Notes EAP Option PDF
Notes EAP Option PDF
Notes EAP Option PDF
The following was written for the master-level class I taught at MIT Sloan a few years
ago. If time permits, I’ll revise the content to make it more suitable for a PhD level class.
1 Options, an Overview
• Why Options? The development of options as an exchange-traded product was an
important landmark in the practice of Finance. It offers investors an alternate way to
buy and sell the risk inherent in the underlying stock. In the language developed later,
it offers non-linear exposures to the underlying stock or index. This non-linearity cuts
the entire distribution of stock returns into various pieces.
After the 2008 crisis, people sneered at the Wall Street practices such as tranching
and repackaging. I think this is very unfortunate. A small fraction of Wall Street
clearly mis-used and abused derivatives and contributed to the financial crisis in 2008.
Looking back into the history of financial innovation, this was not the first time, nor
will it be the last.
Finance is about optimal allocation of risk: match the right kind of risk to the right
kind of investors and distribute the right kind of investment to the right kind of firms
or entrepreneurs. If we think of this distributional effort as a network of pipelines,
then financial markets on equity, bond, foreign exchange, and commodity offer the
basic infrastructure. The limited flexibility of these markets gave rise to derivatives.
Options are a very good example. When we invest in the stock market, we have to
take the whole package: the entire distribution of the stock. In our earlier classes,
we talked about how we can minimize our exposure to idiosyncratic risk by forming
portfolios and how we can take out the market risk by long/short strategies. The
motivation behind options is the same. What if we are interested in hedging out not
the entire market risk, but only a specific portion of the market risk, say the left tail?
The long/short strategy will not help us do that: you are either all in or all out. But
buying a put option on the S&P 500 index will achieve this goal for you. Now the
question is how much are you willing to pay for this product? This is option pricing.
1
Figure 1: The distribution of a stock plotted against the payoff function of call and put
options with varying strike prices.
2
Let me expand on this example further. As illustrated in Figure 1, moving the strike
price of a call option from left to right with increasing strike prices, we are making
the call option more and more out of the money. At the same time, this call option
becomes more and more sensitive to the right tail of the distribution. Likewise, moving
the strike price of a put option from right to left with decreasing strike prices, we are
making the put option more and more out of the money. At the same time, this put
option becomes more and more sensitive to the left tail of the distribution. Effectively,
the market’s valuations of such OTM call and put options provide us information about
the right and left tails. As we learned early, the left and right tails are not abstract
concepts. They are made of extreme financial events: crises show up on the left tail
and rallies add to the right tail.
This is as if we are given a high definition camera with a super strong zooming ability.
We can point our camera to the right tail and zoom into that area using an OTM call
option. Likewise, an OTM put option allows us to zoom into the left tail. If you a
photographer, you would be overjoyed to own such a high-definition camera. Likewise,
if you are in the business of risk, you would naturally be drawn to these new financial
instruments.
3
• Trading Volume and Market Size: To gauge the activity of a market, the most
frequently used measure is trading volume. For the U.S. equity market, the exchange-
listed stocks are traded on 11 stock exchanges (“lit” markets) and about 45 alternative
trading systems (“dark pools”). According to summary data from BATS, for the month
of September 2015, the average daily trading in the stock market is 7.92 billion shares
and $321 billion (dollar volume). For the same month, the overall daily trading volume
in the options market is about 16.94 million contracts and $6.30 billion (dollar volume).
As you can see, in terms of trading volume, the options market is small compared with
its underlying stock market.
In comparing the trading volumes in the stock and options markets, one interesting
observation is that, after the 2008 crisis, the trading in the stock market has been
badly hurt. For example, the average NYSE group trading volume peaked around 2.6
billion shares per day in 2008 and has decreased quite dramatically to a level near 1.0
billion shares per day in 2013 and 2014. This is not an NYSE specific problem. The
overall stock market trading peaked in 2009 around 9.76 billion shares per day and
bottomed to 6.19 billion shares in 2013. By contrast, the trading volume in options
did not suffer this dramatic reduction. The average daily trading volume was around
14 million contracts in 2008, increased to 18 million contracts in 2011, and held up
steady at around 16 million contracts in 2013.
In terms of size, the U.S. equity market has a total market value of $26 trillion by
end-2014. At the end of September 2015, the open interest for equity and ETF options
is 292 million contracts, and 23.7 million contracts for index options. Given that the
average premium is around $200 for equity and ETF options and $1,575 for index
options, this open interest amounts to $95.7 billion in total market value. Again, the
options market is small compared to its underlying stock market.
• Leverage in Options: Although the options market is small compared to the un-
derlying stock market, the risk in this market is anything but small. Because of the
non-linearity, the leverage inherent in options could be large. Given an investment of
the same dollar amount, the profit and loss in options could be many times larger than
those in the underlying stocks.
For example, let’s consider a one-month at-the-money put option. Using the Black-
Scholes pricing formula, Figure 2 plots the returns to this option as a function of the
underlying stock returns, assuming the stock return volatility is 20% per year. As
we can see from the plot, for a 10% drop in the underlying stock price, the option
yields a return over 300%. So the inherent leverage in options amplifies a dollar’s
4
Figure 2: The return of an at-the-money put option plotted against the underlying stock
return
• Types of Options: Broadly speaking, there are three types of exchange-traded op-
tions: equity, ETF, and index options. Equity options are American-style call and put
options on individual stocks. One contract is on 100 underlying shares and the option
settles by physical delivery. This CBOE link gives the exact specifications of equity
options. Using the September 2015 numbers as an example, the average daily trading
volume for equity options is around 7.57 million contracts and $1.58 billion per day in
dollar trading volume.
On any given day, there are thousands of stocks with options traded. Larger stocks
usually have higher options trading volume. In September 2015, options on AAPL are
5
by far the most active options traded. Other popular stocks include FB, BAC, NFLX,
and BABA, although there is quite a bit of variation over time in terms which stock
options show up among the actively traded. If you are curious, this OCC link provides
monthly summaries of all equity and ETF option trading volume by exchange.
ETF options are American-style call and put options on ETFs. Again, one contract is
on 100 underlying shares and the option settles by physical delivery of the underlying
ETF. This CBOE link gives the exact specifications of ETF options. Since the mid-
2000s, the growth in ETF options is an important development in the options market.
For September 2015, the average daily trading volume for ETF options is around 7.33
million contracts per day, on par with the trading activity for equity options. The
dollar trading volume in ETF options averages to $1.50 billion per day, similar in
magnitude to equity options.
Among the popular ETFs are SPY, EEM, IWM, and QQQ, which command relatively
high option trading volume. By far, the most actively traded ETF option is SPY (op-
tions on SPDR). For September 2015, SPY options are traded on 12 options exchanges
with an average daily volume of 3.3 million contracts.
Index options are European-style call and put options on stock indices. Except for mini
products, one contract is on 100 underlying index. Instead of physical delivery, the
settlement of index options is done by cash. This CBOE link gives the specifications
of SPX, the most important index options. For September 2015, the average daily
trading volume of SPX is about 1.14 million contract and $2.78 billion in dollar trading
volume. Recall that the overall dollar trading volume in the options market is about
$6.30 billion. This implies that over 30% of the options dollar trading volume comes
from SPX. It is therefore not surprising that all options exchanges would like to get
involved with this product. So far, CBOE is able to maintain the exclusive license in
this product.
