Corporations A Comparative Perspective
Corporations A Comparative Perspective
Corporations A Comparative Perspective
s ............ 1
Chapter 1. Comparative Corporate Law: The Building Block
............. 1
Why Study Comparative Corporate Law ? .............................................
Comparative Corporate Law and Legal Families; Convergence of
" ... 16
Corporate Law and the (Questionable) Search for the "Best System
............... 24
Ownership Structures of Corporations in Different Legal Systems
atory
Chapter 2. Choice of Applicable Corporate Laws and Regul
Competition ........................................................ ......... .......... ... ................ 29
................ 29
Introduction ......................... ...................................................... .........
.......... ... ...... 34
Freedom of Incorporation ............................................. ..................
ean
The Real Seat Approach and Its Gradual Abandonment in the Europ
........ 57
Union .................. .................................................................................
......... . 91
Japan's New Liability -Based Approach ............. .................. ...................
atory
Race to the Top or to the Bottom? A 1-fore Theoretical View of Regul
.......... ...... 94
Competition ................................................... .............................
xv
MMARYOF CONTENTS~-----------
SU ························· ··········· ··········· · 229
xv i of Dir ector s .. .... ... ............. .......... .................... 246
om osition of the Boardhareholders ··········· ·······
8
C P f D. ectors vs. . D utie s ...... .. ......... ........ 267
Powers o ir . bT ty and Fidu c iar y ..... ... ...................... . 267
Ch ter 6. D1rec. tors' Lia i i ....... .... ... ... 2
ap . ......................... . . . . . . . . .. . . . ··········· ········ ····· .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. . . . . ... ... 68
. . . .
I t oduct10n............ .. ··· ···· · .... .· · · · ··· ········· 288
;u ;y of Care ··················· · ::: ::::: . ··• ·· ···· ·· ·· ·· · : :::::: :::: ::::: ...... · .... ··· .. ····· 304
Al
Duty of Loyalt y ............. ··:·· Toward Creditors· ·······
Fe
Dir ectors' Fiduciary Duties ..... ........ ... .... ................ 317
A:
h O lders ' Litigation ···· ··········· ····· ····· ··· ... .. .. ·············· 317
Chapter_7. Share
In trod uction ····················· ·············
·········
· ·····
· ····
s st ems : T 8 · ·h· ····
u ·s··;~·d the U.K . ............. 319 3
T.
. S ·t
Derivative m s m . . . Common Law y
E opea n Systems . . ... .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. . . . .. . 350 N
. tive
· Suit
Derivative
Deriva
sui·t ss in
in Civil
Asia
Law ur
. ....................... ................· ·· ·· ·· ·· · ··
. . .... . . . . . . . . .... . . .. . . . ....... 65
1
VE CORPORATE LAW: CH. 1
COMPARATI G BLOCKS
THE BUILDIN . . .
2 t" drafting new legislation m
£ · corpora ion, 1 1 systems can
the board of directors of a or~li~ ·ty with different ega
s. fami iari
the area of ta k eover . . .
certainly make you more effective. 1 w course have however also
This book and a comparative corTpor~~d; different legal sy_stems, lto
h f 1 and pedagogical goals. o ·c phenomena different Y,
t edoret1acand why they regulate similar econdomti and of statutory and
un ers . 1 of prece en s b th
and to question the rationa e . . d' tions are unique ways to o
regulatory provisions from different
understand better your own
JU~l
system ,da
t: think "out of the box" and not
"mental library'' of cases and
take anything for granted. It e~pan s :?u; r advocate more effectively.
1 Footnotes omitted.
f
(
I
I
CORPORATE LAW". CH. 1
COMPARATIVE BLOCKS ---
THE BUILDING =-- · gly dominate
. ·ncreasm CH. l
4 . 1 corporations i one of the most
with one another as transn;:~:~ markets. Ind!=t~hip has been the alterna i
global capital, labor and ~f corporate-law sch~t seems to pose to the view a~
. rtant recent corners d the challenge the cou
impo h convergence an
question of sue . f modular polarity. . relatim
abstract conceptiono which c
. comparative corporate from a
[... ] e benefits of introduc~ng t least some general [. ..]
An assessment of ~h calls for making a . h Apart from
· the basic course . . d d to accomp 1is · . Tl
governance m h t the course 1s mten e s training 1n case perha1
assumptions about V:tad with most law school c1asse tation advocacy, policyi
b · tives associa e
t h e o Jee t t tory interpreta wn,
t· argumen '
the basic course m
. intern
law ~nalysis, ~ agu critical thinking, and so o_n-students a firm but Statei
analogical reasomn ' b bl is supposed to give . 1 tes in recov«
business organizations pro a Y f and its organizationa cogna
d. g of the corpora ion State :
broad understan m . . d social contexts.
their legal, business, pohtica 1' an simil:
d t t function in professional King,
The basic course shou eqm ld ·p the stu °
end therwise) ·
and busmess
settings where busmess aw . 1 (corporate an ° should give the stu d en t a
h . h · t rn means the course
issues arise , w ic m u . 1 d unusual role the business 1awyer
sense of business and of the spec1~ an at least in addition to-that of (and
plays as business advisor rather t an~r d with most typical law school in di
advocate or litigator (the model ~ssocia ~-cle for conveying the basics of corp,
subjects). Ul~im~t:lyd
corpora_tean re a e .
f~: ~~u~:~P~:; ;:;ents
.bly political
understand that law f~om
glob
bore
theoretical, normative, poss1 ' and certainly practical
on t
perspectives . all ,
So how, if at all, would including comparative corporate gov_ern _anc~ crrn
in the basic course advance these broad . an~ gener~l obJecti':es. Ch1
Unexceptionally, the basics of business orgamzation law 1n the United Pet
I States can best be taught by covering United States law. But part of that
I
I Petroleum.
This increasing global activity means many more students are likely
to encounter businesses organized outside the United States during the
early stages of their professional careers.
[... ]
Other benefits can accrue from introducing comparative corporate
governance in special circumstances, such as where students from around
the world are in the class [... ]. This presence could further enrich
classroom discussion of comparative issues. Contrariwise, it may be even
more important for students at schools that are more homogenous to get
exposure to the international arena through some treatment of
comparative corporate governance.
[... ]
[There is] the common problem of finding suitable materials. No
corporate law casebooks I have reviewed treat comparative corporate
LAW·
IVE CORPORATE . CH. l
r ______
coMPARAT
THE BUILD
ING B5JL~O~C:::.!K~S~---
few cases specifically raising CH.:
6 . addition, there are
ance as a topic._In porate governance. .
govern f rnparat1vecor
questionso co *** .
. 11 answered this last of o
at least partla y Cor
·th this book, to have . 'sto
We hope, wi · ham d ·
f Professor Cunning · t law and how oes it an
concern o h0 ever is comparative c?rpora e and legal scholars? leg
Wha\:x:r~!~ed ;, la~yers, courts, leg~sl::~~:Sieading c~mparative de !
affect, or . rpt by Klaus J . Hopt, on ·nteresting ideas, also th ,
The following exce f times offers some i CO'
corporate law scholars o _our ' .
Ill
from an historical perspective. ,
cc
COMPANY LAW IN THE 11
KLAUS J. HOPT, CoMP~rJ'~oMPARATIV E LAW cc
OXFORD HANDBO d ) Oxford 2006, 1161 ffl p
(Mathias Reimann & Reinhard Zimmermann, e s. ' ' , .
i
modern. . It is
. y law 1.s at once very old and very first existe d
Comparative compan .
since compames an
d company laws , '
j
from comparison.
1
I But comparative company law is also very modern. Most comparative
work has focused on the main areas of private law, such as contract and
• I' torts, rather than company law. While the law of business and private
i I
t organizations was covered in voluminous International Encyclopedia of
Comparative Law, and national company law books and articles
occasionally also provided some comparative information, an
internationally acknowledged standard treatise on comparative company
law has not yet emerged. Company law and comparative company law
w~rk remained a task for professionals. The few academics who joined in
this work tended also to be practitioners such as outside counsel
arbitrato~s, or advisers to legislators, who were less interested in theor;
..and doctrme.
[... ]
' l
I 2
Footnotes omitted.
' !
COMPARATIVECORPORATELAW:
CH. 1 THE BUILDING BLOCKS 7
(a) Legislators
ual understanding
One important aim of comparative law is the mut
altruistic purposes.
of other P~ple and nations. But this serves not only
an enrichment of the
Comparative law has always been considered to be
rience. Some speak of
'stoc#kof legal so!utions' and a wealth of actual expe
nce experiments'. The
an. ecole d~ verite, some even of real 'social scie
centuries were already
legislators ~n the _nineteenth and early twentieth
pany law statutes on
demonstrating this when they prepared their com
experiences of other
the basis of thorough comparisons of the laws and
the second half of the
countries. The major company law codifications in
ed away from the state
nineteenth century, when European countries mov
an Company Act of
concession system, testify to this. Before the Germ
law opinions were
1937 was drafted, many preparatory comparative
tute in Berlin, the
commissioned from the Kaiser Wilhelm Insti
burg. One of the most
predecessor of today's Max Planck Institute in Ham
lish company law was
impressive opinions dealing with American and Eng
ident of the European
written by Walter Hallstein, who later became pres
Institute in Berlin and
Commission, while he was still an assistant at the
rt of Appeals, the
Referendar (legal trainee) at the Berlin Cou
Kammergericht.
law, the use of
In the United States, where company law is state
mon in so far as one
comparative company law by the legislator is com
other American states
state will take into account the company laws of
taken the lead since
when reforming its own company law. Delaware has
state for American
it became, and remains, the major incorporation
lators is a well-kno~n
companies. The competition of state company legis
omenon., _Yet_ its
and, until recently, largely indisputable, phen
to th_e top ~s. highly
interpretation as a 'race to the bottom' or a rac~
s leadmg positi?n-. be
controversial, and the precise reasons for Delaware
ers and specialized
it its company law, or rather its company lawy
courts-remain disputed.
thing. More or less
Merely learning from foreign company laws is on~
even press~re
d f th m either voluntarily or under moral suas10n or although its
~ op itnhg Je an is one of many examples. M China is another, be
ap tl th
1s ano er. diffe rent in important respects. ost rece n y e s~m e ca1:
osition is h,
p · f th Middle and Eastern European countries whic
d or are reforming their
seen ~n m;ny 1~ e f the Soviet Union, reforme
joining the Euro~ean
following t e co~f:et~e aim, sooner or later, of n
co~pany law~ ntext it is also important to mention the Americ~
-Union. In this co t . s particularly strategic ones such as Russia
h is sometimes secured
Influence. on these stco~;s ~; the Soviet Union, whic
and certain former a . . The Japanese company law of 1893
a draft by the German
with the help of financial pr~mi~~s. nt extent on
bined elements of the
(Kyu-shoho) wa~ ba~ed Htoa s1gn1::esler ' and com
scholar Carl Fr1ednch ermann
CORPORATE LAW".
I COMPARATIVE
THE BUILDIN
G BLOCKS
CH.I
d of the German CH. l
I 8 ainly as to its formJl a(concerning many
(c
French Code de commer ;a~r;Je lsgesetzbuch of }81899 (Sh6h6) was close
I Allgemeines D_eu~sches he later company la~ o_ts revised form of 1884, .A
substantive prmc1ples). \aw revision of 1870 ~nl{ d on the German Stock comp:
to the German compa~nyf 1938 was closely mo e ~ anese company law devel
and the revised Shoho9~7 After World War II, ap law principles, in treat'
Corporation Act of 1 d ~he United States
ation
comi~~;3
Act o
This was because -
ma~der for the Allied
tradi
thesE
reform closely f?llo_w;usiness Corpor
particular the Illm?is fficial of the Suprem e C~-?1 Such historical certa
the relevant Amer~can:ned to come from ~
1
~ag 0
~n and this is also but
Powers (SCAP) appore often than is general y ni° 'reform some of alwa
coincidences happ~n m Modern Japanese compan y aw_ e com~ar ison of the ·
true i~ co1:1pany ~~- ut at present , is based on extens1 v
. .
com
which is bemg car~ie o o ean company laws. Con
both United States and Eur p d . terest in comparative fore
h h been renewe m law
Most recently t ere as nee of European company 1aw
company law, partly because of the emerg:nce movement has sharpened Em
and partly because the corpora te governt . The German ministries of unc
·t · ith other coun ries. t" con
the sense of competi wn w h missioned several com para ive
justice and finance, for example,h ave ~~m Max Planck Institute when
I
'
law studies from, amont~t h~t erstrov:rsial questions such as
prepari
to
statement s.
their rs
makengdirecto liableonto I~mves
refo~m ors for untrue or
Y ~on
whethe
misleading financial
r me
he
mi
ob
(b) Lawyers and Legal Counsel . . co
E1
The role of lawyers · and legal counsel in compar_ativ~ law is m
traditionally underrated, since they do their work for their che~ts and cc
-· enterprises on a day-to-day basis. Yet they are the real ~x~erts m both
I
E
conflict of company laws and of foreign company laws. This is even m~re
true now that the forces of globalization have also reached law firms, with
the consequence that the top layer of firms in all major countries has C
I become international either by merger or by cooperation. Occasionally
C
of
some of their comparative work is published, often only in the form
l
I
1
practical advice, but sometimes also with fully legitimate academic
claims. The creation of companies abroad and their subsequent control
is
tax law
I common practice today. Working out the best company and
structures for international mergers, and forming and doing legal work
, I
i- 1
for groups and tax haven operations, is a high, creative art. . . .
f ·i
;! Much_more in the public eye is the comparative company law work of
! : !
J !1 I the Amencan Law Institute, aimed at drafting uniform company laws
r
and model. codes. .Notable results are the Principles of Corporate
:
i ,
1. I
(c) Academia
As ~tated above, traditionally only a few have engaged in
comparative company law work. In all industrialized countries with well-
devel_oped companies there are, of course, standard company law
trea~i~es, many ~f the~ highly knowledgeable and some at the peak of
traditional doctrinal wisdom. Yet, what is conspicuous about most of
these leading texts is their restriction to national law and practice. This is
certainly the impression for Germany, France, and the United Kingdom,
but also for smaller countries where looking beyond their borders has
always been more natural, such as Switzerland. Exceptions seem to prove
the rule, but even they are usually confined to areas such as conflict of
company laws, that is, national law, and, more recently, to European
Community company law, or to the occasional use in a general text of
foreign literature and comparative observations. Comparative company
law work is rarely addressed in these leading texts as a prerequisite of
European company law harmonization or to provide a better
understanding, and to aid the development, of one's own national
company law.
Of course, the state of comparative company law is different as far as
more specialized monographs and articles are concerned. It is impossible
here to go into detail; it would not only be futile, but also unjust to the
many works which could not be mentioned. Some more general
observations must suffice. First, of course, there is much comparative
company law work in the context of conflict of laws and, more recently, of
European company law. As to the latter, there were initially quite
influential collections of texts on European company law, which included
comments and some case law. Since then impressive treatises on
European company law have been developed in most member states.
Second, in many countries American company law has had a
considerable influence on legal literature. This is not surprising for those
countries mentioned above where American company law and securities
regulation was broadly followed. But similar trends can be discerned, for
example , in Germany after World War II, where contacts with German
emigres were rekindled and whole gener~tions of young academi~s
studied in the United States and wrote their doctoral theses and their
Habilitationen on comparative American and German company law.
Some of these works happened to stand at the beginning of the
development of whole new areas in their respective national laws. At a
later stage there were even treatises and handbooks on American
company law written by non-~me~icans i~ G_e~manand other languages,
which provided much insight into its peculiarities.
Third the influence of international networks has been important for
comparati~e company law. Some examples of organized efforts include
10
. L the work of international
International Encycloped w o . fC mparative aw ,
. t'tutions such as the Interno . al FacultY of CorPora t L d
ins 1 at1 on t' al e aw an ab
Securities Regulation an d the 1nterna 10n Ac ad emY of Comparative en
Law, f Tt ted by internat1.ona 1 ins
· t' t t'
or the research which w~s ac\
such as the European Un ' a Institute in Florence , 1 u ions tb
iver;' Y anies, corporate where b~
comparative work on group O governance, m
s ~omt
directors' ha. b'l" .1es,an d the. harmon1za10pn of companies was done and
11t s
the so-calledgr!l<lnbook senes wa st t d Other such networ k s resu 1ted
from private m1t1atives, for s ar1: between the United States, 1
examP dB Jgiuxn Ital y and
Germany,and Switzerland;_ the United t
Germany an e '
States or within Scandinavia. t
F;urth, the Jaw and economics t
movement in the U_nited Sta
abroad Jed to a new and increa tes and 1
sed interest in comparative com
This will be dealt with in more pany law .
Fifth this new interest in com det ail bel ow .
parative company Jaw was
perinane~tly coveredby a few nat not only
German Zeitschrift fii.r Unt<rneh ional company Jaw reviews such as the
mens-und Gesellschaftsrecht
Italian Rivista della SocU?tit, (ZGR) , the
and to a certain degree als
Revue des Societes, but a num o the French
ber
on the market such as the of new specialized law reviews appear ed
English International and
Corporate Law Journal (ICCJ Comparative
),that seemed for a while to ha
for the Journal of Corporate La ve made wa y
w StudU?s (JCLS), the Du
Busillf!ss Organiza_tion Law tch European
Review (EBOR), the Germ
mea_ntimemternationa!ly based, an, and in the
European Company and Fin
Review (E~FR)_,~nd the !Eu
ropean Compan y Law (ECL), ancial Law
by the Umvers1ties ofLe1den, Utr pu bli shed · ointl
echt, and Maastricht.
J y
. -;~ law In sucvie
h wasofthe
the UN
golden age of the ela
IDROIT p . . 1bora t'mn of
common prm. c1p
,..)
[
S s1'd s t e cou rts of er C
con eration. Th ic are mor l'k 1 ommonwealth.
is is sm
e ' ely to take f . coun t .a ler
countries are general] becaus nes such as
e the academics ore1gn
m their larger neighb~ ~ore decisions into
open to looking to thand law
rm. g states · But even then te wealth yerfs in such
. o experi · e
l. :
' I
he fact that they enc look
' I
; ~.I
! ~
I i 1
u
COMPARATIVE CORPORATE LAW:
nal CH. I THE BUILDING BLOCKS 11
nd
lVe abroad rarely results in the actual citation of foreign company law in
ns court decisions themselves. One reason for this may be the traditional
ire theory in Continental Europe that judges simply 'find the law' as enacted
~e, by the legislature. This, of course, is not true, as is shown very clearly by
many cases decided by the Second Senate of the German Federal
Supreme Court, which is responsible for disputes in company law.
A similar observation can be made for the European Court of Justice.
Ninon Colneric, the German Justice on that Court, remarked recently
that comparative law plays a much higher role in the decision-making of
the Court than one might assume from reading its decisions. The fact that
d the Court does not cite literature does not mean that it does not take legal
'· literature into consideration. Quite the contrary is true: sometimes even
special research notes on the treatment of a legal question in the member
y states are commissioned by the Court. Of course, the European Court of
Justice is special due to its nature and jurisdiction; it needs to consider
not only the law of the member state concerned in a specific case, but
more broadly the acceptability of its decision in all member states.
While company law has long been the domain of national courts in
the EU, this is no longer true. The European Court of Justice has
rendered quite a number of important decisions in the fields of company
law and accounting. For a long time, national courts were rather
reluctant to refer questions concerning harmonized company law and
accounting to the European Court of Justice. In the meantime, however,
the relationship between the judiciaries has become more relaxed. Most
recently, one of the landmark cases in company law and conflict of
company laws was the Centros decision of the European Court. Combined
t with the decisions in the subsequent cases of Uberseering and Inspire Art,
j this marked an end, at least within the European Union, to the seat
I
theory that had been so dear to German lawyers for so long. These cases
allow free incorporation in any of the EU member states, which has
binding effects in all member states under the incorporation theory.
. In concluding this section, it should be mentioned that, according to
some observers, the real impetus toward comparative company law is
provided by the forces of financial and other markets, with their scandals;
the needs of these markets do not stop at national frontiers. Although
true to a considerable extent, this is not the whole story. Comparative
company law is conceived, practiced, and reformed by persons such as
those dealt with in this section. Their actions and reactions depend on
many influences, not only on market forces. Yet the observation that
company law reforms, like many others, are driven by scandals (and
therefore often come too late and overreact) can be verified throughout
the history of company law and investor protection, and was seen most
recently in the Enron scandal and the shock waves which it sent through
company law in the United States and abroad.
TELAW:
I CORPORA
COMPARATIVE ING BLOCKS ------- Ca.1
I 12 --~
THE BUILD
***
. s the 1 relevance nd
of comparative
courts. Let's
CH.l
l
I " or Hop
Pro1ess
t law ior
s
. explam
t ' analysis
" leo-islatures,
d mies
aca e e concre a wyers, a·ally wit. h respect
' t e, espec1al business ) 1aw t
i:,~ • even mor e gener . h' h
corpora e th·s discussion te (and mor ·tuations in w ic of dj
howevermake ~mparative corporat?In addition t~ s~ diction, in which colle
rts Does c in cour · ~cc nt Juns b d
to cou . ecific relevance I ws of a duiere d courts look a roa follo
have any sp d t apply the a £ ·go Jaw, o 1 ?
courts are require o d to understand ore1 e persuasive va ue.
obviouslythey are fo~ce precedents have som . d Mathias Siems
. ? Do foreign · Gelter an
for gmdance. ticle Martm d Superfluous, or
I n an interestin~ recenCtar~s-Illegitimate anp L 35 (2014)), have
Fi ign ou AM. J . COM . . b
(Citations
· .d ble'2 . ore from Europe,
toEvidence h 62the use of foreign precedents y
I Unavoi a . empirical researc on
condu~d t~~Ynote in the introduction (c1
.tations omitted):
.al whether courts
I
I
courts. s
!:0
~:
. h" hly controversi
U ·t d States it is ig
b;•;lowed, or::~: ::~ ;;:'e1~
from foreign courts. Th If. divided on
0
d to refer to prece en s
academ_ic_debat;i:a~:
whether it is lef
d t
US
U.S. Supreme Co~rt itse \: the interpretation_ of t e . .
international
law, 16
,,.-generalprivatelaw,
139
civilprocedu~ 32}
unfaircompetition,45
COMPARATIVE CORPORATE LAW:
CH.1 THE BUILDING BLOCKS 15
Talking about the use by courts of foreign sources, we must mention
one interesting but bizzare experiment in legal history. The 1769
Portuguese Lei da Boa Raz<ioprohibited the (then common) use of Roman
law sources to resolve commercial disputes. This statute, however,
indicated that Portuguese courts, when applicable national rules could
not be identified, had to apply the laws of other "enlightened and polished
Christian nations" (interestingly enough, a commentator in the XIX
interpreted the reference as including all other European countries, but
not Turkey). In other words, courts were obliged to engage in a
comparative analysis, and apply foreign law. Contradicting the nomen
omen adage, the statute led quickly to irrational, contradictory and
arbitrary results. It was unclear which systems would be relevant, which
rules should be selected, and it was obviously impracticable for
Portuguese and Brazilian judges, lawyers and parties to understand and
apply foreign law. This approach was abandoned both in Portugual and in
Brazil, but not before several decades. None suggests replicating this
bizzare experiment, but we wanted to mention it because it is very telling
about the possible role of comparative law. It also confirms that, as we
observed beforehand not surprisingly, smaller countries with a limited
number of cases tend to be more outward looking than bigger systems.
For more on the Portuguese experiment and generally on the history of
corporate law reforms in Brazil see Mariana Pargendler, Politics in the
Origins: The Making of Corporate Law in Nineteenth-Century Brazil, 60
AM.J. COMP. L. 805, 815 (2012).
Another interesting and more recent example of courts of one country
relying or at least attentively considering decisions and scholarship of
another system is offered by Israel, whose judges often take into account
U.S. and specifically Delaware law. This is probably due to both the
extensive cultural connections between the two jurisdictions, in light of
the significant number of Israeli jurists studying and teaching in the
U.S., and the economic relationships between the two countries. Whether
this consideration for U.S. law is always correct and desirable is debated:
for a discussion focused on how Israeli courts have used the notion of
"good faith" in corporate law, see Itai Fiegenbaum & Jana Rabinovich,
Lost in Translation: "Good Faith" in Israeli and Delaware Corporate Law,
in Festchrift for Prof. Joseph Gross (A, Barak, Y. Zamir, D. Libai, eds.,
forthcoming in 2015 in Hebrew).
.•,,.
LAW'
IVE CORPORATE . CH. l
COMPARAT ING BLOCKS
L-----~T[!CORP
t6
H~ORAT
E~B~ U:I
ANDL:D
E LAW RPO
:-:,
LEGA L ; CH.
RATE
C~
LAW
!it t~i ;~N VQ E~.~E
~::i~~
AR:i?
CHE~ ma3 ,
also
AND THE ( "BEST SYSTEM - relic
. FOR THE . ht already be familiar with
ou reading this b~ok mig taken a general course on dis
Many ofl y enerally You might hav\ ) include a comparative mo
comparat~vela: gor other. courses ~hat l(ofen International Business COi
comparative a '
h as European Un10n aw,d mestic law courses your ex :
elemen\io~~c and the like. Also in pure 1y p:rative law aspects. It is pr
Transac , ed you to com th
m
. structors might have expos d legal families, for a t 1eas t th ree pl
1 few war s on
nonetheless usefu to say a h t h e no backgroun d in . compa f
ra ive S)
reasons: to familiarize the ~nes t a ;vthe methodological perspectives c~
law with the field; to clar1!y so~_ea~d to discuss some specific general Cl
shared by the authors of this bool ' d some economic data concerning c1
.
issues on comp~rative corpor
b . ateth'aw discuss
an
ion will provid . . . h
e 1ns1g h
ts t at C
different countries. We e1ieve is .
will be useful throughout the course.
1
The human mm · d eds to organize and systematize information,
ne .
even at the cost of some simplifications . In comparative law~ on~ of the
most important systematizations aggregates legal systems 1n d1ffere~t
legal families based on shared features. ?f course one of the basic
distinctions is between common law countries (generally, the U.K., the
U.S., Australia, New Zealand, and other former British colonies) and civil
law countries; civil law systems are also generally divided into French
civil law traditions and German civil law traditions (some comparativists
distinguish a ''Roman" and a "Germanic" tradition). Several other
important legal families exist that cannot be easily accommodated in the
common law/civil law distinction: examples are Scandinavian systems
(Denmark, Finland, Norway, and Sweden), Socialist or "non-market''
econom~es(the relevance of this group is fading for obvious reasons) and
also Asian systems ha~e distinctive features. In Africa and other pa~ts of
the world, together with the legacy of colonialism trad·t· 1 t 'b
legal t d ·t' ·
ra i wns are important, especially in certain , areas i -such 10na or ri a1
law. And of course non-secular legal as famil
t . Y
secular ones: in Arabic and Musli:s ems ~1so exist or co-exist with
j,
relevant. There are also syste th t count~ies Sharia is extremely
practitioners, must be consid:r:d ~~i acc~r~in? t? ~ome scholars and
I
major role in shaping Israeli corporate law and securities regulation, and
also on legal · scholarship in these areas in light of the extensive
relationships between Israeli and American law schools.
Focusing on the divide between common law and civil law, the
distinctive features are often identified in the sources of the law, the
model of legal education, and the approach to legal thinking. More
concretely, differences often pointed out, and too well known to be here
examined analytically, are the fact that in common law systems judicial
precedents are particularly important and often technically binding, and
that common law countries did not experience the codification of their
private law in the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries; in civil law
systems, on the other hand, statutory law seems to be more relevant than
case law, precedents are not binding, and codification played and plays a
crucial role in the development of the legal system. The role of the jury in
common law systems is also often mentioned as a basic difference with
civil law systems, as well as the way in which judges and justices are
appointed (generally, elected in some kind of political fashion in common
law, and selected through a purely technical exam in civil law countries).
We believe that these differences, which exist and are relevant, are
however often overemphasized and are, in any case, fading. For example,
if you are a lawyer in a civil law system and you need to research a legal
issue, of course you will look at the applicable statutory provisions, but
you will immediately also look at precedents and how courts interpret the
law. Even if precedents are technically not binding, they have a strong
persuasive authority, especially the ones of the higher courts. Keep also
in mind that, differently from common law countries, in civil law ones,
only a small percentage of cases are published and easily accessible in
legal journals. Similarly, statutory and regulatory law is becoming more
and more pervasive also in common law countries, especially in complex
technical areas such as commercial law or securities regulation; and even
in these systems it is often easy to distinguish a case from a precedent,
therefore reducing the binding value of the precedent. The role of the jury
in common law systems is also often exaggerated. In the U.S., for
example, approximately 2% of litigation actually goes to trial (most is
settled or dismissed before trial); and one of the most important
f. jurisdictions for corporate law, Delaware, has a Chancery Court that
l
In lighter -gray countries people drive on the right side of the street ,
and in darker-gray countries people drive on the left side. In general,
former British colonies follow the second rule, but a notable exception is
the United States (by the way, the historical roots of this difference are
interesting, and there are conflicting theories: we do not have space to
discuss them here, but if you are curious you should look it up). This little
example suggests how one should be careful in distinguishing different
legal families .
Having said that , in this casebook we will focus primarily on two
common law countries, the U.S . and the U.K., and on several civil law,
continental European countries (in particular France, Germany, and
Italy), and Japan, but occasionally we will also consider cases and
materials from other jurisdictions including Asia, Latin America, and
Eastern European countries. In our analysis we will often start from the
U.S. perspective, and then examine comparative differences with other
~------~c~o:M~P~A~R~A1
±20 THEBUILDIN
.al eriod), we believ_e,allows
ecially due to th~ c?lom_ ~or orate law regimes and
of other systems (es~
t the existing variat1~ns ;f£ !nt rules. The econornic
us to cap~ure moS : basis to discuss specific_~ ;: focus also justifies the spe
offers a rich enoug f the countries on wh1c effi
importance of some o . att
attention that we give them. U S. and the European Umon ~n pre
b ic distinction between the_ . d briefly, also because we will a ,
One as ces of law must be ment10ne ters In the U.S., corporate dit
termsbof kso: this issue in the followingtclhapthe federal legislature has "a :
. tate law even I·r mor e recenth Y internal a f~1.airs of rist ed
come ac · de
!aw ~s s d some' rules that affect e Jl
cess or composition of the
p1
intro
corpora utc1~ons
, for example in terms of
. 0 f th Sarbanes- x proxOy laecy
Act and the Dodd-Frank n,
board of directors (thmk _ elaws of the single member states govern C<
A t) In Europe, the national f h monization has been made
c . . .fiicant effort o1 tions ar It is obvious 1y 1mposs1
. "ble C
I corporations, but a s1gm a
I through European directives and regu al p~cts of EU. law, but suffice C
here to offer a eras h -course on the db generath asEuropean Umon. . an d must be t
I jurisdictions and legal families has been made by four economists: Rafael
La Porta, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W.
Vishny (their work became so famous that they are sometimes collectively
I
i
referred to as "LLSV''). In a series of papers starting in the mid-1990s,
LLSV have extensively studied the level of investors' and creditors'
protection in different countries and tried to correlate it with different
legal origins (in particular, English -origin, French-origin, German-origin,
and Scandinavian-origin).
,,...
, ' ,
..,,,.,,, ~ ' /
English-origin
French-origin.
Scandinavian-origin
INTRODUCTION
Any time you are faced with a corporate law problem, the first
question you have to ask yourself is what are the applicable laws
governing the issue at hand . In essence, what you have is a choice-of-law
determination, whereby you must determine which statutes and case law
precedents govern the internal affairs of the corporation. This question is
not only crucial from a practical point of view, but is also important, and
perhaps even more interesting, from a theoretical standpoint, because it
affects the way corporate law develops and influences both the legislature
and the judiciary in their rulemaking activity at a substantive level.
I
l
In the United States, corporate law is largely within the competence
of the states. While the federal legislature has adopted some governance
rules that are applicable to publicly held corporations, the internal affairs
of a corporation are for the most part subject to the laws of the state of
l incorporation. For obvious reasons concerning the common cultural and
historical background of the states, harmonizing initiatives such as the
enactment of the Model Business Corporation Act, and also a
phenomenon of imitation among states, there are significant similarities
among both the corporate law statutes and case law of the different
states; but meaningful differences still exist .
. As in the U.S., corporations in the European Union are regulated at
the level of the single Member States. From a comparative perspective,
however the differences that exist among different jurisdictions within
'
the European Union are more profound than the differences that can be
found in the United States among different states. Language and cultural
barriers and the path-dependency of legal systems affect, and to some
extent hinder the harmonization of European corporate law. In an effort
to harmonize 'Eu:r:opean corporate law, the European Umon . has enacted
several directives and regulations. These directives and regulations cover,
for example, the regulation of legal capital, financial statements, mergers
and divisions, shareholders' rights, takeovers, etc.
The starting point of our analysis in this chapter is that, generally
speaking, there are two choice-of-law principles that can be adopted in
29
'',.
CHOlCE OF APPLICAULI~ COHl'OHA'l'I~ LAW:-!ANU
~3~0
_______ l~tY
~ C~(!!
)M !.!.!..
_!:R~F~,(~m~I~.A~1~'(:!_:) P!:!
l•:'
.!.
1'.l'l
:..:
:'l.:..:
..:O;.:..
N:,________ 11.:J.
.
c.c;.,;.
"
in the U.S . and in other common law count.r.,t:A,lA • ~o •. mwr ~'. , 1~ !, t.ho "1
· · l e,,, a Iso re1erre
prmcip r d to as the "freodom of mcorporndon
'f . (' . .
pun c1p1,u. cont.n
Under the "incorporation principle," th e intornnl !'I ·nm~ o II cor11o;utu,_n for ll
laws of the state in which tho corpornt.10111.R 'l'hiM
are governed bY th e . . . . .. . ·I , l 1·
·1ncorpora t ed, meaning the 1\1r1 s
. · d1ct10n m which the pro ct < ur o to CHtn> 11-1h
.. .. t t ti · ·1
rlll,(U I
the corporation as a legal entity has been pe! foct.t•d. 11 . ur sunn o 11s ru < , corp,
th em· ternal affairs of a corporation are subJoct to .th0 lnws of lh Ht.nt.o of
. t Irn t sl.1h0• , nn cJ,
in H:'
· orporation even if the corporation does no bwnn oss m
inc no meaningful contacts with th e state, best'd os .h nvrng
has . .
rncorporntoc l
inco
there. The historical rationale for this rule is probably root •d in _th curt
colonial period, when England want ed to be able to r 'guluto _e n\ orprtROS cnn'
primarily doing business abroad'. as l_ongas t~ey_w~re_crca~cd 1~ hn~ land. acli
The formal process of incorporation, m these Juri sd1ct10ns, 1s quit e sunplo. rlll,(
In order to incorporate, it is generally sufficient to file the governing mi~
documents of the corporation (charter and bylaws) with the Secretary of in I
State or other similar office, and to pay a small fee. --.. 1.m
..fr
The second choice-of-law principle, which prevails (or us ed to pr evnil) Stf
in continental Europe, and more generally in civil law systems, is the so- 0f\
called "real seat approach." According to this rule, a corporation is subj ect of
to the laws of the state with which it has the strongest physic al sr
connection. This physical connection is known as the corporation' s "real ll .l
seat." The real seat of a corporation is defined in a variety of ways in rl
different systems, for example based on where the "center of th e Cl
administration" is located, which is determined by where the corporat e a
bodies (board of directors or shareholders' meeting) meet; or alternatively, 1
a corporation's real seat is located in the jurisdiction where most of the t
corporate purpose is carried on. A corporation doing business primarily in
France, for instance, would have to incorporate in France and would be
regulated by French law. The consequences of the real seat approach to
choice-of-law can be significant. For example, using again the ca se of a
corporation with its real seat in France, but which is formally
incorporated in the U.K., a French judge might conclude that the
corporation is subject to French law, and since the corporation did not
properly incorporate in France, it might even be treated as a partnership,
with members potentially facing unlimited liability for the obligations of
the corporation; in addition, several issues concerning the internal affairs
of the entity would be governed by French law, notwithstanding
incorporation in the U.K.
As you can see, these two choice-of-law principles have very different
effects. In a system based on the incorporation principle, corporations are
free to choose the state in which they prefer to incorporate indep endentl y
of where they are physically located or where they do business. In other
words, they can engage in regulatory arbitrage. On the other hand, under
~
CHOICE OF APPLICABLE CORPORATE LAWS AND
nd CH. 2 REGULATORY COMPETITION 31
on
~-,, the "real ~eat" app~oach, since the applicable law depends on physical
contacts with _aspecific jurisdiction, it might be impossible, or inefficient,
for_a corporat10n to choose incorporation in one jurisdiction over another.
This means that i~. countries that follow the incorporation principle, a
e, regulatory competlt10n can develop among states in order to attract
)f ~orporations . This type of regulatory competition, however, is much rarer
m systems following the real seat principle.
d
d Why do states compete to attract corporations under the
e
incorporation principle? Since a corporation can choose to incorporate in a
certain state without carrying on any business activity there, the answer
s
cannot simply be that a state is acting in order to attract more business
activity. There are probably two major reasons why states engage in
regulatory competition. One has to do with tax revenues. Because there
r)
might be state taxes or other fees that apply to corporations incorporated
f in a given jurisdiction, the desire for increased revenues can make it very
important for a state to attract corporations. In the U.S., for example, a
"franchise tax ," which is based on the shares issued, must be paid in the
state of incorporation (attention, this is not an income tax based on
earnings!). The proceeds from these taxes can be an important percentage
of the state's budget, especially in states with a smaller economy. It
should be observed that in some systems, however, these kinds of taxes
are not permitted, which is a potential disincentive for the development of
regulatory competition. The second reason for state regulatory
competition is that having a large number of corporations incorporated in
a state, and therefore subject to its laws, can be very profitable for the
local legal services industry. Lawyers and other legal constituencies can
therefore be particularly invested in regulatory competition for
incorporation.
You deserve a warning, however. The common wisdom that States,
especially in the U.S ., compete to attract and retain corporations, possibly
with the exception of Delaware, is questioned by some scholars. In a
brilliant article, Marcel Kahan of New York University and Ehud Kamar
of Tel Aviv University (but at the time of the article at the University of
Southern California) have argued that the existence of fierce competition
among states in this area is largely an urban legend. They list several
reasons to support their claim. As a side research project, find this paper
I
and keep it in mind as you continue reading: The Myth of State
Competition in Corporate Law, 55 STANFORD L. REV. 679 (2002).
Interestingly enough, both the incorporation and the real seat
principles often have exceptions. For example, even in the U.S., where the
incorporation principle prevails, there are some states that have adopted
so-called "pseudo-foreign corporation statutes." These statutes mandate
the application of some local state rules to corporations incorporated
elsewhere, if the corporation is primarily doing business within the state.
CHOICE Ol~ APPLI CABL E COIU'ORA'fl!~ LAWS AND
32 REGULATORY COMPETITION CH,2
One question we will discuss is whether these types of provisions are CH.2
compatible with the U.S. Constitution . There ar e similar exceptions with
~egard to the real seat approach. In Europe, whore the real seat principle internal
is or was followed in many countries (for example, France, Germany, exampl e
Italy), the principle ha s been eroded by the jurisprud ence of th e European r elatioru
govern e,
Court of Justic e, which-to put it briefly-considers it in conflict with the
law. Of
freedom of establishm ent principle set forth by the European tr eati es. In wh ereir
this chapter, we will consider th ese possible "exceptions" to the of a cor
incorporation and real seat principles. pi ercin1
In the U.S., the state of Delaware is the clear "winner" in the "market which,
for corporate charters," as the majority of the listed and the largest third p
corporations are incorporated there. Delaware snatch ed the competitive also ad
advantage in incorporation originally enjoyed by the neighboring stat e of A1
New Jersey . In considering the success that Delaware has had in wh eth
attracting the incorporation business, one question that comes to mind is the "g
how it maintains its competitive advantage over other jurisdictions. top" (
Wouldn't it be easy for other jurisdictions to simply "copy" Delaware 's mark1
corporate law statutes, therefore becoming more attractive? After all, effici e
there is no copyright on statutory materials. stake·
mino1
The answer to this question is, obviously, that simply copying comp
statutory materials is not sufficient to attract corporations. While by st
Delaware's statutory rules can be copied by other jurisdictions fairly craft
easily, one might argue that the real advantage of Delaware (and other man:
successful states in the incorporation market) is not so much in its ("rac
statutory provisions, but rather in the sophistication, specialization, and freec
efficiency of its judiciary. Delaware courts are highly specialized in shar
corporate law matters, partially as a consequence of the large number of regt
important and complex cases that they decide. This level of specialization not
of the judges, and the extensive body of corporate law precedent, is much oth1
more difficult for another state to replicate than Delaware's statutory pro
'' ' fill
provisions. Another reason that might make Delaware an attractive
inc
forum for corporate litigants is the fact that the Delaware Court of
me
• i Chancery is historically a court of equity, and therefore there are no jury ·.
COJ
trials.
.,i efl
; /
I As we have discussed, the "internal affairs" of a corporation can be di
·I
regulated by either the laws of the state of incorporation or by the laws of tr
the state where the real seat is located. The "internal affairs" of a rr
corporation generally concern relationships V
among shareholders,
relationships between shareholders and the corporation, relationships 1
between the corporation and directors, the inner workings of corporate
!
' bodies, etc. It is important, however, to understand precisely what t
l'
I
l corporate actions are included in the definition of "internal affairs." For
j
i example, a bond indenture, a contract concerning the issuing of bonds to
! obtain financial resources, is generally not included in the definition of
2
CHOICE OF APPLICABLE CORPORATE LAWS AND
CH.2 REGULATORY COMPETITION 33
internal affairs (at least in the U.S.). Therefore it can happen, for
exa~ple, .that a Delaware corporation will issue bonds and the
relat10nsh1p between the corporation and the bondholders will be
governed by a contract subject to New York law, rather than by Delaware
law. C?f_course, there are always issues that fall into a "gray area,"
wherem it can be debated whether the issue concerns the internal affairs
of a corporation or not . One example of this "gray area" is the doctrine of
pie:cing the corporate veil (Chapter 3), which deals with the situations in
which, contrary to the general rule, shareholders might be liable toward
third parties for the obligations of the corporation . In this chapter we will
also address this question.
Another policy question that we will address in this chapter is
whether regulatory competition-famously defined by Roberta Romano as
the "genius" of American corporate law-results in either a "race to the
top" or a "race to the bottom." In other words, does a competitive
marketplace for rules lead to the development and enforcement of more
efficient rules, rules that are sufficiently protective of the different
stakeholders involved with the life of the corporation, and particularly
minority shareholders and creditors ("race to the top"); or does
competition lead to excessive laxity in corporate law rules, brought about
by state legislatures and judges, who in order to attract corporations,
craft rules aimed solely at pleasing corporate decision makers such as
managers and controlling shareholders who decide where to incorporate
("race to the bottom")? Does regulatory competition simply result in
freedom of contract, flexibility, protections for directors and controlling
shareholders against liability? Prominent scholars have argued that
regulatory competition results in excessive freedom of contract and does
not provide adequate protection for minority shareholders, creditors, and
other stakeholders. Others advocate, however, that if a state is not
protective enough of investors and other stakeholders (again, especially
minority shareholders and creditors), they will not invest in a corporation
incorporated locally or, at least, ask for a higher return to compensate for
increased risk, therefore resulting in a higher cost of capital for the
corporation. Following this view, regulatory competition produces
efficient rules that strike an optimal balance between the needs of the
different corporate constituencies. We will have to discuss, therefore, if
the "market for rules," in corporate law, works well or is plagued by
market failures. It is quite interesting, also from a methodological point of
view, to look at the process of rulemaking as a "market" in which
legislatures, policy makers, and courts compete.
· One final caveat. The principles we discuss in this chapter concern
the substantive corporate law rules applicable to a corporation. They are,
as mentioned, choice-of-law rules, and must be distinguished from the
l
f
I issue of jurisdiction. Jurisdiction concerns the court or courts that have
CHOICE OF APPLICABLE CORPORATE LAWS AND
34 CH. 2
REGULATORY COMPETITION
different
th_e power to adjudicate corporate disputes, and can follow
federal
criteria. It is therefore possible that the courts of s~ate X (or t
apply
courts) have jurisdiction over a certain dispute, even if they ~uS
s our
the substantive laws of state Y. This possibility further complicate
~o
analysis, and raises also strategic procedural questions on where
that 1s
litigate. This is an issue that must be taken into account and
addressed in some of the cases presented.
FREEDOM OF INCORPORATION
y,
As we discussed in the Introduction, under the incorporation theor
state
the internal affairs of a corporation are regulated by the laws of the
of the
of incorporation. The incorporation theory provides that the laws
ration,
state of incorporation regulate the internal affairs of a corpo
in that
regardless of whether the corporation is in fact headquartered
is
state or has business connections therein. This rule, however, which
is not
generally followed in the U.S. as well as in other jurisdictions,
adopted
without possible exceptions. For example, some U.S. States have
es."
statutes commonly referred to as "pseudo-foreign corporations' statut
ular
These statutes are designed to require the application of a partic
ent
state's law when a corporation, although incorporated in a differ
In other
jurisdiction, has significant connections with a particular state.
seat
words, these rules tend to achieve a similar legal effect as the "real
e" is
approach." A famous example of a "pseudo-foreign corporation statut
§ 2115 of the California Corporations Code. Pursuant to this
provision,
it is
when a corporation meets certain requirements that indicate that
rate
predominantly doing business in California, some California corpo
sions.
law rules will apply. Other jurisdictions have adopted similar provi
these
In the U.S. t~ere has been a lively debate on the legitimacy of
the U.S.
