Ang 2006
Ang 2006
Ang 2006
Andrew Ang
Columbia University and NBER
Joseph Chen
University of Southern California
Economists have long recognized that investors care differently about downside
losses versus upside gains. Agents who place greater weight on downside risk demand
additional compensation for holding stocks with high sensitivities to downside market movements. We show that the cross section of stock returns reflects a downside
risk premium of approximately 6% per annum. Stocks that covary strongly with the
market during market declines have high average returns. The reward for beasring
downside risk is not simply compensation for regular market beta, nor is it explained
by coskewness or liquidity risk, or by size, value, and momentum characteristics.
(JEL C12, C15, C32, G12)
Portions of this manuscript previously circulated in an earlier article titled Downside Correlation and
Expected Stock Returns. The authors thank Enrique Arzuc Brad Barber, Geert Bekaert, Alon Brav,
John Cochrane, Randy Cohen, Qiang Dai, Kent Daniel, Bob Dittmar, Rob Engle, Wayne Ferson, Eric
Ghysels, John Heaton, David Hirschleifer, N. Jegadeesh, Gautam Kaul, Jonathan Lewellen, Qing Li,
ubos Pastor, Adam Reed, Akhtar Siddique, Rob Stambaugh, and
Terence Lim, Toby Moskowitz, L
Zhenyu Wang. We especially thank Cam Harvey (the editor) and Bob Hodrick for detailed comments.
We also thank two anonymous referees whose comments greatly improved the article. We thank seminar
participants at Columbia University, Koc University, London Business School, London School of
Economics, Morgan Stanley, NYU, PanAgora Asset Management, UNC, USC, the American Finance
Association, the Canadian Investment Review Risk Management Conference, the Conference on Financial Market Risk Premiums at the Federal Reserve Board, the European Finance Association, the Five
Star Conference, an Inquire Europe meeting, a LA Society of Financial Analysts meeting, an NBER
Asset Pricing meeting, a Q-Group meeting, the Texas Finance Festival, the Valuation in Financial
Markets Conference at UC Davis, and the Western Finance Association for helpful discussions. The
authors acknowledge funding from a Q-Group research grant. Address correspondence to Andrew Ang,
Columbia Business School, New York NY 10027 or e-mail: aa610@columbia.edu.
The Author 2006. Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of The Society for Financial Studies. All rights
reserved. For permissions, please email: journals.permissions@oxfordjournals.org.
doi:10.1093/rfs/hhj035
Advance Access publication March 2, 2006
Yuhang Xing
Rice University
Pettengill, Sundaram, and Mathur (1995) and Isakov (1999) estimate the CAPM by splitting the full
sample into two subsamples that consist of observations where the realized excess market return is
positive or negative. Naturally, they estimate a positive (negative) market premium for the subsample
with positive (negative) excess market returns. In contrast, our approach examines premiums for asymmetries in the factor loadings, rather than estimating factor models on different subsamples. Price, Price,
and Nantell (1982) demonstrate that skewness in U.S. equity returns causes downside betas to be different
from unconditional betas but do not relate downside betas to average stock returns.
1192
Downside Risk
1193
Our strategy for finding a premium for bearing downside risk in the
cross section is as follows. First, we directly show at the individual stock
level that stocks with higher downside betas contemporaneously have
higher average returns. Second, we claim that downside beta is a risk
attribute because stocks that have high covariation with the market when
the market declines exhibit high average returns over the same period.
This contemporaneous relationship between factor loadings and risk
premia is the foundation of a cross-sectional risk-return relationship,
and has been exploited from the earliest tests of the CAPM [see, among
others, Black, Jensen, and Scholes (1972) and Gibbons (1982)]. More
recently, Fama and French (1992) also seek, but fail to find, a relationship
between postformation market betas from an unconditional CAPM and
realized average stock returns over the same period. Our study differs
from these earlier tests by examining a series of short one-year samples
using daily data, rather than a single long sample using monthly data.
This strategy provides greater statistical power in an environment where
betas may be time-varying [see comments by Ang and Chen (2005) and
Lewellen and Nagel (2005)].
Third, we differentiate the reward for holding high downside-risk stocks
from other known cross-sectional effects. In particular, Rubinstein (1973),
Friend and Westerfield (1980), Kraus and Litzenberger (1976, 1983), and
Harvey and Siddique (2000) show that agents dislike stocks with negative
coskewness, so that stocks with low coskewness tend to have high average
returns. Downside risk is different from coskewness risk because downside
beta explicitly conditions for market downside movements in a nonlinear
fashion, whereras the coskewness statistic does not explicitly emphasize
asymmetries across down and up markets, even in settings where coskewness
may vary over time [as in Harvey and Siddique (1999)]. Since coskewness
captures some aspects of downside covariation, we are especially careful to
control for coskewness risk in assessing the premium for downside beta. We
also control for the standard list of known cross-sectional effects, including
size and book-to-market factor loadings and characteristics [Fama and
French (1993) and Daniel and Titman (1997)], liquidity risk factor loadings
[Pastor and Stambaugh (2003)], and past return characteristics [Jegadeesh
and Titman (1993)]. Controlling for these and other cross-sectional effects,
we estimate that the cross-sectional premium is approximately 6% per
annum.
Finally, we check if past downside betas predict future expected returns.
We find that, for the majority of the cross section, high past downside beta
predicts high future returns over the next month, similar to the contemporaneous relationship between realized downside beta and realized average
returns. However, this relation breaks down among stocks with very high
volatility. We attribute this to two effects. First, the future downside covariation of very volatile stocks is difficult to predict using past betasthe
While standard power, or CRRA, utility also produces aversion to downside risk, the order of magnitude
of a downside risk premium, relative to upside potential, is economically negligible because CRRA
preferences are locally mean-variance.
1194
Downside Risk
Outcomes above (below) the certainty equivalent W are termed elating (disappointing) outcomes. If 0 < A < 1, then the utility function
(1) down-weights elating outcomes relative to disappointing outcomes.
Put another way, the disappointment-averse investor cares more about
downside versus upside risk. If A 1, disappointment utility reduces to
the special case of standard CRRA utility, which is closely approximated
by mean-variance utility.
To illustrate the effect of downside risk on the cross section of stock
returns, we work with two assets x and y. Asset x has three possible
payoffs ux , mx and dx , and asset y has two possible payoffs uy and dy .
These payoffs are in excess of the risk-free payoff. Our setup has the
minimum number of assets and states required to examine cross-sectional
1195
pricing (the expected returns of x and y relative to each other and to the
market portfolio, which consists of x and y), and to incorporate higher
moments (through the three states of x). The full set of payoffs and states
is given by:
Probability
ux ; uy
mx ; uy
dx ; uy
ux ; dy
mx ; dy
dx ; dy
p1
p2
p3
p4
p5
p6
1196
Payoff
Downside Risk
expected returns increase with , but does not fully reflect all risk. This
is because the representative agent cares in particular about downside
risk, through A < 1. Hence, measures of downside risk have explanatory
power for describing the cross section of expected returns. One measure
of downside risk introduced by Bawa and Lindenberg (1977) is the downside beta (denoted by ):
coskew
Eri i rm m 2
p
;
varri varrm
1197
0.038
0.14
0.036
0.13
0.034
Relations
in
CAPM Alpha
Mean Return
0.12
0.11
0.032
v ersion
Cross-Sectional
0.03
0.1
0.028
0.09
0.026
1.1
1.2
1.3
1.4
1.5
Downside Beta
1.6
1.7
1.8
1.1
1.4
1.5
Downside Beta
1.6
1.7
1.8
0.036
0.036
0.034
CAPM Alpha
0.034
CAPM Alpha
1.3
0.038
0.038
0.032
0.03
0.032
0.03
0.028
0.028
0.026
0.026
0.024
0.024
0.5
0.55
0.6
0.65
0.7
0.75
0.8
0.85
0.9
0.95
0.36
0.038
0.34
0.32
0.3
0.28
Coskew
0.26
0.24
0.22
0.038
0.036
0.036
0.034
0.034
CAPM Alpha
CAPM Alpha
1.2
0.032
0.03
0.032
0.03
0.028
0.028
0.026
0.026
0.024
0.024
1.08
1.09
1.1
1.11
1.12
1.13 1.14
+
1.15
1.16
1.17
1.18
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
+
0.5
0.6
0.7
Figure 1
Risk-Return Relations in a Disappointment Aversion Cross-Sectional Equilibrium
This figure shows risk-return relations for an asset in the DA cross-sectional equilibrium. In the top row
we have (i) a plot of the assets mean excess return versus downside beta , and (ii) a plot of the assets
CAPM alpha versus downside beta ; in the second row, (iii) a plot of the assets CAPM alpha versus
relative downside beta, , and (iv) a plot of the assets CAPM alpha versus coskewness; and in the
bottom row, (v) a plot of the assets CAPM alpha versus relative upside beta, , and (vi) a plot of
the assets CAPM alpha versus .
1198
0.024
0.08
Downside Risk
Regular, downside, and upside betas are, by construction, not independent of each other. To differentiate the effect of upside risk from downside risk, we introduce two additional measures. Similar to relative
3
Taylor expansions have been used to account for potential skewness and kurtosis preferences in asset
allocation problems by Guidolin and Timmerman (2002), Harvey, Liechty, Liechty, and Muller (2003),
and Jondeau and Rockinger (2006).