You might also notice that both SPX and SPY are trading on the S&P 500 index.
There are, however, a few differences between these two products. SPX is on the index
itself while SPY is on the ETF SPDR, which is about 1/10 of the index. As a result,
per contract, SPX is larger in size than SPY. Recall that average daily trading volume
in SPY from 12 exchanges adds up to 3.3 million contracts. This translates to a daily
trading volume around $804 million, a large number for ETF and equity options but
small compared with the daily dollar volume of $2.78 billion for SPX. Finally, while
SPY is an American-style option, SPX is European-style; SPY is physical settlement
while SPX is cash settlement.
6
Regardless of their differences, SPX and SPY share the same underlying. Therefore
there must be market participants who actively trade between these two contracts to
profit from any temporary mis-pricing between the two. As a result, the pricing of
these two contracts should be very much aligned with one another, taking into account
of the difference in their exercise style. For those who are interested, it might be a good
exercise to go to the CBOE’s website to get quotes for near-the-money near-the-term
SPX and SPY call and put options, back out the Black-Scholes implied volatilities
from these contracts and see if there are any significant pricing differences (above and
beyond the quoted bid and ask spreads).
• Options Exchanges: As we see earlier, over 30% of the option dollar trading volume
comes from SPX: call and put options on the S&P 500 index. Not surprisingly, CBOE
fought really heard to keep its exclusive rights to SPX. In 2012, after 6 years of litiga-
tion, CBOE won the battle and was able to retain its exclusive licenses on options on
the S&P 500 index. As a result, CBOE remains its dominance in index options with
over 98% of the market share. In addition to SPX, options on VIX have also grown in
popularity, which is also traded exclusively on CBOE.
In other areas, however, CBOE has not been able to retain its market power. Until
the late 1990s, CBOE was the main exchange for options trading. By the early 2000s,
however, CBOE was losing its market share in equity options to new option exchanges
like ISE. For equity options in September 2015, CBOE accounts for 16.32% of the
trading volume, PHLX has a market share of 17.50%, and the rest are shared by
BATS (14.37%), ARCA (11.81%), ISE (10.53%), AMEX (8.89%) and others. Trading
in ETF options took off around the mid-2000 and have been spread over many options
exchanges in a way similar to equity options: CBOE (15.93%), ISE (15.55%), PHLX
(15.02%), BATS (10.48%), ARC (10.15%), AMEX (10.14%), and others.
You might have noticed the fragmentation of the options market. Indeed, equity and
ETF options are traded in 12 different options exchanges. This phenomenon of market
fragmentation is not option specific. For example, US stocks regularly trade on 11
exchanges. In addition to these exchanges which are called “lit” markets, a non-trivial
amount (20% to 30% in 2015) of stock trading is done in alternative trading systems
such as “dark pool.”
7
S&P 500 index or on AAPL versus how many call options are bought. The same thing
cannot be said about the over-the-counter (OTC) derivatives market. While pricing
information on OTC derivatives can be obtained from Bloomberg or Datastream, the
real-time transaction information is very much protected by dealers as proprietary
information. In my personal view, if the trading information in products such as CDS,
CDO, synthetic CDO, and CDO2 were available to the public back in 2005, more
people would have paid attention to this market.
Like most markets, there are designated market makers in the options market. Their
presence in the market is to facilitate trading and provide liquidity. They make money
by quoting bid and ask prices: buy at the bid and sell at the ask. The bid-ask spread
(ask price - bid price) is the source of their profit. In the options market, the percentage
bid-ask spread is much larger than that of the underlying stock, reflecting the leverage
risk inherent in options. It is also a reflection of the relative illiquidity in options.
When there are buying and selling imbalances, market makers might have to keep an
inventory, which exposes them to market risk. This risk exposure is further exaggerated
if this imbalance is caused by some private information the market maker is not aware of
(information asymmetry). The inventory cost and the cost of information asymmetry
are two important drivers for the bid and ask spread in financial prices. In the options
market, it is typical for a market maker to minimize his exposure to the underlying
stock by delta hedging.
Coming back to the topic of SPX and SPY, two options products with very similar
underlying risk. You might notice that there is a substantial difference in their bid/ask
spreads. In particular, the average bid/ask spreads (as a percentage of the option price)
are much higher for SPX than SPY. The average percentage bid/ask spread for SPX
is about 9% while that for SPY is about 1%. If the market risk is similar, then where
does this difference in trading cost arise?
Investors who trade against the market makers can be summarized into four groups:
customers from full service brokerage firms (e.g., hedge funds), customers from discount
brokerage firms (e.g., retail investors), and firm proprietary traders. Using CBOE
data from 1990 through 2001, we see that customer from full serve brokerage firms
are the most active participants in the options market while firm proprietary traders
concentrate their trading mostly on index options as a hedging vehicle. Of course,
these are older data and the options market has exploded after 2001.
Another way to look at the market participants is through their trading activities
against the market makers. Some investors come to the options market to buy options
to open a new position, while other buy options to close an existing position. Some sell
8
options to new a new position while others sell options to close an existing position.
In doing so, their trading motives are very different.
This equation does not look very appealing at the moment, but you will come to
appreciate or even like it later. Under this model, the expected stock return is µ and
its volatility is σ, both numbers are in annualized terms. So if you like, µ is about 12%
and σ is about 20%. Moreover, under this model, stock returns (to be more precise,
log-returns) are normally distributed. Let me use the rest of this section to explain
why it is so.
Let ST be the stock price at time T . Implicitly we are planning ahead for the time
T , when the option expires. Standing here at time 0 and holding a European-style
option, all we care about is the final payoff:
where 1ST >K = 1 if ST > K and zero otherwise. Let’s focus on call options for now.
Once we know how to deal with call options, the put/call parity will get us to put
options very easily.
Option pricing bolts down to calculating the present value of the payoff in equation (2).
How should this calculation be done? What is the discount rate to use in order to bring
the random cash flow to today? Let’s keep this question hanging for a while.
• Brownian Motion: Since it is the first time we are working with Brownian motions,
let me summarize the following three important properties of Brownian motions and
relate them to Finance:
– Independence of increments: For all 0 = t0 < t1 < . . . < tm , the increments are
independent: B(t1 ) − B(t0 ), B(t2 ) − B(t1 ), . . . , B(tm ) − B(tm−1 ) . Translating to
Finance: stock returns are independently distributed. No predictability and zero
auto-correlation ρ = 0.
9
– Stationary normal increments: Bt − Bs is normally distributed with zero mean
and variance t−s. Translating to Finance: stock returns are normally distributed.
√
Over a fixed horizon of T , return volatility is scaled by T .
– Continuity of paths: B(t), t ≥ 0 are continuous functions of t. Translating to
Finance: stock prices move in a continuous fashion. There are no jumps or
discontinuities.
ST = S0 eRT .
RT = ln(ST ) − ln(S0 ) ,
which tells us that RT is the log-return of the stock over the horizon T . Now I am
going to do one magic and you just have to trust me on this. Next semester when you
take 450, you will learn the mechanics behind it, which is call the Ito’s Lemma.
