Long-Term Investment and Accounting: Overcoming Short-Term Bias

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 24

Long-term investment

and accounting:
overcoming short-term bias
Public policy paper
INFORMATION FOR BETTER MARKETS INITIATIVE

BUSINESS WITH CONFIDENCE icaew.com/bettermarkets


1. The problem

Investment is an essential ingredient of better economic performance – both for individual firms
and for the economy as a whole. For long-term performance what matters is a mixture of short-,
medium- and long-term investment. In the private sector this will be financed by short-, medium-
and long-term investors, using financial instruments of different durations.

The challenge is to maintain an appropriate balance between the short term, the long term
and everything in-between. However, both managers and investors are often accused of being
biased towards the short term. And it is sometimes claimed that accounting as we know it has
inherent biases that encourage short-termism in managers and investors, discouraging long-term
investment.

There are five counts on the charge sheet:

• It is claimed that the use of fair-value-type measurements encourages short-termism. We look
at this question in section 2.

• Firms report on their performance over short periods, with the result, it is said, that there is no
accountability for managers’ long-term performance and they are therefore encouraged to
focus on the short term (section 3).

• It is also claimed that frequent reporting – quarterly, for example – makes managers
more short-termist in their decisions (section 4).

• Firms provide information about their performance and financial position as quickly as possible
so as to meet investors’ demand for timely information. This requires preparers to make
arguably premature accounting judgements, which – under current accounting conventions –
tend to be biased towards writing off spending on investments whose outcome is uncertain.
This, it is claimed, creates a bias against investment in intangibles (section 5).

• Finally, firms’ activities have consequences for society and the environment that are not
reflected in their accounts and are therefore, it is argued, ignored by firms and their investors.
Some of these consequences are long term (section 6).

In section 7 we draw some conclusions and identify questions for further work.

Types of investment
There are two distinct types of long-term investment and in this report we are concerned
with both:

• investment by firms in assets that have potentially long lives – eg, brands, technologies, land
and buildings, mines, oil wells, pharmaceuticals; and

• investments by shareholders or lenders (‘investors’) that are held for the long term.
There is not necessarily any connection between the two types of long-term investment. Firms
that invest in short-life assets may be financed by long-term investors and firms that invest in
long-life assets may be financed by short-term investors. Of course, short-term finance for long-
life assets can be a recipe for disaster. The problem is usually overcome by ensuring that long-life
assets are financed by long-term financial instruments, either equity or long-term debt. But these
may be held by short-term investors.

Accounting information in the form of financial reporting is only one of the ways that firms
provide information to investors, and investors also have access to other sources of information.
Non-financial reporting, disclosures outside the regular reporting cycle, and information from
third parties are all relevant to investors’ decisions. So, even if financial reporting does impart a
short-term bias to investment, this may be countered by other forms of information. For example,
firms that invest heavily in intangibles that do not appear as assets in their accounts can (and
should) provide additional information on these assets so that investors are fully informed.

2 Long-term investment and accounting: overcoming short-term bias


Financial reporting also plays a disciplinary role for other sources of information, as investors
can check that the expectations raised by other disclosures are subsequently confirmed by
information in the audited accounts.

Defining the ‘long term’


Investments nowadays are often bought and sold in a fraction of a second. In this context,
investors who hold on for a year or two may be regarded as long-termist. At the other extreme,
a human life in a developed economy typically lasts for 80 years or more, and individuals may
make investment decisions at an early age that can still affect their lives 50 or 60 years later.

In this report, we take the long term to be 20 years or more. This is somewhat arbitrary, but
few business decisions look 50 years ahead, a year is definitely too short to be the long term,
and something in-between looks more reasonable.

We take the short term to be periods of a year or less. On this basis, the boundaries between
the short and long terms are ill-defined, but this does not affect our argument.

Long-term investment and accounting: overcoming short-term bias 3


2. Fair value accounting

It is sometimes claimed that fair value or other current value measurements can make the
reported performance of long-term investments unnecessarily volatile. This is partly because
current value measurements of such items reflect not only changing expectations of future
cash flows, but also changes in the discount rate applied to the cash flows. It is argued that
this unnecessary volatility can deter investors from selecting such investments.

It is also claimed that fair value measurements can encourage short-termist attitudes by
rewarding performance that in the short term appears successful, but which in the long
term may not be (or vice versa). In particular, it is argued that short-term falls in asset values
can cause unnecessary problems in regulated firms’ balance sheets, giving an unwarranted
appearance of insolvency or capital-adequacy difficulties. These arguments relate particularly
to banks and to the potential causes of the Global Financial Crisis of 2008.

In spite of these claims, we are not aware of any evidence that the use of fair value
measurements has led to short-termism in investor behaviour, and we consider it unlikely that
it has done so. In general, more volatile financial performance implies greater risk for investors,
which should make them more reluctant to invest. But the evidence suggests that investors
understand that fair value numbers are inherently more volatile than historical cost numbers;
they do not assume that greater volatility from this cause indicates greater risk.

Ironically, in view of the concerns that have been expressed about fair value, some of the most
important ways that financial reporting has improved in recent decades have involved greater
use of fair value or similar estimates of current value in reporting on long-term items.

For example, accounts now contain better information than they used to on the implications
of firms’ long-term commitments for pensions and healthcare benefits for current and former
employees. These costs, which are uncertain amounts to be met possibly several decades in
the future, can only be measured sensibly using some form of present value calculation – if not
exactly fair value, then something like it.

Accounts also contain better information now on the long-term environmental costs of firms’
operations. For example, where decommissioning costs or environmental restitution costs will
eventually be incurred by the firm, these are recognised in its accounts. Again, this requires a
calculation of the present value of the future payments involved – something like fair value.

In these and other ways, fair-value-type measurements of long-term items are making financial
reporting more transparent, and helping businesses and their investors face up to the long-
term consequences of their decisions. Although these changes can be presented as a shift
towards fair value, it is probably better to see them as a move away from cash-based to accrual-
based accounting. This requires matching income with the costs incurred in generating it, even
though the relevant expenditure may be some way off in the future. Such measurements may
also perhaps be seen as countering managers’ potential ‘hyperbolic discounting’ – the tendency
to discount future consequences excessively.

A possible disadvantage of fair-value type measurements of long-term items is that they involve
a significantly higher degree of estimation; there is a relevance v reliability trade-off in moving
from cash-based to accrual-based accounting.

To the extent that fair-value-type measurements of long-term items are considered to give a
misleading picture of performance (but, for some items, are perhaps more useful nonetheless
than alternative measures), changes in them can be segregated to the statement of other
comprehensive income (OCI). This happens already with some gains and losses, but currently
not on the basis of a consistent rationale.

4 Long-term investment and accounting: overcoming short-term bias


3. Long-term data series

If we wish to encourage better long-term performance, then perhaps it would make sense to
have financial reporting that covers long periods. Otherwise it could be argued that there is no
accountability for long-term performance, reducing managers’ incentives to pay due attention
to the long term.

It would be possible for firms to provide long-term series of data as supplementary information.
They might, for example, provide 20 years of data for key financial reporting numbers. After all,
government statisticians manage to produce long runs of data on consistent bases and adjusted
for inflation. These go back decades and are considered to be essential in judging economic
performance.

In practice, investors already look at longer runs of data on firms. Investment analysts often
maintain databases going back a number of years. The cyclically adjusted price/earnings (CAPE)
ratio goes back 10 years, and other commercial information providers sell data going back for
longer periods. We are aware of at least one provider that makes adjustments to 20-year data
runs for eg, the effects of inflation and changes in lease capitalisation policies. Data series are
available for even longer periods than this but do not appear to include such adjustments.

Investors are interested in these longer data runs for several reasons:

• a single year’s results can be misleading;

• looking at a number of years gives the user an idea of trends in the firm’s performance; and

• a longer period makes sure that the picture of the firm’s performance includes how it
performs at different points in the business cycle.

