Assessing Changes in The Monetary Transmission Mechanism: A VAR Approach
Assessing Changes in The Monetary Transmission Mechanism: A VAR Approach
Assessing Changes in The Monetary Transmission Mechanism: A VAR Approach
Jean Boivin is an assistant professor of finance and economics at Columbia The authors thank Kenneth Kuttner for fruitful discussions, an anonymous
University; Marc Giannoni is an economist at the Federal Reserve Bank referee, and Alex Al-Haschimi and Kodjo Apedjinou for research assistance.
of New York. Jean Boivin thanks the National Science Foundation (grant SES-0001751) for
<jb903@columbia.edu> financial support. The views expressed are those of the authors and do not
<marc.giannoni@ny.frb.org> necessarily reflect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or
the Federal Reserve System.
2.2 Empirical Evidence Notes: The figures are the p-values for the Andrews (1993) sup-Wald test.
Under the null of the test, the coefficients are time-invariant. The test is
applied jointly to the constant and the coefficients and the lags of the
variable corresponding to the given column. The p-values were com-
puted using the simulation approach proposed by Hansen (1997).
Stability Tests on the Reduced-Form VAR PCOM inflation denotes commodity price inflation.
B iZZ B iZ R
then we know that the mechanism that propagates the Bi = ,
fundamental disturbances t must have changed.14 B iRZ B iRR
To isolate properly the contribution of changes in the for i = 0, , k . Noting that the scalar B 0RR = 1 , it follows
fundamental shocks, more structure needs to be added. We that our structural VAR (equation 2) can be written as
turn to this in the next section. k
(3) Z t = ( B 0ZZ ) 1 b Z + B iZZ Z t i B 0ZR Rt
i=1
k
Chart 1
Impulse Responses to a Monetary Shock over Different Samples
0 0 0
0 0 0
Interest Rate, 1963:1 to 1979:3 Interest Rate, 1980:1 to 1997:4 Interest Rate, 1984:1 to 1997:4
1.5 1.5 1.5
0 0 0
particular, the response of inflation appears somewhat stronger VAR-Based Counterfactual Analysis:
Pre-1980 Sample versus Post-1980 Sample
when the VAR is estimated on the post-1984 sample, and the
response of output, while of similar shape overall, becomes
(pre-80, pre-80): Pre-1980 sample
positive after six quarters, though not significantly so.19
(pre-80, post-80): Pre-1980 policy, post-1980 economy
(post-80, pre-80): Post-1980 policy, pre-1980 economy
(post-80, post-80): Post-1980 sample
Counterfactual Analysis with Structural VARs 0.5
Output
-0.5
1. See, for example, McConnell and Perez-Quiros (2000) and 11. The test used is a version of the Breush-Pagan LM-test adapted for
Blanchard and Simon (2000). the present split-sample context.
2. See, for example, Sims (1980), Watson (1994), and Stock and 12. The same is true for the VAR that involves output growth instead
Watson (2001). of detrended output.
3. Bernanke and Boivin (2001) consider an empirical model that 13. Note that given the interaction between the propagation
accounts for much more information. mechanism and the variance of the errors, there is no unique way of
performing this decomposition. For instance, in the fourth column of
4. To check the robustness of our results, we have replicated all Table 3, the variance of the innovations, u , can be kept fixed at either
exercises by replacing the output gap with quarterly output growth. sample estimate. We report the change in variance evaluated at the
While we report only the results obtained from the VAR with average of the sample estimates of u . The same approach is used in
detrended output, the VAR with output growth yields very similar the last column of Table 3. More formally, we rewrite the VAR
results. (equation 1) in companion form as Y t = AY t 1 + u t , and express the
vectorized variance-covariance matrix of Y t for sample s as
5. All series are from the Standard and PoorsDRI database. The v Y, s = A s v u, s , where v Y, s vec E ( Y tY 't ) , v u, s vec E ( u tu'
t ) , and
1
mnemonics are GDPQ for real GDP, GDPD for the GDP deflator, and A s ( I A s A s ) . We then decompose the change in variance
PSCCOM for the commodity price index. between two samples as follows:
v u, 1 + v u, 2 A1 + A2
6. When output growth is considered instead of detrended output, - (A 2 A 1 ) + ------------------
v Y, 2 v Y, 1 = ------------------------ - ( v u, 2 v u, 1 ) .
2 2
the analysis is performed on the 1960:2-2001:2 period.
The figures in the fourth column of Table 3 correspond to the first
7. Bernanke, Gertler, and Watson (1997) find evidence of instability term on the right-hand side, while the numbers reported in the last
in a monetary VAR, while Bernanke and Mihov (1998) and column correspond to the second term.
Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Evans (1999) reach the opposite
conclusion. 14. Arguably, the split between the systematic and shock components
in a model of the form equation 2 is somewhat arbitrary. Indeed, if we
8. For the VAR with output growth instead of detrended output, of had a full understanding of the functioning of the economyand
the sixteen tests performed, eight50 percentreject the null considered all variables that explain the evolution of output and
hypothesis of stability at the 5 percent level. inflation as well as all variables that determine those explanatory
variables, and so onmost changes would in fact be accounted for by
9. To see this, suppose that we have a linear model, changes in the functioning of one or another part of the economy. Our
y t = x' 1t 1 + x'2t 2 + t for t = 1, , T , where the first column of understanding of the economy, however, is much more limited, so
x 1 t contains only 1s, the i s are constant, and the distribution of x it many changes are unexplained by the model and thus are represented
is time-invariant. If we omit x 2t from the regression, the OLS estimate by the disturbance vector t . Since our simple estimated VAR
bias is time-invariant, and thus misspecification by itself cannot 15. See Bernanke (1986), Bernanke and Blinder (1992), Cochrane
generate instability. (1994), Leeper, Sims, and Zha (1996), Christiano, Eichenbaum, and
Evans (1996, 1999), Bernanke and Mihov (1998), Evans and Kuttner
10. We do not include 1979:4 in the second sample to be consistent (1998), and Stock and Watson (2001), among others.
with the one used by Rotemberg and Woodford (1997), Bernanke and
Mihov (1998), and Clarida, Gal, and Gertler (2000).
16. The federal funds rate probably provides a less adequate measure 19. A similar result is obtained by Gertler and Lown (2000) for a
of monetary policy stance for the 1979-82 period, as nonborrowed different VAR and different subsamples in the post-1980 period.
reserves were set to achieve a level of interest rates consistent with
monetary growth targets. However, Cook (1989) argues that the fed 20. See, for example, Woodford (1996, 1999), Goodfriend and King
funds rate may still provide a satisfactory indicator during this (1997), Rotemberg and Woodford (1997), Clarida, Gal, and Gertler
episode. (1999), and McCallum and Nelson (1999).
17. Note that while the identifying assumption here is not uniformly 21. All variables are expressed here in terms of percent deviations
adopted, the effects of an unexpected monetary policy shock on from their long-run values.
output and inflation described below are in line with the effects
commonly obtained. For alternative identifications of monetary 22. Technically, we assume that t satisfies E t t + j = 0 for all j > 0 .
policy, see, for instance, Bernanke (1986), Blanchard and Watson
(1986), Sims (1986), Leeper, Sims, and Zha (1996), Bernanke and 23. This sum is converging, as r t is expressed in terms of deviations
Mihov (1998), and Stock and Watson (2001). from its long-run average.
18. The results reported in the table are obtained from the VAR with
detrended output. Similar results are obtained from the VAR with
output growth.
Andrews, Donald W. K. 1993. Tests for Parameter Instability and Christiano, Lawrence J., Martin Eichenbaum, and Charles L. Evans.
Structural Change with Unknown Change Point. Econometrica 1996. Identification and the Effects of Monetary Policy Shocks.
61, no. 4 (July): 821-56. In Mario Blejer, Zvi Eckstein, Zvi Hercowitz, and Leonardo
Leiderman, eds., Financial Factors in Economic
Barth, Marvin J., and Valerie A. Ramey. 2001. The Cost Channel of Stabilization and Growth, 36-74. Cambridge: Cambridge
Monetary Transmission. NBER Macroeconomics Annual University Press.
2001.
. 1999. Monetary Policy Shocks: What Have We Learned and
Bernanke, Ben S. 1986. Alternative Explanations of the Money-Income to What End? In John B. Taylor and Michael J. Woodford, eds.,
Correlation. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Handbook of Macroeconomics, 65-148. Amsterdam: Elsevier.
Public Policy 25 (autumn): 49-99.
Clarida, Richard, Jordi Gal, and Mark Gertler. 1999. The Science of
Bernanke, Ben S., and Alan S. Blinder. 1992. The Federal Funds Rate Monetary Policy: A New Keynesian Perspective. Journal of
and the Channels of Monetary Transmission. American Economic Literature 37, no. 4 (December): 1661-1707.
Economic Review 82, no. 4: 901-21.
. 2000. Monetary Policy Rules and Macroeconomic Stability:
Bernanke, Ben S., and Jean Boivin. 2001. Monetary Policy in a Data- Evidence and Some Theory. Quarterly Journal of Economics
Rich Environment. NBER Working Paper no. 8379. 115, no. 1 (February): 147-80.
Bernanke, Ben S., Mark Gertler, and Mark W. Watson. 1997. Cochrane, John H. 1994. Shocks. Carnegie-Rochester
Systematic Monetary Policy and the Effects of Oil Price Shocks. Conference Series on Public Policy 41 (December): 295-364.
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, no. 1: 91-142.
Cook, Timothy. 1989. Determinants of the Federal Funds Rate.
Bernanke, Ben S., and Ilian Mihov. 1998. Measuring Monetary Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review 75, no. 1
Policy. Quarterly Journal of Economics 113, no. 3: 869-902. (January-February): 3-19.
