Antitrust - Longwell - Spring 2012
Antitrust - Longwell - Spring 2012
Antitrust - Longwell - Spring 2012
Antitrust Outline
§ 7, Clayton Act: Incipiency statute allows prevention of acquisition or mergers when “the effect of such acquisition may be to
substantially lessen competition, or to tend to create a monopoly”
FTC Act, § 5
- “Unfair methods of competition in or affecting commerce, and unfair or deceptive acts or practices in or affecting commerce
are hereby declared unlawful” 15 USC § 45
- Only FTC can use
- Can be used to purse Sherman violations
Economics
Antitrust promotes competition out of the belief that competition presses producers to satisfy consumer wants at the lowest price while
using the fewest resources
- Basic Assumptions
o Cartels must be able to reduce output either individually or collectively
In Microsoft, court found co. had unilateral monopoly power. Internal corporate e-mails cited this.
Microsoft could reduce its own output and raise prices
o Four necessary means to control output
Set a plan. Frustrated by competitor’s differing cost structures and achieving consensus on mkt allocation
Monitor
Punish deviants
Cope w/ entrants
- Benefits of Competition
o Economic Benefits
Less transfer of wealth from buyers to sellers
Less Allocative Efficiency Loss
Non-Economic Benefits
Prevent Concentration of Wealth
Individual autonomy
o “Competition is destruction in our industry” generally rejected
1
ANTITRUST- LONGWELL- SPRING 2012 2
Three statutes cover horizontal agmts
- The most important is Sherman Act § 1 - Every contract, combination in the form of trust or otherwise, or conspiracy, in
restraint of trade or commerce among several States, or w/ foreign nations, is declared to be illegal
Per Se
SCOTUS has held that certain agmts are so likely to be anticompetitive, and so unlikely to have procompetitive effects, that they are
condemned “per se”
- i.e. price fixing, mkt divisions, output restraints and boycotts
- when pro se, SCOTUS will not consider procompetitive justifications or whether anticompetitive effects actually occurred
Rule of Reason
If not a per se violation, the Cts consider on a case by case basis whether the agmt has a plausible procompetitive justification
- must prove an anticompetitive effect either through direct proof or by showing mkt power that can be used to infer the
anticompetitive effect
o If shown, the must prove the procompetitive justification and that this was the least restrictive means of
accomplishing that pro-competitive virtue
- Then Ct must balance effects – does anticompetitive effects outweigh procompetitive?
However, no reason to keep pro se and rule of reason separate b/c SCOTUS stated:
1. Even if a horizontal agmt literally constitutes price-fixing, an outright restraint or a boycott, it will not be deemed per se
illegal when a procompetitive justification in fact exists
2. Even if a restraint falls w/in rule of reason, it will condemned summarily as a naked restraint if not procompetitive
justification is offered
One way to think about the cases will be to keep in mind the distinction b/w horizontal agmts among unrelated firms and those among
firms that are in a productive business relationship (which seeks through joint efforts to produce some tangible product or service).
- When there is a productive joint venture, the pro-competitive justification may take a restraint out of the per se rules
- Unwilling to listen to unrelated horizontal businesses that restraints have a procompetitive justification
The distinctions between the pro and anti competitive agmts
- Courts have been less willing to condemn per se professional efforts to self-regulate through horizontal agmts that are not
ancillary to any productive business collaboration
Sherman Act § 2: “Every person who shall monopolize, or attempt to monopolize, or combine or conspire w/ any other person or
person, to monopolize any part of the trade or commerce among the several States, or w/ foregin nations, shall be deemed guilty of a
felony…”
- Agmts to form a corp’n that exercises monopoly power have long been held to constitute a violation of § 2
FTC Act § 5: “Unfair methods of competition in or affecting commerce . . . are hereby declared unlawful”
The earliest cases acknowledged that explicit agmts by competing firms to fix process are a primary concern of § 1
- The idea of price fixing is so abhorrent, there should not be a reasonableness standard for such agmts
- “Any combination or agmt between competititors formed for the purpose and w/ the effect of raising, depressing, fixing,
pegging or stabilizing the price of a commodity in interstate commerce is illegal per se.