-~ ~ statut_es, . specifically .on whether they are compatible with
following
1t Cons~1tution and/or v10late the "internal affairs doctrine." The
,.:1
lent exam ple of the application of§ 2115 of the C a 1·£ ·
1·1 case 1s an· excel
cd · 1 orn1a
'I
Corporat10ns o e to a business entity incorporated in Utah , b u t th a t was
,I
i · b us1ne
d 01ng · Ca i·fi
· ss 1n . .
1 orn1a
I
'I
'/ RESOURCES INC.
I Ross A. WILSONV. Lou1slANA-PACIFIC
iI Court of Appeal, First District, Division 2, California, 1982 '
! 138 Ca1.App.3d 216
GRODIN, P. J.
l . ·.
The question presented by this a
ss~on and
considerable significance, is whethe~pet:' o~e of first im~re
constitutionally impose its law r . ~ tate of ~ahforn1a may
shareholders upon a corporation whiche!u~r1n~ ·1cud mlulative voting by
om1c 1 e e sewhere, but whose
CHOICE OF APPLICABLE CORPORATE LAWS AND
CH.2 REGULATORY COMPETITION 59
corporation was located, i.e., where the board of directors met, to determine
the applicable law. The decision mandates the application of French (tax) law
le) to businesses that are established under French law and have a meaningful
1n connection with France. In this respect, even if the case presents peculiar
~d aspects, it can be considered a forerunner of the real seat approach.
ts 2. Do you think it might make sense to apply the laws of one state to
ts the internal affairs of a corporation and the laws of a different state to tax
re transfers of shares or to tax income? In other words, when do you think there
·e
d I is a rationale to decouple corporate law and tax law?
***
As discussed in the Introduction, several continental European
3 countries used to follow-and to some extent still do-the "real seat"
~ approach. Under the "real seat" approach, the internal affairs of a
corporation are regulated by the laws of the jurisdiction where it has its
"real seat." "Real seat" can be defined in different ways, but the definition
is primarily based on elements of "physical" contact between a
corporation and a particular jurisdiction. For example, the real seat of a
f corporation might be the state where most of the corporate business is
I
I
f
conducted or where the governing bodies of the corporation (especially the
board of directors) meet . One consequence of the real seat approach is
that corporations must incorporate according to the rules of the state
where their real seat is located. If they fail to incorporate properly in the
jurisdiction where the real seat is located-even if they are duly
t incorporated in a state in which they do not operate-there may be very
l serious consequences for shareholders, including denial of the benefits of
limited liability and/or treatment as partners of an unincorporated
business entity.
Beginning in the late 1990s, the European Court of Justice began
"attacking'' the real seat approach, arguing that it might be contrary to
the "freedom of establishment" principle set forth by the European
f Treaty. The Centros case below opened the door toward the abolition of
the real seat rule in Europe.
l Summary
It is contrary to Articles 52 and 58 of the Treaty for a Member State
to refuse to register a branch of a company formed in accordance with the
law of another Member State in which it has its registered office but in
which it conducts no business, where the branch is intended to enable the
company in question to carry on its entire business in the State in which
that branch is to be created, while avoiding the need to form a company
t
CHOICE OF APPLICABLE CORPORATE LAWS AND
60 REGULATORY COMPETITION CH. 2
there, thus evading application of the rules governing the formation of CH.2
companies which, in that State, are more restrictive as regards the
paying up of a minimum share capital. Given that the right to form a regist 1
Anpar
company in accordance with the law of a Member State and to set up
branches in other Member States is inherent in the exercise, in a single Ii
market, of the freedom of establishment guaranteed by the Treaty, the "·
fact that a national of a Member State who wishes to set up a company simih
chooses to form it in the Member State whose rules of company law seem Euro1
to him the least restrictive and to set up branches in other Member States I
cannot in itself constitute an abuse of the right of establishment. regis1
' '
That interpretation does not, however, prevent the :3-uthorities of the 1
Member State concerned from adopting any appropriate measure for Cent :
preventing or penalizing fraud, either in relation to the company itself, if to es
need be in cooperation with the Member State in which it was formed, or c1rcu
in relation to its members, where it has been established that they are in ofm
fact attempting, by means of the formation of a company , to evade their 1991
obligations towards private or public creditors established in the territory
of the Member State concerned.*** refu
THE COURT, gives the following Judgment
judt
Grounds Hoj-
By order of 3 June 1997, received at the Court on 5 June 1997 the
Hojesteret referred to the Court for a preliminary ruling under Article con
177 of the EC Treaty a question on the interpretation of Articles 52, 56 the
and 58 of the Treaty. for:
That question was raised in proceedings between Centros Ltd, a De
private limited company registered on 18 May 1992 in England and thE
Wales, and Erhvervs- og Selskabsstyrelsen (the Trade and Companies
Board, 'the Board') which comes under the Danish Department of Trade, fo1
concerning that authority's refusal to register a branch of Centros in es
Denmark. VO
El
It is clear from the documents in the main proceedings that Centros pl
has never traded since its formation. Since United Kingdom law imposes tr
no requirement on limited liability companies as to the provision for and SC
the paying-up of a minimum share capital, Centros's share capital, which N
amounts to GBP 100, has been neither paid up nor made available to the
co~pany. It i~ ~ivid~d into two shares held by Mr and Mrs Bryde, Danish Ct
nationals res1dmg 1n Denmark . Mrs Bryde is the director of Centros, b
wh~se registered office is situated in the United Kingdom, at the home of 0
a friend of Mr Bryde. I
Under Danis~ la~, . Centros, as a 'private limited company', is I
I
regarde~ as a foreign hm1ted liability company. The rules governing the
CHOICE OF APPLICABLE CORPORATE LAWS AND
of CH.2 REGULATORY COMPETITION 61
1e
a registration of branches ('filialer') of such companies are laid down by the
lp Anpartsselskabslov (Law on private limited companies).
le In particular, Article 117 of the Law provides:
Le "1. Private limited companies and foreign companies having a
y similar legal form which are established in one Member State of the
n European Communities may do business in Denmark through a branch ."
'S
During the summer of 1992, Mrs Bryde requested the Board to
register a branch of Centros in Denmark .
e The Board refused that registration on the grounds, inter alia , that
r Centros, which does not trade in the United Kingdom, was in fact seeking
f to establish in Denmark, not a branch, but a principal establishment, by
r circumventing the national rules concerning, in particular, the paying-up
l of minimum capital fixed at DKK 200 000 by Law No 886 of 21 December
1991.
Centros brought an action before the Ostre Landsret against the
refusal of the Board to effect that registration.
The Ostre Landsret upheld the arguments of the Board in a
judgment of 8 September 1995, whereupon Centros appealed to the
Hojesteret.
In those proceedings, Centros maintains that it satisfies the
conditions imposed by the law on private limited companies relating to
the registration of a branch of a foreign company. Since it was lawfully
formed in the United Kingdom, it is entitled to set up a branch in
Denmark pursuant to Article 52, read in conjunction with Article 58, of
the Treaty.
According to Centros the fact that it has never traded since its
formation in the United Kingdom has no bearing on its right to freedom of
establishment. In its judgment in Case 79/85 Segers v Bedrijfsvereniging
voor Bank- en Verzekeringswegen, Groothandel en Vrije Beroepen [1986]
ECR 2375, the Court ruled that Articles 52 and 58 of the Treaty
prohibited the competent authoritie 's of a Member State from excluding
the director of a company from a national sickness insurance scheme
solely on the ground that the company had its registered office in another
Member State, even though it did not conduct any business there.
liability, under certain conditions, would be more restric~ive than the CH.2
requirement to provide for and pay up a minimum share capital. justify
It should be observed, first, that the reasons P':t forward do not f~ll its reg
within the ambit of Article 56 of the Treaty. Next, it should be b?rne m T
mind that, according to the Court's case-law, national measures hable to contr:
hinder or make less attractive the exercise of fundamental freedoms to re{
guaranteed by the Treaty must fulfill four conditions: th~y 1;1ust be anotl
applied in a non-discriminatory manner; they must be JUS!ified by cond1
imperative requirements in the general interest; they must be suitable for comr
securing the attainment of the objective which the_y ~mrsue; and they that
ther ,
must not go beyond what is necessary in order to attam it. [. · .]
com 1
Those conditions are not fulfilled in th[is] case . ... First, the practice payi
in question is not such as to attain the objective of protecting creditors how
which it purports to pursue since, if the company concerned had ado
conducted business in the United Kingdom, its branch would have been eitl
registered in Denmark, even though Danish creditors might have been Me
equally exposed to risk. wh
of i
Since the company ... holds itself out as a company governed by the or
law of England and Wales and not as a company governed by Danish law, COJ
its creditors are on notice that it is covered by laws different from those
which govern the formation of private limited companies in Denmark and
they can refer to certain rules of Community law which protect them,
such as the Fourth Council Directive 78/660/EEC of 25 July 1978 based
on Article 54(3)(g) of the Treaty on the annual accounts of certain types of J·
companies (OJ 1978 L 222, p. 11), and the Eleventh Council Directive
89/666/EEC of 21 December 1989 concerning disclosure requirements in
respect of branches opened in a Member State by certain types of E
company governed by the law of another State (OJ 1989 L 395, p. 36).
Second, contrary to the arguments of the Danish authorities it is
'
possible to adopt measures which are less restrictive, or which interfere
less with fundamental freedoms, by, for example, making it possible in
law for public creditors to obtain the necessary guarantees.
, Lastly, the fact that a Member State may not refuse to register a
~;
ii branch of a company formed in accordance with the law of another
t
Member State in which it has its registered office does not preclude that
Why do you think that European law, at least accordmg to Mucciarelli s precluc
analysis, does not fully prevent this phenomenon? ?hould the Eur?pean incorpc
legislature, or Member State, do something to avoid forum shoppmg of anothe
bankruptcy laws? If so, what, based on the few information offered by the by thE
short excerpt from Mucciarelli? decisic
of esb
*** limit 1
Centros and Uberseering marked the beginning of a fundamental ownl:
shift in the interpretation of the principle of freedom of establishment by move
the ECJ. Soon after these two decisions were issued, the number of (
English "Private company limited by shares" in other Member States of
the European Union began to grow. The growth in the number of English
companies occurred primarily in Member States where access to the
corporate form was difficult due to administrative barriers. Response to
the growing influence of English corporate law in Europe was different in
each Member State.
ml
After Centros, the Netherlands adopted a law allowing foreign
Ami
~· companies to move their real seat to the Netherlands, but required them reni
;
/:
to comply with certain provisions of Dutch corporate law. The ECJ plai
rejected this approach in the Inspire Art case in 2003. In Inspire Art, the
:
/
i ren
court held that the law at issue similarly violated the freedom of the
establishment (30.9.2003-C-167/01, ECR 2003 I-10155). After Inspire sea
Art, it became obvious that European Member States would have to
·l
. I
I sh:
··/
I compete with English corporate law. As a consequence several States C01
'
?egan undertaking massive reforms of their national cor~orate law codes de
m an effort to keep pace with English corporate law. These reforms Tl
focused. ~specially on s~eeding up the incorporation process and pl
' I
Facts
Plaintiff is a Dutch corporation (Besloten Venootschnap [BV]) founded
in 1990 and which is registered in the [Dutch] companies' register in
Amsterdam and Haarlem. In 1992, plaintiff asked the defendant to
renovate a motel. After defendant rendered the promised services,
plaintiff refused to pay the remuneration and claimed that some of the
renovation work was poorly performed. After the defendant refused to fix
the alleged defects, the plaintiff did it. In 1994/95 plaintiff moved its real
seat from the Netherlands to Germany because the corporation's two
shares were acquired by two German nationals who were mainly
conducting plaintiffs business in Germany. Soon thereafter, plaintiff
demanded payment of 1.163.657,77 DM from the defendant as damages.
The trial regional court (Landgericht) dismissed the suit, holding that
plaintiff lacked legal capacity to bring the suit. The appellate court
(Oberlandesgericht) affirmed.
CHOICE OF APPLICABLE CORPORATE LAWS AND
94 REGULATORY COMPETITION CH. 2
representatives in Japan (Art. 933(2)) before it engages in business (Art.
818(1)). Individuals violating this requirement are jointly and severally liable
with the foreign corporation for any obligation that has arisen from such
transactions (Art. 818(2)). Also, a registered foreign corporation, which is
equivalent to a Japanese stock corporation, must publish its financial
statements annually (Art. 819(1)).
The standard story is that states make corporate law, with state
competition critically determining its content. This may be so, but
perhaps the relationship between the states and Washington is just as
determinative, because federal authorities can displace the states and
often do so on big issues. Corporate law issues can always go federal or
attract federal attention. The SEC is always on stand-by, and Congress
takes up issues that deeply affect the economy or the opinion polls . ·
[. ..J
11 Footnotes omitted .
~
CHOICE OF APPLICABLE CORPORATE LAWS AND
CH.2 REGULATORY COMPETITION 99
)le
ne
on Al_th ough managers historically are often seen to have had the upper
ha nd m fDelaware, they don't fully dominate there. This is not just
nt · · n. Delaware d oesn 't
· o,f state competit10
· · spite
)D
because o ' and. perhaps ism
~et;~em hdommate--or they themselves choose to be moderate-because if
or ~t i , t e game could move to Washington, where new players could
1d md~~e new results. Hence, local interest groups compromise and local
1e decision ~akers are evenhanded, even if local politics doesn't demand
al compromise or evenhandedness.
~r
Sometimes, the issue is so big-generating headlines in the media
r, and fears for the economy-that it necessarily attracts federal attention.
II Different coalitions can, and do, emerge at the federal level. When
~t cor~o.rate la':' stays in Delaware, the state limits the range of the first
.g decision-making stage by excluding corporate outsiders and public
y policymakers; sometimes managers and investors can make their deal in
Delaware and then unite at the federal level to fight off other forces. L
i .
n Probably more often than not, their interests are sufficiently similar that
both want the states and not the federal authorities to make corporate
r
law. But sometimes Delaware loses control of the agenda , usually when ..r";·.,"
:l the public is sufficiently motivated, because the economy is weak or !-'.>
•I • ~ :
t ~...~,...
because scandals dominate the media, and Congress acts. Congress t ,,' .
ousted Delaware most recently with Sarbanes-Oxley, after the Enron and t !, ....!-:
.
-... . .. .
. !' '
l WorldCom scandals hit the headlines. 1· ·. I' J . .. ;:
\,-- . - ,c
therefore are attracted by jurisdictions and rules that favor flexibility and E
103
TION PROCESS AND
-_Q~_____ iT~H~E!:!l~N~CC!OQR ~PEO~R~A~!:,~IM~IT!:!E~D~L~I~A~B~IL~I~T~
_!04 LIMITATIO NS ON ~ Y~=::::-::C~3
. these systems there are often specific CH.3
· es more time · 1nt f the articles f ·
complex and requir o mcorpora t·10n and
rules on the form and the ~onten oante control on the legality of the On tl
bylaws. Additionally, there is an ex f on conducted by public or quasi "difficult,
governing documents of th e corpor:a~y public Minimum legal capital is corporat{
public officers, such as judge_sor ; no di tors and in part for the protection very nar
also required for the protect wn _0 tchreE u ' a minimum capital of 25,000 Example
1e m
of share h olders. For examp . ' t a ejoint· ·•
stock corporation · , an d m · some "domina1
euros is necessary to mco~pora e ary Furthermore, specific and more (e.g ., in
t . higher sum is necess . . . d h. h comply,
coun r1es, a h f n of contributio ns m km , w 1c often
1
rigid rules apply to t. e. evabua inoindependent expert appointed by the corporat
· a fairness opm10n Y a . · narrow
reqmre
t In these systems, even 1·f the duration of the mcorporati .
on process
f
German
cou~ · . . h .
varies, it m1g t eas11y t a k e a few weeks ' and to incorporate is o ten more the corp
expensive than in common law systems. . In
In many c1v aw· il 1 countries however these strmgent rules have require
, ' stakehc
ast partially relaxed, probably as a consequence of
recen tl y b een at le . f . d. .d
o m ivi ua 11egis
·increase d latory competitio n and the desire . 1t some a1
regu . . . 1 · a ures
to create incentives for business activities. One n?table ex~mp e is J apan,
h. h abolished its minimum legal capital reqmrement m 2005. Japan,
; ~~ver, still requires articles of incorporation to be certified by a n?tary Tl
0
public and contributions in kin_d _to b_e evaluated ~Y a court-appomted ''body.'
expert. Despite recent changes, it is fair to say that m these systems the notion
incorporation process is still strictly regulated. ''body''
were c
These different approaches to incorporation are partially reflected in
the l
the rules on piercing the corporate veil. Simplifying the issue, it can be corp01
observed that in jurisdictions where it is "easier" to incorporate, courts as otl
f are often more willing to pierce the corporate veil on an equitable basis corpo:
.·i / when the plaintiff can establish some kind of abuse of the corporate Diffm
structure. Differences still exist even within common law jurisdictions. them
For example, U.S. and U.K. case law differ substantially on this issue, sever
with veil piercing being quite more common in the U.S. In fact, piercing of mode
the corporate veil is one of the most commonly litigated issues in U.S. - corp<
corporate law. In the U.K., on ·the other hand, piercing is less frequent. shar ,
For example, a leading British case of the 1990s, Adams v. Cape bodi1
Industries plc, held that piercing is appropriate ·only in case of fraud, or shar
when the corporation is established to avoid an existing obligation . A free ]
similarly restrictive approach was followed in three subsequent cases:
Ord v. Belhaven Pubs Ltd (1998), Prest v. Petrodel Resources (2013) and orig
VTB ~apital plc v. Nut:itek Inte:national (2013). In VTB Capital plc, one ope:
of t_heJ_udges obse~ved: 'The not10n that there is no principled basis upon The
which 1t can be said that one can pierce the veil of incorporation con
receives
some support from the fact that the precise nature basis and meaning of Eli:
or
t~ie principle ~re a~l somew~at obscure, as are 'the precise nature of
cor
circumstances m which the principle can apply".
THE INCORPORATION PROCESS AND
CH. 3 LIMITATIONS ON LIMITED LIABILITY 105
ByLawsi
of
"Company Name"
A Delaware Corporation
ARTICLE I-Offices
Section 1. The registered office of this corporation shall be in the
County of County, State of Delaware.
Section 2. The corporation may also have offices at such other
places both within and without the State of Delaware as the Board of
Directors may from time to time determine or the business of the
corporation may require.
ARTICLE II-Meetings of Stockholders
Section 1. All annual meetings of the stockholders shall be held at
the registered office of the corporation or at such other place within or
without the State of Delaware as the directors shall determine. Special
meetings of the stockholders may be held at such time and place within or
without the State of Delaware as shall be stated in the notice of the
meeting, or in a duly executed waiver of notice thereof.
Section 2. Annual meetings of the stockholders, commencing with
the year ... , shall be held on the . . . day of . . . each year if not a legal
holiday and, if a legal holiday, then on the next secular day following, or
at such other time as may be set by the Board of Directors from time to
time, at which the stockholders shall elect by vote a Board of Directors
and transact such other business as may properly be brought before the
meeting. Meetings may be held by telephonic conference call provided all
stockholders are present telephonically, or have expressly declined to
"attend."
Section 3. Special meetings of the stockholders, for any purpose or
purposes, unless otherwise prescribed by st~tute or by the Articles of
Incorporation, may be called by the President or the Secretary by
resolution of the Board of Directors or at the request in writing of
stockholders owning a majority in amount of the entire capital stock of
the corporation issued and outstanding and entitled to vote. Such request
shall state the purpose of the proposed meeting.
[... ] ~
ARTICLE XII-Amendments and
pre1
Section 1. The Bylaws may be amended by a majority vote of all
onl:
the stock issued and outstanding and entitled t_ovot~ at a1:y annual or sys
special meeting of the stockholders, provided notic~ of mtention to amend Co:
shall have been contained in the notice of the meetmg. del
Section 2. The Board of Directors by a majority _vote ~f the whole an
Board at any meeting may amend these bylaws, mclud1_ng Byl~ws pr
adopted by the stockholders, but the stockhol~ers may from time to time SE
specify particular provisions of the Bylaws which shall not be amended by
the Board of Directors. cc
t<
APPROVED AND ADOPTED this ... day of ... ,
n
0
C
Secretary
l
***
A well-drafted corporate charter and bylaws, as any contract, can be
a work of art. A bad one can be a receipt for disaster. A complex mix of
different skills is necessary in drafting the governing documents of a
corporation: negotiation skills, the ability to fully understand the intent of
the parties, the ability to foresee problems or specific needs that might
arise in the future, etc. There are some very important strategic
considerations that you need to make when drafting charters and bylaws.
The first one concerns which provisions should be included in the articles
of incorporation and which provisions should be included in the bylaws,
when there is a choice between the two. In some legal systems, for
example, there might be provisions that can only be included in one of
these documents in order to produce specific legal effects. An example is
the provision limiting the liability of directors included in article 8 of the
sample charter above that, pursuant to section 102(b)(7) of the Delaware
General Corporation Law, must be included in the articles of
4 incorporation.
, '
·-.
!,
I; You should also keep in mind the rules concerning future
amendments to the governing documents. Who has the authority to make
'r. the amendments and what procedural rules shall be followed? This can
' f,
'!J obviously be extremely important for your client, because she might want
, 1,
I to be sure that a certain provision will not be changed or erased without
her consent. For example, in most U.S. state jurisdictions, shareholders
must approve amendments to the charter, but the directors must initiate
I the amendment and require the vote of the shareholders. This implies
and ~he sh~reholders have a concurrent power to amend the bylaws . More
preci~ely, m s?me sta~es, such as Delaware, directors have this power
only if t~e art_icles_of mcorporation specifically grants it to them (opt-in
systems),_ while i~ other states that follow the Model Business
Corporat10n Act, directors have the power to amend the bylaws as a
default rule, unless the charter provides otherwise (opt-out systems) . In
e any ?~se, also ~ased on the bylaws, shareholders can sometimes indicate
s
prov:i,sionsof this documents that directors cannot amend (see Article XII,
Sect10n 2, of the sample bylaws above).
e
r In_ other countries, especially continental European civil law
countries and Japan, shareholders have a more central role with respect
to amendments of the charter and bylaws. A vote at the shareholders'
meeting is (almost) always necessary to approve such amendments, and
often shareholders, at least if they own a minimum threshold of shares,
can unilaterally call a shareholders' meeting to propose an amendment.
Keeping in mind what we discussed at the end of Chapter 1 concerning
ownership structures, this central role of shareholders is also a reflection
of concentrated ownership.
You should also pay attention to the procedural rules applicable to
amendments to the articles or bylaws. For example , if you are assisting a
minority shareholder who owns 20% of the voting shares of a closely-held
corporation, and there is one provision in the bylaws that is particularly
important for him (for example, a right of first offer in case other
shareholders intend to sell their shares), you might negotiate that this
provision can only be amended with a supermajority (for example, 85%),
in order to give your client a veto power over the amendment of the
clause. An interesting application of this strategy will be discussed in
Chapter 8 with respect to limitations to the transferability of shares.
A third element to consider is whether both the charter and the
bylaws are public documents, accessible to everybody, and also if a
provision included in the governing documents is enforceable toward
shareholders that have not voted in favor of it, future shareholders, or
third parties more generally. This depends of course on the_jurisdiction.
In the U.S., for example, the bylaws are not necessarily a public
document, · especially in closely held corporation~. Bylaws' prov~s~ons
might not be binding for a third party, and sometimes ~hese provi~ions
are only binding for shareholders that ap~roved the_m_.This also applies to
charters in Japan. On the other hand, m other civil law countries, the
governing documents are generally publicly available and, for this reason,
enforceable against third parties.
offer included in the. bylaws
Consi·d er, £or example , a right of first
. h . h
providing that shareholders, before sellmg t e1r s _ar~s to a third party,
must offer them at the same conditions to other existmg shareholders. If
THE INCORPORATION PROCESS AND
.!:.1.!:.1~8
_____ _2:L~I.:!:M~IT~A~T~I~O~N~S~O~N~L::!:I~M~
_____ ....::C~~
l:...:::T..:::E=D:.... :L:=I:::.A::::B'--I_L_IT_Y
a shareholder violates this provision and sells the shares t~ a third Party
breaching the pre-emptive right of his fellow shareholders m the U.S., he inc
might be liable toward the other existing shareholder~, but the buyer of joi
the shares, especially if he ignored in good faith the existence of th: right
of first offer, will surely become a shareh~lder_ and ~e able to exercise his
co
rights as such. In some civil law countr_i~s, i~ ":'hich the. bylaws are a
m
public document, the fact that the provis10n is mclude~ m the bylaws
w
creates a sort of unrebuttable presumption that the third-party buyer a:
knew (or could have known) about the limitation. to the free r•
transferability of the shares. As a consequence, the third party that li
bought the shares can be pre~ented ~rom exercising shareho~d~rs' rights C
(he might have a cause of act10n agamst the seller, but thats irrelevant C
for his position vis-a-vis the corporation). 1
;. · ..
. .
,.
•c ·,
THE INCORPORATION PROCESS AND
CH. 3 LIMITATIONS ON LIMITED LIABILITY 121
[... ]
The Second Directive's minimum initial capital requirement provides
no meaningful protection for creditors. The amount required, euro 25,000,
is trivial. It is also meaningless because it is unrelated to the debt that a
company may incur and to the sorts of business activities that a company
may pursue. Clearly, it makes no sense for a highly leveraged company
that transports radioactive waste to have the same minimum capital
requirement as a company with little leverage that designs software.
The legal capital doctrine assumes, falsely, that the fixed amount of a
firm's legal capital informs current and potential creditors of the
resources that a firm possesses and may not freely distribute to its
shareholders. In the real world, however, creditors (and potential
creditors) care neither about these resources nor about the legal capital
rules that are supposed to signal these resources.
The primary reason that creditors do not give significant weight to
legal capital is that as soon as a firm starts to operate, it can use its
capital to purchase assets that decline in value. Because a firm may
immediately begin to incur losses, either merely in the normal course of
business or by entering into one of the many kinds of unfair transactions
that Article 11 of the Second Directive does not cover, the initial paid-in
capital is a meaningless amount. In other words, creditors willing to
inform themselves about a firm's existing equity cushion must examine
its entire balance sheet. Moreover, creditors must consider the current
value of the firm's assets, not the value of such assets at the time of
purchase. The legal capital entry on the right-hand side of a corporation's
balance sheet thus provides no useful information to creditors. Even if it
did, creditors could just choose to deny credit to firms without satisfactory
amounts of paid-in capital. ·
Even assuming that creditors care about how much equity
shareholders really injected into a venture at its outset, requiring an
expert report on contributions in kind is of little benefit to them. First,
evaluation techniques leave experts with a very wide range of discretion.
This is true even when the expert must explicitly state "the methods of
valuation used," as the Second Directive requires. Second, experts can
never really be "independent." Even when a third party (like a judge)
chooses the expert, that expert will be a professional offering her
accounting and valuation services on the market. Normally, she will
2 Footnotes omitted.
THE INCORPORATION PROCESS AND
122
.
LIMITATIONS ON LIMITED LIABILITY
·ent, Kenny and Peggy Baatz (Baatz) appeal from summary judgment
dismissing Edmond, LaVella, and jacquette Neuroth, as individual
s of defendants in this action.
1ere
J.S. Facts
by Kenny and Peggy were seriously injured in 1982 when Roland
the McBride crossed the center line of a Sioux Falls street with his
uit automobile and struck them while they were riding on a motorcycle.
dd McBride was uninsured at the time of the accident and apparently is
·s). judgment proof.
ve Baatz alleges that Arrow Bar served alcoholic beverages to McBride
:ld prior to the accident while he was already intoxicated . Baatz commenced
~d this action in 1984, claiming that Arrow Bar's negligence in serving
:1t alcoholic beverages to McBride contributed to the injuries they sustained
~e in the accident. Baatz supports his claim against Arrow Bar with the
n affidavit of Jimmy Larson. Larson says he knew McBride and observed
e him being served alcoholic beverages in the Arrow Bar during the
d afternoon prior to the accident, while McBride was intoxicated.
Edmond and LaVella Neuroth formed the Arrow Bar, Inc. in May
1 1980. During the next two years they contributed $50,000 to the
corporation pursuant to a stock subscription agreement. The corporation
purchased the Arrow Bar business in June 1980 for $155,000 with a
$5,000 down payment. Edmond and La Vella executed a promissory note
personally guaranteeing payment of the $150,000 balance. In 1983 the
corporation obtained bank financing in the amount of $145,000 to pay off
the purchase agreement. Edmond and La Vella again personally
guaranteed payment of the corporate debt. Edmond is the president of the
corporation, and Jacquette Neuroth serves as the manager of the
business. [.. .] [T]he corporation did not maintain dram shop liability
insurance at the time of the injuries to Kenny and Peggy.
In 1987 the trial court entered summary judgment in favor of Arrow
Bar and the individual defendants. Baatz appealed that judgment and we
reversed and remanded to the trial court for trial. Baatz, supra. Shortly
before the trial date, Edmond, LaVella, and Jacquette moved for and
obtained summary judgment dismissing them as individual defendants.
Baatz appeals. We affirm.
. .•r
I
THE INCORPORATION PROCESS AND
_!1!2§.8
_____
I
_!L~I~M~IT!:A~T!:.!I~O~N~S~O~N~L~IM~IT~E:'.!D::..L::::=IA.=B=-=Ic:::L_IT_Y
____ ---.::~
CH.3
Individual liability by piercing the corporate veil.
Baatz claims that even if Arrow B~r, Inc. is the licensee, the capital
l corporate ve1·1 sh ould be pierced ' leavmg. theA Neuroths,. · as the
corporf
shareholders of the corporation, individually ha?le. ~o~poration shall be not ex
considered a separate legal entity until there 18 s7:fficient reason to the reason
persor
contrary. When continued recognition ~fa c~rporat10n as a separ~te legal $150,(
entity would "produce injustices and meqmtable conseq_uences, then a no e,
court has sufficient reason to pierce the corporate veil. Factors that inade
indicate injustices and inequitable consequences and allow a court to to
pierce the corporate veil are: unde
1) fraudulent representation by corporation directors; corp<
dete1
2) undercapitalization; simi:
3) failure to observe corporate formalities; so.\
pree
4) absence of corporate records;
5) payment by the corporation of individual obligations; or forr
6) use of the corporation to promote fraud, injustice, or illegalities. tha
req
When the court deems it appropriate to pierce the corporate veil, the cor
corporation and its stockholders will be treated identically. sp1
Baatz advances several arguments to support his claim that the st~
corporate veil of Arrow Bar, Inc. should be pierced, but fails to support ab
them with facts, or misconstrues the facts. UI
cc
First, Baatz claims that since Edmond and La Vella personally E
guaranteed corporate obligations, they should also be personally liable to s1
Baatz. However, the personal guarantee of a loan is a contractual a
agreement and cannot be enlarged to impose tort liability. Moreover, the r
personal guarantee creates individual liability for a corporate obligation,
the opposite of factor 5), above. As such, it supports, rather than detracts
from, recognition of the corporate entity.
Baatz also argues that the corporation is simply the alter ego of the
Neuroths, and, [that accordingly] the corporate veil should be pierced.
Baatz' discussion of the law is adequate, but he fails to present evidence
that would support a decision in his favor in accordance with that law.
When an individual treats a corporation "as an instrumentality through
which he [is] conducting his personal business," a court may disregard the
corporate entity. Baatz fails to demonstrate how the Neuroths were
transacting personal business through the corporation. In fact, the
evidence indicates the Neuroths treated the corporation separately from
their individual affairs.
Baatz next argues that the corporation is undercapitalized.
Shareholders must equip a corporation with a reasonable amount of
'l' HE I NCORPORATION PRO CFSS AND
CH . S L IMITATIO .,
NS ON LIMITED LIABILITY 129
cl:lpital ~or th nat ur e of th . . .
corpornt1on was sta rt ed with e busmess . mvolv<.-! d. Dnatz claims ih e
not explain how thnt . . only_$5,000 m borrowed capitul, but doos
11
reasonable amount of am~)tU t failed to equip the corporation with a
capi a 1: In add"t'1 10n, B aa t z fui ·1s to cons1'd er th e
personal guarantees to a
$150 ,000 , and the $SO o6o
y off
st0
th0 pu:ch_ase contract in the amount of
no evidence that th~ cor ck_su?scnption agreement. There simply is
inadequate for the O t' poration s capital in what ever amount was
to individual hperah10n of th~ b':1~iness.Normally questions relating
s are
h ld o1der hab1htY resu lt'mg from corpora t e
undercapitalizati
corporate liabilit ors SdOU ~Ot be reac~ed until th~ p~imary question of
. t· Y etermmed . Questions depending m part upon other
d.et ermma ions
. are not normall Y rea dy £or summary Judgment
· . However,
1
simp ~ assertmg tha~ the corporation is undercapitalized does not make it
so. Without ~ome evidence of the inadequacy of the capital, Baatz fails to
present specific facts demonstrating a genuine issue of material fact.
Fi~~lly, Baatz argues that Arrow Bar, Inc. failed to observe corporate
formalities be_cause none of the business' signs or advertising indicated
that the busmess was a corporation. Baatz cites SDCL 47-2-36 as
requiring the name of any corporation to contain the word corporation,
company, incorporated, or limited, or an abbreviation for such a word. In
spite of Baatz' contentions, the corporation is in compliance with the
statute because its corporate name-Arrow Bar, Inc.-includes the
abbreviation of the word incorporated. Furthermore, the "mere failure
upon occasion to follow all the forms prescribed by law for the conduct of
corporate activities will not justify'' disregarding the corporate entity.
Even if the corporation is improperly using its name, that alone is not a
sufficient reason to pierce the corporate veil. This is especially so where,
as here, there is no relationship between the claimed defect and the
resulting harm.
In addition, the record is void of any evidence which would support
imposition of individual liability by piercing the corporate veil under any
of the other factors listed above in 1), 4) or 6).
In summary, Baatz fails to present s~eci~c facts that w?uld allow the
trial court to find the existence of a genume issue of matenal fact. There
· · d'cation that any of the Neuroths personally served an alcoholic
1s no m i 'd N · h ·d
beverage to McBride on the day of the acci ent. or _1st .ere any evi ence
· d' t· th a t the Neuroths treated the corporation m any way that
m 1ca mg . .
would produce the injustices and meqmtable conseque~ces necessary ~o
· 'f · · th corporate veil. In fact, the only evidence offered 1s
sti
Jllh Y _piercTinhg £e we affirm summary judgment dismissing the
ot erw1se. ere ore,
Neuroths as individual defe nd ants.
THE INCORPORATION PROCESS AND
130 LIMITATIONS ON LIMITED LIABILITY
Ctt. 3
***
WALKOVSZKYV. CARLTON
Court of Appeals of New York
18 N.Y.2d 414 (1966)
FULD,J.
This case involves what appears to be a rather common practice in
the taxicab industry of vesting the ownership of a taxi fleet in many
corporations, each owning only one or two cabs.
The complaint alleges that the plaintiff was severe!~ injured four
years ago in New York City when he was run down by a taxicab owned by
the defendant Seon Cab Corporation and negligently operated at the time
by the defendant Marchese. The individual defendant, Carlton, is claimed
to be a stockholder of 10 corporations, including Seon, each of which has
but two cabs registered in its name, and it is implied that only the
minimum automobile liability insurance required by law (in the amount
of $10,000) is carried on any one cab. Although seemingly independent of
one another, these corporations are alleged to be "operated ... as a single
entity, unit and enterprise" with regard to financing, supplies, repairs,
employees and garaging, and all are named as defendants. The plaintiff
asserts that he is also entitled to hold their stockholders personally liable
for the damages sought because the multiple corporate structure
constitutes an unlawful attempt "to defraud members of the general
public" who might be injured by the cabs.
The defendant Carlton has moved to dismiss the complaint on the
ground that as to him it "fails to state a cause of action".
[. ..]
The law permits the incorporation of a business for the very purpose
of enabling its proprietors to escape personal liability but, manifestly, the
privilege is not without its limits. Broadly speaking, the courts will
disregard the corporate form, or, to use accepted terminology, "pierce the
corporate veil", whenever necessary "to prevent fraud or to achieve
equity''.
[... ]
In the case before us, the plaintiff has explicitly alleged that none of
the corporations ''had a separate existence of their own" and, as indicated
above, all are named as defendants. However, it is one thing to assert
that a corporation is a fragment of a larger corporate combine which
actually conducts the business. It is quite another to claim that the
corporation is a "dummy'' for its individual stockholders who are in reality
carrying on the business in their personal capacities for purely personal
rather than corporate ends. Either circumstance would justify treating
a THE INCORPOR
CH.3 LIMITATIONS o:~ON PROCESS AND
. IMITED LIABILITY 131
the corporat10n as an age t .
· · I b t d"
prmcipa u a 1fferent result n and pier · t h e corporate veil to reach the
cing
. would foll · ~ach case. In the first, only
ow m
a 1arger corporate entity would b
the other, the stockholder e held financially responsible while in
stockholder is conducting th bwo':1ldb~ personally liable. Either 'the
. be liable·e·f husmess
. h e will m h.is m .
. d.iv1dual
not. If h e 1s, 1 . capacity or he is
as his personal liability is' e Is not, then, it does not matter-insofar
being carried on by a larger" co~cer~ed-that the enterprise is actually
en erprise entity"
[.. .] .
Reading the complaint in th·
do not believe that th is case most favorably and liberally, we
allegations required to ere can . re d from 1·t s averments
be gathe th e
defendant Carlton. 11
spe out a vahd cause of action against the
CH. 3
[. .. ] . . t' h h
1 h Id is that a partic1pa mg s are older of
Wh~t I would me~e y o ublic interest, organized with capita decid
than
~orpora~10n vested 1~itiiti:s ~hich are certain to arise in the ordina:l
msuffic1ent to meet 1~ , business may be held personally responsib{
course of _th~~~rpo~:~: corporate' income is not sufficient to cover th: intei
for such habihties. . b the statutory minimum or wh ente
cost of insurance premmms a ove f . _ere Rus:
. . . t fi ances dwindle under the pressure o competition defa
m1tial~y adequa et in d1'nary and unexpected liability, obviously th~
bad times or ex raor aga
shareholder will not be held liable. and
Th deft
1 t es of corporate enterprises that will be discouraged as a
efondy .Y? allowing the individual shareholder to be sued will be the
resu 1t o a ec1s10n . . b h am
t h ose sue h as the One in question , designed
. solely to a use t e corporate
wh
privilege at the expense of the public mterest. est
NOTES AND QUESTIONS
Ch
'
1. Let's start with a· side issue, one not exactly centered on piercing the of
veil. In Baatz, the plaintiffs based their complaint on dram-shop liability
provisions, and in particular on the rule stating that bartenders can be held
liable for the damages caused by an intoxicated client, if they served him
a:
liquor when he was already clearly intoxicated. In lots of countries there are
p
no similar provisions, and it might in fact be extremely difficult, if not
s
impossible, to hold a bartender liable under similar circumstances. It can be
interesting, especially when discussing this in a culturally diverse group, to
a
J
consider the pros and cons of dram-shop liability.
2. In Baatz, the Court strongly disagrees with the way in which the
plaintiff considers the personal guarantees given by individual shareholders
for the benefit of the corporation. For the plaintiffs, it confirms that the
corporation and the shareholders are acting as one single entity, but for the
. -i
J Court it proves the opposite. Who do you think is right?
\
'
3. Did you find Judge Keating's dissenting opinion in Walkovszky
convincing? Do you think that the conclusion of the majority would allow
private parties to make a mockery of justice, and use the corporate structure
·;
,,
'· to avoid liability in a way that is clearly contrary to the spirit of the law?
'
4. What are the possible economic consequences of easy piercing?
Could it adversely affect business activity, and therefore hinder economic
growth? Is there any possible inequitable consequence of piercing? Consider,
for example, the position of "innocent" creditors of the shareholders that
might be adversely affected as a consequence of piercing.
***
. The doctrine of piercing the corporate veil also exists in the United
Kingdom. Notwithstanding the fact that the two previous U.S. cases were
THE INCORPORATION PROCESS AND
156 LIMITATION S ON LIMITED LIABILITY ~
This
structur1
instrum1
its busir
(securiti
number
instrum
in te rme
,_r provide
also l:
subord i
NE
that s1
losing
· isinf
right 1
have 1
appoi 1
inter£
prote ,
blurr
.. ~
corpc
,, ~
princ
pay
corp ,
(
I'
, · ....
s1m1
suer
po s1
rigb
I som
Ade
pro ·
t adc
. ' .., adc
r. ,''
•. ;1
a
......
CHAPTER4
•••
INTRODUCTION
This chapter discusses selected issues concerning the financial
structure of the corporation. There are of course almost
endless
instruments to provide the corporation with' the funds i{ needs to carry
on
its business: equity (shares), debt in the form of bonds and deben
tures
(securities representing a loan, generally issued and distributed to
a large
number of investors; for the sake of brevity we will refer to
these
instruments as ''bonds"), financial loans obtained from banks and
other
intermediaries and third parties, commercial loans obtained from
providers, and so on. We will focus our attention on shares and bonds
, but
also briefly discuss one important issue concernmg equita
ble
subordination of shareholders' loans.
Needless to say, the basic distinction between shares .and bonds
is
that shareholders are residual claimants of the corporation, and they
risk
losing their investment and not obtaining any dividend if the corpo
ration
· is in financial distress, while bondholders generally have a contra
ctual
right to receive interest and the principal. For this reason, shareh
olders
have more significant administrative rights, in particular voting
rights to
appoint and remove directors, while bondholders have limited power
s to
interfere with corporate decisions, and their rights are
primarily
protected contractually. Financial innovation has, however,
somehow
blurred the distinctions between these securities . For examp
le, a
corporation can issue subordinated bonds, for which the repayment
of the
principal is conditioned on the prior payment of other creditors,
or that
pay a variable interest rate based on the economic performance
of the
corporation. In terms of financial risk, these instruments can
be more
similar to shares. Conversely, shares with enhanced economic
rights,
such as a minimum dividend, can be issued, making the shareh
olders'
position potentially more secure: Si~il~rly, in terms. of a~min
istrati:e
rights, there might be shares ~1th hm_1ted or no voti_ng r1g~ts
, a~d 1n
some legal systems it is possible to issue bonds w1~h voting
rights.
Additionally, bond indentu:es (the cont:acts regulating bor_ids) often
provide covenants that significantly re~tric_t th_e fre~d?m of direct
ors_ to
adopt certain decisions, for example d1stributing d1v1dends
0
or seeking
additional credit.
159
_!
1_!!6
!!_
0 _____ _ I N~
1~\N~C~IN~G~T~H~E:....:C~O.:..:H:.:..P..:::.O
_.EF_!.: ..:.
R=-A;;..:T'-I'-O_N
_____ --.:~
De awHre, however, that different legal rights are relevant o~ly when
tlwre is a chunce of enforcement . For example, the contr~ctual right of a
bondholder to the repayment of the princi~al ~as_very httle meaning or
consequence, economically, if the corporat10n is insolvent and does not
have the funds to make any payment.
In 1958 Franco Modigliani and Merton Miller, two finance scholars
published a' groundbreaking paper on the financial structure of th~
corporation, introducing the "Capital Structure Ir~elev~nce Principle"
(the article, entitled "The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance and the
Theory of Investment" was published in 48 AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW
261 (1958)) . They both won the Nobel Prize for this contribution. In short
the Modigliani-Miller theorem posits that in an efficient market, in th~
absence of asymmetric information, agency costs, taxes, and bankruptcy
costs, the value of a firm is unaffected by how it _isfinanced (for example,
the balance between shares and bonds), and its dividend policy. Of course
in the real world the limit of the theorem is that the hypotheses on which
it is based are totally unrealistic: taxes, bankruptcy, agency costs, and
information asymmetries exist, and market efficiency is highly debatable.
Consequently, the reality is that financial decisions have a profound
impact on the value and profitability of the corporation.
The chapter is organized as follows. First, we will discuss classes of
shares, focusing on the flexibility existing in different jurisdictions for
creating categories of shares with different economic and administrative
rights. We will also consider some important protections for shareholders,
and specifically pre-emptive rights in case of issuing of new shares, and
class voting. Second, we will concentrate on selected problems concerning
bonds: different legal strategies used to protect bondholders, statutory
limits to the issuance of bonds (when present), and interpretation of the
bond indenture. Finally, we will illustrate the problem . of equitable
subordination of shareholders' loans.
_!1~6~2
______ __!F'._!l~N~A~N~C~I~N~G~T~H~E~C~O~R~P~O~R:.:A:.=-=-T::..:IO::..:N:..;._
_____ -!:~
;!
J ,j
:i
di~ded into two or more classes, the shares of each class shall be
f+.,
/ ! designated to distinguish them from the shares of all other
. l
·' . i
,;, iI
l_ i
"•t
l -~
\
CH.4
FINANCIN 163
G THE CORPORATION
classes. . Shares wh· h
. t ri .bution
dis of d" ·d ic are entit. 1ed to preference in the
common shares. IVI Sh ends or. asse t s sh all not be designated as
.
th e d"1str1bution ares.d which a re not entit. 1ed to preference in
of d"
even if identified b iv\ end s or assets shall be common shares
designated as pre£eya cdahssor other designation, and shall not b;
rre s ares
Italian Civil Code Ar . .
ticle 2351-Voting Rights
1. Each shar e grants the right to vote
2. With the exception of . . :
bylaws can allow th . provisrnns m separate statutes, the
with voting rights r e_:ssuance 0 ! shar~s. without voting rights,
conditioned u on s1m1_e?-to specific dec1s10ns,with voting rights
will of a pariy Ti:c:fic events ~ot. merely depending on the
exceed half of th. . mlount of hm1ted voting shares cannot
e capita.