( )
1 2
dRt = µ − σ dt + σ dBt
2
Comparing with equation (1), the dynamics of Rt is simpler. It does not have those µSt
and σSt terms. Instead, we have µ − σ 2 /2 as its drift and σ as its diffusion coefficient.
The extra term of σ 2 /2 is often call the Ito’s term.
With this dynamics for Rt , we can now fix the time horizon T and write out RT :
∫ ( )
T
1 2 √
RT = dRt = µ − σ T + σ T ϵT , (3)
0 2
where ϵT is a standard normal random variable (zero mean, variance equals to 1). You
∫T ∫T √
will agree with me that 0 dt = T . Let me explain why 0 dBt = BT − B0 is T ϵT :
it comes from the second property, stationary normal increments, of the Brownian
motion.
When it comes to valuation under the Black-Scholes model, the math will be done at
the level of equation (3). As you can see, it is not that scary, isn’t it? This model tells
us that the log-return of a stock over a fixed horizon of T is normally distributed with
√
mean (µ − σ 2 /2) T and standard deviation of σ T . Other than the Ito’s term, σ 2 /2,
everything looks quite familiar. No?
10
• The Ito’s Term: Now let me explain why we have this Ito’s term. In the continuous-
time model of equation (1), the stock price grows at the instantaneous rate of µ dt:
E(ST ) = S0 eµT ,
S0 = e−µT E(ST ) .
Now let’s do the same calculation with our model for log-return in Equation (3),
( )
E(ST ) = S0 E eRT .
E(ex ) = eE(x)+var(x)/2 .
Let me emphasize, this works only when x is normally distributed. Applying this
formula to the above calculation, we have
( )
E(ST ) = S0 E eRT = S0 eE(RT )+var(RT )/2 = S0 e(µ−σ /2)T +σ T /2 = S0 eµT ,
2 2
• Risk-Neutral Pricing: Now let’s come back to the present value calculation. As
discussed earlier, the payoff of a call option at time T is as in Equation (2). It is a
random payoff, depending on the realization of ST . It is a non-linear random payoff
11
with a kink at the strike price K: the payoff is zero if ST falls below K and is ST − K
if ST rallies above K and the option is exercised at time T . So what is the present
value of this random non-linear payoff? Which discount rate should we use?
Risk-neutral pricing is the answer to that question. Although it has “risk-neutral” in
its name, it is anything but risk-neutral. Let me first tell you the approach of the
risk-neutral pricing. Recall that after some hard work, we have
( )
1 2 √
RT = µ − σ T + σ T ϵT .
2
I am going to call this model the actual dynamics and label it by “P.” Then I am going
to introduce a different model, called risk-neutral dynamics and label it by “Q.”
( )
1 2 √
Actual Dynamics (“P”): RT = µ − σ T + σ T ϵT (4)
2
( )
1 2 √
Risk-Neutral Dynamics (“Q”): RT = r − σ T + σ T ϵQ
T (5)
2
By writing down the model in the Q-dynamics, I am bending the reality by forcing
the stock return to grow at the riskfree rate r. And then I am going to do my present
value calculation under this bent reality: 1) the expectation of the future cash flow is
done under the Q-measure and 2) this expectation is discounted back to today using
the riskfree rate r. And somehow, two wrongs make one right, the calculation works
out. You just have to trust me on this. This pricing framework is widely adopted on
Wall Street in fixed income, credit, and options.
• Pricing a Stock: Before applying this risk-neutral pricing framework on options, let’s
first try it on something easier: the linear random payoff of ST . We know what the
answer should be: the present value should be S0 . We’ve already done it under the
P-dynamics: S0 = e−µT E(ST ). It works out and using µ as the discount rate makes
perfect sense ... because this is how the dynamics is written.
Now let’s do it under the Q-dynamics:
So it also works! Just to emphasize that risk-neutral pricing has nothing to do with
investors being risk-neutral, let’s bring in a risk-neutral investor to price the same
stock. He takes the P-dynamics (because it is the reality) and discounts the cash flow
12
with riskfree rate r (because he is risk neutral):
So he is paying more than S0 for the same cash flow. Why? Because he is risk-neutral.
Recall that if ST is the market portfolio, then µ − r is the market risk premium.
Risk-averse investors demand a premium for holding the systematic risk in the market
portfolio. That gives rise to the positive risk premium in µ−r. A risk-neutral investor,
however, is not sensitive to risk. As such, he is willing to pay more for the stock.
This exercise might seem trivial mathematically, but it is very useful in clearing our
thoughts. In particular, I would like to emphasize that risk-neutral pricing does not
mean pricing using a risk-neutral investor. In a way, this name “risk-neutral pricing”
is unfortunate and confusing.
• Pricing the Option: We are now ready to price the option. Let C0 be the present
value of a European-style call option on ST with strike price K:
C0 = e−rT E Q ((ST − K) 1ST >K ) = e−rT E Q (ST 1ST >K ) − e−rT KE Q (1ST >K )
Comparing where we are now with the solution, we see some internal logic. In partic-
ular, it is obvious that
and ( )
−rT Q ST
N (d1 ) = e E 1S >K .
S0 T
13
• Understanding N (d2 ) in the Black-Scholes formula: The part associated with
N (d2 ) is actually pretty easy. It calculates the probability that the call option is in
the money under the Q-measure. So let’s work it out:
( ) ( )
ProbQ (ST > K) = ProbQ S0 eRT > K = ProbQ eRT > K/S0 = ProbQ (RT > ln(K/S0 )) ,
where, in the last step, I took a log on both side of the inequality, which is OK because
ln(x) is a monotonically increasing function in x.
Now let’s use the Q-dynamics of RT in Equation (5) to get,
(( ) )
1 2 √ Q
Q
Prob (RT > ln(K/S0 )) = Prob Q
r − σ T + σ T ϵT > ln(K/S0 ) .
2
or equivalently, ( ( ) )
ln(S0 /K) + r − 1 2
σ T
ProbQ − ϵQ
T < √ 2
,
σ T
So N (d1 ) involves a calculation that takes into account that we are calculating the
expectation of ST when ST is greater than K (the option expires in the money). So it
is not a simple probability calculation such as N (d2 ). Here, it involves an interaction
term. As a result N (d1 ) should always be larger than N (d2 ). This is true because
√
d1 = d2 + σ T . As you will see later, this difference between d1 and d2 is really where
√
the option value of an option comes from. In other words, σ T is the best summary
of the option value.
Given the amount of math we have been doing up to this point, I have a feeling that
most of you are not willing to go further. For those (of you who)are interested, you can
do the math to prove that N (d1 ) is in fact e−rT E Q ST
S0
1ST >K .
14
For those who are not willing to go through the math, let me offer this observation.
√
Under the Q-dynamics, the drift in RT is (r −σ 2 /2)T and the volatility is σ T . That’s
how we get the expression of d2 (and our previous calculation just proved this point).