2
ANTITRUST- LONGWELL- SPRING 2012 3
o Agmts which create such potential power may well be held to be in themselves unreasonable or unlawful restraints,
w/o the necessity to inquire about the reasonableness of a particular price
o Unreasonable restraints on trade such as price fixing are illegal regardless of the price fixed
1) The agmt is the most efficient way to protect the business of the s
3
ANTITRUST- LONGWELL- SPRING 2012 4
Horizontal price fixing case usually a per se violation, unless the s can come up w/ very strong procompetitive
justifications to get the court to employ the Rule of Reason analysis
- Such justifications include
o Only efficient way to control against copyright infringement
o Productive joint venture that is a single firm competing w/ other sellers in the mkt
Given any particular mkt demand curve, every output level implies a price and every price implies an output level
- Thus, horizontal agmts to restrict output below the competitive level are just the flip side of horizontal agmts to fix prices
- Indeed, a horizontal agmt on output production is generally necessary for any price-fixing agmt, otherwise members of the
cartel might increase production to greater mkt share at the cartel price, and, if left w/ unsold product, may be tempted to
undercut the mkt to unload it
- Cartels like OPEC do this all the time and focus on agmts to restrict rather than fix price
Thus, like price-fixing, horizontal agmts to restrict output are typically regarded as per se illegal
- However, like price fixing, the Ct has recognized circumstances where an agmt that literally restricts output should
nonetheless be characterized as falling outside the per se rule
When it is claimed that a certain degree of cooperation is essential for competition, the court may apply rule of reason
Any agmt (explicit or tacit) among businesses performing similar services or dealing in similar products whereby the available mkt is
divided up and each is given a share is illegal per se
- Such mkt divisions generally involve territorial divisions where each firm agrees to limit itself to a geographic area different
from the other firm
Consumers may also be divided in other ways, such as having one rival sell to commercial users and another to regular consumers, or
by having firms agree to restrict themselves to different products or lines of commerce
- Bid rigging is also a form of mkt division, where conspirators agree that only one of them will really bid for each particular
job
4
ANTITRUST- LONGWELL- SPRING 2012 5
US DOJ/PTC Guidelines for Collaborations Among Competitors (2000)
- Competitor collaboration: set of one or more agmts, other than merger agmts, b/w or among competitors to engage in
economic activity resulting therefrom
- Treat a competitor collaboration as a horizontal merger if:
o Participants are competitors in that relevant mkt
o Formation of the collaboration involves an efficiency-enhancing integration of economic activity in the relevant mkt
o The integration eliminates all competition among the participants in the relevant mkt
o Collaboration does not terminate w/in a sufficiently ltd period by its own specific & express terms
- Agmts Challenged as Per Se Illegal
o If participants in an efficiency enhancing integration of economic activity enter into an agmt that is reasonably
related to the integration and reasonably necessary to achieve its procompetitive benefits, the Agencies analyze the
agmt under the rule of reason, even if it is of a type that might otherwise be considered per se illegal
Was there facially a good reason for the collaboration?
Ct may do some sort of balancing
o Agmt may be reasonably necessary w/out being essential
Agencies consider whether practical, significantly less restrictive means were reasonably available when
the agmt was entered into, but do not search for a theoretically less restrictive alternative that was not
practical given the business realities
Undertake a limited factual inquiry to evaluate claim
- Identifying Procompetitive Benefits of the Collaboration
o If agencies conclude that the agmt has cx-d or is likely to cx anticompetitive harm, they consider whether the agmt is
reasonably necessary to achieve “Cognizable Efficiencies” = efficiencies that do not arise from anticompetitive
reductions in output or service, and cannot be achieved through practical, significantly less restrictive means
Cognizable efficiencies are assessed net of costs produced by the competitor collaboration or incurred in
achieving those efficiencies
- Safety Zone for Competitor Collaborations in General
o Absent extraordinary circumstances, the Agencies do not challenge a competitor collaboration when they account
for no more than 20% of the relevant mkt
o Safety zone does not apply to per se illegal agmts
These are known as “horizontal boycotts” and are considered to be per se illegal
- Not to protect competitors, just competition
Differ from other per se offenses such as fixing prices or output or dividing mkts
- 1. Boycotts are often aimed at harming particular competitors rather than competition in general
o But should it be condemned by antitrust law then?
- 2. More likely to have plausible noneconomic justifications, such as punishing particular bad actors
Productive collaborations not OK when denies open access to competitors in situation when open access is important. To
violate § 1, need to be able to tie restraint being challenged to productive collaboration.
If the agmt has the effect of being a group boycott, but there is enough procompetitive justification, the rule of reason analysis
will apply
A seeking application of per se rule must present a threshold case that the challenged activity falls into a category likely to
have predominantly anticompetitive effects.