1199
The Taylor expansion in Equation (8) is necessarily only an approximation. In particular, since the DA utility function is kinked, polynomial
expansions of U, such as the expansions used by Bansal, Hsieh, and
Viswanathan (1993), may not be good global approximations if the
kink is large (or A is very small).3 Nevertheless, measures like coskewness
based on the Taylor approximation for the utility function should also
have some explanatory power for returns.
Downside beta and coskewness may potentially capture different
effects. Note that, for DA utility, both downside beta and coskewness
are approximations, because the utility function does not have an explicit
form [Equation (1) implicitly defines DA utility]. Since DA utility is
kinked at an endogenous certainty equivalent, skewness and other centered moments may not effectively capture aversion to risk across upside
and downside movements in all situations. This is because they are based
on unconditional approximations to a nonsmooth function. In contrast,
the downside beta in Equation (5) conditions directly on a downside event
that the market return is less than its unconditional mean. In Figure 1,
our model shows that more negative coskewness is compensated by
higher expected returns. However, the Appendix describes a case where
CAPM alphas may increase as coskewness increases, which is the opposite of the relation predicted by the Taylor expansion.
With DA utility, a representative agent is willing to hold stocks with
high upside potential at a discount, all else being equal. A stock with high
upside potential relative to downside risk tends to pay off more when an
investors wealth is already high. Such stocks are not as desirable as
stocks that pay off when the market decreases. Consider two stocks
with the same downside beta, but with different payoffs in up markets.
The stock that covaries more with the market when the market rises has a
larger payoff when the market return is high. This stock does not need as
high an expected return in order for the representative agent to hold it.
Thus, there is a discount for stocks with high upside potential. To measure upside risk, we compute an upside beta (denoted by ) that takes
the same form as Equation (5), except we condition on movements of the
market excess return above its average value:
1200
Downside Risk
1201
example, the CAPM implies that stocks that covary strongly with the
market have contemporaneously high average returns over the same
period. In particular, the CAPM predicts an increasing relationship
between realized average returns and realized factor loadings, or contemporaneous expected returns and market betas. More generally, a
multifactor model implies that we should observe patterns between
average returns and sensitivities to different sources of risk over the
same time period used to compute the average returns and the factor
sensitivities.
Our research design follows Black, Jensen, and Scholes (1972), Fama
and MacBeth (1973), Fama and French (1992), Jagannathan and Wang
(1996), and others and focuses on the contemporaneous relation
between realized factor loadings and realized average returns. More
recently, in testing factor models, Lettau and Ludvigson (2001), Bansal,
Dittmar, and Lundblad (2005), and Lewellen and Nagel (2005), among
others all employ risk measures that are measured contemporaneously
with returns. While both Black, Jensen, and Scholes (1972) and Fama
and French (1992) form portfolios based on preformation factor loadings, they continue to perform their asset pricing tests using postranking
factor loadings, computed using the full sample. In particular, Fama
and French (1992) first form 25 portfolios ranked on the basis of preformation size and market betas. Then, they compute ex post factor
loadings for these 25 portfolios over the full sample. At each month,
they assign the postformation beta of a stock in a Fama-MacBeth (1973)
cross-sectional regression to be the ex post market factor loading of the
appropriate size and book-to-market sorted portfolio to which that
stock belongs during that month. Hence, testing a factor relation entails
demonstrating a contemporaneous relationship between realized covariance between a stock return and a factor with the realized average
return of that stock.
Our work differs from Fama and MacBeth (1973) and Fama and
French (1992) in one important way. Rather than forming portfolios
based on preformation regression criteria and then examining postformation factor loadings, we directly sort stocks on the realized factor loadings
within a period and then compute realized average returns over the same
period for these portfolios. Whereas preformation factor loadings reflect
both actual variation in factor loadings and measurement error effects,
postformation factor dispersion occurs almost exclusively from the actual
covariation of stock returns with risk factors. Moreover, we estimate
factor loadings using higher frequency data over shorter samples, rather
than lower frequency data over longer samples. Hence, our approach has
greater power.
A number of studies, including Fama and MacBeth (1973), Shanken
(1992), Ferson and Harvey (1991), and Pastor and Stambaugh (2003),
2.1.2 Empirical results. We investigate patterns between realized average returns and realized betas. While many cross-sectional asset pricing
studies use a horizon of one month, we work in intervals of 12 months,
from t to t 12, following Kothari, Shanken, and Sloan (1995). Our
choice of an annual horizon is motivated by two concerns. First, we
need a sufficiently large number of observations to condition on periods
of down markets. One month of daily data provides too short a window
for obtaining reliable estimates of downside variation. We check the
robustness of our results to using intervals of 24 months with weekly
frequency data to compute downside betas. Second, Fama and French
(1997), Ang and Chen (2005), and Lewellen and Nagel (2005) show that
market risk exposures are time-varying. Very long time intervals may
cause the estimates of conditional betas to be noisy. Fama and French
(2005) also advocate estimating betas using an annual horizon.
Over every 12-month period, we compute the sample counterparts to
various risk measures using daily data. We calculate a stocks regular
beta, downside beta as described in Equation (5), and upside beta as
described in Equation (9). We also compute a stocks relative downside
beta, , a stocks relative upside beta, , and the difference
between upside beta and downside beta, . Since these risk measures are calculated using realized returns, we refer to them as realized ,
realized , realized , realized relative , realized relative , and
realized .
In our empirical work, we concentrate on presenting the results of
equal-weighted portfolios and equal-weighted Fama-MacBeth (1973)
regressions. While a relationship between factor sensitivities and returns
should hold for both an average stock (equal weighting) or an average
dollar (value weighting), we focus on computing equal-weighted portfolios, because past work on examining nonlinearities in the cross section
has found risk due to asymmetries to be bigger among smaller stocks. For
1202
compute predictive betas formed using conditional information available at time t and then examine returns over the next period. These
studies implicitly assume that risk exposures are constant and not timevarying. Indeed, as noted by Daniel and Titman (1997), in settings
where the covariance matrix is stable over time, preformation factor
loadings are good instruments for the future expected (postformation)
factor loadings. If preformation betas are weak predictors of future
betas, then using preformation betas as instruments will also have low
power to detect ex post covariation between factor loadings and realized returns. We examine the relation between preformation estimates
of factor loadings with postformation realized factor loadings in
Section 3.
Downside Risk
In their article, Harvey and Siddique (2000) state that they use value-weighted portfolios. From personal
correspondence with Cam Harvey, the coskewness effects arise most strongly in equal-weighted portfolios
rather than in value-weighted portfolios.
The theoretical number of lags required to absorb all the moving average error effects is 11, but we
include an additional lag for robustness.
1203
Table 1
Returns of Stocks Sorted by Realized Factor Loadings
Panel A: Stocks sorted by realized b
Return
1 Low
2
3
4
5 High
3.52%
6.07%
7.58%
9.48%
13.95%
0.28
0.59
0.82
1.10
1.64
0.36
0.67
0.90
1.18
1.72
High-low
t-stat
10.43%
[4.98]
1.36
1.36
Return
0.19
0.51
0.77
1.06
1.63
1 Low
2
3
4
5 High
2.71%
5.62%
7.63%
10.16%
14.49%
0.40
0.63
0.83
1.06
1.49
0.19
0.61
0.89
1.23
1.92
0.42
0.62
0.79
0.99
1.34
1.44
High-low
t-stat
11.78%
[6.16]
1.09
1.72
0.92
Return
1 Low relative
2
3
4
5 High relative
4.09%
7.69%
8.53%
9.56%
10.73%
0.98
0.83
0.80
0.84
0.98
0.56
0.73
0.86
1.08
1.60
1.12
0.84
0.75
0.72
0.71
High-low
t-stat
6.64%
[7.70]
0.00
1.04
0:41
Portfolio
Return
1 Low
2
3
4
5 High
5.73%
7.42%
8.29%
9.33%
9.83%
0.44
0.62
0.82
1.05
1.49
0.63
0.73
0.90
1.10
1.46
0:04
0.45
0.76
1.12
1.85
High-low
t-stat
4.11%
[2.62]
1.05
0.83
1.89
Portfolio
Return
0.91
0.82
0.81
0.85
1.03
1.19
0.95
0.88
0.87
0.95
0.25
0.58
0.76
0.99
1.56
1 Low
2
3
4
5 High
11.35%
9.83%
8.53%
7.35%
3.55%
0.12
0:23
1.31
High-low
t-stat
7:81%
[9.03]
Portfolio
Return
1 Low relative
2
3
4
5 High relative
10.48%
9.51%
8.53%
7.72%
4.37%
High-low
t-stat
6:11%
[9.02]
Portfolio
Portfolio
0.94
0.83
0.80
0.84
1.02
1.45
1.03
0.87
0.78
0.70
0.37
0.62
0.75
0.95
1.46
0.08
0:75
1.08
This table lists the equal-weighted average returns and risk characteristics of stocks sorted by realized
betas. For each month, we calculate ; ; , relative (given by ), relative (given by
), and with respect to the market of all stocks listed on the NYSE using daily continuously compounded returns over the next 12 months. For each risk characteristic, we rank stocks into
quintiles (15) and form equal-weighted portfolios at the beginning of each 12-month period. The
number of stocks in each portfolio varies across time from 216 to 317 stocks. The column labeled
Return reports the average return in excess of the one-month Treasury-bill rate over the next 12
months (which is the same period as the period used to compute ; , and ). The row labeled Highlow reports the difference between the returns of portfolio 5 and portfolio 1. The entry labeled t-stat in
square brackets is the t-statistic computed using Newey-West (1987a) heteroskedastic-robust standard
errors with 12 lags for the High-low difference. The columns labeled , and report the timeseries and cross-sectional average of equal-weighted individual stock betas over the 12-month holding
period. The sample period is from July 1963 to December 2001, with the last 12-month period from
January 2001 to December 2001, and observations are at a monthly frequency.