It therefore appears that investors, either by constructing their own data series or by buying
information from commercial providers, already have the long-term performance data that
they need. We are not aware of any calls from investors for firms to provide significantly longer
time series of data, but it could be done if there were a demand for it and if the benefits could
be shown to exceed the costs. Longer-term information is of interest to people other than
investors eg, researchers, and perhaps there could be said to be a public interest in it, but the
benefits of providing it would still have to be compared with the costs. It would probably not
be practicable for firms to provide such information on a fully comparable basis for more than
a few years, partly because of changes in accounting policies, but also because firms’ structures
and business models are liable to change significantly over time. Changes in the value of
money are a problem as well, of course, but the numbers could be adjusted to allow for this.

The problem of motivating managers to focus on long-term performance is also addressed to


some extent in practice by long-term incentive plans (LTIPs) and by deferred bonus schemes.
These are not ‘long-term’ in the sense of this report, as they would generally last no longer
than three to five years. But senior executives are rarely in place for 20 years, and there is a limit
to how long employees would be willing to wait before they are paid, so shorter periods make
sense in this context.

Long-term investment and accounting: overcoming short-term bias 5


4. Frequency of reporting

It is often said that quarterly reporting can encourage short-termism in corporate managers
and so impede long-term investment; there is some evidence to support this view.

Greater reporting frequency can increase transparency, leading to beneficial capital market
outcomes, such as a lower cost of capital and greater market liquidity in share trading,
facilitating capital raising for long-term investments. There is some research evidence that
supports this view and some that casts doubt on it; we summarise this evidence in the
appendix. But when the frequency of reporting is increased there is a trade-off between
increases in transparency (which should make it easier to attract finance for investments of
any duration) and managers’ wishes to meet market expectations (which may militate against
incurring short-term costs that promise longer-term payoffs). This can also be seen as a trade-
off between transparency and managerial autonomy, with managers believing that, left to
themselves, they can be trusted to do the right thing in the firm’s long-term interests, and
investors wishing to monitor the managers.

There is a limit to how often it is sensible to report information externally, and reporting
too frequently may well impede long-term investment. But the ideal frequency of financial
reporting is likely to vary among jurisdictions and among firms. In the same way, firms’
statements on their future viability under The UK Corporate Governance Code (2014) cover
different periods reflecting, among other things, ‘the nature of the business and its stage
of development’.

The Kay Review of UK Equity Markets and Long-Term Decision Making (2012) commented that, for
businesses with long-term investment horizons, ‘interim assessments of evolving performance
are necessary, but can only be qualitative and subjective. The meaningful measurement of
annual profit requires fine and subjective judgement, and quarterly earnings will be dominated
by random fluctuations – or worse, will be managed to avoid them.’ The review accordingly
recommended that quarterly reporting requirements should be removed, which has
subsequently been done at the EU level.

The concern about the frequency of external reporting contrasts with what happens inside
firms. We are unaware of any firm that has decided to stop requiring monthly (or quarterly)
management accounts because they focus managers’ attention too much on short-term
performance. It would be interesting to consider why there is this difference between the
presumed effects of internal and external reporting frequency, and how far the presumption
is justified.

6 Long-term investment and accounting: overcoming short-term bias


5. Timeliness v reliability

The trade-off
Investors want progress reports on how the firms in which they invest are performing, and
they want this information on a timely basis so that they can take action where appropriate.

Many measurements in accounts are affected by expectations about the future. These
measurements could be made more reliable just by waiting. For example, when managers
prepare accounts, often they do not know whether or to what extent the amount that the firm
has spent on a particular asset will be recovered from the future income that it will generate.
If they waited long enough, they would (ignoring allocation problems) know the answer.
How long they would have to wait depends on the asset: perhaps a few months for trade
debts, some years for plant and machinery, and up to 25 years for a mortgage. On the liability
side, the same problem arises with provisions for future uncertain amounts. If they wait the
necessary months, years or decades, managers will know how the liability turns out.

In practice, of course, investors – and indeed other interested parties such as tax authorities –
do not want to wait to see how things will turn out at some point in the possibly distant future.
They want timely information, even though this requires the preparers of accounts to make a
series of arguably premature judgements.

An important convention in accounting is prudence. This is reflected in the requirements of


standard-setters and in preparers’ judgements. It affects, among other things, which assets
are recognised in accounts and how they are measured. One of its effects is that expenditure
on intangible assets created by a business is usually not recognised as an asset in the accounts
but is written off as it is incurred because at the time of the expenditure its future recovery is
regarded as too uncertain. This can lead to a significant discrepancy between the assets that
a firm holds and the assets that it shows in its accounts. As investment in intangibles becomes
relatively more important, this discrepancy tends to grow.

It has been argued that the absence from accounts of many intangibles acts as a deterrent to
firms to invest in them. Accounting researchers have argued on different sides of this question
and we refer to the evidence in the appendix. But on balance we do not believe that the
accounting treatment of intangibles has led to under-investment in them to the detriment
of long-term performance. Investors understand – and are happy with – how intangibles are
accounted for and they use other sources of information when investing in intangibles-based
firms. Among other things, prudent accounting on such matters counters an inherent tendency
to excessive optimism among preparers – an aspect of the well-attested phenomenon of
‘managerial optimism’ ie, over-optimism.

However, there is a trade-off between timely reporting and reliable information, and this
affects how a business’s performance is reported. We look below at a possible way in which
this conflict could be mitigated by taking a longer-term approach to financial reporting.

Updating past estimates


In financial reporting, it is accepted that prior years’ results should be adjusted for errors but
not for changes in accounting estimates. Is this the most useful approach?

It would be possible for companies to produce revised versions of their accounts for earlier
years, adjusting them with the benefit of hindsight so that they give a more accurate picture of
performance than would have been available on the basis of information available at the time.
And some people have indeed suggested that this should be done.

Although we note an exception below, revisions of prior years’ estimates would usually only
be practicable over a relatively short period, perhaps going back over five years at the most.
They would not, therefore, be a method of reporting on long-term performance, although they
would give a more accurate picture year by year of medium-term performance. An exception is
insurance, and US property and casualty insurers are required to provide information updating
previous years’ experience in the light of subsequent developments for a period of 10 years.

Long-term investment and accounting: overcoming short-term bias 7


This is possible because of the nature of the records kept for insurance of this sort, reflecting
the duration of the relevant liabilities.

Revising previous years’ results using the benefit of hindsight to improve past estimates of the
future would no doubt produce interesting information. And the further we are from a past
period, the more accurately we can adjust its results. Would the benefits exceed the costs?

When firms report, their managers are reporting on their own performance. Their reports
are on the face of it unlikely to be independent and objective in the absence of appropriate
safeguards. It is difficult to know how effective existing safeguards would be if preparers
were given the obligation – or the opportunity – to correct past estimates with the benefit
of hindsight as well as to report on current performance. The effort and attention to secure
objectivity would be likely to remain focused on the current period’s reporting on the basis that
this is what matters most. The adjustment of earlier years’ results would be likely to get less
attention and might therefore be less reliable. It would also open up opportunities for incoming
managers to rewrite the story of their predecessors’ performance; this could be either highly
informative or open to abuse. The problems of changing business structures and changing
prices, which we mentioned earlier, would also be relevant.

There are therefore changes that could be made to financial reporting to adjust medium-
term series of data with the benefit of hindsight. It is unclear whether such changes would be
worthwhile, and again we are not aware of any calls for this sort of information from investors,
but it could be done.

8 Long-term investment and accounting: overcoming short-term bias


6. Externalities

The problem of externalities is at the heart of many concerns about the contrast between the
alleged short-termism of financial reporting and the long-term effects of business activities.
Businesses can be highly profitable in the short term but have damaging long-term effects by
exhausting or polluting natural resources. Or they may be (unintentionally) unprofitable but
produce significant long-term benefits because of pioneering work that others subsequently
exploit more successfully. It may therefore be argued that financial reporting fails to align
measures of business performance with society’s long-term interests.

The key issues here are economic as well as accounting ones. Business activity creates some
costs and benefits that are not reflected in the costs incurred or benefits received by those
who create them. These are referred to as ‘externalities’ and may be either short or long term.
In the short term, a poisonous discharge into a river could kill the fish in it, but the fish stocks
may recover if proper remedial steps are taken. In the long run, a useful drug confers benefits
even after the patent expires and the company that invented it ceases to make any gain
from it. Neither the short-term nor the long-term externality is reflected in the accounts of
those responsible for them, unless the legal framework imposes relevant costs or rewards. For
example, regulatory authorities could impose fines on the polluter or the legal system could
give enforceable rights to the fishermen who use the river.