In several cases, the defendants had engaged in horizontal conduct that restrained trade argued that certain social welfare benefits
justified the conduct, at least enough to move out of per se territory to rule of reason analysis
Quick Look Analysis: The difficulties wrt per se and rule of reason in these cases has lead the court to develop a “quick look”
analysis which requires a Ct to briefly examine the benefits of a horizontal agmt to determine if a full blown Rule of Reason analysis
should apply
2) s must respond by articulating a theoretically plausible claim that there exists a procompetitive justification for
which the restraint was reasonably necessary
a. If fails to do so, they lose summarily – per se (Trenton Potteries; Klors; Professional Engineers; Indiana Dentists;
Trial Lawyers)
b. If ’s can articulate a theoretically plausible procompetitive justification, then the treatment varies depending on
other factors:
i. If the restraint at issue is reasonably necessary to advance the procompetitive purposes of productive
business collaboration among those s (that is, the collaboration that actually has some business product),
then the court moves to step 3 – the full scale rule of reason analysis (BMI; Northwest Stationers; Dagher)
ii. If the restraint is not alleged to be reasonably necessary to advance the procompetitive purposes of any
productive business collaboration and is on price (or on a output level that would affect price), then the
procompetitive justification is inadmissible, and the agmt is condemned under the per se rule (Maricopa
County)
iii. For other restraints that are not reasonably necessary for any productive business collaboration, treatment
likely varies depending on whether the s are professionals that traditionally engage in mkt self-regulation
or are financially disinterested in the restraint
8
ANTITRUST- LONGWELL- SPRING 2012 9
1. Professionals apparently get rule of reason review for such self- regulation even when they have a
financial self-interest, at least when the regulation is directed at informational mkt defects, and
thus can get to step 3 by articulating a procompetitive justification for which the restraint is
reasonably necessary (California Dental)
2. Non professionals probably do not enjoy the same rule of reason review for self-regulation
unrelated to productive business collaborations, at least not if they are financially interested, and
instead the agmt is summarily condemned under the per se rule (Fashion Originators). But, they
may well enjoy a rule of reason review and be able to go onto step 3 when they are financially
disinterested in their restraint
3) If both sides have articulated theoretically plausible anti-and procompetitive effects in a way that triggers full-scale rule
of reason review, then the has the burden of producing empirical evidence of the anticompetitive effects under rule of
reason. (California Dental). Such anticompetitive effects can be shown by direct evidence or inferred from mkt power.
(Indiana Dentists). If the does prove anticompetitive effects, then the court moves to step 4
4) Given evidence of actual anticompetitive effects, the has the burden of producing empirical evidence to support the
claimed procompetitive effects and to show that less restrictive alternatives could not equally achieve those
procompetitive effects. (California Dental). If the does, then the court moves to step 5
5) In the final stage, the tribunal weighs the anticompetitive and procompetitive evidence to determine which is greater. The
has the burden of persuasion on whether the net effect is anticompetitive.
Less Restrictive Alternatives: The issue of whether a less restrictive alternative exists is often considered a separate step, but it can
be applied at steps 2 and 4 because it bears on whether theoretically or empirically the restraint was reasonably necessary to advance
the claimed procompetitive justification
- Step 2 should be used to consider theoretical arguments that the restraint is not reasonably necessary to advance the
procompetitive justification because a less restrictive alternative exists that could equally advance that justification. But,
often such arguments are controverted by theoretical arguments that the posited alternative was not feasible etc. Such a
theoretical relationship between the justification and the restraint to survive step 2
- Step 4 should be used to resolve such theoretical conflict w/ empirical evidence about whether the posited alternatives are in
fact, feasible, useful and less restrictive
There is an inherent tension between antitrust law and patent law because antitrust aims to protect competition and patents create
monopolies that aim to eliminate competition in order to reward invention
- May be seen that the procompetitive effects of protecting invention outweigh need for competition
US v. GE (SCOTUS 1926)
- GE licensed the right to make light bulbs under its patents to Westinghouse, limiting the prices and terms of conditions
Westinghouse could sell the product
- Issue: May the patentee, GE, limit the license to sell the light bulbs?