3. · The
· bylaws
h . .
can provid e £or 1·1m1tat10ns to the voting rights of
a sindg1e s ar~holder independently from the amount of shares
owne ' or scaling voting rights.
;h ~n th e absence of special provisions, the bylaws can allow
e _1ssuan~e. of multiple-voting shares also with respect to
specific_ decis10ns or_conditioned upon specific events not merely
dep~nd1ng on t~e will of a party. Each multiple-voting share can
attribute a maximum of three votes.
'
CH. 4
FINANCING THE CORPORATION
165
***
We have seen above that the Italian legislature provides for several
limitations to the issuing of different classes of shares, even if it has
recently abolished the pre-existing absolute prohibition of multiple -voting
shares. But what is the situation in Europe and other systems more
generally with respect to listed corporations? In several countries
multiple-voting shares, with some limitations, are allowed, in others they
are not. Also with respect to nonvoting shares the situation varies from
CH. 4 171
FINAN(.;INU Tim COHPOJlATION
emal_market/company/docs/shareholders/study/final_
------------:--=u/intat
t Available http://ec.europa.e
report_en.pdf
172 FINANCING THE CORPORATION
1%
0% 0% 0%
0%
Denmark Finland France Ireland UnitedKingdom
_!11_7!4
______ jF~IgN~AN~C:'..-!I:.£N~G~T~H~E~C~O~R~P~O:::.:R:::A:..:.T.=..:I=-=O=-=N-
·~
sh?wed that multiple vo~ing shares can be necessary. As a consequence
\
this _dr~ft allows t?~issuance of multiple-voting shares with the
p ermission °~
~he _M1~1stry of Economic Affairs, the Ministry of Justice
and oth:r m1n1stries 1f the issuance is in the best interest of the stock
corporat10n or of general economic development (§ 12 subs. 2 sent. 2). By
~------~F~IN~A~N~C~I~N~G~T!._H~E~C:::,:O~R~P
.!178 ~O~R~A:..=T~IO~N~==-~=--..:::.~
MARCO VENTORUZZO, ISSUING NEW SHARES
AND
PREEMPTIVE RIGHTS: A COMPARATIVE ANA
LYSJS3
12Richmond J. Global L. & Bus. 517(2013)
Introduction
[ ] One fundamental area in which [Eur?pe~n and U.S.
· d.: corporate
laws] 1verge concerns how they regulate the 1ssu mg of new shares, in
particular preemptive rights-a problem rarely a ddresse db ·
Y comparative
corporate law scholars. [. · .] -
The issuing of new shares by a corporation is often
. · t·10n. I !'act when new shares are issued and not a reci~e for
11tiga n .1
1
, offered oto existing
sh are h lders shareholders may suffer two types of damages ._ n the one
h d ohareh,olders' voting power within the corporat1·
t::oth:r hand, the value of their investment can be reduced
price is lower than the actual value of the shares.
·
0n 1s d.l d
1 ute . On
if the selling
3
Footnotes omitted.
CH. 4 FINANCING THE CORPORATION 179
Th ere are three basic sets of rules that contribute to strike such a
balance: rul es conc: rning the allocation of powers between directors and
shareholders to decide on the issuing of new shares, preemptive rights in
case new shares are sold, and fiduciary duties of directors engaging in the
sale of new shar~s. Th~ purpose of this essay is to consider how different
legal _syst .ems st ~ike this balance in regulating the issuance of new shares,
focusing 1n particular on preemptive rights. The comparison is not only
~mpo~tant for the relevance of the problem, but also because it
illuminates some of the fundamental differences in the corporate
governance philosophies underlying different legal systems.
[. · .] Focusing on these systems is particularly apt because the two
models follow nearly opposite approaches. In the U.S., directors enjoy
broad po~ers in th~ issuing of new shares, and there is greater freedom of
contract in regulating preemptive rights in the corporate charter. Under
this system, shareholders are mainly protected through directors'
fiduciary duties. In Europe, shareholders are protected through statutory
rules that mandate preemptive rights. Shareholders have the power to
waive preemptive rights, but only in limited circumstances.
One might argue that European systems still follow the approach
adopted in the U .S. until roughly the 1960s, and a possible explanation is
that Europe did not experience the same separation between ownership
and control that occurred in the U.S. The comparison will allow
exploration of a more general difference between shareholder protection
in the U.S. and in the civil law systems of continental Europe, namely,
the fact that the former jurisdiction relies more on ex-post litigation, and
the latter on ex-ante mandatory rules.
[... ]
Part I: U.S. Law
Competence to Issue New Shares
In the U.S., the power to issue new shares is primarily entrusted to
the board of directors. Directors enjoy a great degree of freedom in issuing
new shares; however one important limitation is that they can only issue
the number of shares authorized by the articles of incorporation.
Generally, corporations have outstanding s~ares, which are. shares
already sold to shareholders tha~ form the ~~pital of the ~orporat1on '. but
the articles of incorporation provide for add1t10nal auth?r1zed shares that
directors can issue and sell . For example, a corporat10n can have 100
. g shares held by two shareholders, but the articles of
0 t t d · · f
u s an intion can authorize the issuing o a it10na dd' · 1 200 h
inco s are s. If
. rtpora
d1rec ors wan . to
t to 1·ssue more than .the additional 200 shares, they ne ed
obtain shareholders' approval to increase the number of the authorized
shares.
§_Q_
______ JF~I~N~A~N~
~l.£!N~
C G!.-:T~
· E~C~OH~~R.!!l:.
:::.::
E:.::IA
:..::..
...:'0
T::..;
J:....;:
O;_N~-=--~~-~~
.!180 4
--
. .
This rule gives sh ar eholders some control over th e financial structur
. h t d"l t
.
of the corporatwn. a S les of shares th at m1g 1 u e sh are holderse '
h. f the corporation above the thres h old se t bY th e au th orized
owners ip o b t d by sharehold ers as an amendment to the articles of
shares must e voe .
. t·
mcorpora wn.
The practice however, 1s to prov1·de £or a num b er of
'
authorized shares significantly larger t h an th e nu mber of out t d.
. s an 1~g
th
sh ares, so a 1t ·f new financ ial resour ces are neede d, direct ors can easily
issue new shares. In contrast to European law, iss~:g · · h ·
news tres i~ .the
U.S. is substantially and practically in the ~ands o irec~ors. n addition,
minority shareholders in corporations with a c_on~rolhng shareholder
derive little protection from this rule be~ause maJor1ty shareholders can
consent to increase the number of authorized shares.
One exception to this allocation ~f powers i~ e~tablished by M.~.C.A.
§ 6 21(£) which requires shareholders approval 1f (1)the shares are issued
for ·consideration other than cash, and (ii) the voting po~er of shares that
are issued comprises more than 20 perce~t of the voting power of the
outstanding shares. Also in listed corporations,_ shareholde~s' appro~al _is
necessary when the issuing of new shares might determine a shift m
control. Rules enacted by the NYSE, the NASD, and the American Stock
Exchange require a vote at the shareholders' meeting when a listed
corporation issues an amount of new common shares exceeding 20% of the
outstanding ones, if the issuance is not made through a public offer for
cash.
Preemptive Rights
Another way to protect shareholders in the event new shares are
issued is to grant them a preemptive right to purchase these shares. In
this case, shareholders who want to avoid the dilution of their
participation can acquire pro-rata the new shares paying the required
consideration. Of course, this protection is effective only to the extent that
shareholders have the financial means and the willingness to buy the new
shares but if they do, no dilution will occur.
The traditional approach in the U.S. was that shareholders enjoyed
preemptive rights .... More modern corporate statutes [have however
abandoned] this approach and generally deny preemptive rights unless
the governing documents of the corporation opt for them. The default rule
is t~at shareholders do not have a preemptive right in case of issuance
of
new shares, unless the articles of incorporation (or sometimes, the
bylaws) expressly provide so. In Massachusetts this rule was adopted
in
1964, under chapter 156B, section 20 of the general corporation statute
.
The M.B.C.A. and Delaware law also provide for similar rules.
Notably, there are some differences in how preemptive rights are
s~ructured . ~ome statutes allow shareholders to opt-in to preemptive
rights, both in the charter and in the bylaws of the corporation. The effec
t
-
CH. 4
FINANCING THE CORPORATION 181
is obviously different bee .
approval is necessar; t ause if _the rule is in the charter, shareholders'
could be able to amendo i:m~ nd it, while if it is in the bylaws, directors
shareholders' right with0 ut shareholders' consent. It follows that
forth in the articles s fa:e more P~otected if the preemptive rights are set
0 mcorporation.
Alternatively, a different . .
corporate statut . approach followed by a mmority of
Under this _es provides an opt-out mechanism for some corporations.
ule but the re~-~e, sfh~reholders enjoy preemptive rights as a default
r ' ar ices O Incorporation can waive them.
[... ]
Directors' Fiduciary Duties and Other Limitations to the Sale of New
Shares
A delicate issue that might arise is whether directors are allowed to
freely sell shares only to some shareholders therefore altering the
balance _of P?wer within the corporation. In g~neral terms [... ] when
preemptive rights do not apply, directors can sell new shares (or treasury
shares) as they see fit. This freedom is, however, not unlimited. Consider,
for example, a situation where the charter of the corporation provides for
a supermajority of two-thirds of the votes to approve certain
extraordinary transactions, such as a merger. One shareholder owns 60%
of the outstanding shares, and another one owns 40%. Can the directors
sell shares only to the first shareholder, thus bringing his participation
above the 66.6% threshold and giving him absolute control over those
transactions? In this case, the solution should not be found in preemptive
rights, but rather in directors' fiduciary duties and in the principle of
equal treatment of shareholders.
Part II: European Law
The European Framework: The Second Company Law Directive
The Second Company Law Directive, enacted in 1977 and amended
several times sets forth a harmonized regulation of the formation of
corporations focusing in particular on legal capital and its maintenance
and alterati~n. Its breadth spans from the minimum amount of capital to
eligible contributions and from purchasing of. owned shares to
distributions to shareholders. For ~he purposes o~ this essay the_ relevant
· · a re contained in Articles 25 1 applicable to
provis10ns . publicly ·.held
. Two key principles need .to be emphasized here. First,
corpora t ions. · · · 1 b
. l p graph 1 provides that any increase
Art IC e 25 ' ara in capita must e
'd d ' Id ers ' meeting.
. . 1e 29
Secon d , Ar tic
d ec1 e upon b Y the general shareho . . · d d th h
establishes that when the capita 1 1s increase an e ne~ s are~ are
'd · h th shares must be offered on a preemptive basis to
pa1 1n cas
shareholders in e · l t db
proportion to the capita represen e Y th err · h
s ares.
182 FINANCING THE CORPORATION
.::.::.=------------------------Ca. 4
These two provisions establish a minimum level of harmoniz t'
that is very different from, and arguably opposite of, the Amear·ion
h . 1can
regulatory model. The European approac gives more powers to th
shareholders' meeting in deciding the issuing of new shares ~
mandates preemptive rights as a general rule when shares are iss;eda;
. cas h .
. 1n
a cons1'd erat1on or
To get a clearer sense of how the general provisions of the Second
Company Law Directive have been implemented in some Member State8
it is helpful to examine some specific European jurisdictions. '
I
l
Q!!!-~4~-----F~IN~AN~C]l' ING THE C
h ORPORATI
the news ares proportio 11 ON 183
difference with U.S. la;a. Y to their stake int .
shareholders that exerc· is ~hat, in a cl 1he corporation. Another
right to buy the new i~e their preemptive o~e{-held corporation, the
additional preemptive r~ ~;es pro rata, but r: t do not only ha~e the
not bought. Hence if g on the shares th t ey can also exercise an
. ' a corporatio h a other shareholders have
them exercises her preem t . _n as two sharehold
percentage of shares that ~hive right, she has the rig~:
t f h e other sh h
:n
d 1
Ion Ybonehof
o a so uy t e
perce~ age_ o t e corporation's c . are older refused, increasing her
ex~rcise t~is additional right of r apital. Only if shareholders do not
third parties. p eference can directors sell the shares to
. similarly
The law. is not
it. comes t o ISsuing
1 . resp t t
different c 1ear with ec o preemptive . rights when
. h . a specific rule for
c asses of share s. Th ere is
non-vot ing s ares issued b r d
Consolidated Law on Financey T~~te corpo~ations: Article 145 of the
different option in the corpo~at is ~ule provides that, in the absence of a
have a preemptive right on sh e cf arter, holders of non-voting shares
are not issued holders of th aresho the same class. If non-voting shares
' ese s ares have a t' · h
classes of shares that are iss d M preemp ive rig t on the
view that this rule is th ue .. ost commentators have expressed the
e express10n of a more general pr. . 1 h
preemptive rights include the right to su b scri'b e sh.aresincip e,_w ere
of different
· ·f . .
categories ~ the capital increase does not respect the proportion between
the categories of shares already outstanding.
Statutory Limitations to Preemptive Rights
Pree!11ptive rights c~n be_limited or excluded only in four specific and
narrow circumstances, hsted 1n Article 2441 I.C.C . The first circumstance
applies when the resolution approving the capital increase provides that
the consideration for the new shares must be a contribution in kind. The
rationale is the same as that adopted by U.S . courts to limit contractual
preemptive rights included in the corporate charter in the absence of a
specific provision: the interest of the corporation to receive exactly the
property it seeks to acquire trumps the interest of shareholders not to be
diluted. The law suggests, however, that, even in this case, it is not
sufficient that the resolution indicates a contribution in kind, but also
that a specific business purpose for the contribution in kind be shown in '""
order to not elude the right of shareholders to maintain their stake in the
corporation.
The second case in which preemptive rights do n~~ app_lyis, pursuant
to Article 2441, Paragraph 5 of the I:C.C., ~~er~ the interest of the
. · ·t" The scope of this prov1s1on 1s clearly broader and
Corpora t 10n requires 1 . . .
more blurred, but a few examples ca~ be derived from co:p?rate practice.
· t' · goi·ng public 1t needs to have a m1n1mum number
'.
When a corpora .ion 1sd r to be admitted · · ·
to a stoc k exc h ange. The 1n1tial
Ofsh are h old ers 1n or e
-- -·-- -- - --
~1~8~4
______ -=-F~I~N~A~N~C~IN:....:..::;.;G~T~H_E
______ ~ca.4
_C_O_R_P_O_R_A_T_I_O _N
public offer must, therefore, be_made to a broad range of investors, and
preemptive rights woul~ be an msurmounta~le obstacle to_the creation of
a widespread ownership structure. In this case, the mterest of th
corporation to be listed arguably requires that preemptive rights be
limited. This may occur, for example, when a corporation wants to attrac~
a new shareholder in order to become part of a corporate group, or to
exploit the business relationships and expertise of the new shareholder.
[A] third possible exclusion of preemptive rights can be based on an
intention to compensate employees with shares of the corporation.
Pursuant to Article 2441, Paragraph 8 of the I.C.C., when new shares are
offered to employees, a maximum of one-fourth of the new shares can be
sold without granting existing shareholders a preemptive right. It should
be noted, however, that the limitation on preemptive rights can only
affect 25% of the newly issued shares in order to curb the possible
dilution of existing shareholders.
The fourth and last situation in which preemptive rights can be
limited applies only to listed corporations. This is a relatively recent
innovation introduced in 2003 and inspired by German law. Article 2441,
Paragraph 4 of the I.C .C. provides that the charter of a listed corporation
can opt for the possibility of increasing the amount of outstanding shares
up to 10% of their number without granting preemptive rights . The
rationale · of this rule is to give more flexibility to listed corporations in
designing their financial structure by allowing the issuing and selling of
new shares without the time -consuming offer to existing shareholders
required by preemptive rights. In a listed corporation, when shares are
traded on a liquid regulated market, the risk of shareholders' dilution is
more limited: existing shareholders that want to maintain their position
in the corporation can, in fact, easily buy additional shares on the market.
As mentioned above, these four exceptions to mandatory preemptive
rights are the only ones allowed: contribution in kind, interest of the
corporation, shares offered to employees, and 10% of the outstanding
shares in listed corporations. Only in these cases can the stake of a
shareholder in the corporation be diluted if the shareholders' meeting so
decides. The law, however, provides for specific rules concerning the
issuing price of the new shares in case of limitation or exclusion of
preemptive rights, in order to avoid an economic damage to investors. The
selling price of the shares cannot, in these cases, be lower than a fair
price determined through specific procedures.
More precisely, in the -first three cases listed above, the directors
must present the shareholders with a proposal indicating the issuing
price calculated on the basis of the actual value of the corporation, taking
into account, in the case of listed shares, their market price in the last six
months.
CH. 4
FINANCIN
G THE CORPORATION 195
meeting is necessary for an .
Act, Art. 199(2), Art. 20 2 ( f(i~suance of _ne:v shares (Japanese Companies
3
charter provision or by a spe . f'
unles_s it 1s delegated to the board by a
is effe~tive for only one year. c~::esolution of the_sharehold~r's ~~eti1:g that
it similar to the rule ado t d . you see the rationale of this d1stmction? Is
Civil Code, discussed in pp f,e m paragraph 4 of Article 2441 of the Italian
ro essor Ventoruzzo's article above?
***
A very delicate issue co b' . ·
the £allowing . Consi'd er a legal m ming class voting and pre-emptive right is
t .
andatory p _ t· . sys em in wh'ich shareholders do have
: ) I re hemp ive rights (or pre-emptive rights are granted by the
1
Yaws · n sue a system, if different classes of shares are outstanding it
can happen that a shareh ld
o er 1oses control · of ·
the corporat10n as '
consequence of a capital increase . Would the shareholder be entitled to aa
separate vote on th~ issuing of new shares? The "Mondadori litigation" in
!taly addresse~ !his problem. The case is intriguing also because it
involved ~r. Sil:71? Berlusconi, the well-known Italian media mogul and
former Prime Minister. A little bit of additional background is, however,
necessary. As we mentioned before, under Italian law (Article 2376 of the
Civil Code), when different classes of shares are outstanding, a
shareholders' meeting resolution that adversely affects the rights of a
class of shareholders must be approved also by a separate vote of only the
holders of the shares of the affected class. Now, imagine the following
scenario. A corporation XYZ has issued 100 common shares (voting on the
election of the , board) and 100 limited-voting shares voting only on
amendments of the governing documents and the issuance of new shares.
All shareholders enjoy mandatory pre-emptive rights, and if only shares
of one class are issued, holders of all classes can subscribe them
proportionally. Shareholder A o~ns 60 common ~hares and controls the
corporation because he can appmnt the board of directors. Shareholder B,
however owns all the 100 limited-voting shares, and 40 common s~ares.
Consequ~ntly, B controls the majority of the votes that can be cast in the
general shareholders' meeting of all the share~olders competent to
·
au th orize th ·
e issu ance of new shares (200 shares), since he controls 100 +
40 votes, versus on ly 60 controlled by A. The general shareholders ,
. .
· d h £ B can decide to issue 100 new commons h ares. If
meeting an t ere ore ' ·
rights, A wi·111ose contro I of t h e
' · their pre-emptive ·
both A and B exercise ·
. B ·nb come the new controlling h h Id
s are o er, owning ·
a
corporation and wi e h I fact A will be entitled to subscri be
. . f th common s ares. n '
maJority o e h s (SOshares) while B will be able to subscribe
60/200 of the 100 new s arhe (l 4 0/200) As a consequence after the
on s ares ·
70 of the new :omm common shares (his original 60 plus ' 30), and B
transaction, A will own 9 0 . umstances is A entitled to a separate vote
110 (40 + 70). Un de r these circ '
h res to approve the issuanc .
e of new shares,
only by holders ~f co~mo~f ~icl~ 2376 of the Civil Code?
arguing the apphcabihty · . .
196 FINANCING THE CORPORATION
Ca. 4
~
E
A CORPORATE LAW SAGA: THE MONDADORI CAS
n involved) is
The "Mondadori case" (from the name of the corporatio
de a translation
extremely long and complex and it is not possible to inclu
ide an account of
of the major judicial decisions here. Instead we will prov
ons written by
the facts and legal issues, and an excerpt of legal opini
originated in 1989
famous jurists consulting the parties. The litigation
that also tells you
and some parts of it dragged on until 2013 (a fact
The case concerns
something about the duration of litigation in Italy . .. ).
and a listed
control over Mondadori, a leading Italian publisher
fight between two
corporation, and saw a bitter financial and judicial
Berlusconi and his
major Italian entrepreneurs: on the one hand, Silvio
Benedetti and his
Fininvest corporation, and on the other hand Carlo De
CIR corporation. They are pictured below.
Silvio Berlusconi
--. .,
.t
7
.. ~-
Carlo De Benedetti
-
CH,4 FINANCINGT
Milan where Mondadori has itseh ~tle of Segrate," from the town near
in the 1980s Berlusconi and F·1e~ quarters. To make a long story short,
:Mondadori. At the end of the
shareholders: Berlusconi and his
n;~~~st acquired ~ significant stake in
s, ~ondadori had three relevant
through CIR (roughly 16%) a d ~ up (with roughly 8%), De Benedetti
O
class of shares they owned; Berlusconi did not own enough common
shares to block this resolution. Pursuant to the appellate rules, in fact, in
case new shares of only one class were issued, they had to be offered to all
shareholders. In the light of the ownership structure, if the capital
increase would have been accomplished, De Benedetti, so far holding the
majority of the limited-voting shares, would have obtained also a majority
of the common shares, and acquired control of the corporation and the
right to appoint the board of directors. The question was if, in this
scenario, holders of common shares had to separately approve the capital
increase because it damaged their position (since the controlling
shareholder would lose control). If the answer would have been
affirmative, Berlusconi could have vetoed the issuance of new shares and
kept control.
Pursuant to Article 2376 of the Italian Civil Code, a separate class
vote is necessary whenever the general shareholders' meeting approves a
resolution that "adversely affects" the "rights" of a class of shareholders.
Does the fact that one shareholder loses control due to the issuance of
new shares adversely affects the rights of a class of shareholders
)
(
pursuant to this rule? Due to the conflict among the parties, and the legal
uncertainties, the capital increase was not pursued, but several law
professors and lawyers issued legal opinions on this matter, and these
opinions have been published in law journals.
According to the opinions of some scholars, Article 2376 of the Italian
Civil Code does not apply in this scenario:
"The shareholders' meeting resolution does not envisage the
issuance of a new class of shares with preferred rights nor does it
determine any change of the current balance between common
~
shares and preferred shares: on the contrary, it increases the
. number of common shares, which results in a dilution of
.
I preferred shares. In this way, it strengthens the position of the
common shares with respect both to the voting rights and to the
cash-flow rights. Therefore, it cannot be said that the rights
attached to the common shares are adversely affected. The
opposite is true" (R. COSTI, in Giur. comm., 1990, p. 571).
"The shareholders' meeting resolution affects only one kind of
interest, i.e., the interest attached to the common shares to
maintain the same voting power. Such interest shall be protected
only by the pre-emption right. Therefore, in this case, Art. 2376
I.C.C. does not apply since there isn't any prejudice to a legal
entitlement deemed as 'a right' nor, above all, to 'a right of a ,
class of shares"' (P. FERRO LUZZI-B. LIBONATI, in Riv. dir.
comm., 1991, I, p. 708).
CH. 4 FINANCING
THE CORPORATION 199
Other scholars exp ressed a dif!' . .
"When th . . i.erent opinion:
e capital is raised th .
not deemed to be f£ ' e rights of the different classes are
distribution of new ha ected when theh planned issuance and
. s ares togeth er wit . the exercise of the pre-
emptive right have th f; · · the shareholders in
· t aming
' e e i.ect of m am
th e same position th h 1
terms of voting powe:y de d before t~e capital increase (both in
the pre-emptive rights~oil~sh-flow rights). When th~ exercise of
between classes of h not prevent the alterat10n of power
shares, it would be ns ares caused by the distribution of new
ecessary to call a se~ara t e meeting . f h
h old ers of the affected stock o t e
the exercise of the : In t~e case discussed hereby, since
shares is not suffici::t~:ptive right _by ~he holders of common
before a separat . order to maintain the same position as
appro;e the tra e mt~eti,?g of holders of common shares must
nsac wn (F · D'ALESSANDRO , 1n . G·
1990, pp. 587-58 8). iur. comm.,
~-. First of all, consider the relevance of opinions by legal scholars and
pract;,t10ners _(so-c~lled ''pro~v~ritate" opini~ns, froi_nLatin "in the interest of
truth ), especially 1n some civil law countries. ObVIously these opinions have
no binding force, but they are often respected by courts and administrative
agencies, and can be important also to avoid the risk of liability .
2. We agree with the first two opinions, Article 2376 of the Italian
Civil Code does not apply to this case. As hinted in the excerpts reprinted, the
key issue is that the "rights" of a class of shares have not been altered here:
this would be the case, for example, if a preference in the payment of
dividends would be reduced, or limitations to voting rights would be
introduced. In our case, there is only a factual change in the position not of an
entire class, but only of one shareholder who happens to have the majority of
the common shares. Obviously this is not desirable for the shareholder losing
control but technically it is not an adverse modification of the rights of one
class. A substantive reason also supports this conclusion. Since under Italian
(and European) law shareholders have pre-emptive r~ght~, a shareholder
having the majority of the common shares and a minority of preferred,
limited-voting shares has probably decided or accepted this ownership
structure. There must have been a point in time when the shareholder, for
CHAPTER 5
CORPORATE GOVERNANCE
•••
INTRODUCTION
"Corporate Governanc " · . .·
th e is an ambiguous term. Narrowly defined it
concerns
. . e powers ' rights d d · f · '.
(m particu 1ar, shareholders' , meeting
an uties o the different corporate bodies
and directors and when it exists as
a. separate body. , the
. board of supervisors
· · ' · the
or auditors), and deals with
mternal orgamzat10nal structure of the corporation and its functioning.
!n a broader sense, however, it also includes other legal and economic
mstruments that affect the conduct of directors and shareholders: in this
broader sense, for example, the market for corporate control and
takeovers regulation is also a governance mechanism in the sense that
the possibility of a takeover can "police" the conduct' of directors. More
generally . one might argue that, directly or indirectly, corporate
governance can include all rules that have an effect on the governing
bodies of the corporation including, for example, rules concerning the
financial structure of the corporation, or shareholders' agreements.
In this chapter, we will focus on corporate governance in a fairly
narrow perspective. We will first consider the different corporate
governance models that can be found around the world, discuss the
composition of the board, and finally focus on one of the fundamental
relationships defining the governance of the corporation, the one between
the shareholders' meeting and the board of directors. In particular we will
discuss the often blurred line that divides the powers and competences of
the shareholders from the ones of the directors. Needless to say, as in
other parts of this book, it is i~possible to c?ver everything: we selected a
few topics to make the discuss10n more specific, concrete, and relevant.
219
220 CORPORATEGOVERNANCE ~
' '
CH. 5 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE 221
e l
Mode
[On~tier Anglo..SuonGo1"ernanc I
J!
.5
0
"'
~
I shareholders'meeting I
·ITwo..tiel'GermanModelI
Iboard of supervisors[A¢"ichtsrat]I
'
fshareholdersmeetin
, g[HauptversammlunIg]
,.
'
/ TraditionalLatin Model/
/ shareholders'
meeting[assemb1ee,junta, assemble-a]J
I evaluations and financial issues (e.g., confirming the fair price of newly
issued shares when required). One variation of the Latin model worth
mentioning can be found in Brazil, where listed corporations can, as a
controlling body, either have a permanent or a temporary "fiscal board"
(conselho fiscal). For further information on this model, and ~mpirical
data on its use, see B. S. Black-A. Gledson de Carvalho-E. Gorga ,
Corporate Governance in Brazil (2009), available on www.ssrn.com, and
also, if you read Portuguese (which you should), E. Gorga, Direito
Societario Atual, Elsevier, 2013, 263 ff.
In Germany, during the National Socialist dictatorship, a general
corporation statute was enacted in 1937 (substituted with a new statute
in 1965). In terms of governance, one distinctive feature of the 1937
German Corporation Law was the so-called Fiihrerprinzip , or "rule of the
lead~r," according to which-in line with the dom inating i deology-the
President of the Vorstand could adopt decisions also without the consent
of the other members of the board and, in addition , the Vorstand had to
manage the corporation not only in the interest of the shareholders but
also of the people and of_the State (§ 70 AktG 1937: "wie der allge~eine
Nutzen von Volk und Reich es forden") We will come b k t th" ·
later. · ac o Is Issue
CH. 5
_:::.:;:.;...;;'-------~~
Co
R~PPORATE G
. OVERNANCE
One mteresting ch 223
~
. 11y 1ollowed aracteri f
partia also . s ic of the Germ
("Mitbestimmung') T in other t ~n governance model,
. · he expr . sys em, is "co-determination"
representation of emplo . ession refers t O th d
t' Th' Yees in the b e man atory
corpora ions. . is ~o-called worker , oard ?f ~upervisors of larger
today was mamly introduced b t~ co-d~termmat10n as it is structured
because the German coal d Y e Alhed Forces after World War II
st ~~l conglomerates had supported th~
Third Reich and the Geri:n
an military · Ar guablY, some large mining
.
en t_e~prises, an d their controllin
facilitated the Nazi rearma g shareholders or directors had
. . ment, and one Of th e ideas. '
determmahon was that a more "democratic" underpinning co-
. h wor k ers • representative · · of the board,
composition
wit
. di ctatorships and s,
. ht -wmg
rig · dwould. preve n t ns. k Y an·iances between
future. Consequently, the sum u~trial potentates to occur again in the
corporations in the coal and sI'ers~ry boards of several newly formed
t
of the workers. After this rest ee t m. US ry had to include representatives
set into place by the West ruclliurn:i,gof th e coal and steel industry was
ern a es m the Weste t fG
this structure became legally b' di £ rn s~c ors o ermany,
industry in 1951 pursuant to the;:;. ~g CorDthe e~tire_ coal and steel
11K· b · . mmg o- etermmation Act (Montan-
.
. with
t 1 an d coa1 compames
estimmungsgeset
.1.t,1.itth 1 000 z) • which required a 11see
more an , emp 1oye~s to have a supervisory board consisting of
eleven members, five of which were appointed by th e emp1oyees, an d five
bY t.h e shareholders. The eleventh board member had (and has) to be
appomted by both groups.
In 1976, workers' co-determination was expanded to all corporations
by th~ Workers Co-Determination Act (Mitbestimmungsgesetz). According
to this statute, all corporations with more than 2,000 employees must
have a supervisory board in which half of the members are appointed by
the shareholders and half by the employees. The chairman ·of the
supervisory board, appointed by a two-thirds majority of the members of
the board, has a casting vote. If the supervisory board does not reach a
two-thirds majority to appoint the chairman, the representatives of the
shareholders appoint him or her, and the representatives of the
employees appoint the deputy chairman. Moreover, all corporations with
more than 500 employees must have a supervisory board in which one-
third of board members are appointed by the employees ("One-third
Workers Co-Determination Act" or "Drittelmitbestimmungsgesetz").
Although generally all German corpora~ion~ fall under the scope of the
workers co-determination, co-determination does not apply to
corporations with a political, confessional, charita~le, s~ientific, _arti_stic,
or journalistic purpose since this would be considered an un1usti_fied
vi l t' f th fundamental rights of the owners of the corporations
press, e t c. Th e
. . German
o a 10n
. o f ed of speech religion,
. .
r egar d mg ree om t upheld , the Workers Co-Determmat10n Act
·t · al C .
ons t 1 ution
Ciu:· our . .
b · t ,\ of 1976 by argmng that, for corporations with a
( 1.r1it estimmungsgese z1
224 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE Ctr
~
different purpose than the ones mentioned above, shareh?lder~' Propert
rights are sufficiently protected by granting a double votmg right to thy
chairman of the supervisory board appointed by the shareholders in th:
absence of an agreement between shareholders and employees (see
Constitutional Court as of 1/3/1979-1 BvR 532, 533/77, 41 9177, 419/78, 1
BvL 21/78, BVerfGE 50, 290). Although some members of the super~isory
board are appointed by shareholders, and some by employees, there 1snot
a distinction concerning the legal duties of board m~mbers. Con~equently,
all members of the supervisory board have to a~t m the best interest of
the corporation and all members of the supervisory board can_be held
liable for a violation of this duty. Nevertheless one has to consider that
German corporate law follows a rather broad definition of the best
interest of the corporation taking into account the interest of the workers,
the creditors and the shareholders as a whole.
Interestingly enough, several other European legal systems provide
for some form of co-determination, of course with notable local variations:
Austria, Denmark, Finland, France, Luxembourg, the Netherlands,
Poland, and Sweden (in France, for example, the number of
representatives of the workers on corporations' boards is lower than in
Germany). A proposal for co-determination was even considered in the
United Kingdom, just before the "winter of discontent" (the winter of
widespread strikes in 1977-1978 that lead to Thatcherism), in the so-
called "Bullock Report." The effect of workers' representations in the
Anglo-Saxon model would have been even more profound than in
Germany because in this latter case the workers only appoint members of
the supervisory board, not of the managing board; in the British proposal,
on the other hand, the representatives of the workers would have been
seated in a board with managing functions. The idea was however
abandoned. The European Union also has entertained the idea of
harmonized legislation on this issue, but no proposal has ever reached a
sufficient level of consensus. .
.., I
, .· ·
What could be the causes and consequences of co-determination for
~xampl~ wi_th_respect to labor law? The following excerpt offers s~me
:f 1nterestmg ms1ghts .
..
,,'
I
!
" '
I .
'j !
j
i I
·-... ..
, '
'") .-
CH.5
CORPORATE GOVERNANCE 225
JENS DAMMANN T
REDEFINING'~E MANDATORY LAW PUZZLE:
IN CoERRICANEXCEPTIONALISM
PORATELAW
65HAS TINGS L. J . 441 (2014)1
[... ]
7, . One of these reasons relates t O . . ..
,f disclosure mechanism A H the function of codetermmation as a
i work on corporate ow~er ~-1 enry Hansmann has shown in his seminal
t it can lower the corporat; P•a centr~l benefit of codetermination is that
~
asymmetries between fi1on s contractmg costs by reducing informational
nd
negotiate. If labor union ~m~ a . th~ labor ~nions with whom they
partners' economic s·t s t~c credible mformat10n about their bargaining1
1 ua ion then both si'd es m1g . ht resort to cost y
measures such as st ·k '
this problem Thr r~ :~ or lockouts. Codetermination helps toteovercom e
th . h oug_ e employ ee represe ntatives on corpora boards
e umons ave re~iable information about the economic situation of
firms, greatly reducmg the likelihood of strikes and other distributive
measures.
~he di~closure. function of codetermination is now widely recognized.
C_rucially, 1~ has important implications for explaining transnational
differences m codetermination laws. Obviously, the disclosure function
can only acquire relevance where firms (or associations of firms) are
confronted with labor unions, and where wages are in fact determined by
collective bargaining agreements. It is in this context that a further
difference between the United States and Europe gains importance.
Compared to the United States, European countries rely much more
strongly on collective bargaining agreements to set wages.
As of 2011-the most recent year for which data is available-only
about 13% of U.S. employees were covered by collective bargaining
agreements. This number contrasts rather sharply with the
corresponding percentages in European countries: 99% of employees are
,
covered in Austria, 92% in France, 92% in Slovenia, 91 % in Sweden
89.5% in Finland, 62% in Germany, 40% in Slovakia, and 28.9% in
Poland .
It follows that one of the central benefits of codetermination-:--namely
its potential to reduce bargaining costs betweer:i labor umons and
employers-simply has much more relAevanc~ mh m~nyd Eu~opeahn
· h Germany France, or ustria, t an 1t oes m t e
countries, sue as ' d · · · ffi ·
United States. This does not per se imply th~t c~ eterm16nat10Hn1s e 1ciehnt
· th its costs might outweigh its bene its. owever , t e
m Europe ere, codetermination
; · even· that . · ·k 1 b 1 t· 1
. is h e Y to e re a ive y more
crucial pomt is . U ·t d States
th · .
efficient in Europe than m e m e
•
1 Footnotes omitted.
226
~~-----~~~~~~~:.::..:,::..::..:.;~------
CORPORATE GOVERNANCE ~ CLJt
[... ]
There is also another reason why codeterminatio_n might be rnore
efficient in Europe than the United States. In ~ractice, th e employee
representatives tend to use their role in the supervisory board to voice the
concerns of employees and ensure, as they view it, that the latter are
treated fairly. The additional protection thus accorde~ to employees
might be the answer to an efficiency problem that arises _due to the
particular structure of European employment law. In the Umted ~tates,
employees can generally be fired at will. In most Europea? countri_es,by
contrast, the basic rule is that employees cannot be termmated without
cause. One can question whether this typ~ of strong ~mployment
protection is efficient, but that is beside the pomt. As a prac~ical ~atter,
for most European countries, far-reaching steps toward the hberahzation
of employment markets are simply not politically feasible. _
One major drawback of the for-cause requirement is that it creates
an obvious incentive for harassment and, more generally, bad faith
treatment. Seeking to rid themselves of below-average employees,
employers have an incentive to make the relevant employees' work
environment unpleasant in order to persuade them to quit "voluntarily."
This is an issue of great practical importance. Empirical studies in
various , European countries suggest that workplace bullying is a
widespread and serious problem affecting between two and twenty-two
percent of employees and that it has significant negative consequences for
the health of employees .
. ~
:I Admittedly, one can make a theoretical case that workplace bullying
and other bad faith treatment aimed at persuading employees to leave is
not necessarily inefficient. After all, if one strongly believes in the
efficiency of termination at will, then measures that weaken Europe's for-
cause requirements might seem prima facie desirable. However, in light
of the significant negative impact that bullying has on the affected
employees' health-costs that are not usually reflected in the employer's
cost-benefit analysis-such a line of reasoning seems rather implausible.
If, on the _ot~e_rhan~, one assumes that bullying aimed at persuading l
workers t_oquit i~ mefficient, then one of codetermination's benefits might
be that it _proVIdes some ?rotection against such bullying; employee
representatives can use their clout in the supervisory board to persuade
corporatio~s to respect the rights of the employees. If one further assumes
that American ~mploy~rs who can fire their employees at will do not need
to rely ?n bul_lymgto rid themselves of unwanted employees, the relevant
·'
.'
I
protect10n might be more sorely needed in Europe than · th
States. in e m
u· ted
.-: In sum, the fact that some European countries prote~t em lo ees
i
} I through corporate governance, while the United States does not, pea~ be
: ·i
I .,
l ·,
I ,-
; '
CH. 5 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE 227
a certa. in t . ·
explained · to · h t sim I bex ent by efficiency consi. derations.
' det ermina t·ion mig · ce
ier relian
Co . b . . PY ea response to Europe's heav
11 t argai ning agre t . . .
on co ec ive emen s and less flexible termination rules.
***
f
It . is .interesting also t o consi·der the possi·ble effects o co-
ets o · ht £or examp Ie, that
determination h on. securities mark · ne mig argue, oyee s might be
a b?ar d t at in cludes representatives of the empl
g that the
particul~rly a~verse to a hostile acquisition or merger, fearin
respect the
transactwns will lead (as is often the case) to layoffs. In this
mung in
Ger~an governance. structure, and the use of Mitbestim
entators,
particular, can contribute to explain, according to some comm
to the U.K. or
the lower level of takeover activity in Germany as opposed
the U.S.
and linked
· We ha':e menti~ned the three basic governance models,
that in the
them to their countries of origin. It should be noted , however,
different
last few decades several countries have made available
in its bylaws,
governance models to their corporations: a corporation can,
in a "menu"
opt for one of two or sometimes even three models available
France it is
offered by the legislatures. Since 1966, for example, in
e, and a two-
possible to opt between the traditional model discussed abov
similar to the
tier model with a conseil de surveillance and a directoire
adopted this
German system. Some large French corporations have
choose from,
option. Several other European systems offer two models to
reform; and
and some even three: this is the case of Italy , after a 2003
blic allow to
Portugal, after 2006. Also recent reforms in the Czech Repu
d model in
choose between different models. Japan introduced a secon
of the one-tier
2002, and a third one in 2014. The second one, a variation
the Board of
Anglo-Saxon system , mandates three committees within
a majority of
Directors (audit, compensation and nomination) with
on the German
outside directors. The third model, however, is not based
only the audit
tradition, but is rather a simplifi ed one-tier model with
committee.
to add this
The theoretical reasons why a legislature might want
all: since all
level of flexibility are quite obvious--0ne size doesn't fit
to define the
models have pros and cons , and it is probably impossible
sh arehold ers or
most desirable model under all circumstanc es, to let the
for minority
the managers decide, providing ad~quate pr~t ections
what could be
shareholders and third parties, seem s hke a good id ea. But
one particular
the practical reasons why a corporation might pr efer
and try to li st
model? Before continuing reading , pause for a second
of th e three
possible reasons that you can imagine for adopting one
models.
~AN~C~E
___
~R~N
___ ~Ctt.5
_______
_2_2_8 C~O~R~PO~RA~T~E~G~O~VE ~
ts.
first reason might be related to cos
D_one?OK, let's see. Of course a mi ght
held corporation, some models
Especially for a small, closely erning bodies and theref ore less
e few er me mb ers of the gov
requir e Anglo.
ed organizational structure. Th
expenses and a more streamlin bil l: it can be structured in a way
r mo del see ms to fit the
Saxon one-tie
rd members .
that minimizes the number of boa ss
the oth er han d, the two -tier system could ease busine
On ecdotal
case of a friendly merger. An
combinations, especially in the has been adopted by some Italian
exa mp le, sho ws tha t it
evidence, for ego
tha t me rge d. Th e rea son is sim ple, and has to do with human
banks g a
underestimated when negotiatin
(something that should not be tem has two boards (even if with
bin atio n): the two -tie r sys
business com "Presidents" or "Chairpersons": one
ent fun ctio ns) , and the ref ore two
differ is might
one for the managing board. Th
for the board of supervisors, and ire s of the bosses of the merging
ier to acc om mo dat e the des
make it eas e. In
atio ns, gra nti ng to eac h of the m a satisfactory position and titl
corpor is apt
that the German two-tier system
this perspective it is also possible the helm of a family business: the
gen era tio nal tra nsi tio n at
to manage a sit on the supervisory board,
and
nde rs of the cor por atio n can
old fou but not
remove the managing directors,
retain the power to appoint and the new
rations of the business; while
interfere with the day-to-day ope
ing board.
generation can serve on the manag
·./ als o be des ira ble for the subsidiary of a foreign parent
It might similar
atio n to ado pt a gov ern anc e structure that mirrors, or is as
corpor iary of
sib le, to the one of the par ent . For example, a French subsid
I•
as pos ages of
pt the two-tier model: the advant
/, a German corporation might ado parent
re, already familiar to the
a similar governance structu
corporation, are self-evident.
tile
models might also make hos
Arguably, some governance German two-tier model, if
dif fic ult . Fo r exa mp le, wit h the
takeovers more stake in a corporation, even in
old er obt ain s a con tro llin g
a new shareh l
e of a co- det erm ina tio n me cha nism, before being able to contro
the absenc first
nag em ent of the cor por atio n, the new shareholder must
the ma ones;
the me mb ers of the sup erv isory board and appoint new
remove of the
, the new sup erv iso ry boa rd must change the composition
second ces and
ing boa rd. Th ese ste ps might take time and resour
manag least, more
trib _ut e to ma ke a hos tile acquisition less likely or, at
con
expensive.
,
lig ht of the se pos sib le rea son s to adopt ·a particular model
Even in
for get tha t leg al sys tem s hav e a certain degree of inertia
one should not
pre fer s to say , pat h-d epe nde ncy. Also in countries that
or, as someone lly the
~ . ma d:, mu ,~t ipl e gov ern anc e models available, statistica
hav
mo del ten ds to be by far the most widely adopted, even
trad1t10nal local
_9:!·5 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE 229
years after the introduction of d'f£ .
·n
1
Italy only six listed corpo t' i erent options (as of 2013, for example,
f little less than 300 h d d ra 10ns--eve ·f f 1
n i air y 1arge ones-over a t ot a 1
·
~012, only 2.2% of the c~r ~r o~ted t~e German model). In Japan, as of
dopted the second mod ~ ations hsted on the Tokyo Stock Exchange
athe reasons for the 1
introde introduced
t" in. 2002 . Can you now
un ders t an d
uc ion of the third model in Japan in 2014?
;: f H
iI ' I). '·• 1·'
; r 11 !; •
I ; ,
i ,~ ' t
.... ·! l
:_
f_H, 5 CORPORAT G
E OVERNANCE 231
rigorous rules concerning ind
t h a t an "a dequa t e" number ofependent
d" dire ct ors. F.Irst of all, 1t
. requires
.
it contains a definition of inde Ir:ctors sho~ld be independent; secondly,
more rigorous than the statut pen ence that Is more detailed and possibly
other words, indicates best pror~_one.The Corporate Governance Code, in
one established by the legislate Ices th at set a higher threshold than the
ure.