1204
Portfolio
Downside Risk
1205
the reward for unconditional market risk into downside and upside
components.
Panel B shows that stocks with high contemporaneous have high
average returns. Stocks in the quintile with the lowest (highest) earn
2.7% (14.5%) per annum in excess of the risk-free rate. The average
difference between quintile portfolios 1 and 5 is 11.8% per annum,
which is statistically significant at the 1% level. These results are consistent with agents disliking downside risk and avoiding stocks that covary
strongly when the market dips, such as the DA representative agent
described in Section 1. Stocks with high must carry a premium in
order to entice agents to hold them. An alternative explanation is that
agents have no particular emphasis on downside risk versus upside
potential. High stocks may earn high returns simply because, by
construction, high stocks have high regular . The average spread
between quintile portfolios 1 and 5 is very large (0.19 to 1.92), but sorting
on also produces variation in and . However, the variation in
or is not as disperse as the variation in . Another possible explanation is that sorting on high contemporaneous covariance with the market
mechanically produces high contemporaneous returns. However, this
concern is not applicable to our downside risk measure, since we are
picking out precisely those observations for which stocks already have
very low returns when the market declines. In Panels C and D, we
demonstrate that it is the reward for downside risk alone that is behind
the pattern of high stocks earning high returns.
In panel C of Table 1, we sort stocks by realized relative downside beta
. Relative downside beta focuses on the incremental impact of
downside beta over the regular, unconditional market beta. Panel C
shows that stocks with high realized relative have high average
returns. The difference in average excess returns between portfolios 5
and 1 is 6.6% per annum and is highly significant with a robust t-statistic
of 7.70. We can rule out that this pattern of returns is attributable to
regular beta because the loadings are flat over portfolios 1 to 5. Hence,
the high realized returns from high relative are produced by the
exposure to downside risk, measured by high loadings.
Panel D shows a smaller spread for average realized excess returns for
stocks sorted on realized , relative to the spreads for and in panels
A and B. Since only measures exposure to a rising market, stocks that
rise more when the market return increases should be more attractive
and, on average, earn low returns. We do not observe a discount for
stocks that have attractive upside exposure. We find that low (high)
stocks earn, on average, 5.7% (9.8%) per annum in excess of the risk-free
rate. This pattern of high returns to high loadings seems to be
inconsistent with agents having strong preferences for upside potential;
however, this measure does not control for the effects of regular or for
1206
Downside Risk
Eri i rm m 3
cokurt p
;
varri varrm 3=2
10
where ri is the firm excess return, rm is the market excess return, i is the
average excess stock return, and m is the average market excess returns.
Finally, we also include the Pastor and Stambaugh (2003) historical
liquidity beta at time t to proxy for liquidity exposure.
1207
Table 2
Fama-MacBeth Regressions
Model
Intercept
Bk-Mkt
Past Ret
Std Dev
Coskewness
Cokurtosis
L
II
III
IV
VI
0.300
[9.35]
0.177
[8.19]
0.044
[3.39]
0.054
[1.66]
0.046
[1.42]
0.246
[7.62]
0.257
[7.79]
0.069
[7.17]
0:029
[4.85]
0:039
[8.82]
0.017
[3.87]
0.017
[1.91]
8:433
[10.7]
0:229
[10.7]
0.015
[1.57]
0.064
[7.44]
0:025
[4.15]
0:007
[1.47]
0.024
[5.17]
0.063
[6.32]
0.028
[2.68]
0.003
[0.22]
0:013
[3.03]
0.023
[5.03]
0.053
[5.40]
0:181
[4.31]
0.062
[6.00]
0.020
[2.33]
0:034
[7.77]
0.017
[3.67]
0.020
[2.12]
5:781
[6.41]
0:196
[5.07]
0.045
[4.40]
0.056
[5.25]
0.017
[1.91]
0:034
[7.39]
0.018
[3.76]
0.015
[1.50]
6:459
[7.04]
0:188
[4.59]
0.047
[4.52]
0:008
[0.93]
Mean
(Std Dev)
0.828
(0.550)
0.882
(0.739)
0.722
(0.842)
5.614
(1.523)
0.768
(0.700)
0.085
(0.370)
0.355
(0.174)
0.179
(0.188)
2.240
(1.353)
0.166
(0.456)
This table shows the results of Fama-MacBeth (1973) regressions of 12-month excess returns on firm
characteristics and realized-risk characteristics. The sample period is from July 1963 to December 2001,
with the last 12-month period from January 2001 to December 2001, and observations are at a monthly
frequency (451 months) for all stocks listed on the NYSE. For regression VI, the sample period is from
January 1967 to December 2001 (397 months). The number of stocks in each regression varies across time
from 1080 to 1582 stocks. The t-statistics in square brackets are computed using Newey-West (1987a)
heteroskedastic-robust standard errors with 12 lags. The firm characteristics are log of market capitalizations (Log-Size), book-to-market ratios (Bk-mkt), and past 12-month excess returns (Past ret),
all computed at the beginning of each period. The realized risk characteristics are ; ; , standard
deviations (Std Dev), coskewness and cokurtosis are all calculated over the following 12-month period
using daily continuously compounded returns. We also include the Pastor-Stambaugh (2003) liquidity
beta, L , for January 1967 to January 2001. All independent variables are Winsorized at the 1% level and
at the 99% within each month. We report time-series averages of the cross-sectional mean and standard
deviation (in parentheses) of each independent variable in the last column.
For example, if an observation for the firms book-to-market ratio is extremely large and above the 99th
percentile of all the firms book-to-market ratios that month, we replace that firms book-to-market ratio
with the book-to-market ratio corresponding to the 99th percentile. The same is done for firms whose
book-to-market ratios lie below the 1%-tile of all firms book-to-market ratios that month.
1208
Log-size
Downside Risk
By construction, is a weighted average of and . If we place both and on the right-hand side
of regressions IIVI and omit , the coefficients on are the same to three decimal places as the
coefficients reported in Table 2. Similarly, if we specify both and to be regressors, the coefficients on
are almost unchanged.
1209
1210
Downside Risk
firm characteristics and risk characteristics, including upside beta. Moreover, downside beta risk remains significantly positive in the presence of
coskewness risk controls. On the other hand, the reward for upside risk
( ) is fragile. A priori, we expect the coefficient on to be negative,
but in data, it often flips sign and is insignificant when we control for
other cross-sectional risk attributes. Thus, aversion to downside risk is
priced more strongly, and more robustly, in the cross section than
investors attraction to upside potential.
1211
Table 3
Returns of Stocks Sorted by Realized Downside Beta and Coskewness
Panel A: b Sorts controlling for coskewness
Coskewness Quintiles
Portfolio
5 High
Average
1 Low
2
3
4
5 High
7.21%
10.55%
13.63%
15.63%
21.84%
5.74%
8.40%
11.30%
12.82%
15.85%
4.03%
6.94%
8.30%
9.35%
11.51%
3.40%
5.59%
6.08%
6.74%
6.81%
0.22%
2.61%
3.76%
2.56%
2.32%
4.21%
6.82%
8.61%
9.42%
11.67%
High-low
t-stat
14.64%
[5.62]
10.11%
[5.22]
7.48%
[3.91]
3.41%
[1.87]
2.10%
[1.32]
7.55%
[4.16]
5 High
Average
Quintiles
Portfolio
1 Low coskew
2
3
4
5 High coskew
High-low
t-stat
1 Low
4.69%
4.17%
2.74%
1.50%
0.41%
7.15%
6.19%
6.51%
5.24%
2.96%
9.30%
9.61%
8.68%
6.68%
3.86%
12.59%
12.33%
11.31%
9.16%
5.37%
17.61%
18.21%
16.07%
12.83%
7.65%
10.27%
10.10%
9.06%
7.08%
4.05%
4:28%
[4.23]
4:18%
[5.64]
5:45%
[7.12]
7:22%
[8.09]
9:96%
[7.94]
6:22%
[8.17]
This table examines the relation between and coskewness. For each month, we compute and
coskewness with respect to the market of all stocks listed on the NYSE using daily continuously
compounded returns over the next 12 months. In panel A, we first rank stocks into quintiles (15) at
the beginning of each 12-month period based on coskewness over the next 12 months. Then, we rank
stocks within each first-sort quintile into additional quintiles according to computed over the next 12
months. For each 5 5 grouping, we form an equal-weighted portfolio. In panel B, we reverse the order
so that we first sort on and then on coskewness. The sample period is from July 1963 to December
2001, and the number of stocks in each portfolio varies across time from 43 to 64 stocks. We report the
average return in excess of the one-month Treasury bill rate over the next 12 months. For the column
labeled Average, we report the average return of stocks in each second-sort quintile. This controls for
coskewness in panel A (B). The row labeled High-low reports the difference between the returns of
portfolio 1 and portfolio 5. The entry labeled t-stat in square brackets is the t-statistic computed using
Newey-West (1987a) heteroskedastic-robust standard errors with 12 lags for the High-low difference.
the low and high quintiles is 14.6% per annum. The average return
difference in the low and high portfolios decreases to 2.1% per annum
for the quintile of stocks with the highest coskewness.
