Behemoth. A History of The Factory de Joshua B. Freeman
Behemoth. A History of The Factory de Joshua B. Freeman
Behemoth. A History of The Factory de Joshua B. Freeman
Joshua B. Freeman
As always,
for Debbie, Julia, and Lena
Rereading your book has made me regretfully aware of our increasing age. How
freshly and passionately, with what bold anticipations, and without learned and
systematic, scholarly doubts, is the thing still dealt with here! And the very illusion
that the result will leap into the daylight of history tomorrow or the day after gives
the whole thing a warmth and vivacious humour—compared with which the later
“gray in gray” makes a damned unpleasant contrast.
At sea, the sailors … manufacture a clumsy sort of twine, called spun-yarn… . For
material, they use odds and ends of old rigging called “junk,” the yarn of which are
picked to pieces, and then twisted into new combinations, something as most
books are manufactured.
—Herman Melville,
Redburn: His First Voyage (1849)
Contents
INTRODUCTION
CHAPTER 1
CHAPTER 2
CHAPTER 3
CHAPTER 4
“I WORSHIP FACTORIES”
Fordism, Labor, and the Romance of the Giant Factory
CHAPTER 5
CHAPTER 7
“FOXCONN CITY”
Giant Factories in China and Vietnam
CONCLUSION
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS
NOTES
ILLUSTRATION CREDITS
INDEX
INTRODUCTION
The first factories were built not out of grand social visions but to
take advantage of mundane commercial opportunities. The Lombes
put up their factory to profit from a shortage of organzine, a kind of
silk yarn used for warp. To make cloth, yarn, called the weft, is
woven over and under a crossing set of yarns, called the warp.
Because alternate strands of warp are repeatedly pulled up to allow
the weft to be pushed through, they need to be stronger. To make
organzine, long threads produced by silkworms were wound into
skeins. These had to be put onto bobbins, twisted, “doubled” with
other threads, and then twisted again to make yarn, a process
known as silk throwing. While on the continent machines were being
used to throw silk, in England it was done using spinning wheels, a
process too slow to meet the demand from weavers.
In 1704, a Derby barrister built a three-storied, water-powered
mill to house imported Dutch silk-throwing machines, but he proved
unable to produce quality yarn. Thomas Lombe, a local textile dealer,
tried next, sending his half brother John to northern Italy to study the
methods used there. Defying laws banning the disclosure of
information about the construction of silk-throwing machinery, he
returned with several Italian workers and enough information for the
Lombes, working with a local engineer, to build and equip their
factory. Children apparently did much of the work inside.
Thomas Lombe claimed that his mill was never a great success,
in part because of his difficulty in getting raw silk from Italy. This may
have been a strategy to discourage competitors and convince
Parliament to extend the patent he took out on his machines.
Instead, in 1732 the British government, to promote industrial
development, gave Lombe a large cash payment in return for making
public a model of his machinery.4
The factory system spread slowly. In 1765 there were just seven
mills producing organzine, though one, near Manchester, by the end
of the century had two thousand workers, a gigantic enterprise by
contemporary standards. More common were smaller mills using
power-driven machinery to produce tram, a weaker type of silk
thread used for weft.5
While entrepreneurs, driven by practical calculations, moved
cautiously in following the Lombes’ footsteps, observers almost
immediately recognized the novelty and importance of the Derby
mill. Daniel Defoe visited the factory—“a vast Bulk”—in the 1720s,
declaring it “a Curiosity of a very extraordinary Nature.” Like Charles
Dickens’s Thomas Gradgrind, fictional archetype of the early
industrial age, Defoe, in the face of this modern marvel, fell back
upon “Fact, fact, fact!” “nothing but Facts!” Anticipating the gee-whiz
wonder of so many future descriptions of large factories, he
recounted how the Lombe machinery “contains 26,586 Wheels and
97,746 Movements, which work 73,726 Yards of Silk-thread, every
time the Water-wheel goes round, which is three times in one
Minute, and 318,504,960 Yards in One Day and Night.”6 James
Boswell, who visited the same mill a half century later, in the stream
of tourists who came to see this new thing under the sun, more
tersely described the machinery as “an agreeable surprize.”7
Alone, the Derby mill might have remained “a Curiosity of a very
extraordinary Nature.” But it turned out to be the opening of the
factory age. In its wake came ever more factories, which would
radically transform the British economy and ultimately world society.
The large factory would prove to be the leading edge and the leading
symbol of a broader Industrial Revolution that created the world we
live in.
Cotton
The lasting importance of the Lombes’ factory was not as a template
for silk mills but as a template for cotton mills. Limited demand,
foreign competition, and difficulty obtaining suitable raw material
restricted British silk production. But cotton was a different story,
becoming the driving force for the Industrial Revolution and the
creation of the factory system we still use today.
Cotton cloth, used for clothing and decoration, long predated the
first British cotton mills. By the sixteenth century, textiles produced in
India by spinners and weavers working at home with simple, hand-
powered equipment were being exported to Europe, West Africa,
and the Americas. A century later, they had become a truly global
commodity.8
Until the late seventeenth century, it would have been rare to
have seen someone in Europe wearing cotton clothes; imported
cotton textiles were used largely for household decoration. Most
clothing was made out of other fibers: wool, flax, hemp, or silk.9 But
the quality and variety of cotton cloth soon made it a favorite for
European garments. With increasing population and rising income
pushing up demand, local merchants tried to take over at least some
of the processes for making cotton textiles from foreign producers,
an early example of what would later be called import substitution.10
Instead of importing calicos—cotton cloth with printed patterns—
European traders began buying plain white Indian cloth, which they
had decorated by local artisans. By the mid-eighteenth century,
large-scale calico printing shops, some with hundreds of workers,
were operating in various parts of Europe.11 English merchants also
began weaving imported cotton yarn with flax to produce fustians.12
In 1774, Britain ended restrictions on producing and decorating
all-cotton textiles, earlier put into place to protect the silk and wool
industries. Deregulation, along with fustian production, contributed to
ballooning demand for cotton yarn.13 Merchants, artisans, and
entrepreneurs set out to capture the market with locally produced
product. But the obstacles they faced were considerable.
Simply getting enough raw cotton was the first problem. Indian
producers used Indian-grown cotton, but the European climate was
unsuitable for its cultivation. In the late eighteenth century, Britain
imported cotton from all over the world, including Asia and various
parts of the Ottoman Empire. Supply lagged behind demand, leading
to the increasing cultivation of cotton in the Americas using slave
labor, first in the West Indies and South America and then, after the
introduction of Eli Whitney’s cotton gin (patented in 1794), in the
southern United States. By the early nineteenth century, over 90
percent of the cotton used in Britain was grown by slaves in the
Americas. As British textile production exploded, cotton growers in
the United States moved westward into the Mississippi River valley,
where a brutal empire arose on the labor of enslaved Africans (“food
for the cotton-field,” Frederick Douglass called them). Thus, the rise
of the factory system, with its association with modernity, was utterly
dependent on the spread of slave labor. “Without slavery you have
no cotton; without cotton you have no modern industry,” wrote Karl
Marx—an overstatement, but one with much truth.14
The technical demands of turning raw cotton into weft and warp
presented a second challenge. As Edward Baines wrote in his 1835
History of the Cotton Manufacture in Great Britain, whereas “silk
needs only that the threads spun by the worm should be twisted
together, to give them the requisite strength,” “[c]otton, flax, and
wool, having short and slender filaments, require to be spun into a
thread before they can be woven into cloth.” The raw cotton used in
Britain had individual fibers generally less than an inch long. To
convert it into yarn it had to be “carded,” combed to pull apart the
fibers and line them up in parallel to create a “sliver.” Slivers were
then drawn out to a prescribed thickness (“roving”) and twisted to
gain strength. Both the last step and all the processes together were
called “spinning.”15
Until the 1760s, spinning was a domestic industry, with men
doing the heavy work of carding, while women used spinning wheels
to create finished yarn and children helped out in various ways. As
Blaines noted, “the machines used . . . were nearly as simple as
those of India.” However, it cost more to produce cotton yarn in
Britain than in India and the quality was lower, too fragile to use as
warp. And there was not enough of it; it took at least three spinners
along with a few ancillary workers to keep one weaver (generally
male) in yarn, meaning weavers often had to go beyond their own
household for supplies, a problem exacerbated by the introduction of
the flying shuttle in the 1730s, which greatly increased weaving
productivity.16
Conditions were ripe for a radical change. Expanding fustian,
hosiery, and cotton textile production ensured inventors and
investors a payoff if they could increase the output, improve the
quality, and lower the cost of cotton yarn. Merchant entrepreneurs
already had experience with large-scale production through their
organization of extensive networks of domestic spinners and
weavers, who were given raw materials by a central agent to make
specific types of yarn or cloth and paid by the piece. Though the
banking system in the textile districts had limited financial and
technical capacity, manufacturers, merchants, and landed gentry had
capital resources to back new enterprises. A large, underemployed
agricultural workforce constituted a potential labor pool for large-
scale industry.17
In the last decades of the eighteenth century, English inventors,
artisans, and merchant manufacturers developed a series of
machines to boost the quality and quantity of locally produced cotton
yarn. James Hargreaves developed the first mechanical spinning
device in 1764, the jenny. It proved of limited use, since it could only
produce weft and required a skilled worker to operate. Richard
Arkwright was more successful. A tinkerer, who had had his ups and
downs as a barber, wig maker, and public house owner, Arkwright
applied for a patent on a spinning machine in 1768 and seven years
later for carding equipment. With partners, he first built a mill in
Nottingham that used horses to power spinning machines. He soon
switched to water power, long used for sawmills, grain mills, mineral-
crushing mills, and paper mills, building a factory in Cromford, an
isolated spot sixteen miles up the River Derwent from where the
Lombes had built their mill. Once he perfected his carding and
spinning machinery, Arkwright and various partners built additional
factories along the Derwent and then elsewhere. Arkwright’s profits
from his mills and royalties from his patents made him a very rich
man.18
In part to circumvent Arkwright’s patents, other carding and
spinning machines were developed, including Samuel Crompton’s
spinning mule, giving those seeking to go into cotton yarn
manufacturing a choice of equipment, some better suited for warp
and some for weft. The boosts in productivity were startling: the
earliest jennies increased output per worker sixfold or more, while
Arkwright’s equipment, once perfected, proved several hundredfold
more efficient. In the late eighteenth century, the first power looms
for weaving were introduced, mechanizing the next step in textile
production. The early looms had many problems and could produce
only low-quality fabric. As a result, hand-weaving remained dominant
in cotton production until the 1820s and even later in worsted and
wool. But with incremental improvements, power looms gradually
became the norm in virtually all forms of weaving.19
Arkwright’s Nottingham mill employed three hundred workers,
about the same number as the Lombes’. His first mill in Cromford
was smaller, with about two hundred employees, mostly children. A
second mill he put up in Cromford had eight hundred workers.
Jedidiah Strutt, a hosiery manufacturer and early partner of
Arkwright’s, erected a mill complex in Belper, seven miles south of
Cromford, that employed 1,200 to 1,300 workers by 1792, 1,500 in
1815, and 2,000 by 1833. The complex of mills in New Lanark,
Scotland, which Arkwright helped build but Robert Owen and his
partners took over, had 1,600 to 1,700 workers in 1816. By then,
steam-powered cotton mills were being erected in urban areas, with
several factories in Manchester employing over a thousand workers.
The giant factory had arrived.20
Figure 1.2 English inventor and entrepreneur Sir Richard Arkwright in 1835.
Factory Tourism
Although recent scholarship has debunked the idea that the factory
system arose from the genius of a few inventors and entrepreneurs
who changed everything, drawing a subtler picture of economic and
social changes that began long before the Industrial Revolution took
off, the Industrial Revolution nonetheless was a revolution, and seen
as such at the time. Contemporary observers had no doubt that the
cotton mill and the changes it wrought represented a technical,
economic, and social break from the past. From the late eighteenth
century on, factories, factory villages, and manufacturing cities drew
tourists, journalists, and philanthropists from continental Europe and
North America as well as Great Britain itself.47 Part of the attraction
was their novelty. W. Cooke Taylor, the son of an Irish manufacturer
who toured the industrial districts of Lancaster in the early 1840s,
wrote that “The steam-engine had no precedent, the spinning-jenny
is without ancestry, the mule and the power-loom entered on no
prepared heritage: they sprung into sudden existence like Minerva
from the brain of Jupiter.”48
The scale and setting of mill buildings, whether in rural river
valleys or crowded industrial cities, startled visitors. British poet
laureate Robert Southey wrote that the approach to the New Lanark
mills reminded him “of the descent upon the baths of Monchique,”
built by the Romans in southern Portugal. Like many other
observers, Southey searched for precedents to understand the
novelty he confronted. The view, he wrote, surprised him because
there was “too a regular appearance” of the buildings, which “at a
distance might be mistaken for convents, if in a Catholic country.”
Alexis de Tocqueville, who visited Manchester in 1835, likened mills
to “huge palaces,” a common comparison in a world with few secular
structures of such scale. One German visitor to northern England
wrote that he “might have arrived in Egypt since so many factory
chimneys . . . stretch upwards towards the sky like great obelisks.”
“Just when they seem engaged in revolutionizing themselves and
things, in creating something that has never yet existed,” Marx wrote
three decades after Southey visited New Lanark, “precisely in such
period of revolutionary crisis,” people “anxiously conjure up the
spirits of the past to their service and borrow from them names,
battle cries, and costumes in order to present the new scene of world
history in this time-honored disguise and this borrowed language.”49
Even more than mill buildings themselves, the machinery they
contained mesmerized visitors. In Michael Armstrong, Trollope wrote
of visitors being given a mill tour: “It is the vast, the beautiful, the
elaborate machinery by which they were surrounded that called forth
all their attention, and all their wonder. The uniform ceaseless
movement, sublime in its sturdy strength and unrelented activity,
drew every eye, and rapt the observer’s mind in boundless
admiration of the marvelous power of science!” Trollope bemoaned
the visitors’ inattention to the child laborers nearby: “Strangers do not
visit factories to look at them; it is the triumphant perfection of British
mechanism which they come to see.” French socialist and feminist
Flora Tristan wrote of a steam engine she saw in England: “In the
presence of the monster, you have eyes and ears for nothing else.”50
The modernity of the mills dazzled observers. To lengthen hours
of operation, in the early nineteenth century mill owners began
installing gaslights, a spectacle that drew visitors from near and far.
In Hard Times, Dickens described morning in “Coketown” as “The
Fairy palaces burst into illumination.” The size of the mills and
accompanying warehouses even made possible new types of
entertainment. Sam Scott drew an immense Manchester crowd in
1837 when he leapt off the roof of a five-story warehouse into the
River Irwell, surviving to repeat the stunt in Bolton. Another
daredevil, James Duncan Wright, attracted even larger crowds in the
1850s with his act of using a pulley to slide down ropes attached to
mill chimneys, which he claimed made him the fastest man alive.51
Figure 1.3 Carding, Drawing, and Roving, a somewhat idealized 1835 illustration
of English factory life.
In the early decades, mill owners generally ran their factories day
and night, with two twelve- or thirteen-hour shifts (including an hour
break for dinner), following the schedule pioneered by the Derby Silk
Mill. Children worked both shifts. With Sunday the only day off,
workweeks of over seventy hours were normal. To keep exhausted
children awake and working, supervisors and adult workers hit them
with straps, hands, and even wooden poles (though there was much
debate about how common such abuse was).55
Perhaps not surprisingly, early mill owners often found
themselves unable to fully staff their mills with willing workers. So
some turned to unwilling workers. Workhouses—the prisonlike
residences of last resort for orphans and the destitute—were tapped
for child workers, whom parish officials apprenticed to mill owners,
giving them full legal authority over their charges and making it a
criminal act for the children to run away. In Yorkshire, it was not
uncommon for 70 percent or more of a mill’s workforce to be parish
apprentices. At New Lanark, before Robert Owen took over
management, some of the apprentices were as young as five years
old. Ordinary apprentices, signed up by their parents, also could be
jailed for running away. So could workers who signed fixed-term
contracts if they quit before their termination date. Further, an 1823
law made any worker who left his or her job without notice liable to
three months imprisonment. Thus the power of the state helped
assemble and keep in place a workforce for the new factory system.
What’s more, it was not uncommon for the state and an employer to
effectively be one and the same, since mill owners sometimes
served as magistrates who judged cases of desertion involving their
own workers.56 Legally unfree labor, not only in the growing of cotton
but in the mills themselves, played an essential role in the early
decades of the factory system.
Today, in popular discourse and mainstream ideology, the
Industrial Revolution is often associated with individual liberty and
what is called the free market.57 But in the early years of the factory
system, it was as likely to be dubbed a new form of slavery as a new
form of freedom. Joseph Livesey, a well-known journal publisher and
temperance campaigner, himself the son of a mill owner, wrote of the
apprenticed children he saw in mills during his childhood, “They were
apprenticed to a system to which nothing but West Indian slavery
can bear any analogy.”58 In The Life and Adventures of Michael
Armstrong, Trollope wrote that apprenticed paupers suffered
“miserable lives, in labour and destitution, incomparably more
severe, than any ever produced by negro slavery.” In its structure,
Michael Armstrong is a version of the slave rescue narrative,
recounting the frustrated efforts of the heroine, the rich daughter of a
factory owner, to liberate Armstrong from his villainous
apprenticeship at an isolated factory and his ultimate escape.59
The metaphor of slavery for factory labor no doubt reflected the
intense debate over slavery itself during the early decades of the
nineteenth century, leading up to emancipation in the British Empire
in 1834. Still, it was a measure of how horrifying factory labor was
seen to be that so many observers equated it with chattel slavery.
One self-described “Journeyman Cotton Spinner” wrote of the
terrible heat in spinning rooms, where workers had no breaks: “The
negro slave in the West Indies, if he works under a scorching sun,
has probably a little breeze of air sometimes to fan him; he has a
space of ground, and time allowed to cultivate it. The English spinner
slave has not enjoyment of the open atmosphere and breezes of
heaven.” Engels, writing of English textile workers just a few years
after Trollope, believed “Their slavery is more abject than that of the
negroes in America because they are more strictly supervised.” He
also bemoaned that, as in slavery, the wives and daughters of
workers were forced to gratify the “base desires” of manufacturers.
Elsewhere, Engels compared workers under the factory system to
“the Saxon serf under the whip of the Norman baron.” Similarly, in
Benjamin Disraeli’s novel Sybil, or the Two Nations, one character
pronounces that “There are great bodies of the working classes of
this country nearer the condition of brutes than they have been at
any time since the Conquest.” Richard Oastler entitled his 1830 letter
in the Leeds Mercury, which launched the Ten Hours Movement to
reduce factory working hours, “Yorkshire Slavery.”60
For Robert Southey, the association of slavery with the factory
system did not stem from particular abuses but from the nature of
the system itself. Calling the New Lanark mills under Owen, who
even before his radical turn was known for his humane treatment of
workers, “perfect of their kind,” he nonetheless felt that “Owen in
reality deceives himself. He is part-owner and sole Director of a large
establishment, differing more in accidents than in essence from a
plantation: the persons under him happen to be white, and are at
liberty by law to quit his service, but while they remain in it they are
as much under his absolute management as so many negro-slaves.”
The factory system, Southey believed, even at its best, tended “to
destroy individuality of character and domesticity.” At its worst it was
outright devilish; after visiting a Manchester cotton factory, he wrote
“that if Dante had peopled one of his hells with children, here was a
scene worthy to have supplied him with new images of torment.”61
Some critics of the factory system—and some defenders of
slavery—questioned the very distinction between free labor and
slavery, given the circumstances in which mill workers lived. British
laborers were “slaves of necessity,” wrote Samuel Martin in 1773,
unable to “mitigate their labours” or “increase their wages.” Owen
asked of factory operatives, “Are they, in anything but appearance,
really free labourers? . . . What alternative have they or what
freedom is there in this case, but the liberty of starving?”62 Here lay a
critique that went to the very heart of the spread of market relations,
part and parcel of the Industrial Revolution.
Besides the ill-treatment of labor, environmental despoilment
figured heavily in critiques of the factory system. Over and over
again, accounts of Manchester and other industrial centers noted the
darkness and foul air. Scottish geologist Hugh Miller wrote of
Manchester in 1845: “One receives one’s first intimation of its
existence from the lurid gloom of the atmosphere that overhangs it.”
Similarly, Cooke Taylor wrote, “I well remember the effect produced
on me . . . when I looked upon the town . . . and saw the forest of
chimneys pouring forth volumes of steam and smoke, forming an
inky canopy which seemed to embrace and involve the entire place.”
The air was so polluted, Taylor observed, that everyone who could
live outside Manchester proper did so.63 Major General Sir Charles
James Napier, appointed in 1839 to command the northern district of
England, which included Manchester, described the city as “the
entrance to hell realized,” with its rich and poor, immorality, and
pervasive pollution; the whole city, was “a chimney.”64
Water pollution was as severe as air pollution. Hugh Miller
recounted the befouling of the River Irwell from cloth dyes, sewage,
and other waste, so it resembled “considerably less a river than a
flood of liquid manure, in which all life dies.”65 Maybe the most
impressive aspect of Sam Scott’s leap was not the five-story drop
but his surviving the toxic brew into which he plunged.
The environmental damage of cotton manufacturing extended far
beyond mill sites themselves. Cotton growing required deforestation
and it rapidly depleted soil, one reason why in the United States it
migrated (along with its slave labor force) from the eastern seaboard
to the Mississippi Valley. Coal mining polluted rivers and scarred the
landscape.66
Worker Protest
Journalists, critics, government investigating committees, novelists,
even poets, almost all from the middle or upper classes, poured out
a flood of words about the factory system during the first half of the
nineteenth century. By contrast, we have only a tiny corpus of
appraisals from workers themselves, most of whom, if not illiterate,
had little occasion or capacity to record their thoughts in forms that
would receive much attention or survive through the years.85 To the
extent we can reconstruct the attitude of workers toward the factory
system, we have to do so largely by looking at their actions, not their
words.
One relevant word, though, was brought into the English
language by workers, “Luddite.” Today “Luddite” is widely used as a
catchword for technophobes, opponents of machine-based
advancement, stripped from its original context.86 The word came
from the bands of workers and their supporters who in 1811 and
1812 and again from 1814 to 1817 attacked textile machinery, mills,
and mill owners in the Midlands and in northern England, claiming
they were acting under the command of General (or sometimes
Captain or King) Ned Ludd.
Britain had a long history of machine-breaking as a form of
protest and pressure, which predated the Luddites and continued
after them. In the textile industry alone, incidents of machine
wrecking occurred as early as 1675, with an attack on silk-weaving
machines, and continued through the 1820s with periodic assaults
on cotton equipment. Both Hargreaves and Arkwright had early
installations of their machines destroyed by mobs, leading Arkwright
to design his Cromford complex to be easily defended, with building
placements, walls, and gates restricting access.87 But the Luddites
represented a more extensive, threatening, and enthralling episode
of machine breaking than anything before or after.
Luddite attacks generally were preceded by letters threatening
the destruction of machines and buildings and even murder unless
employers met specified demands. An 1811 letter, apparently sent to
a hosier named Edward Hollingsworth, read (as transcribed from the
damaged original) “Sir if you do not pull don the Frames or stop pay
[in] Goods onely for work or m[ake] Full fason my Company will [vi]sit
yr machines for execution agai[nst] [y]ou. . . ,” signed “Ned Lu[d].”88
The framework knitters, who made stockings, lace, and other
woven goods on looms they sometimes owned but often rented from
merchant-hosiers, were the first group of Luddites to go into action.
To cut labor costs, merchants increased the rent and introduced wide
looms, on which, instead of making a single item, large pieces of
knitted material could be produced and then cut and sewed to make
cheap goods, including stockings. Also, many merchants began
paying in truck rather than cash. Faced with declining income and
what they saw as the debasement of their trade, the frameworkers
rallied under the banner of the mythical General Ludd, targeting wide
frames and merchants who were cutting wages. Over the course of a
year, an estimated one thousand knitting frames in Nottinghamshire,
Leicestershire, and Derbyshire were destroyed. It took the passage
of a law making framebreaking a capital crime to halt the attacks.
The “croppers” in West Riding, Yorkshire, formed a second
battalion in King Ludd’s army. Croppers did the final, highly skilled
finishing work on woven wool, raising the nap and using large,
heavy, hand shears to cut and even the surface. The introduction of
gig mills, to raise the nap, and shearing frames, to trim it, threatened
to eliminate cropping as a skilled, well-paid craft. After trying
unsuccessfully to use lawsuits and parliamentary lobbying to check
the advance of the new machines, the croppers took to armed
attacks on mills housing the machinery, including a successful
assault by some three hundred Luddites on a mill near Leeds and an
armed battle at a mill in Rawfolds that left two Luddites dead (and
provided the plot for Shirley). Soon after, a particularly hated mill
owner was assassinated. To restore order, four thousand troops
were sent to occupy West Riding.89
In Lancashire, a third eruption of worker violence broke out,
including food riots and assaults on mills using steam-powered
weaving equipment. The mill attacks—including one by a crowd of
over a hundred, marching behind a straw effigy of General Ludd,
which burned down a mill owner’s house before being fired on by a
military unit, killing at least seven protesters—reflected the impact of
mechanization on the hand-loom weavers. Initially, the factory
system led to boom times for handweavers, as spinning machinery
produced a bountiful supply of cheap yarn and a growing demand for
weavers. The hand-loom workforce probably exceeded a half million
between 1820 and 1840, outnumbering all factory textile workers.
But the weavers’ “golden age,” as E. P. Thompson called it, was
short-lived. The entrepreneurs who supplied the weavers with yarn
and bought their products pressed down wages, even before power
mills began providing substantial competition. Once they did, the
downward pressure on wages and living standards became horrific,
as mass impoverishment—sometimes literal starvation—descended
on the weavers and their families. Looking back from not long after
power weaving finally all but eliminated hand work, Marx wrote that
“History discloses no tragedy more horrible than the gradual
extinction of the English hand-loom weavers.” And it was not just in
England that the incorporation of weaving into the factory system
took its toll; governor-general of India William Bentinck reported in
1834–35 “The bones of the cotton-weavers are bleaching the plains
of India.”90
Luddism, though the focus for much of the debate about
industrialization, for the most part was only indirectly connected,
when connected at all, to the giant factories that had popped up
since the late eighteenth century. Hosiery knitting generally occurred
in modest-sized workshops. Wool finishing likewise generally did not
take place in massive mills. Only the attacks on power looms
occurred on the terrain of the factory behemoth.
Luddites generally were more concerned with particular
grievances against particular employers than with abstract
opposition to technology. Some machine wrecking was part of a
tradition of what Eric Hobsbawm called “collective bargaining by riot,”
using the destruction of property to pressure employers to raise
wages and make other concessions. Many of the Luddites
themselves operated machinery, albeit hand-powered, and most
depended on factory-produced yarn for their livelihoods.91
Rather than as an expression of opposition to machinery or the
mill system, Luddism is better understood as one of many forms of
protest against the miseries workers—in factories, competing with
them, and not engaged with them at all—experienced during the
helter-skelter industrialization of the first half of the nineteenth
century. Worker action took the forms that it did in part because other
forms of collective activity were blocked. The concentration of
workers in factories and urban neighborhoods created a critical mass
for political discussion and labor organization, the context in which
“The working-class made itself,” as Thompson famously wrote.92 But
the outlets for action were limited.
Workers were shut out of direct participation in governance
through most of the nineteenth century, with women and working-
class men excluded from voting during the decades when the factory
emerged as a key social institution. Workers did seek redress from
Parliament, proposing laws, gathering signatures on petitions,
testifying at commission hearings, and sending delegations to lobby
members, but generally with scant results. The demand of the
Chartists, who led massive popular mobilizations in the 1830s and
1840s, for universal male suffrage and the democratization of
Parliament, fell on deaf ears.93
The government also severely limited the ability of workers to join
together to pressure employers to improve wages and conditions. In
reaction to the late eighteenth-century growth of proto-trade unions
(among nonfactory workers) and the fear among British rulers,
brought on by the French Revolution, of any type of radicalism or
popular action, Parliament passed a series of laws—most
importantly the 1800 Combination Act—against worker organization.
Between 1792 and 1815, the government built 155 military barracks
in industrial areas.94
In spite of legal prohibitions, workers formed open and secret
organizations, held strikes, and joined in marches and mass
demonstrations. The 1810s saw the first substantial walkouts by
factory workers, some involving thousands of cotton spinners. The
government reaction was heavy-handed, arresting, imprisoning, and
transporting to the colonies leading activists and, in the case of some
Luddites, hanging them. When in 1819 some sixty thousand
protestors gathered in Manchester to demand democratic reforms, a
military unit made up of local manufacturers, merchants, and
storeowners charged the peaceful crowd, killing eleven people and
leaving hundreds wounded in the so-called Peterloo Massacre. The
government response was to pass still more repressive legislation,
among other things banning meetings with more than fifty people
present.
The 1820s brought yet more strikes, machine breaking, and
reform campaigns, followed in the 1830s by a massive push to win
legislation limiting factory working hours. In 1842 came a widespread
strike among mill workers and miners, called the Plug Riots because
strikers removed the plugs from steam engines, rendering them
inoperable. By the 1850s, larger and more stable (though still mostly
local) unions began to form among textile workers. Some launched
large, prolonged, though generally unsuccessful strikes. Over a half
century after the first factory giants had been erected, in spite of
repeated, episodically large-scale efforts, the workers within them
still lacked any effective political or organizational method for
improving their lot or shaping the society in which they lived.95
Late eighteenth- and early nineteenth-century Great Britain often
has been portrayed as a freer society than continental Europe. Some
scholars, like Landes, suggest that this was one reason why the
Industrial Revolution took off there first.96 But for workers, especially
factory workers, Britain was far from a free society. Factories grew
up under an autocratic political regime, at least as far as it concerned
working people. Workers did not have the right to vote, they did not
have the right to assemble, they did not have the right to join
together to bargain collectively with their employers, they did not
have the right to quit their jobs whenever they wanted to, they did not
have the right to say whatever they thought. Nothing better
symbolized the support the state gave the emerging industrial
system than the hanging of workers for the crime of not attacking
persons but inanimate objects, breaking machines. Later to be
extolled as the triumph of a new kind of freedom, the factory system
was nurtured by severe restrictions on the rights of those whose
labor made it possible. It took—and continued to take—the
repressive power of the state to enable the giant factory to take root
in unbroken soil.97
Becoming Ordinary
In the second half of the nineteenth century, cotton mills became
less central to discussions and struggles about the structure of
British society and the shape of its future. For one thing, they were
no longer novel. By then, generations had grown up with large mills
as a part of the world they lived in. Other, newer marvels had taken
the lead as symbols of modernity, most importantly the railroad,
which drew extraordinary attention from writers, artists, and the
general public. In 1829 some ten to fifteen thousand people
assembled in Lancashire to watch a competitive test of newly
designed locomotives. The next year, when the first modern railway
line opened, linking Liverpool to Manchester, dignitaries filled the first
train and huge crowds lined the tracks. Trains became, as Tony Judt
put it, “modern life incarnate.”98
Textile mills no longer held first place, either, in sheer size, as
other types of worksites came to rival or exceed them. The railroad
system had a huge workforce, with some shops that built and
maintained equipment employing as many workers as large textile
mills. Other industries, especially metalworking, also built very large
plants. By the late 1840s, the Dowlais iron works in Wales employed
some seven thousand men in a complex that included eighteen blast
furnaces, puddling ovens, rolling mills, and mines, dwarfing even the
largest textile mill.”99
Changed economic and political circumstances also muted
attention to the textile factory. In the mid-nineteenth century, the
British economy began to significantly improve, with growing
international markets for English textiles contributing to increased
revenue and improved conditions for workers. Legislation also began
easing the lot of mill employees, especially the 1831 Truck Act,
which required workers to be paid in cash, the 1833 act regulating
child labor, and an 1847 law that limited the working day for children
and women in mills to ten hours, realizing a long-time goal of
working-class reformers. When Engels returned to Manchester in
1849, just seven years after he began research for what became
The Condition of the Working Class in England, he found a very
different city, more prosperous and peaceful. “The English
proletariat,” he complained, “is actually becoming more and more
bourgeois.”100
The transformation was as much political as economic. The
failure of the Chartists to win their demands, in spite of their huge
success in mobilizing support, took much of the wind out of the sails
of the radical movements. At the same time, Chartism, with its
emphasis on male suffrage, shifted attention away from female and
child mill workers to adult men: artisans, construction workers, and
other nonfactory laborers. The campaign against the Corn Laws,
which began in 1838 and triumphed eight years later, rearranged the
political terrain, too, in effect bringing workers and mill owners into
alliance against the landed gentry, at least on this one, much
debated issue. Further easing tensions, more mill owners began
adopting paternalist practices, which had been prevalent among
some of the earliest textile manufacturers, like Arkwright and Strutt,
but rejected by many others.101
Textile workers continued to protest conditions they faced in the
mills, but their struggles were no more prominent than those of
miners and other groups acting through unions. After the mid-
nineteenth century, the attention of middle-class reformers and
observers shifted away from the mill, even as conditions for mill
workers, though improved, remained often oppressive and child
labor, albeit slightly older, continued to be widely used into the
twentieth century. The questions surrounding the large textile mill
and the factory system it brought into being devolved into part of a
more general and less apocalyptic debate about the rights and
standards of labor. By the time Charlotte Brontë published Shirley in
1849, she viewed the great dramatic struggles over the factory
system as something from the past, with the large cotton mill having
been, all in all, a source of social betterment.102
By then, the giant cotton factory had led to new ways of
organizing production, new sets of social relations, and new ways of
thinking about the world. All but its most adamant defenders
recognized that in the short run the big factory had brought with it
massive human suffering, both among the workers in the mills and
those displaced by them. Yet for many, the mill held forth the promise
of a better world. In an unpublished article which would become the
basis of The Communist Manifesto, Friedrich Engels wrote:
“Precisely that quality of large-scale industry which in present society
produces all misery and all trade crises is the very quality which
under a different social organization will destroy that same misery
and these disastrous fluctuations.”103 For better and for worse, the
extraordinary social invention that first appeared with the Lombes’
mill and the early cotton spinning mills, the factory behemoth,
represented a giant leap toward a new world, our modernity.
CHAPTER 2
Lowell
Waltham established the model, but it was Lowell that became
famous. The Boston Manufacturing Company founded the city to
expand its capacity. After erecting a third mill in Waltham, the
company directors decided to build a new complex to produce
calicoes. Without enough water power in Waltham for additional
mills, company leaders found a site twenty-three miles north of
Boston, in what was then East Chelmsford, Massachusetts, where at
Pawtucket Falls the Merrimack River dropped thirty feet, unleashing
enormous energy.
Years earlier, a company called the Proprietors of Locks and
Canals on the Merrimack had built a canal around the falls to permit
navigation. Quietly, Boston Manufacturing bought up the stock of the
older company and land along the river. To launch the new
enterprise, in 1822 it created the Merrimack Manufacturing
Company, offering shares to its investors. Using Irish laborers, the
new company widened and deepened the existing canal and rebuilt
the locks to create mill sites with adequate power. At a time
preceding power equipment and dynamite, the infrastructure work,
along with building and equipping new mills, proved extremely
expensive. Only an assemblage of some of the richest men in New
England could have financed industrial development on this scale.18
The mills built at the new site—and others later modeled on them
—were much larger and more substantial than the early Rhode
Island factories. Handsome, durable brick structures, without much
ornament, they bore at least a superficial resemblance to the
Lombes’ mill, by then already a century old.19 Technical
considerations dictated their size and shape. The wooden shafts
used to convey power from waterwheels could be extended only so
long before breaking, no more than one hundred feet. Even after
builders began centering mills over their waterwheels, allowing
horizontal shafting on both sides, building length was limited. The
need to bring in light from perimeter windows restricted mill width. So
floor plates could not be very big, in the case of the Merrimack mills,
156 feet by 44½ feet. To create more space and fully utilize the
power of the waterwheels, mills were built up, in the Merrimack
model five stories high, including an attic and a basement. For
greater capacity, Merrimack and other textile companies built
multiple mills in clusters, sometimes arrayed around a central yard.
New England textile firms did not make much use of iron
structural elements until the 1840s. Cast iron was expensive in the
United States, while large wooden beams were readily available,
familiar to local construction workers, and capable of supporting
heavy weights and absorbing vibrations. Like the British, the
Americans worried about the danger of fire, but they adopted a
different approach to minimizing it, not attempting fireproof
construction by replacing wood with iron and brick but instead
seeking to retard the spread of flames by using very heavy timbers,
not only for beams but also for flooring, which would be slow to catch
fire and capable of continuing to support weight even if charred.
By 1825, Merrimack had completed five virtually identical mill
structures and additional buildings for bleaching and calico printing.
Each mill was self-contained, with both spinning and weaving
equipment, capable of turning raw cotton into woven cloth.20 As in
Waltham, the new mills proved quickly profitable; within two years of
commencing production, Merrimack paid its first dividend. To further
expand, its directors came up with a strategy of creating additional
firms, each of which would have its own stockholders and directors,
with heavy overlap in ownership from company to company. The
structure facilitated raising capital from new investors, while allowing
existing stockholders to withdraw money from older companies to
invest in new ones.
To advance the corporate metastasis, Merrimack transferred the
land and water power it did not need to a reconstituted Locks and
Canals company, which also took over the machine-shop operation
of Boston Manufacturing. Like the William Fairbairn’s company in
England, Locks and Canals could provide what today would be
called a turnkey facility. When new companies were formed—starting
with Hamilton Manufacturing in 1824, followed by Lowell
Manufacturing, Appleton Company, Lawrence Manufacturing, Boott
Mills, Suffolk Manufacturing, and Tremont Mills—Locks and Canals
sold them mill sites and machinery and provided water power
(usually for a per spindle fee).
Figure 2.1 An engraving of Lowell, Massachusetts, in the 1850s, featuring a
bucolic setting in the foreground.
Scaling Up
Even as the core group of textile investors—what economic historian
Vera Shlakman dubbed the “Boston Associates”—expanded their
production in Lowell by forming multiple corporations, they expanded
beyond Lowell by founding new mill towns across northern New
England. In Chicopee Falls, on the edge of Springfield,
Massachusetts, they helped launch four textile companies,
mimicking the Lowell pattern of having an additional company to
control land and water power and manufacture machinery. Other
complexes arose in Taunton and Holyoke, Massachusetts; Nashua
and Manchester, New Hampshire; and Saco and Biddeford, Maine.
In the mid-1840s, when Lowell itself ran out of mill sites, a group of
Boston investors developed a new town, Lawrence, nearby on the
Merrimack River, which became a major wool and cotton center. In a
few instances, the Boston group took over mills others had founded,
like the complex in Dover.24
The Boston Associates companies were genuinely Boston
companies. Their owners consisted largely of Boston residents who
had made their fortunes before their textile investments. Most rarely
visited their mills. Even companies with distant factories were run by
a treasurer who lived in Boston, operating through an on-site agent.
Selling and banking were done in Boston as well. The combination of
absentee ownership and workers largely recruited from afar meant
that the mills and mill towns often had few local roots. Industrial
capitalism—which in the United States, as in England, had the textile
industry at its lead—did not develop organically out of existing
communities but was implanted, fully formed, by outside merchant
capital.25
The textile complexes built by the Boston group dwarfed
contemporary factories. An 1832 federal survey found that of the
thirty-six manufacturing enterprises reporting more than 250
employees, thirty-one were textile companies. On the eve of the Civil
War, manufacturing establishments in the United States employed
on average only 9.34 workers. By contrast, Merrimack, the largest
Lowell company, in 1857 had 2,400 workers, while six other
companies in the city had over 1,000.26
Continuing growth, however, did not mean continuing innovation.
After an initial burst of inventiveness, the Boston-based mill owners
and managers proved a conservative lot, not introducing major
technological changes for decades. Until the mid-1840s, individual
mill buildings rarely exceeded by much the dimensions of the second
Waltham mill, each housing 250 to 300 workers. The companies
increased production by speeding up existing equipment and
building new mills using their well-established template. Able to
make a good return on their money by doing more of the same, the
Boston investors felt little need for novelty.27
The question of power provides a good illustration. With plentiful
water power, and coal farther away and more expensive than it was
for British mills, New England mill owners did not widely adopt steam
power until after the Civil War, long after it had become common in
England. As a result, New England mill towns had none of the black
smoke and soot so characteristic of British industry. When the
growth of Lowell and the planning of Lawrence presented the
possibility that companies on the Merrimack would run out of water
power, instead of installing steam engines the mill owners bought
real estate and water privileges at the outlet of Lake Winnipesaukee
in New Hampshire, over sixty miles away, to direct more water into
the river (outraging Ralph Waldo Emerson for what he saw as
arrogance).28
The corporate arrangements adopted by the Boston textile
investors allowed expansion on a scale unprecedented for
manufacturing. In 1850, the mills they controlled accounted for about
a fifth of all the cotton spinning in the United States. In Lowell alone,
in 1857 the ten mill companies, the Lowell Bleachery, and the Lowell
Machine Shop (spun off from Canals and Locks) together employed
over thirteen thousand workers.29
But the Lowell model did not take full advantage of potential
efficiencies that came with size. Within firms, running each mill
building as a self-contained production unit meant that while there
were some shared functions that no doubt lowered costs—most
importantly buying raw cotton and selling finished goods—in other
respects each building operated as a separate, modest-sized
enterprise. The idea of a fully integrated, rationalized, multisite
company still lay in the future. The Lowell mills did not begin to even
calculate unit costs until the 1850s, so they had no way to know the
advantages and disadvantages of different arrangements, sticking by
habit to the system Lowell had introduced in the first Waltham mill.
Even after the companies began connecting once-freestanding mill
buildings to one another and completely ringing mill yards with
buildings—to the dismay of workers who could no longer look out at
town and country scenes—they continued to treat each mill as a
separate entity. And because each cluster of four or five mills was
organized as a separate corporation, other savings that might have
accrued in purchasing, sales, and management were not realized.30
Amoskeag Manufacturing Company was the exception that
suggested there might be greater efficiencies in a different
organizational structure. Set up in the late 1830s to develop a new
textile center on the Merrimack River in New Hampshire, along with
a town grandiosely named Manchester, the company at first
replicated the Lowell pattern, expanding through the creation of new
corporate entities. But unlike in Lowell, eventually the separate
companies began to consolidate under one management, until all
the mills in Manchester were controlled by Amoskeag. The
consolidated corporate structure facilitated expansion. At its peak in
the early twentieth century, Amoskeag had 17,000 workers in thirty
mills and many associated buildings, bordering the river for over a
mile on one side and a half mile on the other. Its size allowed the
company to be almost completely self-sufficient, using its own
workers for even major construction projects and building most of its
own machinery.31
The model of expansion through replication—many separate mill
buildings, controlled by many separate companies—proved
something of a dead end. When other companies began to approach
and then exceed the size of the Boston Associates network, like the
Pennsylvania Railroad, Standard Oil, and U.S. Steel, some
experimented with interlocking directorates, but most quickly moved
to consolidate corporate control and financial supervision, even with
far-flung facilities.32 Organizationally idiosyncratic, nonetheless it
was the Waltham-Lowell system that first brought large-scale
factories to the United States, and it was that system that until the
Civil War represented industrialism in political and cultural discourse,
a pole for criticism and, more often, praise of a new type of society.
Factory Girls
“The American factory girl,” declared an 1844 article about Lowell in
the New-York Daily Tribune, “is generally the daughter of a farmer,
has had a common education at the district school, and has gone
into the factory for a few seasons to acquire a little something for a
start in life. She spends some weeks or months of every year under
her father’s roof, and generally marries and settles in its vicinity.
Many attend Lectures and evening schools after the day’s work is
over, and of the six thousand more than half regularly occupy and
pay for seats in the numerous Churches of Lowell. . . . [H]ardly any
where is Temperance more general or are violations of the law less
frequent.” The newspaper perhaps painted an overly rosy picture,
but its description was basically accurate. It was the character of the
Lowell “girls” and their life in the mill town that so impressed visitors
from home and abroad and led them to sharply contrast American
mills to British ones.33
Frances Lowell and his partners turned to farm girls as a
workforce largely out of a lack of alternatives. The Lowell group
sought to avoid the social disapproval that accompanied the
wholesale employment of children and, in any case, their power
looms required considerable strength to operate, necessitating adult
operators. Unlike Britain, the United States had neither a surplus of
urban male workers nor an overpopulated countryside to draw on.
Perhaps in an earlier era slaves might have been used; in the much
smaller Southern textile industry, they were used; by one estimate,
more than five thousand slaves labored in Southern cotton and
woolen mills by 1860. But by the time Lowell built the Waltham mills,
slavery was all but over in the North.
Instead, the Waltham-Lowell–style factories found a brilliant
solution in the recruitment of young women from rural New England.
Unmarried, in their teens and twenties, they provided a well-
educated workforce, accustomed to seeing and doing hard work and
being subservient to male authority, but not so vital to their families
that their withdrawal would create an economic or social crisis. And,
to the mill owners’ liking, they were a revolving labor force. When
they became unhappy or the mills lacked work, they could return to
their families rather than staying nearby and making trouble,
avoiding the discontent and disorder that came in England with the
creation of a permanent proletariat.34
For these workers, the mills represented an opportunity before
marrying to expose themselves to a wider world, while economically
helping themselves and their families. Few came from destitute
homes, desperate for additional income, as was so commonly the
case in Great Britain. Rather, they typically came from middling
families, daughters of farmers or rural artisans. But money did play a
big part in why they came. Typically, they kept their earnings, using
them to buy clothes, accumulate a dowry, save money for normal
school, or to set themselves up independently from their families.
Many also sent money home, to help pay off a farm mortgage or
family debts, to support a widowed mother, or to pay for a brother’s
education. A big attraction of the Waltham-Lowell–style mills was
that they paid cash, not credit at a company store, like many of the
Rhode Island–style mills. At the time, women had few other ways to
make money, except domestic service (which many New Englanders
rejected as subservient), schoolteaching (more seasonal than factory
labor), or seamstressing.
