The Cost of Money: Production Opportunities Time Preferences For Consumption Risk Inflation
The Cost of Money: Production Opportunities Time Preferences For Consumption Risk Inflation
The Cost of Money: Production Opportunities Time Preferences For Consumption Risk Inflation
The four most fundamental factors affecting the cost of money are
1. production opportunities,
2. time preferences for consumption,
3. risk, and
4. inflation.
To see how these factors operate, visualize an isolated island
community where people live on fish. They have a stock of fishing gear
that permits them to survive reasonably well, but they would like to
have more fish. Now suppose one of the island’s inhabitants, Mr. Crusoe,
had a bright idea for a new type of fishnet that would enable him to
double his daily catch. However, it would take him a year to perfect the
design, build the net, and learn to use it efficiently. Mr. Crusoe would
probably starve before he could put his new net into operation.
Therefore, he might suggest to Ms. Robinson, Mr. Friday, and several
others that if they would give him one fish each day for a year, he would
return two fish a day the next year. If someone accepted the offer, the
fish that Ms. Robinson and the others gave to Mr. Crusoe would
constitute savings, these savings would be invested in the fishnet, and
the extra fish the net produced would constitute a return on the
investment.
Obviously, the more productive Mr. Crusoe thought the new fishnet
would be, the more he could afford to offer potential investors for their
savings. In this example, we assume that Mr. Crusoe thought he would
be able to pay (and thus he offered) a rate of return—he offered to give
back two fish for every one he received. He might have tried to attract
savings for less—for example, he might have offered only fish per day
next year for every one he received this year, which would represent
a rate of return to Ms. Robinson and the other potential savers.
How attractive Mr. Crusoe’s offer appeared to a potential saver would
depend in large part on the saver’s time preference for consumption. For
example, Ms. Robinson might be thinking of retirement, and she might
be willing to trade fish today for fish in the future on a one-for-one basis.
On the other hand, Mr. Friday might have a wife and several young
children and need his current fish; so he might be unwilling to “lend” a
fish today for anything less than three fish next year. Mr. Friday would
be said to have a high time preference for current consumption, and Ms.
Robinson, a low time preference. Note also that if the entire population
were living right at the subsistence level, time preferences for current
consumption would necessarily be high; aggregate savings would be
low; interest rates would be high; and capital formation would be
difficult.
rates. Higher risk and higher inflation also lead to higher interest
rates.
© CengageLearning®
There is a price for each type of capital, and these prices change over
time as supply and demand conditions change. Figure 7.2 shows how
long- and shortterm interest rates to business borrowers have varied
since the early 1970s. Notice that short-term interest rates are
especially volatile, rising rapidly during booms and falling equally
rapidly during recessions. (The shaded areas of the chart indicate
recessions.) In particular, note the dramatic drop in short-term interest
rates during the recent recession. When the economy is expanding,
firms need capital; and this demand pushes rates up. Inflationary
pressures are strongest during business booms, also exerting upward
pressure on rates. Conditions are reversed during recessions: Slack
business reduces the demand for credit, inflation falls, and the Federal
Reserve increases the supply of funds to help stimulate the economy.
The result is a decline in interest rates.
In recent years, inflation has been quite low, averaging about a year,
and it was even negative in 2009, as prices fell in the midst of the deep
recession. However, long-term interest rates have been volatile because
investors are not sure if inflation is truly under control or is about to
jump back to the higher levels of the 1980s. In the years ahead, we can
be sure of two things:
1. Interest rates will vary, and
2. they will increase if inflation appears to be headed higher or decrease if
inflation is expected to decline.
Self Test