Comparing d1 and d2 this way, we notice that suppose we bend the reality further by
making the drift in RT to be (r + σ 2 /2)T and keep the same volatility. Then, under
this strange dynamics, let’s call it QQ, we have N (d1 ) = ProbQQ (ST > K). Intuitively,
because of the interaction term, the valuation is higher. One simple way to express
this higher valuation is by allowing RT to grow faster than its Q-measure, with a drift
of (r + σ 2 /2)T . Under this probability measure, the probability of ST is greater than
K (the option expires in the money) becomes N (d1 ). I’ll stop here.
• Add Dividend Yield: We are going to apply the Black-Scholes model to SPX. So it
is important that we can handle stocks paying dividend with a constant dividend yield,
which, for the S&P 500 index, is a good enough approximate. Let q be the dividend
yield. Again, let ST be the time-T stock price, ex dividend. Then, the stock dynamics
becomes,
dSt = (µ − q) St dt + σ St dBt .
15
existing securities whose market values are known to us. The present value of this cash
flow equals to the cost of the replication.
The best example in our current setting is the put/call parity. As I am sure that you’ve
learned in 15.415 (or 15.401), the time-T payoff of buying a European-style call and
selling a European-style put (with the same strike price K) is the same as taking a
long position in the underlying stock and borrowing K from the bond market. The
present value of the underlying stock is e−qT S0 , where, as usual, we use ex dividend
stock price. The present value of the bond-borrowing portion is e−rT K, with r being
the riskfree rate, continuously compounded. So the replication cost is e−qT S0 −e−rT K.
The present value of buying a call and selling a put is, by definition, C0 − P0 . As a
result, C0 − P0 = e−qT S0 − e−rT K .
As you can see, in getting this relation, we do not have to use any model, just simple
logic. In practice, this put/call ration holds pretty well in the market. There are
investors actively arbitrage between the options and the cash (i.e., the S&P 500 index
or the S&P 500 index futures via “E-mini”) markets. Even if the Black-Scholes model
fails (which it does), this relation still holds. Arbitraging using put/call parity is
very similar to arbitraging between the futures and cash markets (arbitraging between
Chicago and New York).
When it comes to pricing call and put options, however, we do need to use a model. So
far, we’ve used the Black-Scholes model. It turns out that even with a stock and a bond,
we can still replicate the non-linear payoff of an option. This is the important insight
of Prof. Black, Merton, and Scholes: dynamic replication. You need to continuously
rebalance your hedging portfolio, doing delta hedging at a super high frequency. I am
sure that you’ve got a heavy dosage of that in your 15.415. So I am not going to spend
time on dynamic replication or delta hedging.
Recall that the third property of a Brownian motion is continuity of paths. This implies
that stock prices move in a continuous fashion. There is no jumps or discontinuities.
This is why models like geometric Brownian motions are called diffusion models. As you
can see, the property of dynamic replication falls apart as soon as we move away from
the Brownian motion by adding random jumps to the model. This is just one example.
If we add another streams of random shocks to volatility, making it a stochastic process
(instead of a number σ = 20%), then this replication also falls apart.
As such, the Black-Scholes formula is very much confined to the model itself. We will
see that the Black-Scholes model does not hold very well in the market. We will then
extend in two dimensions: adding jumps to the model to allow crashes; relaxing σ from
16
a number to a stochastic process and build a stochastic volatility model.
• Why so many equations? Since Fall 2015, because of the MFin students, I made
a conscious effort in being as rigorous as possible and giving you as much detail as
possible. While using the Black-Scholes model as a black box is fine for most people,
I feel that most of you deserve to know a little bit better. In past years, 15.450 was
taught along with 15.433. So I made the comfortable choice of letting the professor in
15.450 carry more of the math burden. Now that 15.450 has been moved to the Spring
semester, I feel that I’ve lost my excuse. And Prof. Wang kept asking me to push you
more. So this is my effort in pushing you.
If you’ve seen this before, don’t presume that you know everything. Honestly, I started
to work in this area as soon as I entered the PhD program at Stanford GSB 20 years
ago. But I’ve only developed these intuitions over the years. So take your time to
digest the materials and make them your own.
17
Figure 3: The N (d1 ) and N (d2 ) for an one at-the-money call or put option with one-month
to expiration. The underlying stock volatility is 20%.
Now let’s use a Taylor expansion that is very useful in Finance: ex ≈ 1 + x , for small
x. Applying this to the integrand,
x2 x2
e− 2 = 1 − .
2
where I dropped the cubic term to make our approximation even simpler. But you can
see, if you include the next order of approximation, the net effect will make the option
√
price lower. This approximation works well for small σ T . For a typical one-month
√
option on the S&P 500 index, σ = 0.20 and T=1/12, we have σ T being around
( √ )3
0.0577. As a comparison, the higher order term σ T /24 is 8 × 10−6 . So this level
√
of σ T , our approximation works really well.
√
As shown in Figure 4, as σ T becomes large, this approximation becomes imprecise.
Moreover, the approximation is bias upward compared with the Black-Scholes pricing.
This makes sense because the next higher order term is negative. It also makes sense
√
because C0 /S0 cannot grow linearly with σ T forever. The call option price is bounded
18
Figure 4: The ratio of an at-the-money
√ call or put option price to the underlying stock
√ price,
√
C0 /S0 or P0 /S0 , as a function of σ T . The approximation of C0 /S0 = P0 /S0 ≈ σ T / 2π
is in red and the Black-Scholes pricing is in blue.
from above by the underlying stock price: C0 /S0 cannot be bigger than 1. At some
point, this ratio has to taper off.
√
What kind of options will give us σ T that is too large for this approximation to
work? Options on volatile stocks with long time to expire. For example, for an option
√
with σ = 100% and 1 year to expiration, σ T = 1. As you can see from Figure 4, our
approximation is no longer very good.
√
• ATM Options as Financial Vehicles on σ T : In spending time to analyze the
at-the-money options, we learned an important lesson. In fact, it is the cleanest way to
understand what options are really about. By buying a call option, we get a positive
exposure to the underlying stock; by buying a put option, we get a negative exposure.
Neither of these exposures is unique to options. There are other ways we can get this
kind of exposure. And the exposure can be easily hedged out by stocks. But what’s
unique about options is the volatility exposure. In the Black-Scholes model, volatility
is a constant. So you might not appreciate the significance of this volatility exposure.
As soon as we allow volatility to move around, which is true in reality, then you find
√
in options a vehicle that is unique in offering exposures to σ T . Nothing in the stock
market can offer this kind of exposure.
19
Recall that dynamic replication makes options a redundant security within the Black-
Scholes model. At that point, you might be wondering to yourself that: if it is redun-
dant, then what is the point? Well, in reality, with random shocks to volatility and
fat-tails in stock returns, options are not at all redundant. That is why, as beautiful
and revolutionary as the dynamic replication theory is, I do not want us to spend too
much time on it.
Going back to our discussions regarding N (d1 ) and N (d2 ), the example of ATM options
further clarifies what really matters in d1 and d2 . It’s the fact that d1 is always
√
larger than d2 , by the amount of σ T in the Black-Scholes model. If you trace back
to the calculation of d1 , you notice that it comes from E Q (ST 1ST >K ), the positive
interaction between ST and 1ST >K . Within the Black-Scholes setting, we have the
exact formulation of this option value. As we later move away from the Black-Scholes
model, N (d1 ) and N (d2 ) will be replaced by other formulas. That is why I have been
emphasizing calculations like E Q (1ST >K ) and E Q (ST 1ST >K ) for call options. These
calculations are the main building blocks of a call option, whose values might be
different in different models. Likewise, for put options, calculations like E Q (1ST <K )
and E Q (ST 1ST <K ) are the main building blocks.