But money was not the whole story. The mills also provided an
escape from families, rural life, boredom, and isolation, a chance to
experience a new, more cosmopolitan world of independent living,
consumer goods, and intense sociability. Earning their own living
gave women a sense of independence and relieved their parents of
a burden. Ironically, the mills themselves made redundant one of the
main contributions young women had made to the family economy,
spinning yarn and weaving cloth at home for family use or for the
market.35
There were other components of the mill workforce besides
young women. Especially in the early days, there was a strict sexual
division of labor. Women held almost all the jobs operating
machinery, except for picking and carding. Men did all the
construction, maintenance, and repair work and held all the
supervisory positions. In addition, the mills recruited skilled male
workers from England and Scotland for specialized jobs for which
there was no pool of qualified native workers, including calico
printing and producing woolens. A small number of children worked
in the mills, too (though the Lowell mills generally did not hire anyone
under age fifteen), as did a few older, married women. The Hamilton
Manufacturing Company was probably typical in 1836, with women
making up 85 percent of its workforce. Over time, the percentage of
female workers dropped, at least modestly. In 1857, excluding the
all-male Lowell Machine Shop, the Lowell textile workforce as a
whole was a bit over 70 percent female.36
The Lowell-style mills rarely had to advertise for workers. Young
women—a sample of Hamilton workers found their average age on
hiring just under twenty—came on their own after hearing about the
mills, often joining or sending for sisters, cousins, or friends. The
Lowell Offering, a magazine of poetry and fiction by mill workers, not
only received extensive praise from visitors, it also served as a form
of job advertising for the companies (which quietly subsidized it).
When nearby hinterlands became tapped out of workers, the mills
sent recruiters to scour the more distant countryside, bringing back
their finds on wagons before railroads eased transportation.37
Female mill workers typically had a relatively short tenure. Most
estimates agree that women stayed on average something like four
or five years, commonly returning home for stretches while
employed.38
From the start, mill owners calculated that parents would allow
their daughters to live on their own and work in the mills only if they
were assured of their safety and well-being. For the mills “To obtain
their constant importation of female hands from the country,” wrote
the Burlington [Vermont] Free Press in 1845, “it is necessary to
secure the moral protection of their characters while they are
resident in Lowell.” To that end, the companies established what the
paper termed a system of “moral police.” Elaborate company rules
regulated workers off the job as well as on. The Middlesex Company
declared that it would “not employ any one who is habitually absent
from public worship on the Sabbath, or whose habits are not regular
and correct.” Workers were forbidden from smoking or using any
kind of “ardent spirit” in the mills and were generally required to live
in company-owned boardinghouses unless they had family living
nearby. The boardinghouses, in turn, had their own sets of rules,
including a ten o’clock curfew and, in at least one case, the
requirement that all residents be vaccinated for smallpox (which the
company agreed to pay for). The matrons who ran the
boardinghouses had to report rules violators, who could be fired.
Companies required workers to sign one-year contracts and give two
weeks’ notice before quitting. They circulated among themselves
lists of workers who had been discharged or who had quit before the
end of their contracts, whom they agreed not to hire, and imposed
fines for lateness and poor-quality work.39
Company paternalism was not simply regulatory or punitive;
especially in the early years the companies tried to make the mills
attractive places to work and the mill towns attractive places to live.
Lowell was carefully laid out, with trees lining its broad streets and
an orderly placement of the mills, boardinghouses, and commercial
structures. Companies planted trees and put in flower beds around
their buildings and in their mill yards and allowed workers to grow
plants and flowers on windowsills inside the factories. One newly
arrived worker in Manchester, impressed by the brick houses and
“very handsome streets,” wrote her sister that she thought it “a
beautiful place.” The sociability of the mill towns, especially Lowell,
with its lectures and literary societies, was widely praised, though
also somewhat exaggerated, since, given the very long hours of
work, workers had limited time for other activities. Still, cities like
Lowell and Manchester looked and felt very different than the
crowded, filthy, impoverished English textile centers like Wigan,
Bolton, and the namesake Manchester.40
The experience of working in a factory and living in a factory town
transformed the women who flocked to Lowell, Manchester,
Chicopee, and the like. Augusta Worthen, two of whose sisters had
worked in Lowell, later recalled that the young women from her town,
Sutton, New Hampshire (population 1,424 in 1830), who traveled to
take jobs in Lowell or Nashua had “a chance to behold other towns
and places, and see more of the world than most of the generation
had ever been able to see. They went in their plain, country-made
clothes, and after working several months, would come for a visit, or
perhaps to be married, in their tasteful city dresses, and with more
money in their pockets than they had ever owned before.” For one
group in particular, mill work could be utterly altering, widows and
older unmarried women, dependent on their relatives for support. Mill
worker Harriet Robinson later remembered them “depressed,
modest, mincing, hardly daring to look one in the face. . . . But after
the first pay-day came, and they felt the jingle of silver in their pocket
and had begun to feel its mercurial influence, their bowed heads
were lifted, their necks seemed braced with steel, they looked you in
the face, sang blithely among their looms or frames, and walked with
elastic step to and from their work.”
Many mill workers returned to their hometowns to marry,
sometimes settling down to farm lives much like those of their
parents. But a detailed study, by historian Thomas Dublin, of women
who had worked for Hamilton Manufacturing found that they typically
married at a somewhat later age than women from their hometowns
who had not gone to a mill, were far less likely to marry a farmer, and
were more likely to settle down in a city, with quite a few staying in
Lowell after marrying. Although the New England countryside itself
was changing, with improvements in transportation and the spread of
commercial relations, for young workers the mill experience
accelerated the transition out of a world of semi-subsistence
agriculture into an emerging commercial society. Even those women
who settled back home were never quite the same as those who
never left.41
Unlike British textile workers, the young women who flocked to
the New England mills left behind a veritable flood of words. Almost
all literate, they kept diaries, wrote letters back home and to one
another, contributed to The Lowell Offering, its successor, The New
England Offering, and labor papers like The Voice of Industry, and,
in a few cases, wrote memoirs or autobiographies. In their letters,
money is discussed frequently: wage rates, how much could be
earned in alternative types of employment, expenses, and so on.
Work itself does not figure as strongly as activities outside of work,
family news, or religion. There are very occasional comments on the
pace of work, but surprisingly little description of the mills. Social life
and saving money—the reasons why so many workers left their
homes—remain at the forefront, while work tasks and the factories in
which they occurred seemed to have been taken for granted.42
Perhaps one reason was that, at least in the first decades, mill
workers generally did not consider their labor especially arduous.
“Many of the girls who come to Lowell, from the country,” an 1843
editorial in The Lowell Offering noted, “have been taught by their
good mothers that industry is the first of virtues.” Responding to
claims about the unhealthful effects of factory labor, the editorial
declared mill work “light—were it not so there would not be so many
hurrying from their country homes to get rid of milking cows, washing
floors, and other such healthy employments.”
Just as in England, often new hires walking into a mill for the first
time found the noise and motion of the machinery overwhelming, the
experience of sharing a huge work space with scores of others
disorienting, and the tasks tiring. But acclimation usually followed.
Though the intensity of jobs varied considerably, at least in the early
years, when the companies were still perfecting machinery and
operations and profits were high, many jobs were not especially
taxing. In the spinning and weaving rooms, workers often had
stretches of free time while they monitored equipment, waiting for a
thread to break or a bobbin to need replacing, in some case defying
rules to read or socialize.43
But the work was work. In a review of Dickens’s American Notes,
The Lowell Offering quoted approvingly his comment about the
“Lowell operatives” that “It is their station to work. And they do
work. . . . upon an average, twelve hours a day; which is
unquestionably work, and pretty tight work too.” Repetitive actions
over the long days brought boredom and fatigue. The air in the mills
was often foul, especially during the winter when candles and lamps
were needed for light, and the noise could become oppressive. Often
it was too hot or too cold. And many workers resented the tight
regulation of their lives, what some came to call “factory tyranny.”44
Mill town life also had its downside. Some newcomers found
being surrounded by so many other people, after having spent their
lives on isolated farms or in small villages, disconcerting. The
boardinghouses were crowded, with four to six women sharing each
bedroom (two to a bed), affording little privacy (though that was
nothing new for those who had grown up in large New England farm
families, crammed into close quarters). But the opportunities for
richer social, intellectual, and religious life than possible in their
hometowns—and to make money—seemed to outweigh the
challenges of urbanity for most of the newcomers.45
Conditions, however, were not static; they deteriorated over time.
An extended burst of mill building—both of the Slater and Lowell
types—began narrowing the gap between supply and demand for
cloth. By 1832, some five hundred cotton mills operated in New
England alone. To keep up dividends in the face of growing
competition and falling prices, the Boston-based corporations sought
to cut costs. Payroll was not necessarily their biggest expense. In
some years, companies paid more for raw cotton than for the labor
to convert it into cloth. But it was an expense over which they had
control.46
Companies reduced labor costs in multiple ways. Sometimes
they simply lowered wage rates, which for many workers were piece
rates. In March 1840, for example, the directors of Merrimack
Manufacturing voted “That in consequence of the depression of the
times a reduction of the wages of the operatives is indispensable,”
authorizing the company treasurer to cut wages “to the point that
they may be deemed expedient & practicable.” The companies also
began running machinery at higher speeds, taking advantage of
technical improvements in shafting and equipment. And they began
assigning spinners and weavers more machines to monitor.
Whereas once a weaver might have been assigned one or two
looms, by the 1850s it was common to assign three or four. As
output—and the strain of work—went up, piece rates were reduced,
so that wages rose at most modestly. A study of four Lowell-style
mills in northern New England found that between 1836 and 1850
productivity increased by almost a half, while wages went up only 4
percent.47
In the 1830s, in response to wage cuts, a few dramatic if brief
flashes of protest occurred. They came at a moment of increasing
labor organization nationally, as a language and politics of worker
mobilization emerged. An announcement by the Lowell mills in early
1834 of a forthcoming 12½ percent wage cut set off a wave of
meetings, petitions, and agitation, seeking to reverse the decision.
When a mill agent fired a leader of the protest, other workers walked
out with her, parading the streets and visiting other mills, calling for
their employees to walk out, too. Some eight hundred women joined
the “turnout.” But it was short-lived and unsuccessful. Within less
than a week the strikers had either returned to their jobs or quit
them, and the wage reduction went through as planned.
Two years later, 1,500 to 2,000 workers took part in a much
better organized turnout, protesting a hike in the price of room and
board in the company boardinghouses, effectively another wage cut.
At some mills, the walkout lasted for weeks, with at least one
company having to shut down a mill, consolidating its nonstriking
workers in its others to keep production going. A newly formed
Factory Girls’ Association, with a reported 2,500 members,
coordinated the strike. Though the exact outcome remains unclear,
at least some mills partially or fully rescinded the increase.48
These were not the first mill worker strikes; there had been
earlier, brief walkouts in Pawtucket, Rhode Island, and Waltham and
Dover, Massachusetts. But the Lowell walkouts were bigger and
carried more symbolic weight because they took place in the most
celebrated factory town in the nation. Also, though the organized
labor movement in the United States had been developing in fits and
starts since soon after the Revolution, walkouts by women and
factory workers were still a novelty.
In other ways, though, the Lowell strikes fit a national pattern, in
which the language of republicanism and the spirit of the Revolution
were invoked to mobilize workers against what was seen as an
emerging tyranny of economic power. “We circulate this paper,” read
one petition circulated during the 1834 strike, “wishing to obtain the
names of all who imbibe the spirit of our Patriotic Ancestors, who
preferred privation to bondage. . . . The oppressing hand of avarice
would enslave. . . . [A]s we are free, we would remain in possession
of what kind Providence has bestowed upon us, and remain
daughters of freemen still.” Strikers saw wage reductions and the
power to impose them as not just a menace to their economic well-
being but also to their independence and respectability, threatening
to reduce them to the opposite of freemen—or daughters of freemen
—slaves. Just as in England, workers feared that the mill might not
be a source of freedom but of its opposite. During the 1836 walkout,
strikers walking in procession down the Lowell streets sang:
Faded Visions
The debate over Lowell raised what already had become a recurring
question: Was the factory system inherently oppressive to workers
and threatening to social cohesion or did its nature change with its
environment? Over time, the critical views of Brownson, Tocqueville,
and Luther became more widely shared. In England, the cotton mill
quickly brought a broad acceptance of the idea that it was creating a
new type of class society. In the United States, there was an
interregnum during which the large factory was associated with the
idea that industry and republican community could coexist. But by
the time of the Civil War, changes in the factory system itself, evident
in Lowell and other cotton centers, faded visions of “commercial
Utopia.”
Above all, it was the transformation of the workforce that changed
the public perception of the New England mills. By the late 1840s,
fewer young New Englanders were coming to the mill towns as a
result of growing displeasure with the pay, hours, and increased
workload, evident in the strikes of the 1830s and the ten-hour
movement. Also, for young women other alternatives to staying in
rural homes opened up. Railroads made it easier to move to urban
centers or out West. With the spread of public education, the number
of jobs for teachers swelled and salaries improved.65
Fortunately for the mills, in the mid-1840s, just as the influx from
the countryside diminished, a new labor pool materialized with mass
migration from famine-gripped Ireland. Between 1846 and 1847
alone, immigration from Ireland more than doubled, and by 1851 it
more than doubled again. There were always Irish workers in Lowell
and other mill towns; Irish men dug the canals and helped build the
factories. But before 1840, the textile companies generally spurned
Irish women; in 1845, only 7 percent of the Lowell mill workforce was
Irish. Necessity ended the discrimination; by the early 1850s, about
half the textile workers in Lowell and other mill towns were Irish. At
the Hamilton mill, by 1860 over 60 percent of the employees had
been born abroad.66
The increasing number of immigrant workers brought other
changes. More children began being hired in Lowell-style mills,
especially boys, as whole families needed to work to support
themselves, a reversion to the pattern in the early Slater-type mills.
The gendered division of labor broke down as male immigrants
accepted jobs once reserved for women, paid wages that in the past
only women would take. At Hamilton, in 1860, 30 percent of the
workforce consisted of adult men.
Immigrant family labor contributed to the decline of the
boardinghouse system and company paternalism. Lowell firms put
up mills at a faster pace than they built housing, and after 1848 they
stopped building housing entirely. Institutional arrangements once
needed to attract rural young women and reassure their parents
became increasingly superfluous, as the companies acknowledged
in the 1850s when they dropped requirements for church attendance
and boardinghouse residence for single women. A growing
proportion of the workforce—including more and more single women
—lived in non-company-owned boardinghouses or in rented
tenement apartments. The company boardinghouses lingered on—
between 1888 and 1891 a quarter of the workers at the Boott mills
were still living in company-owned housing—but they declined in
importance as the immigrant workforce grew.67
Figure 2.3 Winslow Homer’s 1868 engraving of New England factory life, Bell-
Time.
Exhibiting Modernity
Even standing still, the steam engine became a symbol of progress
and national prowess, part of the broader celebration of machinery
and manufactured goods, so evident at the Centennial Exhibition.
Before the Philadelphia fair and continuing long after it, public
exhibitions were built around the processes, symbols, and products
of mechanical manufacturing, equating them with modernity. In 1839,
for example, the Massachusetts Charitable Mechanic Association
held its second exhibition at Boston’s Quincy Market. Over the
course of twelve days, seventy-thousand people attended. Among
the exhibits were an operating miniature railroad, a small steam
engine that powered other machinery, planning machines, a
“cassimere shearing machine,” printing presses, and knitting
machines. Displayed goods included textiles from Lowell, looking
glasses, cabinets, coaches, saddles, hosiery, hats, caps, furs,
confectionery, soaps, perfumes, boots, cannons, rifles, swords,
hardware, cutlery, locks, pumps, fire engines, and musical
instruments. Defending against the belief that manufacturing was
undermining republican virtue, James Trecothick Austin, in an
address at the exhibition, tried to dismiss “the supposed conflicting
interests of the various classes in American society.” “Our splendid
manufacturies of silver,” he said, “are worse than useless, if it is a sin
against democracy to use a silver fork.”5
The 1851 Crystal Palace Exhibition in London, officially the
“Great Exhibition of the Works of Industry of All Nations,” marked the
beginning of the great international expositions and world’s fairs,
temples dedicated to progress and modernity as reflected in
machines and machine-made objects. The building that contained
the fair was at least as impressive as the exhibits within it. A huge
iron and glass conservatory, the Crystal Palace was constructed
entirely out of machine-made parts, so that after the exhibition
closed it was easily disassembled and reconstructed on a different
site. The British exhibit, by far the largest, had sections devoted to
fine arts, “raw materials,” “machinery,” and “manufactures.” The
industrial tourism that the well-connected had indulged in with factory
visits now was brought to the masses. Fifteen steam-driven
machines for carding, spinning, and weaving took raw cotton and
converted it to cloth while viewers stood nearby. The enormous
display of manufactured goods educated attendees about the
emerging consumer society, showing the myriad things that could be
made and how they would make life better. “World exhibitions,”
Walter Benjamin would later write, were “sites of pilgrimage to the
commodity fetish.”6
The United States mounted a “Crystal Palace” exhibition of its
own, the Exhibition of the Industry of All Nations, in 1853. The iron
and glass exhibit hall, built in New York City on the site of what is
now Bryant Park, was essentially a smaller version of the London
building, with a dome added. It created a sensation; nothing like it
had ever been seen in the New World. Like the London exhibition, it
contained a hodgepodge of art, machinery, and manufactured
products.7
Other countries, too, mounted international exhibitions. The
French held a series of fairs in Paris, starting with the 1855
Exposition Universelle and its Palais de l’Industrie, intended by
Napoleon III to top the London display. Succeeding exhibitions came
in 1867, 1878, 1889, and 1900. Vienna put on an International
Exhibition in 1873. Chicago created the large, well-attended, and
widely celebrated 1893 Columbian Exposition. Other United States
fairs followed in short order, including in Omaha (1899), Buffalo
(1901), and St. Louis (1904).8
Even the 1895 Cotton States and International Exposition, held in
Atlanta to highlight the economic recovery of the South under white
rule and the continued reign of King Cotton, prominently featured a
Machinery Hall. One account called it “the heart” of the fair; “wheels,
big and little, whirl in every quarter; dynamos generate untold volts of
electricity; pumps and lathes, planes and drills are hard at work, all
obediently responding to an unseen but irresistible force.”
“Southerners joined with millions of Yankee guests,” wrote historian
C. Vann Woodward about the Southern expositions held in the
1880s and 1890s, “to invoke the spirit of Progress and worship the
machine.”9
The Eiffel Tower, built for the 1889 Exposition Universelle,
became the foremost icon of the international fairs. Gustave Eiffel, a
successful French engineer, won a government competition for a
centerpiece for the exposition celebrating the hundredth anniversary
of the French Revolution. Made up of more than eighteen thousand
wrought-iron members, fabricated at an off-site factory, the 312-
meter tower soared to nearly twice the height of what had been the
world’s highest structure, the Washington Monument, completed just
five years earlier. From the top, the tower offered vistas previously
known only to a few balloonists, a preview of the bird’s-eye view of
the great metropolis that would become common only decades later,
after the invention of the airplane.10
Before it was built, a group of prominent French artists,
musicians, and writers protested what they called the “useless and
monstrous Eiffel Tower,” “the hateful column of bolted iron,” which
they declared would desecrate the beauty and honor of Paris.11 But
the tower almost immediately became celebrated as a symbol of
modernity, portrayed as a new kind of beauty. Even before it was
completed, George Seurat made it the subject of one of his best-
known canvases. A flood of drawings, paintings, and lithographs
followed, including works by Henri Rousseau, Diego Rivera, Marc
Chagall, and, perhaps most delightfully, Robert Delauney, who
returned to the subject over and over again. The tower proved an
ideal subject for modernist approaches to representation, including
pointillism and cubism. Pioneer filmmakers also engaged the tower,
the subject of short films by Louis Lumière in 1897 and George
Méliès in 1900.12 So did writers. In Guillaume Apollinaire’s poem
“Zone,” the tower herded the way to modernity:
Iron
The crystal palaces in London and New York, the great machinery
halls, and the Eiffel Tower were possible because of advances in the
iron industry. If the first half of the nineteenth century constituted the
age of cotton, the decades after 1850 were the age of iron. By the
time of the Centennial Exhibition, the largest manufacturing plants in
Europe and the United States made iron and steel goods, not
textiles. Iron mills and, later, steel mills supplanted textiles mills as
symbols of modernity, as poles for debate about the nature of the
society and what kind of future people sought.
Until the nineteenth century, iron was made only in small
quantities for specialized products. Typically, in Europe and North
America, the mining of ore, its conversion into iron, and the
production of finished goods all took place at one site, by small
groups of skilled workers. But by the middle of the nineteenth
century, the rising demand for iron outstripped traditional production
techniques, in which small furnaces, fueled by charcoal or coke,
were used to remove oxygen and impurities from iron ore, producing
metal which could be cast into finished goods or later reheated and
converted into stronger, more malleable wrought iron.19
A huge boost in the demand for iron came from the spread of the
railroad and the need for rails. In 1840, there were 4,500 miles of
railway worldwide; by 1860, 66,300 miles; and by 1880, 228,400. At
first, producing rails proved painfully difficult. Because not enough
iron could be rolled at once to make a single rail, small bars had to
be rolled into strips, which were layered, reheated, and rolled again.
Quality was low; sometimes rails delaminated and, on heavily used
lines, they wore out in as little as three months. American
metallurgist Frederick Overman wrote in the early 1850s, “The
application of science and machinery in the manufacture of iron does
not exhibit so high a state of cultivation as we find in . . . the
manufacture of calico prints and silks.”20
That changed with a series of technical innovations that
increased the quantity and quality of production. First came the blast
furnace. Instead of forcing cold air through heated iron ore to remove
the carbon in it, starting in 1828 in England and six years later in the
United States, hot air, heated by the exhaust of the furnace itself,
was used, greatly increasing the speed and efficiency of the process.
Raising the temperature and pressure of the air yielded further gains.
From a typical output in the 1850s of one to six tons of iron a day, by
1880 furnaces neared an output of one hundred tons a day.21
Iron produced by blast furnaces could be used to make some
products by casting, like stoves and plows. But it was too brittle for
many uses. Further reducing the carbon content to make wrought
iron gave it greater strength and flexibility but required intensive
labor, either repeated pounding at a forge or chemical transformation
through a process known as puddling. Puddlers reheated cast-iron
bars, so-called pig iron, along with scrap iron in special furnaces,
stirring the mixture to oxidize the carbon and burn off impurities.
Experience, skill, and physical strength were needed to control the
process.
With a strong craft culture and a high level of unionization,
puddlers forced iron manufacturers into what effectively was a
partnership. The workers regulated all aspects of the puddling
process, including how much iron to produce in each turn and their
hours of work. They often paid helpers out of their own wages. In
Pittsburgh, the most important iron center, a sliding scale linked
puddlers’ pay to their output and the selling price of iron, so that they
shared any gains that resulted from higher productivity or improved
market conditions. The men who operated rollers for shaping rails
and other products also exerted near total control over the
production process. In some mills, they negotiated a price per ton for
an entire team of workers, which they decided among themselves
how to divide.22
Early iron plants tended to be small, as puddling could make
wrought iron in batches of only about six hundred pounds at a time.
Soon, though, technical and financial considerations pushed up plant
size. Rolling rails required expensive equipment; to be profitable, rail
mills had to be operated around the clock, which necessitated a
great deal of wrought iron. Some rail makers purchased iron from
other firms, but the leading companies integrated backward, setting
up their own blast and puddling operations. Switching fuel from
charcoal to coke liberated them from the need to be near large tracts
of forested land from which charcoal could be produced. Coal
deposits and major rail lines made Pennsylvania particularly
attractive for large-scale operations.
Figure 3.2 Cambria Iron and Steel Works in Johnstown, Pennsylvania, circa 1880.
Hellish though they might have been, iron and steel mills were
often hailed as markers of national greatness and the advance of
civilization. Their growth allowed the introduction of iron and steel
implements on farms and in homes, the mechanization of other
industries, a transformed landscape of railroads, bridges, and
skyscrapers, and imperial power based on giant guns and steel
warships. In 1876, George Thurston described the then-new Edgar
Thomson steel mill in Braddock, Pennsylvania, as “a striking
illustration of . . . the progress of civilization.” “No grander monument
to the growth of the nation . . . or the triumph of American
manufactures and of American mechanics, could well be built.” Mary
Heaton Vorse, a left-wing journalist with a very different sensibility,
nonetheless agreed in her 1920 book Men and Steel: “Our
civilization is forged in the steel towns.” And not just any civilization,
but modernity: “Iron and Steel began the life of the moderns.”
Sociologist Sharon Zukin noted that “Steel has power because it has
been the lifeline of industrial society. . . . Steel is linked upward to the
national government by warfare and international trade, and
downward to the local manufacturing community as an emblem of
economic power.” In the late 1940s, best-selling journalist John
Gunther declared, “The basic power determinant of any country is its
steel production.”34
Class War
Fire, power, but one more thing, too, made iron and steel factories
centers of public attention—labor strife. The English textile industry
sparked a great debate about child labor and working conditions, if
not much effective worker organization. The American textile
industry was hailed, with considerable exaggeration, for harmonious
relations between owners and workers. By contrast, labor conflict
came to be strongly associated with the iron and steel industry, the
site of some of the most dramatic episodes of what can only be
called class war in the history of the United States.
In the decades after the Civil War, the growing power of industrial
capital set off fierce economic and political struggles, at their
broadest about what type of society the United States would be, and
who would decide. Former slaves, farmers, women, and the
unemployed mobilized, as a wide range of voices, far wider than we
hear today—populists, monetary reformers, socialists, anarchists,
social Darwinists, Christian reformers, feminists, and cooperativists
—jumped into debates over social values and structures. Workers
and the organizations they built composed the single most important
force challenging the growing economic and political dominance of
industrialists and financiers during what Mark Twain so aptly labeled
the Gilded Age. Nowhere was labor conflict more intense than in the
iron and steel industry.35
More than any other industry, iron and steel seemed to confirm
the notion that the factory system was creating two, new, hostile
classes. With much higher costs for starting up an iron or steel mill
than a textile mill, capital tended to concentrate in a handful of
powerful firms. For the men who controlled them, usually hands on,
they were not one of many investments—as the textile mills were for
the Boston Associates—but the source of all their wealth and power,
the means to achieve some of the largest fortunes in the country.
Their workers recognized what they were up against. The preamble
to the constitution of the Amalgamated Association of Iron and Steel
Workers declared “Year after year the capital of the country becomes
more and more concentrated in the hands of the few . . . and the
laboring classes are more or less impoverished. It therefore
becomes us as men who have to battle with the stern realities of life,
to look this matter fair in the face.” Only admitting skilled workers, the
Amalgamated’s membership fluctuated with good times and bad,
peaking in 1891 at more than 24,000 members. Its power rested on
a sense of solidarity among its members and their skills, without
which the mills could not operate.36
Or couldn’t until they began mechanizing. New technology and
the shift from iron to steel diminished the number of skilled workers
and the level of skill needed in various phases of production. The
move to steel also increased firm size and created an intensely
competitive atmosphere, both of which worked against labor.
The market for rails, which drove the steel industry until late in
the nineteenth century, fluctuated wildly, encouraging a ruthless
management culture. During economic upswings, there were plenty
of orders for everyone, but in downturns companies had to scramble
and slash prices to keep their mills operating. Steel executives
repeatedly made and broke deals with other companies to fix prices
and divvy up markets, while pressing their subordinates to lower
costs. Mechanization provided one route; reducing wages and
extending hours another. But squeezing labor costs meant having to
take on unions, leading to escalating battles in the 1880s and
1890s.37
The big companies took the lead in fighting the Amalgamated,
equipped with the financial resources and multiple plants to win
extended battles. Homestead saw some of the sharpest clashes. In
1882, the management of the plant (not yet owned by Carnegie)
insisted that to keep their jobs employees had to sign an ironclad
agreement not to join a union. Refusing, several hundred skilled
workers struck for over two months, surviving repeated battles with
private guards and the state militia until the general manager
capitulated. Six years later, Carnegie used a four-month lockout and
Pinkerton National Detective Agency guards to crush the union at his
Edgar Thomson mill and go from a system of three shifts of eight
hours to two shifts of twelve, a rout not only of unionism but of the
standards it had defended.38
The next year, 1889, Carnegie tried to replicate his Thomson
triumph at the Homestead mill, which he had purchased in 1883,
plotting his moves while on a visit to Europe to see the great Paris
exhibition. Once again, his company delivered a take-it-or-leave-it
ultimatum to his workers, locked them out when they rejected it, and
hired Pinkerton guards. But after two efforts to bring in scabs were
repulsed by massive crowds of steelworkers and Homestead
residents, the local manager gave in and negotiated a new
agreement with the Amalgamated Association.39
When the contract expired at the end of June 1892, Carnegie
sought to rid himself of the union once and for all. By then, nearly a
decade of industrial strife had placed the issue of labor relations at
the center of American life. Observers saw Homestead as a
bellwether for the future of class relations. The high productivity of
the Homestead plant and the Amalgamated’s sliding scale made
labor costs at the mill, according to Carnegie’s calculations, above
the norm, while allowing its skilled workers relative comfort, buying
small houses in town (and electing one of their own to lead its
government), purchasing some furnishings, living in decency.
The economic conflict had an ideological dimension. Carnegie
and his partners, determined to drive down labor costs, wanted
complete freedom to set wages and working conditions without union
interference, to control what they saw as solely their property. By
contrast, workers felt they had a moral claim on the company, having
contributed to its success through their skill and toil. Many shared
what at the time was a common democratic vision in which working
people (or at least the white, English-speaking men among them)
should—and in Homestead for a while did—have a say in both civic
and industrial life.40
As the battle loomed, Carnegie again absented himself to
Europe, leaving in charge his partner Henry Clay Frick. Again, the
company prepared an offer it knew the union would reject. As it shut
down operations and locked out its workers, Frick surrounded the
mill with an eleven-foot-high fence, with gun ports and topped by
barbed wire, and contracted with Pinkerton for three hundred guards.
All remained peaceful until the company tried to sneak the
Pinkertons into Homestead on barges. In the middle of the night,
union lookouts spotted them, alerting the town. As the New York
Herald described it, “Like the trumpet of judgement blew the steam
whistle of the electric light works at twenty minutes to three-o’clock
this morning. It was the signal to battle, murder and sudden death,
though not one of the thousands who heard and leaped from their
beds to answer its signal dreamed of how much blood was to flow in
response to its call.” Workers and townspeople positioned on the
steep banks of the Monongahela River kept the well-armed private
army from disembarking, firing a cannon at them (which ended up
killing a union backer by mistake), rolling flaming railcars toward the
moored barges, raining down fireworks and sticks of dynamite, and
pouring oil on the river and setting it on fire. Finally surrendering, the
Pinkertons found themselves beaten, robbed, and humiliated by a
gauntlet of strikers and local residents. Seven workers and three
Pinkertons died in the fighting.
The union victory proved short-lived. Within a week, the governor
of Pennsylvania sent 8,500 men—the state’s entire National Guard
—to occupy Homestead, where they remained until October. This
massive application of state power—accompanied by the indictment
of well over a hundred workers on charges of murder, riot, and
conspiracy—proved the key to the company’s victory. With the troops
in place, it began recruiting scab workers from around the country.
On July 23, anarchist Alexander Berkman attempted to kill Frick—a
rare American example of European-style propaganda by the deed
—but the Carnegie executive proved a tough bird, surviving bullet
and knife wounds, even helping to tackle his assailant. When a
National Guardsman shouted, “Three cheers for the man who shot
Frick,” he was court-martialed and hung from his thumbs. In
November, the union formally gave up.41
Figure 3.4 An Awful Battle at Homestead, Pa., depicting the bloody clash between
Carnegie’s locked-out workers and the Pinkertons in the summer of 1892.
The fight at the Carnegie plant was closely followed across the
country and abroad. A hundred reporters and sketch artists from
major magazines, the press syndicates, and newspapers in
Pittsburgh, New York, St. Louis, Chicago, Philadelphia, Baltimore,
and London assembled in Homestead to cover the conflict. With
special telegraph lines installed, news from the front lines
immediately spread. Photographers documented the clash as well.
Several companies sold stereoscopic images for home viewing,
providing three-dimensional portrayals of the industrial war.42
The workers’ defeat reverberated far and wide. Having been
pushed out of the most advanced steel mill in the country, the
Amalgamated saw its hold in the industry rapidly deteriorate. Within
a year, more than thirty of the sixty-four mills in southwestern
Pennsylvania rid themselves of the Amalgamated. In the iron
industry, the union maintained strength among puddlers and sheet
and tin plate workers, but even there company resistance and inept
leadership gradually diminished its power. By 1914 it was down to
just 6,500 members.43
Like the early British textile industry, the American iron and steel
industry grew in an atmosphere of denied political rights—free
speech, free assembly, rule of law. With unions weakened or
eliminated, the steel companies came to exert near-autocratic
control over not only the mills but the communities in which they
were located. The town of Homestead sank into a dark era of
suspicion and demoralization. In mid-1894, Hamlin Garland wrote in
McClure’s Magazine, “The town was as squalid and unlovely as
could well be imagined, and the people were mainly of the
discouraged and sullen type to be found everywhere labor passes
into the brutalizing stage of severity.” Theodore Dreiser, who lived in
Homestead for six months that same year, found “a sense of defeat
and sullen despair which was over all.” More than a dozen years
later, when John Fitch came to town, residents shied away from
talking to him, fearful of company spies and retribution. Steel
company influence over Homestead was so great that no halls could
be found for any sort of union meeting. As late as 1933, four
decades after the lockout, the only place in Homestead Secretary of
Labor Frances Perkins could find to address a crowd of workers was
inside a post office, an island of federal authority.44
In 1919, radical critic Floyd Dell called Pittsburgh, across the river
and likewise dominated by the iron and steel industry, “capitalism
armed to the teeth and carrying a chip on its shoulder. . . . lynch-law
carefully codified by a trained legislature and carried out by
uniformed desperadoes.” The city, he suggested, was “an
experiment in what might be called super-capitalism. It is a
sociological experiment, akin (despite the oddity of the comparison)
to the Utopias founded here and there from time to time by
enterprising if unrealistic socialists. But instead of a poor, precarious,
struggling, starved, doomed Utopia, it is a flourishing and, so far,
absolutely triumphant Utopia. It is a Billion Dollar Capitalist Utopia.”45
Often repression and paternalism mixed together. During the
1870s and 1880s, leading European iron and steel companies built
industrial villages, including Krupp in Essen and Schneider in Le
Creusot. Many American companies followed suit. Like the Lowell
textile firms, steel mills in isolated locations needed to provide
housing if they were to attract a workforce. When in the early 1890s
the Pennsylvania Steel Company built its complex at Sparrows
Point, an empty spit of land on the north side of Baltimore’s harbor, it
constructed a new town a half mile from the blast furnaces. Under an
arrangement with the governor of Maryland, the company directly
ran the community, without any local democratic structures. Rufus
Wood, the company executive who designed the town, was the son
of a foreman at the Boott cotton mill in Lowell. He modeled Sparrows
Point on the Massachusetts city, though with mostly family
accommodations rather than boardinghouses. Dwellings ranged in
size and quality from an eighteen-room, three-story colonial for
Wood himself down to small wooden houses without running water
or indoor plumbing for black workers. As in Lowell, elaborate rules
governed behavior not only on the job but in the housing, too.46
The most ambitious mill town scheme came in 1895, when the
Apollo Iron and Steel Company decided to build a new mill a mile
and a half from its existing plant in western Pennsylvania. It
contracted with the firm headed by Frederick Law Olmsted, the
foremost landscape architect and town planner in the country, to
design a new town, Vandergrift, named after the Standard Oil partner
who was the largest investor in the company. Cost concerns kept the
Olmsted plan from being fully realized, but parts of the town featured
curvilinear streets, wide boulevards, scattered small parks, and a
village green, characteristic of the high-end suburbs that were
beginning to surround older cities. But only the best-paid workers
could afford those areas; most lived in a less attractive grid laid out
on one side of town or in an unplanned hovel on another.47
Company officials saw housing as a way to retain workers. Some
companies offered their employees rental housing at below market
rates. Others sold them houses. Carnegie built housing for his
workers just outside Homestead, offering low-interest loans that
could be repaid through small deductions from their pay. Because
many steel mills sat in essentially one-employer towns, home-
owning employees, as their bosses knew, would be reluctant to
jeopardize their jobs in any way, because without them they would
be forced to move. Companies hoped that orderly, well-regulated
communities—both Sparrows Point and Vandergrift banned the sale
of alcohol—would produce orderly, disciplined workers.48
In the early twentieth century, when the world’s largest company
built the world’s largest steel mill, it, too, built a company town. As
the United States recovered from the depression of the 1890s, a
wave of corporate mergers swept through the already highly
concentrated steel industry. In 1901 Carnegie threatened to expand
his finishing operations, in response to the backward integration of
firms that had been purchasing his steel ingots. To avoid
overcapacity and ruinous competition, J. P. Morgan, the country’s
leading financier, arranged a huge merger of steel concerns. For his
interests, Carnegie received $226 million (the equivalent of several
billion dollars today). The new entity, the United States Steel
Corporation, controlled almost 60 percent of the output of the
industry and was widely seen as the very embodiment of industrial
capitalism.49
Four years after its formation, U.S. Steel bought nine thousand
acres on the shore of Lake Michigan, just east of Chicago, where it
erected a massive, sprawling integrated steel mill. To allow boat
delivery of ore from its Minnesota mines, the company built a deep
harbor next to the plant. It also laid out a new city, Gary, named after
its chairman, Elbert H. Gary—American industrialists loved naming
towns after themselves and each other—where it sold vacant lots
and constructed rental housing. Vandergrift, by then part of the U.S.
Steel empire, served as something of a model. But in building the
new city, the company spurned the utopian pretensions of Lowell
and Vandergrift, stating that it was not trying to create a model
community, only building a necessary adjunct to its new facility.50
Scientific Management
Even with unions defeated and worker resistance tamed, steel
companies still struggled to control labor in their mills and reduce
labor costs, an imperative in periods of intense competition. With
sprawling physical facilities and a large array of jobs, managers had
difficulty even knowing what all their workers did, let alone how
efficiently they were working. Skilled workers retained considerable
autonomy, using knowledge accumulated through formal or informal
apprenticeships to determine their methods of work, often effectively
setting their own pace. Foreman pushed unskilled workers using
threats and verbal abuse, with little planning or measurement of
productivity.
Throughout American industry, factories had swollen in size and
complexity without a proportionate increase in managerial personnel
or sophistication. Well into the 1880s, many major firms still
managed labor through the direct presence of top executives. Cyrus
McCormick’s brother and his four assistants long managed the giant
McCormick Works in Chicago. Thomas Edison and three assistants
personally supervised production at his factories in Harrison, New
Jersey, and New York City.51 But with the development of giant
multiplant firms, such personal, informal control was no longer
tenable.
“Systematic management,” later more widely known as “scientific
management,” grew out of a quest for internal corporate controls and
increased productivity, a sweeping effort at reorganizing production.
Its development involved many different companies, engineers, and
managers over an extended period, who instituted a series of
incremental changes that together represented a substantial
transformation in how manufacturing—and later office work—was
carried out. But in the public mind, scientific management became
largely associated with one man, Frederick Winslow Taylor, who
emerged as its leading theoretician, ideologue, and publicist.
Taylor, the son of a prominent, liberal Philadelphia family,
followed an unusual path in spurning college to become an
apprentice machinist and patternmaker, before taking on a series of
factory-management positions and then a career as an industrial
consultant. (In 1876, he took six months off from his apprenticeship
to work at the Centennial Exhibition.) Many of Taylor’s key
innovations took place during the 1880s at Midvale Steel Works, a
Philadelphia producer of high-quality steel products, and then, during
the last years of the nineteenth century, at the much larger
Bethlehem Steel Company. Taylor had an intense interest in the
mechanics of steel production and metalworking, particularly high-
speed machine tools, making numerous technical advances. But his
greater importance lay in applying a systematic, engineering mind-
set to what commonly had been a seat-of-the pants, chaotic
approach to managing manufacturing.
Taylor’s contributions included improvements in cost accounting,
inventory control, tool standardization, and shop floor layout. But his
best-known innovations involved labor. Working among machinists,
Taylor realized how commonly workers set a stint, a maximum
output, designed to conserve their energy and spread out the work.
Managers had no idea what the maximum output could be or what
should constitute a full day’s work. The first step to boosting
productivity, Taylor came to believe, lay in the careful observation
and measurement of workers as they did their jobs, using
stopwatches and, later in the hands of his disciples, stop-action
photography and motion pictures. Once managers understood the
elements of any given task, they could determine the best way to
carry it out and the time it should take to complete.
Critical to the Taylor method was the separation of the planning of
work from its execution, breaking the hallmark of the skilled
craftsperson, his or her ability to conceive of how to make various
items and then to do the work themselves. All planning, Taylor
believed, should be in the hands of management, in a specialized
planning department (something previously all but unknown). Using
knowledge of machinery and worker practices gathered through
systematic observation, workers would be given detailed instructions
about how to carry out each task (usually in the form of an instruction
card). Pay would be calculated by a piecework system that rewarded
with higher rates workers who met specified production norms and
penalized those unable or unwilling to meet management-dictated
standards.
For skilled workers in particular, like the machinists that steel
companies employed to make finished products and maintain their
equipment, Taylorism meant a loss of autonomy and an attack on
craft pride, as well as an intensification of work, leading to fierce
battles. But Taylor always claimed his system would benefit workers
as well as company owners, because the increases in productivity
that would result from scientific management were so great that
workers could be given higher pay even as company profits rose. In
an example Taylor repeatedly used in publicizing his system, a
Bethlehem laborer he called Schmidt, who was loading pig iron into
railroad cars, increased his daily tonnage to forty-seven tons, from a
previous gang average of twelve and a half, by following precise
instructions. For his increased output, Schmidt received a wage
boost from $1.15 to $1.85 a day. His wages thus went up by roughly
60 percent, while output nearly quadrupled, a good deal for the
company though also a gain, if much more modest, for the worker. At
least in theory, scientific management, or Taylorism as it was
sometimes called, made the struggle between workers and owners
over wages no longer a zero-sum game. For this reason, in the eyes
of many Progressive Era reformers, scientific management held the
promise of eliminating or at least ameliorating the class conflict that
had come with industrialization and the giant factory, without
fundamentally restructuring society.52
“I WORSHIP FACTORIES”
Fordism, Labor, and the Romance of the Giant
Factory
INA 1926 ENTRY IN THE ENCYCLOPEDIA BRITANNICA, Henry Ford (or the
publicist who ghostwrote the article) defined “mass production” as
“the modern method by which great quantities of a single
standardized commodity are manufactured.” If anyone knew about
the manufacture of “great quantities of a single standardized
commodity,” it was Ford. His Model T, introduced in 1908, turned the
automobile from a luxury plaything into a mass-consumer good. Prior
to then, automobile companies typically manufactured at most a few
thousand cars a year. By 1914, the Ford Motor Company was rolling
out nearly a quarter of a million Model Ts annually. By the time the
company stopped selling the iconic model in 1927, fifteen million had
been produced.1
Henry Ford’s worldwide fame stemmed as much from the
methods his company used to make the Model T as from the car
itself. To manufacture it, the Ford Motor Company built some of the
largest factories that ever had been seen and introduced countless
technical and organizational innovations, including the assembly line,
which enormously increased the speed and efficiency of production.
To control the tens of thousands of workers who populated its plants,
the company devised new methods of labor management that
extended beyond the factory walls into workers’ homes and minds.
Ford pioneered what amounted to a new political economy of
inexpensive consumer products that transformed people’s lives,
high-volume factories to produce them, and high wages and strict
controls to discipline the workforce. Before Ford himself popularized
the term “mass production,” commentators often spoke of “Fordism,”
“Ford methods,” or the “Ford system,” appropriate terms for the new
production, distribution, and consumption regime, for it was Henry
Ford and the Ford Motor Company that ushered in a new phase of
industrialization and a factory scale that would be unsurpassed for
nearly a century.2
Just as the “factory system” of early nineteenth-century England
captured the interest and imagination of journalists, political activists,
writers, and artists, so, too, did the “Ford system” of the twentieth
century. Once again, it seemed like a new world was aborning. Part
of what made Fordism so transfixing was the promise of a wholesale
rise in the standard of living and amelioration of the class conflict that
had been shaking the United States. In 1924 merchant and reformer
Edward Filene wrote that in Fordism lay “a finer and fairer future than
most of us have even dared to dream.” Beyond the social
implications of Fordism, many writers, painters, filmmakers, and
photographers were entranced by the physical structures in which it
unfolded. More than with earlier industrial production, artists and
intellectuals explicitly linked Fordism to modernist trends in art and
society. The great photographer Margaret Bourke-White, who
through her work in Fortune and Life magazines did more than any
other individual to popularize industrial imagery, captured the age
when she bluntly declared “I worship factories.”3
River Rouge
Even as Kahn’s practice grew, Henry Ford remained his most
important client. Together they designed what became the next
flagship of industrial giantism, Ford’s River Rouge plant. Almost as
soon as the New Shop was completed, Ford began planning a much
larger complex in nearby Dearborn, buying massive tracts of land.
Some was used for Ford endeavors besides the car company,
including a separate firm that produced Fordson tractors. But most of
it was devoted to making the Model T. Ford decided to advance to
the extreme his effort at vertical integration, seeking to make not only
parts but also basic materials like steel, glass, and rubber for his
cars, eliminating the possibility of suppliers raising prices or not
fulfilling orders when inventories were tight. The Dearborn property,
along the Rouge River, allowed the direct delivery of bulk goods,
including iron ore, coal, and sand, from Great Lakes ships and had
plenty of water for industrial processes. Also, the sparsely populated
Dearborn suburb gave Ford greater control over his environment
than Detroit, with its heterogeneous population and episodic labor
activism.37
Ford began constructing a blast furnace at River Rouge in 1917.
It was followed by a series of other processing plants, including coke
ovens, open-hearth furnaces, a rolling mill, a glass factory, a rubber
and tire plant, a leather plant, a paper mill, a box factory, and a
textile mill. Ford put great effort into integrating the various plants
and reusing byproducts. Impurities from the blast furnaces, for
example, were sent to an on-site factory to be made into cement.
