PWC Beps Action 11 Analysis May 2015
PWC Beps Action 11 Analysis May 2015
PWC Beps Action 11 Analysis May 2015
8 May 2015
Dear Mr Bradbury,
PricewaterhouseCoopers LLP (PwC) welcomes the opportunity to comment on the OECD’s Public
Discussion Draft on Action 11: Improving the Analysis of BEPS.
We commend the Secretariat and the Working Group for their efforts in realistically assessing the
conceptual challenges and data limitations that must be addressed to quantify either the scale or the trend
in BEPS activities.
The discussion draft appropriately identifies a number of important caveats in connection with measuring
the scale and trend of BEPS activities, including:
The need to exclude from BEPS measures income attributable to, inter alia, real activity,
government incentives, and productivity differences between locations;
The recognition that book-tax differences do not necessarily reflect BEPS activity; and
The recognition that recent data are affected by the global financial crisis.
In an appendix to this letter, we have compiled key caveats regarding the measurement of BEPS that are
identified in the discussion draft itself.
This letter reflects the views of the PwC network of firms, and we offer our observations on several aspects
of the discussion draft.
The indicators highlighted in the discussion draft and referred to below are broadly:
PricewaterhouseCoopers LLP, 600 13th St., NW, Suite 1000, Washington, DC 20005
T: +1 202 414 1666, F:+1 813 288 7870, www.pwc.com
1. Relative concentration of net foreign direct investment (FDI) to GDP
2. High profit rates of low-taxed affiliates of top global MNEs
3. High profit rates of MNE affiliates in lower tax countries
4. Profit rates compared to effective tax rates (ETRs) for MNE domestic and foreign operations
5. ETRs of MNEs compared to comparable domestic firms
6. Relative concentration of royalty payments relative to R&D expenditures
7. Interest expense to income ratios of top global MNE affiliates in high statutory tax rate countries
For two indicators (#1 and #6), time trends are reported over the 2005-2012 period. In both cases, the
BEPS indicator are coincident with the global financial crisis. Calculating indicators over a longer period
of time would be helpful in assessing whether, and to what extent, macroeconomic conditions may affect
the BEPS indicators.
For indicator #2, in 2011, it is reported that 67% of top global MNE affiliate income is in countries with
high profit rates (relative to the MNE worldwide average), of which 45% is in countries with low ETRs
(relative to the MNE worldwide average). Thus two-thirds of income of high profit rate affiliates is
reported in low-tax countries (45%/67%). This is taken to be evidence supportive of BEPS. However,
among the population of affiliates with low profit rates, an even higher percentage (79%=26%/33%) of
affiliate income is reported in low-tax jurisdictions. The smaller share of high profit rate than low profit
rate affiliate income in low-tax jurisdictions does not seem consistent with BEPS-related activity.
As the very largest MNEs may not be representative, we recommend calculating indicators for all MNEs
for which data are available.
Indicators may be significantly affected by inclusion of loss companies in the sample. We recommend
that results be reported with and without inclusion of loss companies.
Outliers are a common issue with indicators of the type suggested in the discussion draft. ‘Winsorizing’
the data may be appropriate.
2 of 5
3. Observations on economic approaches to measuring the scale of BEPS
The report correctly observes that measurement of the scale of BEPS activity requires a counterfactual
determination of where profits would be reported absent BEPS activity. This requires that the analysis
take into account non-tax factors that affect income including R&D, intangible capital, public
infrastructure, industry agglomeration effects, and synergies with other affiliates [p. 61]. However, these
factors generally are omitted in academic studies.
Based on a meta-analysis of econometric research on profit shifting, Heckemeyer and Overesch (2013)
find that studies using company-level data find significantly smaller tax effects on reported profitability.
The authors conclude that aggregated data (e.g., at the industry or country level) are associated with
misleadingly high tax effects.2
PwC agrees with the discussion draft conclusion that multiple approaches to measuring the scale and
trend of BEPS activities are better than reliance on a single measure,
“Given the many uncertainties associated with estimates of the scale and economic impacts of
BEPS, using multiple approaches and seeing where their ranges overlap should provide more
comfort to policymakers than relying on a single approach or a single data source.” [p. 60]
The aim of public policy should be to improve economic welfare. This requires that policy actions
generate increases in economic welfare in excess of costs. The report takes a “balanced budget” approach
to analysing BEPS meaning that revenues raised by BEPS are assumed to be used to lower other taxes.