20
option on the same underlying might be worth just a few dollars. A short-dated options
is worth much less than a long-dated options. Since all of these options are on the
same underlying, you would like to be able to compare their pricing. But comparing
these options in the dollar space is not at all intuitive. By contrast, all of these options
share the same underlying. Hence the same σ. So comparing these options in the
volatility space is much more intuitive and productive. In fact, in OTC markets,
options are typically quoted not in dollar but in the Black-Scholes implied volatility.
This is analogous to the adoption of yields in the bond market. So Black-Scholes
implied vols in options and yields in bonds.
21
Figure 5: Time-Varying Volatility of the S&P 500 Index. The red line is the option-implied
volatility using SPX traded on CBOE. The blue line is measured directly from the underlying
stock market using daily returns of the S&P index.
VIX, especially those sudden increases in VIX are often accompanied by sudden and
large drops in the index level. Of course, this observation is outside of the Black-
Scholes model, where σ is a constant. But this plot gives us the intuition as to what
could go wrong with selling volatility: you lose money when the markets are in crisis.
Basically, by selling volatility on the overall market (e.g., SPX), your capital is at risk
exactly when capital is scarce. In the language of the CAPM, you have a positive beta
exposure.
But this positive beta exposure is more subtle than the simple linear co-movement
captured by beta. As highlighted by the shaded areas, volatility typically spikes up
when there are large crises. Just to name a few: the October 1987 stock market crash,
the January 1991 Iraq war, the September 1993 Sterling crisis, the 1997 Asian crisis, the
1998 LTCM crisis, 9/11, 2002 Internet bubble burst, 2005 downgrade of GM and Ford,
2007 pre-crisis, March 2008 Bear Stearns, September 2008 Lehman, the European and
Greek crises in 2010 and 2011, and the August 2015 Chinese spillover. In other words,
what captured by Figure 6 is co-movement in extreme events, like the crisis beta in
Assignment 1 (risk exposure conditioning on large negative stock returns). Also, as
shown in Figure 6, not all crises have the same impact. For example, the downgrade
of GM and Ford was a big event for the credit market, but not too scary for equity
22
and index options.
Figure 6: Time-Series of the CBOE VIX Index Plotted against the Time-Series of the
S&P 500 Index Level. Prior to 1990, the old VIX (VXO) is used. Post 1990, the news
VIX index is used.
The comovement in Figure 6 gives rise to a negative correlation between the S&P 500
index returns and changes in VIX, which ranges between -50% to -90%. Figure 7 is an
old plot from Classes 8 & 9, which uses the EWMA model to estimate the correlation
between the two. As you can see from the plot, the correlation has experienced a
regime change. During the early sample period, the correlation hovers around -50%,
while in more recent period, the correlation has become more severe, hovering around
-80%.
All of these observations have direct impact on how options should be priced in practice:
the Black-Scholes model needs to allow σ to vary over time. The time variation of σ
should not be modeled in a deterministic fashion. As shown in Figure 6, the time
series of σt is affected by uncertain, random shocks. So just like the stock price St
follows a stochastic process (e.g., geometric Brownian motion), σt itself should follow
a stochastic process with its own random shocks. Moreover, the random shocks in σt
should be negatively correlated with the random shocks in St to match the empirical
evidence in Figure 6. There is a class of diffusion models called stochastic volatility
models developed exactly for this purpose.
These models are similar to the discrete-time models like EWMA or GARCH, which
23
Figure 7: The Time-Series of EWMA Estimates for the Correlations between the S&P 500
Index Returns and Daily Changes in the VIX Index.
also allow volatility to be time-varying. But one distinct feature of stochastic volatility
models is that it has its own random shocks. In EWMA or GARCH, the time-varying
volatility comes from the random shocks in the stock market. We will come back to the
stochastic volatility model later in the class, which are very useful in pricing options
of different times to expiration, linking the pricing of long-dated options to that of
short-dated options.
• OTM Options and Tail Events: In developing our intuition for the Black-Scholes
model, we’ve focused mostly on the ATM options, which are important vehicles for
volatility exposure. Now let’s look at the pricing of the out-of-the-money options.
Recall the risk-neutral pricing of a call option,
( )
C0 = E Q e−rT (ST − K)1ST >K = e−rT E Q (ST 1ST >K ) − e−rT K E Q (1ST >K ) ,
where the pricing bolts down to calculations involving E Q (1ST >K ) and E Q (ST 1ST >K ).
For K > S0 erT , the call option is out of the money. In fact, the larger the strike price
K, the more out of the money the option is, and the smaller E Q (1ST >K ). So if we
focus on OTM calls, we zoom into the right tail.
24
Figure 8: The Distribution of a Standard Normal with N (−d1 ) and N (−d2 ).
.
where the pricing bolts down to calculations involving E Q (1ST <K ) and E Q (ST 1ST <K ).
For K < S0 erT , the put option is out of the money. In fact, the smaller the strike
price K, the more out of the money the option is, and the smaller E Q (1ST <K ). So if
we focus on OTM puts, we zoom into the left tail.
Within the Black-Scholes model, the above calculations can be taken to the next level
using the probability distribution of a standard normal:
P0 = e−rT K E Q (1ST <K ) − e−rT E Q (ST 1ST <K ) = e−rT K N (−d2 ) − S0 N (−d1 ) ,
where I’ve changed the color coding so that this equation matches with Figure 8. More
specifically, for a 10% OTM put striking at K = S0 er T × 90%, we can re-write the
above pricing into:
P0 e−rT K
= N (−d2 ) − N (−d1 ) = 0.90 × N (−d2 ) − N (−d1 )
S0 S0
25
Figure 8 gives us a graphical presentation of what matters when it comes to pricing
such OTM options: the left tail in red and the slice in yellow. The areas in red and
yellow are mapped directly to the CDF of a standard normal (hence N (−d1 ) and
N (−d2 ) - N (−d1 )) because we are working under the Black-Scholes model. But the
intuitive goes further. For any distribution (even it is not normal), what matters for
the pricing of this OTM put option is the left-tail distribution. If this left tail is fat
because of many financial crises, then the pricing of OTM put options should reflect
these tail events. In Assignment 3, you will have a chance to work with a model with
crash and see the link between fat tails and option prices.
As mentioned a few times, the actual distribution of stock market returns is not nor-
mally distributed. This is especially true for returns at higher frequencies (e.g., daily
returns). As such, the Black-Scholes model fails to capture the fat tails in the data.
As we will see, this becomes a rather important issue when it comes to pricing options.
Conversely, by looking at how these OTM options are priced, we learn about investors’
assessment and attitude toward these tail events.
• Option Implied Smirks: After the 1987 stock market crash, one very robust pattern
arose from the index options (SPX) market called volatility smiles or smirks.