Ford also began buying coal and iron mines and vast tracts of forest
land in the Upper Peninsula of Michigan, where he built sawmills,
kilns, and factories to make wooden parts for the Model T. Sawdust
and scrap lumber were used to make the charcoal briquettes, sold
under the Kingsford brand, which to this day fuel barbecues and
family happiness across America. His grandest effort at backward
integration was a vast rubber plantation in the Amazon Basin that
proved a costly failure.38
Complete Model Ts were never produced at River Rouge, which
initially served as a feeder plant for Highland Park. Engines, tires,
windows, and other components were taken from the Rouge to
Highland Park for final assembly. But with the high volume of Model
T production, even the feeder operations were vast. The River
Rouge foundry, where engine blocks were cast from molten iron
conveyed from adjacent blast furnaces, was the largest in the world,
employing ten thousand men.39
When final assembly operations did begin at the Rouge, it was,
ironically, to make boats, not cars. During World War I, Henry Ford
contracted with the Navy to build 112 submarine chasers using
assembly-line methods. The Navy paid for a new plant to produce
them, the “B Building,” designed by Kahn. Freestanding, it was the
largest factory ever built, 300 feet wide and 1,700 feet—a third-of-a-
mile—long, a huge shed with walls composed almost entirely of
windows. As tall as a three-story building but open inside to
accommodate boat production, it was designed to allow the later
addition of intermediate floors. When the last of the Eagle Boats left
the building in September 1919 (none were completed in time to be
used in combat), floors were added and the building was used to
assemble Model T bodies, which previously had been purchased
from outside contractors.
The B Building represented the beginning of a shift in factory
design principles for Ford and Kahn, moving away from the
ingenuous architectural machine that they had just developed at the
New Shop. Kahn helped lead not one but two revolutions in industrial
architecture. Rather than multistory buildings, at the Rouge Kahn
and Ford erected very large single-story factories to avoid the cost of
hoisting materials and to allow bigger uninterrupted spaces, since
columns to support upper floors were no longer needed. The
expansive, open areas gave engineers flexibility in machine
placement, aided by the company decision to stop using overhead
shafts and belts to power machinery, instead deploying individual
electric motors. Single-story plants also avoided the need to punch
holes between floors when assembly lines were repositioned. In
1923, Ford switched its standard design for branch plants from
multistory to single-story as well.
With the move to single-story factories, Kahn abandoned
reinforced concrete, no longer needing its vibration dampening
qualities. Instead he used steel frames, which allowed structures to
be put up more quickly and expanded more easily. Kahn’s new
buildings had, if anything, even more glass on the walls than his
earlier structures, and he generally used roof monitors—raised
structures with glass facing in varied directions—rather than
sawtooth roofs, which provided more diffuse natural light.
The loft-style, concrete buildings Kahn helped popularize
continued to be built for manufacturing and storage. Resistant to
water damage and strongly constructed, they can be found in large
numbers in older American industrial districts, sometimes still used
for manufacturing, sometimes abandoned, sometimes converted to
warehouses or offices, and occasionally turned into trendy
apartments. But Kahn himself almost never returned to the style.
Instead, Kahn embraced sleek surfaces of glass and metal in
buildings both functional and beautiful. Over the course of two
decades, he created a bounty of industrial buildings of great
modernist design—clean, light, spare, seemingly endless. Many of
Kahn’s Rouge buildings were expressions of almost pure form—tall
cylindrical chimneys, long glass walls, shapely monitor roofs—
unsullied by ornamentation. The Engineering Laboratory, completed
in 1925, where Henry Ford had his office, had a particularly striking
interior, with a long central space flanked by smaller galleries, with
two levels of monitor windows on both sides flooding it with light.
Some of Kahn’s later designs, like his Chrysler Half-Ton Truck Plant,
are widely recognized as among the greatest industrial buildings
ever erected, modernist masterpieces.
Yet neither Kahn nor Ford thought of themselves as modernists.
In a 1931 speech, Kahn gave a nuanced but largely negative
appraisal of modernist architecture. Kahn criticized the extreme
functionalism and lack of ornamentation of architects like Walter
Gropius and Le Corbusier (arguably traits that characterized his own
factory designs). “What we call modernism today is largely
affectation, a seeking for the radical, the extreme.” In his
nonindustrial projects, Kahn drew on a variety of historical styles,
designing often handsome but rarely pathbreaking buildings. Henry
Ford was even more explicitly antimodernist at the very moment he
was creating a new industrial modernity. Concurrent with the creation
of the Rouge, he continued to add to his collection of old machines,
furniture, and buildings, which he eventually installed in Greenfield
Village, near the Rouge plant, a recreation of an earlier, small-town
America. Even as his cars and factories promoted urbanization and
cosmopolitanism, Ford remained deeply nostalgic about the
parochial, rural world he grew up in and chose to leave.
Buildings continued to be added at the Rouge all through the
1920s and 1930s. The Press Shop, completed in the late 1930s,
became the largest single factory building in the world, with a floor
area of 1,450,000 square feet. Ford spaced the Rouge buildings far
apart to allow for later expansion, having plenty of room on the
1,096-acre site. An elaborate system of rail lines, roads, 142 miles of
conveyors, monorails, and an elevated “High Line” with an automatic
transport system moved raw materials, parts, and subassemblies
within and between buildings. Employee parking lots ringed the vast,
isolated complex, but many workers arrived at special streetcar and
bus terminals. Fences, railroad tracks, and guarded gates restricted
access to the plant, which came to resemble a fortress, in contrast to
Highland Park, which was situated in a busy urban neighborhood,
with public sidewalks alongside the factory buildings.40
Ironically, while the Rouge was being built out to produce
everything needed to make a Model T, the car itself was becoming
obsolete. By the mid-1920s, other car companies, including General
Motors and Chrysler, had introduced more technically advanced and
varied models than Ford, which still only sold the Model T (though it
offered luxury cars under the Lincoln nameplate). By 1927, as sales
diminished, it became evident that something had to be done.
Abruptly, Ford stopped making the Model T, even before finalizing
the design of its replacement, the Model A. For six months, Ford
factories sat idle, while the company replaced 15,000 machine tools
and rebuilt 25,000 more. New molds, jigs, dies, fixtures, gauges, and
assembly sequences had to be created. Meanwhile, the layoff of
60,000 Detroit-area Ford workers created a social crisis, as relief
agencies, free clinics, and child-placement agencies struggled to
meet the huge demand for their services.
The underbelly of the Ford system had been exposed. Extreme
standardization had allowed other companies to win over consumers
on the basis of style and change, what General Motors president
Alfred P. Sloan, Jr., called “the ‘laws’ of Paris dressmakers . . . in the
automobile industry.” Single-purpose, specialized machinery, which
made it inexpensive to produce particular parts, made it expensive to
switch over to new products (a problem that went all the way back to
the high-speed but inflexible machinery used in the early Lowell
mills). The changeover from the Model T to the Model A cost the
Ford Motor Company $250 million ($3.5 billion in 2017 currency) and
first place in sales to General Motors. Vertical integration had its
downside, too, evident when the economy and auto sales tanked just
a few years after the introduction of the Model A; Ford had a harder
time cutting costs than the other major automakers, which bought
most of their parts from outside suppliers. Over the course of the
decade starting in 1927, Ford had a cumulative net loss, while
General Motors made nearly $2 billion in after-tax profits.
The introduction of the Model A completed the transfer of the
center of the Ford empire from Highland Park to River Rouge. The
final assembly line for the new car was set up in the B Building,
which was so large that it also could house at various times an
assembly line for Fordson tractors, a trade school, fire department,
and hospital. The geographical move was accompanied by a purge
of pioneer Ford engineers and executives, most of those remaining
from the team that had created the Model T, the assembly line, and
the Ford system. With Harry Bennett and Charles Sorenson, a long-
time, very tough Ford production manager, effectively running the
Rouge, an autocratic, chaotic, and brutal culture came to
characterize the plant. Workers decried harsh discipline for petty
offenses, arbitrary, ever-changing rules, and tyrannical foremen. One
Rouge worker complained that “The bosses are thick as treacle and
they’re always on your neck, because the man above is on their
neck and Sorenson’s on the neck of the whole lot—he’s the man that
pours the boiling oil down that old Henry makes. . . . A man checks
’is brains and ’is freedom at the door when he goes to work at
Ford’s.”
The Rouge—“that self-sufficing industrial cosmos, a masterpiece
of ingenuity and efficiency,” Edmund Wilson called it—embodied an
extreme strategy of industrial concentration. Ford set up dozens of
branch plants in the United States to assemble kits of parts shipped
from Highland Park and later Dearborn, but manufacturing remained
highly centralized at the major complexes. During the 1920s and
1930s, the company built a series of “village industry” factories in
rural southeastern Michigan. Powered by small hydroelectric dams,
the plants produced small parts for use at Highland Park and the
Rouge—starter switches, drill bits, ignition coils, and the like. Henry
Ford conceived of the plants as providing work for farmers during the
slack winter season. Again, as at Greenfield Village, he seemed to
be embracing an idealized vision of a decentralized Jeffersonian
society, even as his life’s work undermined it. But with a combined
workforce at their height of only some four thousand workers, the
village factories were not much more than an ideological gesture in
the shadow of the giant Ford plants.
Other automakers also built very large plants. The complexity of
manufacturing an automobile, with its hundreds of different parts; the
cost of transporting bulky components like frames, axles, motors,
and bodies; and the heavy investment needed to build and equip an
automobile plant made concentration of production a widely shared
strategy. The Dodge Main plant in Hamtramck (an independent
enclave within Detroit) began as a parts supplier for Ford, but the
Dodge Brothers later expanded it to produce their own car. Albert
Kahn designed the first buildings; Smith, Hinchman, & Grylls,
another Detroit architectural firm, many additional buildings, most of
them multistory structures made of reinforced concrete. Under the
Dodges and later Chrysler, which bought the company after its
founders’ deaths, the factory became a fully integrated
manufacturing and assembly plant, larger in floor space than
Highland Park, its nearest equivalent. It had some 30,000 workers in
the late 1930s and even more during World War II, remaining in
operation until 1980. General Motors became famous for its
divisional structure and decentralization, but in Flint, Michigan, it, too,
had a huge production complex, several really. In the late 1920s, the
gigantic Buick plant (yet another Kahn design) had 22,000 workers;
a cluster of Chevrolet factories employed 18,000 workers; Fisher
Body, by then a GM subsidiary, had 7,500 workers; and still more
workers could be found in the factories of AC Spark Plug, another
GM subsidiary.
But nothing touched the Rouge in sheer scale. Historian Lindy
Biggs characterized it as “more like an industrial city than a factory.”
In 1925 it had 52,800 workers, still trailing Highland Park, where the
workforce had swelled to 55,300. With the Model A, though, the
Rouge moved ahead. It peaked at 102,811 workers in 1929, a level
of employment entirely unprecedented at a single factory complex.
To this day, at least in terms of the size of its workforce, it remains
unmatched in the United States. It was, simply, the largest and most
complicated factory ever built, an extraordinary testament to
ingenuity, engineering, and human labor.41
Celebrating Ford
Ford methods attracted widespread interest among industrial
professionals as soon as they were introduced. Henry Ford
welcomed reporters, especially from the technical press, into his
factories, openly sharing details about his latest innovations, a
departure from the usual wariness among manufacturers about
releasing information about their techniques. Trade journals like
American Machinist, Iron Age, and Engineering Magazine ran
extensive articles about the methods developed to produce the
Model T. Other American automobile companies and consumer
goods manufacturers quickly adopted the assembly line.42
The general public was likewise fascinated by the Ford system,
especially the assembly line. Henry Ford realized that public interest
in the methods of making Ford cars could help sell them. In addition
to providing tours of the Highland Park plant, he took the assembly
line on the road. At the 1915 Panama-Pacific International Exposition
in San Francisco, just two years after the assembly line had been
introduced, a Ford exhibit included a working production line that
turned out twenty Model Ts a day. When in 1928 Ford unveiled the
Model A at Madison Square Garden, the company put up displays of
every facet of the production process, from dioramas of Ford iron
and coal mines to workstations for making glass and upholstery. At
the 1933–34 Chicago Century of Progress Exposition, part of the
Ford Exposition Building, designed by Albert Kahn and later moved
near the entrance to the Rouge plant, showed “the complete
production of the car in all its parts.” In 1938, nearly a million people
visited the display. And they flocked to the Rouge itself, too. In the
late 1930s, Ford offered a two-hour tour of the complex starting
every half hour. Other manufacturing firms, including Chrysler and
General Motors, also opened their plants and set up exhibits for a
public endlessly fascinated with how things were made, especially
with the complex, wondrous choreography of the assembly line. The
Kahn-designed General Motors Exhibit at the Chicago Exposition
featured a model production line, which allowed visitors on an
overlooking balcony to watch workers assembling vehicles.
The public romance with the giant factory and the assembly line
proved long-lasting. In 1971, 243,000 people visited the Rouge, a
record number. A few years later, the U.S. Department of Commerce
published a list of plants in the United States that offered tours. It ran
to 149 pages, with everything from distilleries to steel mills, including
a dozen auto plants.43
Intellectuals and political activists were caught up in the allure of
Fordism, too. Perhaps surprisingly, given Ford’s later reputation as a
union-hating, conservative autocrat, some prominent leftists at first
praised the Ford system. In early 1916, after visiting the Highland
Park plant, Kate Richards O’Hare, a well-known socialist leader,
published two articles in The National Rip-Saw, a mass circulation
socialist monthly, praising Henry Ford. O’Hare saw the Five Dollar
Day, the Sociological Department, and the Ford English School as
advancing the lot of workers (along with Ford’s decision to take the
power to fire away from foremen). Using a jarringly racist simile, she
wrote that as a result of Ford’s policies “men freeze to a job in the
Ford plant like a negro to a fat possum.” “If every Capitalist in the
United States were to suddenly become converted to Ford’s
ideas . . . it would not solve the social problems, eliminate the class
struggle or inaugurate the co-operative commonwealth, BUT it would
advance the cause of social justice, demonstrate the soundness of
the socialist theories and bring the mighty pressure of education to
hasten the final and complete emancipation of the working class.”44
Later that same year, John Reed, soon to be the most important
chronicler of the Russian Revolution and a founder of the American
Communist Party, wrote a similarly glowing if more sophisticated
portrait of Ford in the left-wing journal The Masses. Ford’s strategy
of low prices and high wages, especially the profit-sharing built into
the Five Dollar Day, for Reed represented a huge step forward from
normal industrial practices. Reed detailed the difference high wages
made in the lives of Ford workers. Beyond that, after interviewing
Ford, he came to believe that the auto giant was moving toward
some sort of new form of corporate control that would give workers a
say; the Five Dollar Day was “turning into something dangerously
like a real experiment in democracy, and from it may spring a real
menace to capitalism.” This was why, Reed believed, “capitalists
hate Henry Ford,” an echo of Ford’s own perception of himself, in the
Populist idiom he grew up around, as a producer of value having to
fight off the parasitic financiers of Wall Street.45
Left-wing praise for Henry Ford diminished over time, in part in
response to changes in his company’s practices and his rabid anti-
Semitism during the 1920s; Edmund Wilson, writing fifteen years
after Reed, dubbed him the “despot of Dearborn.” But Fordism struck
a strong chord with a group that during the New Deal would ally with
elements of the left, businessmen and their supporters who saw
mass consumption as critical to maintaining prosperity and profits.
Edward Filene, who made his money in department stores, was
perhaps the most outspoken member of those who have been
dubbed “proto-Keynesians” for seeing the need for mass purchasing
power to maintain economic growth. Unlike in the past, Filene wrote
in 1924, businesses needed to produce “prosperous customers as
well as saleable goods.” Fordism, with its promise of high wages and
cheaper products, was a way to create a virtuous circle of mass
purchasing power, mass consumption, mass production, and
economic growth. Unlike O’Hare and Reed, Filene acknowledged
the monotony of Fordist labor, but saw shorter hours as partially
ameliorating the problem. And, in any case, “every man is not an
artist, every man is not a creative craftsman.” “Poverty brings a
monotony a thousand times more deadly to body and mind than the
monotony of factory routine,” he added in a comment reminiscent of
W. Cooke Taylor’s remark about child labor eighty years earlier.46
Novelists, too, saw in Fordism a startling development, a step
into a new type of world. John Dos Passos profiled Ford in The Big
Money (1936), which concluded his great three-volume portrait of the
country, U.S.A., writing not only about the Model T and the
exhausting labor used to produce it but also the automaker’s many
contradictions, his pacifism, war profiteering, and anti-Semitism, his
revolutionary inventions and antiquarianism. (Alfred Kazin shrewdly
observed that U.S.A., with its complex structure composed of
different types of narrative building blocks, was itself a “tool,”
“another American invention—an American thing peculiar to the
opportunity and stress of American life.”)47 Louis-Ferdinand Céline,
who visited a Detroit Ford factory in 1926, included a scene of
working on the company assembly line in Journey to the End of the
Night (1932). Upton Sinclair wrote a not very good novel about Ford,
The Flivver King: A Story of Ford-America (1937). And most
famously, Aldous Huxley’s Brave New World (1932) depicts a
dystopia of Fordism, a portrait of life A.F.—the years “Anno Ford,”
measured from 1908, when the Model T was introduced—with Henry
Ford the deity.48
Dos Passos, Sinclair, Céline, and Huxley all wrote about Ford
and Fordism during the 1930s, well after the initial burst of
journalistic and industrial excitement over mass production. Their
work was colored by the Great Depression and the Ford Motor
Company’s violent antiunion actions, which radically changed the
public image of Ford and the Fordist project. By contrast, the key
visual depictions of Fordism began earlier, during the 1920s. More
than in the written word, it was in the visual arts that Fordism and the
giant factory were celebrated.
Giant Factories and the Visual Arts
Factories had been portrayed from their earliest days in drawings,
lithographs, and paintings. But only in the twentieth century did the
factory become an important subject for artists. It is difficult to think
of a truly great eighteenth- or nineteenth-century artistic
representation of a factory, but there are plenty of great twentieth-
century factory paintings, photographs, and films. For many artists
during the 1920s and 1930s, the factory represented modern life—
secular, urban, mechanical, overwhelming—a break from the rural
landscape or intimate domestic interior. And it provided a vehicle for
modernist modes of artistic representation, moving toward
abstraction. While in the nineteenth century, novelists and other
writers played a major role in shaping public perceptions of the
factory and the factory system, in the twentieth century, visual artists
came to the fore.
Photography, in particular, took the lead in influencing public
perceptions of the giant factory. Itself a product of the Industrial
Revolution that created the factory system, photography allowed the
easy reproduction and dissemination of imagery, while painting
remained an inherently elite form, largely created for private viewing
by collectors or museum goers. It was fitting that photography and
film, so well suited to the creation of unlimited identical products,
proved the most important media for the representation of mass
production.
Early in the twentieth century, a number of American
photographers, including Paul Strand, Alfred Stieglitz, and Alvin
Langdon Coburn, began taking pictures of machinery, machine
parts, and industrial landscapes. By the 1920s, photographers and
artists elsewhere—purists in France, futurists in Italy, Bauhaus
affiliates and Neue Sachlichkeit photographers in Germany,
constructivists in the Soviet Union—also had turned to industry for
visual ideas, symbols, and a machine aesthetic.49 But photographing
actual factories, especially their interiors, presented formidable
technical problems in an era of large, heavy cameras, a limited
choice of lenses, slow film, and primitive lighting devices. The
photographer who first overcame many of the challenges and did
more than any other to disseminate images of giant industry was
Margaret Bourke-White.
Bourke-White’s father, an engineer and inventor, worked for a
printing press manufacturer. He often took Margaret, while a child
living in New Jersey, to the plants where presses were being made
or installed. She later wrote of the first time he took her to a foundry,
“I can hardly describe my joy. To me at that age, a foundry
represented the beginning and end of all beauty.” Her lifelong
fascination with industry was linked to her intense feelings for her
father, who died when she was only eighteen. “I worshipped my
father,” she wrote. “Whenever I go on a job, I always see machinery
through my father’s eyes. And so I worship factories.”
Bourke-White moved to Cleveland in the mid-1920s to try to
make a go of it as an architectural photographer, documenting
upscale homes and gardens. But she found herself drawn to the
Flats, the smoky, dirty, noisy district in the heart of the city that
housed heavy industry. “Fresh from college with my camera over my
shoulder, the Flats were photographic paradise.”
Soon Bourke-White was selling exterior shots of industry to a
local bank for its house publication. But getting inside factories was
another story; Cleveland industrialists, like most factory owners, had
no interest in allowing outsiders inside. Her break came when the
head of Otis Steel gave her access to his mill. With a confidence
beyond her years, she pronounced to him “that there is a power and
vitality in industry that makes it a magnificent subject for
photography, that it reflects the age in which we live.” She had come
to believe that “Industry . . . had evolved an unconscious beauty—
often a hidden beauty that was waiting to be discovered.”
After five months of experimenting with camera positions,
lighting, film, and darkroom technique, Bourke-White managed to
capture the drama of molten steel being poured. Otis Steel bought
her prints, and other industrial commissions began coming her way.
For the stage set of Eugene O’Neill’s play Dynamo, she
photographed the generators at the Niagara Falls Power Company.
Years later, when she reprinted the image, she wrote in the caption,
“Dynamos were more beautiful to me than pearls,” quite a statement
for a woman devoted to stylish looks and expensive clothes.50
In 1929, Henry Luce, the publisher of Time, hired Bourke-White
for his new business publication, Fortune. A lavish, heavily illustrated
magazine, with some of the top writers and designers in the country,
Fortune provided sophisticated documentation, celebration, and
analysis of American business. Its photographers, including Bourke-
White, had access to the largest and most advanced industrial
complexes in the country. In 1930, she photographed the Rouge.
Four years later, she took pictures at Amoskeag Mills, where years
earlier Lewis Hine had photographed child workers.
Bourke-White’s audience expanded exponentially when Luce
shifted her to his new “photo-magazine,” Life. The cover of the first
issue, dated November 23, 1936, was a Bourke-White photograph of
the spillway of the world’s largest earth-filled dam, the Fort Peck
Dam in eastern Montana, a masterpiece of formal, nearly abstract
composition and human-dwarfing scale. Within months, Life was
selling a million copies a week, with Bourke-White one of its stars.
In her early industrial photographs, Bourke-White displayed little
interest in workers. Often they are totally absent. When present, they
seem negligible compared to the huge structures and machines that
dominate her pictures. This effacing of workers from industrial
imagery was a common characteristic of photographs and paintings
during the 1920s and early 1930s (in Europe as well as the United
States), a sharp contrast to the earlier work of Hine. Though Hine
sometimes showed machines dwarfing humans, emphasizing their
large scale and abstract shapes, the bulk of his work centered on the
human experience of labor, on the faces, bodies, and expressions of
the workers who inhabited the industrial realm. For Bourke-White, at
this stage of her career, it was not the worker who held her interest,
nor the products being made, but the abstract forms of industry.
“Beauty of Industry,” she wrote in 1930, “lies in its truth and
simplicity.”51
Charles Sheeler, who beat Bourke-White to the Rouge, shared
her credo. “I speak in the tongue of my times,” he said in 1938, “the
mechanical, the industrial. Anything that works efficiently is
beautiful.” “Our Factories,” he declared, “are our substitutes for
religious expression.” A precisionist painter from Philadelphia, whose
early work included the magnificent, abstracted urban landscapes
Church Street El (1920) and Skyscrapers (1922), Sheeler took up
photography as a way to support himself while painting. His
commercial work included photographs for a Philadelphia advertising
agency, N. W. Ayer & Son, which the Ford Motor Company engaged
to promote the introduction of the Model A. Vaughn Flannery, the
Ayer art director, working with Ford, decided to sell the new car by
portraying the giant machines and factories used to manufacture it.
Flannery sent Sheeler off to the Rouge, where he spent six weeks
producing an extraordinary portfolio of images. Most of the
photographs depict steelmaking and stamping processes, with their
giant equipment and elemental drama. There are no photographs of
assembly operations. Many of the images appear nearly abstract,
with chimneys, conveyors, pipes, and cranes cutting across the
picture plane, often at dramatic angles. Workers are entirely absent
in many photographs and barely visible, at the edges of the frame, in
others. As in some of Bourke-White’s photographs, when humans
are present they serve to make evident the massive scale of the
equipment and buildings near them (not dissimilar to the relationship
between man and machine in illustrations of the Corliss engine at the
Centenary Exhibition).
Figure 4.3 Charles Sheeler’s striking photograph of the Ford River Rouge factory,
Criss-Crossed Conveyors—Ford Plant, 1927.
Figure 4.4 Left to right: Albert Kahn, Frida Kahlo, and Diego Rivera at the Detroit
Institute of Arts on December 10, 1932.
With this signal, in perfect synchronization, with the rhythm they had
learned in a great mass-production industry, the tirebuilders stepped back
from their machines.
Instantly, the noise stopped. The whole room lay in perfect
silence. . . . A moment ago there had been the weaving hands, the
revolving wheels, the clanking belt, the moving hooks, the flashing tire
tools. Now there was absolute stillness.
When the silence broke, the men began cheering. “We done it!
We stopped the belt!” Then they sang “John Brown’s Body.” Out the
windows they chorused “He is trampling out the vintage where the
grapes of wrath are stored.”65
It was like the end of the world, or at least the beginning of the
end of the world of industrial autocracy that had been part and parcel
of factory giantism. The great labor upheaval in the United States
during the late 1930s and 1940s transformed the giant factory, the
lives of industrial workers, their families and communities, and the
nation itself. With unionization, an industrial system that had once
brought so much misery now brought unprecedented working-class
upward mobility, security, and well-being. The unionized giant factory
helped create what many Americans look back at as a golden era of
shared prosperity, when children did better than their parents and
expected their children to do better than themselves.66
Workers had tried to unionize large-scale industry before the
1930s, but repeatedly they had been repulsed, unable to overcome
the physical fortresses and financial resources of the giant
manufacturing concerns. But by the mid-1930s conditions had
changed. The Great Depression robbed big business and its allies of
political legitimacy and popular support. Financially pressed,
companies eliminated many of the welfare programs they had
introduced in the early twentieth century. Wage cuts, speedup, and
layoffs further angered workers. Various left-wing groups, though
small, provided ideas and leaders to disaffected workers, by this time
less divided by ethnicity and language as a result of the restrictions
on immigration that came during and after World War I. And crucially,
the New Deal and its state-level equivalents provided symbolic and
practical support for workers trying to unionize. In 1935, a group of
veteran unionists, seeking to capitalize on the new circumstances,
founded the Committee for Industrial Organization (CIO), dedicated
to organizing the mass-production industries across the board,
bringing skilled and unskilled workers into the same organizations.67
The largest industrial facilities, like the U.S. Steel plant in Gary
and the main plants of the Big Three automakers—General Motors,
Ford, and Chrysler—initially remained impervious to significant union
gains. Instead, industrial workers generally first made organizational
advances in smaller or peripheral plants. In the automobile industry,
unions progressed among skilled tool- and die-makers; in parts
plants, like Electric Auto-Lite in Toledo, Ohio, struck in 1934; and at
smaller firms outside of the industry’s Michigan heartland, like White
Motors in Cleveland and Studebaker in South Bend, Indiana. In the
electrical-equipment industry, early labor success largely came at
smaller companies, like Philco Radio in Philadelphia and Magnavox-
Capehart in Fort Wayne, Indiana. At the number-two company,
Westinghouse, unionists established a toehold at the East
Springfield, Massachusetts, plant, but at the company’s giant East
Pittsburgh facility, scene of bitter battles in earlier years,
management maintained firm control. General Electric, the industry
giant, had a more liberal labor policy, allowing small unions to start
up at its giant complexes in Schenectady, New York, and Lynn,
Massachusetts, but they had little real power.
By 1936, with an economic recovery under way and the CIO
providing support, industrial unions began making progress even in
some factory goliaths. In Akron, where the nation’s tire-making
capacity was highly concentrated in a few large factories, a
prolonged strike at Goodyear followed the Firestone sit-down. In the
auto industry, the CIO-affiliated United Automobile Workers (UAW)
began building a base in the General Motors empire.68
The UAW picked General Motors—which operated 110 factories
and had more employees than any other manufacturing enterprise in
the world—as its primary target in its effort to break into the Big
Three. The contest between the infant union and what by some
measures was the largest corporation anywhere seemed absurdly
lopsided. But UAW organizers understood that a high degree of
centralization and the tight integration of the company production
processes left it vulnerable to a militant minority. In particular, only
two sets of dies for making the bodies for the newest GM model
existed, one in Cleveland and the other in Flint. Stopping those
factories would shut down most of the company’s domestic car-
making.
Franklin Roosevelt’s reelection in November 1936, in a campaign
marked by sharp class rhetoric and massive labor support for the
president, gave a boost to organizing efforts. UAW leaders hoped to
launch a national strike against GM in early 1937, but outbreaks of
worker militancy forced their hand sooner. In mid-November, workers
at the GM plant in Atlanta began a sit-down strike. A month later, so
did GM workers in Kansas City. Then, on December 28, workers in
the GM plant in Cleveland sat down, too.
In Flint, the heart of the GM production system, after several
years of effort the union still had signed up only a small minority of
the forty thousand workers. But when on December 30 a union
activist saw body dies being loaded to ship out, apparently to
factories in areas with less union strength, the workers sat down in
the small Fisher Body Plant No. 2 and the seven-thousand-worker
Fisher Body No. 1, blocking the removal of the equipment. In the
days that followed, workers at more GM plants in Indiana, Ohio,
Michigan, and Wisconsin followed suit. With the production of car
bodies and other key components halted, within a week the whole
GM national operation began grinding to a halt, with roughly half the
workforce idled. The efficiencies and strategic advantages of the
giant factory had come back to haunt the company, as a minority of
workers, by seizing key choke points, leveraged power far beyond
what one might expect from their modest numbers (which the sit-
down tactic help disguise).
During the forty-four days strikers stayed inside the Flint plants,
the giant factory turned from a site of managerial control to an arena
of worker self-expression. The strikers organized themselves into
committees in charge of overall leadership, security (including
making sure no machinery was damaged), sanitation, and food.
Makeshift sleeping quarters were built in car bodies and on factory
floors, using car cushion stuffing to provide a touch of comfort.
Cards, games, radio, Ping-Pong, and classes on labor history and
parliamentary procedure helped ease the boredom and fear. So did
dancers, theater troupes, and other sympathetic outsiders who
entered the plants to provide entertainment.
The GM strike captured national attention, closely reported by
newspapers, radio, and newsreels. The tense confrontation included
an effort by company guards and Flint police to evict the occupiers of
Fisher No. 2, repulsed by workers heaving heavy door hinges out
second-story windows and training high-pressure water hoses on the
police (who during their retreat opened fire on union backers); the
mobilization of strikers’ wives and other family members to physically
defend the occupied plants and provide the sit-downers with food
and supplies; the seizure of an additional Flint plant, the gigantic
Chevy No. 4 factory, which made every engine used in a Chevrolet;
the mobilization of the Michigan National Guard, which surrounded
the occupied factories; and, ultimately, negotiations involving GM
officials, CIO President John L. Lewis, Michigan governor Frank
Murphy, and federal officials, all the way up to President Roosevelt.
The agreement that ended the strike, in itself, constituted but a
modest union gain, a written company pledge that for six months it
would recognize the UAW as the representative of its members in
the struck plants. But as huge crowds cheered the haggard,
bearded, smiling men who marched out of the occupied Flint plants,
everyone knew that the world had changed; workers had shown that
they could bring one of the most powerful corporations in the world
to its knees by shutting down the giant factories in which they
labored.69
The UAW victory set off a wave of strikes and union organization
everywhere from giant factories to local retail stores. Nearly five
million workers took part in walkouts during 1937, including four
hundred thousand sit-downers. For its part, General Motors gave its
workers a 5 percent pay hike and agreed with the UAW to a shop-
steward system and the use of seniority in layoffs. Meanwhile, the
auto union won agreements with smaller car companies, with parts
makers, and, after a month-long sit-down in Dodge Main and six
other factories, with Chrysler. In the electrical-equipment industry,
the United Electrical Workers signed a contract with RCA covering
the nearly ten thousand workers (three-quarters female) at its
Camden, New Jersey, plant while General Electric agreed to a
national contract that covered most of its largest plants, including its
sprawling complex in Schenectady.70
The most remarkable breakthrough came in the steel industry,
what Lewis called “the Hindenburg line of [American] industry.” Less
than a week after the end of the General Motors strike, Lewis signed
an agreement with Myron Taylor, the chairman of U.S. Steel, which
granted workers a wage increase, the forty-hour week, time-and-a-
half for overtime, and a grievance procedure. The CIO had created
the Steel Workers Organizing Committee (SWOC) to try to unionize
the industry, but the going had been slow. Nonetheless, Taylor
apparently decided that, given the union victory over GM and the
pro-labor sentiment in Washington and in the statehouses of key
steelmaking states, unionization was inevitable. Rather than allowing
a prolonged battle that would mobilize the rank and file and perhaps
interrupt production, Taylor cut a deal with Lewis, with no
involvement of local activists or even SWOC leaders.71
As impressive as it was, the CIO offensive failed to sweep the
field, as a number of key operators of very large industrial facilities
successfully resisted unionization. The worst setback came in steel,
as the so-called “Little Steel” companies, giants except in
comparison with U.S. Steel, refused to recognize SWOC. In
response, their workers walked out in late May 1937, but the strike
ended in defeat; as in the past, the companies mobilized local
governments, police, and the press against the strikers. Eighteen
workers died during the battle, including ten shot by police during a
peaceful protest in front of Republic Steel’s South Chicago mill. Just
days earlier, when the UAW sent organizers to pass out leaflets
outside the Rouge, they were set upon by Ford thugs and beaten
mercilessly. Westinghouse, Goodyear, International Harvester, and,
most importantly, Ford all dug in their heels and refused to sign
contracts with the CIO, weakened as it was by the Little Steel defeat
and a downward plunge of the economy that began in mid-1937. The
victory of industrial unionism was not yet assured.72
But World War II allowed the American labor movement to
complete the unionization of large-scale industry. Even before the
United States entered the conflict, a defense buildup revived the
economy, tightening labor markets and bolstering worker confidence.
Also, the 1935 National Labor Relations Act, which gave workers the
right to join unions without reprisal and established a mechanism for
their legal recognition, finally began forcing employers to change
their ways. By late 1941, through a combination of legal challenges,
worker mobilization, strikes, and federally supervised recognition
elections, SWOC succeeded in organizing Little Steel.
Westinghouse, International Harvester, Goodyear, and other
holdouts fell to the CIO as well.73
The largest and symbolically most important victory came at
Ford. In the fall of 1940, the UAW relaunched its stalled effort to
organize the company. By the end of the year, the union had won
substantial backing at the Rouge and a Lincoln plant in Detroit, filing
for recognition elections. On April 1, 1941, a strike broke out at the
Rouge after the company fired members of a union grievance
committee in the rolling mill. As the number of strikers swelled, union
leaders called a full-scale walkout at all Ford plants. To keep scabs
out of the Rouge, with its immense perimeter, the strikers
supplemented traditional picketing with a motorized encirclement of
the plant and even aerial surveillance. In a reversal of the past
pattern, Ford “servicemen” working for Harry Bennett found
themselves being beat up by unionists. After ten days, the company
agreed to end the strike by reinstating the fired workers and holding
union recognition elections. At the Rouge, seventy-four thousand
workers cast ballots in one of the largest such elections ever held,
with 70 percent supporting the UAW. The union won decisive
victories at Highland Park, the Lincoln plant, and other Ford factories
as well. Then, in a startling and somewhat inexplicable move, the
company agreed to one of the most generous contracts that any CIO
union had achieved, including a provision that required all new
employees to join the union, a checkoff of union dues (which the
company took out of workers’ pay and gave to the union), disbanding
Bennett’s Service Department, strengthened seniority and grievance
systems, the rehiring, with back pay, of workers fired for union
activity, and even allowing smoking in designated areas at the
Highland Park and Lincoln plants, repudiating Henry Ford’s
imposition of abstinence on his employees.74
The swelling of the union movement continued during the war
itself. To check inflation, the federal government kept wage rates at
prewar levels, but gave unions a boost by granting them
“maintenance of membership,” requiring all workers at unionized
plants to join unless they took advantage of a brief opt-out window.
Virtually every new hire at unionized firms automatically became a
union member, a flood of dues-payers as defense payrolls soared.
Other new members came through organizing campaigns, which
unions, aligning themselves with the war effort, often portrayed as
patriotic endeavors. Union membership, which jumped from 3.6
million at the start of the Great Depression to 10.5 million in 1941,
reached 14.8 million in 1945, with roughly one out of three
nonagricultural workers carrying a union card. With only a few
notable exceptions, the giant factory had been placed under the roof
of the house of labor. Fordism had revolutionized the American
economy and society; the uprising of industrial workers gave mass
production a new, more democratic meaning.75
CHAPTER 5
On June 17, 1930, just fourteen months after Amtorg signed its
contract with Kahn, tens of thousands of spectators gathered in
Stalingrad to watch the first tractor, decorated with red ribbons and
placards, come off the assembly line. By then, a start-up workforce
of 7,200 had been assembled, 35 percent female. Stalin sent his
congratulations to the workers, declaring, “The fifty thousand tractors
which you are to give the country every year are fifty thousand shells
blowing up the old bourgeois world and paving the way to the new
socialist order in the countryside.” He ended, less bombastically, by
giving “Thanks to our teachers in technique, the American specialists
and technicians who have rendered help in the building of the
Plant.”27
While work on the Tractorstroi was proceeding, Amtorg went on a
buying spree in the United States, signing technical assistance and
equipment purchase agreements with some four dozen companies.
The most important agreement was with Ford. When Kahn signed
his contract, Henry Ford seemed to regret not being involved in the
great experiment of Soviet industrialization. Publicly, he offered Kahn
help and asked him to tell the Soviets “anything we have is theirs—
our designs, our work methods, our steel specifications. The more
industry we create no matter where it may be in the world, the more
all the people of the world will benefit.” Privately, he asked Kahn to
signal to the Soviets that he was now willing to make a deal.
Nine months earlier, the Soviet government had set up a
commission to build up its vehicle industry, which at the time
consisted of only two small factories producing fewer than a
thousand trucks a year. In the spring of 1929, the decision had been
made to build a giant vehicle plant near Nizhny Novgorod, 250 miles
east of Moscow. By then, the Soviets had approached both Ford and
General Motors about assistance, but without much progress.
Impatient, Stalin personally intervened behind the scenes,
demanding that Amtorg speed up negotiations. Ford’s new interest
was thus a godsend, and by the end of May Amtorg signed an
agreement with his firm.
The pact did not revive the idea of Ford setting up a plant in the
Soviet Union. Instead, it called for massive assistance to the Soviets
in building up an automobile industry under their own aegis. In a
nine-year contract, Ford agreed to help design, equip, and run a
plant at Nizhny Novgorod capable of manufacturing seventy
thousand trucks and thirty thousand cars a year, as well as a smaller
assembly plant in Moscow. Ford granted the Soviets the right to use
all of its patents and inventions and produce and sell Ford vehicles in
the country. It pledged to provide detailed information about the
equipment and methods used at River Rouge and to train Soviet
workers and engineers at its Detroit-area plants. The agreement also
called for the Soviet Union, during the period its own plants were
being started up, to buy seventy-two thousand Ford cars, trucks, and
equivalent parts. (The vehicles were sent as knocked-down kits to be
assembled at Soviet plants.) Although Ford later claimed that it lost
money on the agreement, it served both sides well, giving the
U.S.S.R. a huge boost in setting up a modern car and truck industry
while providing Ford with work during the depth of the Depression
and allowing it to sell off the tools and dies for the Model A as it
switched to its new V8 model.28
To design the Moscow assembly plant and a temporary assembly
plant in Nizhny Novgorod, the Soviets again turned to Kahn. But for
the main Nizhny Novgorod factory, which was to be the largest
automobile plant in Europe—conceived of as a scaled-down version
of the Rouge, a fully integrated, mass production facility—and for a
nearby city to accommodate thirty-five thousand workers and their
families, the Soviets signed a contract with the Cleveland-based
Austin Company, one of the leading industrial builders in the United
States, which had recently erected a huge Pontiac factory for
General Motors. If Kahn’s firm was noted for its design innovations,
Austin was best known for its one-stop approach, planning, building,
and equipping complete industrial facilities using standardized
designs and highly rationalized techniques. Though experienced with
big projects, the Soviet commission was larger than anything it had
ever undertaken.29
Like the Kahn engineers in Stalingrad, the first fifteen Austin
engineers to arrive at Nizhny Novgorod—there would be forty at the
peak—faced challenges quite unlike anything they had known. Living
conditions were difficult and good food scarce. Chronic shortages of
materials and labor delayed construction (though at the height of the
effort forty thousand workers—40 percent female—were on the job).
Water, heat, and power facilities and systems for transporting and
storing equipment and supplies had to be built from scratch. The
Soviets lacked the managerial experience or tools for a project of
this scope. Expensive imported equipment was lost, misplaced, left
outside to deteriorate, and stolen, while primitive machinery and
brute force were used in its stead. Layer upon layer of bureaucracy,
competition among organizations involved in the project, and
constant personnel changes made decisions torturous and their
implementation difficult. Cost-cutting forced last-minute design
changes and the redoing of carefully worked out plans. And then
there were the natural conditions, months and months of extreme
cold, springtime floods, and massive fields of mud.30
Austin largely retained control over the design and engineering of
the factory complex, but the Soviets ultimately took over planning the
adjacent city. The urban center would be one of the first new cities
built in the Soviet Union and as such became an opportunity to
envision what a socialist city should look like. A design competition
led to a plan that included extensive communal facilities and, in
some sections, no traditional living units.
The first phase of the city had thirty four-story residential
buildings. Most were divided into individual apartments housing
several families each (already the urban norm in the face of a
massive national housing shortage), but some buildings were
designed for an experiment in social reorganization. Clusters of five
of these buildings, connected by enclosed elevated walkways, were
to be living and social units for a thousand persons each. Each unit
had its own clubhouse with social, educational, and recreational
facilities and a large communal dining room, where it was anticipated
that most meals would be consumed. Showers were clustered
communally and there were library, reading, chess, and telephone
rooms and special spaces for the study of political matters, military
science, and science experimentation (to encourage innovation and
technical expertise, allowing the country to free itself of dependence
on foreigners). Kindergartens and nurseries allowed parents to leave
their children as long as they chose, including, essentially, full time.
Living spaces were small, meant largely for sleeping, with no
individual cooking facilities. The top floors of the “community units”
had larger rooms designed for “communes” of three or four young
people who would live, work, and study together.
The utopianism of the auto city quickly floundered in an ocean of
need and the desire of construction workers and later automobile
workers for individual apartments. Even before the first residential
buildings were completed, they were flooded with squatters, workers
who had been living in tents, dugouts, and other improvised
structures through a long winter. Cots and little individual stoves
appeared everywhere. Planners expected that communal living
would become more popular, allowing them to convert buildings
divided into traditional apartments to the community unit model, but
in the end the conversions went the other way, as workers sought
more private, individualized spaces. Also, cost-cutting meant that
after the first buildings were completed, designs for communal
facilities were reduced, and eventually the whole master plan for the
city was abandoned. Still, even in its truncated form, the new
workers’ city represented a particularly elaborate realization of a
broader effort to provide extensive social, cultural, and recreational
programs and benefits through the workplace, with factories all over
the Soviet Union taking responsibility for housing and feeding their
workers and their families, educating them, and uplifting their cultural
level. The Soviet welfare state centered on the large factory.31
In spite of all the obstacles, the huge auto complex at Nizhny
Novgorod, soon to be renamed Gorky, was essentially completed in
November 1931, just eighteen months after the first American
engineers arrived (though construction of the accompanying city
lagged behind). Specialists from the United States and the
application of American methods accounted for some of the success.
But much of the credit had to go to Soviet government and party
officials, who, in spite of their inexperience, bureaucratic ways, and
frequent ineptitude, proved able to mobilize heroic efforts by Soviet
workers. They could do so because they could capitalize on a
reservoir of deep commitment by at least some workers, particularly
young ones, to crash development—industrialization as a form of
revolution. Engaged in what they understood as a world-historic
project and defense of the revolution, Soviet workers made
extraordinary sacrifices, living in miserable circumstances,
volunteering to work unpaid Saturdays, joining “shock brigades,”
accepting dangerous worksite conditions, and putting up with the
bumbling and arrogance of officials in charge of the big Five-Year
Plan projects. For at least a brief moment, many Soviet workers saw
the factories they were building as theirs, as the means to a brighter
future, to a different kind of society, and were willing to do whatever
was necessary to complete them.32
Starting Up
If building the gigant Soviet factories had been an enormous
challenge, getting them to actually produce goods proved even more
difficult. Their start-up became a moment of truth for the idea that the
Soviet Union could leapfrog into modernity by adopting the most
advanced capitalist methods on a giant scale, building a socialist
society without going through an extended process of
industrialization like the United States and the Western European
powers had experienced.
The Stalingrad Tractorstroi was the first test. Stalin’s June 1930
message congratulating the tractor-factory workers on beginning
production of fifty thousand tractors a year proved wildly premature.
During the first month and a half, the factory produced only five
tractors. During its first six months, only just over a thousand. During
all of 1931, 18,410.
Not all the equipment had arrived and been installed when the
plant opened. But the bigger problem was the utter unfamiliarity of
the vast bulk of the workers and Russian supervisors with basic
industrial processes, let alone advanced mass production. When
Margaret Bourke-White visited the factory during its first summer of
operation, she reported, “the Russians have no more idea how to
use the conveyor than a group of school children.” In the plant, “the
production line usually stands perfectly still. Half-way down the
factory is a partly completed tractor. One Russian is screwing in a
tiny bolt and twenty other Russians are standing around him
watching, talking it over, smoking cigarettes, arguing.”38
The American workers, engineers, and supervisors hired to help
start up production and teach the workforce necessary skills had
their hands full. Henry Ford’s dictum, that mass production could
occur only if parts were so standardized that no custom fitting was
required, immediately proved a trial. The skilled Russian workers the
plant did have largely had been trained in craft ways. Plant manager
Vassily Ivanov raced around the factory in a rage when he saw
foremen using files to fit together parts (probably because some
parts were not truly interchangeable, a problem at Highland Park as
late as 1918). As usual in the Stalinist universe, the metaphor of war
was used to describe the situation: “We were fighting our first battle,”
Ivanov later said, “against handicraft ‘Asiatic’ methods,” making the
traditional Marxist equation of Asia with backwardness and Europe
with modernity.