The reason for this pattern is as follows. As defined in Equation (6),
coskewness is effectively the covariance of a stocks return with the square
of the market return, or with the volatility of the market. A stock with
negative coskewness tends to have low returns when market volatility is
high. These are also usually, but not always, periods of low market
returns. Volatility of the market treats upside and downside risk symmetrically, so both extreme upside and extreme downside movements of the
market have the same volatility. Hence, the prices of stocks with large
1212
1 Low
Downside Risk
1213
negative coskewness tend to decrease when the market falls, but the prices
of these stocks may also decrease when the market rises. In contrast,
downside beta concentrates only on the former effect by explicitly considering only the downside case. When coskewness is low, there is a wide
spread in because there is large scope for market volatility to represent
both large negative and large positive changes. This explains the large
spread in average returns across the quintiles for stocks with low
coskewness.
The small 2.1% per annum 51 spread for the quintiles for the
highest coskewness stocks is due to the highest coskewness stocks exhibiting little asymmetry. The distribution of coskewness across stocks is
skewed towards the negative side and is negative on average. Across the
low to the high coskewness quintiles in panel A, the average coskewness
ranges from 0.41 to 0.09. Hence, the quintile of the highest coskewness
stocks have little coskewness. This means that high coskewness stocks
essentially do not change their behavior across periods where market
returns are stable or volatile. Furthermore, the range of in the highest
coskewness quintile is also smaller. The small range of for the highest
coskewness stocks explains the low 2.1% spread for the quintiles in
the second last column of panel A.
Panel B of Table 3 repeats the same exercise as panel A, except we
examine the reward for coskewness controlling for different levels of .
Panel B first sorts stocks on coskewness before sorting on , and then
averages across the quintiles. This exercise examines the coskewness
premium controlling for downside exposure. Controlling for , the 51
difference in average returns for coskewness portfolios is 6.2%, which is
highly statistically significant with a t-statistic of 8.17. Moreover, there
are large and highly statistically significant spreads for coskewness in
every quintile. Coskewness is able to maintain a high range within
each portfolio, unlike the diminishing range for within each
coskewness quintile in Panel A.
In summary, downside beta risk and coskewness risk are different. The
high returns to high stocks are robust to controlling for coskewness
risk and vice versa. Downside beta risk is strongest for stocks with low
coskewness. Coskewness does not differentiate between large market
movements on the upside or the downside. For stocks with low coskewness, downside beta is better able to capture the downside risk premium
associated only with market declines than an unconditional coskewness
measure.
rf
and
rf
11
We define downside and upside beta relative to the zero rate of return as:
0
and
0
12
1214
Downside Risk
Table 4
Correlations of Beta Measures
rf
z
rf
z
rf
0
rf
0
1.000
0.779
1.000
0.770
0.971
1.000
0.762
0.967
0.990
1.000
0.760
0.464
0.447
0.447
1.000
0.769
0.444
0.467
0.461
0.972
1.000
0.776
0.439
0.452
0.464
0.969
0.991
1.000
In addition, we conduct further robustness checks that are available upon request. In particular, to
control for the influence of nonsynchronous trading, we also repeat our exercise using control for
nonsynchronous trading in a manner analogous to using a Scholes-Williams (1977) correction to compute
the downside betas. Although this method is ad hoc, using this correction does not change our results. We
also find that the point estimates of the premiums are almost unchanged when we exclude stocks that fall
into the highest volatility quintile, but statistical significance increases dramatically.
1215
This table reports the time-series averages of cross-sectional correlations of various risk characteristics for
stocks listed on the NYSE. The risk characteristics are regular beta , downside beta , downside
beta defined relative to the risk-free rate rf ), downside beta defined relative to a zero return 0 ,
upside beta , upside beta relative to the risk-free rate rf , and upside beta relative to a zero return
0 . The regular downside and upside beta, and , respectively, are calculated relative to the
sample mean market return. All risk characteristics are computed using daily returns over the past 12
months. The sample period is from July 1963 to December 2001, with the last 12-month period from
January 2001 to December 2001. There are a total of 451 observations at a monthly frequency.
Table 5
Robustness Checks of Realized Downside Beta Portfolios
Portfolio
Exclude small
Two-year weekly
Value-weighted
All stocks
Nonoverlapping
4.48%
6.25%
7.69%
10.33%
12.81%
7.08%
12.54%
16.86%
21.34%
29.35%
2.62%
4.23%
6.04%
9.32%
9.76%
4.14%
7.23%
8.84%
11.35%
19.37%
3.69%
5.74%
8.33%
10.68%
16.15%
High-low
t-stat
8.34%
[4.54]
22.27%
[4.96]
7.14%
[3.30]
15.24%
[5.57]
12.46%
[3.51]
5.07%
8.01%
8.66%
9.44%
10.37%
11.46%
15.78%
18.06%
20.48%
21.37%
3.19%
6.86%
7.07%
7.56%
7.18%
5.58%
8.66%
9.41%
10.86%
14.21%
5.67%
8.78%
8.42%
9.67%
12.05%
High-low
t-stat
5.30%
[6.46]
9.91%
[4.29]
3.99%
[3.06]
8.63%
[7.02]
6.38%
[3.87]
We perform robustness checks of the results in Table 1. For each month, we calculate and relative
using weekly (Wednesday to Tuesday) continuously compounded returns over each 24-month period or
daily continuously compounded returns over each 12-month period. We report the results using realized
in panel A and the results using realized relative (given by ) in panel B. For each risk
characteristic, we rank stocks into quintiles (15). In the first column of each panel, we form equalweighted portfolios among NYSE stocks, but exclude stocks that fall in the lowest size quintile. In the
second column, we form equal-weighted portfolios among NYSE stocks formed by ranking on or
computed using two years of weekly data. In the third column of each panel, we form valueweighted portfolios using stocks listed on the NYSE at the beginning of each 12-month period. In the
fourth column, we use all stocks listed on the NYSE, AMEX, and NASDAQ and form equal-weighted
portfolios at the beginning of each period, using quintile breakpoints based on NYSE stocks. In the last
column, we compute the risk characteristics using stocks listed on the NYSE and form equal-weighted
portfolios at the beginning of each January using nonoverlapping 12-month horizon observations. We
report the average return in excess of the one-month T-bill rate over the next 12 months. The row labeled
High-low reports the difference between the returns of portfolio 5 and portfolio 1. For the columns
labeled Exclude small, Value-weighted, and All stocks, the sample period is from July 1963 to
December 2001, with the last 12-month period from January 2001 to December 2001, with observations
at a monthly frequency. For the column labeled Two-year weekly, the sample period is from July 1963
to December 2001, with the last 24-month period spanning January 2000 to December 2001. For the
column labeled Nonoverlapping, the sample period is from January 1964 to December 2001, with the
last 12-month period lasting from January 2001 to December 2001. The number of stocks in each
portfolio varies across time from 216 to 317 stocks, except for All stocks, where it varies from 289
to 2330 stocks. The entry labeled t-stat in square brackets is the t-statistic computed using Newey-West
(1987a) heteroskedastic-robust standard errors with 24 lags for the second column, 1 lag for the last
column, and 12 lags for all other columns for the High-low difference.
removed, the difference between quintiles 5 and 1 for the stocks sorted by
realized remains strongly statistically significant (with a robust t-statistic
of 4.54) at 8.34% per annum, but is slightly reduced from the 51 difference
of 11.8% per annum when small stocks are included in Table 1. Similarly,
the 51 difference in average returns for relative also remains highly
significant.
1216
1 Low
2
3
4
5 High
Downside Risk
10
We have also reproduced the Fama-MacBeth regressions using risk measures calculated at the weekly
frequency and found virtually identical results to Table 2. In addition, when we examine realized betas
and realized returns over a 60-month horizon using monthly frequency returns, we find the same
qualitative patterns that are as statistically significant as using a 12-month horizon.
1217
13
where r
m minrm ; m equals rm if the excess market return is below its
sample mean, or its sample mean otherwise. We estimate the coefficients
bm , bm , bSMB , and bHML by GMM using the moment conditions:
Emr 0;
1218
14
but we have fewer observations. Nevertheless, the results show that the
point estimates of the 51 spreads are still statistically significant at the 1%
level. Not surprisingly, the point estimates remain roughly unchanged
from Table 1.
In unreported results, we also conduct additional robustness checks
to value weighting and using all stocks in a Fama-MacBeth regression
setting. First, we run a set of value-weighted Fama-MacBeth regressions to make sure that small stocks are not driving our results. We
do this by running a cross-sectional weighted least squares regression
for each period, where the weights are the market capitalization of a
firm at the beginning of each period. Using value-weighted regressions
continues to produce a strong, statistically significant, positive relation between downside risk and contemporaneous returns with or
without any additional controls. Similar to the results of using all
stocks in the portfolio formations of Table 5, using all stocks in the
Fama-MacBeth regressions only increases the magnitude of the downside risk premium, which remains overwhelmingly statistically significant.