Consider the nearest term options, say one month to expiration (T=1/12). Let’s vary
the strike price of these options. Typically, for options with one month to expiration,
you can find tradings of OTM puts and calls that are up to 10% out of the money. It
is generally the case that OTM options are more actively traded than in-the-money
options. This makes sense. If you are using options for speculations, you would prefer
options that are cheaper (and are liquid) so that you can get more action for each
dollar invested in options. If you are using options for hedging, it is likely that you
are hedging out tails events. So either way, the OTM puts and calls are referred
instruments than ITM options.
Between OTM calls and puts of SPX, it is generally the case that OTM puts are more
actively traded and the level of OTM-ness can reach up to 20%. For the S&P 500
index, a typical annual volatility is 20%, implying a monthly volatility of 5.77%. So
for a 10% OTM put option, it takes a drop of 1.733-sigma (10%/5.77%) move in the
S&P 500 index over a one-month period for this option to come back to the money.
Using the market prices of all the available SPX puts and calls, we can back out the
Black-Scholes implied volatility σ I for each one of them. If investors are pricing the
options according to the Black-Scholes model, then we should see σ I being exactly the
same for all of these options, regardless of the moneyness of the options. What we see
26
in practice, however, is a pattern like that in Table 1.
Table 1 lists six short-dated OTM put options with exactly the same time to expiration
but varying degrees of moneyness. The first option is nearest to the money, striking
at K = 1285 when the underlying stock index is at S0 = 1287. The last option is the
farthest away from the money, striking at K = 1170. The S&P 500 index needs to drop
by over 9% over the next 16 calendar days in order for this option to be in the money.
Not surprisingly, options are cheaper as they are farther out of the money. But what’s
interesting is that their Black-Scholes implied vols exhibit this opposite pattern: the
more out of the money a put option is, the higher its implied vol. In other words, even
though the pricing of $0.40 (per option on one underlying share of the S&P 500 index)
seems very cheap in dollars and cents, it is actually over priced. Plugging a σ = 10.06%
to the Black-Scholes model (which a closer to the market volatility around March 2,
2006), the model price for this OTM put is $0.000013. In other words, this option is so
out of the money, the Black-Scholes model (with normal distribution) deems its value
to be close to zero. In practice, however, there are people who are willing to pay $0.40
for it.
Why? Don’t they know about the Black-Scholes option pricing formula? If they care
about tail events, then what about OTM calls which are sensitive to right tails? As we
see in the data, the tail fatness shows up in both the left and the right. But the OTM
calls are not over-priced. If anything, the implied vols of OTM calls are on average
slightly lower than ATM options. That is why we are calling this pattern volatility
smirk, which is an asymmetric smile.
27
Table 2: Expected Options Returns
Strike - Spot -15 to -10 -10 to -5 -5 to 0 0 to 5 5 to 10
Weekly SPX Put Option Returns (in %)
mean return -14.56 -12.78 -9.50 -7.71 -6.16
max return 475.88 359.18 307.88 228.57 174.70
min return -84.03 -84.72 -87.72 -88.90 -85.98
mean BS β -36.85 -37.53 -35.23 -31.11 -26.53
corrected return -10.31 -8.45 -5.44 -4.12 -3.10
Option data from Jan. 1990 through Oct. 1995.
the return could be as positive as 475.88%, or as negative as -84.03%. This option has
a beta of -36.85, which is due to the inherent leverage of these options. The CAPM-
alpha of this investment is -10.31% per week. Whoever is selling this option would
make a lot of money...on average. But he needs to be well capitalized when an event
like 475.88% happens.
Calculations like those in Table 2 are rather imprecise because of the large variations
in option returns. So we do not want to take the numbers too literally. But the
qualitative result of this Table is important: when it comes to investing in options,
there are large variations in option returns. Moreover, buying put options give you
negative alpha. The more out of the money the put option is, the more negative the
alpha becomes. For investors who are selling such put options, they are able to capture
such alpha. But such trading strategies are in generally very dangerous. You need to
be well capitalized to survive large crises like the 1987 stock market crash. Otherwise,
you are just one crisis away from bankruptcy.
The results shown here in the return space is very much consistent with the earlier
results in the implied-vol space, where OTM put options are over priced relative to
near-the-money options. The level of over-pricing gets more severe as the put option
becomes more out of the money and are more sensitive to market crashes. So it is not
surprising that the put option returns are on average negative. Most of the times, you
purchase an insurance against a market crash, but the crash does not happen and your
put option expires out of the money. But once in a while, a crisis like 1987 or 2008
happens, then this put option brings you over-sized returns. Sitting on the other side
of the trade are investors who sell/write you these crash insurances. Most of the times,
they are able to pocket the premiums paid for the insurance without having to do
anything. But once in while, they lose quite a bit of money if a crisis like 1987 or 2008
happens. As such, the risk profile of such option strategies differs quite significantly
from that of a stock portfolio, where all instruments are linear. In Assignment 3, you
28
will have a chance to see this kind of risk/return tradeoff of options in more details for
yourselves.
29
Soon, the fixed-income arbitrage space was crowded and spreads in arbitrage trades
were shrinking. In early 1998, LTCM began to short large amounts of equity volatility.
Betting that implied vol would eventually revert to its long-run mean of 15%, they
shorted options at prices with an implied volatility of 19%. Their position is such that
each percentage change in implied vol will make or lose $40 million in their option
portfolio. The size of their vol position was so big that Morgan Stanley coined a
nickname for the fund: the Central Bank of Volatility. For more details, you can read
Roger Lowenstein’s book on LTCM.
During normal time, volatility does revert to its mean. So the idea behind the trade
makes sense. Moreover, as we’ve seen in the data, selling volatility (via ATM options) is
a profitable strategy on average because of the premium component. But the premium
was not a free lunch: it exists because of the risk involved in selling volatility. As we’ve
seen in the data, when the volatility of the aggregate market suddenly spikes up, the
financial market usually is in trouble. Whenever the market is in the crisis mode, there
is flight to quality: investors abandon all risky asset classes and move their capital to
safe havens such as the Treasury bond market.
For the case of LTCM in 1998, it had arbitrage trades in different markets (e.g., equity,
fixed-income, credit, currency, and derivatives) across different geographical locations
(e.g., U.S., Japan, and European). Lowenstein’s book gives more detailed descriptions
of these arbitrage trades. One common characteristics of these arbitrage trades is
30
that they locate some temporary dislocation in the market and speculate that this
dislocation will die out as the market converges back to normal. In a way, these
arbitrage trades betting on convergence make money because they provide liquidity
to temporary market dislocations. The key risk involved in these arbitrage trades is
that timing of the convergence is uncertain. Sometimes, instead of converging, the
dislocation becomes even more severe before converging back to normal.
Prior to the Russian default in the summer of 1998, these arbitrage trades were not
highly correlated. But after the default, most of these previously uncorrelated arbitrage
trades lost money for LTCM at the same time. This certainly includes the volatility
trades. As shown in Figure 9, early in the year, volatility was fluctuating around 20%.
By summer 1998, however, the market became quite volatile because of the Russian
default. At its peak, the VIX index was around 45%. Recall that LTCM was selling
volatility when VIX was around 19% in early 1998. The position was such that each
percentage change in implied vol will make or lose $40 million. So if the volatility
converges back to its long run mean of 15%, then roughly 4 × $40 = $160 can be made.