It is a basic principle of economics that we attach lower values to future than to present costs
and benefits. We also attach lower values (and frequently no value) to costs and benefits that
affect others rather than ourselves. For both these reasons, the present generation attaches
lower values to the costs and benefits that it passes on to later generations than will those who
receive them. This reflects externalities between generations. For example, a bridge can last for
hundreds of years but in deciding whether it is worthwhile to build it, the effect of discounting
future benefits is likely to mean that the decision only takes into account, say, the first 20 years.
Conversely, if it suits us to deplete the world’s natural resources now, although we no doubt
feel some concern about the costs this imposes on future generations, we are unlikely to attach
as much weight to their needs as we do to our own.

At the same time, the further ahead we look the more difficult it is to forecast the effects of
our actions. In 50 years’ time, the bridge that looks so useful now may be in the wrong place
and the resources whose prospective disappearance concerns us may have been replaced by
alternatives.

These are not problems that financial reporting as we know it can solve as it is restricted to the
financial costs and benefits experienced by the reporting firm. They are, though, problems that
should arguably be addressed in firms’ non-financial reporting, and reporting principles have
been developed that are designed to deal with them. The International Integrated Reporting
Framework, for example, provides a way for firms to report on, among other things, their
effects on natural capital. In this way, non-financial reporting can at least in part bridge the gap
between financial reporting and recognition of the full short- and long-term costs and benefits
of a firm’s activities.

But to the extent that such reporting makes assumptions about the future, it is – like financial
reporting – inevitably subjective, and the further ahead we look, the more likely it is that our
estimates of costs and benefits will be wrong. And unless the costs and benefits reported are
ultimately borne by firms and their investors, there is a risk that their decisions will in any case
be unaffected by such information.

Long-term investment and accounting: overcoming short-term bias 9


7. Conclusions and questions for further work

In the long run what matters to a society is long-term growth and development, which will be
the product of short-, medium- and long-term investments, financed by short-, medium- and
long-term investors, using financial instruments of different durations.
What matters to firms is the ability to raise money from investors at the lowest possible cost so
that they can invest it profitably in assets of varying duration. What matters to investors is the
ability to invest so as to maximise realised returns over whatever timescale they prefer.
Financial reporting should therefore facilitate investment of all durations. It does so by
providing information that, among other things:
• allows investors to understand a firm’s financial performance and financial position; and
• establishes trust between managers and investors.
The best way in which financial reporting can assist long-term investment – or indeed investment
of any duration – is by providing relevant and reliable information, so that investors can make
better decisions and can feel greater trust in the firms providing the information. In this way,
capital for investment is more likely to be provided and at lower cost, and allocated to the most
productive investments, regardless of their duration. The nature of the relevant information
does not seem to differ with the duration of the investment ie, whether it is long or short term.
Although investors are interested in long-term performance looking forward, firms do not
report on their long-term performance looking back. It would be possible for them to do so in
supplementary disclosures, but there would be practical challenges. Also, investors appear to be
content with long-term data series that they construct themselves or buy from third parties.
It would also be possible for firms to adjust past estimates in financial statements with the
benefit of hindsight. This would probably not be feasible for most firms for more than a few
years and it would involve additional costs. And again there appears to be no demand from
investors for this sort of information.
We are not aware of evidence that current financial reporting practices impede long-term
investment, except in relation to the frequency of reporting, where there is a trade-off between
the benefits of transparency and the costs of ensuring, at frequent intervals, that investors’
expectations of performance are met.
Nonetheless, the evidence on these matters is often sketchy. There is a substantial body of
research linking financial reporting to investment in various ways, and in general – as one
would expect – this finds a positive relationship between the two. But this research does not
address the possible relationship between financial reporting information and the duration of
corporate assets ie, whether investment is short term or long term.
There are a number of questions on which more research would be welcome.
• What sort of investors hold on to investments in firms for the long term? Do their
information needs differ from those of other investors?
• Is there, or should there be, a demand for firms in industries that invest in long-life assets to
report on their long-term performance? Would the benefits exceed the costs?
• Is there, or should there be, a demand for certain types of firm – eg, those that invest
heavily in intangibles – to restate with the benefit of hindsight financial reporting
information for, say, the past five years? Would the benefits exceed the costs?
• Are the capital market effects of financial reporting information affected by asset duration?
• Is the frequency of internal reporting an obstacle to long-term performance?
In answering these questions it could be particularly interesting to look at evidence from
countries such as Germany and Japan that have a reputation for taking a long-term view of
investment, and at whether their firms have in fact out-performed in the long term.
We would welcome comments on this report and its conclusions; please send them to
bettermarkets@icaew.com.

10 Long-term investment and accounting: overcoming short-term bias


Appendix: Research evidence

Introduction
The structure of this appendix mostly follows that of the main report. We look at the
evidence on whether:

• fair value accounting contributes to short-termism;

• frequent reporting encourages short-termism ; and

• the trade-off between reliability and timeliness causes short-termism.

In section 7 of the report we state that financial reporting can assist long-term investment by
providing relevant and reliable information. We look at support for this statement.

We also report in this appendix proposals for financial reporting reform, put forward by
the European Financial Reporting Advisory Group (EFRAG), intended to reflect ‘long-term
investment’ business models.

Although, as we note in the main report, there is a substantial body of research relating
financial reporting to investment in various ways, there appears to be no research relating the
effects of financial reporting to the duration of corporate investments (asset life). This may be
because relevant data are not readily available or because researchers consider the question
of no interest eg, because when they do look at it, they do not find that asset life makes a
difference, or because it is impossible to disentangle asset life from other questions eg, the
nature of firms’ business models. However, as promoting long-term investment is a widely
held public policy objective, there does seem to be a gap in the research.

In the main report we define the long term as 20 years or more. This is much longer than
what many in business would regard as long term. Barclays (2015), in its survey of opinions
in UK privately owned companies, finds that, when asked about what they considered long
term to be, half of businesses said three years out, while a further 30% said five years. However,
while the survey does not give the numbers for this, it appears that most of the businesses
expect still to be existence in 20 years’ time.1

Fair value accounting


The report notes two arguments that fair value causes short-termism in investors. The first
relates to volatility. Where accounting policies are stable, greater volatility in reported results
should indicate increased risk in the underlying investment. Increased risk should make
investors more reluctant to invest, which may affect the level of long-term investment.
However, where the increased volatility in the accounting numbers reflects a change in
accounting policies eg, greater use of fair values, investors should ideally be able to ‘see
through’ it, as it is not necessarily an indication of increased volatility in the underlying
investments.2
The evidence on fair value and volatility – on pension accounting and asset allocation, and on
investment trust share prices and to a limited extent on banks – is considered below.

The second argument relates to the alleged role of fair value accounting in encouraging
investments that appear to be successful in the short term but are unsuccessful in the long run
(or vice versa). This claim is often made in connection with the Global Financial Crisis, and we
briefly review the evidence on this. A related argument is that at times of falling asset values,
unduly low fair values can cause unnecessary problems in regulated firms’ balance sheets,
giving an unwarranted appearance of insolvency or capital-adequacy difficulties. As this would
be an instance of something appearing unsuccessful in the short term that would be successful
in the long term, we also look at the evidence on this. It has been claimed that Enron’s history
demonstrates how fair value accounting can lead to poor investment decisions, and we explore
this claim.

1 The published survey only gives the numbers for those that do not expect to be in business in 20 years’ time.
2 If increasing use of fair value provides increased transparency of risk, then it may well lead investors to make more accurate
assessments at the firm level – increasing their assessment of risk in some cases and reducing it in others.

Long-term investment and accounting: overcoming short-term bias 11


The overall conclusion on these issues is that the case against fair value is not proven. This does
not exclude the possibility that, at some point, convincing evidence will be found that supports
the theory that fair value promotes short-termism, but it does not appear to have been found
so far.