Under this approach, the economic benefit of BEPS counter-measures is not the revenue raised, but
rather the improvement (if any) in the allocation of economic resources that leads to increased output.
PwC appreciates that OECD plans to analyse the full economic impact of BEPS countermeasures
including the effects on “economic efficiency and growth … and the burden of … BEPS countermeasures”
[p. 71].
PwC notes that it is not clear ex ante that BEPS counter measures will be efficiency enhancing. In
particular, proposed changes in transfer pricing rules that more closely align profit with economic activity
such as employment and assets may have the effect of increasing investment by MNEs in tax havens.
1 Dhammika Dharmapala, “Base Erosion and Profit Shifting: A Simple Conceptual Framework,”
University of Chicago, Coase-Sandor Institute for Law and Economics Working Paper no. 703, September
2014.
2 Jost Heckemeyer and Michael Overesch, “Multinationals’ Profit Response to Tax Differentials: Effect
Size and Shifting Channels,” Centre for European Economic Research, Discussion paper No. 13-045,
2013.
3 of 5
5. Other issues
The discussion draft (Para. 14, page 7 and Table 1.1, page 10; and Table 2.1, page 34) attempts to make a
distinction between “real investment” and investment that includes “mergers and acquisitions and the
accumulation of reinvested earnings.” It is not clear what distinction is intended to be made here – FDI
through mergers or investment of retained earnings does confer real economic activity to the company
which undertakes this FDI.
We hope that these comments are helpful to the Working Party, and we remain available to provide any
assistance that the OECD may require.
Yours sincerely,
4 of 5
Appendix
Key Caveats Raised in the Discussion Draft
Quantifying either the scale or trend in BEPS activities
1. Due to “significant limitations of existing data … attempts to construct indicators or undertake an
economic analysis of the scale and impact of BEPS are severely constrained and, as such, should be
heavily qualified.” [p. 4]
2. “The use of any indicators to identify the scale and economic impact of BEPS can only provide
‘general indications’ and the interpretation of any such indicators must be heavily qualified by
numerous caveats.” [p. 25]
3. “it is difficult for researchers to disentangle real economic effects from the effects of BEPS-related
behaviour.”
a) “Many BEPS behaviours cannot be identified as specific entries on tax returns or financial
accounts. … thus, policymakers need economic analyses of BEPS and BEPS countermeasures,
rather than just compile descriptive statistics.” [p. 6]
b) “there are three different categories of effects that ideally would be separately estimated: (i) real
economic activity across countries independent of tax; (ii) real economic activity across countries
influenced by differences in non-BEPS-affected tax rates (e.g., responsiveness of capital
investment to a change in a country’s effective tax rate); and (iii) BEPS-related activities across
countries … Only category (iii) effects should be attributed to BEPS.” [p. 7]
c) “If economic functions, assets, and risks are effectively relocated to another country to take
advantage of a low rate or tax credit, this does not constitute BEPS.” [p. 58]
d) “identifying deviations from arm’s-length pricing is a highly fact-intensive analysis. … Simple
descriptive statistics can only provide indications, rather than correlation or causation, of
potential BPES behaviours ...” [p. 18]
e) “With the growing reliance of modern business on intangible property and risk as part of global
value chains, it becomes more difficult to identify where the activities creating profits take place
without better data, careful transfer pricing analysis of individual transactions, and other income
measurement rules.” [p. 58]
f) “Indicators should focus on tax shifting due to BEPS, not real economic responses to tax rate
differences that reflect the impact of current-law provisions adopted by legislators, including
incentives to expand business operations in their country. Legislated or discretionary tax
incentives can have an important impact on reported corporate income tax payments that reflect
the location of real economic activity. The challenge in developing indicators is distinguishing
between the economic effects and BEPS.” [p. 68]
5 of 5