But if instead of converging, the volatility increases to 45%, you can imagine the loss.
The Russian default affected not only LTCM but other hedge funds and prop trading
desks who pursued the same kind of convergence trades. At a time like this, capital
becomes scarce, and all leveraged investors (e.g., hedge funds or prop trading in in-
vestment banks) are desperately looking for extra source of funding. They do so by
unwinding some of their arbitrage trades, further exacerbating the widening spreads.
At a time like this, holding a security that pays (e.g., an existing long position in puts)
could be very valuable. By contrast, a security that demands payment (e.g., an ex-
isting short position in puts) would be threatening to your survival. Therefore, being
on the short side of the market volatility hurts during crises. That is why volatility is
expensive (i.e., ATM options are over-priced) in the first place.
• The 2008 crisis: The OTM put options on the S&P 500 index is a good example
for us to understand crash insurance. In writing a deep OTM put option, the investor
prepares himself for the worse case scenario when the option becomes in the money.
This happens when the overall market experiences a sharp decline. The probability
of such events is small. But if he writes a lot of such options believing that the
exposure can somehow be contained by the low probability, then he is up for a big
surprise when a crisis does happen. As we learned from the recent financial crisis, some
supposedly sophisticated investors wrote such OTM put options without knowing the
real consequence.
31
Gillan Tett from Financial Times wrote an excellent book called Fool’s Gold with
details of how investment banks developed and later competed for the market shares
of the mortgage-linked CDO products. The following is a brief summary.
By 2006, Merrill, who was late into the CDO game, topped the league table in terms
of underwriting CDO’s, selling a total of $52 billion that year, up from $2 billion in
2001. Behind the scenes, Merrill was facing the same problem that worried Winters at
J.P. Morgan: what to do with the super-senior tranch?
CDO’s are the collateralized debt obligations. It pools individual debt together and
slices the pool into tranches according to seniority. For a mortgage-linked CDO, the
underlying pool consists of mortgages of individual homeowners. The cashflow to the
pool consists of their monthly mortgage payments. The most senior tranch is the first
in line to receive this cashflow. Only after the senior tranch receives its promised
cashflow, the next level of tranches (often called mezzanine tranches) can claim their
promised cashflow. The equity tranch is the most junior and receives the residual
cashflow from the pool.
As default increases in mortgages, the cashflow to the pool decreases. The equity
investors will be the first to be hit by the default. If the default rate further increases,
then the mezzanine tranch will be affected. The most senior tranch will only be affected
in the unlikely event that both equity and mezzanine investors are wiped out and the
cashflow to the pool cannot meet the promise to the most senior tranch. Such super
senior tranches are usually very safe and are Aaa rated. By contrast, the mezzanine
tranches are lower rated (Baa) because of the higher default risk. And the credit
quality of the equity tranch is even lower.
The pricing of such products is consistent with their credit quality: the yield on the
mezzanine tranches is higher than the senior tranches to compensate for the higher
credit risk. Investors, in an effort to reach for yield, prefer to buy the mezzanine
and equity tranches. As a result, the investment banks underwriting the CDOs are
often stuck with the super senior tranches. As the business of CDOs grew, the banks
are accumulating more and more highly rated super senior tranches. Initially, Merrill
solved the problem by buying insurance (credit default swaps) for its super-senior debt
from AIG.
Let’s take a look at what the super-senior tranch is really about. It is highly rated
because of the low credit risk. Imagine the economic condition under which this credit
risk affecting the super-senior tranch will actually materialize: when the default risk is
so high that both mezzanine and equity investors are wiped out. A typical argument
32
for the economics of pooling is that default risk by individual homeowners can be
diversified in a pool. This is indeed true when we think about the risk affecting the
equity tranch: one or two defaults in the pool would affect the cashflow to the equity
tranch, but would not affect the mezzanine tranch, let alone the senior tranch. So the
risk affecting the senior tranch has to be a very severe one. The default rate has to be
so high that the cashflow dwindles to the extent that it would eat through the lower
tranches and affect the most senior tranch. In other words, many homeowners must be
affected simultaneously and default at the same time to generate this type of scenario.
By then, the risk is no longer idiosyncratic but systemic. So writing an insurance on
a senior tranch amounts to insuring a crisis — a deep OTM put option on the entire
economy.
In late 2005, AIG told Merrill that it would no longer offer the service of writing
insurance on senior tranches. By then, however, AIG has already accumulated quite
a large position on such insurance. Later, AIG was taken over by the US government
in a $85 billion bailout and the insurance on senior tranches was honored and made
whole by AIG (and the New York Fed).
After AIG declined to insure their super senior tranch, Merrill decided to start keeping
the risk on its own books. At the same time, Citigroup, another late comer, was also
keen to ramp up the output of its CDO machine. Unlike the brokerages, though,
Citi could not park unlimited quantities of super-senior tranches on its balance sheet.
Citi decided to circumvent that rule by placing large volumes of its super-senior in
an extensive network of SIVs (Special Investment Vehicle) and other off balance sheet
vehicles that it created. Citi further promised to buy bank the super-senior tranch if
the SIVs ever ran into problems with them.
Now let’s try to understand what Merrill and Citi are actually doing by retaining the
super-senior tranch. Effectively, they are holding the super-senior tranch without an
insurance. If you are holding a US treasury bond, you don’t have to worry about
credit risk (except for when the US government defaulted). So holding a super-senior
tranch without an insurance is like holding a default-free US treasury bond and selling
a deep OTM option on the overall economy at the same time. Before, they were able
to buy that put option from AIG to hedge out this risk. Now, they are bearing this
risk themselves.
Then the crisis happened in 2007 and 2008, and the mortgage default rate increased to
such an extent that it started to affect the super-senior tranches. In other words, the
deep OTM put options became in the money. During the 2007-08 crisis, the pricing
of these super-senior tranches became one of the biggest headaches on Wall Street.
33
Merrill and Citi, along with other Wall Street banks, had to take billions of dollars of
writedowns.
34
Appendix
35
cash flow is very much up in the air, you see a similar pattern. I am not an expert in either
of these areas, but it is safe to say that the level of precision required of a Finance model
is relatively low in these areas, or the margin of errors allowed for such valuation models is
rather high.
In writing this introduction on valuation, my objective was to compare and contrast the
role of valuation in various parts of Finance. On the one end of the spectrum, you have
valuations in VC and private equity. In this space, the cash flows are highly uncertain;
which discount rates to use is also not clear. The role of a valuation model in such a setting
is indeed very limited. If you are working in this area, spending time to perfect your Finance
model is not at all your number one priority. On the other end of the spectrum, you have
valuations in options and fixed income. In options, the cash flow comes from the fluctuation
of the underlying stock price. In fixed income, the cash flow comes from the coupon and
principal payments. In both cases, the cash flow can be modeled rather precisely and the
present value calculation can be done with super high precision. In these areas, people take
their valuation models rather seriously. If anything, the danger is that people take their
models too literally to the extent that they are lost in their models.
I hope that you do not read this introduction as “one against another.” This concern
made me move this introduction to the appendix so as not to distract you from the main
topic. The role of a professor is to offer knowledge and perspective. As a student, your
responsibility is to absorb the useful, discard the useless and build a system for yourself. I
can see how a teacher can influence his students (OK, maybe not MBAs). My cousin in
Shanghai used to hate English because her English teacher was not nice to her. Isn’t that
crazy?
