2011 values for the standard deviations of the ladder
data in each country. Table 2.8 in World Happiness Report
2013 shows changes in the income Ginis by global region.
70 N
ote also the wide standard error bars for the Icelandic
changes, reflecting the relative infrequency and sometimes half-size of the survey samples there. Even with
these smaller samples, the change shown in Figure 2.7
for Iceland is significantly positive.
71 S
ee Dussaillant & Guzmn (2014). In the wake of the
2010 earthquake in Chile, there was looting in some
places and not in others, depending on initial trust levels.
Trust subsequently grew in those areas where helping
prevailed instead of looting.
45
References
Alesina, A., Di Tella, R., & MacCulloch, R. (2004). Inequality
and happiness: Are Europeans and Americans different?
Journal of Public Economics, 88(9), 2009-2042.
Atkinson, A. B. (2015). Inequality: What can be done? Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Atkinson, A. B., & Bourguignon, F. (Eds.) (2014). Handbook of
income distribution (Vols. 2A & 2B). Elsevier.
Barrington-Leigh, C. P. (2013). The Quebec convergence and
Canadian life satisfaction, 19852008. Canadian Public Policy,
39(2), 193-219.
Becchetti, L., Massari, R., & Naticchioni, P. (2014). The drivers
of happiness inequality: Suggestions for promoting social
cohesion. Oxford Economic Papers, 66(2), 419-442.
Bonikowska, A., Helliwell, J. F., Hou, F., & Schellenberg, G.
(2013). An assessment of life satisfaction responses on recent
Statistics Canada Surveys. Social Indicators Research, 118(2), 1-27.
Cantril, H. (1965). The pattern of human concerns. New
Brunswick: Rutgers University Press.
Chen, C., Lee, S. Y., & Stevenson, H. W. (1995). Response style
and cross-cultural comparisons of rating scales among East
Asian and North American students. Psychological Science,
6(3), 170-175.
Clark, A., Flche, S., & Senik, C. (2014). The great happiness
moderation: Well-being inequality during episodes of income
growth. In A. Clark & C. Senik (Eds.), Happiness and economic
growth: Lessons from developing countries (pp. 32-139). Oxford:
Oxford University Press.
Clark, A. E., & Georgellis, Y. (2013). Back to baseline in
Britain: Adaptation in the British Household Panel Survey.
Economica, 80(319), 496-512.
Corak, M. (2013). Income inequality, equality of opportunity,
and intergenerational mobility. The Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 27(3), 79-102.
Deaton, A. (2010). Price indexes, inequality, and the measurement of world poverty. American Economic Review, 100(1), 5-34.
Deaton, A. (2013). The great escape: Health, wealth, and the
origins of inequality. Princeton University Press.
46
Diener, E., Gohm, C. L., Suh, E., & Oishi, S. (2000). Similarity
of the relations between marital status and subjective
well-being across cultures. Journal of cross-cultural psychology,
31(4), 419-436.
Diener, E., Helliwell, J., & Kahneman, D. (Eds.) (2010).
International differences in well-being. Oxford University Press.
Diener, E., Lucas, R. & Oishi, S. (2016). Advances and open
questions in the science of well-being. Unpublished manuscript.
Durand, M., & Smith, C. (2013). The OECD approach to
measuring subjective well-being. In J. F. Helliwell, R. Layard,
& J. Sachs (Eds.), World happiness report 2013 (pp. 112-137). New
York: UN Sustainable Development Solutions Network.
Dussaillant, F., & Guzmn, E. (2014). Trust via disasters: The
case of Chiles 2010 earthquake. Disasters, 38(4), 808-832.
Exton, C., Smith, C., & Vandendriessche, D. (2015). Comparing happiness across the world: Does culture matter? OECD
Statistics Working Papers, 2015/04, Paris: OECD Publishing.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5jrqppzd9bs2-en
Frank, K., Hou, F., & Schellenberg, G. (2015). Life satisfaction
among recent immigrants in Canada: comparisons to
source-country and host-country populations. Journal of
Happiness Studies, 1-22. http://doi.org/10.1007/s10902-0159664-2
Fredrickson, B. L. (2001). The role of positive emotions in
positive psychology: The broaden-and-build theory of positive
emotions. American psychologist, 56(3), 218-226.
Gandelman, N., & Porzecanski, R. (2013). Happiness inequality: How much is reasonable? Social Indicators Research, 110(1),
257-269.