- Holding: Yes, provided the conditions of sale are normally and reasonably adapted to secure pecuniary reward for the
patentee’s monopoly
o Price at which a patented article sells is certainly a circumstance having a direct relation and is germane to the rights
of the patentee
o Not price fixing b/c this is a patent, which is basically immune from antitrust
o Ct does not want to pursue an antitrust law that would undercut the rights of patentees
However, the agmts may be held to be illegal when the move beyond what is protected by the patent monopoly
9
ANTITRUST- LONGWELL- SPRING 2012 10
- Holding: where license agmts are entered into w/ knowledge on the part of licensor and licensees of the adherence of others,
w/ control over prices and methods of distribution through the agmts is sufficient to establish a prima facie case of
conspiracy, violating Sherman Act
o Need to look at value of patent when evaluating whether price fixing is justified
o Cross licensing as a means of price control was barred in US v. Line Material as way of patent monopoly
Examine mkt relevant to the patent technology. If in fact all the manufacturers are practicing the patent and have placed a
significant value on the patent more likely court will apply GE rule
H. Buyer Cartels
If the agmt is: (1) Price fixing; (2) Output restriction; (3) Mkt division; and (4) Certain group boycotts, then the per se rule
applies
If the agmt is “inherently suspect” then the s must provide some procompetitive justification under the “quick look analysis”
All other agmts where the purpose or effect is unclear, then the Rule of Reason applies where the court will balance the harms
and benefits
Sherman Act § 2
- Every person who shall monopolize, or attempt to monopolize, or combine or conspire w/ any other person or persons, to
monopolize any part of the trade or commerce among several states or w/ foreign nations, shall be deemed guilty of a felony
To determine whether a has monopoly power, the π must first define the relevant mkt.
- Mkt definition will often determine the outcome of the case
- Cts tend to use alternative of inferring monopoly or mkt power from firm mkt shares, at least when coupled w/ evidence that
entry barriers to that mkt are relatively high
o will argue for a narrow mkt definition, which will make appear to be the dominant player in the mkt
o will argue for an expansive mkt which will make the share smaller and lead the court to conclude that the is not
a monopolist
- The relevant mkt is comprised of 2 parts: the relevant product mkt and the relevant geographic mkt
o Thus, to establish the first element the must show:
1) The relevant product mkt
2) Define the relevant geographic mkt
3) Prove the has monopoly power over that mkt
The relevant product mkt is largely determined by consumer preferences and the extent to which physically dissimilar products can
fulfill the same consumer need; i.e., what products are viewed as being reasonably interchangeable?
11
ANTITRUST- LONGWELL- SPRING 2012 12
Reasonable interchangeability for the purposes for which they are produced—price, use and
qualities considered – Test for deciding if in Same Mkt
o Cost of production is not relevant, profit margin is b/c a product facing very high profit margins may be a single
factor towards the determination of mkt power
- Dissent: does think that cellophane and other flexible wrapping materials are differ enough to constitute differ mkts
- Cellophane Fallacy: inferring a single product from substitution at current prices b/c really want to know what substitution
rates will be if prices were elevated from competitive levels
The general rule is that “commodities reasonably interchangeable by consumers for the same purposes make up the ‘part of
the trade or commerce,’ monopolization of which may be illegal”
12
ANTITRUST- LONGWELL- SPRING 2012 13
o Objective information about product characteristic and costs and delays of switching
products, especially switching to products outside the candidate mkt
o % of sales lost by one product in candidate mkt, when its price alone rises, that is
recapture by other products in candidate mkt, w/ a higher recapture % making a price
increase more profitable
o Evidence from other industry participants
o Legal or regulatory requirements
o Influence of downstream competition faced by customers in their output mkts
Also conduct critical loss analysis- asks whether imposing at least a SSNIP on one or more
products in a candidate market would raise or lower profits
o Critical loss is defined as the # of lost unit sales that would leave profits unchanged
o Predicted loss is defined as the # of unit sales that the hypothetical monopolist is
predicted to lose due to the price increase
o Price increase raises profits if predicted loss < critical loss
o Geographic Mkt Definition
Defined by supplier locations
Evidence for considering customer reaction to price increases in a geographic mkt:
o How customers have shift purchases in past b/w different locations
o Cost and difficulty of transporting the product in relation to its price
o Whether suppliers need a presence near customers to provide service and support
o Evidence on whether sellers base business decisions on the prospect of customers
switching b/w geographic locations in response to changes in price
o Costs and delays of switching from suppliers in candidate geographic mkt
o Influence of downstream competition faced by customers in their output mkts
Defined by location of consumers
- Market participants, market shares, and market concentration
o Mkt participants: all firms that currently earn revenues in the relevant mkt
o Mkt share and mkt concentration are based on historical evidence
o Mkt share is measured by its actual or projected revenues in the relevant mkt
The “act” or “conduct” referred to is that by which the alleged monopolist obtained and/or maintains a monopolistic position
Predatory Pricing
A violation may be found for predatory pricing, often defined as pricing below average or marginal cost. However, it is often difficult
to prove predatory conduct or distinguish it clearly from honestly industrial, competitive price cutting behavior. SCOTUS has made it
clear that charges of predatory pricing must make economic sense (i.e. the must produce evidence that a predatory pricing scheme
carries a reasonable chance of success at a reasonable cost to the ) for such charges to survive a ’s MSJ (see Matsushita v. Zenith).