Unskilled workers posed, if anything, a greater problem. Many
had just arrived from small peasant villages, never having seen a
telephone, let alone a precision machine tool. Frank Honey, an
American toolmaker, described the first worker sent to him to train as
a spring maker as “a typical peasant . . . dressed as he was in some
strange, countrified sort of clothes.” Such workers did not have any
notion of basic factory procedures. Bearings in expensive new
machines were quickly damaged because they did not know to keep
oil free of dirt. Discipline was often lax, with a great deal of standing
around doing nothing. It required a slow, painstaking process to
teach the new workforce, which swelled to fifteen thousand, how to
operate the sophisticated machinery, especially as the American
instructors had to work through translators.
Furthermore, the Soviet Union lacked the well-developed supply
chains on which Fordism rested. High-speed machine tools required
steel of precise specifications, but when the tractor factory could get
the raw materials and supplies it needed at all (which was often not
the case), the composition and quality varied from batch to batch,
making for spoiled parts, damaged tools, and long delays.
Fordism also required complex coordination, which the plant
management had no experience in achieving. Workers and
managers spent endless time in consultations and meetings, but
nonetheless things did not arrive where and when they were
expected. When Sergo Orjonikidje, the Commissar for Heavy
Industry, in charge of implementing the Five-Year industrialization
plan, visited the factory as political pressure mounted to get
production going, he reported, “What I see here is not tempo but
fuss.”
With Stalin personally monitoring daily production figures—a
measure of how important the plant was seen to the future of the
country—personnel changes came quickly. Ivanov was replaced by
a more technically knowledgeable communist official to work
alongside a new top engineering specialist. The Soviet Automobile
Trust sent yet another American engineer to the plant, an expert on
assembly-line production, to try to straighten out the mess. To help
establish order, the plant cut back from three daily shifts to just one.
Slowly, production began to improve, though product quality
remained a problem. Much of the advance came from the growing
experience of the workforce and skills gained though a massive
training and education effort. The peasant newcomer whom Honey
schooled eventually became a skilled worker and later foreman of
the spring department. (Rapid promotions for such workers, though,
created more problems, as their replacements needed to be trained.)
During the first six months of 1933, the plant turned out 15,837
tractors, a significant improvement, but, after three years of
operation, still well below the projected annual production of “fifty
thousand shells blowing up the old bourgeois world.”39
At the Nizhny Novgorod auto plant, managers tried to avoid the
start-up problems encountered at Stalingrad. They sent hundreds of
workers to Detroit to learn production techniques at Ford, while
recruiting hundreds of Americans to come help get the plant going.
(The presence of a female Soviet metallurgist studying heat
treatment at Ford merited a headline in the New York Times, part of
an unending fascination among American reporters and engineers
with Soviet women holding blue-collar jobs that in the United States
were strictly male.) Production was begun gradually, first just
assembling car and truck part kits sent from Detroit before beginning
to make all the needed parts on site. Still, the plant took longer than
expected to get up to speed.40
Again, shortages of supplies and managerial ineptitude were part
of the problem, but a shortage of labor, especially skilled labor, would
have made a rapid start-up impossible under the best conditions.
Larger than the Stalingrad Tractorstroi, what was soon named GAZ
(Gorkovsky Avtomobilny Zavod [“Gorky Automobile Factory”]) had
thirty-two thousand workers. Few had any industrial experience or
much work experience of any kind. When the plant opened, 60
percent of the workers were under age twenty-three and only 20
percent over age thirty. Nearly a quarter of the manual workers were
female. It was almost like being in an early British or American textile
mill, in a world of the young.
New workers and their foreign teachers confronted difficult
conditions. Living quarters were primitive, if somewhat better for the
Americans, and meat, fish, fresh fruit, and vegetables nearly
impossible to find. When Victor and Walter Reuther, auto union
activists from Detroit, arrived at the plant in late 1933 to work as tool-
and die-makers, most of the complex had no heat. They were forced
to perform and teach precision metalworking in temperatures far
below freezing, periodically going into the heat-treatment room to
warm their hands.
As at Stalingrad, political pressure quickly mounted to get
production going. Even before the plant opened, ineptitude became
criminalized; nine officials were tried for “willful neglect and
suppression” of suggestions made by American workers and
technical specialists. After a show trial in Moscow before several
thousand spectators, light sentences—at most the loss of two
months’ pay—were handed out, in a warning to other managers.
Three months after production began, Orjonikidje came to inspect,
accompanied by Lazar Kaganovich, like him a member of the
Politburo, the top communist ruling body. The pair blamed local
communists and unionists for mismanagement and slandering
engineering and technical personnel, resulting in the firing of some
plant and regional party officials.
But slowly production improved, a measure of the eagerness of
the young workforce to learn new skills and what amounted to a
whole new way of life and their resilience in the face of hardship. By
the time the Reuther brothers headed back to the United States after
eighteen months at GAZ, most of the other foreign workers already
had departed, the skill level of the native workforce had enormously
improved, more food and consumer goods were available, and cars
and trucks were steadily coming off the line. New York Times
Moscow reporter Walter Duranty, a big booster of Stalinist
industrialization, in declaring his confidence that GAZ would quickly
get up to speed, chided that “Foreign critics sometimes fail to realize
two things about Russia today—the astonishing capacity for bursts
of energy to get the seeming impossible accomplished and the fact
that Russians learn fast.” When two Austin engineers returned to the
plant site in 1939, they were “dumbfounded” to see that a city of
120,000 people had grown up around the core residential area they
had constructed, with six- to eight-story apartment buildings, paved
streets, “quite a few flowers,” and people who “looked better.”41
As a cadre of skilled workers developed, other start-ups became
easier. When the Kharkov tractor plant began operations in the fall of
1931, it benefited from a large group of experienced workers who
were transferred from its twin in Stalingrad. Also, rather than
immediately having to manufacture the 715 custom parts that went
into its tractors, the plant could begin assembling vehicles using
some parts shipped over from the Stalingrad factory.42
By contrast, the construction and initial operation of the
Magnitogorsk Metallurgical Complex made the Stalingrad tractor
factory and the Gorky automobile plant look like easy sailing.43
Before the revolution, Russia had only a small iron and steel
industry. The First Five-Year Plan called for a huge leap in metal
production. Key to the effort was to be a massive integrated steel
plant forty miles east of the Urals, next to two hills which contained
so much iron ore that they affected the behavior of compasses,
giving them the name Magnetic Mountain (Magnitnaia gora) and the
city that was to arise with the plant the name Magnitogorsk. By some
accounts, Stalin personally called for the creation of the complex
after learning about the U.S. Steel plant in Gary, Indiana. Like Gary,
the plant was to include every phase of the production of steel
products, including blast furnaces, open-hearth converters, rolling
mills and other finishing plants, coke-making furnaces, and
equipment to make chemicals out of coke by-products. Unlike Gary,
the complex included its own iron mine.
Magnitogorsk—“The Mighty Giant of the Five Year Plan,” as one
Soviet periodical dubbed it—was but one component of an even
larger scheme, a Kombinat, an assemblage of functionally and
geographically related facilities, which stretched all the way to
Kuznetsk in Central Siberia, the source of most of the coal initially
used in the steel complex, and which included the Chelyabinsk
tractor factory, 120 miles northwest of Magnitogorsk. Even some of
the less-heralded Kombinat factories were huge, like the railroad car
plant in Nizhny Tagil, north of Chelyabinsk. A prominent part of the
Second Five-Year Plan, which began in 1933, the sprawling factory
complex employed forty thousand workers and had its own blast
furnaces and open-hearth department.44
Foreign experts helped design Magnitogorsk, but unlike in
Stalingrad and Nizhny Novgorod no one firm coordinated the whole
effort, creating myriad problems. In 1927 the Soviets retained the
Freyn Engineering Company of Chicago as a general advisor in
developing its metallurgy industry, and it did some initial planning for
Magnitogorsk. Then the Soviets hired the Cleveland firm of Arthur G.
McKee & Company to do the overall design, but amid much rancor
the company proved unable to churn out plans at the rate the
Soviets desired. So its role was cut back and other U.S. and German
firms were brought in to design particular components of the
complex, with various Soviet agencies playing a part, too. As a
result, in the words of American John Scott, who spent five years
working at Magnitogorsk, its elements were “often very badly
coordinated.” The whole project was late in getting going and took
far longer to complete than originally projected.
Even if the planning had been better managed, the scope of work
and the challenges of the site would have made the “super-American
tempo” the Soviets claimed was being maintained impossible to
achieve. When work at Magnitogorsk began, there was nothing in
place, no buildings, no paved roads, no railroad, no electricity,
insufficient water, no coal or trees to provide heat or energy, no
nearby sources of food, no cities within striking distance. Out of the
dust of the steppe, Soviet officials and foreign experts had to conjure
up a vast industrial enterprise, and do so in the cruel weather east of
the Urals, where summers were short and winters exceedingly long
and cold. In January and February, the low temperature averaged
below zero degrees Fahrenheit. Some winter mornings it was thirty-
five degrees below zero. John Scott, while working as a welder on
blast furnace construction, once came upon a riveter who had frozen
to death on the scaffolding.45
Much like the first English textile factory owners, Magnitogorsk
managers had to recruit a workforce to build and operate the
complex, which by 1938 had twenty-seven thousand employees, and
come up with ways to house it, feed it, and take care of all its needs
in an isolated spot where there never had been a large assemblage
of people. Some workers came voluntarily, swept up in enthusiasm
for the effort to leap forward to modernity and socialism or simply
looking for an escape from their village or an unpleasant situation.
Others were assigned by their employers to go to Magnitogorsk, like
it or not. But such workers were not enough, especially since they
flowed out of Magnitogorsk almost as quickly as they flowed in, put
off by the extremely primitive living conditions and difficult work. So,
again, like the early English mill owners, the Soviets turned to unfree
labor, on a huge scale.
The Soviets used forced labor at many big projects, including the
Chelyabinsk tractor factory, the Dnieprostroi Dam, and, most
famously, the White Sea–Baltic Canal, constructed almost entirely by
prisoners. At Magnitogorsk, by Scott’s account, in the mid-1930s
some fifty thousand workers were under the control of the security
police, the GPU (after 1934, the NKVD), most doing unskilled
construction work but some employed in the steel plant itself. Even
more than the early English textile mills, Magnitogorsk refuted simple
correlations between industrialization, modernity, and freedom.
Forced laborers in Magnitogorsk fell into several categories.
Common criminals made up the largest group, over twenty thousand
workers, most serving relatively short sentences, living in
settlements (including one for minors) surrounded by barbed wire,
going to work under guard. A second group consisted of peasants
dispossessed during the collectivization drive, so-called kulaks,
deported to the steel city. In October 1931, there were over fourteen
thousand former kulak workers and twice that number of their family
members living in “special labor settlements,” initially enclosed by
barbed wire, too. Even by Magnitogorsk standards, conditions for the
forced migrants were appalling, with 775 children dying in one three-
month period. (By 1936, most restrictions on these workers were
eased.) Finally, there were veteran engineers and technical experts,
trained under the old regime, who had been convicted of crimes but
nonetheless worked as specialists and supervisors, in some cases,
especially in the early days, holding very responsible positions,
generally indistinguishable from other managerial personnel except
for their legal status.46
The use of prison labor constituted just one part of the
intertwining of the national security apparatus with the crash
industrialization. In Magnitogorsk, as construction and production
delays and difficulties stretched on and on, the NKVD became ever
more involved with the steel complex, a shadow force with more
power than the factory administration and the local government and,
at some points, even than the local Communist Party. Problems
stemming from poor planning, incompetent management, untrained
workers, supply and transportation shortages, and the wear on
machines and workers from politically driven crash efforts were
increasingly attributed to failure to follow the Communist Party line,
to deliberate wrecking and sabotage, and eventually to conspiracies
involving foreign powers and internal oppositionists, like the
“Trotskyite-Zinovievite Center” and the “Polish Military Organization,”
which were alleged to be operating in Magnitogorsk. Starting in
1936, all industrial accidents became subjects of criminal
investigations. “Often they tried the wrong people,” Scott
commented, “but in Russia this is relatively unimportant. The main
thing was that the technicians and workers alike began to appreciate
and correctly evaluate human life.”
But if technicians and workers developed a greater appreciation
of human life, the police and judiciary became ever more cavalier in
their treatment of workers and managers, as arrests, interrogations
involving “physical measures,” fabricated evidence, detentions, and
executions became common. Top factory managers, state officials,
and party functionaries toppled into the abyss as real and perceived
failures were attributed to treachery and counterrevolution, until
finally even the leaders of the Magnitogorsk NKVD, who led the
terror, themselves fell to it. Though no exact count is available,
according to Scott, in 1937 the purge led to “thousands” of arrests in
Magnitogorsk. And it was similar elsewhere; at the Gorky auto plant,
during the first six months of 1938, 407 specialists were arrested,
including almost all the Soviet engineers who had spent time in
Detroit and some of the few Americans who still remained at the
factory.47
Watching on the ground, Scott saw the fury of charges,
countercharges, and arrests impede production, but in his view only
temporarily and to a limited extent. Overall, as managers and
workers slowly mastered their jobs, supply and transportation
problems were ironed out, and new components of the complex
came on line, Magnitogorsk’s output of iron ore, pig iron, steel ingots,
and rolled steel all moved upward, as did productivity.48 Some of the
gigants built during the 1930s never reached their projected output,
but, overall, the First Five-Year Plan (which was accelerated to be
finished in four years) and the Second Five-Year Plan that followed
led to an enormous leap in Soviet industrial output. Estimates vary,
but between 1928 and 1940 total industrial output increased at least
three-and-a-half-fold and by some accounts as much as sixfold. The
greatest gains were in heavy industry. Iron and steel production
more than quadrupled. Machine production increased elevenfold
between 1928 and 1937, and military production twenty-five-fold. By
the latter year, motor vehicle production approached two hundred
thousand vehicles. Electrical power increased sevenfold.
Transportation and construction also swelled. By contrast, output of
consumer goods—a low priority in the First Five-Year Plan—rose
only slightly. Stalin was premature in 1929 when he said, “We are
becoming a country of metal, a country of automobiles, a country of
tractors,” but a decade later there was much truth to his claim.49
The cities that arose alongside the giant factories were at least as
important in promoting new habits and values as the plants
themselves. Generally, in the U.S.S.R., local Soviets—the
government—owned housing and other urban facilities. But in the
industrial boomtowns, factories often filled that role, taking charge of
almost all aspects of their employees’ lives. Much as in the early
English textile industry, many factories owned stores and farms to
supply them, with workers spending a substantial proportion of their
wages at factory canteens and shops (with special shops with better
goods and lower prices for foreign workers and later on for party
officials, top managers, “shock workers,” and other favorites).
In Magnitogorsk, the steel company had four thousand
employees in its department of “Everyday-Life Administration,” in
charge of housing and an array of social and cultural programs. The
factory controlled 82 percent of the living space in the city and
sponsored many of its cultural institutions, which included a large
theater, two theater troupes, eighteen movie houses, four libraries, a
circus, and twelve workers’ clubs, among them one for ironworkers
and steelworkers, the Palace of the Metallurgists, which featured a
large auditorium, marble hallways, chandeliers, and an elegant
reading room. The largest movie house in town, the Magnit, showed
foreign as well as domestic films, including Chaplin’s Modern Times,
which the local press hailed as “a rarity in bourgeois cinema—a
great film,” perhaps missing the irony of its radical critique of Fordist
production. Physical culture was not neglected, with two stadiums,
many gymnasiums and skating rinks, and an aeronautical club that
offered flying and parachuting lessons, popular activities in the
Soviet Union. What the city did not have was a single church.56
By necessity and design, life in the gigant factory towns was
more communal than in Western industrial centers. Especially at
isolated sites like Magnitogorsk, but even in Stalingrad, workers
initially lived in barracks, without private kitchens or toilets (or often
indoor toilets of any kind), sleeping together in large, poorly heated
rooms. Town construction lagged behind factory construction; in
Magnitogorsk, in 1938, when the population had grown to nearly a
quarter of a million, half of the people still lived in barracks or other
temporary housing. Planning the steel city turned into something of a
fiasco, as a team of modernist German architects, headed by Ernst
May, and various Soviet officials went back and forth over designs,
while on the ground building began haphazardly, with no plan at all.
The first permanent housing in Magnitogorsk, as in the town
adjacent to the Gorky auto plant, had utopian-communal features:
small living spaces in large buildings with shared toilets and baths
and meals to be either eaten at public cafeterias or prepared in a
single kitchen serving a whole structure. But a tilt toward more
traditional family structures, coming from below and above, led to the
adoption of communal apartments as the new norm, with several
families, rather than a whole building, sharing kitchens and toilets.57
Within a few years, the most radical cultural ideas associated
with the First Five-Year Plan were abandoned. Nonetheless, the
giant factory transformed the workforce. The story of G. Ramizov, a
die forger at the Stalingrad tractor plant, captured the national arc.
From a poor peasant family, he arrived with just the clothes he wore,
one change of underwear, and a basket holding all his worldly
possessions. His earnings soon allowed him to buy his very first
toothbrush, a towel, his first suit and tie, and a winter coat. As time
went on, and he switched from construction to production work, he
was able to obtain furniture, books, a clock (a symbol in the
U.S.S.R., just as it had been in England and the United States, of
modernity and industrial discipline), a stove, dishes, and pictures to
decorate his living quarters (including portraits of Lenin and Stalin).
Conventional, ordinary, unimpressive, unless one came from the
poverty, illiteracy, and cultural isolation that was the lot of the vast
bulk of people in the Russian Empire before the revolution and the
crash industrialization it sponsored.58
Did It Work?
Did the giant factory succeed in the Soviet Union? The question
carries a different meaning and weight than if asked about earlier
incarnations of industrial giantism. Elsewhere, big factories had been
built by individuals or corporations for a narrow purpose, their own
economic reward. Sometimes they also had philanthropic or social
goals, but those were almost always secondary and often
instrumental to the economic success of the factory and its payoff to
its creators and investors. By contrast, in the Soviet Union, giant
factories were seen as a means to very large social and political
ends: industrialization, modernization, national defense, and the
creation of socialism. While earlier big factories were conceived of as
a way to expand production, in the Soviet Union they were seen as a
way to transform society, culture, and, ultimately, world history.
By the measure of aggregate output and economic growth, the
Soviet industrialization drive of the 1930s succeeded. The
infrastructure and industrialization efforts under the Five-Year Plans
accelerated the growth of industry and the overall national economy
to rates that surpassed those in the West, where the Depression left
the leading industrial countries in stagnation. In sector after sector,
Soviet industrial output zoomed up, in many cases with industrial
giants playing a critical role.
Economists have debated if the same kind of growth could have
been achieved through a more balanced program of development,
less focused on concentrated investment in landmark gigants. As the
Soviets discovered, there were diseconomies of scale in creating
islands of industrial giantism in a vast, undeveloped nation.
Expensive, advanced equipment went unused, unmaintained, or
prematurely worn down through overuse. Skilled labor shortages
proved endemic and supply chains immensely difficult to create and
sustain, given the thinness of the national industrial base and the
difficulties of coordination through centralized planning structures
rather than markets. Unable to depend on reliable flows of quality
material through official channels, industrial managers built their own
off-the-books networks of suppliers, using barter, favors, and other
methods, creating shortages and difficulties elsewhere, while they
themselves often passed defective goods up the chain.75
But the success of the giant factory cannot be fully judged using
only economic measures. The scale of the great Soviet industrial
projects, more than the scale of projects in the capitalist world,
served an important ideological function. Giantism contributed to the
massive social mobilization required for the industrialization drive,
which became the moral equivalent of revolution and civil war. The
world-historic scale of Soviet factories and infrastructure contributed
to a cultural revolution in which modernity and progress were linked
to Soviet power and mechanization. And it worked, as millions of
Soviet citizens made heroic efforts to construct new facilities, a new
economy, a new society.
At a price. The industrialization drive was linked, by design, to
squeezing as much as possible out of the peasantry, even to the
point, at times, of famine. The brutal collectivization of agriculture
pushed millions of peasants away from their homes to industrial
employment. Conditions during the First Five-Year Plan were worst
in the countryside, but real wages and living standards for workers
fell, too. Circumstances at the new plants were harsh and shortages
widespread.
But comparatively the situation did not look quite so bad. Housing
was very crowded, but lack of private space was nothing new to
most peasants or even to most urban workers. What was new, for
many, was electricity, clean running water, and central heating.
Furthermore, by the standards of the early phases of industrialization
in England and the United States, working hours in the Soviet Union
were short, in the early 1930s generally seven hours a day (not
counting dinner breaks) and six hours in dangerous occupations. By
the late 1930s, material conditions for workers notably improved.76
Isolating the giant factory from everything else going on in the
Soviet Union during the 1930s—including the collectivization of
agriculture and the Great Terror—is impossible, so judgments on the
efficacy of industrial giantism as a developmental strategy are
difficult to make. But in one realm, the record seems clear. The
creation of the metallurgy, automotive, and tractor industries,
especially the plants located deep in the Soviet interior, proved
critical to Soviet survival and ultimate victory during World War II.
One reason the Soviets sited so many industrial behemoths in the
Urals was to distance them from any invasion, positioning them
beyond not only land attack but also aerial bombardment. Many key
industrial facilities were designed to be quickly convertible to
armaments production. While the Reuther brothers were working in
the Gorky tool room, army specialists would show up regularly to
supervise the construction of dies and fixtures for making military
equipment, which would be tested and stored for possible later use.
During World War II, the factory produced cars, trucks, jeeps,
ambulances, armored cars, light tanks, self-propelled guns, and
ammunition for the military. The Stalingrad tractor factory also
poured out light tanks, until the Germans destroyed the factory
during the epic battle for the city. The Chelyabinsk tractor plant
proved even more important, before the war producing self-propelled
artillery pieces, howitzers, and light and heavy tanks. After the
Germans invaded, machinery and personnel from other factories,
including the Kharkov tractor plant and diesel engine factory, were
moved to Chelyabinsk. Over the course of the war, the expanded
complex produced 18,000 tanks and self-propelled guns, 48,500
tank engines, and over seventeen million pieces of ammunition. As
John Scott wrote in early 1942, the Magnitogorsk plant and the
broader Ural industrial district it was part of were “Russia’s number
one guarantee against defeat at the hands of Hitler,” which, of
course, also helped ensure the victory of Britain and the United
States.77
But if the giant Soviet factory contributed to industrialization,
modernization, and national defense, its role in the creation of
socialism depends on what is meant by the term. As state-owned
endeavors, the Soviet giants were part of an economic and social
system built around government and—to a lesser extent—
cooperative ownership of the means of production. But whether this
made the Soviet Union a socialist society, a state capitalist one, or
something else entirely was a subject of fierce debate in the 1940s
and 1950s and is still a matter of controversy in the much-shrunken
universe of people who care about such things.78
Did socialism, or state ownership, change internal relationships
within the factory? A bit, but not much. Even in the years of purges
and terror, Soviet workers felt free to criticize managers and
government officials about how plants operated, probably more so
than workers at, say, Ford or U.S. Steel before they unionized. But
ironically, at the same time that American unions began to grow,
Soviet unions, which once gave workers something of an
autonomous base, were defanged of independence and real power
(though their role in providing social benefits expanded). During the
late 1930s, workers sometimes used the atmosphere of suspicion
and secret police power to bring down disliked officials. After the
terror abated, harsh new labor laws criminalized absenteeism,
lateness, and quitting without permission (a throwback to English law
at the time of the first factories). More fundamentally, social relations
inside the factory remained hierarchical, in much the same way they
were in the West. As one journalist wrote, describing the Stalingrad
tractor factory, the assembly line was “no longer an issue of
disagreement between capitalists and socialists.”79
When in 1931 H. J. Freyn, who had spent four years in the Soviet
Union as a leading consultant to its metallurgy industry, gave a
speech to a meeting of the Taylor Society—disciples of the father of
scientific management—about the First Five-Year Plan, he described
the Soviet Union as a dictatorship, but he felt that at its current stage
dictatorship was “essential for the welfare of the people.” And in any
case, “a modern business enterprise can scarcely be operated or
managed by applying the principles of democracy.” Like Kahn, Freyn
barely mentioned communism when he discussed Soviet industrial
development.80
The giant factory shaped the path along which the Soviet Union
developed, and became a mainstay of ideas of economic growth and
modernity in the country for decades to come. But as an institution
unto itself, it proved remarkably impervious to its surroundings.
CHAPTER 6
“COMMON REQUIREMENTS OF
INDUSTRIALIZATION”
Cold War Mass Production
Military Giantism
The downsizing of American factories came after a final wave of
industrial giantism during World War II, devoted to making military
goods. Some armaments production took place at government
facilities, which swelled during the war. The Brooklyn Navy Yard
doubled its size, taking over adjacent land to build the world’s largest
dry docks and the world’s largest crane, with its employment roll
hitting seventy thousand. But most defense production took place in
corporate-run factories, mills, and shipyards, facilities converted to
war production or newly built for the purpose.3
Albert Kahn designed some of the largest war plants in a last
burst of activity before his death in December 1942. They included
the Chrysler Tank Arsenal in Warren, Michigan; the East Chicago
cast armor plant for American Steel Foundries Company; Amertorp
Corporation’s torpedo plant in Chicago; the Curtis-Wright
Corporation plant in St. Louis; the Wright Aeronautical plant in
Cincinnati; and the Dodge Chicago plant, which made aircraft
engines (the last three of these were huge structures). But Kahn’s
largest war plant, the best known of all the wartime defense facilities,
was the Ford Willow Run aircraft factory, an effort to bring Fordism to
an industry even more complex than the auto industry.4
As World War II loomed, in a dash to build up American air
warfare capacity, defense officials—and Walter Reuther, by this time
a top UAW leader—pressed for the partial conversion of the
automobile industry to airplane production. Officials at Ford, which
previously had manufactured small aircraft, with limited success,
proposed to use assembly-line methods to produce the newly
designed B-24 heavy bomber. When defense officials agreed, a
crash effort began to build a massive factory and adjacent airport on
Ford-owned land in Ypsilanti, Michigan, twenty-five miles west of
Detroit. The main building—which covered sixty-seven acres,
making it at the time the largest factory structure in the world—went
up quickly, but getting production going was a whole other matter.
The federal government and Ford proved not much better than the
Soviets in starting up such a massive endeavor and faced similar
problems in assembling a workforce in an area distant from existing
pools of skilled labor (which, in any case, were too small to meet
wartime demand).
Part of the blame for Willow Run repeatedly falling behind
production schedules—which became a political hot potato—came
from applying mass-production techniques to the manufacture of
bombers. Creating specialized tools and fixtures delayed the start of
parts making, usually done in the aircraft industry using standard
machine tools. Repeated design changes from the Army impaired a
manufacturing approach predicated on long runs of standardized
parts. As in the Soviet Union, slow delivery of materials contributed
to delays. So did repeated reorganizations and personnel changes in
the federal defense agencies and managerial chaos at Ford.
(Contrary to its rationalist public image, Ford suffered from personal
fiefdoms, fierce competition among executives, and a lack of clear
lines of responsibility.) But an inability to find and retain enough
workers presented the biggest problem.
Figure 6.1 The B-24 Liberator assembly line at the Willow Run bomber plant in
Michigan, circa 1944.
Though like the mill, the city of Nowa Huta stood as a national
priority, its construction proved a long, difficult haul. While heavy
equipment was used in building the steelworks, limited funds meant
that the residential and commercial area was largely built by hand,
with shovels, wheelbarrows, and occasional cranes. Material
shortages and mismanagement slowed construction, while the poor
quality of building supplies led to later problems. Authorities used
agitation campaigns, labor competitions (which pitted workers
against one another), and extra voluntary labor to push the pace of
construction at what was dubbed the “great building site of
socialism.” Women were hired in large numbers, at both the mill and
in the construction effort, to promote sexual equality and help meet
the demand for labor. Many held blue-collar jobs traditionally
reserved for men, like the all-female casting crews in the mill and the
bricklayers and plasterers in the city. With housing construction
lagging behind the growth of the steel mill and the flood of arriving
workers, for years most people in Nowa Huta had to live in crude,
cold, single-sex barracks, sometimes with over a dozen men or
women sharing a single room, lacking basic sanitary provisions.
Magnitogorsk redux.40
But by the mid-1950s, the housing shortage and generally
miserable living conditions began to ease. Between 1949 and 1958,
workers built 14,885 apartments in Nowa Huta, with the original plan
essentially completed two years later, as the population reached
100,000. Many residents came to view the city quite favorably.41
The pre-1960 part of Nowa Huta forms half an octagon, with
major boulevards radiating out from a central square on one edge (in
2004 renamed after Ronald Reagan). The steel mill gates are a half
mile away, far enough so that the plant is barely visible from the
center of the city, though, no doubt, in its heyday smoke from the
mill, a notorious polluter, could have been seen. A tramline connects
the mill and the original housing and commercial district.
A distinct urbanism characterizes the city center, reinforced by
the appropriation of elements of Renaissance design, like galleries
and squares, a marked contrast to contemporary residential
developments in the United States of roughly the same size, like
Levittown, New York, and Lakeland, California, with their small,
single-family, detached houses and automobile-based design.
Apartment buildings line the main avenues and fill the areas between
them, organized into clusters designed for five to six thousand
residents. From along the avenues, the long facades of the housing
blocks, ranging from two to seven stories high, feel ponderous, but
behind them are enclosures, quiet and humanly scaled, with little
traffic. Lawns, playgrounds, schools, day-care centers, garages, and
clotheslines fill the space. Each neighborhood unit was meant to be
largely self-sufficient, with stores on the ground floors, health
centers, libraries, and other services. Cinemas, a theater, a
department store, restaurants, and public institutions generally were
within walking distance from the residences, while a tramline
provided a connection to Kraków proper (which in 1951
administratively absorbed Nowa Huta). The social organization in
effect constituted a more fully realized, if less radical, embrace of
communal life along the lines of the early worker housing in Gorky.
Figure 6.4 An aerial view of Nowa Huta.
Plans for Nowa Huta kept being changed, in some ways to the
benefit of the city. The first housing units were quite basic, but,
keeping with the idea of Nowa Huta prefiguring a new socialist
society, many of the estates that followed were built to standards far
above the norm for ordinary Poles, with more space, private
bathrooms, built-in radios, shared telephones in every entryway,
cooling cupboards, and balconies. The blocks completed in the first
half of the 1950s had a generic, socialist realist stodginess, but their
lower height and smaller scale compared to similar housing
elsewhere, like along the Stalinallee (now Karl-Marx-Allee) in East
Berlin, avoided the monumentality sometimes wrongly attributed to
the city. Contributing to the human scale was the abandonment of
plans for an unattractive, towering city hall and a monumental
theater, meant to bookend the central axis. Efforts to incorporate
traditional Polish elements ranged from the charming, like the
octagonal cupolas on the small Ludowy Theater (which housed one
of the most innovative theater companies in the country) to the
absurd, like one of the two factory administration buildings, built to
resemble a Renaissance palace with a “Polish parapet.”
With Stalin’s death, greater variety crept into Nowa Huta housing,
including the modernist “Swedish house” apartment block, derivative
of Le Corbusier. Cost-cutting, however, led to the elimination of such
features as elevators and parquet floors. As the city population grew
to exceed original expectations, new housing estates were built on
the outskirts of town. Many of these were modernist in appearance
but of poor-quality construction, with low- and high-rise buildings
separated by green space, with few nearby stores or amenities, the
sort of “tower in the park” developments that became the vogue for
urban housing in both the communist and capitalist blocs.42
Meant to be a showcase for socialist Poland, Nowa Huta
garnered national and even international attention. Over the years,
visitors included Khrushchev, Charles de Gaulle, Haile Selassie,
Kwame Nkrumah, and Fidel Castro. The steelworks and town figured
in numerous novels, journalistic accounts, films, and even musical
compositions. The mill appeared on postage stamps in 1951 and
1964. Generally, propaganda and artistic renderings presented
Nowa Huta extremely positively, as the start of a socialist future, “the
pride of the nation,” “the forge of our prosperity.” But having been
elevated by communist authorities to a prominent place in the
national narrative, it also became a pole for critiques of the socialist
project. Adam Ważyk’s sensational 1955 “Poem for Adults,” openly
critically of Polish socialism (by a writer until then known as a
communist hardliner), painted an ugly portrait of Nowa Huta (“a new
Eldorado”) and its residents (“A great migration, carrying confused
ambitions, . . . A stack of curses, feather pillows, a gallon of vodka, a
lust for girls”). Andrzej Wajda’s acclaimed film Man of Marble,
released in 1977, used Nowa Huta for a wrenching, clear-eyed look
back at the history and mythology of Polish communism, prefiguring
the revolution that would soon come to the steelmaking city, the
nation, and the whole communist bloc.43
Socialist Citizens
Like their Soviet predecessors, the showcase industrial cities of
Eastern Europe were meant to not only produce steel, concrete, and
other vital supplies, they also were to produce new men and women,
templates for the socialist citizens of the future. One youth brigade in
Bulgaria chose as its motto “We build Dimitrovgrad, and the town
builds us.” But the lived reality proved far more complex.
Some workers did move to Nowa Huta and the other showcase
cities out of genuine enthusiasm for the socialist project and the new
people’s democracies. And some found the experience of helping
build and launch new factories and cities intoxicating, something
they would look back on fondly. But many workers joined the
construction efforts and took jobs at the new plants not out of any
particular ideological identification but from necessity.
As in the Soviet Union, the recruitment of construction and
industrial workforces was intimately connected to miserable
conditions in the countryside, the result of increased taxes, dictated
crop sales, collectivization, long-standing poverty, and the impact of
years of war. Many rural Hungarians who moved to Sztálinváros
were hostile to the communist government because of policies they
saw as attacks on their home villages and way of life. The lack of
any church in Sztálinváros added to their alienation. For at least
some, Sztálinváros came to be seen not as a beacon to a brighter
future but as a symbol of everything that was wrong with the socialist
state. Experienced industrial workers who came to the pioneer
Hungarian city had a more positive view, appreciating the better
housing and higher wages available than elsewhere, but
nonetheless they often resented the autocratic management in the
plant, the intensity of the labor, and the ongoing shortages of food
and other goods.44
Poland, with the tacit approval of the Soviet Union, did not
attempt to collectivize agriculture, so there was no direct link
between forced displacement and worker recruitment for Nowa Huta.
Nonetheless, the bulk of the construction force and city population
came from the countryside, mostly people under the age of thirty.
Even in the steel mill, where many jobs required industrial skills, in
1954, 47 percent of the workers came from peasant backgrounds.
Many were landless peasants from the immediate area. “Looking
into the future,” historian Katherine Lebow wrote, “they saw a life of
relentless drudgery and cultural marginalization and found the
prospect intolerable.” More pushed out of their old life than drawn to
a vision of a new one, they hoped that Nowa Huta would provide an
opportunity to gain skills and money, escape the boredom of rural
life, and achieve a brighter individual future. As later remembered by
trade unionists, the attraction was not any pride in the idea of
working in the country’s leading industrial establishment but the
desire to enjoy the superior wages, housing, and privileges offered in
Nowa Huta once it got past its start-up difficulties.45
For many newcomers, Nowa Huta, especially in the early years,
proved a disappointment, with its challenging living and working
conditions, including high rates of industrial accidents. Many simply
left, creating a serious problem of labor turnover (also the case in
other showcase cities). Rather than Nowa Huta forging socialist men
and women out of peasant stock, the opposite seemed to be
happening, as what the communists saw as ills of rural
backwardness infected the city. Same-sex barracks, a very large
cohort of young men but far fewer women, and the paucity of
entertainment, recreation, or religious opportunities led to boredom
and rowdiness. Alcoholism became epidemic, despite drastic efforts
by authorities to control it. With it came a great deal of brawling and
sexual assault, lumped by communist officials into the category of
“hooliganism.” With civil and familial authority thin and religious
authority absent, sexual freedom (and venereal disease) flourished,
to the dismay of government officials. And when former villagers did
adopt a kind of modernity, it was not necessarily the kind authorities
wanted. Some young men became bikiniarstwo (“Bikini boys,”
named after the bomb site, not the bathing suit), who adopted dress
and hairstyles modeled after American youth culture.
Similar problems arose elsewhere. In Dimitrovgrad, former
peasants took over public parks and courtyards to plant vegetables
and raised goats, chickens, and rabbits in the cellars of apartment
blocks, until communist authorities finally managed, during the
1960s, to stop the urban farming. In Sztálinváros, young factory
workers from urban backgrounds brawled with construction workers
from the countryside.46
Communist authorities wrung their hands over the behavior and
attitudes of the working class they were creating and intensified
efforts to inculcate socialist urbanity. In private and sometimes even
in public, they acknowledged that the leap to socialist personhood
was not taking place as planned. But as long as misbehavior
remained outside the political realm, they took no drastic action.
Serious political trouble first occurred in Sztálinváros, not as a
reaction to conditions specific to the steel mill but as part of the 1956
Hungarian Revolution. Sztálinváros became a center of revolutionary
action, with a workers’ council challenging government authority.
After troops fired on a demonstration, killing eight, workers fought
back, forcing the soldiers to retreat and seizing the local radio
station. Later, when the Soviet army arrived to pacify the city,
workers joined defecting Hungarian soldiers and officers to defend
what its citizens had renamed Dunapetele, the name of the village
that had preceded the steelworks. The factory and city that in their
very appellation were to be testaments to Soviet-Hungarian
friendship turned into the opposite. Ironically, workers finally seemed
to embrace an identity linked to the showcase project when they
declared that they would defend from Soviet troops what they
themselves had built, a form of nationalist expression the planners of
Sztálinváros had not anticipated. After 1956, an effort by the new
communist leadership, installed by the Soviets, to woo worker
support through improved wages and social benefits ultimately
shifted opinion in what was once again called Sztálinváros, as a local
socialist patriotism developed in the late 1950s and early 1960s, a
sense of shared class experience and pride.47
Trouble came later in Nowa Huta, following a different course.
Steelworkers helped lead a challenge to the ruling powers, at first
not over work issues but in assertion of their Catholicism. Like
Magnitogorsk and Sztálinváros, Nowa Huta was designed without
any church, forcing residents to worship in nearby villages. Requests
from the Kraków diocese to build a church in the city were repeatedly
turned down until the fall of 1956, when, in response to widespread
protests, the Polish Communist Party brought back as its first
secretary the once-imprisoned Władysław Gomułka. Attempting to
improve relations with the Church, Gomułka gave the OK. A year
later a site was chosen and a cross erected there. Then authorities
began stalling, and in 1960 reassigned the site to a school, ordering
the cross removed. But the crew sent to take it down was blocked,
first by a group of neighborhood women and then by a crowd swelled
by workers finishing their shift at the mill. The defenders of the cross
sang both “The Internationale” and hymns, a sign of their multiple
allegiances. The day ended with a full-scale battle between four
thousand residents and militia troops, who used water cannons, tear
gas, and bullets, while the crowd threw stones, vandalized stores,
and torched a building. Nearly five hundred people were arrested,
some given substantial prison terms. The authorities, belatedly
realizing the explosive symbolism, let the cross remain.
Within a few years, Catholic leaders resumed their campaign for
a church, with the backing of the new archbishop, Karol Wojtyła, the
future Pope John Paul II. In 1965 the government gave approval for
a church near a new housing development. It took an extended
campaign to raise money for the building and erect it (with no
cooperation from the government), culminating in the consecration of
what was called the Lord’s Ark by the then-cardinal Wojtyła in May
1977, with seventy thousand people in attendance.48
The defense of the cross and building the church helped forge a
culture of resistance and networks of mobilization that soon would be
used for a more profound challenge to the establishment. But the
politics of Nowa Huta were by no means simple. In 1968, when
student protests broke out across Poland, authorities had to move
vigorously to keep secondary and technical school students in Nowa
Huta from joining demonstrations in Kraków. At the same time,
workers from the steel mill were bussed into the nearby city, where
they beat up students from Jagiellonian University, perhaps reflecting
class and cultural antagonisms as much as political differences (as
in the hard-hat demonstrations in the United States two years later,
when construction workers beat up student antiwar protesters). As
late as 1980, about a quarter of the workers in the mill belonged to
the ruling Polish United Workers’ Party.
By then, intellectual and worker opponents of the Polish regime
had become increasingly vocal and well organized. In Nowa Huta, in
April 1979, a group drawing on Catholic social teaching, the
Christian Community of Working People, formed just months before
Pope John Paul II spoke at a monastery on the outskirts of the city,
after being denied government permission to visit the Lord’s Ark.
“The cross cannot be separated from man’s work,” he declared.
“Christ cannot be separated from man’s work. This has been
confirmed at Nowa Huta.”49
Both national and local developments undermined steelworker
support for the regime. Price hikes in 1970 and 1976 led to
widespread worker protests across the country, while in Nowa Huta
the construction of a large steel mill in Katowice and a growing
environmental movement criticizing pollution by the Lenin Steelworks
raised fears about the future.50 When in July 1980 yet another price
hike led to new wave of strikes, workers in Nowa Huta joined in,
winning concessions from management. The following month, they
began forming units of the independent Solidarity trade union,
founded at the Lenin Shipyard in Gdańsk. The Nowa Huta
steelworkers had long had a union, but it had little authority; workers
wanting something often went straight to the party, the real power in
the shop. When an alternative appeared, workers flocked to it.
By the fall of 1980, with 90 percent of the workforce signed up,
the steel mill unit became the largest workplace Solidarity branch in
the country, second in importance only to Gdańsk. In a measure of
their new confidence to assert their own values, workers began
bringing crosses, consecrated at the Lord’s Ark church, into the mill
(along with Solidarity banners), reversing the flow of culture creation
from civic society to the workplace rather than the other way around
as communist planners had envisioned. Nowa Huta Solidarity
activists also joined in creating the “Network,” linking together the
largest industrial workplaces in Poland, acknowledging their
vanguard role.51
The declaration of martial law on December 13, 1981, began a
prolonged “state of war” in Nowa Huta (and elsewhere) between
Solidarity, now driven underground, and the government. Workers
occupied the Lenin Steelworks for three days before militia units with
tanks regained control. By the next year, workers had begun building
a clandestine Solidarity structure in the mill. The size and resources
of the showcase enterprise facilitated organizing. Solidarity activists
used mill supplies and printing presses to produce underground
newspapers and propaganda in large quantities, for circulation both
within and without the complex. Mill technicians helped set up and
maintain a clandestine radio network that served the southern part of
the country. Supplies lifted from the factory were distributed to
Solidarity activists elsewhere. Overseas backers sent aid to the
Nowa Huta unionists, who eventually obtained a computer before the
mill itself had one.
With so many workers toiling and living together, norms and
networks of resistance spread inside and outside the plant, as Nowa
Huta became one of the most militant centers of opposition to the
government. In 1982, regular protest marches began, first led by
workers but over time increasingly consisting of youths. Often the
protesters assembled in churches before setting out for the center of
the city, inevitably to be confronted by police and militia. In the
regular running battles, at least three protesters were killed.
Solidarity was less successful in its efforts to hold protest strikes in
the mill itself.
In 1988, Nowa Huta helped push the country to a radical
resolution of what had become a permanent economic and political
crisis. Once again, price hikes led to protest. On April 26, workers at
the Lenin Steelworks, still the largest industrial enterprise in the
country, launched a sit-down strike demanding an increase in wages
and the legalization of Solidarity. Taking control of the complex,
workers’ spouses and children, sympathetic priests, and outside
Solidarity leaders came into the plant to support the protest. On May
4, soldiers took back control of the mill and arrested the strike
leaders. But by then, the strike had sparked strikes elsewhere, most
importantly at the Lenin Shipyard in Gdańsk. In an effort to end the
protests, the government reached out to Lech Walesa, who had
helped launch Solidarity, ultimately leading to the “Round Table”
negotiations with the group, the legalization of independent unions,
and, in 1989, open elections for the national senate. The massive
victory by Solidarity candidates brought an end to communist rule in
Poland and hastened the end of communist control in all of Eastern
Europe.52
The rise and ultimate victory of Solidarity demonstrated—too late
—to Polish authorities the dangers of factory giantism and industrial
urbanism. Nowa Huta, intended, among other things, to create a
politicized working class largely out of children of the peasantry,
succeeded, but in a way its planners had not anticipated. By the
account of Solidarity unionists, Nowa Huta workers came to have a
shared pride in working in the plant not because of its role in creating
a socialist Poland but because of its role in fighting it.53 As
Goodyear, GM, Ford, GE, and other American corporations had
learned decades earlier, large assemblages of workers who work
together, live together, pray together, drink together, and die together
can turn the largest, most important factories from models of
efficiency into weapons of labor power.
The aftermath of victory proved ironic for Polish workers. Giant
fortresses of industry, built to lead the transition to socialism, stood
little chance of surviving intact the transition back to capitalism. Most
of the outsized Polish industrial complexes suffered from
underinvestment, low productivity, and overstaffing, lacking
advanced machinery found in the West. As government subsidies
were lessened, captive markets lost, and privatization begun, they
could not compete. What had been the Lenin Shipyard in Gdańsk
underwent repeated reorganizations, layoffs, and privatization, until
its workforce, 17,000 in 1980 when it gave birth to Solidarity, shrank
to fewer than 2,000 in 2014.54
In Nowa Huta, one Solidarity unionist, soon after the first
noncommunist government took power, estimated that a mill in the
West with the same output as the Lenin Steelworks would have
7,000 workers, not 30,000, a measure of more modern equipment,
more intense work, and no obligation to keep aging, ill, or alcoholic
workers. With production in Nowa Huta plummeting, in 1991 the
government, after negotiating with various unions (Solidarity, at that
point, represented only about a third of the workforce), began a
program of deintegration, spinning off various support functions, like
the internal railroad network and slag recycling, and some finishing
operations to twenty new enterprises, which together employed
about 60 percent of the old workforce. The original company focused
only on basic steel operations. To reduce pollution, large parts of the
plant were simply shut down, including two blast furnaces, the open-
hearth furnace, the sintering plant, and some coke ovens. The broad
social mandate for the mill was reduced, too; over the years it had
taken on many functions for the workforce and the city, including
running a farm, canteen, medical center, vacation facilities, and a
football club. These, too, were spun off or downsized.