Downside Risk
Table 6
GMM Specification Tests
Linear factor model coefficients
a
bm
bm
bSMB
bHML
J 2 test
Specification I
1.02
5:25
[57.6]
[3.87]
22.84
[2.16]
Specification III
1.08
7:82
[34.5]
[5.21]
Specification IV
1.60
26:97
[7.70]
[3.42]
35.73
[2.56]
0:95
[0.50]
10:24
[4.41]
3:63
[1.52]
11:09
[4.11]
H0 : Spec I
vs H1 : Spec II
3.85
(0.05)
H0 : Spec III
vs H1 : Spec IV
9.49
(0.00)
This table reports GMM estimates and GMM specification tests using the 25 Fama and French (1993)
size and book-to-market sorted portfolios as base assets. Each linear factor model specification takes the
form of Equation (13), with specifications IIII being special cases of Equation (13). In each case, we
estimate the coefficients using the moment conditions in Equation (14). The column labeled J
provides a 2 difference test of a restricted specification H0 versus an alternative specification H1 .
We report the 2 statistic with p-values below in parentheses. The sample period is from July 1963 to
December 2001. In the table, robust t-statistics are reported in square brackets.
1219
Specification II
1.35
17:73
[8.70]
[3.03]
1220
the standard market factor. This is true even when we allow for SMB and
HML to be present in the model. This is a strong result because the SMB
and HML factors are constructed specifically to explain the size and
value premia of the 25 Fama-French portfolios. For both the CAPM
and the Fama-French model, the J test strongly rejects both specifications in favor of allowing for downside market risk. For the FamaFrench model, the p-value of the rejection is almost zero.
Thus, not only do individual stocks sorted directly on loadings
reveal a large reward for stocks with high downside risk exposure, but
other portfolios commonly used in asset pricing also exhibit exposure to
downside risk. In particular, linear factor model tests using the Fama and
French (1993) size and book-to-market portfolios reject the hypothesis
that these portfolios do not have exposure to downside market risk.
Downside Risk
12
Industry classifications are based on groupings of two-digit Standard Industrial Classification (SIC)
codes following Ferson and Harvey (1991). They are Miscellaneous, Petroleum, Finance, Durables, Basic
Industry, Food & Tobacco, Construction, Capital Goods, Transportation, Utilities, Textile & Trade,
Service, and Leisure. In unreported results, we find very little pattern of downside risk exposure across
industries, except that utilities generally exhibit lower exposure to downside risk than other industries.
This is consistent with the notion that utilities are traditionally defensive stocks that tend to hold their
value relative to other industries during market downturns.
1221
Past variables
I
II
III
IV
V
VI
VII
VIII
IX
X
Past
rel. beta
Past
std dev
Log
size
Bk-mkt
Past
ret
ROE
Asset
growth
Sales
growth
Leverage
Ind
[Div]
Std
dev
Coskew
0.007
[10.7]
Cokurt
Liquidity
beta
Indstry
dummy?
Yes
0.251
[6.10]
Yes
0:038
[10.8]
Yes
0.007
[2.04]
Yes
0.052
[4.85]
Yes
0:020
[3.04]
Yes
0.003
[0.43]
Yes
0.006
[1.04]
Yes
0.000
[0.13]
Yes
0:066
[6.82]
Regression
Yes
1222
Table 7
Determinants of Relative Downside Beta
Past variables
Regression
XI
XII
XIII
Past
rel. beta
0.040
[10.7]
0.022
[9.19]
0.017
[5.72]
Past
std dev
0.094
[2.58]
0:150
[6.39]
0:145
[5.88]
Log
size
Bk-mkt
Past
ret
ROE
0:035
[12.8]
0:042
[18.8]
0:041
[18.5]
0:010
[3.56]
0:006
[3.08]
0:005
[2.64]
0.063
[8.12]
0.003
[0.78]
0.001
[0.33]
0:011
[1.10]
0.007
[1.21]
0.008
[1.33]
0.032
[2.62]
0.016
[2.02]
0.011
[1.40]
Sales
growth
0:001
[0.09]
0:009
[1.34]
0:001
[1.46]
Leverage
0.001
[1.47]
0.000
[0.63]
0:001
[1.46]
Ind
[Div]
0:005
[1.08]
0.004
[1.16]
0.004
[1.10]
Std
dev
Coskew
Cokurt
Liquidity
beta
Indstry
dummy?
Yes
0.273
[7.08]
0.275
[6.79]
2:441
[23.5]
2:484
[22.5]
0.092
[3.21]
0.106
[3.48]
Yes
0.006
[1.54]
Yes
This table reports the results of Fama-MacBeth (1973) regressions of realized relative downside risk over a 12-month period on various firm characteristics and risk
measures. The independent variables include both past variables in the information set observable at time t (Past variables) and also risk measures with contemporaneous
realization as the dependent variables (Realized risk measures). For all specifications except regression XIII, the sample period is from July 1963 to December 2001, with the
last 12-month period from January 2001 to December 2001, and observations are at a monthly frequency (451 months) for all stocks listed on the NYSE. For regression XIII,
the sample period is from January 1967 to December 2001 (397 months). The t-statistics in square brackets are computed using Newey-West (1987a) heteroskedastic-robust
standard errors with 12 lags. All regressions include industry dummy variables using the industry classification codes of Ferson and Harvey (1991). The past variables include
realized relative downside risk beta (Past relative ) and realized volatility (Past std dev) over the previous 12-month period. The firm characteristics are log of market
capitalization (Log-size), the firm book-to-market ratio (Bk-mkt), and past 12-month excess returns (Past ret), all computed at the beginning of each period. We also
include firm growth measured over the most recently available four-quarter periodreturn on equity (ROE), the growth rate of assets (Asset growth), and the growth rate
of sales (Sales growth)as well as book leverage (Leverage), and an indicator which equals one if the firm pays dividends (Ind[Div]). The realized risk characteristics
measured contemporaneously as the realized relative downside beta dependent variable are the standard deviation of excess returns (Std dev), coskewness, and cokurtosis. All
of the realized characteristics are computed over the same 12-month period as the relative downside beta using daily continuously compounded returns. We also include the
realized Pastor-Stambaugh (2003) liquidity beta, L , for January 1967 to January 2001. All independent variables are Winsorized at the 1% level and at the 99% within each
month.
Downside Risk
Table 7
(continued)
1223
Downloaded from http://rfs.oxfordjournals.org/ at Oakland University on September 30, 2014
In an unreported table, we do find that firms with low ROE, high growth, and high leverage have high
downside betabut, these characteristics do not add more than what is already captured by regular beta.
We also find that dividend-paying firms exhibit less downside risk, without accounting for the regular
beta.
1224
Downside Risk
14
We find that past has no predictive ability for future returns, even excluding the most volatile stocks
as in Section 3.3. This is consistent with the results in Section 2, which fails to find a consistent
contemporaneous pattern in expected returns for realized risk. These results are available on request.
1225
Table 8
Returns of Stocks Sorted by Past Asymmetry Measures
Realized statistics
Portfolio
Average next
month return
Coskew
0.59%
0.71%
0.77%
0.84%
0.54
0.70
0.85
1.02
0.61
0.77
0.93
1.11
0.48
0.65
0.80
0.96
0:13
0:15
0:17
0:18
5 High
0.70%
1.31
1.41
1.25
0:18
High-low
t-stat
0.11%
[0.60]
0.77
0.80
0.77
0:05
1 Low coskew
2
3
4
5 High coskew
0.84%
0.82%
0.76%
0.60%
0.57%
0.91
0.90
0.89
0.87
0.85
1.01
0.99
0.97
0.95
0.91
0.85
0.84
0.83
0.82
0.81
0:19
0:17
0:16
0:15
0:13
0:28%
[2.76]
0:06
0:10
0:04
0.05
High-low
t-stat
This table reports the equal-weighted average returns and risk characteristics of stocks sorted by past
(panel A) and past coskewness (panel B). For each month, we compute and coskewness with respect
to the market of all stocks listed on the NYSE using daily continuously compounded returns over the
previous 12 months. For each risk characteristic, we rank stocks into quintiles (15) and form equalweighted portfolios at the beginning of each month. The sample period is from July 1962 to January
2001. The number of stocks in each portfolio varies across time from 221 to 346 stocks. The column
labeled Average next month return reports the average return in excess of the one-month Treasury bill
rate over the next month. The row labeled High-low reports the difference between the returns of
portfolio 5 and portfolio 1. The entry labeled t-stat is the simple OLS t-statistic in square brackets. The
columns labeled , , and report the time-series averages of equal-weighted cross-sectional
averages of individual stock betas over the next 12-month period. The column labeled Coskew reports
the time-series averages of equal-weighted cross-sectional averages of individual stock coskewness over
the next 12-month period of the High-low difference.
1226
1 Low
2
3
4
Downside Risk
i
;
m
15
1227
15
In contrast, when
i is held constant, increasing downside correlation can only increase . Hence, we
tend to see high average future returns for stocks with high past downside correlation. Ang, Chen, and
Xing (2002) report that the difference in average future returns over the next month between the tenth
and first decile portfolios sorted on past is approximately 5% per annum.