The alternative to fair value is usually considered to be historical cost. But it has sometimes
been suggested that fair values would be better measured as an average of prices over a period
rather than at a specific date eg, Seeberg et al (2008). This would have the effect of reducing
volatility, which is the rationale behind the suggestion, and would also arguably tend to reduce
any misallocation problem by smoothing out extreme values. This suggestion continues to
obtain some support.

Pension accounting and asset allocation


The European Commission’s 2013 green paper Long-Term Financing of the European Economy
states that ‘fair value accounting principles ... may … be detrimental to stability and long-term
financing horizon … There is merit in examining further whether these standards are fit for
purpose when it comes to long-term investment’. The two examples mentioned in the green
paper in support of this argument are:

‘[S]ome research highlights a reduction by institutional investors in equity


allocations in investment portfolios, since equity is considered more volatile and
risky than bonds. Other research argues that market-consistent valuation may
encourage long-term investors to increase their risk exposure, if the volatility is
recognised outside their profit and loss accounts.’

On the point about investment portfolios, the implication is that the reduction in equity
allocations is attributable to the introduction of fair value accounting. The only empirical
evidence on this point that we are aware of relates to investments by defined benefit (DB)
pension schemes in the UK and the US. This does indeed suggest that there is a correlation
between the adoption of current value measurements and a shift of a few percentage points
out of equities and into bonds. But the research literature also identifies other possible causes
of these developments so far as the UK is concerned, including the following explanations.

• The closure of DB schemes to new entrants at the period covered by the research meant
that their remaining members were on average moving closer to retirement. It is common
practice for pension funds to shift their investment balance towards bonds as their
members approach retirement and their pensions become payable.
• The tax position of investment in equities became less advantageous during the period in
question.

• Thinking about the best way to finance pensions was in any case shifting at this time, and
the wisdom of relying heavily on equities rather than bonds was increasingly questioned
for reasons that had nothing to do with accounting. The key point here is that, as the green
paper notes, investment in equities ‘is considered more volatile and risky than bonds’. Those
who argued in favour of reducing DB pension schemes’ investment in equities questioned
the suitability of using volatile and risky assets to finance stable and predictable long-term
obligations.

Mashruwala (2008) finds a reduction in UK schemes’ equity allocation and Amir et al (2010)
find reductions in equity allocations for both UK and US schemes. Kiosse and Peasnell (2009)
discuss the evidence, based on slightly earlier versions of these two papers.

A more fundamental point is that it is not clear why it should be assumed that a shift by DB
pension schemes (or any other group of investors) away from equities and towards bonds is
detrimental to the financing of long-term projects. Provided the bonds are long-term bonds,
which is usually the preference of pension funds, then they seem as fitted as equity to financing
long-term projects. No doubt such projects need a mixture of equity and debt financing. While
an average shift of a few percentage points between equity and bond asset allocations by
some investors may make the equity element slightly more expensive, it should make the bond
element correspondingly cheaper. What is needed is research on whether fair value accounting
causes a shift from equity and long-term bond issues to short-term bond issues, but we are not
aware of any research on this question.

On risk exposure, the argument mentioned in the green paper appears to be derived from the
OECD working paper The Effect of Solvency Regulations and Accounting Standards on Long-Term
Investing (2012). This referred to what might happen following changes made in the 2011 version
of IAS 19, Employee Benefits, which while introducing greater volatility in pension measurements,
removed much of the income volatility from profit or loss to OCI. These provisions came into effect
in 2013 and we are not aware of any empirical research yet as to their effects on asset allocation.

12 Long-term investment and accounting: overcoming short-term bias


Fair value and excessive volatility
Goncharov (2015) looks at the effect of fair value accounting by UK investment trusts on the
volatility of the trusts’ share (or ‘stock’) prices. He finds that ‘stock price volatility is too high
when firms use a mixed measurement model and carry assets at fair value and related liabilities
at historical cost’. He also finds, however, that:

‘Stock price volatility is low when investment trust shares are traded by
sophisticated investors and are followed by a greater number of analysts. Thus,
a better understanding of fair value reporting issues can return stock price
volatility to the normal level.’

We are not aware of any similar findings in relation to other entities that use fair value
reporting. Goncharov notes that an earlier study by the European Central Bank – Enria et al
(2004), which for this issue looks at evidence from EU banks – ‘does not support the prediction
that stock price volatility increases upon introduction of fair value accounting’. UK investment
trusts may be an extreme case as:

• virtually all their assets are fair valued, whereas in other entities (eg, banks) usually only
some of the assets are at fair value; and

• retail investors typically hold a higher proportion of the shares of investment trusts, which
are aimed at the retail investor market, than of other listed entities. So their investors may
be relatively unsophisticated.

It should be noted that Goncharov argues that it is the mixed measurement model – not fair
value as such or historical cost as such but the combination of the two – that causes the excess
volatility.

In the context of the current report, the significance of excess volatility is that it may mean
that investors perceive an investment as higher risk and therefore are less likely to support it or
would only be willing to do so at a higher price (ie, demanding a higher risk premium). While it
is unclear how far the findings of Goncharov (2015) are applicable to other forms of investment,
his findings concerning sophisticated/unsophisticated investors are of wider interest as one
would expect more sophisticated investors to recognise that increased volatility of accounting
numbers on adoption of fair value is not necessarily an indication of increased risk.

Also, although investment trusts invest predominantly in equity shares, which are a form of
long-term finance for the firms that issue them, it is not clear whether we should expect excess
volatility in investment trusts’ shares to translate into excess volatility of the shares of the
companies in which they invest, which is the question of greater significance for the purposes
of this report.

Short-termism in banking and the Global Financial Crisis


The argument that connects fair value with short-termism in banking makes the point that
fair values can be poor indicators of long-term value. It is claimed that at some points in
the business cycle fair values can be too low, while at others they can be too high. As a
consequence it is claimed that:

• at the high points of the cycle financial results look better than they should do, encouraging
decisions that are not optimal in the long term; while

• at the low points of the cycle financial results look worse than they should do, again
encouraging decisions that are not optimal in the long term. For regulated firms, this
would include situations where short-term falls in asset values cause arguably unwarranted
concerns about solvency and capital-adequacy ratios.

These arguments do not imply that historical cost is necessarily a better indicator of long-term
value. The argument is rather that short-term changes in fair value are often ‘noise’, which it
would be better to ignore.

The possible role of fair value accounting in the Global Financial Crisis has been examined in
a number of papers and reports eg: US Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) (2008),
Barth and Landsman (2010), Laux and Leuz (2010), Shaffer (2010), Bhat et al (2011),
Badertscher et al (2012), Laux (2012), Amel-Zadeh and Meeks (2013), ICAEW (2015),
chapter 11, and European Commission (2015), appendix 6.

In general, the evidence does not suggest that fair value accounting was the immediate cause
of the crisis or that it exacerbated the crisis once it had begun. SEC (2008), for example,
concludes that:

‘Bank failures in the US appeared to be the result of growing probable credit


losses, concerns about asset quality, and, in certain cases, eroding lender and

Long-term investment and accounting: overcoming short-term bias 13


investor confidence. For the failed banks that did recognize sizable fair value
losses, it does not appear that the reporting of these losses was the reason the
bank failed.’

Some of the major US banking failures were of investment banks, which were outside the
mandated scope of the SEC study. The SEC extended its conclusions so as to cover these firms:

‘Rather than a crisis precipitated by fair value accounting, the crisis was a “run
on the bank” at certain institutions, manifesting itself in counterparties reducing
or eliminating the various credit and other risk exposures they had to each firm.’

Bhat et al (2011) go against the general trend, finding evidence that fair value accounting
requirements for mortgage-backed securities drove asset sales. On the other hand, Laux (2012),
which takes into account Bhat et al (2011), concludes that ‘there is still no evidence that fair
value accounting caused widespread fire sales of assets or contagion’.

However, as ICAEW (2015) points out, the research to date does not examine the role of fair
value before the crisis – the period when critics allege that unduly high fair values contributed
to short-termist attitudes in banking. Also, Bhat et al (2011) and Amel-Zadeh and Meeks
(2013) find evidence that the stock market reacted positively to news of relaxations in fair value
accounting requirements, which suggests that the market viewed these requirements
as increasing the risk of insolvency.