In 2001 the Nowa Huta steelworks (by then renamed for Polish
engineer Tadeusz Sendzimir) were merged with the other major steel
mills in the country. Following privatization and a later merger, it
became part of the largest steel company in the world, ArcelorMittal.
The new owner invested some money in modernization, with an
advanced hot rolling mill opening in 2007. But in 2015 only 3,300
employees remained on the payroll, with another 12,000 workers at
separate companies linked to the mill. Wages, once considerably
above the norm, now were comparable to those at other area
businesses. The great heroic days of socialist construction and the
fight for faith and freedom were over. The mill had become ordinary,
like many others across Europe and the United States, employing a
modest-sized workforce, providing only a small percentage of the
output of its parent company, and facing the challenge of a
worldwide glut of steelmaking capacity—the result of many
countries, especially China, still seeing steelmaking as a prerequisite
to national greatness and modernity.55
Global Giantism
During the era when American companies moved to smaller,
dispersed factories and the Soviet Union stuck to the giant factory
model, spreading it to Eastern Europe, very large factories continued
to be built and acclaimed in other parts of the world, too. Some giant
factories operated in Western Europe, most notably in Germany.
There also were some very large factories in the developing world.
Today, the largest automobile factory in the world is in Wolfsburg,
Germany, where 72,000 workers at a 1,600-acre industrial complex
turn out 830,000 Volkswagens a year. With nearly 600,000
employees worldwide, including 270,000 in Germany, the Wolfsburg
workforce represents only 12 percent of the company total.56 Still, no
other company in Europe or North America concentrates so many
workers at one site.
Germany had an industrial history somewhat different than the
United States or Britain. In the nineteenth century, the Krupp
steelworks in Essen was one of the largest factories in the world. But
in the first half of the twentieth century, small and midsize firms
dominated German industry, often working in collaboration with one
another, as the country’s industrial strength lay in the production of
diversified, high-quality goods rather than standardized, low-cost
products. There were some very large plants making producer goods
—most notably steel and chemicals—but consumer-products plants
remained smaller. Though Fordism attracted a great deal of
attention, in practice German companies were slow to adopt its
production techniques and the very large scale factories that came
with them due to capital shortages, trade barriers that limited the
scale of the market, and a highly skilled labor force that would be
underutilized using American methods.57
German auto companies began experimenting with the assembly
line in the early 1920s, but only slowly moved toward integrated,
mass production. When the National Socialists took power, Adolf
Hitler, a great admirer of Ford, pressed the companies to join
together to mass produce a German equivalent of the Model T, a
“people’s car” or Volkswagen. When they declined, the government
itself took charge. In 1938, Hitler laid the cornerstone for a
Volkswagen factory at what was originally called Stadt des KdF-
Wagens bei Fallersleben or the City of the Strength Through Joy Car
at Fallersleban (the nearest village, later to be renamed Wolfsburg).
Like the Soviets, the Nazis turned to the United Sates for
specialized, single-purpose machinery. But the war intervened
before the people’s car could go into mass production; instead, the
factory engaged in war production using forced labor, mostly
conscripted in Eastern Europe.
German manufacturers gained experience with mass production
making armaments during the war. By the early 1950s, conditions in
West Germany facilitated its application to civilian production, as
domestic spending power and trade increased. The Wolfsburg
factory, which survived the war with little damage, converted back to
its original purpose. In a throwback to the early days of Ford, for
years it produced only one model, the Volkswagen Beetle, later
adding a closely related van. The company resisted building plants
overseas to keep up volume and make extensive automation
profitable. The German model of codetermination, which gave an
extensive role to unions in corporate management, and high wages
and generous social benefits (including large profit-sharing
payments) helped ensure peaceful labor relations. Unlike
contemporary American manufacturers, Volkswagen did not fear that
workers might take advantage of concentration to disrupt production
and force their will on the company.58
Though the Mittelstand of small and medium-sized enterprises
continued to dominate the West German and later unified German
economy, there were, besides Volkswagen, some manufacturers
with very large plants. The chemical giant BASF, once part of IG
Farben but reformed as a separate entity after World War II,
concentrated production at its long-established complex along the
Rhine in Ludwigsafen. In 1963, its managing board acknowledged
“that a company whose production volume is concentrated in one
geographical spot is especially vulnerable in many respects (e.g. to
strikes, earthquakes, and other forces beyond one’s control).”
Nonetheless, it decided to continue investing and expanding its
historic main plant, while later adding others to increase capacity. In
2016, some 39,000 employees worked at the four-square-mile site,
which had some 2,000 buildings.59
But Volkswagen remained the showcase of German industry and
Wolfsburg a temple to factory giantism. Like Henry Ford, aware that
a factory could be a merchandising tool, Volkswagen’s management
built an automobile theme park, Autostadt, next to the main plant,
which in 2014 had 2.2 million visitors. Many purchasers arranged to
pick up their newly manufactured vehicles there. After German
unification, the company built an extraordinary new plant in Dresden
to make its highest-priced models. Glass walls make the production
process completely visible, with finished cars displayed in a twelve-
story glass tower, a Crystal Palace for the twenty-first century.60
If Volkswagen exemplified postwar Western European industrial
giantism, dependent on stable labor relations through firm-level and
national social democratic policies, the Misr Spinning and Weaving
Company in Mahalla el-Kubra, Egypt, in the heart of the Nile delta,
demonstrated again the explosive potential when giant factories
brought together masses of workers and treated them poorly. Year
after year, regime after regime, the Mahalla workers have been at
the forefront of the Egyptian labor movement, defending their
immediate economic interests and increasingly intervening in
national political events as well.
The Misr company was founded in 1927 by Bank Misr, an
explicitly nationalist enterprise created to fund Egyptian-owned
businesses during an era when Britain still occupied the country and
controlled much of its economy. Despite the long history of the
Egyptian cotton industry, Misr was the first modern mechanized
textile plant to be owned by Muslim Egyptians. At the end of World
War II, the integrated mill, which did spinning, weaving, and dyeing,
employed twenty-five thousand workers, making it the largest
industrial establishment in the Middle East.
Egyptian authorities and company officials projected mechanized
textile mills as “citadels of modernity, national progress, and
economic development.” But the workforce, largely recruited from
the peasantry, did not accept the elite notion of the mill as a shared
nationalist project, repeatedly protesting harsh work conditions and
low pay. In 1938, the first large strike at the mill demanded higher
piece rates and a switch from twelve-hour to eight-hour shifts. A brief
strike in 1946 was followed the next year by a massive walkout
protesting layoffs and autocratic management. Tanks entered the
plant to crush the strike, and three workers were killed in the
confrontation. When in 1952 army officers led by Gamal Abdel
Nasser seized power, overthrowing the Egyptian monarchy, workers
at the mill expected improved conditions, but when they struck, the
army once again smashed their walkout.
In a measure of the symbolic and practical importance of Misr,
when in 1960 Nasser took a left turn to embrace “Arab Socialism,”
the mill was the first industrial enterprise to be nationalized. Under
government ownership, the tradition of worker militancy continued,
including participation in a three-day strike in 1975 that led to
substantial wage increases for industrial workers employed by the
state. In 1986, workers struck again, winning a wage hike, and two
years later struck yet again, this time explicitly criticizing President
Hosni Mubarak. A strike at the mill in late 2006, when the
government reneged on promised bonus payments, set off a wave of
worker protests at other textile mills and was the prelude to an even
bigger strike the following year that won a big boost in the bonuses.
An April 2008 protest by Mahalla workers, broken up by
thousands of police, leaving at least three dead, helped spark open
opposition to Mubarak, culminating in his tumbling in 2011 during the
Arab Spring. In February 2014 workers at the mill struck, demanding
the removal of Mubarak-era officials still in company management.
Even after yet another quasimilitary regime took power, led by Abdel
Fattah el-Sisi, the textile workers kept up their militancy, striking in
another conflict over bonuses, to protest a government decision to
end cotton subsidies, and to call for the ouster of corrupt company
officials. As had happened elsewhere, the launching of a giant
factory in the name of nationalism and modernity created a
workforce with its own views of what that meant, in a strategic
position to make their ideas about the past, present, and future
matter.61
CHAPTER 7
“FOXCONN CITY”
Giant Factories in China and Vietnam
Maoist Giantism
The giant factories built in China and Vietnam over the past two
decades came after one of the last substantial efforts to reconceive
the factory as a social institution. In the years following the victory of
the communist forces in China in 1949, a complicated story of scale
and struggle unfolded in the effort to modernize the country through
industrialization. Fitfully, the Chinese communists experimented with
new ways of organizing production, not content to simply transplant
the factory as it developed under capitalism and Stalinism to
revolutionary China. The attempts proved deeply controversial,
contributing to divisions that nearly split the country apart and
ultimately led to a radical political and economic reorientation.
At first, the factory story in communist China seemed like a rerun
of the Soviet experience, much like what was occurring in Eastern
Europe. After a period of economic recovery following the end of the
civil war, in 1953 the communist government, with Soviet advice,
launched a Five-Year Plan. Following the Soviet precedent, China’s
plan placed heavy emphasis on industry, which accounted for more
than half the planned investment in the overwhelmingly agricultural
country. Producer goods, especially the iron and steel, machine-
building, electric-power, coal, petroleum, and chemical industries,
had priority. Six hundred and ninety-four large-scale, capital-
intensive projects were to be the driving force for economic growth, a
quarter of which were to be built with Soviet assistance. China
imported much of the machinery and equipment from the Soviet
Union using short-term loans. Like Eastern Europe, China became
an heir to an industrial tradition that had traveled from the United
States through the Soviet Union, with a stress on specialized tasks
and equipment, high-volume output, hierarchical management, and
incentive pay.10
But even before their Five-Year Plan ended, Chinese leaders
began edging away from the Soviet model. First they rejected “one-
man management” of factories, seeking broader party and worker
involvement, and began abandoning individual incentive pay. Then,
in the preliminary planning for a Second Five-Year Plan, priority
shifted from huge, capital-intensive projects to smaller-scale, more
widely distributed plants, seen as more appropriate for China’s
limited financial capacity.
The Second Five-Year Plan never was completed because of a
more radical departure, the Great Leap Forward, launched in 1958 in
an effort to accelerate economic growth through mass mobilization
and decentralized innovation. The Great Leap Forward had a deeply
disruptive, antibureaucratic thrust. In industry, the new policy
embraced “walking on two legs,” continuing capital-intensive, large-
scale, modern factory development while also promoting small-scale,
labor-intensive, technologically simple industry that used local
resources. Microindustry was meant to take advantage of
underutilized rural labor and materials, serve agriculture, and provide
inputs to large-scale industrial concerns. Most famous were the
several hundred thousand very small “backyard” blast furnaces built
across the country, which, along with small mines to feed them, at
one point employed sixty million workers. Local initiatives took on a
more prominent role in industrial development, while the importance
of central directives diminished.
In addition to experimenting with factory scale, supporters of the
Great Leap Forward also tried to break down the division between
management and labor within the factory and the unequal
distribution of power and privilege between them. In May 1957, the
Central Committee of the Communist Party directed that all
managerial, administrative, and technical personnel in factories
spend part of their time directly engaged in productive activities,
exposing them to the conditions, concerns, and views of workers. At
the same time, workers were given greater opportunities to
participate in the management of factories, or at least to have some
say over the behavior of managers. Periodic congresses of workers
evaluated managerial action while wall newspapers provided a more
immediate outlet for criticism. Some administrative tasks, including
accounting, scheduling, quality control, job assignments, and
discipline, were shifted from managers to teams of workers. To
enable workers to engage technical and administrative issues in an
informed way, the country launched a massive program of technical
education, reminiscent of the Soviet Union during the 1930s.
The efforts to create small-scale rural industry and give workers
greater say over factory management reflected a Maoist belief in the
centrality of popular mobilization to economic development and
building socialism. But the Great Leap Forward, including its radical
experiment with industrial scale, proved a disaster. Output of some
goods soared, but they were of such low quality and often in
unneeded varieties that they proved virtually useless. Meanwhile,
pulling labor out of agriculture to local industry, along with the chaos
that came with a weakening of central planning and wild
misestimates of upcoming harvests, led to a severe famine. Even the
strongest backers of the Great Leap Forward, including Mao, had to
acknowledge that economic growth could not be achieved simply
through mass mobilization.
Yet even as the Chinese leadership shut down most of the
backyard iron furnaces, reasserted central control, and put experts
back in charge of industry, experimentation continued, promoted
particularly by Mao, in an effort to avoid what were seen as the flaws
in the Soviet model and the hardening of hierarchy and bureaucracy
at the expense of communist ideals. While again embracing
industrial giantism as a path of national development, Mao hoped to
grant large enterprises considerable autonomy in order to diminish
the complexities and rigidities of central planning and create an
environment for greater worker involvement in management.
The Anshan Iron and Steel Company, along with the Daqing Oil
Field, became a model for the leftist approach to industrial
management promoted by Mao. Anshan, located in the northeast,
had been one of the two largest steelmakers in precommunist China,
expanded with Soviet help during the First Five-Year Plan. In 1960,
Mao approved a “constitution” for the management of the mill,
supposedly written by its workers. Though its details were not
published, its general principles stressed putting politics in
command, relying on mass mobilization, bringing workers into
management, avoiding irrational rules and regulations, and creating
work teams that joined together technicians, workers, and managers.
The “Anshan Constitution” was presented explicitly as a counter to
the management approach at Magnitogorsk, which subordinated
workers through restrictive rules and regulations.11
Giant industrial enterprises, Mao believed, could become anchors
for new social arrangements. Rather than simply pouring out a
narrow range of goods, a steel plant could also operate machinery,
chemical, construction, and other enterprises, in effect becoming an
all-purpose commercial, social, educational, and even agricultural
and military organization. The factory would be the core of an all-
encompassing community, going beyond even the expansive role of
large factories in the Soviet Union and Eastern Europe. The Daqing
Oil Field, like Magnitogorsk, developed in what had been a sparsely
settled area, presented an opportunity to conceive a new type of
settlement to break down the urban-rural divide. Unlike at
Magnitogorsk, where the Soviets built a new city along conventional
lines, at Daqing the Chinese developed dispersed residential areas,
while providing support for agricultural production and a range of
social and educational services.12
Mao believed that the key to the advance to a socialist society,
with both greater equality and more rapid growth, lay in the relations
of production, not simply in the level of material development. Who
ruled the factory made all the difference. But there were plenty of
critics among Chinese leaders as a debate unfolded in the late
1950s and early 1960s—somewhat reminiscent of the debate in the
Soviet Union during the 1920s—over economic policies and
industrial practices. Many Chinese leaders, in the wake of the Great
Leap Forward, rather than promoting enterprise self-sufficiency and
worker self-rule, called for greater specialization of enterprises and
workers and greater use of material incentives.
Minister of Labor Ma Wen-jui represented one side of the debate
when in 1964 he argued—much like Trotsky four decades earlier—
that modern industry, with its complex machinery and coordinated
activity of large numbers of workers, required a particular form of
organization, regardless of whether it operated in a capitalist society
or a socialist one. Maximizing output “to satisfy the needs of society”
remained the “basic task” of state-owned enterprises. Socialism
eliminated the inherent class conflict within the factory under
capitalism because all output was for the benefit of society as a
whole—workers and managers no longer had different interests. But
the actual internal organization of the factory need not differ
significantly from capitalist models. Ma endorsed worker involvement
in overseeing managers but did not anticipate eliminating the
distinction between them.
For others, though, a change in ownership constituted only the
first step in the transformation of the factory and the larger society.
Politics, they argued, needed to take command inside the factory as
well as outside of it, promoting not only greater equality but also “the
revolutionization of man.” Socialism should lessen the distinctions
between mental work and manual work and between manager and
worker. Practically, that meant requiring everyone associated with
the factory to do some physical labor, bringing workers into
administrative and leadership bodies, and having the Communist
Party oversee factory management. Workers might continue to
engage in highly specialized activities within a detailed division of
labor, but that would not be all they would do. With their colleagues,
technical personnel, and political cadre they would join with
managers in determining all aspects of plant operation.13
The Cultural Revolution that began in 1966 intensified the
struggle over who should run the factory and what it should be doing.
The factory, though slow to be drawn into the escalating political
strife, eventually became a center of battle as the turbulent political
climate encouraged attacks on entrenched factory leaders and the
powers and privileges they enjoyed. Worker critics and their allies
challenged what they saw as bloated bureaucracies, full of officials
doing little of real use, while workers were locked out of participation
in such key areas as technical innovation. More radically, supporters
of the upsurge questioned the notion that the factory should be
understood simply as an economic unit responsible for maximum
production. Harking back to Mao’s view during the Great Leap
Forward, they argued that the factory should be a social institution,
serving the multiple needs of its workers and the surrounding
community, even at the cost of diminished production and profit.
Some pushed for the despecialization of factories, especially in rural
areas, so that their equipment and expertise could be used to serve
local needs and make varied products for local consumption, rather
just a narrow range of products for the national market.
The period of radical experimentation proved short-lived. As
political conflict in schools, government agencies, and factories
intensified and threatened to spin completely out of control, top
communist leaders moved to reassert their authority using the army
as their agent, as local Communist Party units were hopelessly
sundered. As order was restored, so was hierarchy, though with
great variation from factory to factory, as some degree of worker
participation in management and experimentation with organizational
forms continued. Still, the shift in the tide was clear.14
“Feeling the Stones”
The Cultural Revolution led to a break between the first Chinese
industrial revolution, based on capital-intensive, state-owned
enterprises making producer goods like steel and petrochemicals,
and a second, based on labor-intensive consumer-goods
manufacturing by privately owned enterprises. The chaos of the
Cultural Revolution, followed by Mao’s death in 1976, left an opening
for reformers, led by Deng Xiaoping, who sought to revive the
stagnant Chinese economy and improve Chinese life. In many cases
themselves victims of the Cultural Revolution, the reform leaders
rejected basic Maoist tenets, including the centrality of mass
mobilization and the need to reject all capitalist forms of
organization. By the late 1970s, many communists came to believe
that China’s continuing poverty, and its lag behind not only
developed Western countries but also rapidly developing Asian
nations like Singapore, stemmed from the country’s lack of markets.
To stimulate growth, the reformers sought at least the limited
introduction of markets. They also pressed for a shift away from
state investment in heavy industry. Somewhat like Bukharin and
others in the Soviet Union a half century earlier, they argued that
labor-intensive production of consumer goods would provide a more
effective path to economic growth and rising living standards in a
country lacking in capital but with plenty of underutilized labor. Over
time, funds generated by light manufacturing could be channeled
into more advanced, capital-intensive endeavors.15
Deng and his allies sought foreign capital and expertise to help
expand industry without having a long-term blueprint. Instead, Deng
called for “crossing the river by feeling the stones.” As an
experiment, in 1979 the government established “special economic
zones” in Guangdong and Fujian provinces, designed to attract
foreign businesses. Within these zones, firms would be taxed at
lower rates than elsewhere in the country. Additionally, companies
could obtain tax holidays of up to five years; repatriate corporate
profits and, after a contracted period, capital investments; import
duty-free raw materials and intermediate products going into export
products; and pay no export taxes. Local authorities within the zones
were granted considerable autonomy and generally aligned
themselves with the privately owned businesses being courted. Seen
as a success, additional special zones were established over the
course of the 1980s in other coastal areas and, in 1990, in the
Pudong New Area of Shanghai. Two years later came a new set of
zones in other parts of the country.16
During the 1980s, Chinese leaders came to share the cultlike
faith in the power and efficacy of markets associated in the West with
Margaret Thatcher, Ronald Reagan, and their followers. The dream
of modernity in China, wrote Hong Kong–based social scientist Pun
Ngai, became associated with “the great belief in capital and the
market,” a one-hundred-and-eighty-degree shift from the prior belief
that socialism represented a more advanced phase of history.
“Search for modernity” and “quest for globability” became
catchphrases as the marketization of a once almost completely
socialist economy began.17
A similar swing took place in Vietnam. The long war with the
United States, the subsequent wars with Cambodia and China, and
the international boycott after the Cambodian conflict had severely
drained the Vietnamese economy. Communist leaders had great
difficulty integrating the capitalist economy in what had been South
Vietnam with the socialized economy in the North. Measured by per
capita income, Vietnam was one of the poorest countries in the
world.
In an attempt to revive the southern economy, in 1981 and 1982
local authorities allowed Chinese merchants in Saigon to resume
their activities, leading to a burst of prosperity. By 1986, the
communists who had led the Saigon effort had won national-
leadership positions, promoting pro-market reforms. The Doi Moi
(“renovation”) policy, meant to move Vietnam toward a “socialist-
oriented market economy,” included reforms in the state sector and
opening up the country to foreign investment, market activity, and
export industry. As in China, ideological change accompanied the
shift in practical policies, with the Communist Party speaking of the
objective laws of the market with a certainty once reserved for the
virtues of central planning. Membership in the World Trade
Organization (WTO) in 2007 deepened Vietnam’s integration into
global markets and further facilitated export manufacturing.18
In China, the new market-oriented policies rapidly transformed
the Pearl River Delta region in Guangdong. The region was selected
as one of the first special economic zones because of its relative
isolation from the major population and power centers of the country
and its proximity to Hong Kong and Macao, and that proved critical
to its success. At the time, the economy of Hong Kong (still under
British control) depended heavily on manufacturing, trade, and
transportation. With land and labor costs rising, the opening up of the
adjacent part of the People’s Republic provided an opportunity to
shift manufacturing to a much lower-cost area with which many Hong
Kong businesspeople had family ties. At first, Hong Kong–run
businesses largely aimed their operations within China at its
domestic market, but by the middle and late 1980s, as the Chinese
government eased restrictions on direct foreign investments, export-
oriented manufacturing became increasingly prevalent, first in the
garment industry, then in footwear and plastics, and finally in
electronics.
The Hong Kong–Guangdong combination proved a remarkable
profit machine, reflecting the advantages for capitalists of uneven
global development. Hong Kong businesses, in many cases with
extensive experience in international trade, initially moved their
simplest, most labor-intensive operations to the People’s Republic,
taking advantage of far lower labor and land costs and the free reign
they were given in managing labor relations. They kept their
administrative, design, and marketing operations in Hong Kong and
used the territory’s advanced infrastructure, including the world’s
busiest container port and extensive airfreight capacity, for exporting
Chinese-made goods. As the authors of a study of the Pearl River
Delta put it, “Third World level costs are combined with First World
caliber management, infrastructure, and market knowledge.”19
As the initial Hong Kong–based forays into manufacturing in
China proved successful and the Chinese government further
loosened regulations and spent heavily on infrastructure serving the
special economic zones, more investment flowed in. Hong Kong
firms began shifting more complex manufacturing processes,
logistics, quality control, sourcing, and packing to China. At the same
time, companies based in Taiwan began manufacturing in mainland
China, too, soon followed by companies from Japan and Korea, at
first almost always operating through Hong Kong or Macao
middlemen. Many of the Taiwanese firms were headed by executives
with family ties to the mainland. Terry Gou, head of Foxconn, which
built its first Chinese plant in Shenzhen in 1988, was a charismatic
army veteran whose family came from north-central China and
whose father fought with the Kuomintang before fleeing with Chiang
Kai-shek to Taiwan in 1949. Once the United States granted China
permanent normal trade relations in 2000 and China joined the WTO
the following year, American companies began shifting
manufacturing operations to China as well.20
Why So Big?
Migrant labor made possible the rapid expansion of export-oriented
manufacturing in China—and also Vietnam—but it does not explain
the creation of factories larger than any ever seen before.30 For the
most part, their size is not a result of technical requirements of
production. Look at a photograph of a large sneaker factory in, say,
Vietnam and what you will most likely see will be rows of workers
sitting at individual workstations assembling precut pieces.
(Sneakers and casual footwear are made by gluing and stitching
together pieces of rubber, synthetic fabrics, synthetic leather, and
sometimes actual leather.) Masses of workers may be under the
same roof, but for the most part their labor is individual or in small
groups, doing work identical to other individuals or groups nearby,
without interacting with them.31 In this respect, these plants are less
like River Rouge or Magnitogorsk and more like the early English
textile mills, where weavers or spinners stood side by side doing
individual tasks.
Even when products require more complex assembly, there is
often no clear relationship between the number of workers needed to
make a particular product and the size of a factory. In the EUPA
factory, the Taiwanese-owned small appliance plant featured in
Manufacturing Landscapes and one of Edward Burtynsky’s best-
known photographs, assembly workers are housed in a vast,
modern, single-story shed. But each assembly line within it is short
and relatively simple. Thirty lines made electric grills, but each had
an average of only twenty-eight workers, not the hundreds found on
integrated assembly lines in automobile or tractor plants. Rows of
assembly workers face each other across a slowly moving belt. For
the most part they use simple hand tools, without mechanical pacing
of production, taking pieces on and off the belt rather than working
on moving components, as in an auto plant.
Figure 7.1 Workers making Reebok shoes in a factory in Ho Chi Minh City,
Vietnam, 1997.
Electronics firms are notoriously secretive, so it is difficult to get a
full sense of their manufacturing processes. But one account of an
Apple production area within the Foxconn Longhua complex
described assembly lines ranging from dozens to more than a
hundred workers each, larger than the lines in shoe or small
appliance factories but still very modest in size compared to the
overall size of the factory, with its several hundred thousand workers.
Vertical integration adds to plant size. Some footwear plants
make the synthetic materials that go into sneakers and shoes, mold
and cut pieces, and embroider logos. EUPA manufactures most of
the parts used in the goods it produces. Foxconn makes some of the
components that go into the devices it assembles, though most of
the high-end elements come from elsewhere.
Still, even adding in parts manufacturing, technological
requirements do not explain giant plant size. Rather it is like Alfred
Marshall’s comment about cotton spinning and weaving, that “a large
factory is only several parallel smaller factories under one roof.” At
Foxconn City, that was almost literally the case, with separate
buildings used to assemble similar products for different companies.
Beyond some point, economies of scale in production diminish or
disappear. In his classic study Scale and Scope Alfred D. Chandler,
Jr., after noting that at one point close to a quarter of the world’s
production of kerosene came from just three Standard Oil refineries,
wrote: “Imagine the diseconomies of scale that would result from
placing close to one-fourth of the world’s production of shoes,
textiles or lumber into three factories or mills! In those instances the
administrative coordination of the operation of miles and miles of
machines and the huge concentration of labor needed to operate
those machines would make neither economic nor social sense.” Yet
something close to that has happened in the production of electronic
devices and some types of footwear. In the case of Apple, production
concentration has gone beyond what Chandler imagined as absurd;
every iPad is assembled in a single factory and most iPhone models
in just one or two.32
Why are the factories so large? The answer seems to lie in
economies of scale and competitive advantages, not for
manufacturers, but for the retailers that sell the products they make.
This reflects a fundamental shift in relations between the two parties.
Until fairly recently, the design, manufacture, and marketing of
consumer products generally occurred within the confines of one
company. But since the 1970s they have been delinked. And, as
sociologist Richard P. Appelbaum has argued, in contemporary
global supply chains it is retailers and branders (designers and
marketers that depend on others for manufacturing) who have the
most power to establish the arrangements and terms of production,
not factory owners. Factory giantism serves their interests.33
Early in the history of factory production, some of the most
successful manufacturers established their dominance by selling
their products under brand names and controlling distribution
networks. In the United States, the Lowell mills pioneered this
approach, which was adopted by such iconic companies as the
McCormick Harvesting Machine Company. The Singer
Manufacturing Company extended the model to a global scale, as its
salesmen and distribution agents sold sewing machines across
Europe and the Americas, largely produced in just two factories. The
big automobile manufacturers used the model as well, selling cars
that they branded—Fords and Chevys, Chryslers and Cadillacs—
through independently owned dealerships that they effectively
controlled. General Electric, IBM, and RCA likewise sold or leased
their products under their own names and exerted considerable
influence, if not total control, over distribution networks.
The manufacturer-dominated system of branded products stayed
in place in Europe and the United States through the 1970s. Goods
producers like Volkswagen, GM, Siemens, Sony, Ford, Whirlpool,
Levi Strauss, and Clarks shoes (which first garnered wide attention
when its products won awards at the 1851 Crystal Palace exhibition)
persisted as household names. The companies, their products, and
the factories that produced them remained tightly bound to one
another in reality and image.34
The severe global recession of the 1970s and a series of
subsequent developments unraveled the ties. With profit rates
declining as a result of increased international competition, rising
energy and labor costs, tight credit, and inflation, many American
corporations, under pressure from corporate raiders, sought to
reduce costs and shed less profitable operations. To become leaner
and more flexible and show a rapid drop in spending, they began
outsourcing to other firms functions they had traditionally performed
themselves. They tended to start with support services, such as data
processing and communications. But over time, companies began
outsourcing core functions, too, including manufacturing.35
Take sneakers. From their introduction in the nineteenth century
through the 1960s, sneakers generally were designed and made by
the same companies, mostly large, stodgy rubber firms like United
States Rubber Company (Keds) and BF Goodrich (PF Flyers). But
then dominance shifted to companies like Adidas, Puma, Reebok,
and Nike that were built around athletic footwear and clothing rather
than rubber and focused on technological innovation, fashionable
design, and marketing. While into the 1980s most of the industry
leaders, including Nike, did at least some of their own manufacturing,
increasingly they contracted out production, until they became
essentially just branders.36
In the electronics and computer industries as well, leading
corporations began contracting out some of their manufacturing. Sun
and Cisco, two Silicon Valley success stories, worked with
specialized contract manufacturers, like Solectron and Flextronics
(before the rise of Foxconn, the largest such firm), to manufacture
advanced products, sold under their brand names. Some
companies, including IBM, Texas Instruments, and Ericsson (a large
Swedish telecommunications manufacturer), sold off individual
factories or even whole manufacturing divisions to smaller firms, with
which they then contracted to do their manufacturing. Over time,
contract manufacturers became increasingly sophisticated in their
design and logistics capacities, partnering with their clients in
integrated, multifirm production systems, stitched together by
electronic data communication.37
During the same years, a revolution in selling took place as well.
It had two facets, the rise of new, giant, low-price retailers and the
burgeoning of global brand companies that did little or no
manufacturing themselves.
In the United States, the new mass retailers had their origins in
the 1960s, when a series of discount store chains, including Wal-
Mart and Target, were founded. But it was not until the 1980s that
they really took off. Wal-Mart, using a combination of low-wage labor,
low prices, advanced technology, and highly efficient logistics, grew
into the largest retailer in the world. In 2007 it had 4,000 stores in the
United States and 2,800 elsewhere. Though no company came even
close to Wal-Mart in size, other retailers based in Europe and the
United States, like Carrefour, Tesco, and Home Depot, ballooned
through expansion and acquisitions.
With their massive purchasing power, giant retailers won an edge
over their suppliers, whether well-known companies like Levi Strauss
or obscure firms that made products sold under the retailers’ house
labels. New communications and logistics technology, including bar
codes, computer tracking systems, and the internet, allowed retailers
to monitor, communicate with, and direct suppliers on an almost
instantaneous basis. Faced with the possibility of the loss of massive
orders, companies that made goods for megaretailers were at their
mercy and often restructured their operations to meet their needs
and desires.38
A parallel process developed in the growth of branded product
companies like Apple, Disney, and Nike. Such firms achieved
massive global sales by concentrating on product design and, above
all else, marketing, making their products symbols of hipness,
worldliness, modernity, and fun. Some of the big brands at one point
or another did some of their own manufacturing, but typically they
eventually outsourced most or all of the production of the goods they
sold. Koichi Nishimura, the CEO of Solectron, in 1998 said of his
customers that “The more sophisticated companies work on wealth
creation and demand creation. And they let somebody else do
everything in between.” Apple initially manufactured its own
products, some in factories near its Silicon Valley headquarters. But
in the mid-1990s it began selling and shutting down plants,
contracting out almost all of its physical production. In 2016 Apple
made only one major product, a high-end desktop computer, in the
United States. Similarly, in the 1990s Adidas, which had made most
of its footwear in factories in Germany, began getting out of the
manufacturing business, closing down all of its plants except for one
small operation it used as a technology center.39
One advantage of contracting out manufacturing was that it
distanced brand companies from the work conditions under which
their products were made. Seeking lower labor costs usually meant
relocating manufacturing to low-wage regions, often with autocratic
or corrupt governments; avoiding unions; and paying less attention
to worker health, safety, and well-being. If child labor, excessive
hours, use of toxic chemicals, repression of unionists, and the like
took place within the facilities of a brand company, its image—its
most important asset—might well be damaged. But if the problems
could be blamed on a contractor down the supply chain, the damage
would be less costly and more easily contained. Nike and Apple
were both able to survive with remarkably little long-term harm
revelations about work conditions and worker treatment in the plants
that made their products by blaming contractors, promising better
oversight and more transparency, and issuing new codes of
conduct.40
The location and size of the contract factories serving large
retailers and brand companies varied greatly and changed over time.
Early on, many American electronic companies contracted with local
firms, some in or near Silicon Valley, to build their products. But
logistical and political changes made it ever easier to locate
manufacturing plants at great distances from contracting firms.
Container shipping and expanded airfreight capacity increased the
speed and lowered the cost of shipping. Cheap international
telephone rates, satellite connections, and the internet improved
communications. Lower tariffs reduced the surcharge on
manufacturing across borders.
As retailers and brand-name firms like Wal-Mart and Apple
relentlessly pressured their suppliers and subcontractors to lower
their prices, firms scouted the world for low-wage regions to locate
their factories. Mexico was one favored site. So, following the
collapse of Soviet communism, were Eastern European countries.
Textile and garment manufacturers built plants in Central America,
the Caribbean, South Asia, and Africa. Malaysia, Singapore, and
Thailand attracted contract electronics manufacturers. And, more
and more, manufacturers looked to China to locate their plants, with
its vast, cheap labor pool and cooperative government authorities.41
The staggering size of orders from transnational corporations like
Hewlett-Packard, Adidas, and Wal-Mart made it convenient for them
to depend on concentrated production centers, minimizing the
administrative and logistical tasks that would result from using many
widely scattered suppliers. The changed economics of shipping
made it possible for them to concentrate manufacturing in a single
small region or just a single factory. In the nineteenth and twentieth
centuries, even companies known for centralized, vertically
integrated production, like Ford, set up branch plants to assemble
products for markets distant from their main factories. But the radical
reduction in shipping costs and increase in shipping speed, largely
as a result of container shipping and highly efficient port logistics,
meant that companies like Apple could supply a particular product to
retail stores and internet customers around the world from just one
or two locations.42
Concentrated production did not necessarily mean big factories.
Sometimes it meant industrial districts or centers where many small
plants and ancillary services clustered together. In the mid-2000s,
over a third of the world’s socks—nine billion pairs a year—were
produced in Datang, China, not by one company but many,
supplying retail giants, including Wal-Mart. Production of neckties
began in Shengzhou, China, in 1985 when a Hong Kong company
moved its production there. Soon various managers left to start their
own companies and tie production grew until the city became the
global leader, able to meet orders of hundreds of thousands of units
at a time. At one point Yiwu, China, had six hundred factories where
workers, who in many cases did not know what Christmas was,
produced over 60 percent of the world’s Christmas decorations and
accessories.43
But sometimes scaling up meant just one giant factory. For some
products, including footwear and electronics, big buyers, especially
brand marketers, have preferred very large factories, which can
consistently provide the vast quantity of goods they sell and quickly
gear up to make new products or meet rush orders. Apple
represents this tendency taken to the extreme. It produces only a
very limited number of products but in mind-boggling quantities. Its
marketing strategy depends on carefully choreographed, highly
publicized annual or semiannual product introductions, stimulating
global stampedes by consumers eager to get the newest product
and demonstrate their position on the leading edge of technology,
style, and modernity. In June 2010, Apple sold 1.7 million iPhone 4s
in the three days following its introduction. In September 2012, it sold
five million iPhone 5s on the first weekend of sales. Three years
later, the company sold more than thirteen million iPhone 6 and 6
Plus units during the first three days after launch. With final product
design often locked up only shortly before sales begin, Apple needs
to mobilize a vast amount of labor in a very short time to produce
inventory for the sales rush to come. Factory giantism has been the
solution Apple has adopted, though the giant factories are not its
own.
Using giant contract manufacturers, like Foxconn and Yue Yuen,
has allowed Apple, Nike, and their ilk to operate without large
standing inventories of products that tie up capital and run up
warehouse expenses. Even more important, just-in-time production
avoids the possibility of being stuck with piles of outdated cell
phones, laptops, or sneakers in what are essentially fashion
industries. Tim Cook—the Apple executive who masterminded the
company’s shift from in-house production to contracting out before
succeeding Steve Jobs as CEO—once called inventory
“fundamentally evil.” “You kind of want to manage it like you’re in the
dairy business. If it gets past its freshness date, you have a
problem.”44
Foxconn and Pegatron keep Apple’s milk fresh by rapidly
mobilizing hundreds of thousands of young, poorly paid Chinese
workers, often under harsh conditions (perhaps closer to evil than
inventory). In 2007, just weeks before the scheduled unveiling of the
first iPhone, Jobs decided to switch from a plastic to a glass screen.
When the first shipment of glass screens arrived at the Foxconn
Longhua plant at midnight, eight thousand workers were awoken in
the dormitories, given a biscuit and a cup of tea, and sent off to
begin a twelve-hour shift fitting the screens into their frames.
Working around the clock, the plant was soon pouring out ten
thousand iPhones a day. On occasion, to fulfill an order, Foxconn
moved large groups of workers from one factory to another in an
entirely different part of the country. Meeting surges of demand
requires not only a vast army of labor but also a large corps of junior
officers, thousands of industrial engineers to set up assembly lines
and oversee them, something that China, with its massive program
of technical education, can provide. It is this ability to quickly scale
up (and, when the rush is over, quickly scale down) production that
Apple and other customers prize in the giant contract manufacturing
plants that have sprung up in East Asia.45
A combination of Fordism and Taylorism facilitates the rapid
mobilization of unskilled workers. Apple is ideal for this approach,
because it makes a very limited number of highly standardized
products, just as Henry Ford did. Some of the final assembly
procedures for Apple’s computers and mobile devices are highly
automated, but most are not. Rather, they involve an extreme
division of labor, very simple tasks repeated over, and over, and over
again. Workers can be taught them in virtually no time—critical given
the very high turnover of workers at factories employing Chinese
migrant workers (who have no reason to be loyal to their employers
and frequently switch jobs) and the need to bring on fleets of new
employees rapidly when big orders come in. The orientation for new
hires at Foxconn involves lectures about company culture and rules,
but no training in actual production tasks.46
Many large contract manufacturing firms cope with big rush
orders by subcontracting some of the work to small companies with
which they have relationships. Rather than either/or, large and small
factories often work in symbiotic relationships, with the bigger
companies helping small ones, sometimes just family workshops, to
set up as parts suppliers or as subcontract assemblers or
processors. Such networks enhance the ability of big firms to quickly
scale up production without adding to their fixed costs.47
Some contract manufacturers have preferred large-scale
factories for their own convenience or out of a kind of corporate
vanity, separate from the preference of their customers. The head of
a firm that made cases for PCs and game consoles related that he
preferred to buy land in low-wage areas close to major markets,
build a large factory, and set up suppliers right there. Rather than
many small factories, his company runs six big industrial parks
spread around the globe. Yue Yuan built gigantic factories in part
simply as a strategy to quickly raise its capacity to produce a vast
volume of shoes in its successful quest to become the world’s
largest footwear company. Foxconn’s Longhua plant grew very large
out of a rush to scale up production, as well as to serve as a
showcase for the company and its CEO, Gou. The manager of the
complex felt it far too big for efficient operation. Most subsequent
Foxconn factories have been considerably smaller, though still very
large.48
Asian industrial giantism requires state support. In recent
decades, the Chinese government has maintained the Soviet and
early Mao-era view that very large concentrations of productive
capacity are the quickest route to industrial advance and economic
growth (a policy Vietnam has followed as well), with distributed,
small manufacturing no longer a major thrust. Concentration has not
necessarily meant giant factories. The Chinese government actively
encouraged the creation of the sprawling clusters of small and
midsize firms making specialized products, providing big parcels of
land for development, creating industrial parks, building
infrastructure and transportation, and providing tax benefits. But
often it has meant outsized plants. One manager in the Chinese
automobile industry, which is partially owned and heavily guided by
government entities, told sociologist Lu Zhang “the government
wants big firms. To achieve large scales and high volumes in a short
time, we rely not only on highly advanced machinery, but also on our
hard-working workers—our comparative advantage.” Provincial
Chinese governments have embraced industrial giantism as a
development strategy. Companies seeking to build large new plants
have been offered land (sometimes for free), tax breaks, reduced-
cost electricity, and help in recruiting a workforce (including student
interns, an increasingly important source of cheap labor for
manufacturers).49
Some giant Asian factories have had severe health and safety
problems. In 1997, an internal report commissioned by Nike found
serious problems with toxic chemicals in a large Korean-owned
contracting plant in Vietnam. Levels of toluene in the air far
exceeded both U.S. and Vietnamese standards. Pervasive dust and
oppressive heat and noise added to the poor conditions. In China,
too, exposure to toluene, along with benzene and xylene, created
hazardous conditions in footwear factories. Chemical solvents used
to clean screens are a hazard in electronics factories. Aluminum
dust, from making and polishing cases for iPads, presents another
danger; workers breathe it in and it can be highly explosive. A 2011
blast at the Foxconn Chengdu plant caused by the dust killed four
workers and severely injured eighteen others.58
In Lowell, boardinghouses, centers of sociability and relaxation
albeit strictly regulated by the companies, provided something of a
respite from the monotony, fatigue, and regimentation of the factory.
At many Chinese factories that is less the case. About a quarter of
Foxconn’s Shenzhen workers live in company housing, one of the
thirty-three dormitories inside its factory complexes or the one
hundred and twenty dorms it rents nearby. Foxconn dorm rooms
typically house six to twelve workers, more than housed in Lowell
boardinghouse rooms, though unlike in Lowell, each worker has her
or his own bunk bed. (Many Taiwanese-owned factories also have
higher-grade housing for managers.) Workers are assigned to rooms
randomly, so that friends, relatives, workers from the same
production area, or workers from the same region rarely bunk
together. With some roommates working day shifts and others at
night, disruptions come regularly and rooms cannot be used for
socializing. As in Lowell, strict rules regulate dormitory behavior:
curfews are enforced, visitors restricted, and cooking forbidden.59
But many industrial giants, including some though not all
Foxconn plants, have extensive on-site social and recreational
facilities that provide opportunities for relaxation, socializing, and
entertainment. Foxconn City, in addition to dormitories, production
buildings, and warehouses, includes a library, bookstores, a variety
of cafeterias and restaurants, supermarkets, extensive sports
facilities including swimming pools, basketball courts, soccer fields,
and a stadium, a movie theater, electronic game rooms, cybercafés,
a wedding-dress shop, banks, ATMs, two hospitals, a fire station, a
post office, and huge LED screens that show announcements and
cartoons. In 2012, a central kitchen used three tons of pork and
thirteen tons of rice every day to feed workers. Another company’s
factory complex, where workers made small motors for electronic
devices and automobile accessories, contained a skating rink,
basketball courts, badminton fields, table-tennis courts, billiards, and
a cybercafé (though workers complained about the lack of Wi-Fi in
the dormitories).
At Foxconn City, the giant outdoor television screens and
extensive shopping and recreational venues brought consumer
modernity into the plant itself, offering workers a taste of the world
they left their villages seeking. Migrant workers often quickly
assimilate to it. Journalist James Fallows wrote after visiting
Longhua in 2012, “At factories I’d previously seen across China,
workers looked and acted like country people weathered by their
rough upbringing. Most of the Foxconn employees looked like they
could have come from a junior college.” Many second-generation
migrant workers own—or are saving to own—the products they
themselves make that symbolize modernity, like smartphones and
stylish footwear and apparel.60
Militant Workers
Fallows sees China as a feel-good story, a country rapidly moving
from working-class living conditions like those in William Blake’s
England to those like in the United States in the 1920s, and
continuing upward. Since China began allowing foreign entities to
build and run factories, there has been an enormous decline in
poverty, also the case in Vietnam. According to World Bank data,
between 1981 and 2012 more than a half billion Chinese rose above
a poverty line defined as living on the equivalent (in 2011 dollars) of
$1.90 a day or less. Life expectancy at birth rose from sixty-seven in
1981 to seventy-six in 2014. Nonetheless, even at the most modern
industrial giants in China and Vietnam, factories with pay and
conditions above local norms, workers have repeatedly expressed
their dissatisfaction through high turnover rates, strikes, and
protests.
In recent decades, China has experienced a massive, if not well
publicized, strike wave. The China Labour Bulletin details 180 strikes
in 2014 and 2015 that involved a thousand or more workers,
estimating that it has information on only 10 to 15 percent of all
strikes that occurred. By contrast, during those same two years,
there were only thirty-three strikes with a thousand or more workers
in the United States.61
All kinds of factories in China have been hit by walkouts—large
and small, state-owned and privately owned. Strikes have occurred
at leading industrial giants in the electronic and footwear industries
over pay, benefits, and working hours. Tactics, beyond stopping
work, have included threatening suicides, blocking roads, and
marching on government offices. With many strikers living in
company dormitories, stoppages often become de facto occupations
or sit-downs.
Even the largest contract manufacturers have been affected. In
2012, 150 workers at a Foxconn plant in Wuhan spent two days on a
building roof threatening to jump off to protest a pay cut that
accompanied their transfer from Shenzhen and conditions in the new
plant. In the Spring of 2014, most of the forty thousand workers at a
Yue Yuen factory in Guangdong Province struck to demand that the
firm comply with a law obligating it to make pension contributions,
one of the largest single-site strikes China has seen. Some protests
have been violent. Workers at the Foxconn Chengdu plant rioted
several times in fury over uninhabitable dormitory conditions and pay
cuts. In one case, it took two hundred police officers to end the
protest.