16
Since we use all stocks listed on the NYSE, AMEX, and NASDAQ in constructing size and book-tomarket benchmark portfolios, the average adjusted returns of all stocks listed on the NYSE does not sum
up to 0.0%.
1228
wherep
corrri ; rm jrm < m p
is
downside correlation,
and
i varri jrm < m and
varrm jrm < m represent stock
m
and market volatilities conditional on down markets, respectively. High
downside beta can be produced by high downside correlation, , or by
high downside volatility,
i . But, holding constant , stocks with high
volatility, or i , tend to have low returns, which is exactly opposite to
the high , high average return effect that we wish to observe.15 Therefore the Ang et al. (2006) volatility effect works in the opposite way as the
expected return pattern for , making it hard to predict downside risk
for stocks with very high volatility.
Table 9 shows that past poorly predicts future only for high
volatility stocks. In panel A, we report selected summary statistics of
portfolios sorted by volatility, measured using daily continuously compounded returns over the previous 12 months. For the overall sample and
for each of the highest volatility groups, we report the average market
capitalization, past , and average returns adjusted for size and bookto-market using a characteristic control similar to Daniel, Grinblatt,
Titman, and Wermers (1997). While the average stock has an annualized
volatility of 36%, stocks in the highest volatility quintile have a considerably higher average volatility of 61% per annum. Stocks in the highest
demi-decile (5%-tile) have an average volatility of over 85% per annum.
The second row of panel A reports that the quintile of stocks with the
highest volatility constitutes, on average, only 3.9% of the overall market
capitalization. Hence, by excluding the highest quintile of volatile stocks,
we exclude stocks that represent only a small fraction of the market. In
fact, the highest demi-decile (5%-tile) of the most volatile stocks constitutes only 0.4% of the total market capitalization. Hence, not surprisingly, the highest volatility stocks tend to be small. In the third row, we
report the size and book-to-market adjusted returns.16 Stocks in the
highest volatility quintile (demi-decile) underperform their benchmark
portfolios by, on average, a large 0.38% (0.67%) per month. This is the
puzzling Ang et al. (2006) effectstocks with very high total or idiosyncratic volatility have low average returns.
The last two rows of panel A explore the interaction between volatility
and . While an average stock has a past loading of almost one
(0.99), high-volatility stocks tend to have high past . In particular, the
average past is 1.44 for the stocks in the highest volatility quintile. We
Downside Risk
Table 9
Stocks Sorted by Past b Excluding the Most Volatile Stocks
Panel A: Selected characteristics of volatility portfolios
Stocks of the highest volatility
Quintile
Octile
Decile
5%-tile
100.0%
35.9%
0.08%
0.99
43.5%
3.9%
61.0%
0.38%
1.44
25.8%
1.9%
68.4%
0.50%
1.47
21.8%
1.3%
72.5%
0.56%
1.48
20.5%
0.4%
85.6%
0.67%
1.44
17.3%
0.58%
0.69%
0.82%
4
0.82%
5 High
0.92%
High-low
Q4-low
0.34%
[2.31]
0.25%
[2.28]
In panel A, each month, we calculate individual stock volatility of all stocks listed on the NYSE using
daily continuously compounded returns over the previous 12 months. We sort stocks according to
volatility into quintiles, octiles, deciles, and demi-deciles (5%-tiles). Panel A reports selected average
characteristics of stocks in each volatility group. The first column reports the characteristics over the
entire sample. The other columns report the characteristics within the highest volatility groups. The row
labeled Annualized volatility reports the average stock volatility over the past 12 months, while the row
labeled Market cap reports the time-series averages of cumulative market capitalization represented by
the stocks in each group. The other rows report the returns adjusted for size and book-to-market using a
characteristic control similar to Daniel et al. (1997), the past over the previous 12 months, and the
autocorrelation of between the past 12 months and the following 12 months. For each characteristic,
we report the time-series averages of equal-weighted cross-sectional averages. In panel B, we report the
average return in excess of the 1-month Treasury bill rate over the next one month of portfolios sorted
on past that exclude the highest volatility quintile of stocks. Each month, we first sort stocks into
quintiles according to volatility measured using daily continuously compounded returns over the
previous 12 months. Then, we exclude the stocks that fall into the highest volatility quintile and rank
the remaining stocks into equal-weighted quintiles (15) according to past measured using continuously compounded returns over the previous 12 months. We report the average excess return over the
next month. The row labeled High-low (Q4-low) reports the difference between the returns of
portfolio 5 (portfolio 4) and portfolio 1. We report simple t-statistics in square brackets. The number
of stocks in each portfolio varies across time and groupings from 177 to 346 stocks. The sample period is
from July 1962 to January 2001.
1229
All stocks
If we exclude fewer stocks and only exclude stocks in the highest volatility octile or decile, the return
difference between highest portfolio and the lowest portfolio is about the same order of magnitude
(roughly 0.31% per month), but the statistical significance is somewhat weaker, with p-values of 0.051
and 0.063, respectively. However, the return difference between quintiles 1 and 4 is unaffected for all the
volatility exclusions at 0.25% per month and is always statistically significant at the 5% level. This is due
to the fact that the volatility effect is strongest among high-volatility stocks which tend to have the
highest past .
1230
Downside Risk
Table 10
Characteristic Controls on Stocks Sorted by Past b
Including additional controls for
Momentum
Coskewness
Liquidity
1 Low
2
3
4
5 High
0:25%
0:09%
0.05%
0.07%
0.20%
0:21%
0:07%
0.04%
0.10%
0.12%
0:21%
0:07%
0.07%
0.04%
0.15%
0:17%
0:02%
0.05%
0.10%
0.13%
High-low
t-stat
0.44%
[3.36]
0.32%
[2.71]
0.36%
[2.69]
0.30%
[2.15]
The table reports robustness checks of the results in Table 9. For each month, we compute individual stock
volatility and with respect to the market of all NYSE stocks using daily continuously compounded
returns over the previous 12 months. We first sort stocks according to volatility into quintiles and exclude
stocks that fall within the highest volatility quintile. We rank the remaining stocks into quintiles (15)
according to past and form equal-weighted portfolios at the beginning of each month. The table reports
characteristic-adjusted holding period returns over the next month of the quintiles that exclude stocks
in the highest quintile. In column labeled Size/bk-mkt adjusted, we report the average returns in excess
of size and book-to-market matched benchmark portfolios similar to Daniel et al. (1997). In the next three
columns, we include additional controls for momentum (as measured by past 12-month returns), past
coskewness, and past liquidity betas, computed following Pastor and Stambaugh (2003). For each additional control, we first perform a quintile sort based on the characteristic and then on past excluding the
highest quintile of stocks. Then, we average the quintiles across the characteristic quintiles and report
size and book-to-market matched returns within each quintile. The number of stocks in each portfolio
varies across time from 177 to 277 stocks. The row labeled High-low reports the difference between the
returns of quintile portfolios 1 and 5. The entry labeled t-stat in square brackets is the simple t-statistic
for the High-low difference. The sample period is from July 1962 to January 2001, except in the last
column, where the sample period is from January 1967 to January 2001.
In the next three columns, we control for additional past return characteristics: momentum, coskewness, and liquidity. For each additional
control, we first perform a quintile sort based on the characteristic and
then on past excluding the highest quintile of stocks. Then, we
average the quintiles across the characteristic quintiles and report size
and book-to-market matched returns within each quintile. To control
for momentum, we use past 12-month returns. Liquidity is measured
using the historical liquidity betas of Pastor and Stambaugh (2003).
Table 10 clearly shows that the spreads in size and book-to-market
adjusted returns between the quintiles 5 and 1 remain significant
at the 5% level after controlling for momentum, coskewness, and liquidity. In each case, the point estimates of the differences average over 0.30%
per month. Therefore, our predictive pattern of returns for past are
not due to size, book-to-market, past return, coskewness, or liquidity
effects.
Finally, as an alternative control for volatility, we consider orthogonalizing the portfolios with respect to volatility in Table 11. We first
rank stocks according to past 12-month volatility into quintiles. Then, we
1231
Size/bk-mkt adjusted
Table 11
Returns of Stocks Sorted by Past Volatility and Past Realized Downside Beta
Past volatility quintiles
Portfolio
5 High
Average
1 Low
2
3
4
5 High
0:26%
0:23%
0:15%
0.01%
0.08%
0:07%
0.01%
0.07%
0.11%
0.17%
0:21%
0:01%
0.03%
0.23%
0.22%
0:27%
0.08%
0.00%
0.17%
0.14%
0:43%
0:37%
0:31%
0:47%
0:31%
0:25%
0:13%
0:07%
0.01%
0.06%
High-low
t-stat
0.35%
[3.25]
0.25%
[2.35]
0.43%
[3.59]
0.41%
[2.84]
0.12%
[0.55]
0.31%
[3.14]
The table examines the relation between past realized volatility and past realized . For each month, we
compute past volatility and past with respect to the market of all stocks listed on NYSE using daily
continuously compounded returns over the past 12 months. We first rank stocks into quintiles (15) at
the beginning of each month based on volatility calculated over the previous 12 months. Then, we rank
stocks within each first-sort quintile into additional quintiles according to realized , computed over
the previous 12 months. For each 5 5 grouping, we form an equal-weighted portfolio. In each cell, we
report the average returns in excess of size and book-to-market matched benchmark portfolios similar to
Daniel et al. (1997). In the column labeled Average, we report the average size and book-to-market
adjusted return of stocks in each second sort quintile, which controls for realized volatility. The row
labeled High-low reports the difference between the returns of quintile portfolios 5 and portfolio 1.