13
ANTITRUST- LONGWELL- SPRING 2012 14
o Must demonstrate likelihood that the predatory scheme alleged would cause a rise in prices above a competitive
level that would be sufficient to compensate for the amounts expended on the predation, including the time value of
the money invested in it
o In other words, if competition in the relevant mkt is such that one party’s predatory pricing, even if it harms a rival,
can never put the D In a position to recover the profits lost by the scheme, then no violation of the laws has
occurred. “The laws protect competition, not individual competitors”
o Increase in price is not itself anticompetitive
Refusals to Deal
No general requirement for a monopoly power to cooperate with its rivals but exclusions by a monopolist that hamper rival
competition are exclusionary if they are not “competition on the merits” or “normal competition”
- Predatory if excluding on some basis other than superior efficiency
Essential Facilities
If a company possesses exclusive access to a facility that is “essential to competition and that it could feasibly share, the company may
be required to provide access to that facility on a reasonable, nondiscriminatory basis – even to its competitors
- The 4 elements necessary to establish liability under the essential facilities are:
1) Control of the essential facility by a monopolist;
2) A competitor’s inability practically or reasonably to duplicate the essential facility;
3) The denial of the use of the facility to a competitor; and
4) The feasibility of providing the facility
Price Squeezing
A price squeeze can exist when a firm sells the inputs (in what is sometimes called an upstream mkt) and also sells the finished
product (in the so-called downstream mkt) that uses that input and the firm prices the inputs high but the finished product low to
defeat competitors who can no longer make a profit
Predatory Bidding
Predatory bidding describes a situation in which an alleged monopolist outbids its potential competitors for a necessary input by
overpaying in order to deny the competitors access to that input
- While such overpayment may cause the monopolist short-term losses, it may result in long-term profits if the firm can
exercise “monopsony” power (mkt power on the buyer side) after it becomes the only buyer left in the mkt. The monopolist
may also be able to charged monopoly prices after rivals are forced out
B. Attempts to Monopolize
An attempt to monopolize requires a specific intent to exclude competitors and gain monopoly power.
- Specific Intent may be inferred from conduct
Because of the intent to monopolize, the must be seeking monopoly power through means other than “business acumen”; i.e. the
must be using “unfair means”
An attempt to monopolize is the “employment of methods, means and practices which would, if successful, accomplish
monopolization, and which, though falling short, nevertheless approaches so close as to create a dangerous probability of it.”
16
ANTITRUST- LONGWELL- SPRING 2012 17
o Where acts are not sufficient in themselves to produce a result which the law seeks to prevent but require further acs
in addition ot the mere forces of nature to bring that result to pass, an intent to bring it to pass is necessary in order
to produce a dangerous probability that it will happen
o Elements:
Anticompetitive conduct
Specific intent to monopolize
Dangerous probability of achieving monopoly power
B. Exclusive Dealing
A buyer may agree to handle only the seller’s products and not those of a competitor
- Often, take the form of a buyer’s agmt to purchase “requirements” exclusively from the seller
- To a certain extent, the effect is similar to tying arrangements
- Exclusive dealing may be treated under either § 1 of the Sherman Act OR § 3 of the Clayton Act (if it involves sale of goods)
- Concerned that such agmts might foreclose enough of the mkt to rival competition to impair competition
- Where network effects exist –meaning one seller’s product is more valuable to buyers the more that other buyers have
purchased the same good from that seller—foreclosure can impair rival efficiency by denying rivals access to the # of buyers
they need to make their products more valuable to all buyers
- May encourage relation-specific investment, increasing efficiency only as to one buyer and seller
Clayton Act § 3
- Provides it shall be unlawful for any person … to lease or make a sale … of goods …, whether patented or unpatented, … or
fix a price charged therefore, or discount from, or rebate upon, such price, on the condition, agmt, or understanding that the
lessee or purchaser thereof shall not use or deal in the goods … of a competitor or competitors of the lessor or seller, where
the effect … may be to substantially lessen competition or tend to create a monopoly in any line of commerce
- Two elements:
o (1) sales or discounts of goods that conditioned on the purchaser not dealing w/ rivals
o (2) proof that their effect may be to substantially lessen competition
17
ANTITRUST- LONGWELL- SPRING 2012 18
- Holding: a man w/ monopoly of theatres in any one town commands the entrance for all firms into that areas and if he uses
that strategic position to acquire exclusive privileges in a city where has had competitors, he is employing his monopoly
power as a trade weapon against his competitors – he was here by linked his closed town theatres w/ his competitive ones
o Not always necessary to find a specific intent to restrain trade or to build a monopoly in order to find that the anti-
trust laws have been violated, but sufficient that a restraint of trade resuls as the consequence of a ’s conduct or
business arrangements
To show a violation of § 3 of the Clayton Act, there must be proof that competition has been foreclosed in a substantial share
of the line of commerce affected
In an exclusive dealing case under Sherman Act § 1 and FTC Act § 5, the foreclosure share should be measured by
aggregating the foreclosure produced by the leading sellers, i.e, adding the total % of the mkt of the main competitors
- Foreclosure can anticompetitively affect the ID of firms in the mkt as well as the # of them
- Even if not simply aggregated, the anticompetitive effect of one firm’s exclusionary agmts can depend on whether other firms
have similar exclusionary agmts
18
ANTITRUST- LONGWELL- SPRING 2012 19
Qualitative Substantiality Test
Later, the Court suggested a second test that focuses on the size of the mkt share foreclosed by the K
Exclusive dealing arrangements are evaluated today under the rule of reason
Factors to consider include:
- Duration of the exclusive arrangement
- Whether the arrangement is terminable on short notice
- Percentage of the mkt foreclosed
- Alternative sources or distribution channels
- Anticompetitive effects
- Presence of legitimate business justifications for the exclusive dealing arrangement
There is no fixed number as to the substantial effect, but exclusive contracts that make it difficult for a rival to gain wider distribution
will be suspect and require strong procompetitive justifications.