The consequence is that, in Ii ht . .
corporations that adopt the C;d 0 ~ the very high number of Italian
important role or at least e, mdependent directors have an
different questio~ would beaipear f:equently on the boards of directors (a
ample in 2013 th o c?nsider how truly effective they are). For
~x ' . ' e average size of the board of directors of an Italian
hsted · corporat10n
1 · · . was approximately 10 d"irec t ors (s1·igh t 1y more 1n ·
financia. 1nstitut10ns,
. 14) , and on avera ge th e boar d of d.irec t ors h a d 3
executive ~irecto~s, 3 non-executive directors, and 4 independent (and
non-executiv~) direc_tors (see Assonime-Emittenti Titoli. La corporate
gov:rnance in Italia: autodisciplina e remunerazioni (Anno 2013),
available at http:/ lwww.assonime .it).
In the last few years, if not decades, the number and relevance of
independent (and/or outside) directors have risen in virtually all
developed nations. Is this desirable? Does this create the risk of a less
cohesive board? Do independent directors without executive roles really
have access to all the information, generally guarded by the managers,
necessary to oversee the business and ensure the legality of corporate
activities? Or should the supervising function of independent directors be
welcome? And what are the possible causes of this evolution? In the
following excerpt, Professor Gordon offers some possible explanations:
even if focusing on the U.S . market, its reasoning is interesting also to
consider the phenomenon in other systems.
·· Th ere 1s
· a power ful trend in favor of.independent
. . directors for public
firms in the United States, yet the emp1nc~l eVIdence addhucedh~hus fadr
· · · explanation. The Article suggests t at t 1s tr en
gives us no conv1nc1ng s r· 1 F.
reflects two interrelated developments in t~e U .. po iticat ecob~omt _y .. itrhst
. . h holder value as the primary corpora e o Jee IVe, e
1s the shift to s are . t· of stock market prices. The
d . h ter informa 1veness
secon 1s t e grea ·t · th firm to a shareholder wealth-
·d· f'!'
overr1 1ng e .1ec IS
t . to comm1 e
d by stock price performance. Stock
. . . t t gy as best measure
max1m1z1ng s ra e f most things. In this environment ,
prices are taken as the measure 0
2 Footnotes omitted.
_0l·5 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE
233
consideration. For example ·
1
concentrated ownership s~r~nt egal syst ems characterized by a more
. c ure such .
indepen d en t directors could be c .d' . as m continental Europe,
. on executive. directors e onsi ered imp ort an t to perform a controllmg.
funct10n
xpressed by th e contro 11mg
. shareholder.
Ar
2. e we sure, however th t .
"independent" and have ' ff:~. indep~ndent directors are really more
understan d mg of the business t O hicient mfo
. su . rma t'10n, k nowIe dge, an d
11
Consider, for a moment the ca cf a enge, if necessary, executive directors?
0
no relationships with the cor se t.a perfectly independent director, that has
· a mem b er of t h e
Pora ion at all . be si'd es b emg
board, but imagine that this is her
she can be removed or not . only or ~rimary source of income, and that
appomted agam by th cont ro 11· h h Id
Are we sure that she would hav . . ~ mg s are ~ er.
decision that seems in th b t . e the right mcentives to oppose a busmess
. ·t h h Id ?e eS mterest of the controlling shareholder ' but not
of minori y s are o ers.
3 .. Japan is a_noutlier among the developed countries with its low rate
of appomtment of. mdependent/outside di.rectors. F or examp 1e, some maJor ·
Japanese corpor~trnns such as Toyota, Canon and Nippon Steel & Sumitomo
Metal had appointed no outside (or non-executive) directors until 2013 or
201~. Al~hough. t~e rati~ of listed corporations that appoint at least one
outside director is 1ncreasmg and reached 74.2% among those listed in the 1st
section of Tokyo Stock Exchange as of June 2014, 39.9% of those corporations
appoint only one outside director. When it comes to independent directors
.
61.0% appoints at least one, and 21. 7% appoints two or more. What would be
'
the reasons of Japanese corporations' reluctance to appoint
independent/outside directors? On the other hand, the Japanese government
is currently encouraging listed corporations to appoint more of them, through
the 2014 reform of the Companies Act and the Corporate Governance Code,
which had been discussed under the auspices of the Financial Services
Agency and will be adopted by the Tokyo Stock Exchange in 2015. What
c~mld be the motives of the government for such a move? See, Japan's
Corporate Governance Code [Final Proposal] (March 5, 2015), available
at http://www.fsa.go.jp/en/refer/councils/corporategovernance/20150306-
l/Ol. pdf.
***
There is in fact a fourth category of directors that needs to be
considered t~gether 'with executive? n~n-executive, and inde~ende~t
directors: directors appointed by minority shareho:ders. Espec1~1ly ~n
leg I t · hich the ownership structure of hsted corporations is
a sys ems in w . · · 1 t · h
· whi'ch applying a strict maJority ru e o app01nt t e
m ore concen t ra t e d , in
board would give to the controlling group _complete control over the
· · o f th e man agi·ng body , mandating . a system to represent
composition .
· · h ld the board might effectively protect the interests
minority share o ers on
. . t·
. · h us d h
1 ·nvestors Similarly, in t e .. an t e . .,
uK
f
o small and 1nstitu 10na i · h · · k h
· , · 'd d ownership structure, t ere is a ris t at
vis-a-VIs a more w1 esprea · h b bl lf
· . · ·th the managers mig t e a e to se -
d1rectors with strong ties wi
_2_3_4
_______ ______ ~Ctt.5
~C~O~l~?I~>O~R~A~T!._E~G~0:!._V~E~•'R~N~A~N ~C~E
----.::.
p_erpetuate themselves, and minority-appoint ed director s can mitigate the
mcestuous" relationship between manag ers and board members .
The following article discusses directors' elections in the U.S
explaining why often, at least until recently , shareholders had littl~
control on the nomination of the directors, and advancing a proposal for a
system that might ensure the representation of minority shareholders on
the board.
3 Footnotes omitted .
.--.
i 5
_9!:--~
:-::--:::-~C~O~R~P~O!!R~A~T~E
OV~Q!
ERN ANC
~~~ ~~--E---_J~
In this respect how
evol·ution· of th e 235
1 · the 'ownerev s he:,
ip str last
t decades have seen
Institutiona investors have ac . uc ure of a pecu 1·iar
Ame rican corp orations
some of the m os t impo · quiredh a more central position
rtant equ't
it is not always possible wi' th i y ol_ders.For and become·
· kl ~ 1·iqm· d a t e its an insti tutio nal investor
qu1c · inve
· stment outA facm m g pot entia · l sign
· ificant losses, to'
large hsted corporation fore · utual fund holding four percent of a
causing a little earthq~ake ;at~P_1e, can hard
ly dump its shares without
market price of the shares ;h m th e val~
e of its portfolio and in the
coupled with even stronger. c
replicate a particular market 0:~::m~s.
e:e ~conomic limitations are sometimes
For ex~mp~e, index funds that
holding the shares of the iss th with a passive mvestment strategy,
alter their portfolio For ;ers .at compose the index, simply cannot
articipate in the life. of th ese 11:1veS t ors in parti
e corp orati on and ha cular, to actively
P
direc tors is often th . . th 1 . f
. . e on 1Y viable course ofve actio a say m e se ectio no
n to protect their
investment agam , . st board's decisions th a t are perceive
· d as contrary to
share h oId ers · inter
I ests . The legal system ha s not , owever,
to h armonious Y respond to the change in the h deve1oped as
ownership structure.
Even ignoring the specific needs of large insti
tutional investors the
rules currently applicable to most listed corp
orations raise serious d~ubts
on directors' accountability to shareholders.
Several legal hurdles stand
in the way of shareholders seeking to influ
ence the composition of the
board.
The first of these hurdles concerns the majo
rity required to appoint a
director. Under Delaware law, as well as in
most other states, directors
are voted one-by-one, and not bundled together.
Each individual nominee
does not need to receive the positive vote
of the majority of the shares
represented at the shareholders' meeting to
be appointed. Like in political
elections to be elected a plurality of the vote
s cast is usually sufficient;
votes agai'nst a specific candidate are not poss . ns
ible and abstent10 are not
relevan t. Simply, the nominees that receive the
positive votes are elected. For example, if 300 high~st number of
,000 voting share_s are
represented at the meeting, nominee John Doe
_
mig ht b~ elected
·ttl
1 e as
60 t if no other individual receives a higher numwith as
l ·t· vo es, . . d' ber of
t U d thi·s rule it is easy for sittm g irect t bt . th
ors o o am e
pos1 1ve vo es. n er . cand. .
. h' h t mbe r of vote s for their idate
re 1a t 1ve 1g es nu s. .
. under the pressure · ·
of institutional investors,
In recent years, 1arge ly . votm
hift toward majority · g. I n a ma3· on·t
there has b~en a s Y vo t·mg
receive the majority of the votes represented
system, nominees need ~o at
b 1 cted and therefore "no" votes or
, ting to e e e
t e shareho
hb ld ers mee f the ,election. . According to a recent
.
a stent10ns can a £feet the outcomehlyo % of S & P 500 companies . had
study, as of February 2ooy,~:ug ting52in
their charter or bylaws. The
adopted some form of maJOrl Y vto ates
that the specific provisions
demons r
same study, however,
______
~2~36~------~C~O~RE.:PO~R~A~T~E:::._:G~O_:_VE~R~N~AN:..::..:..:C::.:E::..- C:::..:._!!:J
I in Delaware and under Federal law, have now made it easier for
shareholders holding a minimum percentage of shares to add their
nominees to the corporate proxy statement.]
For these reasons, [until the recent past, in the U.S.] directors'
elections [have often been] uncontested, which means that the number of
nominees is not greater than the number of available slots on the board,
and the only nominees are the ones selected by the existing board. But
ther~ is more. Until a recent amendment of NYSE regulation, effective for
meetings held on or after January 1, 2010, in uncontested directors
elections brokers could vote uninstructed shares. Uncontested elections,
more precisely, were considered "routine" matters, and brokers had the
discretion to vote the shares in the absence of specific instructions from
the beneficial holders of the securities. In these instances brokers would
usually cast their votes according to managers' proposals. [... ]
-
CH. 5 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE 237
;I
.i
·f
'!
CH. 5
CORPORATE GOVERNANCE 239
minority stake just to be abl t .
strategic or marketing infor;a~i:romt one director and acquire confidential
3. As indicated in the f ".
experience . In 1998 the It l" a\ ic~e, hst ~oting" is inspired by the Italian
the board of auditors w;~anh eg~slature introduced this system to appoint
entirely determine th; i t .e_idea that the same majority should not
controlling body. More r;~:~~siti~ n of both the board of directors and the
of directors Article 147 t O ith
th
is approach has been extended to the board
e TUF, mentioned above, in relevant part
provides th~t- "The B 1- er
should be ele~ted on t~ a:s _provi~e that members of the Board of Directors
participation requir d ;, ~sis of hSt s of_candidates and defines the minimum
he presentatio~ of a list , not exceeding 2.5% of the
apital or the d'f£1 e torpercentage established by Consob taking into account
c ·t . t· fl er~n ·
cap1 a 11za B10n, oatmg shares a d h'
[ ] Th . n owners 1p structures of listed compames.
··· e Yaws1 can proVIde that no director is elected from a list that has
not reached · · ·n
a percentage of v ot es a t 1east equal to half of the participatio
.
t· 1
·d thfor the
reqmred " presentation of the list" · Add't·1 1ona11y, th e same ar 1c e
provi es at at least one member of the Board of Directors must be elected
from the minority lis~ that obtained the largest number of votes [after th~
first one] and that 1s not linked in any way, even indirectly , with the
shareholders who presented or voted the list which resulted first." Do you
understand the rationale of these rules? Why do you think it is important to
distinguish lists "linked" to the first one, and exclude the nominees included
in these lists? Do you think that one director voted by the minority, for
example in a board of nine members, is sufficient? One is, in fact, the
minimum mandated by law; the bylaws are free to increase the number of
minority directors.
4. What do you think is the difference between an independent
director and a minority-appointed director? Is a minority-appointed director
necessarily independent pursuant to the legal definitions of independence
discussed above?
5. How do you think the "independent" state of mind of a director can
be guaranteed? What arrangements (financial or otherwise) would help
achieve this "independence of mind"?
***
'
Talking about the composition of the board, we have discussed the
representation of workers and of minority shareholders, differ~3:1possiblet
"stakeholders" of the corporation. What about the composition of the
board in terms of gender or ethnic minorities?
s e al countries have adopted a mandatory requirement to ensure
ev tr t· n of both genders on the board, which basically means a
represen a 10 ffi · · in· favor of t h e
~or women a sort of a irmative act10n
man da t ory quota 1 1 , •
an extremely
"Ias t -represen t ed" gender · The following . excerpt from
· t · t· 1 by Professor Branson discusses the reasons to regulate
1n eresting ar 1c e . ·i1 · ·
th e existing
on boards of directors, i ustrates
th e presence of women
240 CORPORATE GOVERNAN CE Ctt
- --- ---- ~~~~~~~~~ ~-----~ .5
-----..;;.
[... ]
Arguments abound for an increase of diversity in every profession or
calling-law practice, medicine, academe, law enforcement, firefighting,
and more. One drumbeat, persistent since the 1990s, has been for an
increase in diversity candidates for publicly held corporations' boards of
directors-most particularly, women on boards. "[I]f Lehman Brothers
were actually Lehman Sisters, the company never would have gone
under," is a statement that captures the sentiment. Women are thought
to be more sensitive and adverse to the sorts of risk that led to the global
financial meltdown of 2008. A greater presence of women on boards of
directors may have helped avert many of the debacles which occurred.
There are several benefits to corporations from an increase in women
directors. First, this increase would provide a positive role model for other
women in the middle and lower ranks of corporate organizations. In mid-
2011, over 50% of the middle managers in corporate America were women
while only 2.6% of CEOs of Fortune 500 companies were female.
Second, boardroom diversity aids in avoidance of "groupthink," the
complacency that led to monumental governance failures at Enron and
other corporations. The presence of women aids proliferation of the array
of perspectives and viewpoints on corporate boards, leading to better
assessments of risk and less rubberstamping of CE Os' decisions .
Third, "market reciprocity" means that companies that sell goods and
services to the public send positive signals to consumers who might
purchase their products. Women account for well over 70% of the
purchasing power in our economy. The presence of women in a
corporation's senior management would filter out to and sway potential
purchasers.
Fourth, corporations will increasingly function in a diverse world.
Their governance and the makeup of their boards should reflect this,
including more women and persons of color as directors.
I- . ~t
Fifth, authoritative international laws and conventions state that
i "men and women have the same right to employment opportunities,"
"promotion," and "equal treatment in respect of work for equal value."
The latter are sound bites from Article 11 of the United Nations
4 Footnotes omitted.
241
f.H·5 CORPORATE GOVERNAN CE
Convention on Elimination of A1
Women (CEDAW). Especially in k
Forms of Discrimination Agai~st
, f~alty to CEDAW and its
commands have been influ enti al in cour~pe ion of quota laws and other
mea sures to increase the b nsid erat
rd
seats. num er of women occupying corporate boa
countries with very large populations (e.g., China, Indonesia) and some
smaller nations as well (e.g., Slovenia, Netherlands).
Mark Twain wrote that "there are three kinds of lies: lies, damned
lies, and statistics." At best, the German statistic is a half-truth. On
managing boards (Vorstand), the more exclusive circle in t~ie German
system (where "the rubber meets the road") less than 2% of directors are
women. Standing alone, without background disclosur<:, the 7%figure for
directors on supervisory boards (Aufsichstrat) seems m1slead1ng.
[... ]
Parliaments in Italy, the Netherlands, and Belgium have enacted
gender-based director laws. Norway, the first nation to act, adopted its
quota statute in 2003, ordering full compliance by 2008 and setting the
level at 40%. Spain, the second to act, ordered achievement of the 40%
level by 2016, a significant jump from the 5% level which prevailed in
Spain at the time of the adoption of the law. The Spanish statute, though,
is largely aspirational, while the Norwegian law has severe penalties.
Norwegian companies that do not comply are not only subject to delisting
on the stock exchange but to outright dissolution.
France, the third nation to act, adopted a 40% quota law early in
2011. Looking northward to Norway, a deputy of the Assemblee Nationale
(Marie-Jo Zimmerman) introduced a 20% quota bill in 2006. Thereafter,
the notion of gender parity, at least in French corporate governanc~, had
to negotiate a twisting route.
The Conseil Constitutionnel, a court that renders "advisory'' opinions
on pending measures, declared the proposed 2006 French legislation
unconstitutional. The court found that the 1999 amendments to the
French Constitution only permitted enactment of laws aimed at achieving
~e;11?erparity in elections for political office. The proponents subsequently
1n1t1ated a movement further to amend the French Constitution which
was achieved in 2008. The amendment provides that French la;s shall
promote equal access to "positions of professional and social
responsibility," as well as to elected offices.
In 2009, adding to the momentum for adoption of a quota statute the
quota measure's supporters found that only 8% of directors in Fra~ce's
largest 100 corporations were women. Further, they bemoaned that in
that year, French public companies added only six new women directors
to corporate boards.
Th~ ~ecently enacted French quota mandate is staged. Public
companies boards must have 20% women directors within three years of
enactment and 40% within six years, by 2017. Thus far, large French
.. '.
.,.
CH.5
CORPORAT G
. E OVERNANCE 243
corporat10ns are out in f. t
.
women d 1rectors on boardsion of the
in 2012 _
2014 b '
o Jective, having passed 24%
Sweden, Finland, Germ·
out in opposition to quota la:~· a nd t~e Unit ed Kingdom have all come
Finland (26%) already have fo_r various reasons. Sweden (28.2 %) and
boards . On the other handm~mngful representation of women on their
middling to poor and med 1' ' ermany and the United Kingdom have
countries have long tr ~?te record s, respectively, on the issue. Both
recalcitrant when told wha~ t~ ~~~ of bucking trends and becoming
1
Zealand Stock Exchange has publicly stated that it will not even follow its
-
CH.5
CH,5 C
.:::,.::;~------~O~R!!JP~CORATE G
- --.:::..~O~VE~R~N~AN~C~E~
______ _!24~9
the extreme opposite of th
, ·
primac_!, one might refer toe the spectru
f m, as an example of shareholders'
2~~ Mich. 459 (1919), in which ~mous U.S. case Dodge v. Ford Motor,
d1V1dendsrather than reta· . e court directed Henry Ford to pay
.
an outl ier an d 1s
. often imng the P fit
misinter r ro 1 s. This
.
case, in reality, is quite
courts are extremely reluct t P ~ted: the reality is that also in the U.S.
. t ors concermng
d1rec . divide an to mter£ere wit · h the business decisions of
n ds.
In any case, the debate
Germany, during the Na · d. goes on. We mentioned before that in
. 'tl Y m
. d'1cated that thez1b ictatorship
exp11c1 dh , th e 19 37 Corporate Statute
in the interest of shareholde oa~ ad to manage the corporation not only
State. References to stakehof ~· u!. also of the German people and of the
directors' duties are however e~~h ifferent fr?m shareholders in defining
the past. An interesting m. d~~ e prerogative of totalitarian regimes of
shareholder value') can be £
1
J. course (also known as the 'enlightened
2006, which provides that: oun m section 172 of the U.K. Companies Act
~:.y
~:!· :~ promote the_success of the company .-(!)
A director
would hepmo~t ~~:~ act m the way he considers, in good faith,
th b fit f . y to promote the success of the company for
e ene 1 o its members as a whole, and in doing so have
regard (amongst other matters) to-
. (a) the likely consequences of any decision in the long term,
(b) the interests of the company's employees,
(c) t~e need to foster the company's business relationships with
suppliers, customers, and others,
(d) the impact of the company's operations on the community
and the environment,
(e) the desirability of the company maintaining a reputation for
high standards of business conduct, and
(f) the need to act fairly as between members of the company.
This discussion is both interesting and relevant, but sometimes it
might be quite theoretical, and it does not always have a significant
practical impact on the life of the corporation. For example, let's assume
that it could be established that the goal of the corporation is to maximize
shareholders' wealth. First of all it should be discussed if we mean wealth
maximization in the short or in the long term. The difference can
obviously be substantial. In any case, it is fairly easy to argue that also a
decision that apparently is primarily motivated by the interests of other
stakeholders has an effect, at least indirectly, on the economic situation of
the corporation. Consider, for exa~ple,_ the decision to _make a ~onation to
a charitable or educational institut10n, or to av01d experiments on
250 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE Ca.5
animals m the cosmetics industry, and adopt different and
more
expensive techniques to ensure safety. One might argue that
these
decisions negatively affect the bottom line of the corporation, at least
in
the short term, but it is quite easy to respond that they might have
a
positive impact on public relations, attract more customers, create
a
better work environment, and ultimately be beneficial also in terms
of
value for the shareholders. Similarly, if one argues that directors
can or
should take into account different stakeholders , it is not difficult to
argue
that (legal) profit-maximizing strategies can _also benefit constituenci
es
different from shareholders. For example, cutting some jobs today
in
order to maintain a higher level of profitability can be necessary to
save,
in the medium term, a larger number of jobs. This is an area in which
it is
easy to fall into empty rhetoric .
A probably more concrete question concerns the boundary that
divides directors' and shareholders' powers. The following two
famous
I •
U.S. cases illustrate the issue.
_2_5_2
_______ ___:::C~O'..!R~P~O~R~A~T~E~G~O~VE~R~N::AN~C~E~-----~CR.5
---.:::.
true, one would not need to inquire further. The action taken would
constitute a breach of duty. [... ]
While I am satisfied that the evidence is powerful, indeed compelling
that the board was chiefly motivated on December 31 to forestall ;
0
preclude the possibility that a majority of shareholders might place on the
Atlas board eight new members sympathetic to the Blasius proposal, it is
less clear with respect to the more subtle motivational question: whether
the existing members of the board did so because they held a good faith
belief that such shareholder action would be self-injurious and
shareholders needed to be protected from their own judgment.
On balance, I cannot conclude that the board was acting out of a self.
interested motive in any important respect on December 31. I conclude
rather that the board saw the "threat" of the Blasius recapitalization
proposal as posing vital policy differences between itself and Blasius. It
acted, I conclude, in a good faith effort to protect its incumbency, not
selfishly, but in order to thwart implementation of the recapitalization
that it feared, reasonably, would cause great injury to the Company.
The real question the case presents, to my mind, is whether, in these
circumstances, the board, even if it is acting with subjective good faith
(which will typically, if not always, be a contestable or debatable judicial
conclusion), may validly act for the principal purpose of preventing the
shareholders from electing a majority of new directors. The question thus
posed is not one of intentional wrong (or even negligence), but one of
-<1 authority as between the fiduciary and the beneficiary (not simply legal
. lj
j authority, i.e., as between the fiduciary and the world at large). [... ]
The shareholder franchise is the ideological underpinning upon
I'
·1
which the legitimacy of directorial power rests. Generally, shareholders
have only two protections against perceived inadequate business
performance. They may sell their stock (which, if done in sufficient
numbers, may so affect security prices as to create an incentive for
altered managerial performance), or they may vote to replace incumbent
board members.
It has, for a long time, been conventional to dismiss the stockholder
vote as a vestige or ritual of little practical importance. It may be that we
are now witnessing the emergence of new institutional voices and
arrangements that will make the stockholder vote a less predictable affair
than it has been. Be that as it may, however, whether the vote is seen
functionally as an unimportant formalism, or as an important tool of
discipline, it is clear that it is critical to the theory that legitimates the
exercise of power by some (directors and officers) over vast aggregations
of property that they do not own. Thus, when viewed from a broad,
institutional perspective~ it can be seen that matters involving the
integrity of the shareholder voting process involve consideration not
CH. 5
CORPORATE GOVERNANCE 253
present in any other context . h'
(... ] . m w ich directors exercise delegated power.
The board was not faced with . .
shareholder against the interests a coe~ci~e action taken by a powerful
(such as a public minority) It of a distinct ~hareholder constituency
by a 9% shareholder More· w:s presented with a consent solicitation
had time) to inform· the s~verh l~re it had time (and understood that it
O
Proposal subject to stockh oladre ers of its views on the merits of the
er vote · The 1 . t'fi . h .
such a situation, be offered for th . on Y J~s i icat10n t at can, m
better than do the shareholder e ac~10:° taken is that the board knows
While that premise is no d s what ism the corporation 's best inte~es_t.
. . oubt true for any number of matters , it is
rrrele;ant (except ms.ofar as the shareholders wish to be ided b the
boards recommendation) · is
wh en th e question · who shouldgucomprise·Y
the
.
board
. of directors. The theory f ·
o our corporat10n law confers power upon
directors as the agents of the shareholders; it does not create Platonic
maste~s .. It may be that the Blasius restructuring proposal was or is
unrealistic ai:id would lead to injury to the corporation and its
shareholders if pursued. Having heard the evidence I am inclined to
think it w~s not a so~nd proposal. The board certainl y ~ewed it that way,
and that view, held m good faith, entitled the board to take cert ain steps
to evade the risk it perceived . It could , for example, expend corpor ate
funds to inform shareholders and seek to bring them to a similar point of
view. [. . .] But there is a vast difference between expending corpora te
funds to inform the electorate and exercising power for the primar y
purpose of foreclosing effective shareholder action. A majorit y of the
shareholders, who were not dominated in any respect, could view the
matter differently than did the board. If they do, or did, they are entitled
to employ the mechanisms provided by the corporation law and the Atlas
certificate of incorporation to advance that view . They are also entitled , in
my opinion, to restrain their agents, the board, from acting for the
principal purpose of thwarting that action.
I therefore conclude that, even finding the action taken was taken in
good faith it constituted an unintended violation of the duty of loyalty
that the b~ard owed to the shareholders. I note parenthetically that the
concept of an unintended breach of the duty of loyalty is unusual but not
novel.
cep t, eve n if
Ca
-
the Court says it is not "novel." In
in
t, _th e dir ect ors hav e not bre ach ed any specific rule, and have acted,
fa: an
actions are nonetheless considered
prmc1ple, within their powers. Their olders' franchise. Why?Do you agree
reh
unacceptable infringement on the sha
with the Court?
Wh at alte rna tiv e cou rse of act ion would you have suggested to the
3.
proposal?
dir ors in order to oppose Blasius'
ect
We sho uld wa rn the rea der s that this decision, a classical case
4.
dynamics of corporate governance and
important to understand in theory the m a practical perspective has been
fro
the boundaries of directors' actions, n, Merceir v. lntertel, it has been
isio
rarely applied, and in a 2007 dec
partially revised.
***
OOD OF TEAMSTERS
INTERNATIONAL BROTHERH
COMPANIES, INC.
GENERAL FUND V. FLEMING
Supreme Court of Oklahoma
975 P.2d 907 (1999)
SIMMS,J.
Sta tes Co urt of Ap pea ls, Te nth Circuit, John C. Porfilio,
The United
Jud ge, pur sua nt to 20 O.S .1991, § 1601, certified to the
Presiding
ing question of law:
,.4 Oklahoma Supreme Court the follow
. 1 t the authority to create and
Does Oklahoma law [A] restric ,
' exclusively to the board of directors
implement shareholder rights plans er
resolutions requiring that sharehold
or [BJ may shareholders propose ding
shareholders for vote at the succee
rights plans be submitted to the
annual meeting?
ans we r the firs t par t of the question in the negative and the
We
par t aff irm ativ ely . We hol d under Oklahoma law there is no
second
aut hor ity gra nte d boa rds of dir ectors to create and implement
exclusive
old er rig hts pla ns, wh ere sha reholder objection is brought and
shareh
thr oug h off icia l cha nne ls of corporate governance. We find no
passed
a law wh ich giv es exc lus ive aut hority to a corporation's board of
Oklahom
the for mu lati on of sha reh old er rights plans and no authority
I directors for ing resolutions or bylaw
sha reh old ers fro m pro pos
i which preclu des
reh old er rig hts plans. We hold shareholders
amendments reg ard ing sha
older
t board implementation of shareh
f may propose bylaws which restric vide
I
cate of incorporation does not pro
rights plans, assuming the certifi
otherwise.
of the Teamsters General Fund
The International Brotherhood ing
of Fleming Companies, Inc. [Flem
[Teamsters] owns sixty-five shares er's
the com pan y] sto ck. In 198 6, Fleming implemented a sharehold
or
,..
CH- 5 CORPORAT
- . E GOVERNANCE 255
rights plan with the term of th
implemented by Fleming is an e t~1an to expire in 1996. The rights plan
boards of d.1rectors authorit ant Oi-takeov er mech amsm . . Such plans give
shareholder rights upon the ocy adopt and execute discriminatory
when a cer t am . percentage ofcurrence
h of some t nggermg
. . event usually
shareholder. A board can place" s atr~s. has been amassed by 'a single
· of' shareholdres rictions
trans :fier or receipt . or. cond't·
1 ions on the exercise,
·
shareholding power of one seek· er rights which can severely dilute the
plans usually result in entren~~1ncontr?l ?fa company. The defensive
takeover without the approval f . g ex1stmg management, making a
These rights plans can make 1·tofmcumbent management more difficult.
Because the rights plans mak thar more expens1ve · t o efl!1ect a ta k eover.
the suitor and assist incumb t e e merger of com
. pames · more pam · fu l 1or
I!
board of directors] may create and issue ... rights and options[.]''
--
CH 5
However, in light of the fact that both terms, "corporation" and "board of
directors", are used distinctly throughout the General Corporation Act
and within the text of 18 § 1038 itself , this assertion is flawed. Further ,
the Former Business Corporation Act, 18 § 1.2(1) and (23), defines
"corporation" and "director" differently. The statutes indicate our
legislature has an understanding of the distinct definitions it assigns to
these terms, and we find it unlikely the legislature would interchange
them as Fleming contends .
While this Court would agree with Fleming that a corporation may
create and issue rights and options within the grant of authority given it
in 18 § 1038, it does not automatically translate that the board of
directors of that corporation has in itself the same breadth of authority .
[...]
We find nothing in the Oklahoma General Corporation Act, 18
O.S.1991 § 1001 et seq., or existing case law which indicates the
shareholder rights plan is somehow exempt from shareholder adopted
bylaws. Fleming argues that only the certificate of incorporation can limit
the board's authority to implement such a plan, relying on § 1038. While
this Court might agree that a certificate of incorporation, which somehow
precludes bylaw amendments directed at shareholder rights plans, could
preclude the Teamsters from seeking the bylaw changes which are
proposed in this case, neither party has indicated Fleming's certificate
speaks in any way to the board's authority or shareholder constraints
regarding shareholder rights plans. We find no authority to support the
contention that a certificate of incorporation which is silent with regard to
shareholder rights plans precludes shareholder enacted bylaws regarding
the implementation of rights plans.
A number of states have taken affirmative steps to ensure their
domestic corporations, and in many instances the board of directors itself,
are able to implement shareholder rights plans to protect the company
from takeover . The legislation is typically called a shareholders rights
plan endorsement statute. However, the Oklahoma legislature has not
passed such legislation. There are at least twenty-four states with these
share rights plan endorsement statutes.
[... ]
This Court understands much of the reasoning behind the enactment
of rights plan endorsement statutes and why so many state legislatures
are inclined to facilitate this takeover protection for their domestic
corporations. In addition, we understand Fleming's desire to have a rights
plan available for quick, and more effective, implementation. However , if,
as in this case, the certificate of incorporation does not offer directors th is
broad authority to protect against mergers and takeover, corporations
,,, .
2. . What · ht s Pan
is a "Shareholder r ig 1 "?. We will .
: discuss . more
1t
.
extensively
· m the
th t · 1 d chapter on takeovers , but b as1ca y 1 1s an anti- ak eover
· 11 ·t · · t
device a me u es ~h:ee elements: (a) a triggering event generally
repr~sented by an ~n~ohcited acquisition of a certain percentage of shares by
a third party_ that IS hkely aiming at obtaining control of the corporation; (b)
a cata_stroph1c consequence that would make the takeover very difficult or
financially costly for the acquirer, typically the issuance of shares at a
discounted price to existing shareholders; (c) the possibility for the existing
board to redeem the plan at a nominal cost. These three features combined
create an obstacle for hostile acquisitions, protecting incumbent managers.
Shareholders, however, like Teamsters in this case, often do not like these
types of poison pills. Can you explain why?,
3. In Blasius v. Atlas, reprinted before, the Court limited the ability of
the directors to interfere with the shareholders' franchise. In Teamsters v.
Fleming the Court recognizes the power of shareholders to amend the bylaws
and restrict the board's discretion with respect to shareholder rights plans.
What are the legal grounds to reach this conclusion? Do you think it is always
in the best interest of shareholders that directors cannot effectively adopt
defensive measures in case of a hostile bid?
4. The Court underlines the reasons why shareholders' direct
authority should be limited, but it ultimately ~ecides that _ in this ca~e
shareholders can limit directors' powers . Followmg the rationale of this
decision do you think it would be admissible, under U.S. law, a bylaws
· · ' requ1r· 1·ng the assent of shareholders for every transaction with a
prov1s1on
value of $50,000 or more?
***
·es grapple with the issue of the proper boundary,
Also ot h er coun t r1 board of directors and of the shar eholders
between t h e powers of the interesting example. Two dec1s10ns · ·
are
· · n
meeting. Germany · d by th e F edera 1 Cour t of
is Ra lzmiiller case decide
. . l· th
particularly cruc1a . e o
..
258
--------~~~~~~~~~~-----~ CORPORATE GOVERNANCE Ca .5
---.:c.
Justice in 1982 and, more recently, the Gelatine cases of 2004. As a
general rule, under German law only the Vorstand, the managing board
has the responsibility to run the corporation. The powers of th~
shareholders to interfere with the management of the corporation are
quite limited: they cannot give binding instructions to directors, and the
shareholders' meeting can take business decisions only if required by the
Vorstand. This is also in line with the fact that directors can be liable for
damaging decisions (see Chapter 6), while shareholders, at least in
practice, rarely are responsible for lack of care. This principle is explained
with the adage "Keine Herrschaft ohne Ha/tung' ("No power without
responsibility"). In Holzmuller, however, a peculiar situation concerning
corporations within a group was considered. The Vorstand of the
corporation decided to spin off the most important assets of the
corporation, a harbor-operating business, to an entirely owned subsidiary.
The value of the assets transferred was approximately 80% of the total
assets of the corporation. The consequence would have been that the
directors of the parent corporation would have had extensive control on
the assets transferred to the subsidiary, because they exercise the voting
rights for the shares of the subsidiary owned by the parent. The Court
therefore held that certain key decisions that could be normally taken by
l~0
.:
E
. the shareholders' meeting of the subsidiary (which, in practice, means by
•
•,,,_.,,_
_.
_J(
'
•
. the directors of the parent) require the vote of the shareholders' of the
. . parent, for example in case of issuing of new shares by the subsidiary
(which, as we have seen, in civil law systems is generally a competence of
"1
the shareholders' meeting-see Chapter 4). This is to avoid the result of
depriving the shareholders of any control on relevant assets through the
\ ·: :'/ use of a corporate group. It's a leading decision because it recognizes, for
' I
"
the first time, non-statutory competences of the shareholders' meeting in
a matter traditionally reserved to managing directors. In a way,
Holzmiiller could be considered the German correspondent of Blasius v.
Atlas: notwithstanding the profound differences of the facts, applicable
rules, and holdings, both decisions introduce a limitation to the power of
directors to disenfranchise shareholders. This important and somehow
revolutionary decision, however, created significant legal uncertainty in
terms of its precise meaning and implications, partially addressed in the
Gelatine case.
In the next few pages, we take a closer look at these decisions.
HOLZMULLER
German Federal Court of Justice, 1982
25 February 1982
Facts
The plaintiff was a shareholder holding about 8% of the shares of the
defendant which was a corporation in the lumber industry. According to
f_fl.5 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE 259
the charter of the defenda t
· ·t·ies In
act1v1 · business purposes were
· th e 1umber indun t corporat·ion, its
. . . and acquisition
s ry as well as th e founding
of oth er corporat10ns 1n this area
defendant could allocate parts of itsMoreover the charter stated that the
the board of the defendant £ assets to these corporations In 1972
d ·
assets of a 1um ber harbor run b h th e HKiG
ouu ed - aA and transferred all
contribution in kind in excha It e defendant to this corporation as a
assets of the lumber harbor nge or all th e shares of this corporation. The
the defendant. The plaintiff ~~p.rese~ed around 80% of all the assets of
lumber harbor was void since ~~~s t at the tra?sfer .of all assets of the
transfer and that the transfer gen~ral meeting did not approve this
charter . The Regional Court L;onSb~uted a de facto change of the
(Oberlandesgericht) dismissed the ~:s~~richt) and the Court of Appeals
Grounds
The co1:1rtgrants the appeal but dismisses the case.
[... ]
The transfer is not void under German corporate law.
[... ]
The argument of the plaintiff that the transfer of all the assets of the
lumber harbor to the H-KGaA constituted a de facto change of the charter
does not lead to invalidate the transfer. The court of appeals already
stated correctly that the transfer of all the assets of the lumber harbor to
the H-KGaA did not violate any provision of the charter since the charter
explicitly allowed the transfer of assets to other corporations. Moreover,
the provisions in the charter did not limit these transfers to certain assets
or a certain amount of assets. Consequently the provisions of the charter
cannot be interpreted as prohibiting the transfer of the major assets of
the corporation.
However, this only means that a formal amendment of the charter of
the defendant was not necessary. This does not imply that the transfer of
all the assets of the lumber harbor to the H-KGaA did not require an
approval of the shareholders' meeting. If the competences ~f . the
shareholders' meeting are governed by mandatory statutory provis10ns,
this only means that the charter cannot attribute this power to the
managing board or another corporate body. [... ] ~though it is in the
discretion of the managing board whether to obtain a1: approval_ of the
, t· ·n cases where such an approval. 1s not required by
s h are h oId ers mee 1ng 1
the statute (Sec. 119 subs. 2 German ~tock C0Jo;:-t10~ Law), ther£e ar~
fundamental decisions of the managing boar t atb avde a dpro_ohun_
· h f h eholders and that cannot e a opte wit out
Ihmpact on the rig ts ohs arh lders In these cases the members of the
t e approval of the s are O •
______
~2~6~0 _____
~C~O~R~~PO~R~A~T~E~G~O~V:.!:E~R~N:..:.:A~ -..:::.:.C~
N~C~E:.__
managing board violate their duty of care if they do not refer the decision
to the shareholders' meeting.
The transfer of all the assets of the lumber harbor to the H-KG011
was such a decision and it required the approval of the shareholders'
meeting. This decision had an impact on the core business activity of the
defendant, involved the most valuable asset of the defendant and changed
its structure completely. Therefore this transfer exceede~ the regular
scope of business activity of the defendant and had a severe impact on the
shareholders of the defendant. Consequently the managing board was not
allowed to transfer all the assets of the lumber harbor to the H-KGaA
without a prior approval of the shareholder meeting of the defendant.
Nevertheless the violation of this duty does not affect the validity of
the transfer. According to Sec. 82 German Stock Corporation Law, the
power of the managing board to act on behalf of the corporation can only
be limited by the bylaws. Although under German law there are two
exceptions (abuse of the agent and execution of a contract with a wholly
owned subsidiary) of this principle, these exemptions cannot affect the
I
validity of the transfer since the transfer was made as a contribution in
kind and therefore does not concern only the internal affairs of the
defendant but the affairs of the subsidiary as a separate legal person. In
fact a cancellation of the transfer would require a decrease of the legal
capital or to dissolve the H-KGaA.
[... ]
The issuance of new shares by a subsidiary corporation paid by
transferring the major assets of the parent corporation threatens severely
the interest of the shareholder of the parent corporation since it could
lead to a decrease of the value of the shares of the parent corporation and
to an exclusion of the pre-emptive rights of its shareholders.
Consequently, a participation of the shareholders of the parent
corporation in future decisions of the subsidiary is essential in order to
protect their interest. This also applies in the case that the increase of
capital w~u~dnot be combined with an exclusion of the pre-emptive rights
of su?scripti~n of the parent corporation (dissenting Timm, AG 1980, 183
f.; Timm, Die AG als Konzernspitze, p. 174 f.; Lutter, in: Festschrift
Wester~ann, p. 365 f.). Even in this case the shareholders of the parent
c~rporat10n cannot subsc~ibe newly issued shares of the subsidiary
directly and make further investments in their business. Every issuance
of new shares of the subsidiary increases the probability that it will have
new (external) shareholders.
There~ore,_the general meeting of the parent corporation must be
able to decide _ifthe_capital of the H-KGaA should be raised and whether
th to the
e pre-emptive rights should be excluded or be granted
· ·
shareholder of the parent corporation · In th'1s d ec1s10n, h 1
t e genera
CH.5 CORPORA
. TE GOVERNANCE 261
meetmg of the parent corpo t·10
· the same maJ·ority as
· d a t th e general me t·ra n has t 0 vot e with
reqmre e mg of the sub si·d·iary corporation.
***
The Holzmuller deci'si·on caused · 'fi
the Federal Court of Justice d'd sigm icant legal uncertainty since
of the managing board that c~nn~t clearly defin~ fundamental decisions
shareholders, and therefore . ave a severe impact on the rights of
The Court focused on the · require specific protections of shareholders.
what about other transac~~suanc~ of m~wshares by the subsidiary, but
consequence, the precise blOnsd t ~t might have similar effects? As a
debated. Over 20 years aftero~ 1thanes 0 ~ the Holzmiiller doctrine were
Justice tried to clarif ' Gelatine, the German Federal Court of
generally limiting th ifi
~om: l aspects . of th~ Holzmiiller principle by
had been expanded 1 e lozbmuller doctrme to its original version after it
arge Y Y ower courts.
GELATINE
German Federal Court of Justice , 2004
26 April 2004
Facts
!he plaintif~s were four shareholders of the defendant corporation,
holding about 291/oof the shares of the defendant which was a corporation
in the gelatine industry . The defendant held 100% of the shares of a
Swedish and a British corporation. While the British corporation had
almost no economic impact for the defendant, the Swedish corporation
contributed around 30% of the revenues of the defendant. In 1998, the
managing board of the defendant transferred all shares of these two
corporations to a newly formed corporation in a contribution in kind in
exchange for 100% of the shares of this new corporation. At the
shareholders' meeting in 2000 the managing board asked the
shareholders to approve this transfer and a resolution was passed with a
69% majority. The plaintiffs then challenged the shareholders' meeting
resolution claiming that the transfer constituted a violation of the so
called Holzmiiller principles which-according to the plaintiffs-would
require an approval of the transfer with a three-fourths majority. The
district court (Landgericht) and the court of appeals (Oberlaudesgericht)
dismissed the case.
Grounds
The court rejects the appeal.
[... ]
. f the plaintiffs is not well founded. The shareholders'
Th e ac t 10n o h £ h · · Th e
. 1 t· di"d not require a t ree- ourt s maJor1ty.
m ee t 1ng reso u 10n . h.
Holzmiiller principle does not apply in t is case.
. .·.
CHAPTER 6
267
..:::.!;C~
___ I=-D...::U
~T~O~R~S::...'~L~I.:!A:::.B~IL~l:.:!T~Y~A~N..::D~F--= -=C-=IA::..;_R_Y_D_U_
_2_6_8___ _;::D~l:!:R~E~C
the final part of this chapter. Of course there are also specific remedies in
case of bankruptcy, but they are outside the scope of this book.
Specific procedural issues concerning the possibility to sue directors,
especially derivatively, will be treated in the following chapter. Here we
will consider the substantive definitions of directors' duties and liabilities.
One general observation that we can anticipate is that even if in this area
comparative differences among the different jurisdictions considered exist
and are relevant, some of the basic ideas such as the definition of the duty
of care and the business judgment rule, but also the contents of the duty
of loyalty, are fairly similar. This is not surprising as the underlying
economic issues, and the need to strike a balance between directors'
liability and allowing them sufficient latitude to carry on the business
and take reasonable risks are similar in all legal systems .
DUTY OF CARE
Basically, as mentioned above, the duty of care is the duty of
directors to manage the corporation diligently. In order to understand the
content of the duty of care it can be helpful to start from a distinction
used in civil law systems, not always familiar to the common law lawyer.
In several civil law systems, there is a difference between what might be
called, with a somehow loose translation, "obligations of means" and
"obligations of result." The former are obligations that are performed
simply by being diligent, even if a specific result expected or hoped for by
a party is not reached. The latter are, on the other hand, obligations that
are performed only if a specific result is achieved: diligence or the absence
of negligence do not excuse non-performance and the party is considered
to have breached the contract if the promised result is not obtained.
In this perspective, it is essential to understand that directors do not
have an obligation of result, but only an obligation of means. They must
manage the corporation in compliance with the law and the governing
documents of the corporation, and act diligently, but the fact that the
corporation does not achieve good economic results, or even that it
becomes insolvent or bankrupt, is not automatically a source of liability.
The care required by directors, in addition, is primarily a "procedural"
. care, in the sense that directors that act on an informed basis, devote
sufficient time to their decisions, acquire-when necessary-opinions
V
f
'
.
from independent experts on a business decision, and so on, are generally
not liable for an honest error of judgment. The emphasis is, in other
words, more on the "way" in which a decision has been reached ' rather
than on the merits of the decision itself. This is so also because ' in case of
a lawsuit, judges, who are not business experts, are reluctant to
substitute their judgment for the one of the directors; in addition, it might
be difficult and somehow unfair to second-guess directors' decisions in
' ·. ,..