The entry labeled t-stat in square brackets is the simple t-statistic. The sample period is from July 1963
to December 2001.
1232
1 Low
Downside Risk
1233
The cross section of stock returns reflects a premium for downside risk.
Stocks that covary strongly with the market, conditional on market
declines, have high average returns. This riskreturn relation is consistent
with an economy where agents place greater weight on downside risk than
they place on upside gains. Agents with aversion to downside risk require
a premium to hold assets that have high sensitivities to market downturns. Hence, stocks with high downside risk exposure, or high downside
betas, have high average returns.
We find that the contemporaneous high average returns earned by
stocks with high downside betas are not explained by a list of crosssectional effects, including size and book-to-market effects, coskewness
risk, liquidity risk, and momentum effect. The effect is also different from
regular market beta. Controlling for these and other cross-sectional
effects, we estimate that the cross-sectional premium for bearing downside beta risk is approximately 6% per annum. The downside premium is
robust across a battery of robustness tests. In particular, we find that the
premium captured by downside beta is quite different from the coskewness effect of Harvey and Siddique (2000). Downside beta measures risk
conditional only on market declines, whereas coskewness captures the
unconditional covariation of a stock with extreme downside movements
of the market. In contrast, we find that the premium for upside risk is
weak in the data and often changes signs depending on the set of crosssectional risk controls.
Past downside beta is a good predictor of future covariation with
down market movements, except for stocks that are extremely volatile.
For the vast majority of stocks, past downside beta cross-sectionally
predicts future returns. However, for stocks with very high volatility,
consisting of less than 4% of market capitalization, past downside beta
provides a poor predictor of future downside risk. While high-volatility
stocks constitute only a small fraction of the total market, so a predictive downside beta relationship holds for the vast majority of stocks,
it remains to be explored why the cross-sectional predictive relation
for downside risk does not hold for stocks with very high levels of
volatility.
Appendix
A Solution of the Disappointment Aversion Asset Allocation Problem
@UW
@UW
x1fW W g A E
x1fW >W g 0
@W
@W
@UW
@UW
y1fW W g A E
y1fW >W g 0;
E
@W
@W
E
and
A-1
1
K
ps Ws1
s:Ws W
!
Aps Ws1
A-2
s:Ws >W
s:Ws W
"
and
"
ps Ws xs A
s:Ws >W
#
ps Ws ys
#
ps Ws xs 0
"
s:Ws W
A-3
ps Ws ys 0:
s:Ws >W
Ang, Bekaert, and Liu (2005) note that Equation (A-3) is a standard CRRA maximization
problem with a changed probability measure, where the probabilities for wealth above the
certainty equivalent are down-weighted. That is, defining the probabilities as:
i
p1 ; ; pi ; Api1 ; ; ApN
;
p1 pi Api1 pN
A-4
s Ws xs 0
and
s Ws ys 0:
A-5
The algorithm starts with a state i, solves the standard CRRA problem with probability
distribution f i g for the optimal portfolio weights w*xi and w*yi , and then computes the
certainty equivalent *Wi , given by:
*Wi
N
X
s1
1234
1
!1
Ws* 1 is
Ang, Bekaert, and Liu (2005) develop an algorithm for solving the portfolio allocation
problem for DA utility that transforms the DA asset allocation problem in Equation (3)
into a series of standard CRRA problems under a transformed measure that involves the
degree of disappointment aversion A. The simplicity of their algorithm relies crucially on the
assumption of a discretized state space that is ordered by wealth. However, their setup is only
for a single risky asset. We extend their algorithm to a multiple-asset case, by considering all
possible combinations of the six states. This appendix outlines this numerical solution.
Epstein and Zin (1990, 2001) show that the First-Order Conditions (FOC) for Equation
(3) are given by:
Downside Risk
If this condition holds, then the optimal portfolio weights for x and y, w*x and w*y ,
found, so w*x w*xi and w*y w*yi and the optimal utility is given by *W *Wi .
A-6
have been
x
y
mkt
mean
stdev
0.1168
0.1250
0.1200
0.1863
0.2750
0.1375
0.6944
1.3800
1.0000
To obtain the relations between the , downside beta and coskewness and alphas, we
alter xd from 0:16 to 0:30. Figure 1 shows the risk-return relations for asset x.
With an alternative set of parameters, CAPM alphas increase with increasing but also
increasing coskewness. For this case, 6, A 0:7, Rf 1:05, xu 0:50 ,
xm 0:20 , xd 0:30 , yu 0:35, and yd 0:7. The probabilities are given by
p1 0:10, p2 0:20, p3 0:20, p4 0:20, and p5 0:20. If p1 is altered between 0.08 and
0.10 and solved for each case to obtain equilibrium, then we have:
CAPMa
0.0273
0.0317
0.0348
b
co-skew
0.9567
0.8473
0.7326
2.9883
3.1752
3.3873
0.1417
0.1087
0.0598
However, this case is unrealistic because the values of the s are extremely high.
1235
The Condition (A-6) relies on ordering the states in increasing wealth. To modify this
algorithm, we take all possible M orderings of the states. Then, we find state i of ordering j
where Condition (A-6) is satisfied. This provides the solution to the DA asset allocation
problem over the two assets x and y.
For our calibrations, we set 6, A 0:8 and set the gross-risk free rate to be
Rf 1:05. For a baseline case, we take ux 0:25 , mx 0:16 , dx 0:25 ,
uy 0:40, and dy 0:15. The six states have probabilities given by p1 0:15, p2 0:20,
p3 0:15, p4 0:25, and p5 0:20. In equilibrium, the value of 0:0021. This gives us
equilibrium weights of w*x 0:5543 and w*y 0:4457, which sum to 1 and which represents
the market. In this specification, the mean excess returns, standard deviations, and betas of
the two assets and the market are given by:
For every 12-month period, we construct portfolios based on measures of risk between
asset is excess return, rit , and the markets excess return, rmt . We exclude stocks with more
than five missing observations from our analysis. We first demean returns within each
period and denote ~rit as the demeaned excess return of asset i and ~rmt as the demeaned
^ and the
market excess return. We obtain estimates of the regular market , denoted ,
individual stock volatility , denoted ^, in the usual manner as:
r
P
~rit~rmt
1X 2
~rit ;
^ P 2 ; and
~rmt
T
B-7
P
P
r
r
r
r
it ~
it ~
mt
mt
fr <^ g ~
fr >^ g ~
^ P mt m 2 ; and ^ P mt m 2 :
rmt
rmt
^m g ~
frmt <
frmt >^m g ~
B-8
coskew
and
cokurt
P 2 1 P 2
P 2 1 P 2 3=2 :
1
1
~
~
~
~rmt
r
r
r
it
it
mt
T
T
T
T
B-9
We also collect market capitalizations, book-to-market ratio, and past 12-month returns at
the beginning of each 12-month period for each stock.
To calculate the liquidity betas for individual stocks, at the end of each month, we identify
stocks listed on NYSE, AMEX, and NASDAQ with at least five years of monthly returns.
For each stock, we estimate a liquidity beta, iL , by running the following regression using
the most recent five years of monthly data:
ri;t i0 iL Lt iM rm;t iS SMBt iH HMLt
i;t ;
B-10
where Lt is the innovation in aggregate liquidity, and SMBt and HMLt are size and bookto-market factors of Fama and French (1993). The details of the construction of Lt is in
Pastor and Stambaugh (2003).
Once portfolios are formed, we calculate the returns to holding these portfolios. Over
each 12-month period, we collect the cumulative returns of each stock in excess of the onemonth Treasury bill rate over the period. We also collect the excess stock return over the next
month, as well as stock returns in excess of size and book-to-market matched benchmark
portfolios. These size and book-to-market adjusted returns are calculated in a manner
similar to Daniel et al. (1997). Each month, stocks listed on NYSE, AMEX, and NASDAQ
are sorted into quintiles according to their beginning-of-period market capitalizations based
on NYSE breakpoints. Then within each of these quintiles, stocks are further sorted into
quintiles according to their book-to-market ratios based on NYSE breakpoints. For each
5 5 grouping, we calculate the return on an equal-weighted portfolio consisting of all
stocks that fall into that grouping. For each stock, size and book-to-market adjusted returns
are defined as the return in excess of the portfolio return of the 5 5 grouping to which the
stock belongs. All of these returns are calculated with an adjustment for delisting by taking
1236
where T is the number of trading days in a period. We estimate downside beta and upside
beta by conditioning the observations for which the market realization is below or above the
P
sample mean, ^m T1 rmt . We calculate demeaned excess return of asset i and demeaned
market excess returns conditional on market excess return being below the sample means,
denoted ~r
r
it and ~
mt , respectively. We also calculate demeaned excess return of asset i and
demeaned market excess returns conditional on market excess return being above the
^
^
sample means, denoted ~r
r
it and ~
mt , respectively. We then calculate and as:
Downside Risk
the delisting return at the time the stock is delisted. If a return is missing, we take the next
available return.