Chinese strikes occur in a legal gray zone. For years, workers
had a right to strike, encoded in the constitutions of 1975 and 1978.
But in 1982, as the government moved to attract foreign investment
and reject the mass mobilizations of the Cultural Revolution, the right
was removed from the fundamental law. Now workers cannot openly
organize or publicize job actions. But they strike nonetheless. Most
walkouts arise with little if any prior organization, no union
involvement, and no clear leaders, and last a day or two at most.
Often they end when the government intervenes to mediate.
As long as the stoppages are local, short, and nonpolitical, the
government generally tolerates them. But if they get out of hand or
last too long, physical force and arrests are used to break them up.
Authorities want to make sure that labor turbulence does not drive
away foreign investors or threaten the political status quo. For their
part, foreign factory owners seem confident that the government will
keep labor militancy under control, not hesitating to concentrate
production in very large plants that if shut down would halt most or
all production of particular goods.62
Strikes are even more common in Vietnam than China. Workers
there have a legal right to strike, though in practice most walkouts
have taken place without the elaborate steps necessary for
authorization. Worker strikes hit large South Korean and Taiwanese-
owned factories making shoes for Nike, Adidas, and other global
brands in 2007, 2008, 2010, 2012, and 2015. The gigantic 2011
strike at the Yue Yuen factory, protesting low wages, captured
international attention for its sheer size.
Even more startling were the riots three years later, which
damaged or destroyed scores of foreign-owned factories outside of
Ho Chi Minh City. The disturbances began with a rally of workers
protesting China’s deployment of an oil rig into waters claimed by
Vietnam. But the protesters soon turned against nearby sneaker and
clothing factories, many of which were Taiwanese, South Korean,
Japanese, or Malaysian owned, angry about stagnating wages and
foreign exploitation. A staff person at the Taiwanese Chutex Garment
Factory reported that some eight thousand to ten thousand workers
were involved in an attack on the plant, burning “everything, all of the
materials, computers, machines.”63
In China, worker militancy has pushed up wages and improved
conditions, aided by pressure from international labor rights groups
and brand companies afraid of their reputations being sullied by
stories of worker abuse. Even so, by the 2010s large factories were
having difficulty recruiting and retaining migrant workers. The rapid
expansion of manufacturing, a shrinking rural population, a gender
imbalance favoring men, and the growth of service-sector female
employment meant that the pool of young women from the
countryside that the factories preferred was effectively tapped out.
Foxconn and other firms were forced to broaden their hiring
practices, turning to men—who now constitute the majority of
Foxconn employees—and older workers.64
Companies responded to rising wages and labor shortages by
building new plants in lower-wage regions of central China. Many
also turned to semicoercive measures to recruit and retain workers,
echoes—though much attenuated—of practices from the earliest
days of the factory. Some companies insisted that migrant workers
make “deposits” to obtain their jobs, which would only be refunded if
they left with permission of the firm. Similarly, companies withheld
parts of workers’ wages, promising to pay them at the end of the
year.65 Larger factories, under greater scrutiny and more attuned to
international standards, were less likely to engage in such tactics.
Instead, they turned to student interns as a new, cheap labor supply.
Chinese vocational schools require completion of a six-month or
one-year internship before graduation. Foxconn and other firms have
exploited this requirement by working with government and
educational authorities to have large numbers of student interns sent
to their factories, along with their teachers, who serve as de facto
foremen and forewomen. In the summer of 2010, Foxconn had
150,000 interns, including more than 28,000 making Apple products
at its Guanlan factory in Shenzhen. Generally, interns engage in
basic production jobs that have no relationship to their field of study.
Instead, the internships are simply enforced labor—students can
leave, but doing so jeopardizes their ability to graduate. Interns
receive basic entry-level wages but no benefits, making them
cheaper than regular employees. Though not bound labor like parish
apprentices in English textile mills, the students, who have become
an increasingly important component of the Chinese factory labor
force, are not exactly free workers hired through an open labor
market, either. Rather, they are mobilized by state-company
institutional arrangements that give them no real freedom of
choice.66
Introduction
1. Most manufacturing jobs are in factories, but not all. Some are in retail
establishments, like bakeries, or even in homes. U.S. Bureau of Labor
Statistics, “Employment, Hours and Earnings from the Current Employment
Statistics survey (National),” http://data.bls.gov/pdq/SurveyOutputServlet
(accessed Sept. 24, 2016).
2. Heather Long, “U.S. Has Lost 5 Million Manufacturing Jobs Since 2000,” CNN
Money, Mar. 29, 2016, http://money.cnn.com/2016/03/29/news/economy/us-
manufacturing-jobs/; The World Bank, World Data Bank, “Employment in
Industry and World Development Indicators” (based on International Labour
Organization data), http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/SL.IND.EMPL.ZS, and
http://databank.worldbank.org/data/reports.aspx?
source=2&series=SL.IND.EMPL.ZS&country= (accessed Sept. 24, 2016);
Central Intelligence Agency, The World Factbook, 2017 (New York: Skyhorse
Publishing, 2016), 179.
3. For life on the eve of the Industrial Revolution, see Fernand Braudel, The
Structures of Everyday Life: Civilization and Capitalism, 15th–18th Century, vol.
1 (New York: Harper and Row, 1981) (French life expectancy, 90), and E. J.
Hobsbawm, The Age of Revolution, 1789–1848 (New York: New American
Library, 1962), 22–43. See also Roderick Floud, Kenneth Wachter, and
Annabel Gregory, Height, Health and History: Nutritional Status in the United
Kingdom, 1750–1980 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990), 292;
Thomas Piketty, Capital in the Twenty-First Century (Cambridge, MA: Harvard
University Press, 2014), 71–72; and Central Intelligence Agency, World
Factbook, 2017, 303, 895, 943.
4. Tim Strangleman, “‘Smokestack Nostalgia,’ ‘Ruin Porn’ or Working-Class
Obituary: The Role and Meaning of Deindustrial Representation,” International
Labor and Working-Class History 84 (Fall 2013), 23–37; Marshall Berman,
“Dancing with America: Philip Roth, Writer on the Left,” New Labor Forum 9
(Fall–Winter 2001), 53–54.
5. “modern, adj. and n.” and “modernity, n.” OED Online. September 2016.
Oxford University Press. http://www.oed.com/view/Entry/120618 (accessed
September 17, 2016); Raymond Williams, Keywords: A Vocabulary of Culture
and Society, rev. ed. (New York: Oxford University Press, 1983), 208–09;
Jürgen Habermas, “Modernity: An Unfinished Project,” in M. Passerin
d’Entrèves and Seyla Benhabib, eds., Habermas and the Unfinished Project of
Modernity: Critical Essays on the Philosophical Discourse of Modernity
(Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1997); Peter Gay, Modernism: The Lure of
Heresy, From Baudelaire to Beckett and Beyond (New York: W. W. Norton,
2008).
6. Size can be measured in different ways. I have defined it by number of
employees. As a labor historian, that seems natural, coming from an interest in
the lived experience of workers and class relations. There are other useful
ways to define scale that would lead to the selection of a different set of
factories to study. If we were to look at the size of factory buildings, in the
current era the massive aircraft factories of Boeing and Airbus would rise to the
fore, huge structures that go on and on but have within them fewer workers
than many more compact plants. To understand the ecological impact of large
factories, we might define size by the acreage of the sites on which production
facilities are located. By that standard, chemical plants and, especially, atomic-
fuel and weapons complexes exceed in size most of the factories discussed in
this book. My definition of size is somewhat arbitrary, but it serves well the
focus of this study on the linkage between the factory and modernity.
7. Gillian Darley, Factory (London: Reaktion Books, 2003), and Nina Rappaport,
Vertical Urban Factory (New York: Actar, 2016) are exceptions, but are heavily
architectural in their tilt.
Chapter 1
“LIKE MINERVA FROM THE BRAIN OF JUPITER”
1. Prior to 1721, only a few British industries had centralized production facilities
and these, by later standards, were quite small, like the Nottingham framework
knitting workshops that employed several dozen workers apiece. In Central
and Western Europe, there were a few large-scale, unmechanized
manufacturing operations. Maxine Berg, The Age of Manufactures: Industry,
Innovation and Work in Britain, 1700–1820 (Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1985),
212; Fernand Braudel, The Wheels of Commerce: Civilization and Capitalism,
15th–18th Century, vol. II (New York: Harper & Row, 1982), 329–38. U.S. figure
calculated from 1850 census data in U.S. Census Office, Manufacturers of the
United States in 1860 (Washington, D.C., 1865), 730.
2. The Derby silk mill is generally considered the first factory in England, the
pioneer in the Industrial Revolution. There were at least a few earlier
production facilities that had some if not all the characteristics of modern
factories, including the sixteenth-century silk mills in Bologna, which developed
some of the machinery and organization that the Lombes later copied. Anthony
Calladine, “Lombe’s Mill: An Exercise in Reconstruction,” Industrial Archeology
Review XVI, 1 (Autumn 1993), 82, 86.
3. Calladine, “Lombe’s Mill,” 82, 89; William Henry Chaloner, People and
Industries (London, Frank Cass and Co., Ltd., 1963), 14–15. An 1891 fire
destroyed most of the building, which was reconstructed on a smaller scale. It
now houses the Derby Silk Mill museum.
4. S. R. H. Jones, “Technology, Transaction Costs, and the Transition to Factory
Production in the British Silk Industry, 1700–1870,” Journal of Economic
History XLVII (1987), 75; Chaloner, People and Industries, 9–18; Calladine,
“Lombe’s Mill,” 82, 87–88; R. B. Prosser and Susan Christian, “Lombe, Sir
Thomas (1685–1739),” rev. Maxwell Craven, Susan Christian, Oxford
Dictionary of National Biography (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2004);
online ed., Jan. 2008, http://www.oxforddnb.com/view/article/16956.
5. John Guardivaglio, one of the Italian workers who had come back with John
Lombe, helped set up the mill near Manchester. Tram could be made from raw
silk imported from Persia, easier to get than the higher-quality Italian or
Chinese silk needed for organzine. Calladine, “Lombe’s Mill,” 87, 96–97; Berg,
Age of Manufactures, 202–03; Jones, “Technology, Transaction Costs, and the
Transition to Factory Production,” 77.
6. Daniel Defoe, A Tour Thro’ the Whole Island of Great Britain, 3rd. ed., vol. III
(London: J. Osborn, 1742), 67; Charles Dickens, Hard Times for These Times
([1854] London: Oxford University Press, 1955), 7, 1.
7. James Boswell, The Life of Samuel Johnson, vol. III (London: J.M. Dent &
Sons, 1906), 121.
8. Though India was the most prominent center of cotton textile production, there
were others, including Southeast Asia, the Arabian Gulf, and the Ottoman
Empire, where artisans turned out imitations of Indian cottons. Prasannan
Parthasarathi, “Cotton Textiles in the Indian Subcontinent, 1200–1800,” 17–41,
and Giorgio Riello, “The Globalization of Cotton Textiles: Indian Cottons,
Europe, and the Atlantic World, 1600–1850,” 274, in The Spinning World: A
Global history of Cotton Textiles, 1200–1850, ed. Riello and Parthasarathi
(Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2009), 17–41.
9. Giorgio Riello, Cotton: The Fabric that Made the Modern World (Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press, 2013), 126; Andrew Ure, The Philosophy of
Manufactures or An Exposition of the Scientific, Moral, and Commercial
Economy of the Factory System of Great Britain (1835; New York: Augustus M.
Kelley, 1967), 12.
10. D. T. Jenkins, “Introduction,” in D. T. Jenkins, The Textile Industries (Volume 8
of the Industrial Revolutions, ed. R. A. Church and E. A. Wrigley) (Cambridge,
MA: Blackwell, 1994), xvii; Riello, Cotton, 127.
11. Riello, Cotton, 172–73, 176; Berg, Age of Manufactures, 205.
12. Fustians were easier to produce than all-cotton fabric because flax warps were
less likely than cotton to break during weaving.
13. Riello, “The Globalization of Cotton Textiles, 337–39; Riello, Cotton, 217, 219.
14. In the 1850s, the United States supplied 77 percent of the raw cotton imported
by Britain, 90 percent by France, 92 percent by Russia, and 60 percent by the
German states. Between 1820 and 1860 the number of slaves in Mississippi
and Louisiana, mostly growing cotton, rose from 101,878 to 768,357. R. S.
Fitton and A. P. Wadsworth, The Strutts and the Arkwrights 1758–1830: A
Study of the Early Factory System (Manchester: Manchester University Press,
1958), 347–48; Riello, Cotton, 188, 191, 195 (Marx quote), 200–207, 259;
Frederick Douglass, “What to the Slave Is the Fourth of July?,” in Frederick
Douglass: Selected Speeches and Writings, ed. Philip S. Foner (Chicago:
Lawrence Hill, 1999), 197; Sven Beckert, Empire of Cotton: A Global History
(New York: Knopf, 2014), 243; Walter Johnson, River of Dark Dreams: Slavery
and Empire in the Cotton Kingdom (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press,
2013), 256.
15. Edward Baines, History of the Cotton Manufacture in Great Britain (London: H.
Fisher, R. Fisher, and P. Jackson, [1835]), 11; R. L. Hills, “Hargreaves,
Arkwright and Crompton, ‘Why Three Inventors?’ ” Textile History 10 (1979),
114–15.
16. Baines, History of the Cotton Manufacture, 115; Deborah Valenze, The First
Industrial Woman (New York: Oxford University Press, 1995), 78; David S.
Landes, The Unbound Prometheus: Technological Change and Industrial
Development in Western Europe from 1750 to the Present (Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press, 1969), 57. European commentators and
historians long claimed that Indian wages were far below British ones, leading
to lower prices for cotton products, but recently some historians have
challenged this view. For a restatement of the orthodox position, see Beckert,
Empire of Cotton, 64; for a reassessment suggesting near parity of wages, see
Prasannan Parthasarathi, Why Europe Grew Rich and Asia Did Not: Global
Economic Divergence, 1600–1850 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
2011), 35–46.
17. Jenkins, “Introduction,” x; Franklin F. Mendels, “Proto-Industrialization: The
First Phase of the Industrialization Process,” Journal of Economic History
XXXII (1972), 241–61; S. D. Chapman, “Financial Restraints on the Growth of
Firms in the Cotton Industry, 1790–1850,” Textile History 5 (1974), 50–69;
Berg, Age of Manufactures, 182.
18. Hills, “Hargreaves, Arkwright and Crompton,” 118–23; Berg, Age of
Manufactures, 236; Fitton and Wadsworth, The Strutts and the Arkwrights, 61–
68, 76–78, 94–97; Adam Menuge, “The Cotton Mills of the Derbyshire Derwent
and Its Tributaries,” Industrial Archeology Review XVI (1) (Autumn 1993), 38.
19. Berg, Age of Manufactures, 236, 239, 244, 248, 258; George Unwin, Samuel
Oldknow and the Arkwrights (Manchester: Manchester University Press, 1924),
30–32, 71, 124–25; Landes, Unbound Prometheus, 85; E. P. Thompson, The
Making of the English Working Class ([1963] London: Pelican Books, 1968),
327, 335; Jones, “Technology, Transaction Costs, and the Transition to Factory
Production,” 89–90.
20. Chaloner, People and Industries, 14–15; Fitton and Wadsworth, The Strutts
and the Arkwrights, 98–99, 192–95, 224–25.
21. Small four-spindle, hand-powered spinning frames, built from Arkwright’s plans
for a demonstration model, can be seen at the museums in Cromford and
Belper. Hills, “Hargreaves, Arkwright and Crompton,” 121; Berg, Age of
Manufactures, 236, 239, 242, 246; Menuge, “The Cotton Mills of the
Derbyshire Derwent,” 56 (Arkwright quote).
22. John S. Cohen, “Managers and Machinery: An Analysis of the Rise of Factory
Production,” Australian Economic Papers 20 (1981), 27–28; Berg, Age of
Manufactures, 19, 24, 40–42.
23. Jenkins, “Introduction,” xv.
24. Berg, Age of Manufactures, 40–41, 231–32, 282–83; Pat Hudson, The
Genesis of Industrial Capital: A Study of the West Riding Wool Textile Industry
c. 1750–1850 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1986), 137; Jones,
“Technology, Transaction Costs, and the Transition to Factory Production,” 89–
90; Roger Lloyd-Jones and A. A. Le Roux, “The Size of Firms in the Cotton
Industry: Manchester 1815–1840,” The Economic History Review, new series,
vol. 33, no. 1 (Feb. 1980), 77.
25. V. A. C. Gatrell, “Labour, Power, and the Size of Firms in Lancashire Cotton in
the Second Quarter of the Nineteenth Century,” Economic History Review, new
series, vol. 30, no. 1 (Feb. 1977), 96, 98, 112; Jenkins, “Introduction,” xv.
26. Berg, Age of Manufactures, 23–24; Thompson, Making of the English Working
Class, 208–11; Robert Gray, The Factory Question and Industrial England,
1830–1860 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996), 3–4.
27. Charles Babbage, On the Economy of Machinery and Manufacturers, 4th ed.
(London: Charles Knight, 1835), 211–23.
28. Gatrell, “Labour, Power, and the Size of Firms,” 96–97, 108; Alfred Marshall,
Principles of Economics (1890; London: Macmillan and Co., Ltd., 1920), 8th
ed., IV.XI.7, http://www.econlib.org/library/Marshall/marP25.html#Bk.IV,Ch.XI.
29. Baines, History of the Cotton Manufacture, 184–85.
30. Landes, Unbound Prometheus, 41; Jones, “Technology, Transaction Costs,
and the Transition to Factory Production,” 71–74; Jenkins, “Introduction,” xiii;
Berg, Age of Manufactures, 23–24, 190, 246; Hudson, Genesis of Industrial
Capital, 70–71. Marx discussed the issue of economies of scale and the rise of
the factory system at great length in Karl Marx, Capital: A Critique of Political
Economy, vol. 1 ([1867] New York: International Publishers, 1967), chap. 13
and 14 (“Cooperation” and “Division of Labour and Manufacture”).
31. Jenkins, “Introduction,” x–xii; Berg, Age of Manufactures, 24; Hudson, Genesis
of Industrial Capital, 81, 260; Thompson, Making of the English Working Class,
299, 302.
32. Gatrell, “Labour, Power, and the Size of Firms,” 96–97, 107.
33. On British forms of wealth, see Thomas Piketty, Capital in the Twenty-First
Century (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2014), 113–20, 129–31.
Willersley Castle now is a Christian Guild hotel. Fitton and Wadsworth, The
Strutts and the Arkwrights, 91, 94–98, 102, 169, 246; R. S. Fitton, The
Arkwrights: Spinners of Fortune ([1989] Matlock, Eng.: Derwent Valley Mills
Educational Trust, 2012), 224–96; Frances Trollope, The Life and Adventures
of Michael Armstrong the Factory Boy ([1840] London: Frank Cass and
Company Limited, 1968), quote on 76.
34. Local church towers, however, did rival the mills in height. Mark Girouard,
Cities & People: A Social and Architectural History (New Haven, CT: Yale
University Press, 1985), 211–18; Thomas A. Markus, Buildings and Power:
Freedom and Control in the Origin of Modern Building Types (London:
Routledge, 1993), 263.
35. Fitton, The Arkwrights, 30, 50, 81.
36. Fitton, The Arkwrights, 30, 81; Thomas A. Markus, “Factories, to 1850,” The
Oxford Companion to Architecture, vol. 1, ed. Patrick Goode (New York: Oxford
University Press, 2009), 304–05; Fitton and Wadsworth, The Strutts and the
Arkwrights, 200–207, 211–12; Malcolm Dick, “Charles Bage, the Flax Industry
and Shrewsbury’s Iron-Framed Mills,” accessed Mar. 29, 2017,
http://www.revolutionaryplayers.org.uk/charles-bage-the-flax-industry-and-
shrewsburys-iron-framed-mills/; Markus, Buildings and Power, 266–67, 270–
71, 281–82; Menuge, “The Cotton Mills of the Derbyshire Derwent,” 52–56.
37. A. J. Taylor, “Concentration and Specialization in the Lancashire Cotton
Industry, 1825–1850,” Economic History Review, 2nd series, I (1949), 119–20;
Markus, Buildings and Power, 275. Not all power looms were situated in sheds;
some manufacturers built multistory weaving mills. See Colum Giles, “Housing
the Loom, 1790–1850: A Study of Industrial Building and Mechanization in a
Transitional Period,” Industrial Archeology Review XVI (1) (Autumn 1993), 30–
33. On the spread of the sawtooth roof, first called the “weave shed roof,” to
the United States, see Betsy Hunter Bradley, The Works: The Industrial
Architecture of the United States (New York: Oxford University Press, 1999),
192–93.
38. The first Cromford mills, though near the Derwent, were powered by a sough
draining a lead mine and a brook, not the river itself. Fitton, The Arkwrights,
28–29.
39. Steam power was first used in a cotton mill in 1789, but water remained the
most common power source for several decades. An 1870 industrial census
found that cotton mills used more power from steam engines than any other
industry. Fitton and Wadsworth, The Strutts and the Arkwrights, 103; Unwin,
Samuel Oldknow, 119; Markus, Buildings and Power, 265–66; Parthasarathi,
Why Europe Grew Rich and Asia Did Not, 155; Dickens, Hard Times, 22, 69;
W. Cooke Taylor, Notes of a Tour in the Manufacturing Districts of Lancashire,
2nd ed. (London: Duncan and Malcolm, 1842), 1–2.
40. In the first report of the Factory Commission, Edwin Chadwick described an
elevator as “an ascending and descending room, moved by steam.” Ure, The
Philosophy of Manufactures, 32–33, 44–54 (“upright tunnels” on 45); Markus,
Buildings and Power, 275, 280–81; Gray, The Factory Question, 92–93.
41. The Round Mill, built between 1803 and 1813, remained standing until 1959,
when in the course of its demolition four workers were killed. Fitton and
Wadsworth, The Strutts and the Arkwrights, 221; Markus, Buildings and Power,
125; Humphrey Jennings, Pandemonium, 1660–1886: The Coming of the
Machine as Seen by Contemporary Observers, ed. Mary-Lou Jennings and
Charles Madge (New York: Free Press, 1985), 98; Belper Derbyshire, Historical
& Genealogical Records, “Belper & the Strutts: The Mills,” July 20, 2011,
http://www.belper-research.com/strutts_mills/mills.html.
42. The housing Arkwright built in Cromford is still occupied. The row houses had
lofts for weavers, who bought yarn from Arkwright and whose wives and
children worked in his mill. Fitton, The Arkwrights, 29, 187; Arkwright Society
presentation at Cromford Mills, May 15, 2015; Fitton and Wadsworth, The
Strutts and the Arkwrights, 97, 102–04, 246; Chris Aspin, The First Industrial
Society; Lancashire, 1750–1850 (Preston, UK: Carnegie Publishing, 1995),
184; Unwin, Samuel Oldknow and the Arkwrights, 95.
43. Fitton and Wadsworth, The Strutts and the Arkwrights, 246, 252; Unwin,
Samuel Oldknow and the Arkwrights, 191; Fredrich Engels, The Condition of
the Working Class in England, trans. W. O. Henderson and W. H. Chaloner
(Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 1958), 205.
44. Fitton and Wadsworth, The Strutts and the Arkwrights, 240–44; Unwin, Samuel
Oldknow and the Arkwrights, 178.
45. Ure, The Philosophy of Manufactures, 150, 283–84, 312; Fitton, The
Arkwrights, 146, 151; John Brown, A Memoir of Robert Blincoe, An Orphan
Boy (1832), reprinted in James R. Simmons, Jr., ed., Factory Lives: Four
Nineteenth-Century Working-Class Autobiographies (Peterborough, ON:
Broadview Editions, 2007), 169; Cohen, “Managers and Machinery,” 25;
Engels, The Condition of the Working Class in England, 174, 199; Marx,
Capital, vol. 1, 422. The classic study of the change from task-oriented to time-
oriented work is E. P. Thompson, “Time, Work-Discipline, and Industrial
Capitalism,” Past and Present 38 (Dec. 1967), pp. 56–97.
46. Landes, Unbound Prometheus, 43; Ellen Johnston, Autobiography (1869),
reprinted in Simmons, Jr., ed., Factory Lives, 308; Aspin, First Industrial
Society, 92; “knocker, n.” OED Online. September 2014. Oxford University
Press. http://www.oed.com/view/Entry/104097; “knock, v.” OED Online.
September 2014. Oxford University Press.
http://www.oed.com/view/Entry/104090.
47. Fitton and Wadsworth, The Strutts and the Arkwrights, 97; Gray, The Factory
Question, 136; Giorgio Riello and Patrick K. O’Brien, “The Future Is Another
Country: Offshore Views of the British Industrial Revolution,” Journal of
Historical Sociology 22 (1) (March 2009), 4–5.
48. Taylor, Notes of a Tour, 4.
49. Robert Southey, Journal of a Tour in Scotland in 1819, quoted in Jennings,
Pandemonium, 156; Steven Marcus, Engels, Manchester, and the Working
Class (New York: Random House, 1974), 34–40, 60–61; Riello and O’Brien,
“The Future Is Another Country,” 6; Benjamin Disraeli, Sybil, or the Two
Nations (London: Henry Colburn, 1845), 195; Karl Marx, The Eighteenth
Brumaire of Louis Bonaparte (1852; New York: International Publishers, 1963),
15.
50. Trollope, The Life and Adventures of Michael Armstrong, 236–37; Flora
Tristan, Promenades dans Londres (Paris, 1840), quoted in Riello and O’Brien,
“The Future Is Another Country,” 5.
51. Dickens, Hard Times, 69; Aspin, First Industrial Society, 4, 239–41.
52. It was a measure of how quickly the system was spreading that Taylor used
the metaphor of machinery to describe society, a usage unusual before the
eighteenth century. Gray, The Factory Question, 23–24; Thompson, Making of
the English Working Class, 209; Taylor, Notes of a Tour, 4–5; “machinery, n.”
OED Online. September 2016. Oxford University Press,
http://www.oed.com/view/Entry/111856.
53. Thompson, Making of the English Working Class, 341; Ure, The Philosophy of
Manufactures, 20–22, 474.
54. Fitton and Wadsworth, The Strutts and the Arkwrights, 226; Katrina
Honeyman, “The Poor Law, the Parish Apprentice, and the Textile Industries in
the North of England, 1780–1830,” Northern History 44 (2) (Sept. 2007), 127.
55. Brown, Memoir of Robert Blincoe, 115–18, 132, 173; William Dodd, A
Narrative of the Experience and Sufferings of William Dodd, A Factory Cripple,
Written by Himself (1841), reprinted in Simmons, Jr., ed., Factory Lives, 191,
193–95; Fitton and Wadsworth, The Strutts and the Arkwrights, 98–99, 103,
226; Fitton, The Arkwrights, 152, 160–61; Honeyman, “The Poor Law,” 123–25;
Ure, The Philosophy of Manufactures, 171, 179–80, 299, 301; Jennings,
Pandemonium, 214–15.
56. Some mills withheld part of the wages of workers on contract until the end of
each quarter as further insurance against their departure. Fitton and
Wadsworth, The Strutts and the Arkwrights, 104–06, 226, 233; Aspin, First
Industrial Society, 53, 104.
57. Parthasarathi, Why Europe Grew Rich and Asia Did Not, 3–4, 53–54. See, for
example, Thomas E. Woods, Jr., “A Myth Shattered: Mises, Hayek, and the
Industrial Revolution,” Nov. 1, 2001, Foundation for Economic Education,
https://fee.org/articles/a-myth-shattered-mises-hayek-and-the-industrial-
revolution/; “Wake Up America,” Freedom: A History of US (PBS), accessed
Dec. 8, 2016, http://www.pbs.org/wnet/historyofus/web04/.
58. Livesey quoted in Aspin, First Industrial Society, 86. See also, Brown, Memoir
of Robert Blincoe, 91, 109, 138–39.
59. Trollope, The Life and Adventures of Michael Armstrong, quote on 186.
60. The equation of British factory workers with West Indian slaves was used not
only by critics of the factory system but also by defenders of slavery, who
argued that slaves were actually better off than mill workers. Thompson,
Making of the English Working Class, 220; Engels, Condition of the Working
Class in England, 202, 204, 207–08; Disraeli, Sybil, 198; Catherine Gallagher,
The Industrial Reformation of English Fiction: Social Discourse and Narrative
Form, 1832–1867 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1985), 1–2.
61. Southey, Journal of a Tour in Scotland in 1819, quoted in Jennings,
Pandemonium, 157–58; Robert Southey, Espiella’s Letters, quoted in Aspin,
First Industrial Society, 53.
62. Gallagher, Industrial Reformation of English Fiction, 6–21 (quotes on 7 and
10).
63. Jennings, Pandemonium, 230; Taylor, Notes of a Tour, 1–2, 30.
64. Marcus, Engels, Manchester, and the Working Class, 45–46.
65. Jennings, Pandemonium, 231.
66. Johnson, River of Dark Dreams, 154–57, 180–83; Paul L. Younger,
“Environmental Impacts of Coal Mining and Associated Wastes: A
Geochemical Perspective,” Geological Society, London, Special Publications
236 (2004), 169–209.
67. William Blake, Collected Poems, ed. W. B. Yeats ([1905] London: Routledge,
2002), 211–12. Blake’s original manuscript, with the punctuation used here,
can be seen at
http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/And_did_those_feet_in_ancient_time#mediaviewer/
File:Milton_preface.jpg (accessed Dec. 6, 2016). Steven E. Jones, Against
Technology: From the Luddites to Neo-Luddism (New York: Routledge, 2006),
81–96.
68. By 1881, the Lancashire population had doubled again, to 630,323. GB
Historical GIS / University of Portsmouth, Lancashire through time | Population
Statistics | Total Population, A Vision of Britain through Time (accessed Oct. 5,
2016), http://www.visionofbritain.org.uk/unit/10097848/cube/TOT_POP. Engels,
The Condition of the Working Class in England, 16; Tristram Hunt, Marx’s
General: The Revolutionary Life of Friedrich Engels (New York: Metropolitan
Books, 2009), 78–79.
69. Landes, Unbound Prometheus, 116–17.
70. Taylor, Notes of a Tour, 6–7. For a different view, stressing the infection of both
mill owners and workers by greed, see Robert Owen, Observations on the
Effect of the Manufacturing System, 2nd ed. (London: Longman, Hart, Rees,
and Orml, 1817), 5–9.
71. Engels wrote this not long after leaving his first stint at his family’s cotton mill in
Manchester, a job he himself abhorred and was to return to for another two
decades. Engels, Condition of the Working Class in England, 9–12, 153, 174,
199–202.
72. The Condition of the Working Class in England was an enormously influential
book, both in the development of Marxism and in perceptions of Manchester
and the Industrial Revolution. However, it had no immediate impact in the
English-speaking world, since it did not appear in English until 1886, more than
forty years after its publication in German, when an American edition came out.
It was not published in England until 1892. Engels, Condition of the Working
Class in England, 134–38; Thompson, Making of the English Working Class,
209; Hunt, Marx’s General, 81, 100, 111–12, 312.
73. For the history of debate over factory legislation, see Gray, The Factory
Question.
74. Marx, Capital, vol. 1, 418; Ure, The Philosophy of Manufactures, 17–18, 171,
179–80, 290, 299–301.
75. Taylor, Notes of a Tour, 3–4, 46, 237–38, 330.
76. Thomas Carlyle, Chartism, quoted in Jennings, Pandemonium, 35. Marx and
Engels shared the belief that the rise of the factory system represented
progress for mankind, in their eyes laying the basis for a new, more
democratic, egalitarian, and productive social system. See, for example, Hunt,
Marx’s General, 323–24.
77. Gray, The Factory Question, 100–101, 103–04; Ure, The Philosophy of
Manufactures, 295.
78. Taylor, Notes of a Tour, 80–82, 223–24; Ure, The Philosophy of Manufactures,
334–38; Engels, The Condition of the Working Class in England, 27, 156, 278.
79. Gray, The Factory Question; Valenze, The First Industrial Woman, 5.
80. B. L. Hutchins and A. Harrison, A History of Factory Legislation (London: P.S.
King & Son, 1911).
81. Gray, The Factory Question, 23–24, 59–60, 72, 88 (quote from Factory
Commission First Report), 130; Michael Merrill, “How Capitalism Got Its
Name,” Dissent (Fall 2014), 87–92.
82. Engels, The Condition of the Working Class in England, 195.
83. Marx devoted Chapter X of the first volume of Capital to “The Working-Day,”
capital’s “vampire thirst for the living blood of labour,” including a detailed
discussion of the Factory Acts. Marx, Capital, vol. 1, 231–302 (“struggle” on
235; “vampire” on 256). Engels analyzed the Factory Acts in The Condition of
the Working Class in England, 191–99.
84. Marx, Capital, vol. 1, 219; Hunt, Marx’s General, 1, 7, 179, 198, 234. As Hunt
repeatedly points out, Engels’ years as a cotton mill manager supplied Marx
not only with detailed information about how the business worked but with the
financial support he needed to write Capital.
85. Janice Carlisle, “Introduction,” in Simmons, Jr., ed., Factory Lives, 27–28. See
also David Vincent, Bread, Knowledge, and Freedom: A Study of Nineteenth-
Century Working-Class Autobiography (London: Europa Publications, 1981),
and Kevin Binfield, ed., Writings of the Luddites (Baltimore, MD, and London:
Johns Hopkins Press, 2004) for how limited the sources are for working-class
views of the factory system.
86. In Against Technology, Steven E. Jones traces the changing understanding of
Luddism in British and American culture up through the twentieth century.
87. Berg, Age of Manufactures, 262; E. J. Hobsbawm, “The Machine Breakers,” in
Labouring Men: Studies in the History of Labour ([1964] Garden City, NY:
Anchor Books, 1967), 7–26; Fitton, The Arkwrights, 51, 53–55.
88. There is an extensive literature of Luddism. Particularly useful were
Hobsbawm, “The Machine Breakers”; Thompson, Making of the English
Working Class, chap. 14 (“An Army of Redressers”); and Kevin Binfield, ed.,
Writings of the Luddites (quoted letter on 74).
89. Thompson, Making of the English Working Class, 570–91, 608–18.
90. Maxine Berg, The Age of Manufactures, 42, 259; Aspin, First Industrial
Society, 67; Thompson, Making of the English Working Class, 211, 297–346,
616–21; Marx, Capital, vol. I, 431–32.
91. Jones, Against Technology, 9, 47; Hobsbawm, “The Machine Breakers,” 9–16.
92. Thompson, however, questioned Engels’s depiction of cotton workers making
up the nucleus of the emerging labor movement. Aspin, First Industrial Society,
55; Engels, Condition of the Working Class in England, 24, 137, 237;
Thompson, Making of the English Working Class, 211, 213.
93. Not only were workers unable to vote but also the districts in which mills were
located were vastly underrepresented in Parliament as a result of the way
seats were apportioned. Aspin, First Industrial Society, 56–57, 153–54; Henry
Pelling, A History of British Trade Unionism (Hammondsworth, UK: Penguin
Books, 1963), 18–19.
94. Pelling, History of British Trade Unionism, 24–29; Beckert, Empire of Cotton,
196.
95. Hobsbawm summarizes the major outbreaks of unrest in Britain between 1800
and 1850 in Labouring Men, 155. See also Ure, The Philosophy of
Manufactures, 287, 366–67; Pelling, History of British Trade Unionism, 29–33,
36–37, 43–44, 46–49; and Thompson, Making of the English Working Class,
308, 706–08, 734–68.
96. Landes, Unbound Prometheus, 48–50, 62, 71. Walt Rostow made a similar
claim in W. W. Rostow, The Stages of Economic Growth: A Non-Communist
Manifesto (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1960), 33–34, 54.
97. See, for example, Ludwig Von Mises, Human Action: A Treatise on Economics
(Auburn, AL: Ludwig Von Mises Institute, 1998), 613–19. Von Mises writes of
early factories, “The factory owners did not have the power to compel anybody
to take a factory job,” ignoring the fact that the state performed that function for
them. On hanging Luddites, see Thompson, Making of the English Working
Class, 627–28, and Lord Byron’s eloquent speech in the House of Lords
against making machine breaking a capital crime,
http://www.luddites200.org.uk/LordByronspeech.html (accessed Oct. 7, 2016).
98. Patrick Joyce, Work, Society and Politics: The Culture of the Factory in Later
Victorian England (New Brunswick, NJ: Rutgers University Press, 1980), 55;
Leo Marx, The Machine in the Garden: Technology and the Pastoral Ideal in
America (New York: Oxford University Press, 1964), 194; Aspin, First Industrial
Society, 15–17, 23–30; Mechanics’ magazine, Sept. 25, 1830, reprinted in
Jennings, Pandemonium, 176–79; J. C. Jeaffreson and William Pole, The Life
of Robert Stephenson, F.R.S., vol. 1 (London: Longmans, Green, Reader, and
Dyer, 1866), 141; Tony Judt, “The Glory of the Rails” and “Bring Back the
Rails!,” The New York Review of Books, vol. 57, no. 20 (Dec. 23, 2010), and
vol. 58, no. 1 (Jan. 13, 2011).
99. Timothy L. Alborn, Conceiving Companies; Joint-Stock Politics in Victorian
England (London and New York: Routledge, 1998), 182–83; Jennings,
Pandemonium, 311–12; Landes, Unbound Prometheus, 121.
00. G. W. Hilton, “The Truck Act of 1831,” The Economic History Review, new
series, vol. 10, no. 3 (1958): 470–79; Hutchins and Harrison, History of Factory
Legislation, 43–70; Hunt, Marx’s General, 184–86.
01. Gray, Factory Question, 140, 163; Aspin, First Industrial Society, 185. On
paternalism, see Joyce, Work, Society and Politics, esp. 135–53, 168–71, 185.
02. Brontë, Shirley, 487–88; Pelling, History of British Trade Unionism, 43–49;
Carlisle, “Introduction,” in Simmons, Jr., ed., Factory Lives, 63–65.
03. Engels, “Principles of Communism,” quoted in Hunt, Marx’s General, 144.
Chapter 2
“THE LIVING LIGHT”
Chapter 3
“THE PROGRESS OF CIVILIZATION”
1. Joshua Freeman et al., Who Built America? Working People and the Nation’s
Economy, Politics, Culture, and Society, vol. 2 (New York: Pantheon Books,
1992), xii–xx; Frank Leslie’s Illustrated Newspaper, May 20, 1876; J. S.
Ingram, The Centennial Exposition, Described and Illustrated (Philadelphia:
Hubbard Bros., 1876); Linda P. Gross and Theresa R. Snyder, Philadelphia’s
1876 Centennial Exhibition (Charleston, SC: Arcadia Publishing, 2005); John
E. Findling, ed., Historical Dictionary of World’s Fairs and Expositions, 1851–
1988 (New York: Greenwood Press, 1990), 57–59; Robert W. Rydell, All the
World’s a Fair: Visions of Empire at American International Expositions, 1876–
1916 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1987), 9–37; Centennial
Photographic Co., “[Saco] Water Power Co.—Cotton Machinery,” Centennial
Exhibition Digital Collection Philadelphia 1876, Free Library of Philadelphia,
CEDC No. c032106 (accessed Mar. 20, 2015),
http://libwww.library.phila.gov/CenCol/Details.cfm?ItemNo=c032106. See also
Bruni Giberti, Designing the Centennial: A History of the 1876 International
Exhibition in Philadelphia (Lexington: University of Kentucky Press, 2002).
2. On the national divides at the time of the exhibition, see Freeman et al., Who
Built America? vol. 2, xx–xxiv.
3. When Whitman visited the Centennial Exhibition, he reportedly sat for a half
hour in silence before the Corliss engine. Leo Marx, The Machine in the
Garden: Technology and the Pastoral Ideal in America (New York: Oxford
University Press, 1964), 150–58, 163–64; Andrea Sutcliffe, Steam: The Untold
Story of America’s First Great Invention (New York: Palgrave, 2004); Walter
Johnson, River of Dark Dreams: Slavery and Empire in the Cotton Kingdom
(Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2013), 73–96; Edmund Flagg, The
Far West: or, A Tour Beyond the Mountains, vol. 1 (New York: Harper &
Brothers, 1838), 17–18; John F. Kasson, Civilizing the Machine: Technology
and Republican Values in America, 1776–1900 (New York: Penguin, 1977),
141; Robert W. Rydell, All the World’s a Fair, 15–16.
4. Walt Whitman, Two Rivulets: Including Democratic Vistas, Centennial Songs,
and Passage to India (Camden, NJ: [Walt Whitman], 1876), 25–26; Marx,
Machine in the Garden, 27. There is a very large literature on the railroad and
modernity. See, for example, Wolfgang Schivelbusch, The Railway Journey:
The Industrialization of Time and Space in the 19th Century (Berkeley:
University of California Press, 1986).
5. Giberti, Designing the Centennial, 2–3; “Manufactures of Massachusetts,” The
North American Review 50 (106) (Jan. 1840), 223–31.
6. The Crystal Palace burned down in 1936. Jeffrey A. Auerbach, The Great
Exhibition of 1851: A Nation on Display (New Haven, CT: Yale University
Press, 1999); Benjamin quoted in Robert W. Rydell, Worlds of Fairs: The
Century-of-Progress Expositions (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1993),
15.
7. Many exhibits for the New York fair were not ready when it opened, damping
down attendance. Unlike the profitable original, it ended in bankruptcy. Charles
Hirschfeld, “America on Exhibition: The New York Crystal Palace,” American
Quarterly 9 (2, pt. 1) (Summer 1957), 101–16.
8. Pauline de Tholozany, “The Expositions Universelles in Nineteenth Century
Paris,” Brown University Center for Digital Scholarship,
http://library.brown.edu/cds/paris/worldfairs.html (accessed Mar. 27, 2015). For
a list of nineteenth- and twentieth-century international expositions and fairs,
see Findling, ed., Historical Dictionary of World’s Fairs and Expositions, 376–
81.
9. Report of the Board of Commissioners Representing the State of New York at
the Cotton States and International Exposition held at Atlanta, Georgia, 1895
(Albany, NY: Wynkoop Hallenbeck Crawford Co, 1896), quote on page 205; C.
Vann Woodward, Origins of the New South, 1877–1913: A History of the South
(Baton Rouge: Louisiana State University, 1951), 123–24.
10. Jill Jonnes, Eiffel’s Tower: The Thrilling Story Behind Paris’s Beloved
Monument and the World’s Fair Where Buffalo Bill Beguiled Paris, the Artists
Quarreled, and Thomas Edison Became a Count (New York: Viking, 2009);
“Origins and Construction of the Eiffel Tower,”
http://www.toureiffel.paris/en/everything-about-the-tower/themed-files/69.html,
and “All You need to Know About the Eiffel Tower,”
http://www.toureiffel.paris/images/PDF/about_the_Eiffel_Tower.pdf (both
accessed Oct. 21, 2016); Roland Barthes, The Eiffel Tower and Other
Mythologies ([1979] Berkeley: University of California Press, 1997), 8–14.
11. Letter published in Le Temps, Feb. 14, 1887, reprinted in “All You Need to
Know About the Eiffel Tower.”
12. “Représentation de la tour Eiffel dans l’art,”
http://fr.wikipedia.org/wiki/Repr%C3%A9sentation_de_la_tour_Eiffel_dans_l%2
7art; and Michaela Haffner, “Diego Rivera, The Eiffel Tower, 1914,” the Davis
Museum at Wellesley College,
https://www.wellesley.edu/davismuseum/artwork/node/37002 (both accessed
Apr. 1, 2015). For a different reading of the iconography of the Eiffel Tower, with
less emphasis on its importance as a symbol of industrialism and the
mechanical age, see Gabriel Insausti, “The Making of the Eiffel Tower as a
Modern Icon,” in Writing and Seeing: Essays on Word and Image, ed. Rui
Carvalho Homem and Maria de Fátima Lambert (Amsterdam: Editions Rodopi,
2006).
13. Guillaume Apollinaire, “Zone,” translated by Donald Revell,
http://www.poets.org/poetsorg/poem/zone. For an alternative, more literal
translation by Charlotte Mandell, see
http://www.charlottemandell.com/Apollinaire.php (accessed Apr. 2, 2015).
14. Blaise Cendrars, “Elastic Poem 2: Tower,” trans. by Tony Baker, GutCult 2 (1)
(Winter 2004), http://gutcult.com/Site/litjourn3/html/cendrars1.html.
15. The great nineteenth-century expositions were not only about industry and
consumer goods. They also celebrated national identity and greatness as
manifested in the arts and empire. And empire was tightly linked to ideas of
racial hierarchy, a theme that bluntly recurred in fair after fair. Technological
and racial advance were inextricably linked. See Auerbach, Great Exhibition of
1851, 159–89; Joseph Harris, The Tallest Tower: Eiffel and the Belle Epoque
(Bloomington, IN: Unlimited Publishing, 2004), 88–89, 107–08; Rydell, All the
World’s a Fair, 21–22; Rydell, Worlds of Fairs, 19–22; Findling, ed., Historical
Dictionary of World’s Fairs and Expositions, 79, 181, 183.
16. Guy de Maupassant, La Vie Errane, Allouma, Toine, and Other Stories
(London: Classic Publishing Company, 1911), 1–4.
17. Auerbach, Great Exhibition of 1851, 128–58; Freeman et al., Who Built
America? vol. 2, xxiii.
18. Auerbach, Great Exhibition of 1851, 132, 156; Friedrich Engels to Laura
Lafarge, June 11, 1889,
www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1889/letters/89_06_11.htm (accessed
Apr. 4, 2017); Tristram Hunt, Marx’s General: The Revolutionary Life of
Friedrich Engels (New York: Metropolitan Books, 2009), 335–36.
19. The Making, Shaping and Treating of Steel, published by U.S. Steel in ten
editions between 1919 and 1985, provides encyclopedic information on iron-
and steelmaking, including their history. For a history and analysis of this
remarkable volume, see Carol Siri Johnson, “The Steel Bible: A Case Study of
20th Century Technical Communication,” Journal of Technical Writing and
Communication 37 (3) (2007), 281–303. See also Peter Temin, Iron and Steel
in Nineteenth-Century America: An Economic Inquiry (Cambridge, MA: MIT
Press, 1964), 13–17, 83–85.