"i
ectors to put m · I .
specific duty of dir l control systems
t ·r t d amages. For example, in the rna
P ace ade qua te mte
U.S., see the famous
to preven or mi iga e Litigation, 698 A.2d 959
case In re Ca rema7:k International Inc. Derivative
. 1996 ); in Italy see Article 2381 , p ar. 3 , It a 1·ian c·1v1·1 Code ,
(Del.· Chth t d ·
a irec tor s mu st eva lua te, based on the information received,
stating
ade qua cy of the org ani zat ion al, administrative, and accounting
the
This duty might be interpreted as
syste~s adopted by the corporation.
the internal control system of the
includin? the one .of overseeing often requires more serious
n, eve n if ove rsig ht liab ilit y
corporatio
violations.
start our comparative analysis.
With this framework in mind, we can
dis cus sed bef ore , this is an are a in which, in our opinion, there are not
As
among countries. Most jurisdictions
profound substantive differences
se we have illustrated, and most
limit directors' liability in the sen
ons kno w, in one for m or ano the r, some version of the business
jurisdicti
gm ent rul e, put ting the bur den of proving negligence on the plaintiff.
jud be
areas, is in the details. There might
The devil, here more than in other s
rts interpret and apply the protection
differences in the way in which cou ht
ors in judgment": some courts mig
for what we have called ''honest err
a ma tter of fac t, mo re or les s deferential to directors' business
be, as .,
gm ent . Let 's tak e a loo k at three leading cases from the U.S
jud
is the famous 1985 Smith v. Van
Germany, and Italy. The first one
urt of Delaware : This is one of the few
Gorkom decision of the Supreme Co
nd directors liable for a breach of the
cases in which a Delaware court fou
car e, and as we wil l see in the No tes and Questions following the
duty of
erp t of the dec isio n, it trig ger ed a legislative response from the
exc
Delaware legislature.
W. VAN GORKOM
ALDEN SMITH V. JEROME
Supreme Court of Delaware
488 A.2d 858 (1985)
direct that judgment be entered in favor of the plaintiffs and against the lever:
defendant directors for the fair value of the plaintiffs' stockholdings in confli
Trans Union[ . . .] accot:
II
its C
We hold [. . .] that the Board's decision, reached September 20, 1980, Boar
to approve the proposed cash-out merger was not the product of an appr
informed business judgment[ . . .]
Beginning in the late 1960's, and continuing through the 1970's,
Trans Union pursued a program of acquiring small companies in order to
increase available taxable income [against which it could use the cori:
investment tax credit (ITC) and depreciation deductions its rail car tha1
leasing business generated] . Tra
oft
On August 27, 1980, [Chairperson and Chief Executive Officer salE
Jerome] Van Gorkom met with Senior Management of Trans Union. Van me :
Gorkom reported on his lobbying efforts in Washington and his desire to Crn
find a solution to the tax credit problem more permanent than a kni
continued program of acquisitions. Various alternatives were suggested dir
and discussed preliminarily, including the sale of Trans Union to a asi
company with a large amount of taxable income. m:
Donald Romans, Chief Financial Officer of Trans Union, stated that re,
his department had done a "very brief bit of work on the possibility of a sb
leveraged buy-out." This work had been prompted by a media article
which Romans had seen regarding a leveraged buy-out by management. a
The work consisted of a "preliminary study " of the cash which could be Il'
j . generated by the Company if it participated in a leveraged buy-out. As $
Romans stated, this analysis "was very first and rough cut at seeing a
whether a cash flow would support what might be considered a high price t:
for this type of transaction." t
On September 5, at another Senior Management meeting which Van 1
Gorkom attended, Romans again brought up the idea of a leveraged buy- ]
out as a "possible strategic alternative" to the Company's acquisition
program . Romans and Bruce S. Chelberg, President and Chief Operating
Officer of Trans Union, had been working on the matter in preparation
for the meeting. According to Romans: They did not "come up" with a
price for the Company. They merely "ran the numbers" at $50 a share and
at $60 a share with the "rough form" of their cash figures at the time.
Their "figures indicated that $50 would be very easy to do but $60 would
be very difficult to do under those figures." This work did not purport to
establish a fair price for either the Company or 100% of the stock. It was
intended to determine the cash flow needed to service the debt that would
"probably" be incurred in a leveraged buy-out, based on "rough
calculations" [... ]
· At this meeting, Van Gorkom stated that he would be willing to take
$55 per share for his own 75,000 shares. He vetoed the suggestion of a
CH. 6 DIRECTORS' LIABILITY AND FIDUCIARY DUTIES 273
l -
-ca .6
. · ·
DIRECTORS' LIAB
ILITYANDF
IDUCIARYDU
TIES
1nh1~1t?th~r o~fer~, as would 275
furn1shm the r
g ms1de mformation t p ;hib. . .
Pritzker proposal was a "lo 0 itions against soliciting bids and
c~ ~ :;r bidders. Romans argued
proceeded to the Board meet · that the
P [. · -1 Ne
Ten directors serv d mg as sched 1 d ·vertheless ' Van Gorkom
u e without further delay.
(defendants Bonser, O'Boyle on the T U .
five outside (defendants e B W rans mon Board,
?wder, Chelberg, and Van Gofive inside
Reneker). All directors were: 1 18 rkom) and
was ill. Of the outside direc: ' Johnso th
n, Lanterman, Morgan and
officers and one was the £ esen~ at e meeting , except O'Boyle who
ors, iur were corporate chief
Business School None w orm executive
~r ean of the
analyst. All memb· ers of theasBan mvestment b k Universit y of Chicago
t · d J.':.
and its operations as a go· d . an er or ram •
oar were well mformed about e 1manc1al
mg concern [... 1 the Company
. Van Gorkom beg~n the Spe
cial Meeting of the Board with
mmute oral presentation. Co a twen t -
pie s
delivered too late for study bef of the proposed M A
ore or dur1·ngthe meeet~ t Y
Compan y' s ITC and depreciati mg
ger
. Hgeree
rev~en
iewedwt ehr ee
on problems and the efforts
~ade t~ so~ve ~hem. He discus theretofore
sed his initial meeting with Pri
his mot1vat1on m arranging tha tzker and
t meeting . Van Gorkom did not
the Board, however, the me disclose to
thodology by which he alone
the $55 figure , or the fact had arrived at
that he first proposed the $55
negotiations with Pritzker. price in his
·.
(F]or a period of 90 days, Tra
ns Union could rec eive, but cou
actively solicit, competing off ld not
ers; the offer h ad to be acted
evening, Sunday, September on by the ne xt
21 [.. .] Trans Union was requir
Pritzker one million newly-issu ed to sell to
ed shares of Trans Union at $38
per share.
Van Gorkom took the positio
n that putting Trans Union
auction" through a 90-day ma "up for
rket test would validate a dec
Board that $55 was a fair pri ision by the
ce. He told the Board that the
will have an opportunity to judge wheth "free market
Gorkom framed the decision bef er $55 is a fair price." Van
ore the Board not as whether
share was the highest price tha $55
t could be obtained, but as wheth per
er the
$55 price was a fair price [...
Attorney Brennan advised] the
members ofhthe Bofa!d that t~e
be sued if they failed to acc ~ might
ept the offer and t at a a1rnes
s opm1on was
not required as a matter oflaw
. . in his opinio
at n , $55 was "in the r ange of
Romans to ld t h e B oar d th
a fair price," but "at the beginn '
ing th of
,,
e range .
·
~-J . f Se tember. 20 last ed about two hou rs . B ase d
. The Board meeting ,0
solely upon Van Gorkom s ora
i
resentation [... ] Romans' ora
l statement ,
P
I .
...
Brennan's legal advice, and their knowledge of the market history of the
Company's stock, the directors approved the proposed Merger Agreement.
[... ]
[On] October 9, Trans Union issued a press release announcing: (1)
that Pritzker had obtained "the financing commitments necessary to
consummate" the merger with Trans Union; (2) that Pritzker had
acquired one million shares of Trans Union common stock at $38 per
share; (3) that Trans Union was now permitted to actively seek other
offers and had retained Salomon Brothers for that purpose; and (4) that if
a more favorable offer were not received before February 1, 1981, Trans
Union's shareholders would thereafter meet to vote on the Pritzker
proposal.
., Salomon Brothers' efforts over a three-month period from October 21
,,
l.
to January 21 produced only one serious suitor for Trans Union-General
Electric Credit Corporation ("GE Credit"), a subsidiary of the General
Electric Company. However, GE Credit was unwilling to make an offer
for Trans Union unless Trans Union first rescinded its Merger Agreement
with Pritzker . When Pritzker refused, GE Credit terminated further
discussions with Trans Union in early January.
In the meantime, in early December, the investment firm of
'
'
' .
,
!
' Kohlberg, Kravis, Roberts & Co. ("KKR"), the only other concern to make
a firm offer for Trans Union, withdrew its offer under circumstances
hereinafter detailed.
On December 19, this litigation was commenced and [... ] On
January 26, Trans Union's Board met and, after a lengthy meeting, voted
to proceed with the Pritzker merger. The Board also approved for mailing,
"on or about January 27," a Supplement to its Proxy Statement[ ... ]
On February 10, the stockholders of Trans Union approved the
Pritzker merger proposal. Of the outstanding shares, 69.9% were voted in
favor of the merger; 7.25% were voted against the merger; and 22.85%
were not voted.
IL
We turn to the issue of the application of the business judgment rule
to the September 20 meeting of the Board.
The Court of Chancery concluded from the evidence that the Board of
Directors' approval of the Pritzker merger proposal fell within the
protection of the business judgment rule. The Court found that the Board
had given sufficient time and attention to the transaction, since the
directors had considered the Pritzker proposal on three different
occasions, on September 20, and on October 8, 1980 and finally on
January 26, 1981.
j2:J
JAN~D~F~I ~D~ 77 ~IA~R~
.J_U~C Y[jD~
~B~I~L~IT~Y:___
__.- D_I_R_E_CT_O~R::..:.;:S=-'..:::L:.::IA
f!!~·:...:6:.
[... ]
. . ,s
The Court of Cha. ncery . mad e bu t one fi1nd1ng;1.e., that the Board
Septe mber 20 th roug h J anuary 26 ,
conduct over the entire per . 10d from
informed.
1981 was not rec kl ess or improvident, but
[... ]
te finding that the Board's
[W]e conclu~e that the. Court's ultima
is contrary to the record and not
conduct was not r~ckless or imprudent"
soning process.
the product of a logical and deductive rea
Chancery erred as a matter
The plaintiffs cor:itend that the Court of
directors under the business
of law by exonerating the defendant
g whether the rule's threshold
judgment rule without first determinin
satisfied [... ]
condition of "due care and prudence" was
ent rule is the offspring of
Under Delaware law, the business judgm
fun dam ent al prin cip le, cod ifie d in 8 Del .C. § 141(a), that the business
the
managed by or under its board
and affairs of a Delaware corporation are
480 A.2d 619, 624 (1984);
of directors. Pogostin v. Rice, Del.Supr.,
, 811 (1984) [... ] In carrying
Aronson v. Lewis, Del.Supr., 473 A.2d 805
charged with an unyielding
out their managerial roles, directors are
shareholders. Loft, Inc. v. Guth,
fiduciary duty to the corporation and its
.Supr., 5 A.2d 503 (1939). The
Del.Ch., 2 A.2d 225 (1938), aff'd, Del
and promote the full and free
business judgment rule exists to protect
d to Delaware directors. Zapata
exercise of the managerial power grante
v. Ma ldo nad o, sup ra at 782 . The rule itself "is a presumption that
Cor p.
rs of a corporation acted on an
in making a business decision, the directo
honest belief that the action
informed basis, in good faith and in the
pany." Aronson, supra at 812.
taken was in the best interests of the com
n as uninformed must rebut the
Thus, the party attacking a board decisio
an informed one.
presumption that its business judgment was
ss judgment is an informed
The determination of whether a busine
e informed themselves "prior to
one turns on whether the directors hav
terial information reasonably
making a business decision, of all ma
available to them."
is no protection for directors
Under the business judgment rule there
o hav e ma de "an uni nte llig ent or una dvised judgment." Mitchell v.
wh
hla nd- We ster n Gla ss, Del .Ch ., 167 A. 831, 833 (1933). A director's
Hig
y to info rm him self in pre par atio n for a de?ision d~rives from the
dut
corporat10n and its stockholders.
fiduciary capacity in which he serves the
. _SeeWei~berger v. UG_P,Inc.,
Lutz v. Boas, Del.Ch., 171 A.2d 381 (1961)
d1re~tor 1s vested w1~h the
supra; Guth v. Loft, supra. Since a
_affairs of the corporat10n, he
responsibility for the management of th~
1t10n that he acts on behalf of
must execute that duty with the recogn
faithlessness or self-dealing. But
others. Such obligation does not tolerate
• , f
..
surnr
While the Delaware cases use a variety of terms to describe the giver
~
al to :6~::D:I:R
_9!..:·: IL:E
IT:C
YtT:O~R~S'~L
. ... ANDF
rness
;e_of
r
merge
U
· n r's an
mo a ffdair
·acs.quisitions wa s k nown
to
IDUCIARY DUTIES
r with Trans
~
1n a Th us , the rec ord comp 1 h
and Board lacked valua tion i:£ s t e _conclusio
. ess JU
busin . dgmen n that on September 20
~din Company . t as to th ormf ati
. on ad equate to reach the
e airness of $55 per sh an inf ormed
are for sale of the
'hief
the (2)
the the Th is brings us to the po
defen dants ultimately re;t -8
September 20 decision :ptember 20 "market tes
ited to ac t" upon which
the directors present a cep~ t~ ;~firm the rea
so na ble
the
test" of Pritzker's $55
two- t e ntzker proposal. In ness of their
her per phar ar~ment : (a) this connection,
decision to accept his s are ouer that by making a "mark
the . . of£ a cond't
1' · et
his
.
unpuls1vely or man un er, t h ey ca nn ion of
ot be fou d t the ir Se pte mb er 20
tor the adeq 1'n£orme d
. uacy of .the $ l pre ma nner on Sept bn 20o h ave t d
7 mi.um for sale of d (b)ache
cone em the
er Co ; an
mpany twaats
ms us1vely·destablished . ov
. 1bl er
he . 11ar di
re e evi ence available--ththe following 90 t o 120 days b y t h e most
imp 1e Y contend tha e marketplace .
t the "market test " eli Th us, th e de £en dants
Board to perform any mi
other form of fairness tes nated the need for the
or thereafter. t either on September 20
'
1y '
[.. .]
re The defendants
ly attempt to downplay
prohibition against Tr the significance of the
.d ans Union's actively so
arguing that the dir licitin
n ectors "understood tha g competing offers by
community would kn t the entire financia
ow that Trans Union l
0 announcement of the Pr was for sale upon the
itzker offer, and anyone
offer was free to do so desiring to make a bette
." Yet, the press release r
with the authorization issued on September 22
of the Board, stated tha ,
into "definitive agreeme t Trans Union had enter
nts" with the Pritzkers ed
not even disclose Tran ; and the press release
s Union 's limited right did
offers. Accompanying to receive and accept highe
this press release r
announcement that Pr was a further publi
itzke c
any time one million sh r had been granted an option to purchase at
ares of Trans Union's ca
pital stock at 75 cents
above the then-current
price per share.
Thus notwithstanding what severa
claimed t~ have "though l of the outside directo
t'' occurred at the meetin rs later
cone! · th t Trans Un g, the re~ord compels the
Se t usibon a ion 's Board had no ratio
·n the na
days immediately follow l basis to conclude on
P em er ing, that the Board's
20 or·t 1k r's offer wa . .
a ccep t ance of Pr1 z e
d [
s cond1t1one on ... 1a "mar k et t est ,, f
o
the offer [. . .]
[. . .] .
282 DIRECTORS' LIABILITY AND FIDUCIARY DUTIES
ARAG-GARMENBECK
German Federal Court of Justice, 1997
21 April 1997
Facts
sory board of the
The plaintiffs were members of the supervi
on insurance business.
defendant, a stock corporation in the legal protecti
and several subsidiary
Between 1984 and 1989 the defendant
business relations with a
corporations were engaged in some dubious
victed person who was
foreign corporation headed by a previously con
by borrowing money
actually running some kind of Ponzi scheme
s with very low interest
promising very high returns and granting loan
collapsed causing a loss
rates. In the beginning of 1990 this Ponzi scheme
since the defendant also
for the defendant of more than 80 Million DM
mainly guaranteed the
granted some loans to this foreign corporation but
to other lenders. The
repayment of loans of this foreign corporation
agement board of the
plaintiffs claimed that the head of the man
be held liable . At the
defendant violated his duty of care and should
was decided, without the
meeting of the supervisory board in June 1992 it
for damages against the
votes of the plaintiffs, not to pursue any claims
nt. The plaintiffs claimed
head of the management board of the defenda
court to declare it void.
that this resolution was unlawful and asked the
the claim. The Court of
The Regional Court (Landgericht) granted
.
Appeals (Oberlaudesgericht) dismissed the case
±_2~8~8'..
___.._ D~IR~E~C~T~O~R·~S'~L
~I~LI~~IAB~
TY~
':....:A~
TD~F~l
N .:::D..=U-=C-=IA=-=-R;:.; ~~
__ .Y_D_ U_T_I _E_S
directors liable for an honest error in judgment. Consider,
for example, the
holding of this recent decision of the Italian Supreme Court
:
''With respect to directors' liability , it is necessary to dist~n
guish
between directors' duties that have a specific content determ
ined by
statutory law or by the charter of the ~orpor_ation-for exam
p~e-the
procedural rules concerning the way m which corporat_e.
dec1s1ons
must be approved-and duties defined with general provis
ions, such
as the duty to manage the corporation diligently and
without
conflicts of interest. With respect to the second group
of duties,
directors' liability requires a violation of the general duty
of care,
therefore the exercise of due care is sufficient to exclude any
breach,
independently from the effects of directors' decisions. With
respect
to specific duties, on the other hand, their violation leads to
liability
unless the directors can demonstrate that the violation
could not
have been avoided exercising due care." (Trustee in Bankr
uptcy of
Giza Corporation v. Campari, Corte di Cassazione, Section
I, March
23, 2004, n. 5718).
In your opinion, is the distinction between duties with
a "specific content"
"determined by statutory law or by the charter," and duties
"defined with
general provisions" sufficiently clear and practical?
Using a different
terminology, it evokes the distinction between "rules"
and "standards": for
example, not exceeding the 50 mph is a "rule," not drivin
g recklessly is a
"standard." What are the effects of these different regula
tory strategies in
terms of enforcement?
DUTY OF LOYALTY
A director breaches his or her duty of loyalty when he or she
acts in
conflict of interest with the corporation . The classical notion of
conflict of
interest concerns situations in which there is a "zero-sum game
" between
the director and the corporation, i.e., when a gain of the director
implies a
loss or a lower gain for the corporation. An easy example is a
contract for
the sale of real estate between the corporation (buyer) and the
director
(seller). A more subtle situation occurs when the interest of the
directors
is not in overt conflict with the one of the corporation, but it
might still
taint his or her ability to exercise independent judgment
in the best
interest of the corporation. Consider the following simple
example: a
corporation involved in the business of building and opera
ting golf
courses is considering different lots on which to build a new
facility; one
of the lots is close to the house of the director, the other one is
far away. If
the corporation builds the golf course near the house of the
director, the
value of real estate in the proximity of the course will go up .
The director
might have a bias toward this first option, even if strictly speak
ing both
he and the corporation might gain from the decision (it is not
a zero-sum
game). The more modern approach is to also take into acco
unt these
situations. Often, but not always, also indirect interests
might be
89 ~C~IA~R~Y~D~U
~~-~6~__
~2~
___ D~F~I!!
TY~AN~ D~U
D_I_R_E_CT_O_R_S_'_L-:::IAB:.:::::.:l:.::::L~I
a close family member of
relevant, for exa!'11plewhen the conflict is with
th aged by the director.
the director or wi a corporation owned or man
in theory, to address
~here a-:e basically ~hree regulatory strategies,
flicted transactions might
conflicts of inte:e~t of directors. First, all con
ht however deprive the
simply ~e prohibited. A ~imilar approach mig
It is easy to imagine
corpo~atio~ of _good b~s1ness opportunities.
of reasons is willing to pay
situat10ns in which the director, for a number
she has :Uore information
the fair price for corporate assets, also because
t. The negotiation and
than a third party on the value of the asse
other hand, conflicted
transaction costs might be lower. On the
e is no need to spend time
transactions might not be regulated at all: ther
this approach. The usual
to explain why no developed economy takes
ire that the decision is
regulatory strategy is a middle ground: to requ
as to delegate the decision
taken with some procedural protections, such
s fully informed on the
to independent and non-conflicted director
is entirely fair to the
situation, or require that the transaction
corporation.
General Corporation
In this respect, Section 144 of the Delaware
Law provides as follows:
§ 144 DGCL--Interested directors; quorum.
orati~n and 1 or
"(a) No contract or transaction between a corp
orat10n and any
more of its directors or officers, or between a corp
other or~anization
other corporation, partnership, association, or
, a~e d1rect?rs or
in which 1 or more of its directors or officers
v01d or v01dab~e
officers, or have a financial interest, shall be
director or officer 1s
. solely for this reason, or solely because th~
of t~e board or
present at or participates in the meeting
sact10n, or solely
committee which authorizes the contract or tran
or officer's votes are counted for such
b ecause any su Ch dl·rector's
purpose, if:
or offic:r's
1 The material facts as to the director's transaction
( ) h. . t est and as to the contract or
ctors or the
relati?nsl ipdor in eerknown to the board· of dire · d ~ 'th
are disc ose ord arthe board or committee 1n goo 1a1
. affirmative
committee , thean t ct or transaction by the ·
authorizes con ra
. .t f the disinterested directors, even
votes of a d~~
though the 1s1n
:St:d
Jtor1
er
directors be less than a quorum; or
. 1 facts as to the director's or officer's
(2) The mate~ia t d as to the contract or transaction
s entitled to
relationship or intere~ an to the stockholder
is specifically
are disclosed orndare e ~i;~act or transaction
vote thereon, a t~h b ote of the stockholders; or
approved in good fait Yv
~2~9___
Q_O fD~IR~E~Cg_:T~
~L~I
O~R~
A~B~
S~'
I~Ll~T:2;Y..!.AN~D~F~I~D~U~C C~11
___ :'..!:IA~R: ! D_:Uc
..:.Y~
(3) The contract or transaction is fair as to the_corporati
on
as of the time it is authorized, approved or ratified, by
the
board of directors, a committee or the stockholders.
(b) Common or interested directors may ?e
determining the presence of a quorum at a ~eeting of the
counted in
board
of directors or of a committee which authorizes the cont
ract or
transaction."
As you can see the law requires procedural protection
s in case a
director has a conflidt of interest: the transaction is "cure
d" if the decision
has been taken by fully informed uninterested directors
or shareholders .
In case these procedural protections have not . been
followed, the
transaction is still safe if it is "fair" to the corporat10n
when taken. The
concept of fairness is not easy _to defi?e in the ~bst~act
, but clearly it
might include an element of fair dealmg and fair ~rice
. ?ne as_pect.to
keep in mind is that the mere fact that the _corporat10n
paid a fair p~ice
might not be sufficient to cure the transaction: for exa_
mple, purchasmg
goods at a totally fair market price, when the corporat1
0n ~as, howeve~,
no need for those goods, it is not fair for the purposes of
Sect10n 144. This
is an obvious but sometimes overlooked element.
It should be observed that a violation of the above-me
ntioned rules
can also be the basis for a liability suit against a direc
tor who breached
i her duty of loyalty, if the corporation suffered damages.
•J
' It is interesting to compare and contrast the Dela
ware rule with
corresponding rules in other systems. Most syste
ms provide for
procedural protections, such as the approval of
a transaction by
independent and informed directors, as a way to insul
ate a conflict of
interest. If those procedural protections are followed,
the transaction
usually cannot be challenged and no liability can result.
In most systems,
at the same time, even if procedural protections are not
followed, there
should be no liability if the transaction was fair to the
corporation, also
because this generally means that there were no
damages for the
corporation (but, in these situations, disgorgement of direc
tors' gains can
sometimes be obtained). It is less clear if the trans
action can be
challenged and declared void or voidable, also because
the interest of a
third party, which might be in good faith, should be
considered. The
relevance of the fairness of the transaction as an elem
ent to "save" a
conflicted transaction is, for example, debated under Chin
ese law. See, on
this_ ~ssue, Jia~g ~u ~ang, Company Law in Chin
a: Regulation of
Busi~es~ Organizations in a Socialist Market Economy
, Edward Elgar
Publishing, 2014, 207 f., pointing out that a court
could invalidate a
t~ansaction in conflict of interest not approved by infor
med independent
director_s or shareholder~, even if it is fair to the corp
oration; but also
suggesting that courts might adopt a more flexible appr
oach to this issue,
_91.6 DIRE CTORS' LIAilILITYAN
and accept "entir e fairn ess'' n F1ouc1Any DUTIES 291
a breach of the duty of 1oyalty ~
as a Possible de1ense ag · t
Let's take a quick .· amS a claim based on
1
Civil Code below : ook, m this respect , t o Ar t1cle
. 2391 Of
Article 2391 f the Italian
o the Italian c· ·1
"1. A~y d irector
' must not. f hivi Cod e- I nterests of Directors
supervisors of an · i Y t e other dir
which he has . y interest, on his behalf ectors and the board of
the terms the i~ .a .corporate transaction ~rd~n b.ehalf of others,
' rigin and th 1 ' m icatmg the nat
with .delegated powers to ac~ ~: evance of the interest; direc~;:~
refrain from entering into th t behalf of the corporation must
of the decision, in case of e r~nsaction, and invest the board
shareholders at the first sh ah single director he must notify
are olders' meeting
2. In the situations described . .
the board must adequate! m ~aragraph 1 the resolution of
advantages that the corpora/ ~oti:7ate the reasons and the
3 If P ion erives from the transaction
. aragraphs 1 or 2 are not co r d . .
resolution approved with th mp ie with, or in case of a
· e outcome-deter · t·
interested
. director ' if the r eso1u t·ion can damage
mmath1ve vote of .an
it can be challenged and voided b th d' e corporation
~:::~:or;h:/t~!;r:~e~a~~
challen~e it. In any case the rights acquired by third parties in
goo~. faith based on the resolution are not affected by th
dec1s10n. e
4. Directors are liable for the damages caused to the
corporation by their action or omission."
It should be added that also shareholders can challeng ~ the decision
of the board, if it affects their rights . As you can see the approach is not
radically different from the one adopted in Delaware, even if there are
some distinctions. First, under Italian law the director has an affirmative
duty to disclose any interest, and the entire board must take the decision ,
even if nothing prevents the possibility to delegate it to some (non -
conflicted) directors. In addition, there is not a general duty of _abstention
of the interested director. The resolution can only be challenged if: (a.l)
the director did not disclose the interest or the board did not motivate; or
(a.2) the majority has been reached wit~ ~he vote of the interested
director(s); in addition, in both cases, It IS necessa_ry ~hat (b) the
resolution can damage the corporation. If you _compare 1t w1~h Delaware
law th · · 1· htl different way to say that 1fthe transaction has been
, 1S 1S a S 1g Y d' · t' 1 f ·
approved by uninterested fully informed ,rectors, or IS en ire y air to
292 DIRECTORS' LIABILITY AND FIDUCIARY DUTIES
-
CH,6
the corporation, it shall not be void or voidable; similarly directors are not
liable if there is no damage(= the transaction is fair).
It might, however, be argued that the Delawa~e provi_sionis less
broad not including explicitly interests on behalf of third parties and only
limiting its scope to contracts between the corporation and the directors
or an affiliated party; although a similar result can probably be reached
applying the provision. Do you think that, according to a narrow textual
interpretation, the above-mentioned hypothetical concerning the golf
course, might escape § 144 DGCL, but not Article 2391 of the Italian Civil
Code?
The following case offers a classical illustration of a breach of the
duty of loyalty, focusing in particular on the issue of the burden of
proving entire fairness.
judgments entered against him in the United States District Court for the
Western District of New York, Harold P. Burke, Judge, after a bench trial
of his derivative claim against directors of SLE, and of a claim asserted
' against him by the other corporation, Lewis General Tires, Inc. ("LGT"),
which intervened in the suit. The defendants Alan E. Lewis ("Alan"),
Leon E. Lewis, Jr. ("Leon, Jr."), and Richard E. Lewis (''Richard"), are the
brothers of Donald; they were, at pertinent times herein, directors of SLE
and officers, directors and shareholders of LGT. Donald charged that his
brothers had wasted the assets of SLE by causing SLE to lease business
premises to LGT from 1966 to 1972 at an unreasonably low rental. LGT
was permitted to intervene in the action, and filed a complaint seeking
specific performance of an agreement by Donald to sell his SLE stock to
LGT in 1972. The district court held that Donald had failed to prove
waste by the defendant directors, and entered judgment in their favor.
The court also awarded attorney~' fees to the defendant directors and to
SLE, and granted LGT specific performance of Donald's agreement to sell
his SLE stock. ·
On appeal, Donald argues that the district court improperly allocated
to him the burden of proving his claims of waste, and that since
defendants failed to prove that the transactions in question were fair and
reasonable, he _was entitled to judgment. Donald also argues that the
CH, 6 DIRECTORS' LIAB
ILITY AND Fiou
awards of attorneys' £e CIARY DUTIES 293
· es were ·
content10ns, and therefore rev erseimproper. We
and rem an d. agree with each of th ese
I
For many years Le L .
defendant directors was tohn ~wi~, Sr., the father of Donald d th
· ' e prmcip 1 h an e
formedd m
. 1933, operated a t·ire dealea sh.areholder
. of SLE and LGT. LGT'
forme 1~ 1943, owned the land a rs ip m Rochester, New York. SLE,
Avenue m Rochester. This nd complex of buildings at 260 East
Prior to. 1956 LGT occupied si~rerty ~as S~E's only significant asset.
rent paid was initially $200 s premises without benefit of a lease· the
per month and h d . ,
to $800 per month by 195 6 whe ' . . a mcreased over the years
February 28, 1956, SLE gr~nted ~additional parcels were added. On
expanded property ("the Property") ~T a lO-year lease on the newly
$14,400 per year Under the te 'for a rent of $1200 per month, or
payment of real· estate taxe rmst~ t;e lease, SLE was responsible for
expenses were to be borne b sthont e roperty, while all other current
. Y e enant, LGT.
In 1962, Leon Lewis Sr tr £ d h.
to his six children (def;nd;ntt;i:{re d AlisSLE sdtock,90 shares i~ a~l,
Id d t d ar , an an Leon, Jr., pla1nt1ff
D ona , an . , Margaret and caro 1), givmg
wo . aughters · · 15 sh ares to
each . At t h at .time Richard , Alan and Leon, J r., were already
· h oIders,
shh are · officers and directors of LGT· cont emporaneous 1y wit ·h
! err receipt, of SLE s~,oc~, all six of the children entered into a
. shareholders agreement with LGT, under which each child who was not
a shareholder of LGT on June 1, 1972 would be required to sell his or her
SLE shares to LGT, within 30 days of that date, at a price equal to the
book value of the SLE stock as of June 1, 1972.
LGT's lease on th ~ SLE property expired on February 28, 1966. At
that time the directors of SLE were Richard, Alan, Leon, Jr., Leon, Sr.,
and Henry Etsberger; these five were also the directors of LGT. In 1966
Alan owned 44% of LGT, Richard owned 30%, Leon, Jr., owned 19%, and
Leon, Sr ., owned 7%. From 1967 to 1972 Richard owned 61 % of LGT and
Leon, Jr., owned the remaining 39%. When the lease expired in 1966, no
new lease was entered into. LGT nonetheless continued to occupy the
property and to pay SLE at the old rate, $14,400 per year. According to
the defendants' testimony at trial, there was never any thought or
discussion among the SLE directors of entering into a new lease or of
increasing the rent. Richard testified: "We never gave consideration to a
new lease." From all that appears, the defendant directors viewed SLE as
existing purely for the benefit of LGT. Richard_ testified, fo~ example, that
although real estate taxes · rose sharply during the per10d 1966-1971,
from approximately $7,800 to more th~~ $11,000, to be paid by SLE ?ut of
its constant $14,400 rental income, ra1s1ng the rent was neve~ mentioned.
He testified that SLE was "only a shell to protect the operating company
294 DIRECT ORS' LIABILI
--.::...;= _~q.6 RY DUTIES
AND FIDUCIA
TY -=.=:::_ Cu
-----=~~ ~~~~~~ ~~~~~: ..::....== ---..::.
(LGT)." When this suit was commenced there had not been a formal
meeting of either the shareholders or the directors of SLE since 1962
Ri?hard, Alan and Leon, Jr., had largely ignored SLE's separate corporat~
existence and disregarded the fact that SLE had shareholders who were
not shareholders of LGT and who therefore could not profit from actions
that used SLE solely for the benefit of LGT.
Neither Donald nor his sisters ever owned LGT stock. As the June
1972 date approached for the required sale of their SLE stock to LGT
Donald apparently came to believe that SLE's book value was lower tha~
it should have been. He sought SLE financial information from Richard,
who had been president of SLE since 1967. Richard refused to provide
information. Donald therefore refused to sell his SLE shares in 1972, and
commenced this shareholders' derivative action in the district court in
August 1973, basing jurisdiction on diversity of citizenship. The sole
claim raised in the complaint was that the defendant directors had
wasted the assets of SLE by "grossly undercharging" LGT for the latter's
occupancy and use of the Property. Although the complaint charged such
mismanagement for the period 1962 to 1973, plaintiff subsequently
limited this claim to the period between February 28, 1966, the date on
which the lease expired, and June 1, 1972, the date contractually set for
.~ valuation of the SLE shares which plaintiff had agreed to sell to LGT.
i/ LGT intervened and demanded specific performance of Donald's
r agreement to sell his SLE stock. Donald did not contest his ultimate
' obligation to sell, but took the position that since the book value of the
shares would be increased if he prevailed on his derivative claim, specific
performance should be granted only after adjudication of that claim.
There ensued an eight-day bench trial, at which plaintiff sought to
prove, by the testimony of several expert witnesses, that the fair rental
value of the Property was greater than the $14,400 per year that SLE had
been paid by LGT. Defendants sought to show that the rental paid was
reasonable, by offering evidence concerning the financial straits of LGT,
the cost to LGT of operating the Property, the general economic decline of
the East Avenue neighborhood, and rentals paid on two other properties
.,
I'
in that neighborhood. LGT presented expert testimony that the value of
'i' .,
plaintiffs stock as of June 1972, assuming a successful defense of the
derivative claims, was $15,650.
The district court subsequently filed lengthy and detailed findings of
fact and conclusions of law. Many of the court's findings went to the
)
validity and probative value of the testimony given by plaintiffs expert
. '
I
witnesses, and the court ultimately declined to credit that testimony. On
j
'j this basis, the court held that Donald had failed to establish the rental
.:J
value of the Property during the period at issue, and that defendants
l
'i were therefore entitled to judgment on the derivative claims. Implicit in
.i
the district court's ruling, granting judgment for defendants upon
1
i
I
••
possi·ble d et rimental
· effectse of
urath and sub st antive rules to mitigate the
subject is related to another -t~e transactions . More specifically a
controlled by the same entity·ontehi
0
it co~trols it, is controlled by it 0 ; is
for examp e, executives are c .d relatio nsh'1ps are also considered-so
1 ' er '
work for, and family member:n~\~red related to the corporation the;
related parties. The regulation t~ ~dab~ve-m~ntioned subjects are also
of "major relevance" based en i£entifies, m particular, transactions
· 1 ·
particu ar economic importanc £a ormula , meamng
on · .
transactions of
exceeds 5% of the equity or t~' or example transactions whose value
approve these transactions e ass.~s of the corporation. In order to
protections must be adopted . ' speci ic procedural and substantive
b In d particular,
f d. t to
( simplify ' th ese t ransactions
. must be approved by the
. o;r o d i:e~_or\ cannot be delegated to one director). A committee of
m epen ~n. irec ors not related to the corporation must be involved in
the
· 11negotiat10n
d of ·the transaction
. ' obtain adequat e in
· £ormation
· on it, · an d
is a dowe to require further mformation and give · adV1ce
· . In a dd.ition,
· th e
boar can ap~rove the transaction only after having obtained an opinion
by the ~ommittee ~n th~ interest of the corporation to enter into the
transaction, an~ o?its fairn~ss. Alternative procedures can be adopted as
Ion? ~s the ~aJority o~ the mdependent and not related directors have a
decisive role in approving the transaction. Finally, the board can decide to
carr~ ~n the tran~~ction also against the advice of the committee, but only
obtammg a positive vote of the shareholders (for a more detailed
discussion of these rules, including an empirical analysis of the
application, see M. Bianchi and others, Regulation and Self-Regulation of
Related Parties Transactions in Italy, Quaderni di Finanza Consob, 2014,
available at www.consob.it).
This regulation is partially inspired by the U.S. approach, in the
sense that in the presence of a potential conflict it requires the adoption
of procedural safeguards to ensure the fairness of the transaction . One
problem worth discussing, however, is whether the regulatory approach,
or at least the way in which it is enforced, mixes up procedural and
substantive protections. As we have discussed, under U.S. law, if a
director has a conflict of interest but the transaction is approved by fully
informed independent directors or shareholders, the transaction cannot
be challenged. When the procedural protections are no~ foll~wed, the
transaction can be saved only if the defendants prove entire fairness. In
other words, the substance of the deal (its fai_rness)is o~ly examined if
there was a procedural failure. In the Italian re_gulation_on related
arti'e , t t' s on the other hand, the committee of independent
P s ransac 10n , · b ·
directors does not simply approve the transaction, ut _must_issue an
·n· ·t " · I thi's opinion protected by the business Judgment
Opi 10n on i s 1airness. s . .
rule? Or can courts and enforcement agencies second-guess the merits of
304 DIRECTORS' LIABILITY AND FIDUCIARY DUTIES
in
le
1e
n CHAPTER 7
:t
3
1 SHAREHOLDERS' LITIGATION
1
)
•••
INTRODUCTION
As we have seen in the prev10us
. itself .
towar d th e corporation t d . chapt er, d"1rectors can be hable
.
and toward corporate creditoowa~mgle sha~eholders or third parties,
fiduciary duties, damage the rs. e~ever directors, breaching their
shareholders. Clearly enough 1.f th corporat10n th · d"
' ey m 1rectly damage also
valuable or the business is 1 ' fieassets of the corporation are less
.
negligence or abuse also ess th
pro 1table as a co
nsequence of d.1rectors,
shareholders is gene;all 1 th
e. va ue of e shares owned by the
· k f th · 't d Y, ~egatively affected; or at least the return and
r1s o e 1nves ment eter10rate.
When th e damage c~used affects both the corporation and its
shareholders,
l one problem
. 1s who is entitled t o sue. Th e corporation
· 1s· a
separate egal entity fro1? the shareholders, and it h~s the right to sue
and be sued. Generally, if the corporation has a cause of action against
someone, it can sue. The decision to sue, if and how to continue litigation,
and the management of the dispute, is normally a business decision
rese~ved to directors (sometimes delegated, at least in part, to high-
rankmg corporate employees). When, however, the potential defendant is
one or more current directors, it is unlikely that the top management
acting on behalf of the corporation, drags to court one of their own.
Of course there could be situations in which the corporation (i.e., the
board of directors) will decide to sue a member of the board, for example
in case of an egregious violation of a single director alienating fellow
directors, or-more often-when new directors are appointed, possibly
after an acquisition, and they realize that the previous board has harmed
the corporation. Even this scenario , however, is not very common: there
can be a certain degree of reciprocal back-scratching among directors that
makes these lawsuits fairly rare. ·
Shareholders however, need to be protected . For this reason most
modern legal syst~ms have introduced "~erivative actions." Even _if, as we
will see, the role of these procedural devices and the rules governmg them
differ in different jurisdictions, they share some common f~atures. In .a
derivative action, shareholders are allowed-meeting cer~ain
· t t corporate directors on behalf of the corporation.
re qmremen s- o sue
317
318 SHAREHOLDERS' LITIGATION CH.7
They can, in other words, step in the shoes of the corporation
and assert a
claim that belongs to the legal entity, in order to overcome the
reluctance,
when not the conflict of interest, which prevents directors from
suing. In
case of victory, monetary damages would be awarded to the
corporat~on
(with very few exceptions, as we will see), not to the share
holders suing
derivatively; and only under certain conditions winning
shar~holders
might be entitled to recover their legal expenses from the corpo
ration.
Based on these elements you might wonder why shareholde
rs bring
derivative lawsuits at all. What incentives do they have?
On the one
hand, even if compensation goes to the corporation, shareholde
rs might
indirectly benefit from it: if the assets of the corporation are
restored to
their original value, this increased value should be reflected
in the value
and the market price of the shares. Secondly, shareholders migh
t sue also
to stop an ongoing abuse (obtaining an injunction), or as part
of a strategy
aimed at ousting incompetent or unfaithful directors. Final
ly, derivative
litigation can be attorney-driven, especially if lawyers can
take the case
on a contingency fee basis.
It is important to understand that shareholders can sue deriv
atively
only when the corporation is damaged. There might be
situations,
however, in which directors, breaching their duties, cause
a damage
directly to the shareholders, a damage that is not the cons
equence of a
damage suffered by the corporation. Consider the following
example:
directors intentionally publish false financial statements
or a false
prospectus that fools existing shareholders into believing
that the
economic situation of the corporation is much better than
it actually is.
Relying on this information, existing shareholders subscribe
newly issued
shares at a price significantly superior to the fair value of
the securities.
When the truth is discovered, the price of the shares drop
s, causing a
significant loss to the shareholders. In this situation, you
might argue
that the breach of the directors has damaged directly
(only) the
shareholders, not the corporation . You might even go as far
as arguing
that the corporation not only has suffered no damage, but
it has had an
advantage because it was able to receive more financial resou
rces for its
shares. In this case shareholders have a direct cause of
action against
directors (and a class action or other form of collective redre
ss might be
available), but there is no derivative lawsuit, since the corpo
ration has not
been hurt. As we will see, to distinguish between direct
and derivative
claims is not always as easy as it might seem.
Keep in mind that, in several jurisdictions, at least in
theory,
shareholders can sue derivatively on behalf of the corporatio
n also a third
party who is not a director and damaged the corporation.
This type of
suits is however rare, and in any case in this book we
only consider
derivative actions against directors.
CH. 7
SHAREHOLDER ,L
S ITIGATION 319
This chapter discusses sharehold , . .
common law systems and in f ~rs derivative actions, starting with
their regulation in other syst par 1; ar :U
derivative claim, and the pro::·
·~
· law, and then considering
e will investigate how to identif~ a
derivatively have to jum th ~al loopholes that shar eholders suing
their corporation. On the ~the:o~g to suc
~es
( nd its directors) can f£ t· 1 and _wewill sfull!' sue the directors_of
a_ . . consider how a corporat10n
will focu e ec ive Y avo id or resi st derivative lawsuits . We
. . s, 1n particular, on some basi·c di'st inc
· t 10n
· s b et wee
and
. civil law systems., and the different role of n common 1aw
. th e sh are h old ers '
m thes~ legal _families also vis-a-vis dire meet 1ng
'
ctors' liabilities toward the
corpo~~tion, a diffe~ence that might partially
prevruling ownership structures (see Chapter be explained in light of the
1).
[. . .]
VEASEY, CHIEF JUSTICE:
[...]
. Facts
. L wis are former minority stockholders
Patrick Tooley and Kevin e of
D ld L fk. (DLJ) a Delaware corporation
ona son, u 1n & Jenrett e, 1nc.
ki ,
uired by Credit. 8 u1s.
engaged in investmen~ ban
Group (Credit Suisse) in .th e
;;ll
DLJ was acq
of 2000 . Before that acquisition , AXA
d o/c of DLJ stock, controlled DLJ.
se
l (since in equity there is no jury). The distinction and the question are not so
relevant in Delaware where the Court of Chancery-as the name suggests-
is a court of equity and no jury is present. Also the distinction between
remedies at law (monetary damages) and in equity (injunctions, specific
performance, modification of contract .. .) is today not so relevant, as courts of
general jurisdiction can grant both remedies. The question has, however,
been addressed in an interesting 1970 Supreme Court case, Ross v. Bernhard
(396 U.S. 351), which based on the Seventh Amendment of the U.S.
Constitution (right to jury trial) has concluded that, at least in federal courts,
if the underlying issue could be brought as an action at law by the
corporation, the shareholders suing derivatively have a right to a jury trial.
We have not included this case, which deals primarily with a procedural law
question, but if you are curious to know more check it out!
***
Shareholders suing derivatively act on behalf of the corporation. The
claim in truth, belongs to the corporation. To allow shareholders to sue.