36
about this cross-sectional approach, I started to think about trading strategies. Since I spent
most of my time thinking about options, the idea came quite naturally to me: would it be
cool to have a signal from the options market and use it to trade in the stock market? The
most obvious signal would be put/call ratio. Consider a stock with a lot of put option volume
traded on it versus a stock with a lot of call option volume traded on it. One is a bearish
signal on the stock and the other bullish.
My problem was that I did not have good options data with clean volume information to
test this idea. Most of the publicly available data mixes open buy with close buy and open
sell with close sell. As a result, the pure signal from open buy is contaminated by close buy.
Likewise for the sell volume. So my test results using the publicly available data were weak
and I did not want to write a paper with these weak results. This is how I located Allen and
his unique dataset. I sent him an email, he sent me a disc with his data and we started to
work together.
We form stock portfolios by their put/call ratios and track their performance for the
next week. We find that stocks with low put/call ratio outperform stocks with high put/call
ratio by 40 basis points over the next day and 1% over the next week. This predictability is
stronger for smaller stocks. We also find that option volumes by customers from full service
brokerage firms (e.g., hedge funds) are by far the most informative. By contrast, option
volumes by firm proprietary traders do not have any predictive power. Our interpretation is
that prop traders use exchange-traded options mostly for hedging needs, which is supported
by the fact that prop traders are much more active on index options than equity options.
After we finished our paper in 2003 or 2004, we got a lot of interest from practitioners.
We even heard from CBOE, who asked us where we got the data. We told them that the
data was sitting in their mainframe and offered to help them package and sell the data (so
that we can have free access). They said “No.” Later they started to sell this data at a pretty
high price. Several years later around 2009 or 2010, a former student of Allen got this big
grant for data purchase. So I asked her to buy the very expensive CBOE data to do the same
test on the more recent data. The strong predictability we found over the 1990-2001 sample
no longer exists in the recent time period. It is difficult to say if our paper has any direct
impact, but the market seemed to become a little more efficient. After writing this paper,
Allen became more interested in the practice of Finance and left his tenured professorship
to join D.E. Shaw. He also got us a coverage on the New York Times.
37
C Brownian Motion
During my office hours, I got a few questions about the Brownian motion and risk-neutral
pricing. Let me use this appendix to explain some of the details.
To understand the Brownian motion, let’s create one. Let’s start from time 0 and end in
time T. Let’s further chop this time interval into small increments. For example, in Figure 10,
T=1 and the interval between 0 and 1 is chopped evenly into 50 smaller increments with
size ∆ = 1/50. We can now start to create a sample path of the Brownian motion:
B0 = 0
√
B∆ − B0 = ∆ ϵ∆
√
B2∆ − B∆ = ∆ ϵ2∆
...
√
BT − BT −∆ = ∆ ϵT .
where the ϵ’s are independent standard normals. In creating this sample path, we use the first
two properties of the Brownian motions: independence increments and stationary normal
increments. I’ve attached the Matlab code I used to create this plot in this note. You can
run it and each time you will get a different sample path.
For our purpose of pricing a European-style option, what matters is the distribution of
38
BT . But if we are interested in pricing an American-style option, then the entire path of Bt
matters and at each node, we will make a decision of whether or not to exercise early. So
the grid should be as fine as possible (larger N and smaller ∆).
Now back to our original process for St :
dSt = µ St dt + σ St dBt ,
where to avoid distraction, I have set the dividend yield q = 0. As usual, we work with
Xt = ln St and, using the Ito’s Lemma, we have
( )
1
dXt = µ − σ2 dt + σ dBt .
2
The nice thing about working with ln St is that you can integrate out the process:
( ∫ T ) ∫ T
1 2
XT = X0 + µ− σ dt + σ dBt
2
(0
) 0
1 2
= X0 + µ − σ T + σ (BT − B0 )
2
( )
1 2 √
= X0 + µ − σ T + σ T ϵT ,
2
√
where in the last step I use T ϵT to express BT − B0 . Recall that the log-return RT is
defined by RT = ln XT − ln X0 . We have
( )
1 √
RT = µ − σ2 T +σ T ϵT
2
This is a big no-no in Finance because it approaches the pricing as if we were risk neutral.
Interestingly, this is why the method of “risk-neutral” pricing arises. It is mostly a math-
39
ematical result. If you Google Girsonov theorem or the Radon-Nikodym derivative, you
will see the related math result. But the math result has its relevance in Finance. Let me
approach it this way.
In Finance, we develop this concept of pricing kernel or the stochastic discount factor.
Armed with this pricing kernel ξT , we can do our pricing:
( )
−rT ξT
C0 = e E (ST − K)+ .
ξ0
Under the Black-Scholes setting, the markets are complete and the pricing kernel is unique.
In fact, as an application of the Girsonov theorem, this pricing kernel is of the form
dQ
= e−γ BT − 2 γ T .
1 2
ξT =
dP
This ξT is what the mathematician would call the Radon-Nikodym derivative. Notice that
by construction E(ξT ) = 1.
As mentioned earlier, the pricing kernel is unique under the Black-Scholes setting. So the
constant γ is uniquely defined. In Finance, we call this parameter the market price of risk
and for the Black-Scholes setting, it is γ = (µ − r) /σ, which in fact is the Sharpe ratio. In
a more general setting, γ can itself be a stochastic process. Also notice that with a positive
market price of risk, γ > 0, ξT is negatively correlated with BT (hence negatively correlated
with XT and ST ). This is what you were taught in Finance 15.415. When ST experiences
a positive stock, the stochastic discount factor is smaller; when ST experiences a negative
stock, the stochastic discount factor is bigger. This asymmetry has its origin in the fact that
investors are risk averse and the risk in ST is systematic (undiversifiable).
It turns out that we can create a new measure Q, called the equivalent martingale mea-
sure, for the original P and the pricing becomes,
( )
−rT ξT
C0 = e E (ST − K) +
ξ0
( )
= e−rT E Q (ST − K)+ ,
40
Now let’s construct this new Q-Brownian:
( )
1 2
dXt = µ − σ dt + σ dBtp
2
( ) ( )
1 2 µ−r
= r− σ dt + σ P
+ dBt
2 σ
( )
1 2
= r− σ dt + σ dBtQ ,
2
µ−r
dBtQ = + dBtP .
σ
And this change of measure, from P to Q, is the essence of the risk-neutral pricing.
The name of “risk-neutral” pricing is ironical: the whole thing arises from the observation
that we cannot do
C0 ̸=e−rT E P (ST − K)+ .
But if we are willing to change our probability measure from P to Q, under which
( )
1 2
dXt = r − σ dt + σdBtQ ,
2
S0 E ? (1ST >K )
41
is where the new measure QQ comes from. You can start with the observation that
So if we define
dBtQQ = −σ dt + dBtQ ,
under which ( )
1 2
dXt = r + σ dt + σdBtQQ .
2
Then we can indeed get
I am being a bit sloppy in my notation, but I trust a careful and thorough student would fill
in the details (including the other deterministic terms).
42