Goff, L., Helliwell, J., & Mayraz, G. (2016). The welfare costs
of well-being inequality. NBER Working Paper 21900.
Graham, C., & Felton, A. (2006). Inequality and happiness:
Insights from Latin America. Journal of Economic Inequality,
4(1), 107-122.
Grover, S., & Helliwell, J. F. (2014). Hows life at home? New
evidence on marriage and the set point for happiness. NBER
Working Paper 20794.
Helliwell, J. F., Barrington-Leigh, C., Harris, A., & Huang, H.
(2010). International evidence on the social context of
well-being. In E. Diener, J. F. Helliwell, & D. Kahneman
(Eds.), International differences in well-being (pp. 291-327).
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Helliwell, J. F., Bonikowska, A. & Shiplett, H. (2016).
Immigration as a test of the set point hypothesis: Evidence
from Immigration to Canada. Unpublished manuscript.
W O R L D H A P P I N E S S R E P O R T 2 0 1 6 | U P D AT E
Huppert, F. A., Marks, N., Clark, A., Siegrist, J., Stutzer, A.,
Vitters, J., & Wahrendorf, M. (2009). Measuring well-being
across Europe: Description of the ESS well-being module and
preliminary findings. Social Indicators Research, 91(3), 301-315.
47
48
W O R L D H A P P I N E S S R E P O R T 2 0 1 6 | U P D AT E
49
Chapter 3
50
W O R L D H A P P I N E S S R E P O R T 2 0 1 6 | U P D AT E
51
43
32
27
51
52
W O R L D H A P P I N E S S R E P O R T 2 0 1 6 | U P D AT E
53
Conclusion
We live in an increasingly irreligious age, but we
have to ensure that it becomes more, and not
less, ethical. So the world needs an ethical
system that is both convincing and inspiring. In
this chapter we offer the principle of the greatest
happiness as one which can inspire and unite
people of all ages from all backgrounds and all
cultures. But to sustain people in living good
lives, we need more than a principle. We need
living organisations in which people meet
regularly for uplift and mutual support. To
create secular organisations of this type is surely
one of the biggest challenges of the 21st century.
54
2 W
IN/Gallup International Global Index of Religiosity and
Atheism (2012), Table 3 gives data comparing 2012 with
2005 for 39 countries. In the majority religiosity had fallen.
In the U.S. for example the proportion who called themselves religious fell from 73% to 60%. Similarly, weekly
U.S. attendance at a place of worship fell from 43% to 36%
(see Gallup Historical Trends www.gallup.com/poll/1690/
religion.aspx ). Cross-sectional evidence within countries
worldwide shows that religious people are on average
poorer, less-educated and older. This may help to explain
the overall downward trend in religious belief. For evidence
on whether religion improves happiness and why, see
Diener et al. (2011).
3 Putnam (2000), p.139.
4 Dalai Lama (2012).
5 S
ee for example McMahon (2006), Bentham (1789), Mill
(1861).
6 J efferson (1809).
7 T
he 18th century writers like Bentham used average
happiness as the sole criterion for evaluating a state of
affairs but we believe that the dispersion of happiness
should also be given (negative) weight. See ODonnell et al.
(2014), Chapter 4.
8 For further discussion, see ODonnell et al. (2014).
9 F
or a similar view, see Dalai Lama (2012).
10 For further discussion, see Layard (2011), Chapter 15.
11 For the idea of the impartial spectator, see Singer (1993).
12 J inpa (2015).
13 See for example Ricard (2015).
14 T
hese have regular gatherings in 68 chapters across 8
countries www.sundayassembly.com .
W O R L D H A P P I N E S S R E P O R T 2 0 1 6 | U P D AT E
REFERENCES
Bentham, J. (1789). An Introduction to the Principles of Morals
and Legislation (1996 ed. J. H. B. a. H. L. A. Hart). Oxford:
Clarendon Press.
Dalai Lama. (2012). Beyond Religion: Ethics for a Whole World:
Houghton Mifflin Harcourt.
Diener, E., Tay, L., & Myers, D. G. (2011). The religion
paradox: if religion makes people happy, why are so many
dropping out? Journal of Personality and Social Psychology,
101(6), 1278-1290.
Jefferson, T. (1809). Letter to the Maryland Republicans: in
The Writings of Thomas Jefferson (1903-1904) Memorial Edition
(Lipscomb and Bergh, editors) 20 Vols., Washington, D.C: ME
16:359.