20. Eric Hobsbawm, The Age of Capital 1848–1875 (New York: Charles Scribner’s
Sons, 1975), 39, 54–55; Temin, Iron and Steel, 3–5, 14–15, 21. For the
difficulties in producing rails, see John Fritz, The Autobiography of John Fritz
(New York: John Wiley & Sons, 1912), 92–101, 111–15, 121–23, 149. Overman
quoted in Paul Krause, The Battle for Homestead, 1880–1892: Politics,
Culture, and Steel (Pittsburgh, PA: University of Pittsburgh Press, 1992), 47.
21. In addition to iron ore and fuel (charcoal, coke, or sometimes anthracite coal),
limestone was put into blast furnaces to help form slag out of impurities. Temin,
Iron and Steel, 58–62, 96–98, 157–63; U.S. Steel, The Making, Shaping and
Treating of Steel (Pittsburgh, PA: U.S. Steel, 1957), 221–25.
22. Krause, Battle for Homestead, 48–49; David Montgomery, Workers’ Control in
America (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1979), 11–12. For a
firsthand account of puddling, see James J. Davis, The Iron Puddler; My Life in
the Rolling Mills and What Came of It (New York: Grosset & Dunlop, 1922).
23. Temin, Iron and Steel, 66–67, 85, 105–06, 109–13; Fritz, Autobiography of
John Fritz, 91–135; Marvin Fisher, Workshops in the Wilderness: The
European Response to American Industrialization, 1830–1860 (New York:
Oxford University Press, 1967), 162–63.
24. Krause, Battle for Homestead, 52–65; Temin, Iron and Steel, 125–27, 130,
153; David Brody, Steelworkers in America: The Nonunion Era (1960; New
York: Harper & Row, 1969), 8.
25. Some companies also integrated backward, buying or leasing ore mines and
making their own coke. Temin, Iron and Steel, 153–69, 190–91; Brody,
Steelworkers in America, 10–12; William Serrin, Homestead: The Glory and
Tragedy of an American Steel Town (New York: Random House, 1992), 56–59.
26. Hobsbawm, Age of Capital, 213; Harold James, Krupp: A History of the
Legendary German Firm (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2012), 47,
53; Gross and Snyder, Philadelphia’s 1876 Centennial Exhibition, 83;
Schneider Electric, 170 Years of History (Rueil-Malmaison, France: Schneider
Electric, 2005), 3–5, 20–22 (http://www.schneider-
electric.com/documents/presentation/en/local/2006/12/se_history_brands_mar
ch2005.pdf).
27. Daniel Nelson, Managers and Workers: Origins of the New Factory System in
the United States, 1880–1920 (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1975),
6–7; David Nasaw, Andrew Carnegie (New York: Penguin Press, 2006), 405;
U.S. Census Office, Twelfth Census of the United States—1900; Census
Reports, vol. VII—Manufactures, part I (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Census Office,
1902), 583, 585, 597.
28. U.S. Steel, Making, Shaping and Treating of Steel; Carnegie quoted in Brody,
Steelworkers inAmerica, 21.
29. Michael W. Santos, “Brother against Brother: The Amalgamated and Sons of
Vulcan at the A. M. Byers Company, 1907–1913,” The Pennsylvania Magazine
of History and Biography 111 (2) (Apr. 1987), 199–201; Davis, Iron Puddler, 85;
John Fitch, The Steel Workers (New York: Charities Publication Committee,
1910), 36, 40–44, 48, 52. William Attaway’s novel, Blood on the Forge ([1941]
New York: New York Review of Books, 2005), set in Pittsburgh at the end of
World War I, gives a good sense of the rhythms of steelwork, with its alternate
periods of exhausting labor and waiting for the next burst of activity.
30. Harry B. Latton, “Steel Wonders,” The Pittsburgh Times, June 1, 1892,
reprinted in David P. Demarest, Jr., ed., “The River Ran Red”: Homestead 1892
(Pittsburgh, PA: University of Pittsburgh Press, 1992), 13–15; Fritz,
Autobiography of John Fritz, 203; Brody, Steelworkers in America, 9; Mark
Reutter, Sparrows Point; Making Steel—The Rise and Ruin of American
Industrial Might (New York: Summit Books, 1988), 18.
31. Fitch, The Steel Workers, 3; Nathaniel Hawthorne, Passages from the English
Note-Books of Nathaniel Hawthorne, vol. 1 (Boston: James R. Osgood and
Company, 1872), 370–72. I was pointed to Hawthorne’s statement by John F.
Kasson, who quotes part of it in Civilizing the Machine, 142.
32. Marx, The Machine in the Garden, 192, 200, 270–71; Joseph Stella, “In the
Glare of the Converter,” “In the Light of a Five-Ton Ingot,” “At the Base of the
Blast Furnace,” and “Italian Steelworker” (accessed Apr. 28, 2015),
http://www.clpgh.org/exhibit/stell1.html; W. J. Gordon, Foundry, Forge and
Factory with a Chapter on the Centenary of the Rotary Press (London:
Religious Tract Society, 1890), 15; John Commons et al., History of Labour in
the United States, vol. II ([1918] New York: Augustus M. Kelley, 1966), 80.
33. Hawthorne, Passages from the English Note-Books, 371; Thomas G.
Andrews, Killing for Coal: America’s Deadliest Labor War (Cambridge, MA:
Harvard University Press, 2008), 62; Joseph Stella, “Discovery of America:
Autobiographical Notes,” quoted in Maurine W. Greenwald, “Visualizing
Pittsburgh in the 1900s: Art and Photography in the Service of Social Reform,”
in Greenwald and Margo Anderson, eds., Pittsburgh Surveyed: Social Science
and Social Reform in the Early Twentieth Century (Pittsburgh, PA: University of
Pittsburgh Press, 1996), 136; Lincoln Steffens, The Autobiography of Lincoln
Steffens (New York: Harcourt, Brace and Company, 1931), 401.
34. Nasaw, Carnegie, 164; Mary Heaton Vorse, Men and Steel (New York: Boni
and Liveright, 1920), 12; Sharon Zukin, Landscapes of Power: From Detroit to
Disney World (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1991), 60; Gunther
quoted in Reutter, Sparrows Point, 9.
35. For a vivid account of the tumultuous struggles of the Gilded Age, see Steve
Fraser, The Age of Acquiescence; The Life and Death of American Resistance
to Organized Wealth and Power (New York: Little, Brown and Company, 2015),
chap. 4–6, especially chap. 5 on industrial strife.
36. The Amalgamated Association of Iron and Steel Workers was created by an
1876 merger of the Sons of Vulcan with two unions of rolling mill workers.
Brody, Steelworkers in America, 50–53; Preamble to the Constitution of the
Amalgamated Association of Iron and Steel Workers, reprinted in Demarest,
Jr., ed., “The River Ran Red,” 17; David Montgomery, The Fall of the House of
Labor: The Workplace, the State, and American Labor Activism, 1865–1925
(Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1987), 9–22.
37. Some companies continued to just make iron goods, without the intensely
competitive ethos of the dominant steel producers. Montgomery, Fall of the
House of Labor, 22–36; Brody, Steelworkers in America, 1–10, 23–28, 31–32.
38. Krause, Battle for Homestead, 177–92; Nasaw, Carnegie, 314–26.
39. Nasaw, Carnegie, 363–72. See also Krause, Battle for Homestead, 240–51.
40. Joshua B. Freeman, “Andrew and Me,” The Nation, Nov. 16, 1992; Nasaw,
Carnegie, 406.
41. Frick had made a fortune producing coke before joining forces with Carnegie.
Most of the charges against workers were dropped after acquittals in the first
trials. The Local News, July 2, 1892, New York Herald, July 7, 1892, Pittsburgh
Commercial Gazette, July 25, 1892, and Robert S. Barker, “The Law Takes
Sides,” all in Demarest, Jr., ed., “The River Ran Red,” a wonderful compilation
of essays, contemporary accounts, photographs, and drawings about the 1892
battle; Freeman, “Andrew and Me”; Krause, Battle for Homestead; Nasaw,
Carnegie, 405–27.
42. Russell W. Gibbons, “Dateline Homestead,” and Randolph Harris,
“Photographers at Homestead in 1892,” in Demarest, Jr., ed., “The River Ran
Red,” 158–61.
43. Nasaw, Carnegie, 469; Anne E. Mosher, Capital’s Utopia: Vandergrift,
Pennsylvania, 1855–1916 (Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press,
2004), 66–67; Montgomery, Fall of the House of Labor, 41; Brody, Steelworkers
in America, 56–58, 60–75.
44. Hamlin Garland, “Homestead and Its Perilous Trades; Impressions of a Visit,”
McClure’s Magazine 3 (1) (June 1894), in Demarest, Jr., ed., “The River Ran
Red,” 204–05; Dreiser in Nasaw, Carnegie, 470; Fitch, The Steel Workers,
214–29; Serrin, Homestead, 175–76.
45. Floyd Dell, “Pittsburgh or Petrograd?” The Liberator 2 (11) (Dec. 1919), 7–8.
46. Bethlehem Steel later purchased the Sparrows Point mill, which during the
1950s was the largest steel complex in the world. Mosher, Capital’s Utopia, 73–
74; Reutter, Sparrows Point, 10, 55–71.
47. Mosher, Capital’s Utopia, 73–127.
48. Brody, Steelworkers in America, 87–89; Mosher, Capital’s Utopia, 74, 102;
Reutter, Sparrows Point, 50.
49. For many years after its formation, U.S. Steel functioned essentially as a
holding company, with its many subsidiaries operating independently. Alfred D.
Chandler, Jr., The Visible Hand: The Managerial Revolution in American
Business (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1977), 359–62; Nasaw,
Carnegie, 582–88.
50. To prevent workers from sieging or seizing the mill, U.S. Steel redirected a
river on the site into a concrete channelway, a moat separating the plant from
the town. James B. Lane, “City of the Century”: A History of Gary, Indiana
(Bloomington: Indiana University Press, 1978), 27–37; Brody, Steelworkers in
America, 158; Mosher, Capital’s Utopia, 177; S. Paul O’Hara, Gary, the Most
American of All American Cities (Bloomington: Indiana University Press, 2011),
19–20, 38–53.
51. Richard Edwards, Contested Terrain: The Transformation of the Workplace in
the Twentieth Century (New York: Basic Books, 1979), 25.
52. In Taylor’s account, all the iron loaders eventually achieved the high rate, but
independent evidence indicates that only one worker was able to carry
anything like forty-seven tons of pig iron a day over an extended period. Daniel
Nelson, Frederick W. Taylor and the Rise of Scientific Management (Madison:
University of Wisconsin Press, 1980); Montgomery, The Fall of the House of
Labor, esp. chap. 6; Harry Braverman, Labor and Monopoly Capital: The
Degradation of Work in the Twentieth Century (New York: Monthly Review
Press, 1974), 85–123. See also Charles D. Wrege and Ronald G. Greenwood,
Frederick W. Taylor, the Father of Scientific Management: Myth and Reality
(Homewood, IL: Business One Irwin, 1991).
53. Brody, Steelworkers in America, 31–40, 170–73; U. S. Steel, Making, Shaping
and Treating of Steel, 314; Fitch, Steel Workers, 43, 60, 166–81.
54. Fitch, The Steel Workers, 57–64.
55. Steel mills in Maryland also hired a substantial number of black workers.
Homestead was something of an exception in the strong solidarity between the
Eastern European laborers and the English-speaking skilled workers, before
and during the 1892 clash. Brody, Steelworkers in America, 96–111, 135–37;
Henry M. McKiven, Iron and Steel: Class, Race, and Community in
Birmingham, Alabama, 1875–1920 (Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina
Press, 1995), 41; Paul Kraus, “East-Europeans in Homestead,” in Demarest,
Jr., ed., “The River Ran Red,” 63–65. For an evocative portrait of Slovak
steelworkers in Braddock, Pennsylvania, see Thomas Bell’s novel Out of This
Furnace ([1941] Pittsburgh, PA: University of Pittsburgh Press, 1976).
56. Strictly speaking, these were not steelworkers; they worked in a factory that
built steel railway cars. Brody, Steelworkers in America, 125, 145–70; Philip S.
Foner, History of the Labor Movement in the United States, vol. IV: The
Industrial Workers of the World, 1905–1917 (New York: International
Publishers, 1965), 281–305.
57. “Labor,” in Eric Foner and John A. Garrity, eds., The Reader’s Companion to
American History (Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1991), 632; Steven Fraser, Labor
Will Rule: Sidney Hillman and the Rise of American Labor (New York: Free
Press, 1991), 146–47.
58. Andrew Carnegie, “Wealth,” The North American Review 148 (391) (1889):
654.
59. Montgomery, Fall of the House of Labor, 88; Whiting Williams, What’s on the
Worker’s Mind, By One Who Put on Overalls to Find Out (New York: Charles
Scribner’s Sons, 1920); “WILLIAMS, WHITING,” in The Encyclopedia of
Cleveland History (accessed May 5, 2015), http://ech.case.edu/cgi/article.pl?
id=WW1; Nasaw, Carnegie, 386. There is a vast literature on Progressive Era
reform. A good place to start is Michael McGeer, Fierce Discontent: The Rise
and Fall of the Progressive Movement in America, 1870–1920 (New York:
Oxford University Press, 2005).
60. The Pittsburgh Survey examined the whole region and its economy, but steel
dominated the study and was the main subject of several volumes. Greenwald
and Anderson, eds., Pittsburgh Surveyed.
61. In 1920, the Supreme Court dismissed the antitrust case against U.S. Steel.
Brody, Steelworkers in America, 147, 154, 161–71; Fitch, The Steel Workers,
178–79.
62. Melvyn Dubofsky, The State and Labor in Modern America (Chapel Hill:
University of North Carolina Press, 1994), 61–76; union data calculated from
U.S. Bureau of the Census, Historical Statistics of the United States, Colonial
Times to 1970, Bicentennial Edition, part 1 (Washington, D.C.: U.S.
Government Printing Office, 1975), 126, 177; Fraser, Labor Will Rule, 121–40,
144 (quote).
63. David Brody, Labor in Crisis: The Steel Strike of 1919 (Philadelphia: J.B.
Lippincott, 1965), 45–51, 59–60.
64. The most thorough accounts of the steel organizing drive and the 1919 strike
are William Z. Foster, The Great Steel Strike (New York: B.W. Huebsch, 1920),
and Brody, Labor in Crisis. Except where otherwise noted, I have drawn from
them.
65. Freeman et al., Who Built America? 258–61.
66. For the strike in Gary, see Lane, “City of the Century,” 90–93. For a gripping
portrayal of the strike from the point of view of black workers, see Attaway,
Blood on the Forge.
67. The actual demands of the striking workers were far from radical, dealing, very
concretely, with hours, wages, and union recognition. See Brody, Labor in
Crisis, 100–101, 129. The New York Times, like many newspapers, gave heavy
coverage to the strike. From September 23 through September 26, the Times
ran three-line banner headlines about the strike on its front page that
emphasized the strike’s size and violence.
68. Foster, The Great Steel Strike, 1; Vorse, Men and Steel, 21; John Dos Passos,
The Big Money (New York: Harcourt, Brace, 1936).
Chapter 4
“I WORSHIP FACTORIES”
1. Henry Ford, “Mass Production,” in Encyclopedia Britannica, 13th ed. (New
York: The Encyclopædia Britannica, 1926), vol. 30, 821–23; David A.
Hounshell, From the American System to Mass Production, 1800–1932
(Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins Press, 1984), 1, 218–19, 224; Helen Jones
Earley and James R. Walkinshaw, Setting the Pace: Oldsmobile’s First 100
Years (Lansing, MI: Public Relations Department, Oldsmobile Division, 1996),
461; The Locomobile Society of America, “List of Cars Manufactured by the
Locomobile Company of America,” http://www.locomobilesociety.com/cars.cfm,
and “U.S. Automobile Production Figures,”
https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/U.S._Automobile_Production_Figures (both
accessed Feb. 6, 2017); Joshua Freeman et al., Who Built America? Working
People and the Nation’s Economy, Politics, Culture, and Society, vol. 2 (New
York: Pantheon Books, 1992), 277.
2. Hounshell, From the American System to Mass Production, 1, 228. My
discussion of the development of the Ford system draws heavily from
Hounshell’s superb study.
3. Edward A. Filene, The Way Out: A Forecast of Coming Changes in American
Business and Industry (Garden City, NY: Page & Company, 1924), 180; Vicki
Goldberg, Margaret Bourke-White: A Biography (New York: Harper & Row,
1986), 74.
4. Hounshell, From the American System to Mass Production, 4–8, 15–50.
5. Eric Hobsbawm, The Age of Capital 1848–1875 (New York: Charles Scribner’s
Sons, 1975), 44.
6. John A. James and Jonathan S. Skinner, “The Resolution of the Labor Scarcity
Paradox,” Working Paper No. 1504, National Bureau of Economic Research,
Nov. 1984.
7. Hounshell, From the American System to Mass Production, 115–23; Alfred D.
Chandler, Jr., Scale and Scope: The Dynamics of Industrial Capitalism
(Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1994), 196.
8. Alfred D. Chandler, Jr., The Visible Hand: The Managerial Revolution in
American Business (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1977), 240,
249–53; Hounshell, From the American System to Mass Production, 240–43.
9. Until 1915, Ford partner James Couzens played a central role in the Ford
Motor Company, developing many of its innovative practices and contributing
greatly to its overall success. Keith Sward, The Legend of Henry Ford (New
York: Rinehart & Company, 1948), 9–27, 43–46.
10. Sward, The Legend of Henry Ford, 44–45; Hounshell, From the American
System to Mass Production, 224.
11. Stephen Meyer, The Five Dollar Day; Labor Management and Social Control in
the Ford Motor Company, 1908–1921 (Albany: State University of New York
Press, 1981), 16, 18; Adam Smith, An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of
the Wealth of Nations ([1776] London: Oxford University Press, 1904), 6–7;
Hounshell, From the American System to Mass Production, 227.
12. Though various accounts at the time and after, including by the Ford company,
have claimed that by the time of the introduction of the assembly line complete
interchangeability of parts had been achieved, apparently for several years
some filing and grinding of parts on the assembly line occurred. Sward, The
Legend of Henry Ford, 42, 46, 68–77; Ford Factory Facts (Detroit, MI: Ford
Motor Company, 1912), 46–47, 49; Allan Nevins and Frank Ernest Hill, Ford:
Expansion and Challenge, 1915–1933 (New York: Charles Scribner’s Sons:
1957), 522; Hounshell, From the American System to Mass Production, 219–
20, 224–25, 230–33; Meyer, The Five Dollar Day, 10, 22–29; Jack Russell,
“The Coming of the Line; The Ford Highland Park Plant, 1910–1914,” Radical
America 12 (May–June 1978), 30–33.
13. Daniel Nelson, Managers and Workers: The Origins of the New Factory
System in the United States 1880–1920 (Madison: University of Wisconsin
Press, 1975), 21–23; David Gartman, “Origins of the Assembly Line and
Capitalist Control of Work at Ford,” in Andrew Zimbalist, ed., Case Studies on
the Labor Process (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1979), 197–98; Ford,
“Mass Production,” 822; Meyer, The Five Dollar Day, 29–31; Karl Marx,
Capital: A Critique of Political Economy, vol. 1 (1867: New York: International
Publishers, 1967), 380.
14. Hounshell, From the American System to Mass Production, 237–49; Gartman,
“Origins of the Assembly Line,” 201.
15. Russell, “The Coming of the Line,” 33–34, 37 (includes Ford quote).
Photographs of cars and trucks being assembled using the craft method at
various early vehicle companies can be seen in Bryan Olsen and Joseph
Cabadas, The American Auto Factory (St. Paul, MN: Motorbooks, 2002).
16. Hounshell, From the American System to Mass Production, 250–60.
17. Gartman, “Origins of the Assembly Line,” 199, 201–02.
18. Hounshell, From the American System to Mass Production, 249–53; Russell,
“The Coming of the Line,” 38; Lindy Biggs, The Rational Factory: Architecture,
Technology, and Work in America’s Age of Mass Production (Baltimore, MD:
Johns Hopkins University Press, 1996), 27.
19. Joyce Shaw Peterson, American Automobile Workers, 1900–1933 (Albany:
State University of New York Press, 1987), 43; Meyer, The Five Dollar Day,
40–41; Biggs, The Rational Factory, 133–34; Nevins and Hill, Ford: Expansion
and Challenge, 534.
20. Meyer, The Five Dollar Day, 10, 50; Terry Smith, Making the Modern: Industry,
Art and Design in America (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1993), 53;
Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, Abstract of the Census of
Manufactures, 1919 (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1923),
355, 374–75; Chandler, Jr., Scale and Scope, 27; Nelson, Managers and
Workers, 9.
21. Nevins and Hill, Ford: Expansion and Challenge, 288. A selection from the
very large Ford collection of photographs documenting the Highland Park plant
can be viewed online at https://www.thehenryford.org/collections-and-
research/.
22. David Montgomery, The Fall of the House of Labor; the Workplace, the State,
and American Labor Activism, 1865–1925 (Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, 1987), 133–35, 238–40.
23. Meyer, The Five Dollar Day, 77–78, 80–85, 89–93, 156; Russell, “The Coming
of the Line,” 39–40.
24. In 1926, Ford reduced the workweek from six days to five, becoming one of
the first major industrial companies to institute the forty-hour week. Meyer, The
Five Dollar Day, 95–168; Peterson, American Automobile Workers, 156; John
Reed, “Why They Hate Ford,” The Masses, 8 (Oct. 1916), 11–12.
25. Nelson, Managers and Workers, 101–21; Montgomery, The Fall of the House
of Labor, 236–38; Reed, “Why They Hate Ford”; Meyer, The Five Dollar Day,
114, 156–57.
26. Sward, Legend of Henry Ford, 107–09; Antonio Gramsci, Selections from the
Prison Notebooks of Antonio Gramsci, ed. and trans. Quintin Hoare and
Geoffrey Nowell Smith (New York: International Publishers, 1971), lxxxvi–
lxxxvii, 286, 302, 305.
27. Meyer, The Five Dollar Day, 197–200; Sward, Legend of Henry Ford, 291–
342. See also Harry Bennett, We Never Called Him Henry (Greenwich, CT:
Gold Medal Books, 1951).
28. Biggs, The Rational Factory, 89–94. The Piquette Avenue plant is still
standing. It now houses a museum and can be rented for corporate parties,
weddings, and bar mitzvahs. See http://www.fordpiquetteavenueplant.org/
(accessed Sept. 8, 2015).
29. Hounshell, From the American System to Mass Production, 225–26;
“Industry’s Architect,” Time, June 29, 1942; Grant Hildebrand, Designing for
Industry: The Architecture of Albert Kahn (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1974),
26–27. Some of Kahn’s early work can be seen in W. Hawkins Ferry, The
Legacy of Albert Kahn (Detroit, MI: Wayne State University Press, 1970).
30. George N. Pierce became the manufacturer of Pierce-Arrow automobiles.
Nelson, Managers and Workers, 15–16; Betsy Hunter Bradley, The Works: The
Industrial Architecture of the United States (New York: Oxford University Press,
1999), 155–58; Hildebrand, Designing for Industry, 28–43; Albert Kahn,
“Industrial Architecture” (speech), May 25, 1939, Box 1, Albert Kahn Papers,
Bentley Historical Library, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, Michigan; Smith,
Making the Modern, 59.
31. Biggs, The Rational Factory, 93–102, 110; Kahn, “Industrial Architecture.”
32. Smith, Making the Modern, 41–42, 71; Biggs, The Rational Factory, 78, 109,
120–25; Hildebrand, Designing for Industry, 52.
33. I thank Jeffrey Trask for making this point to me. See Gillian Darley, Factory
(London: Reaktion Books, 2003), 157–89.
34. Biggs, The Rational Factory, 103–4, 150; Ford Factory Facts (Detroit, MI: Ford
Motor Company, 1915) is an expanded and updated version of the 1912
booklet.
35. Both the Lingotto plant and the New York Packard service building are still
standing. The former was converted into a cultural, hotel, office, retail, and
educational complex by Renzo Piano; the latter now houses a car dealership.
Jean Castex, Architecture of Italy (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 2008), 47–
49; Darley, Factory, 10–12; Christopher Gray, “The Car Is Still King on 11th
Avenue,” New York Times, July 9, 2006.
36. Photographs of all of the mentioned buildings appear in Ferry, The Legacy of
Albert Kahn, except for the Joy house, which is in Hildebrand, Designing for
Industry, 74. On Kahn’s automobile projects and his firm organization, see
Olsen and Cabadas, The American Auto Factory, 39, 65; George Nelson,
Industrial Architecture of Albert Kahn, Inc. (New York: Architectural Book
Publishing Company, 1939), 19–23; Smith, Making the Modern, 76–78, 85–87;
and Hildebrand, Designing for Industry, 60, 124.
37. Olsen and Cabadas, The American Auto Factory, 39; Biggs, The Rational
Factory, 138–40, 151. For Ford tractors, see Reynold Wik, Henry Ford and
Grassroots America (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1972), 82–97.
38. Biggs, The Rational Factory, 146, 151; Writers’ Program of the Works
Progress Administration, Michigan: A Guide to the Wolverine State (New York:
Oxford University Press, 1941), 221–24; Greg Grandin, Fordlandia: The Rise
and Fall of Henry Ford’s Forgotten Jungle City (New York: Metropolitan Books,
2009). Kingsford is now owned by The Clorox Company. The Clorox Company,
“A Global Portfolio of Diverse Brands” (accessed Sept., 13, 2015),
https://www.thecloroxcompany.com/products/our-brands/.
39. The Rouge foundry also made parts for Fordson tractors. Biggs, The Rational
Factory, 148–49, 152; Hounshell, From the American System to Mass
Production, 268, 289.
40. Nelson, Industrial Architecture of Albert Kahn, Inc., 132; Biggs, The Rational
Factory, 129, 141–57; Kahn, “Industrial Architecture”; Ferry, The Legacy of
Albert Kahn, 113–16, 120–22, 129–301; The Reminiscences of Mr. B. R. Brown
Jr., Benson Ford Research Center, Dearborn, Michigan; Works Progress
Administration, Michigan, 220–21; Hildebrand, Designing for Industry, 91–92,
99, 102–08, 172–82. On Kahn’s and Ford’s antimodernism, see Albert Kahn,
“Architectural Trend” (speech), April 15, 1931, Box 1, Albert Kahn Papers;
Sward, Legend of Henry Ford, 259–75; and Smith, Making the Modern, 144–55
(though Smith’s interpretation is very different than mine).
41. In addition to Highland Park and River Rouge, Ford built major manufacturing
plants in Canada and England that built finished cars and trucks and supplied
parts to foreign branch plants. As employment at the Rouge grew, it shrank at
Highland Park. In 1929, when the average number of hourly employees at the
Rouge was 98,337, at Highland Park it was only 13,444. After the stock market
crash, employment at the Rouge fell but remained substantial. Edmund Wilson,
The American Earthquake (Garden City, NY: Doubleday, 1958), 219–20, 234,
687; Nevins and Hill, Ford: Expansion and Challenge, 210, 365–66, 542–43;
Chandler, Jr., Scale and Scope, 207–08; Bruce Pietrykowski, “Fordism at Ford:
Spatial Decentralization and Labor Segmentation at the Ford Motor Company,
1920–1950,” Economic Geography 71 (4) (Oct. 1995), 386, 389–91; Historic
American Engineering Record, Mid-Atlantic Region National Park Service,
“Dodge Bros. Motor Car Company Plant (Dodge Main): Photographs, Written
Historical and Descriptive Data” (Philadelphia: Department of the Interior,
1980); Ronald Edsforth, Class Conflict and Cultural Consensus: The Making of
a Mass Consumer Society in Flint, Michigan (New Brunswick, NJ: Rutgers
University Press, 1987), 77; New York Times, May 31, 1925, Apr. 9, 1972;
Hounshell, From the American System to Mass Production, 263–301; Biggs,
The Rational Factory, 148; Sward, Legend of Henry Ford, 185–205; The
Reminiscences of Mr. B. R. Brown Jr.
42. Not everyone, though, was enthralled. European carmaker André Citroen, after
reporting that his visit to Dearborn left him “greatly impressed by the power of
Ford’s production and his marvelous industrial creations at the River Rouge
plant,” added “regrettably, the artistic element is absent. Nothing about Ford or
his plant suggests a trace of the finer esthetic qualities.” Hounshell, From the
American System to Mass Production, 260–61; Olsen and Cabadas, The
American Auto Factory, 61, 63, 67, 70–71; New York Times, Apr. 22, 1923.
43. Kahn also helped design both the General Motors and Ford exhibitions at the
1939 New York World’s Fair. John E. Findling, ed., Historical Dictionary of
World’s Fairs and Expositions, 1851–1988 (New York: Greenwood Press,
1990), 22; Nevins and Hill, Ford: Expansion and Challenge, 1–2; Grandin,
Fordlandia, 2; Richard Guy Wilson, Dianne H. Pilgrim, and Dickran Tashjian,
The Machine Age in America 1918–1941 (New York: The Brooklyn Museum
and Harry N. Abrams, 1986), 27; Nelson, Industrial Architecture of Albert Kahn,
Inc., 97; Hildebrand, Designing for Industry, 206, 213; Works Progress
Administration, Michigan, 286, 292–93; New York Times, Apr. 9, 1972; U.S.
Travel Service, U.S. Department of Commerce, USA Plant Visits 1977–1978
(Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, n.d.).
44. David Roediger, “Americanism and Fordism—American Style: Kate Richards
O’Hare’s ‘Has Henry Ford Made Good?’,” Labor History 29 (2) (Spring 1988),
241–52.
45. John Reed, “Why They Hate Ford,” 11–12; Nevins and Frank Ernest Hill, Ford:
Expansion and Challenge, 88.
46. Edmund Wilson, “The Despot of Dearborn,” Scribner’s Magazine, July 1931,
24–36; Roediger, “Americanism and Fordism—American Style,” 243; Steven
Fraser, Labor Will Rule: Sidney Hillman and the Rise of American Labor (New
York: Free Press, 1991), 259–70; Filene, The Way Out, 199, 201, 215–17, 221.
On Ford’s anti-Semitism, see Sward, Legend of Henry Ford, 146–60.
47. John Dos Passos, The Big Money ([1936] New York: New American Library,
1969), 70–77, and Alfred Kazin’s introduction to this edition, xi–xii. Cecelia
Tichi expanded on Kazin’s observation in Shifting Gears: Technology,
Literature, Culture in Modernist America (Chapel Hill: University of North
Carolina Press, 1987), 194–216.
48. Smith, Making the Modern, 16–18; Louis-Ferdinand Céline, Journey to the End
of the Night ([1932] New York: New Directions, 1938); Upton Sinclair, The
Flivver King: A Story of Ford-America (Emaus, PA: Rodale Press, 1937);
Aldous Huxley’s Brave New World: A Novel (London: Chatto & Windus, 1932).
49. Darley, Factory, 15–27, 34; Wilson, Pilgrim, and Tashjian, The Machine Age in
America, 23, 29; Kim Sichel, From Icon to Irony: German and American
Industrial Photography (Seattle: University of Washington Press, 1995); Leah
Bendavid-Val, Propaganda and Dreams: Photographing the 1930s in the
U.S.S.R. and U.S.A. (Zurich: Edition Stemmle, 1999).
50. Margaret Bourke-White, Portrait of Myself (New York: Simon and Schuster,
Inc., 1963), quotes on 18, 33, 40, 49; Goldberg, Margaret Bourke-White, quote
on 74. Bourke-White may have been inspired by O’Neill’s play, in which one
character says “I love dynamos. O love to hear them sing.” Eugene O’Neill,
Dynamo (New York: Horace Liveright, 1929), 92.
51. Wilson, Pilgrim, and Tashjian, The Machine Age in America, 69; Goldberg,
Margaret Bourke-White, 87–89; Life, Nov. 23, 1936; William H. Young and
Nancy K. Young, The 1930s (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 2002), 156.
“Margaret Bourke-White Photographic Material, Itemized Listing” is a
comprehensive list of her photographs at the Margaret Bourke-White Papers,
Special Collections Research Center, Syracuse University Libraries, including
her factory photographs, https://library.syr.edu/digital/guides/b/bourke-
white_m.htm#series7 (accessed Sept. 23, 2015). For Hine, see, for example,
Jonathan L. Doherty, ed., Women at Work: 153 Photographs by Lewis W. Hine
(New York: Dover Publications and George Eastman House, 1983).
52. Sheeler’s portfolio of Rouge photographs can be seen at the Detroit Institute of
Art website for the 2004 exhibition “The Photography of Charles Sheeler,
American Modernist” (accessed Sept. 23, 2015),
http://www.dia.org/exhibitions/sheeler/content/rouge_gallery/hydra_shear.html.
Sharon Lynn Corwin, “Selling ‘America’: Precisionism and the Rhetoric of
Industry, 1916–1939,” Ph.D. dissertation, University of California, Berkeley,
2001, 17–79, 158; Carol Troyen, “Sheeler, Charles,” American National
Biography Online Feb. 2000 (accessed Sept. 24 2015),
http://www.anb.org/articles/17/17-00795.html; Wilson, Pilgrim, and Tashjian,
The Machine Age in America, 24, 78, 218–19; Smith, Making the Modern, 111–
13. The Ford company returned to the strategy of selling cars through imagery
of the magic and majesty of their production in a 1940 film it commissioned,
Symphony in F, shown at the New York World’s Fair. It can be seen at
“Symphony in F: An Industrial Fantasia for the World of Tomorrow,” The
National Archives, Unwritten Record Blog, Mar. 3, 2016, https://unwritten-
record.blogs.archives.gov/2016/03/03/symphony-in-f-an-industrial-fantasia-for-
the-world-of-tomorrow/.
53. Leo Marx, The Machine in the Garden: Technology and the Pastoral Ideal in
America (New York: Oxford University Press, 1964), 355–56; Nevins and Hill,
Ford: Expansion and Challenge, 282–83. For Sheeler’s photomontage
“Industry,” see Wilson, Pilgrim, and Tashjian, The Machine Age in America, 24,
218. American Landscape is now in the collection of the Museum of Modern
Art; Classic Landscape in the collection of the National Gallery of Art. See also
River Rouge Plant, Whitney Museum of American Art, and City Interior,
Worcester Art Museum. Amoskeag Mill Yard # 1 and Amoskeag Canal are in
the collection of the Currier Museum of Art in Manchester, New Hampshire.
Amoskeag Mills #2 is in the collection of the Crystal Bridges Museum in
Bentonville, Arkansas. Hine’s Amoskeag photographs are owned by the Library
of Congress and can be viewed at http://www.loc.gov/pictures/search/?
q=Amoskeag%20hine (accessed Nov. 4, 2016). Bourke-White’s Amoskeag
photographs are in Oversize 5, folders 31–35, Margaret Bourke-White Papers.
54. Smith, Making the Modern, 194; Troyen, “Sheeler, Charles.”
55. Carol Quirke, Eyes on Labor: News Photography and America’s Working
Class (New York: Oxford University Press, 2012), 273–74; Corwin, “Selling
‘America,’” 127; Life, Nov. 23, 1936; Nov. 14, 1938.
56. Sharon Lynn Corwin stresses, contrary to the standard account and to Terry
Smith, that workers do appear in Sheeler’s Rouge photographs and are critical
to their meaning. Corwin, “Selling ‘America,’” 23; Fortune, Dec. 1940.
57. Like Bourke-White, Driggs grew up familiar with the world of industry; her
father was an engineer for a steel company. Rivera and many of the
Precisionists shared a past engagement with Cubism. Corwin, “Selling
‘America,’” 145–48, 159–62, 165; Barbara Zabel, “Louis Lozowick and
Technological Optimism of the 1920s,” Archives of American Art Journal 14 (2)
(1974), 17–21; Wilson, Pilgrim, and Tashjian, The Machine Age in America,
237–42, 343; Linda Bank Downs, Diego Rivera: The Detroit Industry Murals
(New York: Norton, 1999), 21.
58. Downs, Diego Rivera, 22, 28.
59. Henry Ford offered a chauffeured Lincoln to Rivera and Kahlo to use in their
exploration of the city, but Rivera thought it would be embarrassing for artists to
be seen in such luxury, so he accepted a more modest car from Edsel instead.
Mark Rosenthal, “Diego and Frida”; Juan Rafael Coronel Rivera, “April 21,
1932”; Linda Downs, “The Director and the Artist: Two Revolutionaries”; and
John Dean, “’He’s the Artist in the Family’: The Life, Times, and Character of
Edsel Ford,” all in Rosenthal, Diego Rivera and Frida Kahlo in Detroit (Detroit,
MI: Detroit Institute of Arts, 2015). On the impact of the Depression on Detroit,
see Steve Babson with Ron Alpern, Dave Elsila, and John Revitte, Working
Detroit: The Making of a Union Town (New York: Adama Books, 1984), 52–60.
60. Rosenthal, Diego Rivera and Frida Kahlo, 102–03, 219.
61. Rivera’s depiction of the machinery and processes at the Rouge, working from
sketches, photographs, and information provided by Ford engineers, is
remarkably accurate. The one major exception is the giant stamping machine
in the south wall panel. Rivera painted an older model machine—the one
Sheeler had photographed—rather than the one then in use. (Rivera may have
worked from the Sheeler photo.) Apparently Rivera preferred the
anthropomorphic qualities of the older machine. For a detailed description and
analysis of the murals and their relationship to actual Rouge activity, see
Downs, Diego Rivera.
62. Rosenthal, Diego Rivera and Frida Kahlo, 103–07, 182; Detroit News, Mar. 22,
1933, and May 12, 1933. Before returning to Mexico, Rivera completed a
series of murals for the leftist New Workers School in New York City that
included a portrayal of the Homestead strike. See David P. Demarest, Jr., ed.,
“The River Ran Red”: Homestead 1892 (Pittsburgh, PA: University of
Pittsburgh Press, 1992), 218. The Rouge appears in another Detroit mural,
painted in 1937 by WPA artist Walter Speck for the headquarters of United
Automobile Workers Local 174. It now is in the Walter Reuther Library, Wayne
State University, Detroit. See “Collection Spotlight: UAW Local 174 Mural,” Oct.
20, 2016, https://reuther.wayne.edu/node/13600.
63. In another painting Kahlo began in Detroit, Self-Portrait on the Borderline
between Mexico and the United States, the Highland Park powerhouse
appears in the background. Downs, Diego Rivera, 58–60; Rosenthal, “Diego
and Frida: High Drama in Detroit,” and Solomon Grimberg, “The Lost Desire:
Frida Kahlo in Detroit,” in Rosenthal, Diego Rivera and Frida Kahlo.
64. Charles Chaplin, Modern Times (United Artists, 1936); Hounshell, From the
American System to Mass Production, 319–20; Charles Musser, “Modern
Times (Chaplin 1936),” (accessed Sept. 30, 2015),
http://actionspeaksradio.org/chaplin-by-charles-musser-2012/); Joyce Milton,
Tramp: The Life of Charlie Chaplin (New York: HarperCollins, 1996), 336, 348,
350; Mark Lynn Anderson, “Modern Times” (accessed Sept. 30, 2015),
http://laborfilms.org/modern-times/; Edward Newhouse, “Charlie’s Critics,”
Partisan Review and Anvil, Apr. 1936, 25–26 (includes quote from Daily
Worker review); Stephen Kotchin, Magic Mountain: Stalinism as a Civilization
(Berkeley: University of California Press, 1995), 184; Octavio Cortazar, Por
Primera Vez/For the First Times (El Instituto Cubano, Lombarda Industria
Cinematografia, 1967). In an odd coda, after the completion of Modern Times,
Paulette Goddard and Chaplin ended their romantic relationship and Goddard
went on to have one with Rivera. In a mural Rivera painted in San Francisco in
1940, Unión de la Expresión Artistica del Norte y Sur de este Continente (The
Marriage of the Artistic Expression of the North and of the South on This
Continent), he included images of Chaplin, Kahlo, and Goddard eyeing each
other suspiciously and a mashup of the Aztec goddess Coatlicue and a Detroit
Motor Company stamping machine, a rare return to a theme of Detroit Industry.
David Robinson, Chaplin, His Life and Art (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1985), 509;
City College of San Francisco, “Pan American Unity Mural,” (accessed Oct. 1,
2015), https://www.ccsf.edu/en/about-city-college/diego-rivera-
mural/overview.html.
65. Ruth McKenney, Industrial Valley (New York: Harcourt, Brace, 1939), 261–62.
66. For an overview of this era, see Joshua B. Freeman, American Empire, 1945–
2000: The Rise of a Global Empire, the Democratic Revolution at Home (New
York: Viking, 2012).
67. There is a large literature about labor upsurge of the 1930s, but the best single
account remains Irving Bernstein, Turbulent Years: A History of the American
Worker 1933–1941 (Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1970).
68. In addition to Bernstein, Turbulent Years, see, Ronald W. Schatz, The
Electrical Workers: A History of Labor at General Electric and Westinghouse,
1923–1960 (Urbana: University of Illinois Press, 1983); Daniel Nelson,
American Rubber Workers and Organized Labor, 1900–1941 (Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press, 1988); and Sidney Fine, The Automobile Under the
Blue Eagle: Labor, Management, and the Automobile Manufacturing Code
(Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1964).
69. Bernstein, Turbulent Years, 509–51; Henry Kraus, The Many and the Few: A
Chronicle of the Dynamic Auto Workers ([1947] Urbana: University of Illinois
Press, 1985). See, also, Sidney A. Fine, Sit-down: The General Motors Strike
of 1936–1937 (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1969).
70. Joshua Freeman et al., Who Built America? 395; Bernstein, Turbulent Years,
551–54, 608–09, 613; Steve Jefferys, Management and Managed: Fifty Years
of Crisis at Chrysler (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1986), 71–77;
Jefferson Cowie, Capital Moves: RCA’s Seventy-Year Quest for Cheap Labor
(Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1999), 17–33.
71. Robert H. Zieger, The CIO, 1935–1955 (Chapel Hill: University of North
Carolina Press, 1995), 54–60; Bernstein, Turbulent Years, 432–73.
72. Bernstein, Turbulent Years, 478–98; Zieger, CIO, 79, 82.
73. Zieger, CIO, 121–31.
74. No similar size election again would be held until 1999, when seventy-four
thousand home-care workers in Los Angeles were sent ballots to determine if
they wanted union representation. John Barnard, American Vanguard: The
United Auto Workers during the Reuther Years, 1935–1970 (Detroit, MI: Wayne
State University Press, 2004), 153–64; Zieger, CIO, 122–24; Los Angeles
Times, Feb. 26, 1999.
75. Joshua Freeman, “Delivering the Goods: Industrial Unionism During World
War II,” Labor History 19 (4) (Fall 1978); U.S. Department of Commerce,
Historical Statistics of the United States, 1789–1945 (Washington, D.C., U.S.
Government Printing Office, 1949), 72. See also Nelson Lichtenstein, Labor’s
War at Home: The CIO in World War II ([1982] Philadelphia: Temple University
Press, 2003).
Chapter 5
“COMMUNISM IS SOVIET POWER PLUS THE ELECTRIFICATION
OF THE WHOLE COUNTRY”
1. Detroit Sunday News, Dec. 15, 1929. Photographs of the plant site and
construction are in box 10, Albert Kahn Papers, Bentley Historical Library,
University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, Michigan. See also “Agenda for Meeting
with Russian Visitors—Saturday, June 13, 1964,” Russian Scrapbooks, vol. II,
box 13, Kahn Papers; Those Who Built Stalingrad, As Told by Themselves
(New York: International Publishers, 1934), 29; Alan M. Ball, Imagining
America: Influence and Images in Twentieth-Century Russia (Lanham, MD:
Rowman & Littlefield, 2003), 124; New York Times, Mar. 29, 1930, May 18,
1930; Margaret Bourke-White, Eyes on Russia (New York: Simon and
Schuster, 1931), 118–27.
2. V. I. Lenin, “Our Foreign and Domestic Position and Party Tasks,” Speech
Delivered to the Moscow Gubernia Conference of the R.C.P.(B.), Nov. 21,
1920, Lenin’s Collected Works, Volume 31 (Moscow: Progress Publishers,
Moscow, 1966), 419–20.
3. Edward Hallett Carr and R. W. Davies, Foundations of a Planned Economy,
1926–1929, Vol. I–II (London: Macmillan, 1969), 844, 898–902; Alexander
Erlich, The Soviet Industrialization Debate, 1924–1928 (Cambridge, MA:
Harvard University Press, 1967), 164–65; J. V. Stalin, “A Year of Great
Change, On the Occasion of the Twelfth Anniversary of the October
Revolution,” Pravda 259 (Nov. 7, 1929),
https://www.marxists.org/reference/archive/stalin/works/1929/11/03.htm;
Stephen Kotkin, Magnetic Mountain: Stalinism as a Civilization (Berkeley:
University of California Press, 1995), 32 (quoted passage), 69–70, 363, 366.
4. Arens went on to become a leading industrial designer, working for some of
the best-known American corporations. Barnaby Haran cites Arens’s
comments in his article “Tractor Factory Facts: Margaret Bourke-White’s Eyes
on Russia and the Romance of Industry in the Five-Year Plan,” Oxford Art
Journal 38 (1) (2015), 82. The full text is in New Masses 3 (7) (Nov. 1927), 3.
On Arens, see “Biographical History,” Egmont Arens Papers Special
Collections Research Center, Syracuse University Libraries, accessed Feb. 23,
2016, http://library.syr.edu/digital/guides/a/arens_e.htm#d2e97.
5. Of course, there always were some government-owned factories, particularly
to produce armaments. As discussed in Chapter 4, at times these played an
important role in the development of production techniques.