C. Tying Arrangements
Introduction
Under a tying arrangement, the seller refuses to sell product A (the “tying” product) to a customer unless the customer also agrees to
buy product B (the “tied” product) from the seller
- The seller is thus said to “tie” or condition the sale of the desired “tying” product to the purchase of the “tied” product
o Buyers are thus “coerced” and suppliers “foreclosed”
Although limited exceptions are recognized (see the “new industry” and “quality control” defenses), the oft-repeated rule is that tying
arrangements are illegal per se, when the prerequisites of separate products, coercion or force, mkt power, and a more than de minimis
amount of commerce are established
- Note, while courts use the term “illegal per se” to describe tying arrangements, the per se rule in this context is not the
same as it is in the context of horizontal price fixing agmts
- In tying cases, the Courts require a detailed inquiry into mkt definition and the existence of mkt power, something they
do not do in other “per se” cases
Per Se condemnation is only appropriate if the existence of forcing is probable. Thus, application of the per se rule focuses on
the probability of anticompetitive consequences
- As a threshold matter there must be a substantial potential for impact on competition in order to justify per se
condemnation
21
ANTITRUST- LONGWELL- SPRING 2012 22
- Holding: some consumers would prefer to buy just parts or just service, so policy of tying does not almost always
enhance competition
- Scalia, dissenting: says ct has only use per se rule when the seller has a special ability to force a purchaser to do
something— does not understand why a seller’s inherent control over the unique parts for its own brand amounts to mkt
power of a character sufficient to permit invocation of the per se rule against tying
o Would evaluate tying arrangement between after mkt products – parts and service—under rule of reason
To determine whether 2 products are in fact separate for tying purposes, courts do not focus “on the functional relation between them,
but rather on the character of demand for the 2 items”
- There must be sufficient demand for the 2 products for firms to provide them separately
Although this is not usually a problem there are cases where a may credibly argue the product is a single one
- Note that in the context of technological integration, it is sometimes difficult to determine whether there are separate
products.
o If the integration of 2 formerly separate products creates a more efficient new product, the integration may not
constitute tying (US v. MS)
Conditioning or Coercion
Courts have split on what type of proof is required to establish that the conditioned sale of the tying product on the buyer’s agreeing
to purchase the tied product as well
- Some courts hold that a written K containing the condition is sufficient i.e. United Shoe
The conditioning or coercion element is probably satisfied if the bundled products are priced so that purchase of the products
individually is not economically viable
Mkt Power
Early cases
Proof of dominance in the tying product mkt was what was necessary in early cases
- Examples include the patented salt machines to which were tied the purchase of salt (International Salt)
- However, SCOTUS has since reversed its International Salt decision in Illinois Tool Works
o Now, an antitrust must specifically prove that the possesses mkt power in the tying product mkt, even if the
’s product is protected by IP rights
Modern Trend
SCOTUS has subtly shifted the mkt power inquiry
- The court emphasizes the power of ’s to force consumers to make choices they would not make in a competitive
environment
- This test stresses the ability of the s to influence decision making in the mkt for the tied product. Jefferson Parish
Hospital (mkt power not sufficient because 70% of people in mkt go to other hospitals)
Proving more than an insubstantial amount of commerce involved
22
ANTITRUST- LONGWELL- SPRING 2012 23
The must show that more than an insubstantial amount of commerce is involved. This can be done by showing more than a de
minimis volume is involved
- For example, foreclosure of $500k in salt was sufficient commerce in International Salt
The concern w/ vertical distributional agmts is generally that price or nonprice competition among the downstream dealers might be
lessened
The concern w/ vertical conduct like secondary-line price discrimination is that supplying some input at different prices to different
downstream firms might provide the firm getting the input at the lower price w/ an unfair competitive advantage in the downstream
mkt
A vertical minimum price-fixing agmt is an agmt between a manufacturer and dealer that fixes the minimum prices at which the dealer
can resell the manufacturer’s brand.