Jinpa, T. (2015). A Fearless Heart: How the Courage to Be
Compassionate Can Transform Our Lives: Avery Publishing
Group.
Layard, R. (2011). Happiness: lessons from a new science (Second
Edition ed.). London: Penguin.
McMahon, D. (2006). The Pursuit of Happiness: A History from
the Greeks to the present. London: Allen Lane/Penguin.
Mill, J. S. (1861). Utilitarianism (1993 ed. G. Williams).
London: Everyman.
ODonnell, G., Deaton, A., Durand, M., Halpern, D., &
Layard, R. (2014). Wellbeing and policy. London: Legatum
Institute.
Putnam, R. (2000). Bowling Alone: The Collapse and Revival of
American Community. New York: Simon and Schuster.
Ricard, M. (2015). Altruism: The Power of Compassion to Change
Yourself and the World: Little, Brown and Company.
Singer, P. (1993). Practical Ethics (2nd ed.): Cambridge
University Press.
55
Chapter 4
56
Jeffrey D. Sachs, Director of the Earth Institute and the UN Sustainable Development Solutions
Network, Special Advisor to United Nations Secretary-General Ban Ki-moon on the Sustainable
Development Goals
W O R L D H A P P I N E S S R E P O R T 2 0 1 6 | U P D AT E
57
Theories of Happiness
There are of course many competing theories of
human well-being, both secular and religious.
To even describe these theories at any length and
soundness would require a volume or volumes,
not a brief note. Still, at grave risk of trivialization, I would like to argue that various theories
put different relative weights on six dimensions
of happiness.
Mindfulness. Many theories of happiness,
including Buddhism, Aristotelian virtue ethics,
Stoicism, traditional Christian theology, and
Positive Psychology, emphasize the path to
happiness through the cultivation of mindfulness, attitudes, values, habits, dispositions, and
virtues. The emphasis is placed on character,
mindfulness and mental health rather than the
objective circumstances facing the individual,
whether economic, social, or political.
Consumerism. Anglo-American economics has
long emphasized the role of personal income and
market opportunities in enabling individuals to
meet their needs. The emphasis is on the individual
as a rational consumer, acting to maximize
individual utility (or material preferences) subject
to a budget constraint. Easing the consumer
budget constraint (that is, raising income) is the
key to raising well-being in this view.
Economic freedom. For Mill, Nietzsche, Rand,
Hayek, and Nozick in their very different and
distinctive ways, happiness is achieved through
personal freedom of action. In the extreme
modern form, Libertarianism places liberty as
the Summum Bonum, and as the key to social
organization through a minimal state.
58
W O R L D H A P P I N E S S R E P O R T 2 0 1 6 | U P D AT E
Laudato Si
Pope Francis issued an encyclical Laudato Si to
to enter into a dialogue with all people, Catholics and non-Catholics, about our common
home.14 In this encyclical, Pope Francis unravels
the mystery of a world that enjoys unprecedented
technological prowess and yet is beset by profound and growing anxieties, pervasive marginalization of the vulnerable (such as migrants and
those caught in human trafficking), fear of the
future, and environmental destruction.
59
60
holistic approach to economy, society, and environment emphasized by Francis. The agenda is
bold, multi-dimensional, and universal in coverage, meaning that all nations have agreed to
participate so that no one is left behind.
Here is what the nations mean by sustainable
development:
We resolve, between now and 2030, to end
poverty and hunger everywhere; to reduce
ill health, physical and mental; to combat
inequalities within and among countries; to
build peaceful, just and inclusive societies;
to protect human rights and promote gender
equality and the empowerment of women
and girls; and to ensure the lasting protection
of the planet and its natural resources. We
resolve also to create conditions for sustainable,
inclusive and sustained economic growth,
shared prosperity and decent work for all,
taking into account different levels of national
development and capacities.22
W O R L D H A P P I N E S S R E P O R T 2 0 1 6 | U P D AT E
61
The SDG Index aims to measure SDG achievement across the 17 goals, using currently available national cross-country data. For each goal,
one or more cross-country indicators are selected and averaged to produce one sub-index per
SDG. In turn, the 17 sub-indexes are then
aggregated to produce an overall measure of
SDG achievement. In this paper we aggregate
Cantril
Ladder (2)
Cantril
Ladder (3)
Cantril
Ladder (4)
Cantril
Ladder (5)
0.051 ***
(13.46)
0.029 ***
(5.22)
0.019 **
(2.62)
1.267 ***
(13.31)
0.705 ***
(4.21)
0.115
(0.57)
0.069 ***
(8.18)
-0.001
(-0.06)
0.009
(0.92)
LGDPpc
(GDP per capita)
0.488 ***
(4.05)
Unemployment Rate
(IEF Data Set)
-0.037 ***
(-3.67)
Adjusted R-squared
0.604
0.599
0.359
0.67
0.735
119
119
119
119
109
Notes: t-statistics are reported in parentheses. ***, **, and * indicate significance at the 1, 5 and 10 percent levels respectively.