'
derivatively without giving to the corporation-and therefore to its
---=S:...::.H=-AR~E~H~O~L~D~E~RS~_____ :!TI!!~9
'__!L~IT~I~G~A_l!32 O~N~
...:.7
_0!~~_____
e. At
directors-a~y ch~nce ~o control the litigation would seem too extrem
ion. The
the same time, it might prompt excessive and futile litigat
to sue
proced~ral tool used to balance the possibility of shareholders
derivatively
,, a nd corporate control over litigation is the "demand on the
boar d .
tive
. The rule requires that shareholders , before bringing a deriva
Basically
action, must make ~ proper demand on the board of directors.
want
shareholders must give to directors the opportunity to decide if they
on to
to sue or not. On the one hand, directors might be in the best positi
st of the
properly_eval~ate t~e pros and cons of the litigation in the intere
es of a
corpo~at1on, . includi~g. for example the reputational consequenc
often
lawsuit against existing or former directors. Needless to say,
and even
directors prefer not to bring a lawsuit against fellow directors,
might be
more so if the very directors that must decide whether to sue
a conflict
implicated in the litigation. Directors, in other words, can have
rs.
of interest in deciding whether to sue as required by the shareholde
ing
. Shareholders can challenge the decision of the board, follow
by the
demand, not to litigate, but the board decision can be protected
decision,
business judgment rule (see Chapter 6). To set aside the
decision
shareholders would have to overcome the presumption that the
the best
has been taken in good faith, on an informed basis, and in
h of the
interest of the corporation, for example demonstrating a breac
duty of loyalty . As we know, it might be difficult to prevail.
nd
On the other hand, there are some situations when the dema
nd on
requirement, i.e., the rule requiring shareholders to make a dema
excused:
the board before bringing a derivative lawsuit, can be
. This is
shareholders can go directly to court with their derivative claim
n of
the case when shareholders can prove-and they have the burde
proving it-that the demand would be futile, because it is almost certain
of a
that the board would decide not to litigate, for example in the light
conflict of interest.
the
To decide when demand should be excused is not easy, as
s have
following case illustrates. Also for this reason some jurisdiction
is never
preferred to adopt a so-called universal demand rule: demand
holders
excused. In Delaware , however, demand can be excused, and share
e~tly. to
often try to have the demand requirement byp~ssed and. go dir
dismiss
court (on the other hand, the directors _woul_df~le a motion to
ore, to
based on failure to make a demand). It is quite important , theref
are
understand when courts would excuse dema~d. A 1984 Delaw
used but
Supreme Court case, Aronson u. Lewis, has estabhs_hed a broadly
mere fact
not crystal-clear standard holding among other things that the
ient to
that the directors are na~ed as possible defendants is not suffic
demand.
consider them in conflict of interest and therefore to excuse the
330 SHAREHOLDERS' LITIGATION CH. 7
If that was the case it would be too easy for the shareholders-plaintiffs to
always avoid dema~d, simply by naming the exist~ng directors as possi?le
defendants. The court said that in order to consider the den:iand futile,
something more is necessary. More precisely,. the court in Aronson
determined that demand can be excused if shareholders plead
particularized facts raising a reasonable doubt that a majority of direct?rs
are interested and/or not independent; or that the challenged transaction
was not the product of a valid exercise of the board's business judgment.
A more recent case decided in 2000 by the Delaware Supreme Court,
Brehm v. Eisner, illustrates the standard adopted to decide if demand can
be excused. The case concerns the epic litigation over the compensat ion
and termination payout of Michael S. Ovitz as President of the Walt
Disney Corporation. In short, Ovitz was hired in 1995, but was
terminated without fault just over 14 months after, receiving a severance
package worth approximately 140 million dollars. Shareholders were not
happy, and some of them tried to sue derivatively the directors arguing
that demand should be excused . (On the recent corporate story of Disney,
we recommend a page-turner: "Disney War" by Pulitzer Prize winner
James B. Stewart)
Before reading the case, however, it is important to understand and
keep in mind one issue of litigation strategy: from the perspective of
shareholders, to make a demand on the board is risky, because the board
can refuse to sue, and this decision would be difficult to challenge . On the
other hand, if shareholders go straight to court and argue that demand
would be futile, they also are in a difficult position: they must satisfy the
somehow exacting standard of Aronson without having , generally, access
to full discovery. In a way, shareholders are caught between the rock of
"demand on the board " and the hard place of demonstrating the "futility''
of the demand with limited evidence. Notwithstanding this, · most
plaintiffs prefer to try to argue that demand should be excused . This can
cau_se ~xcess_ive litigation (and keep in mind, in this respect, that
derivative suits are often attorney-driven) . For this reason, the American
Law Institute before, and the Model Business Corporation Act after (and
~ev~ral states foll~wing .the MBCA), ha~e suggested or opted for a
universal demand requirement, mandating that shareholders, in any
case, must make a demand on the board.
And, with this, let's take a look at Brehm v. Eisner.
CH. 7
SHAREHOLDERS' L
ITIGATION
331
BREHM V. EISNER 0
s ' VITz, AND OTHERS
upreme Court of DeIaware
746 A.2d 244 (2000)
[... ]
VEASEY, CHIEF JUSTICE:
In this appeal from the C t f
oft h e Court of Chancery thatour th o Chaneery, we agree with · the holding
subject to dismissal for failure to es::~ckholder ~eriv~tive Complaint was
reasonable doubt that the d" orth particularized facts creating a
independent or that the· irectdor defend ants were disinterested and
judgment rule. Our affirmaIr con h uct was . .prot ect ed bY t h e busmess
.
nee, owever Is in pa t b d h
different analysis than th t Of ' r ase on a somew at
·
Accordingly · the inte
In t aOf . .the Court below or th e par t·ies.
. . ' res s Justice, we reverse only to the extent of
proVIding th at one aspect of the dismissal shall be without prejudice, and
we rema~d to the Court of Chancery to provide plaintiffs a reasonable
op?o_rtunity to file a further amended complaint consistent with this
opm10n.
The claims before us are that: (a) the board of directors of The Walt
Disney Company ("Disney") as it was constituted in 1995 (the "Old
Board") breached its fiduciary duty in approving an extravagant and
wasteful Employment Agreement of Michael S. Ovitz as president of
Disney; (b) the Disney board of directors as it was constituted in 1996 (the
"New Board") breached its fiduciary duty in agreeing to a "non-fault"
termination of the Ovitz Employment Agreement, a decision that was
extravagant and wasteful; and (c) the directors were not disinterested and
independent.
The Complaint, consisting of 88 pages and 285 paragraphs, is a
pastiche of prolix invective. It is permeated with conclusory allegations of
the pleader and quotations from the media, mostly of an editorial natu:e
(even including a cartoon). A pleader may rely on factual statements 1n
the media as some of the "tools at hand" from which t~e pleader intends
to derive the particularized facts necessary to comply with ~hancery Rule
ll(b)(3) and Chancery Rule 23.1. But ma~y _of;he quotat10ns fro~ the
media in the Complaint simply echo plaintiffs concl~sory allegat10ns.
. 1 h no purpose other than to complicate the work of
Accor d 1ng y, t ey serve
reviewing courts. .
. . · · 11 a very troubling case on the merits. On the one
This 1s potentia Y · t that· (a) the compensation and
hand it appears from the Comp 1ain · · ·r ·
: . O itz were exceedingly lucrative, 1 not 1uxur1ous,
term1nat10n payout for v h C pany· and (b) the processes of the
d O ·t ' alue to t e om '
compare to Vl Z _v .n with the approval and termination of the
boards of directors 1n deah g casual if not sloppy and perfunctory .
Ovitz Employment Agreement ~~r~ is so ~nartfully drafted that it was
On the other hand, the Comp ain
}
I
CH. 7
332 SHAREHOLDERS' LITIGATION
f
/I
I
second published statement appeared in an article about three
weeks
later in the January 13, 1997 edition of California Law Business.
The
article appears first to paraphrase Crystal: ''With no one expec
ting
failure, the sleeper clauses in Ovitz's contract seemed innocuous
Crystal
says, explaining that no one added up the total cost of the s~ver
ance
package." The article then quotes Crystal as saying that the amou
nt of
Ovitz' severance was "shocking'' and that "[n]obody quantified this
and I
wish we had ." One of the charging paragraphs of the Comp
concludes: laint
and independence
involved in the first prong of Aronson are whether a
majority of the New
Board, which presumably was in office when plaintiffs
filed this action,
was disinterested and independent. That is, were they
incapable, due to
personal interest or domination and control, of objec
tively evaluating a
demand, if made, that the Board assert the corporati
on's claims that are
raised by plaintiffs or otherwise remedy the alleged
injury? This rule is
premised on the principle that a claim of the corp
oration should be
evaluated by the board of directors to determine if pursu
it of the claim is
in the corporation's best interests. That is the analy
sis the Court of
,r'
Cu. 7
SHAREHOLDERS' LITIGATION . -
338 . t O be entrusted with a
· I
this rule and can articu e a
8 t reasonable
. basis h d the rule does
On the other an '
claim that belongs to the corporat10n. or oration to expe1:d mone?7 and
not permit a stockholder to ~au~e the ~to~kholder's quixotic pu_rs_mtof a
resources in discovery and trial I~ the 1 1 on conclusions, opmions or
purport ed corporate claim b~se soDeyald·
t d in Grimes v. on .
speculation. As we st a e t y purpose . First, by
The demand requirement serves a sa 1u ar medies the demand
.
requiring exhaust10n of m · tra-corporate re ' .
. d" pute resolution proce dure
· of alternative is
'
requirement invokes a sp~cies S d if litigation 1s· b ene fi1c1a
· 1,
th
which might avoid litigation altoge er._ eco;h .rd if demand is excused
the corporation can control the procee~;gs. - ~ ~ormally control the
or wrongfully refused , the stockho er w11
proceedings . .
d 1·t rogeny is designed to create a
The jurisprudence of Aronson an sp h hand deter costly
. balanced environment which will: (1) on the _one to eli~inate claim~
· b f g a screening mec amsm
baseless smts Y cream . .
where there is only a susp1c10~exp~essed solety 1 in conclusory terms; and
kh lder who is able to
(2) on the other hand, permit suit by a s oc ?
articulate particularized facts showing that there is a reasonable doubt
either that (a) a majority of the board is independent ~or ~urposes of
responding to the demand, or (b) the underlying transaction 1s protected
by the business judgment rule .
[...]
Independence of the Disney Board
The test of demand futility is a two-fold test under Aronson and its
progeny. The first prong of the futility rubric i~ "whether, under the
particularized facts alleged, a reasonable doubt 1s created that . . . the
directors are disinterested and independent." The second prong is
whether the pleading creates a reasonable doubt that "the challenged
transaction was otherwise the product of a valid exercise of business
judgment." These prongs are in the disjunctive. Therefore, if either prong
is satisfied, demand is excused.
In this case, the issues of disinterestedness and independence
involved in the first prong of Aronson are whether a majority of the New
Board, which presumably was in office when plaintiffs filed this action,
was disinterested and independent . That is, were they incapable, due to
personal interest or domination and control, of objectively evaluating a
demand, if made, that the Board assert the corporation's claims th at are
raised by plaintiffs or otherwise remedy the alleged injury? This rule is
premised on the principle that a claim of the corporation should be
evaluated by the board of directors to determine if pursuit of the claim is
in the corporation's best interests. That is the analysis the Court of
:-:;::~~~S~H~A~R
7
f!!--:·
__~_E_~_H
_ ~O~L~D
~
Chancery brought to bear
examine to the extent nece~snat h
ERS LITIGATIO
) the Court of Chancery held that the Complaint did not create a
reasonable doubt that the Old Board had satisfied the requisite
informational component when it approved the Ovitz contract in 1995. In
effect, Plaintiffs argue that being "reasonably informed" is too lax a
standard to satisfy Delaware's legal test for the informational component
of board decisions. They contend that the Disney directors on the Old
Board did not avail themselves of all material information reasonably
available in approving Ovitz' 1995 contract, and thereby violated their
fiduciary duty of care.
The "reasonably informed" language used by the Court of Chancery
here may have been a short-hand attempt to paraphrase the Delaware
jurisprudence that, in making business decisions, directors must consider
all material information reasonably available, and that the directors'
process is actionable only if grossly negligent. The question is whether the
trial court's formulation is consistent with our objective test of
reasonableness, the test of materiality and concepts of gross negligence.
We agree with the Court of Chancery that the standard for judging the
informational component of the directors' decision-making does not mean
that the Board must be informed of every fact. The Board is responsible
for considering only material facts that are reasonably available, not
those that are immaterial or out of the Board's reasonable reach.
We conclude that the formulation of the due care test by the Court of
Chancery in this case, while not necess arily inconsistent with our
traditional formulation, was too cryptically stated to be a helpful
precedent for future cases. Pre-suit demand will be excused in a
8 J3~4!1
_0!~7------ _____~'.!:LfIT!:!IQGA ~T~I[_QO~N~
~:-.:-= :...:::.H::.A~R::!:::E~H~O~L!!_DE~R~S
. .
derivative suit only if the Court of Ch instan ce, and this
C0 urt in its de novo revie ancery 1n the first
1ude that the particularized facts in the
plaint create a reaso wblco~c
th
~~: directors' decision-mU:ki~ oubt at the informationa l component of
of gross
z· ence included co .d g_ process, measured by concepts
nsi eration of all material inform ation reaso nably
neg~gbl ' Th
ava .a e. . us, we now apply this analytical framework to the
t· f
part1cular1zed facts pleaded juxtaposed w1·th th e presump ion o
regularity of the Board's proce~s.
in
[0~ th ese bases, the_ court examines the conduct of the directors
of
approVIng the compensatwn package and dealing with the termination
that the
Ovitz, ~nd finds that there is no reasonable ground to believe
].
board VIolated procedural or substantive due care, or committed waste
Conclusion
with
One can understand why Disney stockholders would be upset
lucrative compensation agreement and
such . a~ extraordinarily
only a
termination payout awarded a company president who served for
d. That
little over a year and who underperformed to the extent allege
not insurmountable-burden on
said, there is a very large-though
tive
stockholders who believe they should pursue the remedy of a deriva
these
suit instead of selling their stock or seeking to reform or oust
directors from office.
Delaware has pleading rules and an extensive judicial gloss on those
tive
rules that must be met in order for a stockholder to pursue the deriva
. This
remedy. Sound policy supports these rules, as we have noted
does
Complaint, which is a blunderbuss of a mostly conclusory pleading,
not meet that burden, and it was properly dismissed.
[... ]
SHAREHOLDERS' LITIGATION
CH.7 -C
C
344 vail it would make perfect
. d. the likelihood to pre '
In this case, notwiths~an _mgthe directors) not to sue.
sense for the corporation(i.e., . t t this case and especially
. ective con . of t h e German
ras decision
5 · From a comparative
persp . ' h 1997
· · t 4 with t e · 6 A
what we explained above m pom , enbeck examined m Chapter_ . . _nd
Federal Court of Justice ARAG/Garm . on the Mannesmann litigation
, bservations
keep in mind Professor Gevurt_zs O Wh t are the differences, 1 any,
·r
in Germany reported abov~ in Notewi.th 1 a
respect ·
to directors ' d'iscre t·ion in
between German and American La_w ?
decidingto sue directors and executives.
***
na e to initiate the derivative
Let's imagine that the shareholfdelrlsmthaat1emand would have been
success u. tYthat directors can do 1f
example a rguing
• I! .
smt, 1or . h' they come
futile. Is there something, at ~ . ~om 18
18
: otentially very disruptive and
to the conclusion that th_e htigat~on p d the possible benefits?
damaging for the corporation, and its costs excee .
al device envisioned by corporate law attorneys is th~ so-
calle~~':p~c1al litigation committee" (or "SLC"). Direct?rs can appomt a
special committee, composed of individuals completely mde~e_nde~t from
the litigation (sometimes elected to the board af~er the htiga~i?n ~as
commenced specifically for the purpose of servmg ~n the ~1ti~at10n
committee) to decide on the opportunity to file a motion. to d~sm~ss or
·i otherwise settle the litigation . The decision to voluntar~~ d1sm1ss or
settle a derivative action, under both Federal Rules of Civil Procedure
and Delaware Chancery Rules, must be approved by the court. If the
committee is truly independent and in good faith and its conclusions are
well supported, the court should exercise its own independent business
judgment in determining whether the motion should be granted. More
precisely, the decision to dismiss or settle of the SLC is upheld by the
courts if two conditions are met: (1) the corporation proves that the
members of the SLC were independent, in good faith, and conducted a
reasonable investigation; and (2) the court determines, exercising its own
independent judgment, that the motion to discontinue the litigation
should be granted in the light of the best interest of the corporation. In
l '
many ways, this is a kind of "watered down" version of the business
!' judgment rule, one in which it is the corporation that has the burden of
'
'I .
.,j
proving the independence and care of the SLC, and still the court can
second-guess the merits of the decision. In this respect it can be argued
that the court is allowed more latitude in reviewing the decision of the
,.
.1 dir~ctors (to_ ~ismiss the action) than generally with respect to other
:I busmess dec1s10ns, presumably for two reasons: the delicacy of the matter
and the specter of a conflict of interest of directors or at least of some
recip:ocal back-s_cratching with the fellow director~ sued; and the fact
I
.I
t~at ~udges are ~1kely to be more well-equipped to evaluate a decision to
d1sm1ss a lawsmt, rather than other business decisions. Two interesting
I
.f!!·7 . .
SHAREHOLD ,
ERS LITIGATION 345
cases discu ssing the special 1·t·Igati.on c .
. I rea d"I~gs, are ZapaI ta M ommittee, which can be suggested
as optiona
Thompson v. Scientific Atlanta, ~75 aldonado, 430 A.2d 779
(1981), and
example of how the special Iitigat·Ion comm Ga.App. 680 (2005). They offer an
ittee sh Id k
To sum up what we have d" ou wor .
. Iscus sed he ' d'
' _res a Iagram that represents
the diffieren t a It ernatives that · h t occu r ma derivative action:
mig
demand on board
f shareholders / ~
.
I
I
if shareholders are
suing derivatively,
~~~t.~.
) demand excused ~- - - - _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ :d::e~:~
to decide motion
to dismiss
***
picture
~en_ we shif~ our focus on derivative actions in the U.K., the
these actions
emerging IS very different than the one in the U.S. Although
on law, they
were recognized as early as the nineteenth century at comm
ght, rarely
were hardly ever used, and even when they were brou
current U .K.
supported by the court. The following extract discusses the
the reasons
rules (which since October 2007 are governed by statute), and
in mind a
why these actions are so rare. But before that we should keep
, which have
couple of fundamental differences between the U.S. and U.K.
fees and the
a bearing on derivative actions. These relate to attorney's
U.K. loser pays principle (discussed in more detail below
), which means
ative claim
that a shareholder in the U.K. who decides to bring a deriv
be obtained
must not only fund the action (unless third party funding can
r against
or the court orders the company to indemnify the shareholde
ed t?~ay the
liability for those costs), but also bears the risk of ~e~1;gorder
obta1n1ng an
defendant directors' costs (subject to the poss1b1hty of
~osition in the
indemnity from the company). This is ~issimilar to the
ct to
U.S., where parties usually bear their own costs. With respe
in t~e ~ederal
attorney's fees, whereas these are specifically p~ov~dedfor
continuing an
Rules of Civil Procedure and state laws for ~ru~g1ng and
as are the
action, in the U.K. the Companies Act 2006 1s silent on these
,
s' LITIGATION Cu, 7
SHAREHOLDER
350 QUESTIONS
NOTES AND d the two-stage permission
. . un er
extensive criteria. illustrate wel 1 h ov: .proce.duraUy
1. The abov_e derivative claim d to provide d1smcentives to
application to continue/ h law has develo~e hareholder who genuine
ly
and sub~tantiv~ly. E:g I~agine a bona fi ero:gh this (non-ex~a~stive, it
prospective plain_tiff · action and reads thh UK Law Comm1ss1on itself
contemp la t es taking an
d) r t It is no surprise ·
,
as t e · ·
h "list may appear to be a set
should be stresse . isP~per para 16.43), th at t edwhich would deter them.
d ·ts (Consultation ' It
a mi h' h pplicants have to overcome .
an . .
f ot favoring derivative actions .
of hurdle~lwbic se:n as maintaining a policy o hnto shareholders which would
could easi Y e
. 1 of an over-res t ric · tive approac
· the averages h are h old er will
and as a signa " d with these complex1·t ies,
over-deter them . Fae~ d t this early stage.
often give up in despair alrea ya y produce as did the case law
2 The exacting criteria . . 1·sted1 . above maautious ' . 1 d ..
. d . fve action judic1a ec1s10ns (the
1 over-c h
on the common law eriva
. . ·t'
. . 'th applica tion no less t an fiive times
.
1 st' d1sm1s s e .
court is remmded that mu nstrainmg the flex1'bl e exercise .
of
in sections 261-264). It could be_se~n as acsoanxious to encourage, in that
the
discretion which the Law Co~m~ssionf \her criteria may suggest that
. .on of th ese these
an d the om1ss1on o .
0
mclus1 rtant
are the only relevant ones or the most impo . . .
. ractical difficulties, do you thmk the_re is any
3. Given the above P . t' claim procedure under English law at
value in having a statu~ofryh_deriva~v:re was not available to shareholders?
all? What would be lost i t is proce
Do you th m . k u K J·udges should follow U.S. judges and be more
4 · · · t ff · ? If
· · · 11 d ·
willmg to a ow er1vat·1ve a ctions and hence intervene m corpora ea airs.
h?
so, what do you think would be the price of such an approac .
***
DERIVATIVE SUITS IN CIVIL LAW
EUROPEAN SYSTEMS
/ As mentioned in the Introduction, several continental European
systems belonging to the civil law tradition have adopted, more or less
recently, rules that might be considered the equivalent of the common-
law-style derivative suits. Even if with meaningful differences, these
,,
rules share with common-law derivative suits the goal of allowing
},
shareholders "to take matters into their own hands," and sue directors on
behalf of the corporation.
Italian law offers, in this perspective, an illustrative example. You
might remember that in Chapter 5, discussing corporate governance, but
also in other parts of this book, we have observed how in civil law
countries, where the ownership structure also of listed corporations is
more concentrated or at least there are "stronger" owners and "weaker"
managers, the shareholders' meeting often has more powers vis-a-visthe
_0!J SHAREHOL · GATION
DERS' LITI
board of directors when
di·r'1e
Crence ca 1 c
.d . Jt n a so be se ompared to
cons1 ermg a )"ian law en in th e are co0 fmd" mon law system Th'
b
351
,As a general rule, un as a represent a. S.
irectors' liability, spec 1S ast·C
der Italian ative example of these ifically
entrusted to the shareh 1 ju ris di cti ons .
lawsuit would be). Thisolders' !1w, th e decision to su
appro ~etmg, not to e di rectors
resolve the conflict of the directors (as any ot is
interest~~ :i:kes a lo her
themselves or their fe t of se ns e, be ca us e it sh
llow dire ta irectors
wi.th 1a:ge s h areholde can have if they have toould
rs c or s. Bu t
often holdi ' th ere is . ab sue
corporation, the real ~t ... In a sy
minority shareholders. conflict f . ng t a_ controllmg stake in stethm
themselves, or in any Contr ~- mtereS ts be e
ca se
tween controlling and
block holders appoin diroec~~;s~hareholders
t an d are ~£ten directors
compensation and of ave a_strong allegian ce to them:
ten o-i remove directors, de
this means th' at the t:, ~v em or e or 1 ter m ine their
. contr Ir ess s t ne· t d'irecti·ons. In
·11
dire· ctodrs Wl · rare £1y su
° m g s
h
ar eh olders who have appo practice,
inted the
was amaging e . th em . ' especiall Y if th e a11eged
shareholders. or mmonty sharehol di. rectors' breach
ders but n 0 t f
or contro11m· g
To balance ~his po~s
ible agency problem,
allo_wsalso a q~ahfied the Italian Civil Code
minority to sue derivati
vely. Consider the follo
Article 2393-bis: wing
"1. Shareholders representing
outstanding shares or at least one-fifth
the different percentag of the
bylaws, not to exce e established in the
ed one-third, can su
damages caused to th e the directors for
e corporation.
2. In publicly held
corporations, sharehol
least 2.5% of the ou ders representing at
tstanding shares, or
established in the by the lower threshold
laws, can exercise th
e action regulated by
the previous paragrap
h.
3. The corporation
must be served of pr
party in the lawsuit. Th ocess and can be a
e corn.plaint rnust be no
president of the supe
tified also to the
rvisory board.
4. The shareholde
rs intending to sue rn
ust appoint, through a
· majority vote, one or
more lead plaintiffs.
. victory of the shareh
n case Of olders, the corporati
5 I
reimburses the plaintiff on
s for the expenses of t h 1. . . h
the judge has not orde 1t1gation t ~t e
red the losing defendan
ts to pay or that 1S
not possible to recupe
rate from th em.
6 The shareholders
that have
d: . h d' ute· any copr omoted th; lithigadt~on.
rn pensat1on ,or t e 1srn1Scanl
1sm1ss or sett 1et. e sa
isp ' ld b aid to the corp
or settling of the dispute shou oration."
eP
352 SHAREHOLDERS'LITIGATION CH.7
[... ]
INTRODUCTION
. Th~ objective of this symposium
piece is to explore why shareholder
derivative suits are rare in Co
ntinental Europe. I mainly focus
Germany, France, and Italy, and on
further provide less extensive refere
regarding derivative suits in Au nces
stria, Belgium, the Netherlands,
and Switzerland. In doing so, Spain,
I compare the Continental Europ
situation with the one in the Un ean
ited States and Japan, where der
suits are important mechanisms ivative
of corporate governance enforcem
is sometimes thought that sha ent. It
reholder litigation and litigiousn
general are cultural ess in
features of U.S. society. In
shareholder derivative suits hav Jap an- wh ere
e also become common since the
1990s-cultural theories gave way to theories early
incentives that were more stro em pha siz ing eco nom ic
ngly supported by the evidence,
discernible cultural shift occurr as no
ed when suits became widesprea
emphasize economic incentives d. I als o
set by the legal framework to exp
scarcity of derivative suits in lain _the
Continental ~urope. Tins explan
similar to the explanation provid ation,
ed for_Japan, is_also ~nly cultural
as legal and structural constraints as far
setting these incentives are part
of the
respective culture. [... ]
rs omitted.
2 Footnotes and paragrap h s n Umbe
358 SHAREHOLDERS' LITIGATION CH. 7
s and Steel,
In his Pulitzer Prize-winning book Guns, Germ ,
the "Anna Karenina
geographer and biologist Jared Diamond popularized
ic novel. Tolstoy
Principle" based on the first line of Leo Tolstoy's class
characteristics that
suggested that happy families share a number of core
ond varies the idea
must all be present to ensure happy family life. Diam
of criteria, including
to explain that an animal species needs to meet a list
be susceptible to
diet, social behavior, and breeding habits, to
ber of domesticable
domestication by humans. The relatively small num
if even one criterion
species can thus be explained by the observation that
ous to employ for
on the list is not met, the species would be too oner
and Japan seem to
human purposes. Likewise, only the United States
to make derivative
"get it right" with respect to all necessary criteria
contrast, no single
litigation a successful model for shareholders. By
ative litigation in
factor suffices to account for the scarcity of deriv
y the available and
Continental Europe--or even a single country. I surve
criteria have to be
some additional explanations, and suggest that several
met to make derivative suits attractive.
[... ]
entators that
The European evidence is fragmentary, but comm
number of suits is
discuss individual countries uniformly confirm that the
by Armour et al.,
very low. In the United Kingdom, an investigation
twenty-six suits in
spanning 2004 through 2006, brought to light only
not aware of any
which directors were named as the defendants. I am
and Black report
systematic evidence for Continental Europe. Cheffins
bers before 1997 in
only two suits against German supervisory board mem
only two published
which damages were awarded at trial. Ulmer reports
of a submission by
German cases awarding damages on the basis
between 1965 and 1999. Pierre-Henri Conac, Luca
shareholders
published French,
Enriques, and I began to compile a database of
2007 where self-
German, and Italian cases decided between 2000 and
this can provide us
dealing by controlling shareholders is alleged. While
subset of derivative
only with a limited (and maybe not even the main)
found only two such
suits, it is still interesting to note that we have so far
GmbH, roughly the
suits in Germany (one of which related to a
[... ]
equivalent of an LLC), two in Italy, and one in France.
[... ]
ONS
THE ANNA KARENINA PRINCIPLE: EXPLANATI
FOR THE ABSENCE OF SUITS
litigation in
I focus on four issues to explain the scarcity of derivative
the Anna Karenina
spite of its availability in principle. In analogy to
four dimensions to
principle, countries need to "get it right" in at least
nsions are as follows:
allow shareholder suits to proliferate. The four dime
do not include a
there must . be favorable standing requirements that
_91.7 SHAREHOLDER '
- S LITIGATION 359
minimum ownership threshold (S .
allocated favorably to overcome e?tio~ 2.1) ; the litigation risk must be
(Section . 2.2); ~~tential plainti~tority shareholders ' ~ational apathy
informa_t10n to litigate (Section )· must have sufficient access to
make it possible for shareh 2ld3 ' and the enforcement model must
wrongdoers , which not only . 0 ers to derivatively sue potential
. 2.4) .
sharehol d ers (Section inc1udes dire ct ors, but a 1so contro 11·mg
Minimum Share Ownership Re ·
quirements
A number of Continental E · .
shareholders (or grou s of sh uropean Jurisdict~ons require that
h , h p areholders) hold a qualified percentage of
t ~ copmpanys s a~es_or a specified amount of capital to bring a derivative
smt. ercentage hmits can be rationali·zed ·
· b · . as a screening mech anism ·
agamst a usi~e lawsuits on the grounds that the incentive for a
shareholder with a small amount of shares to bring a legitimate suit is
very likely small . Given that any shareholder 's benefits from the results
of a successful suit consist only of a proportionate share in the rise of the
value of the corporation, it seems hard to imagine why a shareholder with
only a few shares would sue for a legitimate reason. For a small investor,
a suit would seem to be rational only when the investor can somehow
coerce management into an abusive settlement that constitutes an
effective bribe to make the investor go away , i.e., the litigation equivalent
of greenmail. Theory cannot explain what particular percentage should
provide the cutoff, which could be set at 1%, 5%, 10%, or any other
number with almost equal justification . A plaintiffs motives are
presumably legitimate when the benefits of the lawsu~t: m~ltipli~d by ~he
probability of its success, exceed the costs of htigat10n , . mcludmg
nonmonetary cost . Any percentage limit is, t? some extent, _arbitrary_and
can preclude some legitimate suits. T~e ~eqmreI?ent to retam a relatively
large number of shares while the smt is pendmg may act as a further
deterrent. ·
Grechenig and Sekyra suggest that percenta~e limits are to blame f~r
· ati've· suits in Contmental Europe. Their
t h e a b sence of d eriv . · · d ·d
. 1 d 1 tures a simple intmt10n: m or er to av01 a
mathematica mo e cap ly need to deal with those
lawsuit, potential defendant_ mbalnatghers hoonldIn order to ''bribe" these
b th apphca e res .
shareholders a ove e ld have to offer these shareholders an
large shareholders, manage~s wou f om managerial wrongdoing. Large
advantage that exceeds th eir 1os~es :nitor management, but become
shareholders, therefore, do nof m exploiting investors whose share is
accomplices of management in ac wns _
below the threshold. · h e reduced minimum
· and 1ta 1Y av
In recent years, Germa~;.
10 1 German enforcement mechanism
ownership thresholds. The tra 1 o/cna DM 2 000 000 until 1998, when it
required a qualified minori ty of 10 o or
. . ' '
CH. 7
360 SH AREHOLDERS' LITIGATION
where shareholders could
was lowered to 5% or € 500,000 for ca~es 1·olations of the law or the
. . d' t· d' honesty or serious v . only
establish facts m 1ca mg is· t' . . d d ·n 2005 requires .
smt mtro uce the1 German legislature
corporate charter. Th e eriva ive . r . t'1
d
1% or €100,000 . To _prev _ent_ ~bus 1,;:w~t~f: :mission procedure," or
1 f which plaintiffs must
introduced a special Judicial· g the course o
..{,h dur~n b . the suit. Shareholders have
Klagezulas-sungsver,a ren,
show that they demanded that directors rmg. vi·olations of the law or
. . d. t· dis · h Onesty or serious
d t ·ne whether litigation
to establish facts m ica mg d th court must b e£ ermi
the corporate charter, an e e allowing it to proceed
would be in the interest of_the company e or
beyond this stage .
· · · · t duced Italian law started
In 1998, when derivative suits were 1~ ro ' r used the 2003
out with a 5% threshold. Since the mechamsm was nev~ d ' t d d ·t
reform eliminated the six month ownership requireme1: an t~ en ~t ~
.,.. to unlisted stock corporations. In unlisted corporatwns , e sui is
restricted to shareholders owning at least 20%, unless the corpor.ate
charter provides an even higher threshold of up to 33}~· For pubhc~y
traded firms the threshold was reduced from 5% to 2.51/oin 2006, agam
because deri~ative suits failed to emerge in practice.
Whereas Belgian law also only requires 1% or a nominal_ capit~l
share of£ 1,250,000 for a derivative suit, the thresholds are higher 1n
Spain (5%) and Austria (10%). [... ]
The percentage limit theory cannot explain the cases of F~an~~ and
Switzerland, where-as in the United States and Japan-1nd1vidual
shareholders can enforce liability claims against directors without
, I holding a minimum stake. These laws also do not have the additional
. I procedural hurdles of German law, such as the demand requirement and
admission procedure . The German situation is not well explained by the
./ theory, since there is a special derivative mechanism available to every
j shareholder in the law of corporate groups, but the mechanism has also
l failed to produce litigation . [... ]
. -1
Costs and the Allocation of Litigation Risk
I
,
f
firm can receive a considerable award under the "substantial benefits"
SHAREHOLD , 361
CH.7 ERS LITIGATION
-
th
doctrine. Specialized · law firm h ~refore only need to find a suitable
lf
plaintiff and sometimes actua to sue
he ar ab ou t a po ssi ble ~a i: d a ~to:k P~rtfolio to be able
once the y
ee n law fi · ~h is sit ua t10 n may result in a "race
to the courthouse" be tw firm to
rol e of lea d irm s s~ nc e, tra ditionally, the first.
file is assigned the cotunthe sel m the case an d th us receives most
ce ab ou
of the fiee. H owever, sin t ye ar 20 _00,Delaware courts have
va rie ty of fa
begun to rely on a dto de term~ne lead counsel, including
pla int iff s sta k c ors
the size of the th e. quaht! of the pleadings filed.
ma rgi O: all y d' e .a~ h
While this may . SU its or mduce plaintiffs to take
are thi s £ I~ nis
cases out of Delaw 1 St rates that the incentive to sue
wi th the ~:w ;:~ ~U
rests almost entirely
The "Loser Pays" Principle
generally 1~ wh at In . is
European countries lis h R "· ap p the United States
urs e the
ng
often called the "E. . . u1e · the losmg party has to reimb
. . ce the outcome of a lawsm·t 1s · rare ly
for liti ga tio n co sts Sin
wmmn ·t rty
· g pa · f
su gg est ed tha
·
t the most 1·mport an t 1a i' ·
ct or det erring
certa 1s
. m,. 1 . . o ten
is tha t sh are ho lde rs wi ll no t be willing to take the risk of
deri_vativesuits s. Th e argument appears persuasive
for the de fen da nts fee
havmg to pay co mp lexity of the case, which is
Fe ~s of_ ten de pe nd on the
a~ fir~t _gl~nce. iss ues. Moreover, to the extent
that
lve s 1n tr1 ca te bu sin ess
high 1f It Invo co urt fees will also be very high in
on _ th' : am ou nt ~n dis pu te,
fees ~epe_nd lue at stake in such suits.
ve su it giv en the hig h va
a derivati
[... ]
the
er, Eu rop ea n rei mb urs em en t systems are often closer to
Moreov ing
Ru le in pra cti ce tha n in the ory. In several countries, includ
American is limited to court fees plus expe
nses
an d Ita ly, rei mb urs em en t
Germany ici al tariff promulgated by the
bar
rs, ac co rdi ng to the off
for lawye er is even more limited in Fran
ce;
. Re im bu rse me nt by the los
association ed, lawyers' fees normally are
not.
urt fee s are us ua lly rei mb urs
while co losing party only when retentio
n of
au tom ati ca lly bo rne by the
These are generally not the case in comm
ercial
ey is ma nd ato ry, wh ich is
an attorn grant
ere co rpo rat e ca ses are litigated. French judges can
courts, wh but, if
fee s to the wi nn ing pa rty under equitable considerations,
lawyers' er than
gra nte d in pra cti ce , the amount tends to be much low
fees are
.
what lawyers actually charged
ion s ha ve sp ec ial . rul es_ reg ar~ing litigation c~s.tsfor
Several jurisdict sli gh tly improve the position of
ve su its , all of wh ich
shareholder derivati iple.
int iff sh are ho lde rs co mp are d to the basic ''loser pays" princ
pla
No Contingency Fees
t could
sid es the "E ng lis h Ru le, " the oth~r classic di~ference tha
Be ce of
the rar ity of de riv ati ve suits_ 1n Europe 1s .the absen s are
explain ncy fee
nt· fi I tra st to the United States, contmge
co mgency ees. n con
362 SHAREHOLDERS' LITIGATION
CH.7
-
C
SHAREHOLDERS' A GREEMENTS
•••
INTRODUCTION
Shareholders' agreement
all) shareholders regulating :h a:e cof t~acts ~mong some (or sometimes
rights; in some cases the elr re _atwnsh 1ps or the exercise of their
agreement. The best way to c~~po;atlon itself is also a party to the
1
consider two of the most co us rate a shareholders' agreement is to
extensively below· lim 1·tat · mmtonhtypesof pacts that we will discuss more
voting agreements. wh'1 wns h o t e free tra ns £era b'l't
11 Yof t h es h ares; and
, c govern the way i h'1 h th h h ld
exercise their voting r 1g
· ht s. n w c e s are o ers
It is important to .under!'
. me th a t sh are h olders , agreements constitute
a s~parate ?0 ntract, ~1stmct from the corporate contract embodied in the
article~ of mcorporat10n and the bylaws, and a contract that generally
onl?7 bmds the specific shareholders that have executed it (while the
art1c_le_sand bylaws generally bind all shareholders). The substantive
provis10ns of a shareholders' agreement can often also be included in the
articles or byl~ws, r~prese~ting in this case a clause of the governing
documents. This opt10n might have some advantages: for instance in
France, in a simplified public limited liability company (societe 'par
actions simplifiee) transferring the shares in violation of a charter
provision would be invalid (Article L. 227-15 of the French commercial
code); on the contrary a bre_ach of a separate shareholders' agreement
would only lead to the payment of damages (the transfer would be valid).
Italian law is similar in this respect. There are, however , very good
reasons why shareholders might prefer, when they have an option, to
enter into a separate contract . For example, shareholders might want to
be bound only with some other shareholders, not with all, and/or they
might want to keep the agreement confidential: in some systems
shareholders' agreements, especially in ~ lis~ed corporation, must be
disclosed but often they can be kept confidential and unknown to other
shareholders especially in a closely held corporation. As we will see,
there might ~lso be other and more technical reasons why shareholders
prefer to include, for example, a pre-emptive r~ght in case of a sale of
shares in a separate contract, rather ~~an m the b~laws; reaso_ns
co · h the agreement can be modified, or the available remedies
ncermng ow · h h.b. · 1 d. ·
in case of breach. In addition, the law m1g t pro 1 1t me u 1ng certam
375
CH.8
SHAREHOLDERS' AGREEMENTS
376
. . th' se a separate agreement to is
r or bylaw s. m is ~a ·ght be tax reaso ns
provisions in the charte the shares
the only option. Finally, in some systems , t ere t:tnsferring donation or
becausde r exclu de lir
execute a shareholders' agreement,
among members of the agree men
t might reb uce . orrtant especially in a VE
inheritance taxes, something that might e impo s1
family-owned business. tock transfer agree ments a:
. . t· t f~ t·
In this chapter we will examme restric ive s lly agreemen s a iec mg s·
first, and voting agreements (and more gener~ d contrasting rules f'
~o~parmg/:m also discuss the
the governance ~f ~he ~orp~ration) ?-e~t, iction s. W . th
and practices ex1stmg m differ ent Jurisd e
, £ ·ng in particu 1ar on s of a
rs agre~ ~ent~ , ~cus~ he differ ent effect
legal effects of shareholde .
consequences in case of breach, d1stmgmshmg or m the bylaws.
clause included in a separ ate share holde rs' agree ment,
· th e u .S . and U ·K ., shareholde rs' agree ments are
As we w1·11 see, 1n of clo_sely held
generally discussed almost exclusively in the conte~t
m publicly held
corporations, and are not particularly common
ook or ma~ual, !he
corporations . If you look at a U.S. corporate law caseb
often be in the. part d~scuss11:g
chapter on shareholders' agreement will
s, howe ver-m ~articular m
closely held corporations. In other system
share holde rs agreemen~s
continental European systems, but not only-
corpo ration s . We will
are broadly used also in publicly held and listed
/ 1 explore possible reasons for this difference .
)I are extremely
, ••. I
One final point is that shareholders' agreements
used in international
'_/;11 common in corporate practice, and are often
ventu re in a foreign
-~
.$. I transactions, for example when establishing a joint
te a shareholders'
country. The ability to negotiate, understand, and litiga
cing nationally or
agreement is an important tool for any lawyer practi
internationally.
I
default rule, it is
To become a voting member of a partnership, as a
partners. This is only
generally necessary to have the consent of the other
sever al liability for the
natural, because partners normally have joint and
, and because the
1. '' . 1 obligation of the partnership (with some exceptions)
of partners in the
governing rules envision an active involvement
,j expression sometimes
management of the business enterprise. The Latin
cteristics of the
used to express the fact that the individual chara
is "intuitu personae"
contracting parties are essential in partnerships
:J (literally, ''because of the person"). On the other hand,
free transferability
indeed, as we noted in
of the shares is the general rule in corporations;
-
I .
I•
:I Chapter 3, free transferability of the shares is one
of the defining features
of corporations. Limited liability . and the governance
structure of the
;' i.
I
,,
f._H.8 SHAREHOLDERS' A .
. GREEMENTS 377
corporation make less rel evant for £ 11
other st a k eh O1ders who the sh are h older e ow share holders ' creditors and
T
s are. his, . at least, is how the
theory goes.
In practice, however th.
limited liability, especially' i ningsl are quite different. Notwithstanding
. t a c osely held corporation, it is obviously
very 1mpor ant for sharehold fellow
shareholders. Just imagine a si·t uatio ers_ to_ know and trust . their .
. 1vency, needs fresh fi n m which a corporation, 1n. order to
avoi'd mso .
inanc1al resour ces m . t erms of eqmty : to be
sure t h at your fellow sharehold g to provide new
funds can be essential. Similarler~~re ca~able and willin ns why you
~;h ere might be sever al reaso
are willing to be in busines trust to her
w_ithone person, from mutu al
skills and experience ' but n ostw1 others.
Restrictive stock transfer
or reduce the risk th t
. . . a
;1f eements represent one way to eliminate
e ow shareholders will transferd 1their
lcom ed new investors · Bu t th ey can b e use a so to
· ipatio
partic hn to unwe · · g the ex1st
· tamm · ·mg ''balance
achieve ot,, er connected goals , s uch as mam
holders against
of powe~ among sha _re~olde~s, protect minority share so on.
changes m the economic situation of the corporation , and
of the shares
T~e adv~ntages o~ lin:iitations to the free transferability
first of all, they might
are quite obv10us. Their risks should also be clear:
rs de la societe'
make some shareholders, as the French put it, ''prisonnie
table obstacles to
("prisoners of the corporation "), by creating insurmoun
r and inefficient.
the alienation of the shares, something that can be unfai
next paragraph)
On the other hand, especially when (as we will see in the
can entrench some
combined with a voting agreement, these pacts
them to control the
shareholders in a position of strength, allowing
contribute , in other
corporation even with a limited investment. They can
that causes agency
words, to separate ownership and control in a way
from the corporation.
costs and facilitate the extraction of private benefits
balance between
Statutes and courts must therefore find the right
results, especially
freedom of contract and the need to avoid undesirable
in order to protect small investors.
ments limiting the
· There are different types of shareholders' agree
of
free transferability of the shares . The following "families" capture _som~
of course keep m ~md
the most common ones that you might encounter;
labels we use are Just
that the following list is not carved in stone: ~he As always, to
. d som eti·mes different name s migh t be used..
conven t 10ns, an . .
1s more important than to
d t h e su b s t a nee Of the provis10ns
un d erstan
commit their names to heart. .
. f fl t f"-'r provisions: these clauses provide that at
1rs o 1.e h th' d t mus
Right o t' a transfer of s ares to a 1r par . y,Unde r
s' agreement
shareholder, before execu mg bers of th e s hareholder
o.£'.£'th e s h ares t o ie" How .mem . b . 11 shareholders who are parties to
uer
a right of first offer provision, asica y,
-
CH. 8
SHAREHOLDERS'AGREEMENTS
378 . b ) on the shares that another
l l op 10
t" n (rig ht to uy provisions can be genera 11y
ffer
the agreement hav e a ca f fi t
irs t t which the shares might be
O 0
shareholder intends to sell. Right ° consideration calculated on
divided into right of first option, pursu~n a d1"tions that the third party
acquired by the offeree-shareh older paying .
1 der the samel con ursu ant to whi ch the price at
un .
the basis of a formu a, _or
is willing to pay; and right of (irs~ :ef~sa
df n the contract. Keep in mind,
this terminology in a different
which the option can be exercise . I~t ixe
rces mdifig use ·ght of first offer as. simply an
however, that different soueop ri
le e ine abefore others, and a right of first
1 P t
way: for examp e, ~ome .th iYd ditions Again do not sweat
obligation to negotia te wi one pa:f . '
con
refusal as a call option under speci ie
these semantic distinctions.
colorful 1:ame refe~s. to
"Russian roulette" provisions: this
·d· th a t if sha reholder X finds a potential buyer wilhling
agreements provi mg shareholders sh~ m~s! pure ase
to buy the shares, upon request of other
that the bu~er i~ willing. to pay
their shares under the same conditions ers are dissatisfied with the h
h er. The i·dea is · that if fellow sharehold .