Blanchard, Olivier J., and John Simon. 2000. The Long and Large Evans, Charles L., and Kenneth N. Kuttner. 1998. Can VARs Describe
Decline in U.S. Output Volatility. Unpublished paper, Monetary Policy? In Topics in Monetary Policy Modeling.
Massachusetts Institute of Technology and Reserve Bank Basle: Bank for International Settlements.
of Australia.
Gertler, Mark, and Cara S. Lown. 2000. The Information in the High
Blanchard, Olivier J., and Mark W. Watson. 1986. Are Business Cycles Yield Bond Spread for the Business Cycle: Evidence and Some
All Alike? In Robert J. Gordon, ed., The American Business Implications. NBER Working Paper no. 7549.
Cycle: Continuity and Change, 123-56. Chicago: University
of Chicago Press. Goodfriend, Marvin, and Robert G. King. 1997. The New Neoclassical
Synthesis and the Role of Monetary Policy. In Ben S. Bernanke
Boivin, Jean. 1999. Revisiting the Evidence on the Stability of and Julio J. Rotemberg, eds., NBER Macroeconomics
Monetary VARs. Unpublished paper, Columbia University. Annual 1997, 231-83.
Boivin, Jean, and Marc Giannoni. 2002. Has Monetary Policy Hansen, Bruce E. 1997. Appropriate Asymptotic p-Values for
Become Less Powerful? Federal Reserve Bank of New York Structural-Change Tests. Journal of Business and Economic
Staff Reports, no. 144, March. Statistics 15, no. 1 (January): 60-7.
Chari, V. V., Lawrence J. Christiano, and Martin Eichenbaum. 1995. Kahn, James A., Margaret M. McConnell, and Gabriel Perez-Quiros.
Inside Money, Outside Money, and Short-Term Interest Rates. 2002. On the Causes of the Increased Stability of the U.S.
Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 27, no. 4 (November): Economy. Federal Reserve Bank of New York Economic
1354-86. Policy Review 8, no. 1 (May): 183-202.
Leeper, Eric M., Christopher A. Sims, and Tao Zha. 1996. What Does . 1992. Interpreting the Macroeconomic Time Series Facts:
Monetary Policy Do? Brookings Papers on Economic The Effects of Monetary Policy. European Economic Review
Activity, no. 2: 1-63. 36, no. 5 (June): 975-1000.
Lucas, Robert E., Jr. 1976. Econometric Policy Evaluation: A . 1996. Comment on Do Measures of Monetary Policy in a
Critique. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public VAR Make Sense? by Glenn Rudebusch. Unpublished paper,
Policy 1: 19-46. Princeton University.
McCallum, Bennett T., and Edward Nelson. 1999. An Optimizing Stock, James H., and Mark W. Watson. 1996. Evidence on Structural
IS-LM Specification for Monetary Policy and Business Cycle Instability in Macroeconomic Time Series Relations. Journal of
Analysis. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 31, no. 3 Business and Economic Statistics 14: 11-30.
(August): 296-316.
. 1998. Median Unbiased Estimation of Coefficient Variance
McConnell, Margaret M., and Gabriel Perez-Quiros. 2000. Output in a Time-Varying Parameter Model. Journal of the American
Fluctuations in the United States: What Has Changed since the Statistical Association 93: 349-58.
Early 1980s? American Economic Review 90, no. 5 (December):
1464-76. . 2001. Vector Autoregressions. Journal of Economic
Perspectives 15, no. 4 (fall): 101-16.
Quandt, Richard E. 1960. Tests of the Hypothesis That a Linear
Regression System Obeys Two Separate Regimes. Journal of Taylor, John B., ed. 1999. Monetary Policy Rules. Chicago:
the American Statistical Association 55, no. 290: 324-30. University of Chicago Press.
Rotemberg, Julio J., and Michael Woodford. 1997. An Optimization- Watson, Mark W. 1994. Vector Autoregression and Cointegration.
Based Econometric Framework for the Evaluation of Monetary In Robert Engle and Dan McFadden, eds., Handbook of
Policy. NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 297-346. Econometrics 4. Amsterdam: North-Holland.
Rudebusch, Glenn D. 1998. Do Measures of Monetary Policy in a VAR Woodford, Michael. 1996. Control of the Public Debt: A Requirement
Make Sense? International Economic Review 39, no. 4 for Price Stability? NBER Working Paper no. 5684.
(November): 907-31.
. 1999. Optimal Monetary Policy Inertia. NBER Working
Sims, Christopher A. 1980. Macroeconomics and Reality. Paper no. 7261.
Econometrica 48, no. 1 (January): 1-48.
The views expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York
or the Federal Reserve System. The Federal Reserve Bank of New York provides no warranty, express or implied, as to the
accuracy, timeliness, completeness, merchantability, or fitness for any particular purpose of any information contained in
documents produced and provided by the Federal Reserve Bank of New York in any form or manner whatsoever.