62
W O R L D H A P P I N E S S R E P O R T 2 0 1 6 | U P D AT E
63
Data Annex
2. Machiavelli (1513).
All variables are for the most recent years. They are taken
from the following sources:
3. Bentham (1789).
4. Rawls (1971).
5. Nozick (1974).
6. World Happiness Reports (2013, 2015, 2016).
7. Aristotle (1902).
8. Aristotle (1902).
9. Aristotle (1902).
10. Aristotle (1902).
11. Pope Francis, 13. (2015).
12. Pope Francis, 164. (2015).
13. Transforming our world: the 2030 Agenda for Sustainable
Development.
14. Pope Francis (2015).
15. Pope Francis, 123. (2015).
16. Pope Francis, 110. (2015).
17. Pope Francis, 112. (2015).
18. Pope Francis, 113. (2015).
19. Pope Francis, 156. (2015).
20. Pope Paul VI (1967).
21. Pope Francis, 128. (2015).
22. 2030 Agenda for Sustainable Development.
23. Transforming our world: the 2030 Agenda for Sustainable
Development.
24. Helliwell, et al. (2016).
25. Helliwell, et al. (2016).
64
W O R L D H A P P I N E S S R E P O R T 2 0 1 6 | U P D AT E
References
Aristotle, Jowett, B., & Davis, H. W. C. (1920).
Aristotles Politics. Oxford: At the Clarendon Press.
Bentham, J. (1789). An Introduction to the
Principles of Morals and Legislation. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Helliwell, J. F., Huang, H., & Wang, S. (2015). The Geography
of World Happiness. In World Happiness Report 2015.
New York: Sustainable Development Solutions Network.
http://worldhappiness.report/download/
Helliwell, J. F., Huang, H., & Wang, S. (2016). The Distribution
of World Happiness. In World Happiness Report 2016 Update
(Vol. I). New York: Sustainable Development Solutions
Network. http://worldhappiness.report/download/
Helliwell, J. F., & Wang, S. (2013). World Happiness: Trends,
Explanations and Distribution. In World Happiness Report 2013.
New York: Sustainable Development Solutions Network.
http://unsdsn.org/wp-content/uploads/2014/02/WorldHappinessReport2013_online.pdf
Index of Economic Freedom (2016). The Wall Street Journal and
The Heritage Foundation. http://www.heritage.org/index/about
Machiavelli, N. (1513). The Prince.
Nozick, R. (1974). Anarchy, State, and Utopia. New York:
Basic Books.
Pope Francis. (2015). Laudato Si. https://laudatosi.com/watch
Pope Paul. (1967). Populorum Progressio.
Encyclical of Pope Paul VI On The Development of Peoples.
http://w2.vatican.va/content/paul-vi/en/encyclicals/documents/hf_p-vi_enc_26031967_populorum.html
Rawls, J. (1971). A Theory of Justice. Cambridge, Mass:
Belknap Press.
The Global Competitiveness Report (2015-6).
The World Economic Forum. http://reports.weforum.org/
global-competitiveness-report-2015-2016/
Sustainable Development Solutions Network (2016). Preliminary Sustainable Development Goal (SDG) Index and Dashboard. http://unsdsn.org/resources/publications/sdg-index/
65
SDSN
The Sustainable Development Solutions Network (SDSN) engages scientists, engineers, business and
civil society leaders, and development practitioners for evidence based problem solving. It promotes
solutions initiatives that demonstrate the potential of technical and business innovation to support
sustainable development (www.unsdsn.org).
Sustainable Development Solutions Network
314 Low Library
535 W 116th Street
New York, NY 10027
USA