23
ANTITRUST- LONGWELL- SPRING 2012 24
- A vertical nonprice agmt restrains distribution of a manufacturer’s brand in some way other than price, usually by limiting
where or to whom the dealer can resell that brand
The most important type of vertical nonprice agmts are those that limit to whom a dealer can resell the manufacturer’s product
- Sometimes these take the form of vertical territorial restraints, limiting dealers to a particular geographic area
- Such contracts are subject to the Rule of Reason analysis
The court will apply rule of reason analysis to intrabrand restrictions on distributers as there are too many economic
justifications to say that it is per se illegal
- Vertical maximum price-fixing cannot further the reduction of free riding in dealer services.
- It directly reflects the manufacturer’s procompetitive interest in minimizing the retail profit margin
- The vertical agmts fixing maximum prices also don’t raise the same anticompetitive concerns as agmts that set minimum
prices because they can’t induce dealers to engage in brand pushing and are unlikely to reflect dealer mkt power or to help
facilitate oligopolistic coordination by manufacturers
It used to be a per se violation of § 1 for a seller (e.g., a manufacturer) contractually to set the minimum price at which the buyer (e.g.
a retailer) can resell the product
1) Per Se rules are very important, but are a very powerful weapon. Ct has a duty to reevaluate these as economic evidence becomes
available that calls them into question
2) Economic evidence for these vertical agmts has shown that there are enough procompetitive justifications to warrant the application
of a rule of reason analysis as opposed to the per se analysis
Applying the rule of reason analysis to Retail Price Maintenance, courts should consider:
1) The number of manufacturers using the practice (“when only a few manufacturers lacking mkt power adopt the practice,
there is little likelihood it is facilitating a manufacturer cartel, for a cartel then can be undercut by rival manufacturers”)
2) The restraint’s source (“if retailers are the source, “there is a greater likelihood that the restraint facilitates a retailer cartel or
supports a dominant inefficient retailer”); and
3) The manufacturer’s mkt power (“if a retailer lacks mkt power, manufacturers likely can sell their goods through rival
retailers”)
Vertical Agmts to Boycott the Rival of a Dealer w/o any Procompetitive Justification
“Conscious parallelism” is the process by which firms in a concentrate mkt might in effect share monopoly power, setting their prices
at a profit maximizing, supracompetitive level by recognizing their shared economic interests (Brooke Group)
- Mere conscious parallelism is not sufficient – the crucial question is whether respondents’ conduct … stemmed from
independent decision or from an agmt, tacit or express. To be sure, business behavior is admissible circumstantial
evidence from which the fact finder may infer agmt
o The Ct has never held that proof of parallel business behavior conclusively establishes agmt or, phrased differently,
that such behavior itself constitutes a Sherman Act Offense
A conspiracy cannot exist between a corporation and its wholly owned subsidiary under § 1 of the Sherman Act
26
ANTITRUST- LONGWELL- SPRING 2012 27
- Holding: the relevant inquiry for a §1 violation is whether there is a “K, combination, or conspiracy” amongst “separate
economic actors pursuing separate economic interests” such that the agmt “deprives the mktplace of independent centers of
decisionmaking,” and therefore “diversity of entrepreneurial interests,” and this of actual or potential competition; NFL’s
licensing activities constituted a concerted action to be judged under the Rule of Reason
o Inquiry is whether the agmt joins together “independent centers of decision making”
If it does, the entities are capable of conspiring under § 1, and the court must decide whether the
restraint of trade is an unreasonable and therefore illegal one
Function of the agmt, not form
o The NFL teams do not possess either the unitary decision-making quality or the single aggregation of economic
power characteristic of independent action
Each of the teams is a substantial, independently owned & independently managed business
There must be evidence that tends to exclude the possibility of independent action by the manufacturer and distributor. That
is, there must be direct or circumstantial evidence that reasonably tends to prove that manufacturer and others had a
conscious commitment to a common scheme designed to achieve an unlawful objective
A § 1 must present evidence that tends to exclude the possibility that the alleged conspiracy acted independently
27
ANTITRUST- LONGWELL- SPRING 2012 28
United States v. United States Gypsum (SCOTUS 1978)
- 9 to 15 producers of gypsum in 60s
- 8 largest make up 94% of the mkt; 7 single plant producers make up the rest
- Gypsum Ass’n is trade ass’n of gypsum bd manufacturers
- Bd manufacturers would telephone producers for price verifications
- Issue: whether verification of price concessions w/ competitors for sole purpose of defense of “meeting competition” should
mean no § 1 liability?