Fair value and misinvestment


Benston (2006) argues that the misuse of fair value accounting by Enron in its assessment of
the success of investment projects and in compensating managers led the company ‘to over-
invest resources in often costly, poorly devised, and poorly implemented projects’. However, he
points out that this was ‘contrary to the way fair-value accounting should be used’ and that, in
other cases, ‘over-optimistic, opportunistic, and dishonest managers have misused historical-
cost-based accounting to overstate revenue and assets and understate liabilities and expenses’.
It is not clear, therefore, how far fair value accounting, rather than incompetent and dishonest
managers, should be regarded as the cause of the misinvestment.

Frequency of reporting
Managers try to meet expectations and may incur costs (dismissal, lower compensation,
impaired career prospects) if they fail to meet them. They therefore face ‘a trade-off between
the short-term need to “deliver earnings” and the long-term objective of making value-
maximising investment decisions’. As a result, they sometimes choose to ‘sacrifice long-term
value to meet earnings targets’ (Graham et al (2005)).

As Graham et al (2005) is based on US evidence, it is set in a context of meeting quarterly


earnings targets, but the same problem would exist to some degree if US companies reported
less frequently – only half-yearly or annually or even less than annually. Arya et al (1998)
draw attention to the view attributed to German managers (not in the context of reporting
frequency) that the use of hidden reserves to manipulate reported earnings allowed them to
‘focus on the long-run rather than the short-run performance of their companies’. The conflict
may therefore be seen as one between transparency and long-termism and, viewed in this
light, the problem with increased reporting frequency would be that it increases transparency.

We may also note that the comments quoted above suggest a view among managers that they
are struggling to do their best in the long-term interests of their firms, while equity investors
place obstacles in their way. It is not obvious that this view is correct, and equity investors may
see things differently.

Much of the research on the effects of reporting frequency focuses on situations where there
is a change in reporting frequency. Findings vary on the costs and benefits of increasing
frequency. The main potential benefit is a reduction in information asymmetries (although the
evidence is not unanimous on this), which may lead to a lower cost of capital and/or increased
market liquidity. Relevant costs include higher preparation costs and, potentially, increased real
earnings management, which in theory should damage a firm’s long-term prospects, although
the evidence on this too is mixed.

The research mostly looks at the effects of quarterly reporting compared with six-monthly
reporting. It does not show whether, if we compared six-monthly reporting with annual
reporting, it would still be found that managers take decisions that improve short-term
performance at the expense of the long term.

14 Long-term investment and accounting: overcoming short-term bias


The research does not relate the effects of quarterly reporting to asset life. It does not, for
example, tell us whether investments with a long life are more or less likely to be cut than
investments with a shorter life.

Most of the research uses US evidence. It would be useful to have more research on experience
in other countries. Japanese companies, for example, have a reputation for taking a long-term
view and it would be interesting to know how far Japan’s adoption of quarterly reporting in
2008 affected this.

Although research on the trade-off between meeting expectations and maximising long-
term value focuses on external reporting, managers also have to meet expectations when
they report internally, and internal reporting is usually more frequent than external reporting.
There is a trade-off here as well and it would be interesting to know more about its effects.3

Effects on cost of capital, market liquidity and information asymmetry


Botosan and Plumlee (2002) look at the effects of the level of disclosure on the cost of equity
capital. Looking at data on US companies for the period 1985–1996, they find that for ‘annual
published and other required information’ a higher level of disclosure is associated with a lower
cost of equity capital. But for ‘quarterly and other published information [that is] not required’,
which includes more timely information, they find that a higher level of disclosure is associated
with a higher cost of equity capital. They comment that their findings ‘provide some support
for managers’ claims that greater disclosure of more timely information increases their cost
of equity capital, perhaps through greater stock return volatility’.

In discussing their results for more timely disclosures, Botosan and Plumlee (2002) refer to
Bushee and Noe (2000). The latter, using the same data source as Botosan and Plumlee (2002)
for disclosure levels, find that rankings of more timely disclosures are significantly correlated
with levels of transient, short-term ownership. The authors suggest that ‘transient [shareholders]
prefer firms whose stocks have liquid markets that allow short-term trading strategies to
be executed without profits being eroded by transaction costs.’ However, transient owners
‘exacerbate a firm’s stock return volatility with their short investment horizons and aggressive
trading strategies’.

Butler et al (2007) look at the effects of voluntary and mandatory quarterly reporting on
‘timeliness’ – as they define it, the speed with which financial reporting information is reflected
in stock market prices. On the face of it, increased timeliness in this sense should indicate
increased transparency (reduced information asymmetry). The sample is US firms over the
period 1950–1973. Quarterly reporting became mandatory for US listed firms from 1970
but most were already doing it voluntarily by that time. The authors find ‘little evidence of
differences in timeliness between firms reporting quarterly and those reporting semiannually’,
but that ‘firms that voluntarily increased reporting frequency from semiannual to quarterly
experienced increased timeliness, while firms whose increase was mandated by the SEC
did not’.
Fu et al (2012) look at the effects of voluntary and mandatory quarterly reporting by US
firms over the period 1951–1973. They find that firms with higher reporting frequency have
lower information asymmetry and a lower cost of capital. This applies whether the adoption of
quarterly reporting is voluntary or mandatory. Information asymmetry is measured using two
measures of market liquidity: bid-ask spreads and the price impact of trades.4
Van Buskirk (2012) looks at the effects of voluntary monthly reporting by US retailers for
the period 1993–2001. He finds that ‘the practice of regularly providing monthly revenue
disclosures is not associated with reduced information asymmetry’ measured by two proxies for
liquidity: bid-ask spreads and ‘depth’ – the total value of shares offered at the current quoted
bid and ask prices. He also finds that ‘information asymmetry is increasing in the days prior to
the interim announcements, which is a pattern that substantiates media reports of institutional
investors going to great lengths to obtain information prior to the release date’. However,
‘by providing more frequent disclosures, [monthly reporters] improve the average level of
information among investors’.

Kajüter et al (2015) look at the effects of the introduction in 2003 of mandatory quarterly
reporting for Singapore-listed firms. The requirement was applicable to firms with a market
capitalisation of more than S$75m, so it is possible to compare firms above the threshold, to
which the new requirement applied, with those below the threshold, to which it did not. The

3 One suggestion on how to avoid the trade-off in internal reporting is that reporting on divisional performance should be based
on changes in the present value of expected cash flows: Bromwich (1974). This approach, with recognition of all currently
unrecognised assets, would also avoid the trade-off in external reporting.
4 Increased market liquidity is taken to be evidence, other things equal, of reduced information asymmetry. Reduced bid-ask spreads
and reduced price impacts of trades are both indicators of increased liquidity.

Long-term investment and accounting: overcoming short-term bias 15


authors find no evidence that quarterly reporting reduces information asymmetry as measured
by bid-ask spreads and return volatility.5

Effects on investment
Kraft et al (2015) look at the effects of increases in reporting frequency by US firms between
1950 and 1970 on the level of their investment expenditure. The sample comprises firms that
increased their reporting frequency, voluntarily or mandatorily, to quarterly, three times a
year, or half-yearly. They ‘find a statistically and economically significant decline in investments
after firms increase their reporting frequency. Additional analyses suggest that at least part
of the investment decline reflects the effects of enhanced managerial myopia following
increases in reporting frequency’. The decline in investment, after including control variables,
is 2.3% on one measure and 1.6% on another. The authors comment that their evidence
‘does not necessarily imply that frequent reporting is value destroying overall’ as there may
be compensating benefits eg, to liquidity and the cost of capital.

Ernstberger et al (2015) look at the effects of introducing interim management statements


(IMSs) – a form of quarterly reporting – in the EU. The 15 EU countries in the sample adopted
requirements for IMSs at various dates between 2007 and 2009. The authors find that ‘firms
that issue IMSs with quarterly earnings information show greater real activities manipulations6
relative to matched control firms’. They also find that ‘reporting frequency-induced real
activities manipulations are conditional on [high] capital market pressure and on … [low]
IMS disclosure and that they are associated with a long-term decrease in firms’ operating
performance’.

