Econ2011 - Chapter 11
Econ2011 - Chapter 11
Econ2011 - Chapter 11
Imperfect Competition
Imperfect competition - market structures with characteristics between those of PC and monopoly.
Assumptions:
1. Allow for varying degrees of competition
2. Allow for differentiated products
3. Allow for strategic behaviour
This means that there is an incentive for firms to engage in collusion or to form a cartel. This occurs when firms coordinate and collectively
act as a monopoly to gain monopoly profits.
Inverse demand: P = 20 - Q and the new price is $11, total profits will be $63
Oligopoly with Identical Goods: Bertrand Competition (firms that chooses the price of its products and not quantity)
1. Firms sell identical products
2. The firms compete by choosing the price at which they sell their products
3. The firms set their prices simultaneously
*In another words: if your price is lower than your competitor, you will capture the whole market and vice versa. The only way to sell
Playstations is to match or beat your competitor
Even though competition is imperfect, in Bertrand competition, market equilibrium is identical to perfect competition and P=MC and
firms earn zero profit.
Oligopoly with Identical Goods: Cournot Competition (firms focus on the quantity decision)
1. Firms make identical products.
2. Firms compete by choosing a quantity to produce
3. All goods sell for the market price, which is determined by the sum of quantities produced by all firms in the market
4. Firms choose quantities simultaneously.
Mathematically:
-Substitute one firm's reaction curve into the other
The both have identical production costs, Iran will also produce 20million barrels per day and the market price will be:
Finally, we can compute the profits earned by both Saudi Arabia and Iran:
If Saudis expect Iran to produce 10million barrels per day, they face the inverse demand curve (similar mechanics to Stackelberg, just that
we already know how many of units the "first-mover" will produce beforehand)
Leftover demand: Residual demand curve. This is the demand remaining for a firm's output given competitor firms' production quantities
Add up Qsa and Qi to get the industry quantity. Plug it back into the inverse demand curve to get the market price. Now with the market
price, we can find each firm's profit.
Similarly, a residual marginal revenue curve is a marginal revenue curve corresponding to a residual demand curve.
What happens if there are more than two firms in a Cournot Oligopoly?
-The more firms there are, the closer these outcomes get to the perfectly competitive case with P=MC and economic profits being zero.
Each company has an incentive to try to choose its output level first and force its competitors to be the one who has to react. The firms
firm could increase its output ignoring what the Cournot Theory say what they should. Because the competitor's reaction curve slopes
downwards in this case, the other competitor seeing the high quantity the original firm is producing, would want to reduce its output. This
is a first-mover advantage in the market.
From the example above, suppose Saudi Arabia is a Stackelberg leader and chooses the quantity first, what will SA do with this first-mover
advantage?
*This is found by plugging in the reaction curve of Iran equation into the inverse demand curve of Saudi Arabia
We did this because SA recognizes that by going first, its output choice affect its demand and therefore its MR both directly and indirectly
through its effect on Iran's production decision.
As the first-mover, SA finds it optimal to producer 30million bpd, 10million more than the Cournot oligopoly output of 20million bpd.
To find how SA's decision affects Iran's optimal production level. Plug SA's output level into Iran's reaction curve:
Iran now produces only 15million bpd rather than 20 as in the Cournot case. By moving first, SA gets the jump on Iran, leaving Iran no
choice but to drop its output level from 20 to 15 million bpd.
Therefore total production is 45million bpd in the Stackelberg case. This is more than the output produced in the Cournot Oligopoly
(40million). Because production is higher, the market price must belower under the sequential production decisions than under Cournot's
simultaneous-decision framework. Specifically, the price is 200 - 3 (30+15) = $65 per barrel instead of the Cournot equilibrium price of $80
Profit for SA 30 x (65-20) = $1,350 million/day which is $150 million more than its $1200 million/day profit in the Cournot oligopoly. =>
Advantage of being the first-mover
Profit for Iran 15 X (65-20) = $675 million per day, which is well below the Cournot Profit level of $1200 million per day.
Consider the following demand curves for the two companies' ( Burton and K2 ) snowboard, where price is measured in dollars:
As the price of Burton snowboards increases, Burton is in less demand but K2 is in greater demand and vice versa.
These are the reaction curves for Burton and K2: as the competitor's price rises, their own price rises.
This is the opposite of quantity reaction in Cournot competition since the reaction curves are in terms of the opponent's price)
Graphically:
*Producer surplus will not be affected by the change in cost since its difference between the market PRICE and the PRICE producers willing
to receive.
Suppose a second firm notices the profitability of operating a fast-food restaurant in this town. With no barriers to entry, the second firm
opens a restaurant.
This model has no strategic response to the behaviour of rivals, it is solely based on the profits and the barrier to enter and exit.
BUT P =/= MC
Firms always face a downward sloping demand curve, entry will occur until demand is tangent with the AC and that is the point where
economic is exhausted.
2. Cournot Competition
1) Replace total demand (Qa + Qb) as Q into the market inverse demand curve
2) Derive EACH FIRM's marginal revenue curve (2 equations)
3) Set EACH FIRM's MR to MC to maximize profit and obtain each firm's reaction curve (2 equations)
4) To solve for equilibrium - substitute one reaction curve into another
5) Substitute quantities back into inverse demand curve to get the market price
6) Profit = TR - TC
3. Stackelberg Competition
1) Get reaction curves for each firm (MR = MC)
2) Substitute the "slow-mover" reaction curve into the inverse market demand (Inverse demand for first-mover) with Q as Qslow
and Qfirst mover
3) Derive to get MR for first-mover and equate with MC to get the profit maximizing output
4) Substitute into slow-mover's reaction curve to find the quantity produced by the slow mover
5) Substitute both quantities into market demand curve to find the market price
6) Profit = TR - TC
5. Monopolistic Competition
1) Profit maximizing output MC = MR
2) Plug the output back into the demand curve to find the profit maximizing price
3) Profit = TR-TC
4) Long run equilibrium : zero economic profit (so firms will be bearing fixed costs)