The Phillips Curve: Background
The Phillips Curve: Background
The Phillips Curve: Background
The Phillips curve shows the relationship between unemployment and inflation in an
economy. Since its ‘discovery’ by British economist AW Phillips, it has become an essential
tool to analyse macro-economic policy.
After 1945, fiscal demand management became the general tool for managing the trade cycle.
The consensus was that policy makers should stimulate aggregate demand (AD) when faced
with recession and unemployment, and constrain it when experiencing inflation. It was also
generally believed that economies faced either inflation or unemployment, but not together -
and whichever existed would dictate which macro-economic policy objective to pursue at any
given time. In addition, the accepted wisdom was that it was possible to target one objective,
without having a negative effect on the other. However, following publication of Phillips’
research in 1958, both of these assumptions were called into question.
The curve suggested that changes in the level of unemployment have a direct and predictable
effect on the level of price inflation. The accepted explanation during the 1960’s was that a
fiscal stimulus, and increase in AD, would trigger the following sequence of responses:
During the 1960s and 70s, it was common practice for governments around the world to
select a rate of inflation they wished to achieve, and then expand or contract the economy to
obtain this target rate. This policy became known as stop-go, and relied strongly on fiscal
policy to create the expansions and contractions required.
By the mid 1970s, it appeared that the Phillips Curve trade off no longer existed - there no
longer seemed a stable pattern. The stable relationship between unemployment and inflation
appeared to have broken down. It was possible to have a number of inflation rates for any
given unemployment rate.
American economists Friedman and Phelps offered one explanation - namely that there is not
one Phillips curve, but a series of short run Phillips Curves and a long run Phillips Curve,
which exists at the natural rate of unemployment (NRU). Indeed, in the long-run, there is no
trade-off between unemployment and inflation.
Assume that the economy starts from an equilibrium position at point A, with inflation
currently at zero, and unemployment at the natural rate of 10% (NRU = 10%). Secondly,
given the public’s concern with unemployment, assume the government attempts to expand
the economy quickly by way of a fiscal (or monetary) stimulus, so that AD increases and
unemployment falls.
Initially, the economy moves to B, and there is a fall in unemployment to 3% (at U 1) as jobs
are created in the short term. Having more bargaining power, workers bid-up their nominal
wages. As wage costs rise, prices are driven-up to 2% (at P 1). The effects of the stimulus to
AD quickly wear out as inflation erodes any gains by households and firms. Real spending
and output return to their previous levels, at the NRU.
According to the new-Classical view, what happens next depends upon whether the price
inflation has been understood and expected – in which case there is no money illusion – or
whether it is not expected – in which case, money illusion exists. If workers have bid-up their
wages in nominal terms only, they have suffered from money illusion, falsely believing they
will be better off – in this case, the economy will move back to point A at the NRU, but with
inflation only a temporary phenomenon. However, if they understand that price inflation will
erode the value of their nominal wage increases, they will bargain for a wage rise that
compensates them for the price rise. Again, the economy will move back to the NRU (with
unemployment at 10%), but this time carrying with it the embedded inflation rate of 2% an
move to point C. The economy will hop to SRPC2 (which has a higher level of expected
inflation – i.e. 2%, rather than 0%). Any further attempt to expand the economy by increasing
AD will move the economy temporarily to D. However, in the long-run the economy will
inevitably move back to the NRU.
The conclusion drawn was that any attempt to push unemployment below its natural rate
would cause accelerating inflation, with no long-term job gains. The only way to reverse this
process would be to raise unemployment above the NRU so that workers revised their
expectations of inflation downwards, and the economy moved to a lower short-run Phillips
curve