Kajüter et al (2015) – referred to above – also find that ‘the investment level of quarterly
reporting firms is significantly lower than the investment level of semi-annual reporting firms’.
In addition, they find that the announcement of the threshold for the requirement prompted a
rise in the share price of firms that fell below it, implying that ‘the market perceives mandatory
quarterly reporting as a net burden’.

It is not clear that ‘real activities manipulation’ is always a bad thing. Gunny (2010) looks at
earnings management by real activities manipulation for a sample of US firms for 1988–2002.
She finds that ‘using [real activities manipulation] to just meet earnings benchmarks is positively
associated with future performance’ and argues that ‘the results suggest earnings management
via [real activities manipulation] is not opportunistic, but consistent with managers attaining
benefits that allow better future performance or signaling’.

It would be interesting to know whether changes in reporting frequency affect investment


efficiency (see ‘Stock markets and long-term investment’ later in this appendix), but we are not
aware of any research on this question.

Myopic loss aversion


If frequent reporting does induce investment behaviour that is sub-optimal in the long term,
this could be consistent with the theory of ‘myopic loss aversion’ (see Benartzi and Thaler
(1995)). This suggests that investors who review their investments frequently, and who are
keener to avoid losses than to make profits, make sub-optimal decisions that mean they are
worse off in the long run. The authors treat annual reviews as ‘frequent’ for a long-term
investor. In an experiment, Thaler et al (1997) find that ‘the investors who got the most
frequent feedback (and thus the most information) took the least risk and earned the least
money’.

In corporate reporting, which these two papers do not discuss, the issue is sometimes one of
avoiding reported losses but more often one of meeting expectations: myopic disappointment
aversion.

Timeliness v reliability
The conflict between timeliness and reliability has been of particular interest in recent decades
in relation to accounting for intangibles. We look briefly at the debate on this and at proposals
to address the problem – for intangibles and other items where there is a conflict between the
timeliness of information and its reliability.

Accounting for intangibles


Skinner (2008) reviews the argument that non-recognition of intangibles results in under-
investment in them, but concludes that ‘theory and evidence from corporate finance suggest
that capital markets perform well in financing investments in innovative, high-technology

5 Other things equal, lower return volatility is taken to indicate reduced information asymmetry.
6 ‘Real activities manipulations’ are eg, cutting back on discretionary expenditures such as advertising or research.

16 Long-term investment and accounting: overcoming short-term bias


activities’ that are high in intangibles. The critics of accounting for intangibles usually focus
on their absence from the balance sheet, but Skinner (2008) draws attention to the usefulness
of the income statement in assessing the value of intangibles-rich companies, as do Penman
(2007) and Penman (2009).

The other side of the case on intangibles is set out in Lev (2001), referred to below, and Lev
(2008), a rejoinder to Skinner (2008).7 There is further discussion of this topic in ICAEW (2009),
chapter 3, which includes additional references to relevant research.

At section 5 of the main report we state that intangibles have become more important, an
assumption common among critics of current practice in accounting for intangibles. Whether
they have in fact become more important is discussed by Basu and Waymire (2008). They
defend existing accounting practice on intangibles and argue that intangibles are ‘ubiquitous
to human economic interaction’.

Revisions to earlier years’ accounts


We refer at section 4 of the report to proposals that firms should revise earlier years’ accounts
with the benefit of hindsight. There have also been proposals, with similar intent, suggesting
that firms should report on the accuracy of earlier years’ estimates but not necessarily produce
revised accounts. Readers of accounts could use the updated information to revise earlier years’
numbers if they wished to. The proposals below cover both approaches.

Lev and Zarowin (1999) look at evidence of the decreasing correlation between financial
reporting information and stock market prices, which they argue is due to the increasing
pace of change in business and to financial reporting’s inability to cope with the uncertainties
associated with change.8 They propose two reforms to deal with this problem. First, they
propose that expenditure on intangibles should be capitalised ‘when the uncertainty about
benefits is considerably resolved’. Second, they propose systematic restatements of earlier
years’ results in the light of subsequently available information. Where appropriate, the two
proposals would be combined. For example, ‘at launch, the expensing of R&D for a new drug
may seem reasonable, yet when the drug received FDA approval the past expensing is clearly
inappropriate. Why then not restate past reports as uncertainty is resolved and one can better
measure the past performance of the firm?’

In support of their proposals the authors emphasise the contextual role of financial reporting
information. Financial reporting information is not only ‘news’ but also background
information, in the light of which subsequent news from various sources is interpreted. Revising
the historical record, it is argued, would enhance this contextual function of financial reporting.

Similar but less extensive proposals are made by Lundholm (1999), who proposes that firms
should report, year by year, on the accuracy of the estimates they made in earlier years eg, for
bad debts. The author suggests that, ‘with a system in place to report on the ex post accuracy
of a firm’s estimates, regulators might be more willing to allow the booking of more difficult-
to-measure assets, such as the value of R&D expenditures’.

Ryan (1997) makes a less detailed proposal, but in the same spirit, for expanded disclosures
on the ex post realisation of risk, as already required in the US at that time for loss provisions
(‘reserves’) made by property and casualty insurers.

Lev (2001), which relates specifically to intangibles, proposes that expenditures previously
written off should be capitalised for ‘intangible investments with attributable benefits that have
passed certain prescribed technological feasibility tests’. Lev (2001) is also discussed in ICAEW
(2003), section 4.9.

Four publications do not add up to a widespread trend in accounting thought, but it is perhaps
significant that they appeared at a time when there was increasing dissatisfaction with the
financial reporting model, in particular because of the non-recognition of internally generated
intangibles; Lev and Zarowin (1999), Lundholm (1999) and Lev (2001) refer explicitly to this
issue. Interest in this issue diminished somewhat with the bursting of the Internet bubble
(2000) but has not disappeared.

Skinner (2008) assesses proposals of the type referred to above and sets out arguments against
such an approach. These include the following points (leaving aside the question of whether
existing accounting practices have any harmful effects on investment in intangibles).

• It would potentially reduce user confidence in the reliability of the numbers.

7 The issue of Accounting and Business Research that publishes Skinner (2008) and Lev (2008) also includes a reply by Skinner to Lev’s
rejoinder.
8 How such changing correlations should be interpreted is open to question; see eg, Ely and Waymire (1999), Ryan and Zarowin
(2003) and Basu and Waymire (2008), discussion at p184.

Long-term investment and accounting: overcoming short-term bias 17


• It could open the door to further earnings management/manipulation.

• The principle underlying the proposed approach could also be applied to liabilities,
which might result in higher levels of liability recognition. This might defeat the object
of the exercise to the extent that it is intended to bring accounting net assets closer to a
company’s market capitalisation.

Full fair value accounting


A more radical way of addressing the reliability v timeliness trade-off would be to abandon
the reliability constraint and prepare accounts that show all assets at their net present value,
recognising all assets in the accounts, including those not currently recognised. This is a form
of full fair value accounting. Its effect would be that the expected long-term benefits of current
expenditures are recognised instantly in the accounts – or possibly even before the expenditure
has been incurred (see Watts (2006), p53).

This approach has not often been advocated but one exception is Boulton et al (2000), who
predict that ‘in the New Economy, companies will need to continuously measure and report
all assets at fair value to all users’. The authors do not in fact foresee reliability problems in
providing this sort of information, but predict that as new web-based markets develop for all
manner of assets ‘emerging technologies will … allow … companies to derive information daily
or even hourly through information delivered to the corporate desktop’. Boulton et al (2000)
is discussed in ICAEW (2003), section 4.7.

Stock markets and long-term investment


At section 7 of the report, we state that financial reporting can assist long-term investment by
providing relevant and reliable information. Support for this proposition comes from, among
others, Bushman and Smith (2001), who argue that ‘capital markets with low liquidity risk
for individual investors can facilitate high-return, long-term (illiquid) corporate investments
… without requiring individual investors to commit their resources over the long term’. The
authors explain that financial reporting’s contribution to this is that ‘firms’ pre-commitment to
the timely disclosure of high-quality financial accounting information reduces investors’ risk of
loss from trading with more informed investors, thereby attracting more funds into the capital
markets, lowering investors’ liquidity risk’.