1
. ·
t e
the cor por atio ~ a iena ting
possible new shareholders, they can exit
e offered by a third party.
shares at the same (and possibly fair) pric
clauses provide that, before
Consent restraint provisions: these
alienating shareholder must
transferring shares to a third party, the
shareholders or corporate bodies,
secure the consent or approval of other
tract can be more or !e.ss narrow
typically the board of directors. The con
consent, and the decis10n can be
in terms of possible reasons to withhold
any duty to justify the denial of
entirely discretionary and not subject to
vision might cause a shareholder
the consent. Needless to say, a broad pro
n, for example if the board of
to become a prisoner of the corporatio
I
,I
,I
directors systematically and for no good
sell the shares. For this reason,
discretionary restraint provisions are
statutory protections are mandated (e.g
reasons denies its permission to
in several systems completely
disliked by courts, or . specific
., appraisal rights in case of
prohibition to sell).
'/ ers: in this case a provision
Limitations to certain possible buy
reholders to transfer the shares
might limit the freedom of existing sha
:Ii only to individuals that meet certain req
and ~xperience, for example only to inv
uirements in terms of education
estors holding a college degree in
managing a lab. The existence of
,I chemistry for a closely held corporation
to be evaluated by a body of the
the desi~ed requirement might have
directors, and in this case the
,
.J
·l
corporatio~, fo_r ~xample the board of
proVIs10n 1s s1mil~r to a consent rest
dependent · on h'
f
ques 10n, 1n t 1s respect, 1s whether lim mple what b t
people are lawful and enforceable · For
raint in which the consent is
certain more . or less objective requiremen
exa
,
ts O · t
. ne 1n eres 1ng
itations to certain categories of
a ou a prov1s10n
t·
· ·
11 ·
ng t
h
e tran sfer of sha res onl y to "Ca ucasian males younger than 45
a owi
' 379
SHAREHOLDER
S AGREEMENTS
_9!·8
hinese citi of Chinese descent"
or to
years old," or to "C et h z~ ~s an ~ pe op le
ican M O 1st going
members of the "Afr t Ep is ~o pa l Church"? We ar.e not
to answer this question bu you can d1scu 't m . c1ass. Hmts for the
' . ' . ss 1
. . Ar d 1minating 1uses ma P . a t e agreement, v0.1dper
discussion: e 1scr ca ' riv
? To th e extent that the g not discriminate, wou
ld
se. ov ;rn m en t co ul d.
inations such
prohibitions of discrim t. a so ap pl y to pr ivate organizations, ns?
ld a cour e similar provisio
as corporations? Wou m your country enforc
Absolute prohibth itions to t ~e r th e shares: as the na
me
e cl ra ns tion of
suggests, in this case c: ~: ~ w ou l~ si m pl y prohibit any aliena
for a lled '1ock-up
the shares, at least pe rw d Cth ese are also ca ' , to
etim m t·ion goes pu blic
rovisions" and som e us ed w he n a
. corpor a
P ' controlling hes ar h ld itted to the investmen
t
ensu re th at er s re m am co m m tle
) sCare o s have lit
for a period of tim e · ourts and corporate law system 'bil't t 11
un re as on ab le re st ra int t o th e poss1 I Y o se
e, however, for s
toleranc ar es .
th e sh
· ht assures
d ta g- al on g pr ov · ·1ons:a tag-a1ong rig
1s
g an ,
D. rag-alon
m aj or ity sh ar eh ol der) sells his shares
i!
th_at a party (gen
erally the
have th e rig ht to jo in th e sale and sell their stak
e
mmonty shareholders m e co nd iti on s. M or e precisely, since the
der the sa agreement, the major
ity
to. the third party_ un no t bo un d by th e
generally es
third-party buyer 1s th at th e bu ye r w ill also purchase the shar
assure party
seller has the duty to is th e op po si te : it is the obligation of a
ag-along the
of the minority. A dr ar eh ol de r) to se ll he r shares together with
(generally the minor
ity sh e same
or ity sh ar eh ol de r) to a buyer under th
maj ong right
seller (generally the ns se rv e di ff er ent purposes: a tag-al
prov is io becoming fellow
conditions. The two fr om th e ris k of
shareholders a presumably fair
protects non-selling t lik e, of fe rin g th em
ne they do no ve called a ''Russian
shareholders of someo r to w ha t w e ha
ehow simila e case of the Russian
way out. It is som ce be in g th at in th
the differen ird party must buy
the
roulette" provision, th e sh ar es to a th
seller of ong,
roulette clause the of th e ag re em en t; in the case of a tag-al
embers ince the third-party bu
yer
shares of the other m re em en t m us t co nv
the ag embers
the selling member of s sh ar es , al so th e ones of the other m
n to hi litate
to purchase, in additio lo ng pr ov is io n, on th e other hand, can faci
drag-a buyer is
of the agreement. A e co nt ro lli ng sh areholder), in case a
(o f th ud:s
the sale of the shares la rg e st ak e in th e corporat~ont~at i~cl
quiring a m this
only interested in ac es of th e ag re em ent. Keep m mmd,
e pa rti e in a co_rporat~on
the shares of all th a c~ nt r~ l~ in ~ st ak
purchaser of der to avoid haVIng
perspective, that the th e m m on t1 es m or
le to buy out
often wants to be ab
to deal with them. ned i~
e- m en tio ne d pr ov isions can be combi
ov
Of course all the ab is far from uncommon to1 have a shareh oldehrs
d I .
t th fi e i't . fi a , an a tag-a ong. t .e
d1·f~ re us
1.eren ways; · er1e dor both a nght of first 1s
re em en t t h at m e u es
ei 'th er bu y th e sh ar es that someone else
ag h · ht t o
· h
parties ave t e rig
I
380 SHAREHOLDERS'AGREEMENTS CH.8
considering selling, or have their shares bought from the third pa~ty
(from a financial point of view, it is like a collar, or call-put option
trigger ed by the intention to sell the shares).
The bottom line here is that contractual freedom, in this area, is
quite broad; and the fantasy of the parties can envision all so~ts of
different rules applicable in case of a transfer of shares. As mentioned
before a critical limitation to contractual freedom, often expressed in
mand~tory statutory provisions or judicial precedents, derives from the
need to avoid freezing the market for the shares and reducing
shareholders to prisoners of the corporation. The magic expression here is
"unreasonable restraint to the free transferability of the shares." In most
legal systems, therefore, absolute restrictions or restrictions that make it
almost impossible to disinvest from the corporation are unlawful or at
least unenforceable. For example, either based on general principles or on
specific statutory provisions, most courts would not uphold absolute
prohibitions to alienate the shares that are not limited to a reasonable
period (e.g., three years). As we will see, some statutes prescribe the
maximum duration of shareholders' agreements limiting the free
transferability of the shares (and also other shareholders' agreements), or
provide that they are not binding when certain events occur, for example
when a tender offer is launched.
One question that sometimes people unfamiliar with these provisions
ask is why a shareholder would accept these limitations to her freedom.
Of course when the provision is enforced, there might always be a
shareholder who would prefer not to encounter any limitation. The
reason, obviously, is that ex ante the agreement might have been
desirable or, at least, necessary to secure an investment. For example ,
imagine that shareholder A is interested in investing in XYZ Inc. with B,
a controlling shareholder, but is afraid that in the future B might decide
to sell the shares to someone else. It might make sense for A to accept to
(
1)
invest only if she and B enter into a tag-along provision, so that she is
sure that if B sells to a third party, A can also sell the shares at the same
conditions. At the same time, if for B it is important to have A as a
shareholder (he might need the funds that A is able to provide) , B might
accept to sign the agreement. It can happen, however, that after a couple
of years A decides to sell the shares, and the tag-along provision would
'
I apply to her sale too. She might not be happy about that, but still to
execute the agreement might have been the best option ex ante .
.
383
sdl. and two shareholders each owning 15% decide to buy, each of them will
be e ntitl ed to rec eive 5 shares. If only one of them exercises the option, he
will be allowed (but also will have) to buy all the 10 shares. This seems fair
because it might be difficult, for the seller, to find another buyer interested in
only 5 shares. The structure of the provision in this respect is, however,
negotiable also subject to the bargaining power of the parties . It is possible to
give more or less flexibility to the shareholders intending to exercise the
option with respect to the percentage of shares that they can/must buy. Try to
imagine situations in which deviations from this approach might be desirable
for one party, and explain them.
***
Hopefully the previous exercise contributed to make you understand
more clearly the possible content of a right of first refusal and other
similar limitations to the free transferability of the shares, including
strategic considerations about how to negotiate and draft them. The
exercise does not however entail, in itself, comparative considerations. We
j
The Executors of the Estate of Gilbert Mather took this appeal from a
•. i decree which entered judgment on the pleadings and ordered specific
'·.~
performance of a written stock option agreement. The Executors claim the
agreement was invalid as an unreasonable restraint on alienation,
because the optional purchase price was fixed at $1.00 per share, which
was only a small fraction of the stock's actual value.
In order to decide this question a review of the relevant facts 1s
necessary.
-
:. 8
c~~s::;-:~~=~S:H~AR~=~
~
.
intent of its drafter: object' .
. F
interpre t a t ion. or a conive inte
OLDERS'A
GREEMENTS
Fox; but if the shares have already been transferred to a third party, it
might be very difficult-indeed, often impossible-to claim the right to
own the shares. The third-party buyer is not part of the shareholders'
agreement, and the agreement is not enforceable against him.
We want to underline one important comparative distinction in this
respect. A stock transfer restriction can be included in a separate
shareholders' agreement, or can be included in the bylaws of the
corporation. In the first case, what we have mentioned above in terms of
unenforceability toward third parties is true in most legal systems; but if
the provision is included in the governing documents, in some systems
(especially in civil law systems, for example in France, Italy, Spain) it also
bears against third parties. The rationale is that the bylaws, in these
systems, are a public document, and a third party, before buying the
shares, can obtain a copy: therefore there is a sort of constructive
knowledge of the agreement by the third party. In this case, the third
party might be forced to relinquish ownership of the shares and our
friend Pinocchio might be able to claim them; alternatively the transfer in
violation of the bylaws provision might be considered void. A good
example is German law. The German Corporation Law offers two ways to
limit the transferability of the shares. First, the charter of the corporation
,/ can state that the transfer of the share requires the approval of the
corporation (Sec. 68 German Stock Corporation Act). In this case a
contract transferring the shares without the approval of the corporation
would be void. However, this limitation, called Vinkulierung (from Latin
vinculum, meaning "chain"), can only be used for registered shares
(Namensaktien). For bearer shares (lnhaberaktien) such a limitation can
only be established in a shareholder agreement on a contractual basis,
and in case of violation only damages would be available. A provision
limiting the transferability of bearer shares in the charter would be
considered void.
In the U.S., the inclusion of stock transfer limitations in the bylaws·
does not make them automatically binding on third parties. Limitations
to the free transferability of the shares might be binding on third parties
if they are noted conspicuously on the share certificates, but inclusion in
the bylaws (which are often not a public document) does not suffice by
itself, to bind third parties. . '
Base_don this additional piece of information, let's go back to our
hypothetical. Put yourself once again in the shoes of Pinocchio's
counselor, and imagine that you are in a civil law system that follows the
above-mentioned approach (for example, Italy). Your client tells you:
"Hey, Fox and Cat have told me that for them it's the same to include the
right of first refusal in a separate shareholders' agreement, or in the
bylaws. What do you suggest to do to make the provision as strong and
effective as possible?"
~ CH,8
AG
SHAREHOLDERS'
trty, it Think about it for a REEMENTS 393
ght to consider th e percentage of shares
>lders'
held by the _three shareho:ome)nt ers . (hint:
You might be tempted t 0
After dall, if this makes it b"in d~uggeS t including the 1 . h e bylaws
n this ing o th' cause mt
iarate the a ":a~tage that Pinocchio willnb ir~ parties, the bylaws option ha~
Lampw1c or any undesired new e a le to recover the shares from
f the that you cai:i th~nk about. Even if :hareholder. There is however a twist
ms of
we are considermg, there is a que?ti~n\~:: nothing about the jurisdiction
but if you should ask yourself.
The question is· wh t
:tems ' . a are the r u 1es to amend a separate
~ also
sh are h oId ers agreement and t
norm all Y can only be amended
' . h th e bY1aws? A separate contract
o amend
:hese
parties; the default rule to a ~it h th e unanimous agreement of all
~ the
majority vote. In our case remmeenbt e bylaws, on the other hand, is a
ctive - • m er that p· h'
shares, while Cat has 55% and Fox 25 o/c _mocc 10 onl! has 20% of the
;hird 0
It is true that, ma way, a stock
transfer restriction in the bylaw . "strong "£ h
our s 1s
reasons; however Pinocchio sh ld b er or t e above-mentioned
8r in · ' ou e aware th t , oth er t h mgs' b ·
equal, if the clause is part of th b 1 a emg
good Cat alone) could change the b 1e yaws, ~a~ and Fox (and possibly even
rs to Yaws and ehmmate or modify the rule in a
way t h at would
. allow
. them to sell the sh ares. Th e 1.d ea, h ere 1s . that to
tion · amen' d ments of
answer t h IS quest10n you must know the rul es governmg
the · 1ar contract
e a
contracts
· h generally (usually ' unanimity) • and of th a par t Icu
t
that IS t e bylaws of a corporation (usually, majority).
tion
1tin It is however possible to have the best of both worlds. If the other
Lres ~hareholders (or _en_oug~shareholders to reach a majority) agree, you can
can mcl~de the restnc_t10_n m the bylaws, but also provide for a supermajority
SIS,
requirement to ehmmate or amend the restriction. For example , in our
10n
case, if a supermajority of 85% is necessary to amend the right of first
refusal, Pinocchio will have a veto power to prevent any undesired
be
modification. Also, you should make sure that in the jurisdiction you are
operating a supermajority requirement like this one is lawful and
ws enforceable (in some systems very high supermajority requirements, or
·llS unanimity requirements in corporate bylaws, are not acceptable for fear
'.eS of a deadlock). But once you have established this, you might help your
in client. Be also aware that in some countries the corporate statute itself,
by for some business organizations, might attribute a veto power on
amendments of the governing documen_ts t_o ~inority sharehold~:s; For
example, in a French simplified pubhc hmited c_ompa1:1y(societe par
.ir
actions simplifiee), provisions like the one ~e are d1scussmg can 01:ly be
,'s
introduced in and removed from the governm_g documents by unammous
1e
vote (Article L. 227-19 of the French commercial code).
1:
, gesti·on in any case, would be-if possible-to
Le A smart Iawyer s sug , . . .
shareholders' agreement and a provision m
:e ac t ua Ily have bot h : a separa te t . t'
d the bylaws containing a stock transfer res ric wn. -
(
CH. 8
-
394 SHAREHOLDER S' AGREEMENTS
One final insight. Also if your only option is a sepa~at~ contract with
other shareholders, and you cannot include the restramt .m the bylaws,
there might be other techniques to make a breach less likely ..18We have
already mentioned the liquidated damages provision, ai:id that fo~ sure
useful. Something else you might consider is to req~nre the parties to
deposit the shares with a trusted independent third party, ~.g., an
attorney or a bank, who will undertake the obligation not to deliver ~he
shares to a third-party buyer unless it is established that the pre-emptive
right has been offered to and refused by other shareholders. In
jurisdictions in which it is possible to establish a trust, a trust can also be
used to achieve this goal.
***
VOTING AGREEMENTS
Voting agreements are another common type of contract among
shareholders. Shareholders participating in a voting agreement basically
agree to vote at the shareholders' meeting of the corporation in a certain
way and following certain rules. In this respect, we can distinguish three
basic types of voting agreements. Ranking them from the less intrusive on
the shareholders' franchise to the more intrusive, they are: consultation
agreements, unanimity agreements, and majority agreements.
Pursuant to the first type, the only obligation that shareholders
undertake is to get together and consult among themselves before any
occasion in which they have to vote, either at a convened meeting, or by
written consent. The purpose of this "weak" type of agreement is simply
, _I
to facilitate the adoption of a shared voting strategy, but no specific
,;, I;;
obligation concerning how to vote is envisioned.
In a unanimity agreement, shareholders are bound to vote in the
shar eholders' meeting according to the outcome of a "pre-vote," but only if
they all agreed on how to vote at the upcoming meeting. Consider for
example a closely held corporation with five shareholders. Three of them,
A, B, and C, holding respectively 30, 20 and 5% of the shares, execute a
unanimity voting agreement. Pursuant to the agreement, before the date
of a shareholders ' meeting called, for example , to approve a merger, the
parties will get together or otherwise communicate according to what has
been established in the agreement. If the three of them agree that they
should vote in favor of the merger, this "pre-meeting" decision becomes
binding, and A, B, and C will have to participate either in person or by
.-!: .. proxy to the meeting, and vote accordingly (in favor of the merger). If they
.r'
do not, they have breached the agreement and might be liable for
damages. On the .other hand , if even just one of them, for example C with
o?ly_a 5% s~a_ke,1s contrary to the merger, without unanimity there is no
bmdmg dec1s1on, and each shar eholder is free to vote as he or she sees fit
.fJI· S SH
:.;:;;c..------~~A~R~E!HHOLDERs' AG
With in the following meeting I REEMENTS 395
aw 8 , · h ·
has t h e rig t to veto a sh dn other words, each b
1ave goal is to foster the b"l· are and binding d -~em er of the agreement
sure a 1 1ty of a gro ecision. Also in this case the
strategy, and the . effects of th e agreem
up of shareholders
t to ~10 11ow a common
s to a mere consu lt ation agreeme t h en are stronger than. th f
an if all the contracting partie n ; owever, there is a bind· idn . ~ case ol
the s see the issu mg ec1s10non y
F" 11 · e eye-to-eye
tive 1na Y,fm a majority voting pact th d . . .
In memb ers o the agreeme t b ' e ec1s1onof the majority of the
shareholders: based on th n ecomes binding also on dissenting
> be e contract all 0 f th
t hemse 1ves to the will of th . ; . e members must align
· u ·
meetmg. smg again the exam e rnaJority
f m t·
vo mg at the shareholders'
agreement the three of the p1e ? A, B, and C, pursuant to a majority
shareholders' meeting that mu~ w~11 have to get together before the
favor of the merger, and B s dvoC e ~11:a merger_.If A, holding 30% is in
majority (of the participants ·a~h ' Jointly ownmg 25% oppose it, the
,ng therefore all three sharehold~~s e agreeme?-t) supports the merger, and
Hy have breached the agreement. muSt vote m favor. If they do not, they
nn
·ee · N~edleless to say,. majority voting agreements are often the most
on attractive
. for the parties
. ' but .also the most cont roversia
· 1. Th ey are a
on typ1~a-1 co_ntrol enhancmg device: in the previous example A, with a
part1c1pat10n,of only 30:° thanks to the agreement controls, in fact, 55% of
the_ votes. As control 1s not absolute, in the sense that B or C might
rs dec1d~ to_breach the agreement, but there might be legal strategies, such
1y as a hqmdated damages provision or others that we will consider below
>y to make breach unlikely, if not impossible. The consequence is a possibl;
ly alteration of the proportionality between economic interest and voting
LC power. For this reason, some authors have even suggested the
unlawfulness of voting agreements, but as interesting as this position
e
might be from a policy perspective, it has rarely gained significant
traction in most modern corporate law systems. Two Italian scholars, for
tf
example, have in the past considered with skepticism these agreements:
r
Tullio Ascarelli at least since the 1950s, and more recently Guido Rossi,
.,
possibly also in ' light of the widespread use (and one might say abuse) of
i
this device in their own national system. Statutes have however recently
expressly regulated shareholders' agreements, . providing for. rules
concerning their duration and dis~lo~ur_e,_as w~ ~111_ see be~o:w,with the
consequence that today, in most 1urisd1ct10ns, 1t 1s 1mp_oss1b:l~_to ar_gue
the unlawfulness of shareholders' agreeI?ents per se, while cr1tic1sms ma
reform perspective is naturally still possible. ·
· ht · gain wonder why a minority shareholder, for
You m1g once a d · · · ·t ·
exam le C in the previous example, woul ~om a maJon y votm~
p . . · is voting freedom. There might be several reasons.
agreement hm1tmg h h h ld s to establish a formal way to
£ ·1 .
am1 y ties sugges m~
f to some s are o er
. Alternatively C might have been
coordinate their votmg strategies. '
-
CROUCH, JUDGE.
[The facts], briefly stated, are as follows: The two corporate
defendants are New Jersey corporations manufacturing medicinal
preparations by secret formulae. The main office, factory, and assets of
both corporations are located in the state of New York. In 1921, and at all
times since, Clark owned 25 per cent and Dodge 75 per cent of the stock of
each corporation. Dodge took no active part in the business, although he
was a director, and through ownership of their qualifying shares,
controlled the other directors of both corporations. He was the president
of Bell & Co., Inc., and nominally general manager of Hollings-Smith
Company, Inc. The plaintiff, Clark, was a director and held the offices of
treasurer and general manager of Bell & ~o., Inc.,.and also had charge of
the major portion of the business of Holhngs-Sm1th Company, Inc. The
formulae and methods of manufacture of the medicinal preparations were
known to him alone. Under date of February 15, 1921, Dodge and Clark,
the sole owners of the stock of both corporations, entered into a written
______
~31!9§.8 1S~H~A~R!_!E~H~O~L~D~E~R~S['~A~G!!:R~E~E~M~E~N~T~S::-..-----..::C
. fter reciting the stock ownership of both
agreement under seal, which a k h Id continue in the efficient
parties, the desire of Dodge that ~lar sfoBu11& Co Inc. so long ash
of the business o e t t so ·'manage ' and cont e1
managemen t an d cont roI . O
should 'remain faithful, efficient and ~ompete~l k hould not be the 0 rf
the said business'; and his further desire t~:t h ar :-1s knowledge th/ ~
custodian of a specified formula, but s~ou s are0 f Dodge provided re?
and of the method of manufacture with a ~on_ ' . , in
t> 11 . Th t Dodge during his lifetime and, after his death,
su bs t ance, as 10 ows. a t h' t k and
a trustee to be appointed by his will, would so vo e is s oc_ so vote
as a director that the plaintiff (a) should continue to be a director of Bell
& Co., Inc.; and (b) should continue as its general managers~ long_as ~e
should be 'faithful, efficient and competent'; (c) s~ould _during his hfe
receive one-fourth of the net income of the corporat10ns ~ither by way of
salary or dividends; and (d) that no unreasonable ?r incommensurate
salaries should be paid to other officers or agents which would so ~educe
the net income as materially to affect Clark's profits. Clark on his part
agreed to disclose the specified formula to the son and to instruct him in
the details and methods of manufacture; and, further, at the end of his
life to bequeath his stock-if no issue survived him-to the wife and
children of Dodge.
It was further provided that the provisions in regard to the division
of net profits and the regulation of salaries should also apply to the
Hollings-Smith Company.
The complaint alleges due performance of the contract by Clark and
breach thereof by Dodge in that he has failed to use his stock control to
continue Clark as a director and as general manager, and has prevented
Clark from receiving his proportion of the income, while taking his own,
by causing the employment of incompetent persons at excessive salaries,
and otherwise.
The relief sought is reinstatement as director and general manager
and an accounting by Dodge and by the corporations for waste and for the
proportion of net income due plaintiff, with an injunction against further
violations.
The only question which need be discussed is whether the contract is
illegal as against public policy within the decision in McQuade v.
Stoneh~m, 263 ~-Y: 323, 189 N.E. 234, upon the authority of which the
complaint was d1sm1ssed by the Appellate Division.
'The business of a corporation shall be managed by its board of
directors.' General Corporation Law (Consol.Laws, c. 23) § 27. That is the
statutory norm. Are we committed by the McQuade Case to the doctrine
that there may be no variation, however slight or innocuous from that
norm, where salaries or policies or the retention of individu~ls in office
are concerned? There is ample authority supporting that doctrine. E. g.,
' '
8
0!_:~-:.
· ~==~~S~HA~R~EH~O~LD~E~R~st'l:A~G
REE~~~
MENTS
~-----_j!fil! 399
West v. Camden, 135 Us
507 • l0 S.Ct 838
Hooper, 76 NJ· ·E q. 592, .75. A. 5 L· , 34 L.Ed. 254 ; Jackson v.
"-I:Sal~mon ~ Co., [1897] A.C. 68,' 27 a .R.A
since 1t furnishes a simple if 22 b'44' nd . (N. S) 658. But cf. Salomon
a m1..rust ra t'1ve convenience ' th ar itrary te somethmg may be said for it
' t A t from
d
mor~ or 1ess ne bulous. Pub' lic e polreasons up s · h'par h . its practical,
ic . .
detnment to the corporation ar hy, th ~n w i_c 1t 1s said to rest are
little. Possible harm to bona' fid: p r~e e mtention of the Legislature,
s which in this connection mean
stock.holding minorities have m pur~
ase
in many instances If the ·en£ ore su st rs of stock or to creditors or to
ance; but such harms are absent
nobody-not even· in any orce~ent
of a particular contract damages
reason for holdin~ it illegaiercep ibh
le de~e:, the public--0ne sees no
broad provision of section ,2 eve[n t ] ough it impin r htl th
7· · · · Where the dire ~esctos ig
rs Y upo
are then sole
e
stockh old
h ers, t h ere £
seems to. be no obJecti. on t o en1~ orc·mg an agreement
among t em to vote or certam people
as officers.[ .. .]
Except for the broad dicta in the Mc
Quade opinion, we think there
can be no ~oubt that the agreement
here in question was legal and that
the complaint states a cause of action.
There was no attempt to sterilize
the board of directors, as in the Manso
n and McQuade Cases. The only
restrictions on Dodge were (a) that
as a stockholder he should vote for
Clark as a director-a perfectly legal contract ; (b) that as dire
should continue Clark as general ma ctor he
nager , so long as he proved faithful ,
efficient, and competent-an agreement which could harm nobody
that Clark should always receive as ; (c)
salary or dividends one-fourth of the
'net income.' For the purposes of this
motion, it is only just to construe
that phrase as meaning whatever
was left for distribution after the
directors had in good faith set aside
whatever they deemed wise; (d) that
no salaries to other officers should
be paid, unreasonable in amount or
incommensurate with services render
ed-a beneficial and not a harmful
agreement.
If there was any invasion of the pow_ersof
the direct~rate under. th at
agreement, it is so slight as to be neg
ligible; and certainly there 1s no
damage suffered by or threatened to
anybody.[.·.]
MR.Av.XYZ
Arbitral Tribunal, 2011 .
November 2011 '
. ·· B c· llone (President), G. Rossi,
Arbitrators: . ava G. De Nova
[... ]
Facts .
. t d on the stock exchange managed by
Borsa
XYZis a corporation 118 e
Italian s.p.a. since March 2007.
SHAREHOLDERS'AGREEMENTS C.!:!.:_!
412 . . ht h
. . . f the exercise of votmg rig s s all not
° ·r1 e owes a duty not to exercise its
It follows that an mJu~ctwn
be ordered as a rule, ev~n if e0
voting rights under Article
th
17
r:: f e
~;eement
ly when
in this case. Injunctive
(i) all shareholders are
relief may be gra~ted as an excep t)
i~n the Agreeme nt clearly requires
certain manner.
parties to the votmg agr~emehn~, an tingnrights in a
shareholders not to exercise t eir vo
NOTES AND QUESTIONS
. d b the restrictions of the availability of injunctive
entdi~~ema :sv~he court denied that Art. 17(1) of the Ccontract
. fl. Asbi:nt
re 1ie are o i er ic u ' t· . question
executed by the shareholders covered the transac wn m . . · ompare
the approach to contractual interpretation of the Nagoya Di~trict Court to the
th mk are the most
one followed in In re Estate of Mather: what do you
remarkable differences, if any?
. 4. Does the position ~f the Nagoya District Court offer any argument
with respect to the question of the validity of a vote in violation of
shareholders' agreement vis-a-vis the corporation?
·1
,,,
. t
1l
\
'
~ .9!=--8 SHAREHOLDERS'A
~
_____ _!!!
. · · --~~G~R~E~E~M~E~N~T~S 413
nsof control. Es e . .
11not 8 cqu1s1t10
3
problem. t·
p cially in listed corpora ions, this can be a
ise its
nctive Most legislatures ' ho wever rath
rs are · · sh are h o1ders' agree er than prohib"t"1 mg or narrowly
Iirn1.etmg d ment's (a ri ·d
iuires ion that might be difficult
to eniorce an contrast with contractuaf1 solut opted for allowing
these contr~cts, but regulatin freedom), have
shareholders agreements and f.
~~em mandating
g their maxi .
disclo
mum
sure of
durat i·on
Disclosure. andb duration provi·s1·ons imitm
are co .dered to achie .
nsi ve a desirable
1ctive compromise etween contractu 1 f
need to protect
1tract shareholders and third parties. a reedom and the
1pare
Disclosure. obligations are generally provid d £ 1·
o the
he ld corporat10ns, not for closel h ld e or 1sted or publicly
most
transparency of the ownership s~ et ones, for the obvious reason that
nd bution of power
is particularly important when t{uc ;:re a of the distri
investors can acquire them. At a e ~ ~res are. traded
7 the on the market and
1, as much stricter for listed than £or cmlose ini mum, disclosure requirements are 1
1y-held corporal" F
under Italian law, most stock transfe r ·t .
· ion~. or examp e,
1tter
in listed corporations are null and vr. 01~~~
.
:!wns and voti~g agreements
1 . ey are not disclosed to the
1 of Italian Securities and E xch ange Comm1ss1on (Cons0b) ·th· fi d
publi shed · · WI m days ays
ive after
· (or after .execu tion , . ma national newspaper withi n ten
f
the execution,
· Ifandh filed ·
with a public reo-is 4
i:. i in fift
ter w'th· i een d ays rom
·
mts
· h tion.
execu t bese disclo.sure obligations are not comp1·ie d w1'th , voting
the rig ts cann~t e _exercised, and if they are the resolution of the
ob (Article 122 of
ion shareho~ders meet~ng can be challenged also by Cons
In addition in
md the Italian Consolidated Law on Financial Markets).
md publicly · held corporations shareholders' agreements must also' be
of shareholders'
deposited with the corporation, and the existence
of any shareholders'
mt agreements must be disclosed at the beginning
In France, any clause
of meeting (Article 2341-ter of the Italian Civil Code).
terms and conditions
in a shareholders' agreement allowing preferential
h are admitted to
to be applied to the sale and purchase of shares whic
at least 0.5% of the
trading on a regulated market and that amount to
Financial Markets
capital or voting rights must be submitted to the
AMF). Failing such
Authority (Autorite des marches financiers, or
, and the parties are
submission the effects of that clause are suspended
d released from ' their undertakings while any public offer of sale is in
AMF. Note that only
e progress. These provisions are made public ~y the
to the AMF and the
tl the relevant provisions have to be commumcated
e public, not the entire shareholders' agreement.
rs' a~eements
rT
:, Again under Italian law , the duration. of shareholde
t d th e years in listed corporat10ns,l"dand dfive years m closely
cannot L F' · 1
excee re n ?o.ns o ate aw on mancia
)
held ones (Articles 123 of the Italia 1
). Agreements can be
r Markets and 234l-bis of the Italian C1~l. Code
.red for an add1t10na three or five years, but
l
r enewe d a fter t h ey h ave ex Pl
I
I
CH. 8
SHAREHOLDERS' AGREBIE?\TS
414
consequence is that most shar eholders ' agreements would remain binding
also in the case of a tender offer. Can you think of pos sible reasons why
Member States have decided to avoid the breakthrough rule?
***
A shareholders' agreement is, as we now know very well, a separate
contract, distinct from the charter and bylaws of the corporation. In
principle it can include a choice of law provision pursuant to which
parties can subject the agreement to the laws of a system different from
the one that governs the internal affairs of the corporation (at least if the
provision does not indirectly affect the structure of the corporation) .
Similarly, the parties can give jurisdiction over disputes arising out of the
shareholders' agreement to courts of a different country or to an
arbitration panel.
As for choice of law, in the absence of an explicit provision most
courts would apply the laws that govern the corporation. As you will
remember from Chapter 2, this means the laws of the state of
incorporation but, in some systems, it might mean the laws of the country
where the corporation has its "real seat." In the U.S., when a choice oflaw
clause has not been included, sometimes parties have tried to argue that
the shareholders' agreement was subject to the laws of the state where
the agreement was executed, or where it had to be performed, if different
from the state where the corporation was incorporated. Courts have
however generally declined to follow this approach, and applied the laws
applicable to the internal affairs of the corporation (for a brief discussion
of this principle, see again Ringling v. Ringling Bros. (29 Del.Ch. 318
(1946)).
Choice of forum or arbitration clauses are generally admissible, if
they do not undermine the public policies of the country in which the
decision will have to be enforced. The previous Mr. Av. XYZ arbitration is
a fitting example.
1
Available at http://ec.europa .eu/internal _market/company/docs/shareholders/stud /final
report_en.pdf. Y -
.0J· 8 SH
::,:;:c.~------2.!YAREHoLnERs' AG
--=:..:cR~E,.c.EMENTS
ling ---- _____
---..:::.::::_ ~4!]1~7
vhy Percentage of "I
argest" EU
sharehold • corporations with
35% r3111%% -- ..!.-.._______ ers agreements
3.te
In
ch
25%
30%
20%
==
====
--======= ==
==
>rn 15%
he 10%
1).
5% +--l~----
1.e 0%
0% t--"--.--- --,-- ~_J
Ln
;t
11
>f As mentioned, the data offer an . t .
y example no shareholders' agreem t m eI~st mg, but partial picture. For
V which they are used also in liste~n s are tted for Germany, a country in
t considered the largest 20-DAX corcorpo~a ion, beca~se the research only
as -Henkel Metro and Po h
' '
0
i;-
hrahtions,excluding corporations such
rsc e, w ic ave shareholders' agreements In
· Ecase, the data
any · reported clearly
. ·
indicate that sha reh olders , agreements
m uropea_n hst~d corporations are quite widespread, especially in civil
law countries with a more concentrated ownership structure (Belgium
France,_Italy, Spain), and less in the U.K., a common law system with~
more widespread ownership structure. In the U.S., as mentioned before
most manuals, casebooks, and treatises only discuss shareholder;,
agreements in the context of closely held corporations, or at least consider
~hem a typical feature of this type of organizations. Japan might again lie
m the middle. In this country, discussions regarding shareholders'
agreements center on closely held corporations, as in the U.S.; but voting
agreements in public corporations have been reported. In addition, as
noted in Chapter 1, cross-shareholdings are fairly common in Japan; for
example, a public corporation often has many shareholders, each holding
less than 5% of shares, who have business relationships with the
corporation. The corporation, in return, also holds the shares of these
shareholders. Although there is no formal shareholders' agreement
among these shareholders, it could ~e argued that they act. under ~n
implicit understanding to support the mcumbent management 1f a hostile
shareholder appears. ·
The limited diffusion of shareholders' agreemen~s as a control
· d · · th UK and in the U.S., as well as mother common
en hanc1ng ev1ce
· 1nfi e d · lso . ·
· by recent empirical · H . M asullo,
analysis.
1aw systems ' 1s con 1rme · A comparison
t · a Publicly Traded Companies: ·
Shareholder Agreemen in
I Cl
CH.8
--
418 SHAREHOLDERS'AGREEMENTS
Betwe en the U.S . and Brazil (2015), available on u:z.:;w.ssrn .~om, notes
that in the period between 2010 and 2012, 54 Brazilian publicly-traded
corporations had signed 64 shareholders agreements, and 6? U .S. ones
signed 69 ones. Considering that as of 2012 there were appr~ximately 353
listed corporations in Brazil and 4,102 in the U.S ., .it is clea.r how c
relatively uncommon these agreements are in t~e U.S. ~n comparison to
other (civil law) systems . This poses an mterestmg conundrum .
']
~
421
~
1 / . ·.,
~4~2~2
------~M!!E~R~G~E~R~S~AN~D~A~C~Q~U-!.!.I~SI~T~IO~N~S:::..------~~
I
Now imagine that Band its shareholder Z want to acquire the business of
A, meaning its assets and liabilities.
One possibility, obviously, is for Z to acquire the shares of A from X
and Y. In this case the transaction will result in Z being the sole
shareholder of the two corporations. Alternatively, the shares of A could
1 be purchased by B, with the consequence of creating a group of
corporations in which Z controls B, and B controls A. Another option
would be for A to transfer its assets and liabilities to B. The assets and
liabilities can be sold to B for cash, with the consequence that A will only
own cash and B the business that used to be managed through A (at
which point A might invest the proceeds of the sale in a new business, or
dissolve and distribute the sums received to X and Y) . A could, however,
also transfer its assets and liabilities to B with a spin-off and a
contribution in kind to B (see Chapter 3): in this case, B will issue new
shares to A. Note the similarities and differences with other scenarios:
here, once again, B will own the business of A, but A (and indirectly its
owners X and Y), becomes a new shareholder of B, together with Z.
Finally, in a merger, the assets and liabilities of A are transferred to B, A
is extinguished, and B issues shares directly to the former shareholders of
_9!J.-- MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS 423
Xlnc Y Inc
A(50%)
200 100 Capital
B (50%)
!
C (100%)
tanding
The shareh~lders of X are A and B, holding 50% of the outs
C. Imagine that the
shares each, while all the shares of Y are owned by
with and into
directorsand the shareholders of X and Y agree to merge y
operation of
X:the assets and liabilities of Y will be transferred to X by
d shares of X.
Jaw,Y will be extinguished, and C will receive newly issue
he owns in Y?
Howmany shares of X should C receive for each share that
In other words, what is the exchange ratio?
on. First ,
To answer this question, we need some additional informati
corporations.
weneed to know the number of outstanding shares of both
a par value or
Let's assume that X has 200 shares outstanding with
tanding, also
accountingvalue of $1 each, and that Y has 100 shares outs
ssed the concept
witha par or accounting value of $1. (We have not discu
rtant for our
of par or accounting value, which is not particularly impo
consider this as
purposesand that would require a long explanation. Just
ever different
a conventional value attributed to each share, which is how
shares.)
from,and generally lower of, the price or actual value of the
is the "fair
The other important information that we need to have
es of the two
value"of X and Y. From an accounting perspective, the valu
unting value of
corporations, simply determined by subtracting the acco
respectively 200
the liabilities from the accounting value of the assets, are
not represent the
forX and 100 for Y. The accounting values, however, do
, in fact, often
"fair" values of . these businesses. Accounting principles
accounting rules
underestimate the real value of a corporation, because
registered in the
are conservative. For example, several assets might be
price that the
financial statements at their historical cost, i.e., the
ion. Their actual
corporationpaid to acquire them, reduced with depreciat
r, for ~xample, a
value, however, might be significantly higher. Conside_
res 1n research
Patent: its historical cost might include only the expenditu
patent, plus some
and development occurred by a business to secure the
register it . A few
additional legal and administrative fees necessary to
426 MERGERSAND ACQUISITIONS CH.9
yea rs after the pat ent has been reg1·s tered h 0 wever its commercial value
might increase dra matically due to a new , '. d
technological eve1op~ent t?at
makes the patent extremely precio · It actual value at this pomt
might be ten tim es its historic al cosus. s . '
ts, but the financial st atements wil,l
still indicate the historical cost. In add
ition, the ?ialanc_e,~heet gen~rally
does not take into account the "goodw
ill" or the badwill of a busmess,
i.e., tha t part of its value derived from
its ability to gener3:te a flow of
earnings or a cash flow, or a loss, in the
future . If you take into ac~ount
these phenomena, it should be clear tha
t the actual value of a busm~ss
might be significantly higher-or,
more rarely, lower-than its
accounting value .
How can you therefore determine the "fai
r value" of X and Y? There
are several criteria that can be adopted
, depending also on the industry
and type of business, to determine the
value of a business . Some criteria
are simply based on the evaluation of
the single assets and liabilities,
independently from their accounting
value. Other criteria take into
account the goodwill (or badwill) by calc
ulating the value of the firm as
the value of any investment, by determ
ining the net present value of the
flow of future earnings or future cash flow
s that the business is expected
to generate. If the corporation is listed
and there is an active market for
the shares , market prices can (and sho
uld) also be considered. In most
cases financial experts must be hired to
find the appropriate formula and
determine the fair value, often a very com
plex calculation that inevitably
depends on several assumptions on which
reasonable minds can disagree .
It is therefore accurate to say that there
is not such a thing as a single
and precise "fair" value, but rather
a range of values that could be
considered acceptable. In addition, also
keep in mind that even if based
on the opinions of the experts, the parties
will negotiate. In our example,
C will try to convince X and its sha
reholders that the value of his
corporation, Y, is as high as possible; and
vice versa A and B will argue
that the value of X is as high as possible.
In any case, for our purposes, we can tak
e the fair values of X and Y
as ~ven. Let'~ imagine, therefore, tha
t after obtaining opinions from
quahfie~ a~d mdependent experts, and
negotiating the transaction , all
~he parties.mvolved agree that the fair
value of Xis $300 ($100 more than
its ac~ountmg v~lue), and that the fair
than its accountmg value) . value of Y is also $300 ($200 more
~ A(25%)
Delta 100 400
Capital \ B (2S%)
C (50%)
As you can see, the assets and liabilities of Y have been transferred
to X and, in X's balance sheet, the value of the assets and liabilities is the
sum of the value of the assets and liabilities of the two merged
corporations: assets = 1000 (assets of X) + 400 (assets of Y) = 1400;
liabilities = 800 (liabilities of X) + 300 (liabilities of Y) = 1100. The new
capital is $400, determined as the old capital of X ($200), plus the $200
that we have just determined as capital increase based on the exchange
ratio. The 200 newly issued shares have been given to C, the former
shareholder of Y, who now owns half of the outstanding shares of X.
Pause here for a second to consider this: does it make sense from a
substantive economic standpoint? Of course yes: if you look at the new
joint venture, you can argue that C ''brought" with him "something'' (the
business of Y) that was worth $300. Also what A and B brought together
to the common enterprise, corporation Y, was worth $300. It is therefore
correct and fair that the former shareholder of Y will control half of the
new business of X, and that the other half is divided among the old
shareholders of X.
But wait a minute. What is that "Delta" of $100 indicated in the
balance sheet of X after the merger, above? Simplifying complex
accounting rules, that number can be considered an expression of the
difference between the fair values of the two corporations and their
accounting values, a sort of goodwill that the merger allows and requires
to recognize and indicate in the financial statements.
This simplified explanation has hopefully made you more aware of
what a merger is and how it works. As simple as this is, if you keep in
mind these basic concepts it will be much easier to understand any
merger transaction that you will encounter (as an exercise, try to
calculate the exchange ratio and the capital increase of a merger of Y
with and into X in the previous example, assuming however that X has
issued 50 shares with an accounting value of $4 each, Y has issued 200
shares with an accounting value of $0.5 each, that the fair value of Xis
MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS 429
~that the
.
fair
.
value of Y 1s $150). The answers which you should
d · · d d · '
$600an t only after h aving trie to eterm1ne the values yourself ' are in the
100k a t
footnot.e . .
A merger 1s often a re~eipt for litigation. Shareholders might
lain that the exchange ratrn or the cash consideration received is not
t · db Y conflict of interest, and so forth.
. that the transac t·rnn was ainte
colllP
fair, · k ed by shareholders in case of
· r_emed'ies th a t can b e 1nvo
W}latare maJor
llegedlyunfair merger or, more generally ' frequently litigated issues
ana t?
inthe merger contex .
First of all, dis sen ting shareholders can challenge the transaction
}leginga breach of the fiduciary duties of the directors, or-to the extent
:hat it might be relevan~f other shareholders, or other substantive or
roceduralviolations. Based on these allegations, shareholders can seek
~onetarydamages, to set aside the merger (but in most jurisdictions, to
protectthird partie~ ~nd ~egal certainty, this is not possible after the
mergerdeed), or an 1nJunct10n to prevent the completion of the merger. In
civillaw countries, as we discussed previously, shareholders challenge the
validityof the shareholders' meeting resolution approving the merger, a
remedynot so often invoked in common law systems. Especially when the
corporationsinvolved are listed, shareholders can also sue for violations
of the securities laws, for example omissions or misstatements in the
proxysolicited for approving the merger. One of the more distinctive
remediesis, however, the appraisal right, which in different forms exists
in mostjurisdictions. To understand this remedy, we need to take a step
backin history.
Until the end of the XIX century or the beginning of the XX century,
in several legal systems, fundamental transactions such as mergers,
which have a profound and lasting impact on the structure of the
corporations involved, traditionally required unanimity of the
shareholders. Unanimity is, however, a problem: even a single small
shareholder can veto an efficient and otherwise desirable transaction.
Mostlegislatures therefore, in the last century, abandoned unanimity
fundamental transactions,
7equirements and provided that most
including mergers, could be approved with the majority of the votes
(sometimesa supermajority). In order to compensate minority dissenting
shareholders, the appraisal right was created. Dissenting shareholders
canask the court to "appraise" their shares, to determine their fair value,
and the corporation (or sometimes other shareholders) will have to
Purchasethe shares of the dissenting minority at the price determined by
the court or by an expert appointed in other ways.
