Theoretical Perspectives On Policy Analysis
Theoretical Perspectives On Policy Analysis
Theoretical Perspectives On Policy Analysis
Theoretical perspectives on
policy analysis
The main disciplines that can be observed within the different schools
define themselves in accordance with the theoretical and normative
perspectives, on which the positions of the different authors are based
and/or towards which they tend. Thus, after Mény and Thoenig (1989)
and Muller (1990, p 3), it is possible to identify three major currents
in policy analysis that reflect different aims without, however, being
mutually exclusive. These currents differ mainly in terms of their focuses
on specific fields of analysis.
Thus, we make distinctions between a first school of thought that
associates policy analysis and the theory of state, a second that explains
the way in which public action works and, finally, a third that focuses
on the evaluation of the results and effects of the latter.
3
Public policy analysis
and lays claim to, in France in particular, attempts to link the policy
approach with political philosophy and major questions concerning
the theory of state. Thus, Mény and Thoenig (1989) define their
approach in terms of a contribution to questions concerning ‘the
emergence and nature of the state’ or to ‘the essence of politics’.
Similarly, Jobert and Muller locate their work on The state in action
(L’etat en action) in the context of “bridging the gap that today still
separates research on policies and the more general reflections on the
state in contemporary society” (Jobert and Muller 1987, p 9). It is
subdivided into different approaches that Mény and Thoenig (1989,
p 67) classify on the basis of three ‘theoretical models’:
The first model is part of a pluralist approach that conceives the
state as a ‘service hatch’ whose purpose is to respond to social
demands. From this perspective, public policies are conceived as
responses to social demands and their analysis is in turn located
in a perspective based on the optimisation of collective choices,
the rationality of the decision-making processes and the behaviour
of ‘bureaucrats’ (‘public choice’ school2, theory of limited
rationality3). According to this concept, the lack of policies in
the area of sport, for example, is a reflection of the fact that there
is no public problem to be resolved. However, this absence could
also be interpreted as the result of corporate or private actions
that are aimed at controlling this sector despite the existence of
significant public problems (in particular drug use, corruption
etc).
The second interpretative model places the emphasis on the
state as an instrument at the service of either a social class (neo-
Marxist approach4) or specific groups (neo-managerial approach5).
In this context, the analysis of public action makes it possible to
demonstrate the weak autonomy of the state with respect to
capitalist interests and/or with respect to the private actors and
organisations of which it consists. Seen in this way, a social
problem can only become a public problem if its resolution serves
the interests of the (economically) dominant classes. The neomanagerial
approach starts from a similar standpoint in that it
replaces the class concept with the concept of elites.
Finally, the third model stresses the distribution of power and
interaction among and between actors, either through the
representation and organisation of different sector-based or
category-based interests (neo-corporatist6 approach), or through
the organisations and institutional rules that frame these
4
Theoretical perspectives on policy analysis
The second school aims to explain the way public action works. Thus,
in this context, the function of policy analysis is not to explain the
general functioning of the political system but to act as a way of
understanding the operational modes and logic of public action (see
5
Public policy analysis
Dente, 1985, 1989; Dente and Fareri, 1993; Gomà and Subirats, 1998,
pp 21-36).
This approach does not exclude the adoption of a viewpoint based
on the above-presented theories, which explains why several authors
from this second group actually have a foot in both camps. Here,
however, the focus is not on the justification of a theory, but on the
demonstration of continuities, general rules of functioning that are
specific to public actions. In this context, policy analysis makes it
possible to understand how the state and, more broadly, public
authorities work.
This second approach actually constitutes the initial set of issues
tackled by policy analysts. Historically, the latter were strongly
influenced by North American political scientists, whose initial
considerations in this area emerged between 1950 and 1960 and were
linked with a context of the ‘rationalisation’ of public decision making
with a view to improving its efficacy. Lerner and Lasswell published
The policy sciences in the United States as early as 1951, thereby laying
the foundations for this approach.
However, this “unified approach to the study of public problems
and policy ... soon settled into two main approaches” (Parsons, 1995,
pp 18-19), one that endeavours to develop a better knowledge of the
policy formation and implementation processes (the analysis of policy),
while the other concentrates on developing knowledge that is usable
in and for the policy formation and implementation processes (analysis
in and for policy). It should be stressed, however, that the analyses
carried out by one school feed into the experiences of the other, and
vice versa. Thus, in their critique of this approach, Mény and Thoenig
(1989, p 65) make a distinction between the function of the scientist
who is interested in the progress of knowledge and learning and that
of the professional whose aim is to apply the sciences for the purpose
of action.
