Lesson: 9.0 Aims and Objectives
Lesson: 9.0 Aims and Objectives
Lesson: 9.0 Aims and Objectives
9
PERFECT COMPETITION
CONTENTS
9.0 Aims and Objectives
9.1 Introduction
9.2 Meaning of Perfect Competition
9.3 Features of Perfect Competition
9.3.1 Large Numbers of Sellers and Buyers
9.3.2 Product Homogeneity
9.3.3 Free Entry and Exit of Firms
9.3.4 Profit maximization
9.3.5 No Government Regulation
9.3.6 Perfect Mobility of Factors of Production
9.3.7 Perfect Knowledge
9.4 Short-run Analysis of a Perfectly Competitive Firm
9.5 Long-run Analysis of a Perfectly Competitive Firm
9.6 Let us sum up
9.7 Lesson-end Activity
9.8 Keywords
9.9 Questions for Discussion
9.10 Model Answer to “Check Your Progress”
9.11 Suggested Readings
9.1 INTRODUCTION
Perfect competition is said to prevail where there is a large number firms producing a
homogeneous product. Competition is perfect in the sense that every firm considers that
it can sell any amount of output it wishes at the prevailing market price, which cannot be
affected by the individual producer whose share in the market is very small. With many
firms and homogenous product under perfect competition, no individual firm is in a portion
Managerial Economics to influence the price of the product and therefore the demand curve facing it will be a
horizontal straight line at this level of the prevailing price.
P P = AR = MR
Market
O X
Q Output
Figure 9.1
Equation (C) indicates that in order to maximise profits, a firm must produce where
marginal revenue (MR) equals marginal cost (MC). Since for a perfectly competitive
firm P is constant and TR = (P) . (Q) so that
d(TR)
dQ
= MR = P
the first order condition for profit maximisation for a perfectly competitive firm becomes
P = MR = MC.
The second order condition for profit maximization requires that the second derivative of
p with respect to Q be negative. That is,
dp d(TR) d(TC)
dQ = dQ – dQ < 0 (D)
so that, d(TR) d(TC)
dQ dQ
< (E)
According to equation (E) the algebraic value of the slope of the MC function must be
greater than the algebraic value of the MR function. Under perfect competition, MR is
constant (MR curve is horizontal). So that equation (E) requires that the MC curve be
rising at the point where MR=MC for the firm to maximise its total profits.
The top panel of Figure 9.2 indicates d is the demand curve for the output of the perfectly
competitive firm. The marginal cost curve cuts the SATC at its minimum point. The firm
is in equilibrium (maximizes its profits) at the level of output defined by the intersection
of the MC and the MR curves (point e in Figure 9.5). To the left of e profit has not
reached its maximum level because each unit of output to the left of Xe brings a revenue,
greater than its marginal cost. To the right of Xe each additional unit of output costs more
than the revenue earned by its sale so that a loss is made and total profit is reduced.
SMC
P SATC
A
B
Q
O Xe Output
Figure 9.2
The fact that a firm is in short-run equilibrium does not necessarily mean that it makes
excess profits. Whether the firm makes excess profits or losses depends on the level of
the ATC at the short-run equilibrium. If the ATC is below the price at equilibrium (Figure 9.3)
the firm earns excess profits (equal to the area PABe). If, however, the ATC is above the
price (Figure 9.4) the firm makes a loss (equal to the area FPeC). In the latter case the
firm will continue to produce only if it covers its variable costs. Otherwise it will close
130
down, since by discontinuing its operations the firm is better off: it minimizes its losses. Perfect Competition
The point at which the firm covers its variable costs is called “the closing down point.”
In Figure 9.5 the closing down point of the firm is denoted by point w. If price falls below
Pw the firm does not cover its variable costs and is better off if it closes down.
P SMC P SMC
SATC SATC
Price
&
Price &
Cost Cost
P e F C
d=P=MR
A P e d=P=MR
B
Q Q
O Xe Output O Xe Output
P SMC SATC
AFC SAVC
Price &
Cost
pw AFC
W
Q
O XW Output
Figure 9.5
P1
D E
O Q Q1 Q O Q
Figure 9.6
The condition for the long-run equilibrium of the firm is that the marginal cost be equal to
the price and to the long-run average cost.
LMC=LAC=P
At equilibrium the short-run marginal cost is equal to the long-run marginal cost and the
short-run average cost is equal to the long-run average cost. Thus, given the above
equilibrium condition, we have,
SMC=LMC=LAC=SAC=P=MR
This implies that at the minimum point of the LAC the corresponding (short-run) plant is
worked at its optimal capacity so that minima of LAC and SAC coincide. On the other
hand, the LMC cuts the LAC at its minimum point and the SMC cuts the SAC at its
minimum point.
9.8 KEYWORDS
Pure Competition
132
Normal Profit Perfect Competition
Supernormal Profit
Free Entry and exit
Break even point
Shut down point
MC SAC
D
Price and Cost
P MR = AR
E
O Qe
Quantity
133