References
Ang, A., G. Bekaert, and J. Liu, 2005, Why Stocks May Disappoint, Journal of Financial Economics,
76, 471508.
Ang, A., and J. Chen, 2002, Asymmetric Correlations of Equity Returns, Journal of Financial Economics, 63, 443494.
Ang, A., and J. Chen, 2005, CAPM Over the Long-Run: 19262001, forthcoming in Journal of
Empirical Finance.
Ang, A., R. J. Hodrick, Y. Xing, and X. Zhang, 2006, The Cross-Section of Volatility and Expected
Returns, Journal of Finance, 51, 259299.
Bansal, R., R. Dittmar, and C. Lundblad, 2005, Consumption, Dividends, and the Cross-Section of
Equity Returns, Journal of Finance, 60, 16391672.
Bansal, R., D. A. Hsieh, and S. Viswanathan, 1993, A New Approach to International Arbitrage
Pricing, Journal of Finance, 48, 17191747.
Banz, R., 1981. The Relation between Return and Market Value of Common Stocks, Journal of
Financial Economics, 9, 318.
Barberis, N., and M. Huang, 2001, Mental Accounting, Loss Aversion, and Individual Stock Returns,
Journal of Finance, 56, 12471292.
Basu, S., 1983, The Relationship between Earnings Yield, Market Value, and Return for NYSE
Common Stocks: Further Evidence, Journal of Financial Economics, 12, 129156.
Bawa, V. S., and E. B. Lindenberg, 1977, Capital Market Equilibrium in a Mean-Lower Partial Moment
Framework, Journal of Financial Economics, 5, 189200.
Bekaert, G., R. J. Hodrick, and D. A. Marshall, 1997, The Implications of First-Order Risk Aversion
for Asset Market Risk Premiums, Journal of Monetary Economics, 40, 339.
Black, F., M. Jensen, and M. Scholes, 1972, The Capital Asset Pricing Model: Some Empirical Tests, in
M. Jensen (ed.), Studies in the Theory of Capital Markets, Praeger, New York.
Chen, J., Hong, H., and J. Stein, 2001, Forecasting Crashes: Trading Volume, Past Returns and
Conditional Skewness in Stock Prices, Journal of Financial Economics, 61, 345381.
Daniel, K., M. Grinblatt, S. Titman, and R. Wermers, 1997, Measuring Mutual Fund Performance with
Characteristic Based Benchmarks, Journal of Finance, 52, 10351058.
Daniel, K., and S. Titman, 1997, Evidence on the Characteristics of Cross-Sectional Variation in Stock
Returns, Journal of Finance, 52, 133.
Dittmar, R., 2002, Nonlinear Pricing Kernels, Kurtosis Preference, and Evidence from the CrossSection of Equity Returns, Journal of Finance, 57, 369403.
Epstein, L. G., and S. E. Zin, 1990, First-Order Risk Aversion and the Equity Premium Puzzle, Journal
of Monetary Economics, 26, 387407.
Epstein, L. G., and S. E. Zin, 2001, The Independence Axiom and Asset Returns, Journal of Empirical
Finance, 8, 537572.
Fama, E. F., and K. R. French, 1992, The Cross-Section of Expected Stock Returns, Journal of
Finance, 47, 427465.
1237
Ang, A., J. Chen, and Y. Xing, 2002, Downside Correlation and Expected Stock Returns, NBER
Working Paper 8643.
Fama, E. F., and K. R. French, 1993, Common Risk Factors in the Returns on Stocks and Bonds,
Journal of Financial Economics, 33, 356.
Fama, E. F., and K. R. French, 1997, Industry Costs of Equity, Journal of Financial Economics, 43,
153193.
Fama, E. F., and K. R. French, 2005, The Value Premium and the CAPM, forhtcoming Journal of
Finance.
Fama, E. F., and J. D. MacBeth, 1973, Risk, Return, and Equilibrium: Empirical Tests, Journal of
Political Economy, 71, 607636.
Ferson, W. E., and C. R. Harvey, 1991, The Variation of Economic Risk Premiums, Journal of Political
Economy, 99, 385415.
Gibbons, M. R., 1982, Multivariate Tests of Financial Models, Journal of Financial Economics, 10, 3
27.
Guidolin, M., and A. Timmermann, 2002, Optimal Portfolio Choice Under Regime Switching, Skew
and Kurtosis Preferences, working paper, University of California, San Diego.
Gul, F., 1991, A Theory of Disappointment Aversion, Econometrica, 59, 667686.
Harlow, W., and R. Rao, 1989, Asset Pricing in a Generalized Mean-Lower Partial Moment Framework: Theory and Evidence, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 24, 285311.
Harvey, C. R., J. C. Liechty, M. W. Liechty, and P. Muller, 2003, Portfolio Selection with Higher
Moments, working paper, Duke University.
Harvey, C. R., and A. Siddique, 1999, Autoregressive Conditional Skewness, Journal of Financial and
Quantitative Analysis, 34, 465477.
Harvey, C. R., and A. Siddique, 2000, Conditional Skewness in Asset Pricing Tests, Journal of Finance,
55, 12631295.
Hong, H., and J. Stein, 2003, Differences of Opinion, Short-Sales Constraints and Market Crashes,
Review of Financial Studies, 16, 487525.
Isakov, D., 1999, Is Beta Still Alive? Conclusive Evidence from the Swiss Stock Market, European
Journal of Finance, 5, 202212.
Jagannathan, R., and Z. Wang, 1996, The Conditional CAPM and the Cross-Section of Expected
Returns, Journal of Finance, 51, 353.
Jahankhani, A., 1976, E-V and E-S Capital Asset Pricing Models: Some Empirical Tests, Journal of
Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 11, 513528.
Jegadeesh, N., and S. Titman, 1993, Returns to Buying Winners and Selling Losers: Implications for
Stock Market Efficiency, Journal of Finance, 48, 6591.
Jondeau, E., and M. Rockinger, 2006, How Higher Moments Affect the Allocation of Assets, forthcoming in European Financial Management.
Kahneman, D., and A. Tversky, 1979, Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision Under Risk,
Econometrica, 47, 263291.
Knez, P. J., and M. J. Ready, 1997, On the Robustness of Size and Book-to-Market in Cross-Sectional
Regressions, Journal of Finance, 52, 13551382.
Kothari, S. P., J. Shanken, and R. G. Sloan, 1995, Another Look at the Cross Section of Expected Stock
Returns, Journal of Finance, 50, 185224.
1238
Friend, I., and R. Westerfield, 1980, Co-Skewness and Capital Asset Pricing, Journal of Finance, 35,
897913.
Downside Risk
Kraus, A., and R. Litzenberger, 1976, Skewness Preference and the Valuation of Risk Assets, Journal of
Finance, 31, 10851100.
Kraus, A., and R. Litzenberger, 1983, On the Distributional Conditions for a Consumption-Oriented
Three Moment CAPM, Journal of Finance, 38, 13811391.
Kyle, A. W., and W. Xiong, 2001, Contagion as a Wealth Effect of Financial Intermediaries, Journal of
Finance, 56, 14011440.
Lettau, M., and S. Ludvigson, 2001, Resurrecting the (C)CAPM: A Cross-Sectional Test When Risk
Premia Are Time-Varying, Journal of Political Economy, 109, 12381287
Lewellen, J., and S. Nagel, 2005, The Conditional CAPM Does Not Explain Asset-Pricing Anomalies,
forthcoming in Journal of Financial Economics.
Newey, W. K., and K. D. West, 1987a, A Simple Positive Semi-Definite, Heteroskedasticity and
Autocorrelation Consistent Covariance Matrix, Econometrica, 55, 7038.
Newey, W. K., and K. D. West, 1987b, Hypothesis Testing with Efficient Method of Moments,
International Economic Review, 28, 777787.
Pastor, L., and R. F. Stambaugh, 2003, Liquidity Risk and Expected Stock Returns, Journal of
Political Economy, 111, 642685.
Pettengill, G. N., S. Sundaram, and I. Mathur, 1995, The Conditional Relation between Beta and
Returns, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 30, 101116.
Price, K., B. Price, and T. J. Nantell, 1982, Variance and Lower Partial Moment Measures of Systematic
Risk: Some Analytical and Empirical Results, Journal of Finance, 37, 843855.
Rouwenhorst, K. G., 1998, International Momentum Strategies, Journal of Finance 53, 267284.
Routledge, B. R., and S. E. Zin, 2003, Generalized Disappointment Aversion and Asset Prices, NBER
Working Paper 10107.
Roy, A. D., 1952, Safety First and the Holding of Assets, Econometrica, 20, 431449.
Rubinstein, M., 1973, The Fundamental Theory of Parameter-Preference Security Valuation, Journal
of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 8, 6169.
Scholes, M., and J. T. Williams, 1977, Estimating Betas from Nonsynchronous Data, Journal of
Financial Economics, 5, 30927.
Scott, R. C., and P. A. Horvath, 1980, On the Direction of Preference for Moments of Higher Order
than the Variance, Journal of Finance, 35, 915919.
Shanken, J., 1992, On the Estimation of Beta-Pricing Models, Review of Financial Studies, 5, 133.
Shumway, T., 1997, Explaining Returns with Loss Aversion, working paper, University of Michigan.
1239
Markowitz, H., 1959, Portfolio Selection. Yale University Press, New Haven, CT.