3. Each ·
expert shall be entitled to obta· f
11 1 ·
h .
in rom t e merging
companies a re evant information and docu t d
out all necessary investigations." men s an to carry
It is interesting
1 · to1 point out that even i·n syste ms in
· wh.ich it· is
· not
mandatedby th e. egis atur~ (such as in several common law systems), the
Opinion of a qualified. and . independent expert on the £airness
· of a maJor
·
corporate , transact10n
d 1s, often.b obtained.
. . . . The reason h as t o do wi·th
directors. a~ managers possi le habihties: an independent opinion is
oftenan indispensable tool to reduce the risk of being accused of a breach
of the duty of care or of loyalty (once again, do you remember Smith v
VanGorkom on this specific issue?). ·
Challengi~g the shareholders' meeting resolution is possible but not
veryfrequent in common laws systems, where the most utilized remedies
are monetary damages or appraisal rights. You should be aware
however, of the fact that even in systems in which challenging the'
validity of the shareholders' meeting is more common, such as in
continental Europe, .the legislature generally only allows this before the
mergerdeed is filed with the public register or the secretary of state (this
generally means only within a few weeks after the shareholders' vote).
After that moment, only monetary damages are available. The rationale
is legal certainty and protection of third parties that might rely on the
validity of the merger, and also the high costs-and sometimes
impossibility--0f untangling a business combination. In these systems,
alsothe creditors of the corporation involved in the merger can enjoin the
transaction in the period preceding the publication of the merger deed, if
they can demonstrate that they will suffer a prejudice as a consequence of
the merger, but after that moment they are only entitled to damages.
Mergers and acquisitions tend to come in waves. This is partially
natural, as changing economic and legal conditions influence the
convenience of business combinations. For example, in a period of low
interest rates in which obtaining fresh financial resources to acquire
other corporations might be easier, M&As can peak; similarly if market
Price are down, and corporations are (perceived to be) underval':1ed,
acquisitions might become more common. Also legal developments mi~ht
hinder or foster mergers, for example more li?eral rules 01:1 defensive
measures or more rigorous enforcing of the. antitrust la~s m1g~t reduce
the numb er · of acqu1s1
· ·t·10ns, not to mention tax considerations. . The
_!4~32L_
_____ ]M~E~R~G~E~R~S~AN~D~
A~C~Q~U':.!:.l~Sl~T~IO~N
..:..:S:.,___~~~-C
. . nl referring to mergers involv
followmg graph en if O ! ing U.K,
corporations, co,nfiev
rms the exist ence 0 f "merger waves" (source: U.K.
Office for National Statistics, 20
14).
Numberof M&AsinvolvingUK
companies
2500 ------------
---------
- - -- -
2000 +----
..
ii
-:l 1500 ..-- - -
0
~
eti
:I
1000 -1- --------- - -- -- '- -----
z ,
0#~~~~~~~~~~~~~#~##
Year
~~#,~~~~
In this section we have conside
red mergers as one particular
business combination, and type of
compared them with other
transactions. We have then alternative
explained a typical merger
focusing in particular on the procedure,
different steps necessary to
transactions. Next we wanted complete the
to clarify the economics of a me
particular the determination rger, and in
of the exchange ratio, someth
have done with some basic acc ing that we
ounting and numbers, hopeful
traumatizing the readers. We ha ly without
ve finally mentioned possible
case of an alleged unfair merge rem
r, and made a reference to "merg edies in
The framework that we laid do er waves."
wn in this chapter is, more or
for most modern jurisdiction less, valid
s, even if of course there are
differences. We believe, howe important
ver, that this common backgro
helpful-in fact, essential-for und will be
the following comparative analy
sis.
SALES OF ALL OR SUBSTA
NTIVELY
ALL THE ASSETS
As we have mentioned, in the
United States as well as in ma
jurisdictions , several "extraord ny other
inary financial transactions
mergers, generally require the " including
approval of both the direct~rs
shareholders of the corporat and the
ions involved. The idea is
transactions are funda~e.ntal that these
amendments to the articles of
and/or have effects s1m1lar to incorporation
the winding up of a corporat
therefore cannot be approved ion and
without the consent of the sha
rehold~rs . A
AND ACQUISITIONS
¢!-- . . MERGERS 433
<1ermight significantly alter the risk/return of the investment of
:e::eholders, and th ey m~ st have a voice in these decisions. Selling some
;,rtheassets of a corporatwn, on the other hand, is generally considered a
iness decision th at falls ~ithin the competences of the board of
~tors- In the absence of a different provision in the charter or bylaws
(iireCtorsare. gene~a~lyfree to sell specific assets, and of course potentiall;
Jjablefor their dec1s1on.
This general rule, howev~r, ~as exceptions or, more precisely, raises
a particular proble?1. What if director~ sell all or substantively all the
ore materially modifying the purpose of the
assets of a . , theref .
corpodratwn
corporation an its econ_omic ~er_spectives? Is a shareholders' vote
ecessary?Are the protections existing for minority shareholders in case
:frnerger also available in this case?
We touched o? a rela~ed problem in Chapter 5, discussing corporate
governance and in . particular the relative powers of directors and
shareholders.You might remember (or go back and review) the German
caseHolzmiiller we discussed there. The question raised by that case was
whether directors, spinning off assets to a different controlled
corporation,infringed the shareholders' franchise because, after the spin-
off, directors would be able to manage the assets that had been
transferred without shareholders' supervision. We now examine a
partiallysimilar issue with respect to sales of assets and mergers.
The problem is particularly evident when the sale of assets has
economiceffects very similar to a merger. Consider the following example:
the directors of corporation X sell all the assets of X to Y, an independent
corporation,for cash. With the proceeds of the sale, X buys shares of Y
fromone of its shareholders. At this point, X is dissolved, creditors are
paid, and the shares of Y owned by X are distributed among X's
shareholders. As you can see, the practical consequences are almost
identicalto the ones of a merger of X with and into Y: X will disappear, its
assets will be transferred to Y, and the former shareholders of X will
a
becomeshareholders of Y. Formally, however, the transaction is not
merger.Should it be treated as a de facto merger for some purposes? For
example,should dissenting shareholders of X be entitled to exercise their
appraisal rights, if appraisal rights are not explicitly provided by the
applicable statute in case of sale of assets? From a broader perspective,
this is a typical problem that lawyers and judges encounter all the time:
s
shouldthe substance of the transaction (the fact that the economic effect
is
are similar to a merger) prevail over its form (the transaction
in
:echnically not a merger), and shareholders be treated and protected as
ase of merger?
Thefollowing case illustrates the Delaware approach to this probl em.
MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS 439
_0!J---
, te objective, this possibility of introducing shareholder control will
ora · £ and old ones are liquidated .. . . FSA
carP. . h as new compames are ormed h ' h .
·J111n1s . . 1 t .
d1ow FCA] hstmg r~ es con am ig ly detailed regulations specifying
[n tions that reqmre shareholder approval based on the percentage of
transacssets, pro r·
·
its, th e capi·t a 1 t h ey entail or the consideration paid ' and
lfl'OSS a . 1 d .
e;·-htransactions me u e maJor asset sal~s .... ".
S ue
***
In other legal ~ystems, the pro~lem raised by the sale of all assets is
roached from different perspectives. One interesting example, which
~ppalsoconnected to another comparative distinction that we have
15
LEVERAGED BUYOUTS
Do you reme~ber Sm~ v. Van Gorkom, the case on directors'
th duty
that we discussed in Chapter 6? If you do (and if you do not we
· ·) ·11
0f caret you review it, you wi remember that the underlying facts
suggesneda leveraged buyout, and in fact one· of the criticism of the
t · th t th ey d'd · the sale price of the
. · nr of the d'irec ors is a
cance i not maximize
ged
decisi~but rather accepted a price that would have made the levera
sharet' possible for the buyer.
buyou
ts
It is now time _to discus~ a little more extensively leveraged buyou
an
d their regulat10n. Basically, a leveraged buyout ("LBO") is
anuisitionin which the buyin g corporation obtains a loan or other credit
h f' · 1 the
. orderto have t e inancia resources necessary to obtain control of
acq
::rget. Often the acquiring. corporation is an empty shell incorp orated
ial
specificallyfor the transaction, and before the acquisition its financ
ed
statementswill only show the debt as liability and the proceeds obtain
the
fromthe creditors as assets. Once control of the target is acquired,
. The
targetis merged with and into the vehicle that the buyer is using
, but
resultis generally a corporation that looks very similar to the target
hasa much higher leverage (more debt).
to
Consider the following example. A, a listed corporation, wants
might
acquireB, another listed corporation. For a number of reasons, A
ple, A
decidethat it needs credit to complete the transaction: for exam
make
mightnot have the required financial resources , or a loan might
ly, A
sense to take · advantage of low interest rates. Consequent
lete
incorporatesa riew corporation , X, essentially a vehicle used to comp
try to
the acquisition. X generally has little capital. At this point A will
launch
convincea bank or other investors to lend it the money needed to
launch
a tender offer on B. If the loan is secured, with the proceeds X will
X.
a tender offer on B. Once control is acquired, B will be merged into
The transaction can be illustrated with the following example:
' I
442 MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS Cu.9
-
~
X \'IC
,.._ 1000
10
10 210 ~
Tnc
100 ..-
Vine
Delta 100
10 Capital
z Footnotes omitted.
\
I
•j
:1
.l
•
NS
MERGERS AND ACQUISITIO 445
9 ---
!:-
f.! ch focused on comparin g th e European and
the dearth
. 1es of resear
. . f ze-outs is startling.
reQ 'ln ' h t
A;erican approac es o minority ree
[... ]
of transactions that allow
There are numerous combin~tions equity interests f . .
trolling sharehholders to appropriate the . o mmoried ty
co n I U ·t dS the dif fer ent tec hni que s are dis till
shareholders.. n t e n~ e tates, out)
sales, reverse stock splits, (cash-
into four maJor categories: asset
e ~wo more common techniques are
mergers, and tender offers. [... ] Th t
erg ers and tender off ers . More . specifically, under Delaware la W, WO
b . ula r: the "long-form merge ' (or
r,,
Ill
shav e eco me 1nc rea s1n gly pop
opproache
eze -ou t") an d th e "ten der -offer/short-form merger" (or "t _
"one-step fre
rger, controlling sharehold::s
C,
I'
r~d
pt•l:lwrtl'tl partially r \solv '. sl'v \ml difC•rent iss ues, including share
•u:1::1,
t\ . ' I
~t:ll . . \ ttl(_'hl\lQlll ~-
h.1t\t10l
lYl'r held that
,w~ \' .inber.., under Dclnwnre lnw, as in oth er U.S.
\ .~ . freeze -out transactions conducted by controlling
f d 1· 'I'hus, f reeze-out transactions are
. t t ·rsns,amount to sel · ca mg.
. d1ct1o
ju.r~
:;h:l:''ho l l •cntire fairness" review. Th e decisio n explor ed the concept of
,ct to · · h · encompa si,,es both
iU bj."- ! . nr1ssin the merger context, a rguing t at 1t
1
en~ired~rn( and "fair price." The former is a procedural element ,
iair t:~l with the way in which the acquisition is negotiated; the latter
eonrtrnb·tantive element, taking into account the economic rational e
is a SUS
behindthe deal.
Th most relevant part of the decision for the current analysis,
. , er is dicta buried in a footnote, where the Suprem e Court of
howe~
Del are e' proscribed the means b y wh'1ch t e entire a1rness reqmr· ement
h · f ·
, ~; be met: the corporation considering a cash-out merger should
•ou ·nt 8 special committee of independent hdirectors, entrusted with the
appo1 . . ' 1
taskof negot1atmgthe merger at arms engt .
The court's laconic observation stirred a theoretical debate.
Supporters of outside directors' ability to ensure truly independent
decisionsin the best interest of all shareholders clashed with critics that
doubtedthe efficacy of a special committee with veto powers . At a more
practical level, however, many corporations soon followed the path
pointed out by Weinberger, and litigation erupted on the precise
consequencesof the committee's approval.
Twoanswers were possible, and the judges of the Delaware Chancery
Courtsplit. Byone approach, the committee's decision would be measured
by the "business judgment rule." In other words, the resolution of the
independent directors would be presumed to have been made on an
informedbasis, in good faith, and in the honest belief that the action was
in the best interest of the corporation. Alternatively, the special
committee'sdecision would simply shift the burden to the plaintiff to
provethe absence of entire fairness. This school of thought was more
fa~ou~able to plaintiffs because to prove that a transaction is not entirely
fair,either for lack of fair dealing or fair price, is less cumbersome than
overcomingthe highly deferential business judgment rule .
W . The Delaware Supreme Court addressed the issue left open in
L emberger in two pivotal cases: Rosenblatt v. Getty Oil and Kahn v.
e~ch. In both decisions, and under different circumstances, the court
P~ r~ced the view that if merging companies complied with specific
ace ural safeguards intended to protect minority shareholders, review
MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS CH. 9
448
would be limited to the entire fairness test, with th e bu rd en of proof
transferred from the defendant to the plaintiff.
Getty Oil settled the question concerning the effect of a majority ?f
the minority shareholders' approval of a merger. In the 196 0s, Gett~ ~11,
an oil behemoth created by Jean Paul Getty, became ~ m~Jor1ty
stockholder of Skelly, another big player in the in~u~try, owning direc~ly
7.42% of the outstanding voting shares, and 1nd1rectly, through its
controlled subsidiary Mission, an additional 72.6%. Jea~ Paul _Ge:ty
opposed any further integration between the two companies'. behevn~g
that a certain degree of competition between them was beneficial to their
own strength and profitable for the shareholders. Soon after his death,
however, Getty Oil's executive vice-president, Ha:o~d E. Berg, ~ontacted
Skelly President James H. Hara to discuss comb1n1ng Getty 011, Skelly,
and Mission.
The directors of Skelly and Getty Oil engaged in an extensive hard-
bargaining process to determine the proper exchange ratio for
outstanding stock. Skelly's representatives were very determined to
obtain the best possible conditions for their shareholders, focusing
extensively on the application of the Delaware Block Method. Eventually,
the boards agreed on an exchange ratio of 0.5875 Getty Oil shares for
every Skelly share. With the boards' unanimous approval, the deal was
submitted to the shareholders of the corporations involved and
conditioned on the approval of the majority of the minority stockholders.
Almost 90% of the minority shares present at the meeting, representing
58% of all the outstanding minority shares, voted in favour of integration,
which was subsequently completed. The merger was, however, challenged
by disgruntled Skelly shareholders, who brought a class action suit
claiming the exchange ratio was unfair. After a lengthy and complicated
trial, the Chancery Court found the deal entirely fair and entered
judgment for the defendants. On appeal, the Delaware Supreme Court
affirmed.
Applying Weinberger, the Delaware Supreme Court evaluated issues
of both fair dealing and fair price. Its decision offers an insightful
discussion of the Delaware Block Method and proper disclosure of all
material facts in a proxy statement. For current purposes, however it
resolved what significance should be attributed to the mino;ity
shareholders' vote:
Clearly, Getty, as majority shareholder of Skelly, stood on both sides
of_this transaction and bore the initial burden of establishing its entire
fairness. However, approval of a merger, as here, by an informed vote of a
m~jority of the minorit~ shareholde~s, while not a legal prerequisite,
shifts the burden of proving the unfairness of the merger entirely to the
plaintiffs. ·
I
TAKEOVERSAND TENDEROFFERS
HOSTILEACQUISITIONS,AND '
DEFENSIVEMEASURES
•••
:
TAKEOVERSTHE ECONOMIC
AND LEGALBASICIDEAS
Takeovers, and the dramatic battles for corporate control that the
entail, are one o~ the few corporate law topics entertaining enough t~
makeit into movies. Hollywood blockbusters depicting takeovers include
WallStreet (1987), Other People's Money (1990), and Pretty Woman
(1990),portraying more-or-less unforgettable corporate raiders such as
GordonGekko ~ich~el Douglas), Larry The Liquidator (Danny DeVito),
andEdward Lewis (Richard Gere). OK, maybe they are not all considered
masterpiecesby movie buffs, but if you haven't yet, we suggest you watch
themas part of your cultural background on takeovers.
When a corporation is listed (and in this chapter we only focus on
listedcorporations), someone interested in obtaining control must, first of
all, decide if a friendly acquisition is possible, or if it is possible-and
necessary-a hostile acquisition. By "friendly'' acquisition we refer to a
transaction in which control is transferred with the consent of the
existing controlling shareholder and/or management of the target
corporation;by contrast, and obviously enough, a ''hostile" acquisition
occurswhen the existing controlling shareholder and/or management of
the corporation opposes the takeover: in this situation the incumbents
andthe buyer engage in a legal and financial duel. This distinction is not
always as clear-cut as it might appear. For example, a "friendly''
acquisitionmight be conducted under the more-or-less overt threat that a
hostile one could be successfully launched . In addition, in a "friendly''
acquisitionother stakeholders, different from major shareholders and top
m~nagement, might oppose the plans of the acquirer: employees and
unions,creditors sometimes even the government. Generally, however,
we distinguish between hostile and friendly acquisitions based on
whetherthe incumbent is willing to transfer control or not.
· ·t 0 f the
If a controlling shareholder owning an absolute maJor~Y
shares exist, it is generally very difficult to obtain control without her
469
TAKEOVERS AND TENDER OFFERS, HOSTILE
470 ACQUISITIONS, AND DEFENSIVE MEASURES CH.10
defenses that share certain features but also present some d1stmc . . .
essence the " ill" . tions. In
'nts of Pthe 1s a set .of rues ·
1 generally mclude · ·
docume d m the governing
characterized b th corporatwn and adopted by the board of director~,
(from the . ( f r~e elements: (a) a triggering event; (b) a catastrophic
possibil"t 1 p;in b O view of the hostile bidder) consequence; and (c) the
. . Y O
e . redeemed at nominal costs by the directo rs. The
t riggermg event 1s often represente d by the acqms1 ·
· · tion f ·
th h Id Of h o a certam
. ;es fo s ares by a shareholder, for example 20%, signaling a likely
in en wn to acquire control (disclosure is mandated by the securities
· · g event occurs, shareholders can exercise some
laws)
k" d · fOnce . th e t riggerm
°
~n right that makes the acquisition much more difficult for the
bidd:r. For. ~xample, in a "flip-in" pill shareholders of the target can
~cqu~r~ addit~?n~ shares from the corporation at discounted price; while
in a flip-over pill shareholders of the target can have the right to obtain
shares of the bidder if, after the acquisition, it wants to merge with the
target. The bottom line is that the pill is calibrated to grant to existing
shareholders advantages that frustrates the goals of the bidder.
The pill-which, as we have seen, is basically a right granted to
shareholders-----can however be redeemed by the directors at a very low
price, for example they can "cancel" the rights for one cent per share. If
you consider the effects of these three elements, the result is that an
acquirer can only hope to obtain control with the agreement of the
existing board, which must redeem the pill (interestingly enough, bylaws
provisions only allow continuing directors to redeem the pill, in order to
avoid that new directors appointed through a proxy fight could get rid of
this defense, even if the permissibility of these "dead-hand" pills 1s
excluded in several jurisdictions, including Delaware).
As you can clearly see, defensive measures comprise a gamut of
different and heterogeneous techniques, ranging from purchase of own
shares to seeking a white knight. Some of them can be adopted after a
hostile takeover has been launched; others work better if introduced
before any declaration of war. From a legal point of view, in different
legal systems, these measures might be within the competence of the
shareholders' meeting or of the directors, and they basically have only one
thing in common: they are designed to frustrate a hostile offer.
'
'
. . . that
example of the tender offer for $4.5 on t h e sh ar es of a corporation £
floats at around $3. The offer might be val':1e-maxii:i~:~g for
shareholders who might be happy to accept it; the bidder mig d in act
have a chan~e to manage the corporation more effectively, :3-n see the
market price go up to $7, but only after having re~oved the incompetent
existing directors . Everyone would be happier with the offer (Pareto-
efficiency), but the directors . They have the power to bloc~ the offer, f~r
example selling the jewels of the crown. By doing so they might succeed in
discouraging the bidder, and keep their job for a few more years, bu~ they
would also have impoverished the corporation. It would be_ as if the
defenders of a citadel under siege, in order to repel the barbarians at the
gates, would set fire to the riches of their community .
If this is the case, why don't corporate law systems si~ply prohibit
directors from adopting defensive measures? The answer is that there
are, in fact, situations in which defensive measures are desirable from the
point of view of shareholders and other stakeholders, and the proposed
tender offer is not value maximizing . Consider again our previous
example. You might imagine a situation in which the market price of the
shares is unreasonably low, for example it is depressed in a period of
extraordinary high interest rates that cause lots of investors to sell equity
and buy bonds. Under these circumstances , the directors of the target
might genuinely and correctly believe that the actual value of the shares
is at least $6, not $3 (the current market price), but not even $4.5 (the
price offered by the bidder). They might believe that if the shareholders
hold on to their shares, wait a few months and let them carry on their
strategy, the market will adjust and prices will go up. Shareholders,
obviously , would not be better off tendering the shares now for $4.5; if the
offer is successful they might not have the opportunity to enjoy the full
possible capital gain. In addition , the bidder might be using techniques
designed to . create a pressure to tender, to the extent that the legal
system allows them, such as giving a very short timeframe to accept the
offer. In this scenario, you might argue that it is not only legitimate and
in the best interest of shareholders that existing directors adopt defensive
measures, but that directors have a duty to protect the corporate bastion.
Using again a military metaphor, when the attackers threaten to sack the
city, the captain of the guards must throw some arrows and boiling oil at
them. If nothing else, a defensive measure might force the bidder to
improve the terms of the offer.
As you can see, the regulation of defensive measures must strike a
complex balance between two opposing goals: preventing the incumbents
from adopting frustrating measures not in the best interest of the
corporation and the shareholders, but at the same time do not tie their
hands so tightly that they cannot adopt defenses necessary to react to
inadequate, damaging and coercive offers.
TAKEOVER S AND T
cu.10 A C· UISITIONS
. ENDER OFFER S HOSTILE
AN D '
D EFEN SIVE MEASURES 477
Legal system s around th
equilibrium but once . he world struggle to find the optimal
divide . Some' countries (inagam . ere w fi d ·
e m an mterestmg · ·
comparative
UK approach ad 0 f 1
c udm~ all the E.U. Member States) follow the
The· idea her~ · fh i~g some kmd of "passivity'' or "no-frustration" rule.
' t·l t' iks a to address the conflict of interest of directors in
f h os
case o i e a eover the b t t· · · · concerrun
· g
deJ.enses away from them es op ion is to take any decision
r
h d 1 t h · ·
, an e s areholders decide since they are the
ones. ~ at can be primarily benefitted or harmed by the offer. The
1
1
passivity rul~, ther .efore, simply says that when an offer is pending the
shareh~lders meeting, and not the directors , must approve any action
that might frustrate the goals of the bidder. We will discuss how and
under whic.h conditio.ns this simple and ingenious solution can work well,
and when it can be ineffective, or even counterproductive. On the other
end of the spectrum, in the U.S., the way in which this problem is
addresse.d is primarily through directors' fiduciary duties. In the takeover
context, 1n other words, a modified duty of care and duty of loyalty dictate
what directors can and cannot do in terms of defensive measures. This
difference is interesting because it shows, once again, a defining feature
of American corporate law, its reliance on litigation and ex post measures
to regulate corporate governance. One note of caution is however
important : focusing on Delaware case law and taking an historical
perspective, it is fair to say that the standards adopted starting in the
1980s to regulate takeovers have been partially relaxed more recently,
according to some commentators as a reaction to the development of other
monitoring mechanisms such as a more significant role of institutional
investors, and the corporate governance movement that has introduced
stricter rules on the composition and incentives of the board of directors
(see S. Davidoff Solomon, R . S. Thomas, The Rise and Fall of Delaware's
Takeover Sandards, ECG! Law Research Paper No. 329/2016, Vanderbilt
Law and Economics Research Paper, 16-24, available on www.ssrn.com) .
., .
To sum up this unusually long but necessary introduction, looking at
different strategies to regulate takeovers you can come up with a matrix
in which you can have fun trying to fit different systems:
'l
,
'
boardneutralityrule
yes no
Cl
UnitedStates
s;:
·C'-
'13
,Cl
~
~ EuropeanUnion
~
E Japan
""
~
(but oftenboard
neutral\tyis optional)
MOORE, JUSTICE.
used in reaching the conclusion that Mesa ,s tender offer price was
inadequate. .
d £
Mr. Sachs also presented various e ensi d·ve strateg ies availa ble to the
ffer was inadequate
board if it concluded that Mesa's two-~tep te~i::d was a self-tender by
O
MOORE, JUSTICE:
In this battle for corporate control of Revlon, Inc. (Revlon), the Court
of Chancery enjoined certain transactions designed to thwart the efforts
of Pantry Pride, Inc. (Pantry Pride) to acquire Revlon. The defendants are
Revlon its board of directors and Forstmann Little & Co. and the latter's
affiliat~d limited partnership (collectively, Forstmann). The injunction
barred consummation of an option granted Forstmann to purchase
certain Revlon assets (the lock-up option), a promise by Revlon to deal
exclusively with Forstmann in the face of a takeover (the no-shop
provision), and the payment of a $25 million cancellation fee to
Forstmann if the transaction was aborted. The Court of Chancery found
that the Revlon directors had breached their duty of care by entering into
the foregoing transactions and effectively ending an active auction for the
company. The trial court ruled that such arrangements are not illegal per
se under Delaware law, but that their use under the circumstances here
was impermissible. We agree. See MacAndrews & Forbes Holdings, Inc. v.
Revlon, Inc., Del.Ch., 501 A.2d 1239 (1985). Thus, we granted this
expedited interlocutory appeal to consider for the first time the validity of
such defensive measures in the face of an active bidding contest for
corporate control. Additionally, we address for the first time the extent to
which a corporation may consider the impact of a takeover threat on
constituencies other than shareholders. See Unocal Corp. v. Mesa
Petroleum Co., Del.Supr., 493 A.2d 946, 955 (1985).
In our view, lock-ups and related agreements are permitted under
Delaware law where their adoption is untainted by director interest or
other breaches of fiduciary duty. The actions taken by the Revlon
directors, however, did not meet this standard. Moreover, while concern
for various corporate constituencies is proper when addressing a takeover
threat, that principle is limited by the requirement that there be some
rationally related benefit accruing to the stockholders. We find no such
benefit here.
Thus, under all the circumstances we must agree with the Court of
Chancery that the enjoined Revlon defensive measures were inconsistent
with the directors' duties to the stockholders. Accordingly, we affirm.
TAKEOVERSANDTENDE O .. ,
ACQUISITIONS ~ . Fl-ER8, HOSTILE
ca.10
- 'AND DEF E!'.SJVE MEA'-;URP.S
I.
499
II.
To obtain a preli~inary injunction, a plaintiff must demonstrate both
a reason~ble ~robabihty of success on the merits and some irreparable
harm which will occur absent the injunction. [... ]
We turn first to Pantry Pride's probability of success on the merits
[... ] . .
[W]hen Pantry Pride increased its offer to $50 per share and then to
~53,_it became apparent to all that the break-up of the c~mpany was
1nevit_able. The Revlon board's authorization permitting management to
negotiate a merger or buyout with a third party was a recognition that
the company was for sale. The duty of the board had thus changed from
the preservation of Revlon as a corporate entity to the maximization of
the company's value at a sale for the stockholders' benefit. This
significantly altered the board's responsibilities under the Unocal
standards. It no longer faced threats to corporate policy and effectiveness,
or to the stockholders' interests, from a grossly inadequate bid. The whole
question of defensive measures became moot. The directors' role changed
from defenders of the corporate bastion to auctioneers charged with
getting the best price for the stockholders at a sale of the company.
III.
This brings us to the lock-up with Forstmann [... ]
A lock-up is not per se illegal under Delaware law [... ]. Such options
can entice other bidders to enter a contest for control of the corporation,
creating an auction for the company and maximizing shareholder profit.
Current economic conditions in the takeover market are such that a
"white knight" like Forstmann might only enter . the bidding for t~e target
company if it receives some form of compensation to cover the risks and
costs involved. [... ]
Forstmann had already been drawn into the contest on a preferred
basis, so the result of the lock-up was not t? foster bidding, ~ut to destroy
it. The board's stated reasons for approving the transactions were: (1)
TAKEOVERS AND TENDER OFFERS, HOSTILE
502 ACQUISITIONS, AND DEFENSIVE MEASURES CH. 10
bette r fina ncing (2) not eholder protection, and (3) higher price. As the
Court of Chanc~ry found, and we agree, any distinctio~s between the
rival bidd ers' methods of financing the proposal were nominal at best, and
such a consideration has little or no significance in a cash offer for any
and all shares. The principal object, contrary to the board's duty of care,
appears to have been protection of the noteholders over the shareholders'
interests.
While Forstmann's $57.25 offer was objectively higher than Pantry
Pride's $56.25 bid, the margin of superiority is less when the Forstmann
price is adjusted for the time value of money. In reality, the Revlon board
ended the auction in return for very little actual improvement in the final
bid. The principal benefit went to the directors, who avoided personal
liability to a class of creditors to whom the board owed no further duty
under the circumstances. Thus, when a board ends an intense bidding
contest on an insubstantial basis, and where a significant by-product of
that action is to protect the directors against a perceived threat of
personal liability for consequences stemming from the adoption of
previous defensive measures , the action cannot withstand the enhanced
scrutiny which Unocal requires of director conduct. [... ]
In addition to the lock-up option, the Court of Chancery enjoined the
no-shop provision as part of the attempt to foreclose further bidding by
Pantry Pride. [... ] The no-shop provision, like the lock-up option, while
n_ot per se illegal, is impermissible under the Unocal standards when a
board's primary duty becomes that of an auctioneer responsible for selling
the company to the highest bidder. The agreement to negotiate only with
Forstmann ended rather than intensified the board's involvement in the
bidding contest.
[... ]
The court below similarly enjoined the payment of the cancellation
fee, pending a resolution of the merits, because the fee was part of the
overall plan to thwart Pantry Pride's efforts. We find no abuse of
discretion in that ruling.
IV.
Having concluded that Pantry Pride has shown a reasonable
probability of success on the merits, we address the issue of irreparable
harm. The Court of Chancery ruled that unless the lock-up and other
aspects of the agreement were enjoined, Pantry Pride's opportunity to bid
for Revlon was lost . The court also held that the need for both bidders to
compete in t~e marketplace outweighed any injury to Forstmann. Given
the complexity of the proposed transaction between Revlon and
Forstmann, ~he obstacles to Pant!y Pride obtaining a meaningful legal
remedy are immense. We are satisfied that the plaintiff has shown the
TAKEOVERS AND TE i ,,
***
Japan started regulating defensive measures quite late. In 2004,
some takeover battles attracted the attention of regulators and in 2005
~~e Min~stry of Econ~my?Tr_adeand Industry and the Mini~try of Justice
Jointly issued the Guidelines Regarding Takeover Defense for the
Purposes of Protection and Enhancement of Corporate Value and
Shareholders' Common Interests (May 27, 2005)", also called "METI-MOJ
Guidelines." The Guid~lines, _w~ichdo ~ot have any formal binging force,
are based on the following principles. First, the adoption, implementation,
TAKEOVERS AND TENDER OFFERS, HOSTILE
CH.10
ACQUISITIONS, AND DEFENSIVE MEASURES
509
Guidelines look for additional d · · · ·
' group.
in your study sources, an
. discuss this question m class or
***
You hopefu~ly now have a good understanding of the basic differences
among alter~ative approaches to takeovers, and more precisely of the
rules governing mandatory tender offers and defensive measures in the
U.S., the European Union, and Japan. It's time for two even more
fascinating questions. Keeping in mind that what we have called the
"European" approach has been largely inspired by U.K. law, a first
question is why the U.S. and the U.K., two legal systems that share
several features (common law tradition, existence of a fairly large number
of listed corporations with a widespread ownership structure, advanced
and competitive financial markets) have developed so radically diverse
rules? And, secondly, what are the effects of having extended the U.K.
approach to continental European systems, with a much more
concentrated ownership structure? The first question is tackled in an
interesting article by John Armour and David Skeel (Who Writes the
Rules for Hostile Takeovers, and Why?-The Peculiar Divergence of U.S.
and U.K. Takeover Regulation, 95 GEO. L. J. 1727 (2007)), and the second
in another article by Marco Ventoruzzo. Since the latter also refers to the
former, consider the following excerpt.
- [... ]
In [an] insightful work, John Armour and D~vid Skeel address ~he
wh takeovers in the U.K. and in the United States of ~merica
reasons re y re ulated so differently. More specifically, their ~?rk
(U.S.) a ; h · torical events and the economic, legal, and political
d~monstrates. ow 11sthe role of lobbying groups-in the U.S. and the
.chmate-pafr;1culdarbyth the content of substantive takeover rules, and the
U K have a 1ecte O · d £ d
. .
processes throug h wh.ich they are created an en orce . . .
- . .t. of a set threshold of the voting shares
[I]n the U.K., ~cqu1sh1iobn er to launch a mandatory tender offer on
. , t) requires t e uy h N
(th irty percen . at the highest price paid for those s ares. o
all the outstanding shar~s t rovi·ded under U.S. law at the federal
1 · Of this sor are P
laws or regu at10ns •d £ r "best-price rules" whose effects are
level, even if some states provib.edroule Similarly the British "City Code"
similar to the UK · · ma ndatory, it· s that· might ' frustrate a hosti·1e b'd
i
imposes a ban on d ir . ectors ac ion
1 Footnotes omitted.
,, ·n Ol"l•'l•'RR HOSTILE
'f AK..:ov..:ns AND 1 l•,NIH, ' MrA su iu .:s CH. 10
510 A C.:qUISITIONS , AND 1)1,:Fl•:NSJVI~ ,, ,
. . m,ts star kly with the relative
wjthout share holder 1:1pprovHl, whach ~ontrh t"le acquisit ion.
a os 1
freedom that U.S. directors have to rc1:111,t .
. d.1re\ •nccs by pointing to the fact
Armour and Skoel explain these · ere h' structure that both
th at, notwith i;tanding ih e widm{pr~nd _owi:i e~: l :~vestors in the U.K. as
syste ms have in common the role of mstitutw . . k .
' . . d . fluencing the po1icy ma ers, 1s
sharcho]d ers and as an organize group in_ · . tment by small and
ahsent in the U.S. Instead, in the U.S., direct inves d Sk
· · n Armour an ee1 1
d1i;organized shar eholders 1s more commo · , the contexta so of
examine why corporate directors and managers, 1hn th . B ·t· h
American federalism, have a more effective role t an eir ri 18
counterparts in shaping takeover rules.
· · l par t of their contribution underlines
Th e most ong1na . . h b t t'the
importance of the rule-making process in determining_ t e su s a~ ~ve
regulatory outcome. In this respect, Armour and Skeel Juxtapose British
"coerced self-regulation, made under a clear gove~nn:iental threat . of
intervention" favored also by the geographical prox1m1ty of the ma~or
actors in the City, with the U.S. legislative and case-law processes, V:h~ch
are largely derived from litigation and judge-made rules. Comb1n1ng
these and other elements, they conclude that, in the U .K., coordina t ed
and influential institutional investors were able to promote a private
takeover regime particularly favorable to minority investors. The pillars
of this regime are the mandatory bid and the non-frustration rule . In the
U.S., by contrast, incumbent directors and managers were able to obtain
more leeway to resist takeovers thanks to a number of factors ranging
from U.S. federalism that (borrowing the image used by Armour and
Skeel) amplifies the voice of corporate managers to the lesser impact of
institutional investors' lobbying efforts on the development of case-law.
The story told by Armour and Skeel is not only well grounded and
convincing from an historical perspective, it is also consistent with
modern public-choice models that analyze the role of lobbying groups in
determining the level of investors' protection in different jurisdictions
[... ] .
But, therein ~ays_th~ rub .. If it is tr_ue that the U.K. ·approach to ·
takeovers ~avors institut10n_al investors 1n systems with a significant
degree of dispersed ownership structure, why would the essential pillars
of this approach be spontaneously adopted, well before the Thirteenth
Directive, in several continental European countries that have
concentrated ownership structures? In these systems entrenched
controlling sharehol~ers an~ the associations representing their interests
are among the most influential pressure groups in the political a and
·1nstitut10na
· · 1 inves
· t 1
ors p ay, a comparatively rena,
. less relevant roe.1 I n th'1s
A
context, rmour an d Sk 1
ee s analysis leads to additi'onal
. ques t·ions: Who
are the lobbying groups that promoted this legislation? Or, is it possible
TAKEOVERS AND TEND
CH. 10 ACQUISITIONS AND DER OFFERS, HOSTILE
~:~~h~l:.::1:~:~~,~~~EIFE~N~S~1yv~E~M~E~A~S~U~R:iEis ___ ~51_!11
.
that t e egis atures were me re 1Y particula
t' f · · · to the need of
r! Y att entive
protec 10n o minority investor s? Wh
Ita~y among the first, dating b;ck t~ ;ere countries such as France and
regime when they have otherw· b he 1990_s,to embrace the British
minority investors? ise een slower m legislative protection of
[... ]
Mandatory bid the be t .
breakthrough provisio ns whic~ price rule, board neutrality, and
th
considered to be effectiv~ takeov::p::seft . e e~tire panoply of what is
effects when applied in systems with~ ation, might have v~r~ different
dispersed ownership. This h th . ncentrated ownership mstead of
especially in the public debate ypo t ~:~st has.
nd
been largely overlooked,
intuitive. ' no wi a ing the fact that it is quite
TION,
TAKEOVER REGULATION, HARMONIZA
GAL
REGULATORY COMPETITION, AND LE
TRANSPLANTS: EUROPE, U.S., CHINA,
INDIA, AND BRAZIL
and harmonization
What is the effect of regulatory competition
t with European law. So
efforts on the regulation of takeovers? Let's star
Takeover Directive, which
far we have referred primarily to the 2004
ry approach in this area;
offers a good sense of the European regulato
have to make with respect
there are, however, some important caveats we
lemented in the different
to the way in which the Directive has been imp
ed in political controversy
Member States. The Directive had been embroil
cerns of some governments
for almost twenty years, especially due to con
champions vulnerable to
that the new rules could make national
of the Directive was only
takeovers by foreign firms . In fact, approval
of making the most
possible thanks to compromise, in the form
optional. The Directive, in
contentious rules not mandatory, but simply
rk, but leaves to Member
other words, sets forth a common legal framewo
ent the different rules. It
States lots of freedom on if and how to implem
l of harmonization and in
provides, in other words, a quite minimal leve
n at all; while others even
fact, according to some, no real harmonizatio
does a two-track regulatory
argue that the Article 12 option, creating as it
ctive pointless . Whatever
environment for takeovers, has made the Dire
ect-for example-to the
the case may be, there is flexibility with resp
datory offer on all the
definition of "control" that triggers the man
the minimum price of the
outstanding shares, on the calculation of
nsions of the obligation to
mandatory offer, on the exemptions and exte
launch an offer, and-particularly important for our purposes-even on
of the "pillars" of the U.K.
the adoption of the board neutrality rule, one
addition, also another rule
approach which inspired the Directive. In
TAKEOVERS AND TENDER OFFERS, HOSTILE
516 ACQUISITIONS, AND DEFENSIVE MEASURES CH. IO
518
TAKEOVERS AND TENDER OFFERS, HOSTILE
CH. 10
i
ACQUISITIONS, AND DEFENSIVE MEASURES 1
I
1
mandated mandated J
not not provided by
mandated mandated law as a by law, but by law, not
by law, by law, default rule, subject to subject to
issuers can issuers can and subject reciprocity reciprocity
adopt it in adopt it in to
the bylaws, the bylaws, reciprocity,
and in this and in this but issuers
board case can case it is can opt out
neutrality decide if it subject to in their
rule is subject to reciprocity bylaws
reciprocity
or not
(before
2014
mandated
by law, but
subject to
reciprocity)
not not not not not
mandated mandated mandated by mandated mandated
by law, bylaw, law, issuers bylaw, bylaw
issuers can issuers can can adopt it issuers can
adopt it in adopt it in in the adopt it in
the bylaws, the bylaws, bylaws, and the bylaws,
and in this and in this in this case and in this
breakthrough case it is case it is it is subject case it is
rule subject to subject to to reciprocity subject to
reciprocity reciprocity (but in case reciprocity
of tender
offer
shareholders'
agreements
are not
enforceable)
rules. Some authors believe in this ability of the market, and therefore
suggest the adoption of almost entirely optional rules (see, ~or example, L.
Enriqu es, R. J. Gilson, and A. Pacces, The Case for an Unbiased Takeover
Law (With an Application to the European Union), 4 J:fARVARD B~s. L.
REV. 85 (2014)). We are more skeptical about the VIrtues _of pnv~te
ordering in this area, but the issue offers the occasion f~r an interesting
discussion. For example, if takeover rules should be flexible, do you ?nd
preferable to have a default rule in favor of incumbents, and corporat10ns
can opt-in a rule more protective of investors, or the other way arou?d? If
the level of protections against hostile takeovers is se~ ~y a res~l';ltio~ of
the shareholders' meeting, what is the role of supermaJority proV1s10ns.
· France has also used the flexibility of the Directive to enact rules
designed to protect incumbents against takeovers. To begin with, it
reduced the threshold for a mandatory bid from 33% to 30% in 2010: as
we have seen, a- lower triggering participation might mean more
expensive hostile takeovers. In 2014, the board neutrality rule was
abandoned and the right of information of the employees' council
strengthened. Also the fact that "loyalty shares" (discussed in Chapter 4)
have become the default rule in 2014 can be considered an anti-takeover
device: when the shareholders' meeting votes on a defensive measure,
long-term shareholders will have proportionately more influence than
more recent ones, including the bidder . The breakthrough rule (Article 11
of the Takeover Directive) could curb the effect of loyalty shares, but as
seen in the above table, the rules is not mandatory in France.
As French loyalty shares suggest, the barriers to takeovers do not
only depend on takeover rules, but also on other corporate law rules.
There are countless examples. Consider, for instance, corporate
governance rules that we have studied in Chapter 5. As we mentioned in
that part of the book, many commentators have argued that the two-tier
German system of governance represents, in itself, a possible protection
against takeovers, because a new shareholder, before being able to control
the management of the corporation, not only has to change the
composition of the supervisory board, but must also wait for the new
members of the supervisory board to change the members of the
managing board. According to some, this apparently minor glitch could
contribute to raising the cost of a takeover. In addition, and probably
more substantively, German Mitbestimmung, the mandatory
representation of employees in the supervisory board, can also make
German boards particularly averse to hostile takeovers. Employees '
representatives, quite clearly, will not be particularly pleased with
acquisition plans aiming at "greater efficiency," if this means layoffs.
We discussed that optional rules and differences in the corporate
laws of the Member States have significantly limited the harmonizing
effects of the Takeover Directive. Should it, however, be considered a total
TAK EOVERS AND T ENDER O
CH.10 ACQUI SITIONS AND D FFER S , HO STILE
' E FENSIVE MEA SURES 52 1
-
failure for the purposes of creating a I 11d .
similar evaluation would be too har sh e;~ e
"' playin g field? We believe a
features of the Directive that have h ·1 ;r e ar~ other less controversial
level playing field for takeovers in E:r pe ~; will _helpto bring about a
th
no ing else, the Directive
bas contributed to the development . oEpe. of a "common Ia~~uage"
' m urope
mak~ r .
on takeov er amon g busine sspeo ple, polic
and legal and economic scholars · It h as con y t 'b s, Judges, practit10ne·rs,1
ri uted to identifyi
aspec ts of takeov er regula tion, and to more easil cl ·r . ng cruc_ia
takeover regimes and rules as more or less in . y f assi yfinghalte~native
k h Id Th . h avor o t e different
st~ e ho ters.b 1·at m_1gt_be ~onsidered a not partic ularly rich consolation
prize, u we e ieve 1t 1s not irrelevant.
It should be noted, on the other hand, that also in the U.S. states
ha~e competed to a~tract corporations through the enactment of rules
e takeovers . we re £er, of
. bents against- hostil
designed to protect " incum
course, t o so-ca11ed anti-takeover statutes." Some of the earlier versions
of these statutes, based ?n~erit review of hostile offers by st~te bodies,
have been held unconstitutional because they were in violation of the
commerce clause and pre-empted by the Williams Act (see Edgar v. Mite
Corp., 457 U.S. 624 (1982)); subsequent generations of anti-takeover
statutes, based on corporate governance rules, have however been upheld
in court (see CTS Corp . v. Dynamics Corp. of Am., 481 U.S. 69, 94 (1987)),
and they offer a broad variety of techniques to protect incumbents. We
find "control share acquisition" statutes, providing limitations to the
voting rights of whoever acquires a certain threshold of shares, unless the
other shareholders approve the acquisition; "fair price" statutes, pursuant
to which business combinations with relevant shareholders (for example,
holding more than 15% of the shares) must be approved by a
supermajority vote unless they offer a minimum price to existing
shareholders; "cash-out" statutes, according to which if a person obtains
control, she must offer to purchase the remaining shares at the highest
price paid (as you can see, the economic effects of these provisions are
similar to the ones of the mandatory tender offer); and ''business
combination" statutes, which limit the ability of large shareholders to
carry on mergers and other transactions fo~ a few years after_ the
acquisition of the shares unless those transactions are approved with a
supermajority vote .
But what about other legal systems, and in. particular "~RIC"
countries? Have the regulatory approaches adopted in Europe or in !he
U.S. been successfully exported to those jurisdictio~s? T_he _follo~ing
,
excerpt very effectively, even if briefly, illustrates the situation 1n China
India, and Brazil.