The second approach adopts its theoretical thrust from several
different scientific approaches: administrative science, the sciences of
complexity (particularly systems analysis), the sociology of (public)
decision making and, more generally, the sociology of collective action,
the economic sciences and the information sciences.
The emergence of this approach was dominated by four major figures
(Mény and Thoenig, 1989; Parsons, 1995). The first is the North
American political scientist Lasswell (1951) who was the movement’s
main source of inspiration and who adopted a completely ‘managerial’
approach: his work deliberately attempted to construct a dialogue
between social scientific researchers, economic circles and public
6
Theoretical perspectives on policy analysis
7
Public policy analysis
8
Theoretical perspectives on policy analysis
9
Public policy analysis
10
Theoretical perspectives on policy analysis
Rather than fitting perfectly within the framework of one of the abovedescribed
schools, our analysis borrows from all three. It is our ambition
to establish a diagnostic approach that demonstrates the factors that
explain the ‘good’ and ‘bad’ functioning of public policies in terms of
public administration production and with respect to the efficacy of
its policies and their products. This type of analysis ultimately leads to
describing, understanding and explaining the workings of the politicaladministrative
system as a whole and its interactions with private actors.
Thus, our approach is mainly based on the explanation of the products
or services provided by public administration that are traditionally
referred to as ‘outputs’, and on the explanation of the effects produced
by these services on social groups (‘impacts and outcomes’) that cause
and/or are affected by a particular collective problem.
To the extent that it aims to understand the ‘logic’ of public actions
by reconstructing the hypotheses on which public authorities
(sometimes implicitly) base their thinking for the resolution of public
problems, our intellectual reasoning belongs within the framework of
the action sciences.
More precisely, the majority of the concepts presented here are
derived from the publications of the Centre de Sociologie des Organisations
(Crozier, 1963, 1991; Crozier and Friedberg, 1977; Friedberg, 1993)
as well as the work of the German social and political scientists of the
1970s (that is, the Frankfurt School), who, in turn, were strongly
influenced by neo-Marxism (Offe, 1972; Habermas, 1973; Grottian,
1974). However, this influence is limited to the individual heuristic
contributions that are particularly well developed by these authors.
This enables us to identify the actors, their networks and their modes
of interaction. As opposed to the ‘systemic forces’ often favoured by
these authors, in our approach, the retraceable strategies, ideas, interests
and actor behaviour essentially depend on factors connected to their
resources and their ‘institutional framework’ and must all be observed
empirically. In this sense, our reasoning strongly resembles actor-centred
institutionalism as presented by Scharpf (1997).
The concept of public policy adopted here (as well as most of the
definitions and terms used in this book) originate in part from the
work carried out in Germany by the Forschungsverbund: Implementation
politischer Programme at the Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft between 1976
and 1981 under the direction of Mayntz, Scharpf, Kaufmann and
Wollmann14; one of the authors of this book was associated with this
work. It is also based on texts on the implementation of public policy15.
11
Public policy analysis
12
Theoretical perspectives on policy analysis
13
Public policy analysis
take the trouble to use the concepts in accordance with the basic
dimensions proposed with respect to their empirical field testing.
Notes
1 This analysis is adopted in part from that presented in the work Analyser les
politiques publiques d’environnement (Larrue, 2000).
2 The ‘public choice’ school is based on the work of Buchanan and Tullock
(1962). A critical review of the main principles of this school can be found in
Self (1993).
6 For France, see, in particular, the work of Jobert and Muller (1987) and, for
Germany, that of Lehmbruch and Schmitter (1982).
7 See, in particular, the work of March and Olsen (1984) and our own approach
(Chapter Five, this volume).
8 See Jordan and Richardson (1987); Marsh and Rhodes (1992); Smith (1993).
14
Theoretical perspectives on policy analysis
13 See Davies et al (2000) and the emergence in 2005 of the journal Evidence &
Policy (see https://www.policypress.org.uk/journals/evidence_policy/).
14 See Mayntz (1980, 1983).
15