- Holding: a good faith belief is sufficient – but need to do close scrutiny under Sherman Act to ensure it is w/in Robinson-
Patman Act compliance
o § 2(b) does not require the seller to justify price discrimination by showing he met a competitor’s price but that price
was made in good faith to meet a competitor’s – must investigate or verify the reliability of informants of a § 2(b)
defense
Howard Hess Dental Laboratories Inc. v. Dentsply Int’l, Inc. (3d Cir. 2010)
- Two dental labs—Hess and Jersey Dental, bring suit against manufacturer or artificial teeth for making deals with Dealers to
not carry certain competing brands of teeth in the form of an exclusive agmt
- DOJ already got an injunction against Dentsply for its anticompetitive acts
- Issue: were the s injured if Dentsply’s direct competitors were injured and DOJ got an injunction against it already?
- Holding: nothing says that a is relieved of its evidentiary burden of showing an entitlement to injunctive relive when the
gov’t has already obtained its own injunction
Merger – Procedure
T Mobile/ATT Merger
- Two cases: DOJ and Sprint’s Private Action
- Clayton Act § 7, 15 USC § 18
No person shall acquire the whole of any part of the assets of another person where in any line of commerce or in any section
of the country, the effect of such acquisition may be substantially to lessen competition, or to tend to create a monopoly
- Regular Rule of Reason analysis applies
- Mergers are a special review area under the law
- HSR Act- gov’t must examine a merger at the outset before it is consummated
- Review of mergers delegated to DOJ and FTC
o Up to the proponents of a merger to convince that it is a good idea
o Review of the relevant mkt as a whole or so-called oligopoly effects (what will the rest of the mkt look like after the
merger)
o Will the merger be so concentrated that the merger will actually facilitate oligopoly type behavior
o Individual effects
o Coordinated effects
o Mitigating circumstances
New entry and entry barriers or lack thereof b/c of continual entry of new competitors
- Horizontal merger – concentration of mkt is very important
o To determine concentration: take A, B, C, and D and square mkt shares. The most you can have is 10,000 because
100 squared is that meaning that there would be 4 participants but there is a monopolist that has SOLE mkt share
- Analysis is under § 1 but always is challenged under § 7 of Clayton Act
Chronology:
Mar 20: AT&T announce acquisition intentions: to acquire from DT AG all issued and outstanding shares of T-Mobile, for approx..
39billion. Said would bring in customers, expand US mobile broadband infrastructure. Expect to close in a year.
Mar 28: Sprint announces formal opposition to merger
Mar 31: AT&T files notice of transaction under H-S-R w/ DOJ
Apr 21: AT&T files Application and description of public interest w/ FCC
Apr 28: Commission sought comment on proposed transaction
Aug 11: AT&T leaked internal document, where it states that AT&T could expand LTE coverage/upgrade for $3.8 billion, which was
less than the cost of the proposed merger
Aug 26: FCC restarts 180 day period (at day 83) in which it makes it decision
Aug 31: DOJ files complaint
Sept 6: Sprint files complaint
28
ANTITRUST- LONGWELL- SPRING 2012 29
Sept 20: C-Spire wireless files complaint (later consolidated w/ Sprint’s)
Sept 30: DOJ files 2d Amended complaint; AT& T files MTD to Sprint’s complaint
Nov 2: Judge Huvelle issues memo opinion on AT&T’s MTD in Sprint case
Nov 21: Verizon states company has no objection to merger
Nov 22: FCC calls for administrative hearing: said was not in the public interest; AT&T would have to defend itself against that
finding. Suggestion that AT&T might divest as much as 40% of T-Mobile’s assets.
Nov 24: AT&T asks to withdraw merger proposal from FCC – to avoid hearing
Nov 30: FCC allows AT&T to withdraw merger proposal; FCC releases its report about how merger would harm public interest
Dec 12: DOJ and AT&T file Jt Motion to Stay – not clear that no deal could never happen
Dec 13: spring, C-Spire & AT&T file Jt Motion to Stay
Dec 19: AT&T formally announced it was ending its pursuit to acquire T-Mobile
29