The chain of argument is as follows:

• increased transparency (provided by financial reporting) leads to improved liquidity;

• improved liquidity attracts more investors, making it easier to raise long-term capital or to
do so at a lower price, because it removes the need for a long-term commitment by the
investor; and

• easier access to long-term capital leads to increased long-term investment by firms.

There is empirical evidence to support each of the links in the chain, but not – as far as we
are aware – to link financial reporting directly to changes in the level of long-term corporate
investment. Levine (1997), for example, referred to by Bushman and Smith (2001), reviews the
arguments and evidence on the relationship between the development of the financial system,
including stock markets, and long-term economic growth, drawing attention to the importance
of improvements in liquidity to securing capital for long-term investments, but does not refer
to accounting. However, the implication of his paper is that anything that improves liquidity
should also improve long-term investment.

Among the evidence linking financial reporting indirectly to increased investment or higher
quality investment decisions are a number of papers on ‘investment efficiency’. Biddle et al
(2009), for example, find that:

‘Higher financial reporting quality is associated with lower investment among


firms that are cash constrained and unlevered, and with higher investment
among firms that are cash constrained and highly levered. In addition firms
with high financial reporting quality invest less when aggregate investment is
high, and invest more when aggregate investment level is low. These results
are consistent with the argument that financial reporting quality facilitates
investment for constrained firms, and curbs investment for firms that are more
likely to over-invest.’

The theory that underlies this stream of research is that, unless they have access to external
funds when they have a good investment case, firms tend to invest when they have the money
(ie, are not ‘cash constrained’) or can access funding (eg, because they are not ‘highly levered’)
regardless of whether they have a good investment case; this state of affairs is inefficient.

18 Long-term investment and accounting: overcoming short-term bias


Higher quality financial reporting should facilitate firms’ access to funding when they have a
good investment case, leading to greater investment efficiency.

While this stream of research provides evidence that financial reporting quality can lead to
greater investment efficiency, it does not distinguish among corporate investments of different
durations.

Shroff (2015) takes a different approach, and links increases in financial reporting credibility
(not quality) to significant increases both in firms’ capital expenditure (up 10.9%) and in their
‘long-term debt’ (up 11.5%). While this provides further evidence on financial reporting’s role
in supporting investment, the paper does not look at the duration of investments (which is
not reported in capital expenditure disclosures) and ‘long-term debt’ is considered to be debt
repayable more than one year after the balance sheet date, so does not match the meaning of
‘long term’ in this report.

There is also some research looking at the relation between record keeping and investment,
although again it does not look at the investments’ duration. Basu et al (2009), using
ethnographic data, find ‘strong support for our … hypothesis that the expansion of impersonal
exchange facilitated by recordkeeping is … associated with increasingly specialized division of
labor and greater overall investment in physical, tangible and political capital’.

Long-term investment business models


EFRAG, tentatively in EFRAG (2013) and positively in EFRAG (2015), has put forward proposals
for an approach to financial reporting intended to reflect the business models of firms engaged
in long-term investment. EFRAG (2015) describes this type of business model as follows, ‘assets
are purchased in order to generate a stream of revenue from period to period’, but inward cash
flows are also generated by sale of the investment assets, ‘often … in the market in which assets
were originally bought and generally in a similar “condition” as when it was bought’.

Property investment companies would be an example of such firms. The report argues that:

‘Changes in value of the assets from period to period are not relevant to periodic
financial performance reporting, as the capital appreciation is secondary to the
business model, the central feature is the stream of income derived from the
assets.’

However, changes in the value of the investment assets, where they can be reliably measured
and where the asset is in the condition in which it would be sold, would be reported but in
OCI rather than profit or loss. Gains or losses would then be recycled to profit or loss when the
assets are sold.

EFRAG (2015) also describes a liability driven business model (eg, insurers) where ‘entities
accept long-term obligations and may invest in assets to meet these’. The report states that:
‘In order to meet their liabilities when due, these businesses may invest in assets in a business
model very similar to the long-term investment business model’, in which case they should
account for the assets in the same way.

Muller et al (2011) look at the effects on information asymmetries, measured by bid-ask


spreads, of disclosure of the fair value of investment properties in accordance with IAS 40,
Investment Property, following mandatory adoption of IFRS. The authors report that:

‘Using as a control group firms that voluntarily provided … fair values [for
investment properties] prior to the mandatory adoption of IAS 40, we find that
mandatory adoption firms exhibit a larger decline in information asymmetry,
as reflected in lower bid-ask spreads. However, we also find that mandatory
adoption firms continue to have higher information asymmetry than voluntary
adoption firms, which appears partially attributable to the lower reliability of fair
values reported by the mandatory adoption firms.’

The paper provides evidence that, at least for one long-term investment business model, fair
value measurements can reduce information asymmetries.

Long-term investment and accounting: overcoming short-term bias 19


Acknowledgements

ICAEW is grateful to the following commentators for providing helpful reactions in a personal
capacity to drafts of this report.

Nick Anderson
Sudipta Basu
Christine Botosan
Kathryn Cearns
Greg Davies
Hilary Eastman
Annita Florou
Vanessa Gough
Robert Hodgkinson
Ken Lee
Richard Macve
Edmond Mjekiqi
Christopher Napier
Christopher Nobes
Rick Payne
Ken Peasnell
Shyam Sunder
Sondra Tarshis
Greg Waymire
Elizabeth White

None of the commentators should be assumed to agree with the views expressed in this report,
and they are not responsible for any errors or omissions.

The principal author of the report is Brian Singleton-Green.

20 Long-term investment and accounting: overcoming short-term bias


Bibliography

Amel-Zadeh, A. and Meeks, G. (2013), ‘Bank failure, mark-to-market and the financial crisis’,
Abacus, vol 49, pp308-339.

Amir, E., Guan, Y. and Oswald, D. (2010), ‘The effect of pension accounting on corporate
pension asset allocation’, Review of Accounting Studies, vol 15, pp345-366.

Arya, A., Glover, J. and Sunder, S. (1998), ‘Earnings management and the revelation principle’,
Review of Accounting Studies, vol 3, pp7-34.

Badertscher, B. A., Burks, J. J. and Easton, P. D. (2012), ‘A convenient scapegoat: fair value
accounting by commercial banks during the financial crisis’, The Accounting Review, vol 87,
pp59-90.

Barclays, (2015), Is Short-Termism Damaging the Growth of Your Business?, London:


Barclays Bank plc.

Barth, M. E. and Landsman, W. R. (2010), ‘How did financial reporting contribute to the
financial crisis?’, European Accounting Review, vol 19, pp399-423.

Basu, S., Kirk, M. and Waymire, G. (2009), ‘Memory, transaction records, and “The Wealth of
Nations”’, Accounting, Organizations, and Society, vol 34, pp895-917.

Basu, S. and Waymire, G. (2008), ‘Has the importance of intangibles really grown? And if so,
why?’, Accounting and Business Research, vol 38, pp171-190.

Benartzi, S. and Thaler, R. T. (1995), ‘Myopic loss aversion and the equity premium puzzle’,
The Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol 110, pp73-92.

Benston, G. J. (2006), ‘Fair-value accounting: a cautionary tale from Enron’, Journal of Accounting
and Public Policy, vol 25, pp465-484.

Bhat, G., Frankel, R. and Martin, X. (2011), ‘Panacea, Pandora’s box or placebo: feedback in
bank mortgage-backed security holdings and fair value accounting’, Journal of Accounting and
Economics, vol 52, pp153-173.

Biddle, G. C., Hilary, G. and Verdi, R. S. (2009), ‘How does financial reporting quality relate
to investment efficiency?’, Journal of Accounting and Economics, vol 48, pp112-131.

Botosan, C. A. and Plumlee, M. A. (2002), ‘A re-examination of disclosure level and the


expected cost of equity capital’, Journal of Accounting Research, vol 40, pp21-40.

Boulton, R. E. S., Libert, B. D. and Samek, S. D. (2000), Cracking the Value Code: How Successful
Businesses Are Creating Wealth in the New Economy, New York: HarperCollins.

Bromwich, M. (1974), ‘Measurement of divisional performance in the long run’, in Harold Edey
and B. S. Yamey (eds.), Debits, Credits, Finance and Profits, London: Sweet & Maxwell, pp15-20.

Bushee, B. J. and Noe, C. F. (2000), ‘Corporate disclosure practices, institutional investors, and
stock return volatility’, Journal of Accounting Research, vol 38, Supplement: Studies on Accounting
Information and the Economics of the Firm, pp171-202.

Bushman, R. J. and Smith, A. J. (2001), ‘Financial accounting information and corporate


governance’, Journal of Accounting and Economics, vol 32, pp237-333.

Butler, M., Kraft, A. and Weiss, I. S. (2007), ‘The effect of reporting frequency on the timeliness
of earnings: the cases of voluntary and mandatory interim reports’, Journal of Accounting and
Economics, vol 43, pp181-217.

Ely, K. and Waymire, G. (1999), ‘Accounting standard-setting organizations and earnings


relevance: longitudinal evidence from NYSE common stocks, 1927-93’, Journal of Accounting
Research, vol 37, pp293-317.

Enria, A. and others, (2004), Fair Value Accounting and Financial Stability, Frankfurt am Main:
European Central Bank.

Long-term investment and accounting: overcoming short-term bias 21


Ernstberger, J., Link, B. Stich, M. and Vogler, O. (2015), ‘The real effects of mandatory quarterly
reporting’, (unpublished but available at SSRN).

European Commission, (2015), Commission Staff Working Document: Evaluation of Regulation


(EC) No 1606/2002 of 19 July 2002 on the Application of International Accounting Standards,
Brussels: EC.

European Financial Reporting Advisory Group, (2013), Is there a Need for Specific Financial
Reporting for Long-Term Investing Activities Business Models?, Brussels: EFRAG.

European Financial Reporting Advisory Group, (2015), Profit or Loss versus OCI, Brussels: EFRAG.

Fu, R., Kraft, A. and Zhang, H. (2012), ‘Financial reporting frequency, information asymmetry
and the cost of equity’, Journal of Accounting and Economics, vol 54, pp132-149.

Goncharov, I. (2015), When does fair value accounting lead to artificial stock price volatility?,
London: ICAEW Charitable Trusts.

Graham, J. R., Harvey, C. R. and Rajgopal, S. (2005), ‘The economic implications of corporate
financial reporting’, Journal of Accounting and Economics, vol 40, pp3-73.

Gunny, K. A. (2010), ‘The relation between earnings management using real activities
manipulation and future performance’, Contemporary Accounting Research, vol 27, pp855-888.

ICAEW, (2003), New Reporting Models for Business, London: ICAEW.

ICAEW, (2009), Developments in New Reporting Models, London: ICAEW.

ICAEW, (2015), The Effects of Mandatory IFRS Adoption in the EU: A Review of Empirical Research,
London: ICAEW.
Kajüter, P., Klassmann, F. and Nienhaus, M. (2015), ‘Causal effects of quarterly reporting –
an analysis of benefits and costs’, (unpublished but available at SSRN).

Kiosse, P. V. and Peasnell, K. (2009), ‘Have changes in pension accounting changed pension
provision?’, Accounting and Business Research, vol 39, pp255-267.

Kraft, A., Vashishtha R. and Venkatachalam, M. (2015), ‘Real effects of frequent financial
reporting’, (unpublished but available at SSRN).

Laux, C. (2012), ‘Financial instruments, financial reporting and financial stability’, Accounting
and Business Research, vol 42, pp239-260.

Laux, C. and Leuz, C. (2010), ‘Did fair-value accounting contribute to the financial crisis?’,
Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol 24, pp93-118.

Lev, B. (2001), Intangibles: Management, Measurement, and Reporting, Washington DC: The
Brookings Institution.

Lev, B. (2008), ‘A rejoinder to Douglas Skinner’s “Accounting for intangibles: a critical review
of policy recommendations”’, Accounting and Business Research, vol 38, pp209-213.

Lev, B. and Zarowin, P. (1999), ‘The boundaries of financial reporting and how to extend them’,
Journal of Accounting Research, vol 37, pp353-385.

Levine, R. (1997), ‘Financial development and economic growth: views and agenda’, Journal
of Economic Literature, vol 35, pp688-726.

Lundholm, R. J. (1999), ‘Reporting on the past: a new approach to improving accounting


today’, Accounting Horizons, vol 13, pp315-322.

Mashruwala, S. D. (2008), ‘Does smoothing in pension accounting encourage equity


investment in corporate pension plans? Evidence from the UK’, (unpublished but available
at SSRN).

Muller, K. A., Riedl, E. J. and Sellhorn, T. (2011), ‘Mandatory fair value accounting and
information asymmetry: evidence from the European real estate industry’, Management Science,
vol 57, pp1138-1153.

Penman, S. H. (2007), ‘Financial reporting quality: is fair value a plus or a minus?’, Accounting
and Business Research, vol 37, International Accounting Policy Forum special issue, pp33-44.

Penman, S. H. (2009), ‘Accounting for intangible assets: there is also an income statement’,
Abacus, vol 45, pp358-371.

Ryan, S. G. (1997), ‘A survey of research relating accounting numbers to systematic equity risk,
with implications for risk disclosure policy and future research’, Accounting Horizons, vol 11,
pp82-95.

22 Long-term investment and accounting: overcoming short-term bias


Ryan, S. G. and Zarowin, P. A. (2003), ‘Why has the contemporaneous linear returns-earnings
relation declined?’, The Accounting Review, vol 78, pp523-553.

Seeberg, T., Starkie, M. and Zielke, C. (2008), ‘Reporting move could break the writedown
spiral’, Financial Times, 3 April.

Shaffer, S. (2010), Fair Value Accounting: Villain or Innocent Victim, Boston: Federal Reserve Bank
of Boston.

Shroff, N. (2015), ‘Real effects of financial reporting quality and credibility: evidence from the
PCAOB regulatory regime’, (unpublished but available at SSRN).

Skinner, D. J. (2008), ‘Accounting for intangibles – a critical review of policy recommendations’,


Accounting and Business Research, vol 38, pp 191-204.

Thaler, R. H., Tversky, A., Kahneman, D. and Schwartz, A. (1997), ‘The effect of myopia and
loss aversion on risk taking: an experimental test’, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol 112,
pp647-661.

US Securities and Exchange Commission, (2008), Report and Recommendations Pursuant


to Section 133 of the Emergency Economic Stabilization Act of 2008: Study on Mark-to-Market
Accounting, Washington: SEC.

Van Buskirk, A. (2012), ‘Disclosure frequency and information asymmetry’, Review of Quantitative
Finance and Accounting, vol 38, pp411-440.

Watts, R. L. (2006), ‘What has the invisible hand achieved?’, Accounting and Business Research,
vol 36, International Accounting Policy Forum special issue, pp51-61.

Long-term investment and accounting: overcoming short-term bias 23


ICAEW is a world leading professional membership organisation that promotes,
develops and supports over 145,000 chartered accountants worldwide. We
provide qualifications and professional development, share our knowledge,
insight and technical expertise, and protect the quality and integrity of the
accountancy and finance profession.

As leaders in accountancy, finance and business our members have the


knowledge, skills and commitment to maintain the highest professional
standards and integrity. Together we contribute to the success of individuals,
organisations, communities and economies around the world.

Because of us, people can do business with confidence.

We are a founder member of Chartered Accountants Worldwide and the Global


Accounting Alliance.

www.charteredaccountantsworldwide.com
www.globalaccountingalliance.com

ICAEW
Chartered Accountants’ Hall Moorgate Place London EC2R 6EA UK

T +44 (0)20 7920 8100 linkedin.com – ICAEW


icaew.com/bettermarkets twitter.com/icaew
facebook.com/icaew

© ICAEW 2016 TECPLM14675 04/16

You might also like