6. On the impact of scientific management and mass production in Europe, see
Thomas P. Hughes, American Genesis: A Century of Invention and
Technological Enthusiasm, 1870–1970 (New York: Viking, 1989), 285–323;
Judith A. Merkle, Management and Ideology: The Legacy of the International
Scientific Management Movement (Berkeley: University of California Press,
1980), esp. 105, 136–223; Charles S. Maier, “Between Taylorism and
Technocracy: European Ideologies and the Vision of Industrial Productivity in
the 1920s,” Journal of Contemporary History 5 (2) (1970), pp. 27–61; and
Antonio Gramsci, “Americanism and Fordism,” in Selections from the Prison
Notebooks of Antonio Gramsci, ed. and trans. Quintin Hoare and Geoffrey
Nowell Smith (New York: International Publishers, 1971).
7. Lenin was particularly attracted to Gilbreth’s work (as other Russian
communists would be) because, by simplifying motions for completing tasks, it
claimed to increase productivity without increasing the exploitation of workers
as speedup did. S. A. Smith, Red Petrograd: Revolution in the Factories 1917–
1918 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1983), 7–12; Merkle,
Management and Ideology, 105–06, 179; Daniel A. Wren and Arthur G.
Bedeian, “The Taylorization of Lenin: Rhetoric or Reality?” International Journal
of Social Economics 31 (3) (2004), 287–99 (quote from Lenin on 288); V. I.
Lenin, Imperialism: The Highest Stage of Capitalism; A Popular Outline ([1917]
New York: International Publishers, 1939).
8. Lenin’s remarks about Taylor were soon translated into English, circulated in
the United States, and frequently quoted in business circles. Wren and
Bedeian, “Taylorization of Lenin,” 288–89; Merkle, Management and Ideology,
111–15 (quote on 113).
9. Isaac Deutscher, The Prophet Armed; Trotsky: 1879–1921 (New York: Oxford
University Press, 1954), 499–502; Merkle, Management and Ideology, 118–19;
Kendall E. Bailes, “Alexei Gastev and the Soviet Controversy over Taylorism,
1918–24,” Soviet Studies 29 (3) (July 1977), 374, 380–83.
10. Merkle, Management and Ideology, 114–20; Bailes, “Alexei Gastev”; Vladimir
Andrle, Workers in Stalin’s Russia: Industrialization and Social Change in a
Planned Economy (New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1988), 101–02; Wren and
Bedeian, “Taylorization of Lenin,” 290–91; Deutscher, The Prophet Armed,
498–501.
11. An earlier All-Russian Conference on Scientific Management had been
organized by Trotsky in 1921, but failed to resolve the differences between the
two sides of the debate. Bailes, “Alexei Gastev,” 387–93; Kendall E. Bailes,
“The American Connection: Ideology and the Transfer of American Technology
to the Soviet Union, 1917–1941,” Comparative Studies in Society and History
23 (3) (July 1981), 437; Wren and Bedeian, “Taylorization of Lenin,” 291.
12. When a delegation from the Ford Motor Company visited Gastev’s institute in
1926, they deemed it “a circus, a comedy, a crazy house,” “a pitiful waste of
young people’s time.” Merkle, Management and Ideology, 123; Andrle, Workers
in Stalin’s Russia, 93–94; Bailes, “Alexei Gastev,” 391, 393; Timothy W. Luke,
Ideology and Soviet Industrialization (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1985),
165–66; Wren and Bedeian, “Taylorization of Lenin” 291–96; Ball, Imagining
America, 28–29.
13. My discussion of RAIC is based on Steve Fraser, “The ‘New Unionism’ and the
‘New Economic Policy’,” in James E. Cronin and Carmen Sirianni, eds., Work,
Community and Power: The Experience of Labor in Europe and America,
1900–1925 (Philadelphia: Temple University Press, 1983).
14. William Z. Foster, Russian Workers and Workshops in 1926 (Chicago: Trade
Union Educational League, 1926), 52; Erlich, Soviet Industrialization Debate,
24–25, 105–06, 114.
15. Erlich, Soviet Industrialization Debate, xvii–xviii, 140, 147, 161; Smith, Red
Petrograd, 7–8, 10–12; Orlando Figes, Revolutionary Russia, 1891–1991: A
History (New York: Metropolitan Books, 2014), 112.
16. Bailes, “The American Connection,” 430–31; Hans Rogger, “Amerikanizm and
the Economic Development of Russia,” Comparative Studies in Society and
History 23 (3) (July 1981); Hughes, American Genesis, 269; Dana G.
Dalrymple, “The American Tractor Comes to Soviet Agriculture: The Transfer of
a Technology,” Technology and Culture 5 (2) (Spring 1964), 192–94, 198; Allan
Nevins and Frank Ernest Hill, Ford: Expansion and Challenge, 1915–1933
(New York: Charles Scribner’s Sons: 1957), 255, 673–77.
17. Foster also claimed that Soviet workers accepted piecework and Taylorism
because “The benefits of increased production flow to the workers, not to
greedy capitalists.” William Z. Foster, Russian Workers, 13, 54; New York
Times, Feb. 17, 1928 (“Fordizatsia”).
18. In seeing socialism as the outcome of a combination of Soviet rule with
American methods, Trotsky was not only echoing Lenin but also voicing a
common Bolshevik belief. In 1923, for example, Nikolai Bukharin declared “We
need Marxism plus Americanism.” Rogger, “Amerikanizm,” 384. The Trotsky
quotes come from his essay “Culture and Socialism,” Krasnaya Nov, 6 (Feb. 3,
1926), translated by Brian Pearce, in Leon Trotsky, Problems of Everyday Life
and Other Writings on Culture and Science (New York: Monad Press, 1973).
19. The Five-Year Plan was a highly detailed document, running more than 1,700
pages long. Erlich, Soviet Industrialization Debate; Carr and Davies,
Foundations of a Planned Economy, 894, 896; Figes, Revolutionary Russia, 4,
139, 146–48.
20. There perhaps was a cultural element in the Soviet embrace of industrial
giantism as well; Russia, before and after the revolution, had a general
predilection to monumentality, evident, for example, in buildings from the
Hermitage to the never completed Moscow Palace of Soviets. My thanks to
Kate Brown for this point. Carr and Davies, Foundations of a Planned
Economy, 844, 898–902; Erlich, Soviet Industrialization Debate, 67–68, 107–
08, 140; Andrle, Workers in Stalin’s Russia, 27; Those Who Built Stalingrad,
33–38.
21. Bailes, “The American Connection,” 431; Merkle, Management and Ideology,
125; Rogger, “Amerikanizm,” 416–17.
22. Another American, Bill Shatov, supervised a second, large early Soviet project,
the Turksib railway, but that was a very different story; Shatov was a Russian-
born anarchist, active in the United States in the Industrial Workers of the
World, who returned to Russia in 1917. Hughes, American Genesis, 264–69;
Carr and Davies, Foundations of a Planned Economy, 900–901; Bourke-White,
Eyes on Russia, 76–88; Sonia Melnikova-Raich, “The Soviet Problem with Two
‘Unknowns’: How an American Architect and a Soviet Negotiator Jump-Started
the Industrialization of Russia: Part II: Saul Bron,” Industrial Archeology 37
(1/2) (2011), 8–9. Melnikova-Raich’s article is the second part of her revelatory
examination of the role of American companies and experts in Soviet
industrialization based on extensive research in both U.S. and Soviet archives.
On Shatov, see the Emma Goldman Papers, Editors’ Notes (accessed Jan. 11,
2016), http://editorsnotes.org/projects/emma/topics/286/.
23. Adler, “Russia ‘Arming’ with Tractor”; Maurice Hindus, “Preface,” in Bourke-
White, Eyes on Russia, 14–15; Dalrymple, “The American Tractor Comes to
Soviet Agriculture,” 210; Andrle, Workers in Stalin’s Russia, 3.
24. The Soviets planned to produce a tractor based on an International Harvester
model, receiving cooperation from the company without paying it royalties. New
York Times, Nov. 5, 1928, May 5, 1929, and May 7, 1929; Sonia Melnikova-
Raich, “The Soviet Problem with Two ‘Unknowns’: How an American Architect
and a Soviet Negotiator Jump-Started the Industrialization of Russia: Part I:
Albert Kahn,” Industrial Archeology 36 (2) (2010), 60–61, 66; Economic Review
of the Soviet Union, Apr. 1, 1930.
25. Detroit Free Press, May 14, 1929, and June 1, 1929.
26. Melnikova-Raich, “The Soviet Problem with Two ‘Unknowns,’ Part I,” 61, 66–
68; New York Times, July 1, 1929, Mar. 29, 1930, May 18, 1930, and Mar. 27,
1932; Those Who Built Stalingrad, 38–45, 50–56 (Ivanov quote on 52), 206;
Andrle, Workers in Stalin’s Russia, 84–85; Rogger, “Amerikanizm,” 383–84.
27. New York Times, June 19, 1930; Those Who Built Stalingrad, 13, 62.
28. Melnikova-Raich, “The Soviet Problem with Two ‘Unknowns,’ Part II,” 9–11,
23–24; New York Times, May 5, 1929, May 7, 1929, June 1, 1929; Nevins and
Hill, Ford: Expansion and Challenge, 677–78, 683; Richard Cartwright Austin,
Building Utopia: Erecting Russia’s First Modern City, 1930 (Kent, OH: Kent
State University Press, 2004), 12.
29. Melnikova-Raich, “The Soviet Problem with Two ‘Unknowns,’ Part II,” 11–12;
Michigan Manufacturer and Financial Record, Apr. 19, 1930; Lewis H.
Siegelbaum, Cars for Comrades: The Life of the Soviet Automobile (Ithaca, NY:
Cornell University Press, 2008), 40; Betsy Hunter Bradley, The Works: The
Industrial Architecture of the United States (New York: Oxford University Press,
1999), 22; Austin, Building Utopia, 5–6, 13–19.
30. Austin, Building Utopia, 31–43, 59–101, 121–39; New York Times, Dec. 2,
1931.
31. In April 1930, the Soviet Automobile Construction Trust decided it had been a
mistake to ask Austin to design the autoworkers’ city: “If Americans are
specialists in automobile construction, they are certainly far from specialists in
designing Socialist town [sic] for the Soviet Republics.” Nonetheless, even in
the radical socialist vision for the city there was some American influence. One
of the key figures involved, architect and educator Alexander Zelenko, had
spent time in the United States, including visits to Hull House in Chicago and
the University Settlement in New York, where he was influenced by the ideas of
John Dewey. New York Times, Dec. 16, 1929, Apr. 11, 1931, Mar. 27, 1932;
Yordanka Valkanova, “The Passion for Educating the ‘New Man’: Debates
about Preschooling in Soviet Russia, 1917–1925,” History of Education
Quarterly 49 (2) (May 2009), 218; Austin, Building Utopia, 45–53, 84–85, 161–
68; Kotkin, Magnetic Mountain, 366.
32. The very popular Soviet novel Cement, by Fyodo Vasilievich Gladkov ([1925]
New York: Frederick Ungar Publishing Co., 1973), vividly portrays the huge
obstacles and heroic efforts involved in Soviet industrialization. For first-person
accounts in English of work on First-Year Plan projects, see Those Who Built
Stalingrad and John Scott, Behind the Urals: An American Worker in Russia’s
City of Steel (Cambridge, MA: Houghton Mifflin, 1942).
33. On-site reports include The Detroit Sunday News, Dec. 15, 1929, and New
York Times, Nov. 21, 1930. Time coverage includes “Great Kahn,” May 20,
1929, “Austin’s Austingrad,” Sept. 16, 1929, and “Architects to Russia,” Jan.
20, 1930.
34. Saul G. Bron, Soviet Economic Development and American Business (New
York: Horace Liveright, 1930), 76, 144–46.
35. Melnikova-Raich, “The Soviet Problem with Two ‘Unknowns,’ Part I,” 60–63;
New York Times, Jan. 11, 1930; “Architects to Russia,” Time, Jan. 20, 1930;
Terry Smith, Making the Modern: Industry, Art and Design in America (Chicago:
University of Chicago Press, 1993), 85; Detroit Free Press, Jan. 18, 1930;
Detroit Times, Mar. 17, 1930.
36. “Industry’s Architect,” Time, June 29, 1942; Melnikova-Raich, “The Soviet
Problem with Two ‘Unknowns,’ Part I,” 62–66, 75.
37. The design of the tractor to be produced in Chelyabinsk and much of the
engineering for its manufacture was done at a Detroit office that had twelve
U.S. and forty Soviet engineers. Melnikova-Raich, “The Soviet Problem with
Two ‘Unknowns,’ Part I,” 69–71.
38. Those Who Built Stalingrad, 56-58, 261; Bourke-White, Eyes on Russia, 188.
Of course, not speaking Russian and unfamiliar with the circumstances, it is
quite possible that Bourke-White and other American observers failed to fully
understand what they were seeing and its causes.
39. New York Times, Nov. 7, 1930, Nov. 24, 1930, Dec. 27, 1930, Sept. 28, 1931,
Oct. 4, 1931, Apr. 14, 1934; Nevins and Hill, Ford: Expansion and Challenge,
522; Meredith Roman, “Racism in a ‘Raceless’ Society: The Soviet Press and
Representations of American Racial Violence at Stalingrad in 1930,”
International Labor and Working-Class History 71 (Spring 2007), 187; Those
Who Built Stalingrad, 64–66, 161, 164, 228–29, 261, 263.
40. New York Times, July 20, 1930; Austin, Building Utopia, 190–91; Victor
Reuther, The Brothers Reuther and the Story of the UAW (Boston: Houghton
Mifflin, 1976), 93, 101.
41. New York Times, July 20, 1930; May 11, 1931; May 14, 1931; May 18, 1931;
Dec. 2, 1931 (Duranty), May 18, 1932; Austin, Building Utopia, 190–91, 197;
Andrle, Workers in Stalin’s Russia, 35; Reuther, Brothers Reuther, 88, 93, 101,
110.
42. Melnikova-Raich, “The Soviet Problem with Two ‘Unknowns,’ Part I,” 69; Those
Who Built Stalingrad, 158; New York Times, Dec. 2, 1931.
43. The following account of Magnitogorsk is based primarily on Stephen Kotkin’s
brilliant history, Magnetic Mountain, and the first-person account by American
John Scott, who worked in the plant, Behind the Urals.
44. “Mighty Giant” from USSR in Construction, 1930, no. 9, p. 14. The Nizhny Tagil
plant looked very much like a Kahn factory, but apparently only Soviet
specialists were involved in designing, building, and starting it up, including
many veterans of First Five-Year Plan projects. See USSR in Construction,
1936, no. 7 (July).
45. “Super-American tempo” from USSR in Construction, 1930, no. 9, p.14. On the
weather, see http://www.weatherbase.com/weather/weather.php3?
s=83882&cityname=Magnitogorsk-Chelyabinsk-Russia (accessed Jan. 26,
2016) and Scott, Behind the Urals, 9–10, 15. For many Americans besides
Scott, cold was a defining feature of their experience in the Soviet Union. When
Victor Herman, who accompanied his father to the Gorky auto plant, attended a
Kremlin celebration of the first vehicles to come off the line, the first thing he
noticed was the warmth in the banquet hall, realizing that he had not been
“really all-over warm” since arriving in the country. Victor Herman, Coming Out
of the Ice (New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, 1979), 53.
46. Kotkin and Scott both extensively discuss the use of unfree labor. See, also,
William Henry Chamberlin, Russia’s Iron Age (Boston: Little, Brown, 1934), 51–
53; Lynne Viola, The Unknown Gulag: The Lost World of Stalin’s Special
Settlements (New York: Oxford University Press, 2007), 101.
47. In addition to Kotkin and Scott (quoted passage on 159), see Melnikova-Raich,
“The Soviet Problem with Two ‘Unknowns,’” Part II, 19; Herman, Coming Out of
the Ice; and Siegelbaum, Cars for Comrades, 58–59.
48. Scott, Behind the Urals, 204–05, 277–79.
49. Siegelbaum, Cars for Comrades, 45; Andrle, Workers in Stalin’s Russia, 16;
Robert C. Allen, Farm to Factory: A Reinterpretation of the Soviet Industrial
Revolution (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2003), 92–93, 102–06.
On the difficulty of obtaining accurate Soviet economic data, see Oscar
Sanchez-Sibony, Red Globalization: The Political Economy of the Soviet Cold
War from Stalin to Khrushchev (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
2014), 12–19.
50. Kotkin, Magnetic Mountain, 70, 363; Sheila Fitzpatrick, Everyday Stalinism:
Ordinary Life in Extraordinary Times: Soviet Russia in the 1930s (New York:
Oxford University Press, 1999), 79–83.
51. Scott, Behind the Urals, 16; Those Who Built Stalingrad, 168–73.
52. Andrle, Workers in Stalin’s Russia, 35; Scott, Behind the Urals, 144; Kotkin,
Magnetic Mountain, 189. Tensions about shifting gender roles are a major
theme in Cement, Gladkov’s widely read novel about the struggle to reopen a
huge, prerevolution cement factory.
53. Nelson Lichtenstein, The Most Dangerous Man in Detroit: Walter Reuther and
the Fate of American Labor (New York: Basic Books, 1995), 39; Those Who
Built Stalingrad, 98.
54. Scott, Behind the Urals, 138, 152, 212–19; Fitzpatrick, Everyday Stalinism, 87;
Kotkin, Magnetic Mountain, 214–15.
55. Scott, Behind the Urals, 40; Katerina Clark, “Little Heroes and Big Deeds:
Literature Responds to the First Five-Year Plan,” in Sheila Fitzpatrick, ed.,
Cultural Revolution in Russia, 1928–1931 (Bloomington: Indiana University
Press, 1978), 197; Reuther, Brothers Reuther, 98–99; Those Who Built
Stalingrad, 52–53. Oddly, artificial palm trees seemed to have been something
of a rage in the Soviet Union; when Ernst May and a team of German
architects entered the country in 1929 to design new industrial cities, they
found artificial palms common in railway waiting rooms. Ernst May, “Cities of
the Future,” in Walter Laqueur and Leopold Labedz, eds., Future of Communist
Society (New York: Praeger, 1962), 177.
56. Fitzpatrick, Everyday Stalinism, 49, 55–56, 95–103; Andrle, Workers in Stalin’s
Russia, 37; A. Baikov, Magnitogorsk (Moscow: Foreign Language Publishing
House, 1939), 19, 30–31; Kotkin, Magnetic Mountain, 67, 182–92, 290–91;
Scott, Behind the Urals, 235–36.
57. Herman, Coming Out of the Ice, 38; Scott, Behind the Urals, 234; Kotkin,
Magnetic Mountain, 108–23.
58. Fitzpatrick, Everyday Stalinism, 80–82; Those Who Built Stalingrad, 212–19.
59. Clark, “Little Heroes and Big Deeds,” 190–92; Susan Tumarkin Goodman,
“Avant-garde and After: Photography in the Early Soviet Union,” in Goodman
and Jens Hoffman, eds., The Power of Pictures: Early Soviet Photography,
Early Soviet Film (New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 2015), 23, 31–32;
Lydia Chukovskaya, Sofia Petrovna (1962; Evanston, IL: Northwestern
University Press, 1988), 4. Chukovskaya’s novella was not published in
Russian until 1962 and in English until 1967.
60. For a comparison of documentary photography in the United States and the
Soviet Union, see Bendavid-Val, Propaganda and Dreams: Photographing the
1930s in the U.S.S.R. and U.S.A. (Zurich: Edition Stemmle, 1999).
61. Over time, the magazine began covering more varied topics, including political
events, the army, ethnic groups, distant regions of the country, and sports.
USSR in Construction, 1930–1941; USSR in Construction: An Illustrated
Exhibition Magazine (Sundsvall, Sweden: Fotomuseet Sundsvall, 2006);
University of Saskatchewan Library, Digital Collections, USSR in Construction,
“About” (accessed Feb. 5, 2016), http://library2.usask.ca/USSRConst/about;
Goodman, “Avant-garde and After,” 27–28; Bendavid-Val, Propaganda and
Dreams, 62–65.
62. SSSR stroit sotsializm (Moskova: Izogiz, 1933); USSR in Construction: An
Illustrated Exhibition Magazine (press run data); B. M. Tal, Industriia
sotsializma. Tiazhelaia promyshlennost’k VII vsesoiuznomu s’ezdy sovetov
[Industry of Socialism. Heavy Industry for the Seventh Congress of Soviets]
(Moscow: Stroim, 1935).
63. Goodman, “Avant-garde and After,” 15, 17; USSR in Construction, 1930, no. 1.
64. Goodman, “Avant-garde and After,” 22–27, 38. Leah Bendavid-Val stresses
similarities between Soviet and U.S. photographers in Propaganda and
Dreams, which includes photographs of Magnitogorsk by Debabov, Albert, and
Petrusov. For more extensive collections of Petrusov’s work, see Georgij
Petrussow, Pioneer Sowjetischer Photographie (Köln, Germany: Galerie Alex
Lachmann, n.d.) and Georgy Petrusov: Retrospective/Point of View (Moscow:
GBUK “Multimedia Complex of Actual Arts,” Museum “Moscow House of
Photography,” 2010).
65. Entuziazm (Simfonija Donbassa), Ukrainfilm, 1931. Filmmakers like Vertov and
Sergei Eisenstein, who used avant-garde techniques to pursue revolutionary
themes, drew considerable attention outside of the Soviet Union, but domestic
audiences preferred more conventional entertainment. Jens Hoffman, “Film in
Conflict,” in Goodman and Hoffman, The Power of Pictures.
66. The Soviets also published in English a collection of letters from foreigners
who worked in the Soviet Union. Melnikova-Raich, “The Soviet Problem with
Two ‘Unknowns,’ Part II,” 17–18; Cynthia A. Ruder, Making History for Stalin;
The Story of the Belomor Canal (Gainesville: University Press of Florida,
1998); Those Who Built Stalingrad; Baikov, Magnitogorsk; Garrison House
Ephemera (accessed Nov. 13, 2016),
http://www.garrisonhouseephemera.com/?page=shop/flypage&product_id=546;
Sixty Letters: Foreign Workers Write of Their Life and Work in the U.S.S.R.
(Moscow: Co-operative Publishing Society of Foreign Workers in the U.S.S.R.,
1936).
67. Duranty’s articles on Soviet industry are too numerous to individually cite. For
Chamberlin, see Russia’s Iron Age. On American academic experts and
intellectuals, see David C. Engerman, Modernization from the Other Shore:
American Intellectuals and the Romance of Russian Development (Cambridge,
MA: Harvard University Press, 2003), esp. 5–6, 9, 156–57, 166, 237 (Fischer
quote).
68. Hans Schoots, Living Dangerously: A Biography of Joris Ivens (Amsterdam:
Amsterdam University Press, 2000), 74–81.
69. Bourke-White returned to the U.S.S.R. in 1941, when she photographed
Moscow during German bombing raids, Stalin in the Kremlin, and the front line.
Bourke-White, Eyes on Russia (quotes on 23 and 42); Margaret Bourke-White,
Portrait of Myself (New York: Simon and Schuster, Inc., 1963), 90–104, 174–
88; Vicki Goldberg, Margaret Bourke-White: A Biography (New York: Harper &
Row, 1986), 128– 32; Haran, “Tractor Factory Facts.”
70. To compare Bourke-White’s Soviet and U.S. textile mill photographs, see
Bourke-White, Eyes on Russia and Bourke-White, “Amoskeag” (1932),
reproduced in Richard Guy Wilson, Dianne H. Pilgrim, and Dickran Tashjian,
The Machine Age in America 1918–1941 (New York: Brooklyn Museum and
Harry N. Abrams, 1986), 234. Bourke-White also took similar photographs at
the American Woolen Company in Lawrence, Massachusetts. For an
interesting discussion of her Soviet work, see Haran, “Tractor Factory Facts.”
71. A drop in grain production during the first years of collectivization, combined
with the export of grain, exacerbated the food crisis. Sanchez-Sibony, Red
Globalization, 36–53 (Stalin quote on 51); Bailes, “The American Connection,”
433, 442–43; Those Who Built Stalingrad, 150, 198; Scott, Behind the Urals,
86–87, 174; Melnikova-Raich, “The Soviet Problem with Two ‘Unknowns,’ Part
I,” 74–75; New York Times, Mar. 26, 1932; Detroit Free Press, Mar. 29, 1932;
Daily Express, Apr. 19, 1932; Detroit News, Apr. 24, 1932; Nevins and Hill,
Ford: Expansion and Challenge, 682.
72. Merkle, Management and Ideology, 132; Bailes, “The American Connection,”
442–44; Those Who Built Stalingrad, 54, 198; Michael David-Fox, Showcasing
the Great Experiment: Cultural Diplomacy and Western Visitors to the Soviet
Union, 1921–1941 (New York: Oxford University Press, 2012), 285–86, 297–
99; Melnikova-Raich, “The Soviet Problem with Two ‘Unknowns,’ Part I,” 75–
76; Scott, Behind the Urals, 230–31.
73. Bailes, “The American Connection,” 445; Chamberlin, Russia’s Iron Age, 61–
65; R. W. Davies, Mark Harrison, and S. G. Wheatcroft, eds., The Economic
Transformation of the Soviet Union, 1913–1945 (New York: Cambridge
University Press, 1993), 95, 155; Figes, Revolutionary Russia, 5, 178.
74. Wikipedia, “Alexei Gastev” (accessed Nov. 12, 2016),
https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Aleksei_Gastev; Melnikova-Raich, “The Soviet
Problem with Two ‘Unknowns,’ Part II,” 17–20; Patrick Flaherty, “Stalinism in
Transition, 1932–1937,” Radical History Review, 37 (Winter 1987). Bill Shatov,
who had returned home from the United States and supervised the Turksib
railway project, was exiled to Siberia in 1937 and executed the following year.
Emma Goldman Papers, Editors’ Notes (accessed Jan. 11, 2016),
http://editorsnotes.org/projects/emma/topics/286/. For an account of the long
imprisonment, Siberian exile, and eventual return to the United States of a
young American worker at the Gorky auto plant, see Herman, Coming Out of
the Ice.
75. Donald Filtzer, Soviet Workers and Stalinist Industrialization: The Formation of
Modern Soviet Production Relations, 1928–1941 (Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe,
1986), 126–27, 261–66; Erlich, Soviet Industrialization Debate, 182–83; Allen,
Farm to Factory, 152, 170–71; Flaherty, “Stalinism in Transition,” 48–49.
76. After their revolution, the Soviets (like the French) introduced a new
organization of time, replacing the weekend with a system of one day off work
during every five days (four days in the metallurgy industry), later switching to
one day off every six days, before ultimately returning to more conventional
timekeeping. Filtzer, Soviet Workers, 91–96, 156; Kate Brown, A Biography of
No Place: From Ethnic Borderland to Soviet Heartland (Cambridge, MA:
Harvard University Press, 2003), 92–117; Fitzpatrick, Everyday Stalinism, 4,
42–45.
77. Most of the twenty thousand Stalingrad Tractor Factory workers were
evacuated as the battle broke out. The factory was rebuilt after the war. The
Nizhny Tagil Railroad Car Factory also was converted to military production,
and, like the Chelyabinsk plant, continues to produce both military and civilian
equipment, employing thirty thousand workers in 2016. Melnikova-Raich, “The
Soviet Problem with Two ‘Unknowns,’ Part I,” 68–69, 71–73; Reuther, Brothers
Reuther, 102–03; Siegelbaum, Cars for Comrades, 61–62; Jochen Hellbeck,
Stalingrad: The City that Defeated the Third Reich (New York: Public Affairs
Press, 2015), 89; “History—Chelyabinsk tractor plant (ChTZ)” (accessed Jan.
18, 2016), http://chtz-uraltrac.ru/articles/categories/24.php; New York Times,
Feb. 25, 2016; Scott, Behind the Urals, vii–viii, 63–65, 103.
78. John P. Diggins, Up from Communism ([1975] New York: Columbia University
Press, 1994), 189–98; Christopher Phelps, “C.L.R. James and the Theory of
State Capitalism,” in Nelson Lichtenstein, ed., American Capitalism: Social
Thought and Political Economy in the Twentieth Century (Philadelphia:
University of Pennsylvania Press, 2006); Filtzer, Soviet Workers, 270–71.
79. Andrle, Workers in Stalin’s Russia, 126–76, 198–201; Kotkin, Magnetic
Mountain, 206–07, 318–19; Filtzer, Soviet Workers, 233–36; Federico Bucci,
Albert Kahn: Architect of Ford (New York: Princeton Architectural Press, 1993),
92.
80. If anything, Freyn thought the Soviets were a bit too democratic; it would be
better if “more decisions might be made by responsible individuals rather than
by committees and commissions.” Edmund Wilson, “A Senator and an
Engineer,” New Republic, May 27, 1931; “An American Engineer Looks at the
Five Year Plan,” New Republic, May 6, 1931; Detroit News Apr. 24, 1932.
Chapter 6
“COMMON REQUIREMENTS OF INDUSTRIALIZATION”
1. Many of Burnham’s arguments had been put forth earlier by Bruno Rizzi, but
received little notice outside of small, left-wing circles. At roughly the same
time, C. L. R. James broke with Trotsky to describe the Soviet Union as “state
capitalist,” with productive enterprises collectively owned by a reemerging
capitalist class through the government. Ultimately, the United States, too,
James argued, would become state capitalist. James Burnham, The
Managerial Revolution ([1941] Bloomington: Indiana University Press, 1960);
Isaac Deutscher, The Prophet Outcast; Trotsky: 1929–1940 (New York: Oxford
University Press, 1963), 459–77; Christopher Phelps, “C.L.R. James and the
Theory of State Capitalism,” in Nelson Lichtenstein, ed., American Capitalism:
Social Thought and Political Economy in the Twentieth Century (Philadelphia:
University of Pennsylvania Press, 2006).
2. These paragraphs draw substantially from David C. Engerman, “To Moscow
and Back: American Social Scientists and the Concept of Convergence,” in
Lichtenstein, ed., American Capitalism.
3. http://brooklynnavyyard.org/the-navy-yard/history/ (accessed Mar. 29, 2016).
For a popular overview of the role of private business in wartime defense
production, see Arthur Herman, Freedom’s Forge: How American Business
Produced Victory in World War II (New York: Random House, 2012).
4. To undertake the war work, Kahn’s firm grew from four hundred to six hundred
employees. Hawkins Ferry, The Legacy of Albert Kahn (Detroit, MI: Wayne
State University Press, 1970), 25–26.
5. To expand the labor pool for Willow Run, Ford opened up jobs to women, who
eventually made up 35 percent of the workforce. However, in a departure from
its policy at Highland Park and the Rouge, the company all but spurned African
Americans. Willow Run workers eventually achieved productivity far above the
airplane industry norm. The latest use of the Willow Run factory grounds has
been as a test site for driverless cars. Sarah Jo Peterson, Planning the Home
Front: Building Bombers and Communities at Willow Run (Chicago: University
of Chicago Press, 2013); Allan Nevins and Frank Ernest Hill, Ford: Expansion
and Challenge, 1915–1933 (New York: Charles Scribner’s Sons: 1957), 242–
47; Nelson Lichtenstein, The Most Dangerous Man in Detroit: Walter Reuther
and the Fate of American Labor (New York: Basic Books, 1995), 160–74; Gail
Radford, Modern Housing for America: Policy Struggles in the New Deal Era
(Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1996), 121–32; New York Times, June
6, 2016.
6. Not all the workers at other airplane manufacturers were housed in single
plants; Republic and Grumman built auxiliary factories near their main plants to
bring work nearer to where workers lived, reducing problems with commuting
and housing. T. P. Wright Memorandum for Charles E. Wilson, Mar. 21, 1943,
box 7, National Aircraft War Production Council, Harry S. Truman Library,
Independence, MO; Ferry, Legacy of Albert Kahn, 25, 127–28; Tim Keogh,
“Suburbs in Black and White: Race, Jobs and Poverty in Twentieth-Century
Long Island,” Ph.D. dissertation, City University of New York, 2016, 53–56, 77;
T. M. Sell, Wings of Power: Boeing and the Politics of Growth in the Northwest
(Seattle: University of Washington Press, 2001), 19; John Gunther, Inside
U.S.A. (New York: Harper & Brothers, 1947), 142–43.
7. “Bethlehem Ship,” Fortune, Aug. 1945, 220; Bernard Matthew Mergen, “A
History of the Industrial Union of Marine and Shipbuilding Workers of America,
1933–1951,” Ph.D. dissertation, University of Pennsylvania, 1968, 2–3, 103–
04, 134–37, 142; [Baltimore] Evening Sun, Dec. 8, 1943; Apr. 5, 1944; Apr. 20,
1944; May 15, 1944; July 1, 1944; Karen Beck Skold, “The Job He Left Behind:
American Women in Shipyards During World War II,” in Carol R. Berkin and
Clara M. Lovett, eds., Women, War, and Revolution (New York: Holmes &
Meier, 1980), esp. 56–58; Eric Arnesen and Alex Lichtenstein, “Introduction:
‘All Kinds of People,’ ” in Katherine Archibald, Wartime Shipyard: A Study in
Social Disunity ([1947] Urbana: University of Illinois Press, 2006), xvi, xxxi–
xxxv; Joshua B. Freeman, American Empire, 1945–2000: The Rise of a Global
Empire, the Democratic Revolution at Home (New York: Viking, 2012), 21;
Peterson, Planning the Home Front, 279.
8. For the impact of World War II on the American working class, see Joshua
Freeman, “Delivering the Goods: Industrial Unionism during World War II,”
Labor History 19 (4) (Fall 1978); Nelson Lichtenstein, “The Making of the
Postwar Working Class: Cultural Pluralism and Social Structure in World War
II,” The Historian 51 (1) (Nov. 1988), 42–63; Gary Gerstle, “The Working Class
Goes to War,” Mid-America 75 (3) (1993), 303–22. Dorothea Lange and
Charles Wollenberg, Photographing the Second Gold Rush: Dorothea Lange
and the East Bay at War, 1941–1945 (Berkeley, CA: Heyday Books, 1995).
9. Jack Metzgar, “The 1945–1946 Strike Wave,” in Aaron Brenner, Benjamin Day,
and Immanuel Ness, eds., The Encyclopedia of Strikes in American History
(Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe, 2009); Art Preis, Labor’s Giant Step: Twenty years
of the CIO (New York: Pioneer Press, 1965), 257–83.
10. Ronald W. Schatz, The Electrical Workers: A History of Labor at General
Electric and Westinghouse, 1923–1960 (Urbana: University of Illinois Press,
1983), 105–64; Nelson Lichtenstein, The Most Dangerous Man in Detroit, 282–
98; Freeman, American Empire,119–24; Labor’s Heritage: Quarterly of the
George Meany Memorial Archives, 4 (1992), 28; Joshua Freeman, “Labor
During the American Century: Work, Workers, and Unions Since 1945,” in
Jean-Christophe Agnew and Roy Rosenzweig, eds., A Companion to Post-
1945 America (Malden, MA: Blackwell, 2002); Ruth Milkman, Farewell to the
Factory: Auto Workers in the Late Twentieth Century (Berkeley: University of
California Press, 1997); Charles Corwin in New York Daily Worker, Feb. 4,
1949, quoted in Karen Lucic, Charles Sheeler and the Cult of the Machine
(Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1991), 114; Jack Metzgar, Striking
Steel: Solidarity Remembered (Philadelphia: Temple University Press, 2000),
30–45 (quote on 39).
11. Daniel Nelson, American Rubber Workers and Organized Labor, 1900–1941
(Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1988), 82–83, 234–45, 257–64,
271, 307–09, 315–17; Charles A. Jeszeck, “Plant Dispersion and Collective
Bargaining in the Rubber Tire Industry,” Ph.D. dissertation, University of
California, Berkeley, 1982, 31, 47–54, 106–08.
12. The Bloomington plant swelled to more than eight thousand employees after
RCA began producing televisions there, but the company eventually shifted
much of the production first to Memphis and then Ciudad Juárez, Mexico.
Jefferson Cowie, Capital Moves: RCA’s Seventy-Year Quest for Cheap Labor
(Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1999), 10, 15, 17, 22–35, 42–43.
13. In a further effort to avoid interruptions in production, General Motors, unlike
Ford, made it a policy to use outside suppliers for a majority of the parts and
accessories that went into its vehicles. Douglas Reynolds, “Engines of
Struggle: Technology, Skill and Unionization at General Motors, 1930–1940,”
Michigan Historical Review 15 (Spring 1989), 79–80; New York Times, Aug. 12,
1935; Alfred D. Chandler, Jr., Scale and Scope: The Dynamics of Industrial
Capitalism (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1994), 208.
14. Jeszeck, “Plant Dispersion,” 33–35; “Flying High,” Kansas City Public Library,
http://www.kclibrary.org/blog/week-kansas-city-history/flying-high, and “Fairfax
Assembly Plant,” GM Corporate Newsroom,
http://media.gm.com/media/us/en/gm/company_info/facilities/assembly/fairfax.
html (both accessed Apr. 5, 2016); Schatz, Electrical Workers, 233. On war-
related industrial development in the Southwest, see Elizabeth Tandy Shermer,
Sunbelt Capitalism: Phoenix and the Transformation of American Politics
(Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press, 2013).
15. Metzgar, “The 1945–1946 Strike Wave”; Freeman, American Empire, 39–41;
Kim Phillips-Fein, Invisible Hands: The Making of the Conservative Movement
from the New Deal to Reagan (New York: W. W. Norton, 2009), 93–97;
Elizabeth A. Fones-Wolf, Selling Free Enterprise: The Business Assault on
Labor and Liberalism, 1945–60 (Urbana: University of Illinois Press, 1994),
138–39.
16. Kim Phillips-Fein, “Top-Down Revolution: Businessmen, Intellectuals and
Politicians Against the New Deal, 1945–1964,” Ph.D. dissertation, Columbia
University, 2004, 220; Joshua B. Freeman, Working-Class New York: Life and
Labor since World War II (New York: New Press, 2000), 60–71; Tami J.
Friedman, “Communities in Competition: Capital migration and plant relocation
in the United States carpet industry, 1929–1975,” Ph.D. dissertation, Columbia
University, 2001, 22, 70–76, 201–04.
17. Schatz, Electrical Workers, 170–75; Phillips-Fein, Invisible Hands, 97–114.
18. Schatz, Electrical Workers, 233–34.
19. Schatz, Electrical Workers, 234–36; Freeman, American Empire, 303–06;
Thomas J. Sugrue, The Origins of the Urban Crisis: Race and Inequality in
Postwar Detroit (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1996), 128–29;
James C. Cobb, The Selling of the South: The Southern Crusade for Industrial
Development, 1936–1980 (Baton Rouge: Louisiana State University Press,
1982); Friedman, “Communities in Competition,” 111–66.
20. See, for example, Martin Beckman, Location Theory (New York: Random
House, 1968); Gerald J. Karaska and David F. Bramhall, Locational Analysis
for Manufacturing: A Selection of Readings (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1969);
and Paul Krugman, Geography and Trade (Leuven, Belgium: Leuven University
Press and Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1989), esp. 62–63 for discussion of
Akron.
21. Counter to the common management view, the productivity of unionized
workers often exceeded that of nonunion workers. Roger W. Schmenner,
Making Business Location Decisions (Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall,
1982), vii, 10–11, 124–26, 154–57, 239; Phillips-Fein, Invisible Hands, 104;
Lawrence Mishel and Paula B. Voos, eds., Unions and Economic
Competitiveness (New York: M.E. Sharpe, 1992).
22. Kimberly Phillips-Fein, “American Counterrevolutionary: Lemuel Ricketts
Boulware and General Electric, 1950–1960,” in Lichtenstein, ed., American
Capitalism, 266–67; John Barnard, American Vanguard: The United Auto
Workers during the Reuther Years, 1935–1970 (Detroit, MI: Wayne State
University Press, 2004), 483; Cowie, Capital Moves, 53–58. See also
Friedman, “Communities in Competition,” 380–81, 403–21.
23. Sugrue, Origins of the Urban Crisis, 130–35.
24. Steve Jefferys, Management and Managed: Fifty Years of Crisis at Chrysler
(Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1986), 155; Historic American
Engineering Record, Mid-Atlantic Region National Park Service, “Dodge Bros.
Motor Car Company Plant (Dodge Main): Photographs, Written Historical and
Descriptive Data” (Philadelphia: Department of the Interior, 1980), 20.
25. Freeman, American Empire, 115; U.S. Bureau of the Census, 1967 Census of
Manufactures, vol. 1: Summary and Subject Statistics (Washington, D.C.: U.S.
Government Printing Office, 1971), table 1 (pages 2–4).
26. Charles Fishman, “The Insourcing Boom,” The Atlantic, Dec. 2012; Mark
Reilly, “General Electric Appliance Park,” in John E. Kleber, ed., The
Encyclopedia of Louisville (Lexington, KY: University Press of Kentucky, 2000),
333–34.
27. “The Rebirth of Ford,” Fortune, May 1947, 81–89. The Evans photographs are
now held by the Metropolitan Museum of Art and can be seen at
http://www.metmuseum.org/art/collection/search/281891 and
http://www.metmuseum.org/art/collection/search/279282 (accessed Apr. 11,
2016).
28. Warren Bareiss, “The Life of Riley,” Museum of Broadcast Communications—
Encyclopedia of Television (accessed Apr. 11, 2016),
http://www.museum.tv/eotv/lifeofriley.htm. See also George Lipsitz, “The
Meaning of Memory: Family, Class, and Ethnicity in Early Network Television
Programs,” Cultural Anthropology 1 (4) (Nov. 1986), 355–87.
29. Nelson Lichtenstein, State of the Union: A Century of American Labor ([2002]
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2013), 148–62, 215–18; U.S.
Bureau of the Census, Census of Manufactures, 1972, vol. 1, Subject and
Special Statistics (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1976),
68; Daniel Bell, The Coming of Post-Industrial Society; A Venture in Social
Forecasting (New York: Basic Books, 1973); Freeman, American Empire, 303–
06, 344–49; Metzgar, Striking Steel, 210–23.
30. Anders Åman, Architecture and Ideology in Eastern Europe during the Stalin
Era; An Aspect of Cold War History (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1992), 76;
Sonia Melnikova-Raich, “The Soviet Problem with Two ‘Unknowns’: How an
American Architect and a Soviet Negotiator Jump-Started the Industrialization
of Russia: Part II: Saul Bron,” Industrial Archeology 37 (1/2) (2011), 21–22;
“History—Chelyabinsk tractor plant (ChTZ)” (accessed Jan. 18, 2016),
http://chtz-uraltrac.ru/articles/categories/24.php; New York Times, Feb. 25,
2016; Stephen Kotkin, Steeltown, USSR: Soviet Society in the Gorbachev Era
(Berkeley: University of California Press, 1991), xii–xiii, 2, 5.
31. Kate Brown, Plutopia: Nuclear Families, Atomic Cities, and the Great Soviet
and American Plutonium Disasters (New York: Oxford University Press, 2013);
Lewis H. Siegelbaum, Cars for Comrades: The Life of the Soviet Automobile
(Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 2008), 80–81.
32. Alan M. Ball, Imagining America: Influence and Images in Twentieth-Century
Russia (Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield, 2003), 162.
33. Most of the housing in Avtograd consisted of apartments for individual families
in five to sixteen story buildings. Siegelbaum, Cars for Comrades, 81–109; Wall
Street Journal, Apr. 11, 2016.
34. KAMAZ, “History,” https://kamaz.ru/en/about/history/ (accessed May 2, 2017).
35. Siegelbaum, Cars for Comrades, 112–24; Wall Street Journal, Apr. 11, 2016;
KAMAZ, “History”; KAMAZ, “General Information” (accessed May 2, 2017),
https://kamaz.ru/en/about/general-information/.
36. Czechoslovakia was exceptional in having a large communist party with
substantial popular support. Tony Judt, Postwar: A History of Europe Since
1945 (New York: Penguin, 2005), 129–39, 165–96; Åman, Architecture and
Ideology, 12, 28–30, 147; Mark Pittaway, “Creating and Domesticating
Hungary’s Socialist Industrial Landscape: From Dunapentele to Sztálinváros,
1950–1958,” Historical Archaeology 39 (3) (2005), 76, 79–80.
37. Romania never had a “first socialist city” of the sort found elsewhere in Eastern
Europe. Åman, Architecture and Ideology, 77 (“cult of steel”), 81, 147, 157–61;
Ulf Brunnbauer, “‘The Town of the Youth’: Dimitrovgrad and Bulgarian
Socialism,” Ethnologica Balkanica 9 (2005), 92–95. See also Paul R.
Josephson, Would Trotsky Wear a Bluetooth? Technological Utopianism under
Socialism, 1917–1989 (Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press, 2012),
65–119.
38. Åman, Architecture and Ideology, esp. 33–39, 102–03, 158, 162; Pittaway,
“Hungary’s Socialist Industrial Landscape,” 78–81, 85–87; Brunnbauer, “‘The
Town of the Youth,’” 94, 98–111; Katherine Lebow, Unfinished Utopia: Nowa
Huta, Stalinism, and Polish Society, 1949–56 (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University
Press, 2013), 46, 52–56.
39. Paweł Jagło, “Steelworks,” in Nowa Huta 1949+ [English version] (Kraków:
Muzeum Historyczne Miasta Krakowa, 2013), quote on 18; Lebow, Unfinished
Utopia, 19–26, 36–40, 69; Alison Stenning, “Placing (Post-)Socialism: The
Making and Remaking of Nowa Huta, Poland,” European Urban and Regional
Studies 7 (Apr. 2000), 100–01; Boleslaw Janus, “Labor’s Paradise: Family,
Work, and Home in Nowa Huta, Poland, 1950–1960,” East European Quarterly
XXXIII (4) (Jan. 2000), 469; H. G. J. Pounds, “Nowa Huta: A New Polish Iron
and Steel Plant,” Geography 43 (1) (Jan. 1958), 54–56; interview with
Stanisław Lebiest, Roman Natkonski, and Krysztof Pfister, Nowa Huta, Poland,
May 19, 2015. The largest U.S. Steel mill, in terms of employment, the
Bethlehem Steel Sparrows Point complex, had 28,600 workers in 1957 and a
capacity of 8.2 million tons a year. The U.S. Steel mill in Gary, Indiana, peaked
at an estimated 25,000 workers in 1976. In 1996, with only 7,800 workers
remaining, it produced 12.8 million tons of steel. Mark Reutter, Sparrows Point;
Making Steel—The Rise and Ruin of American Industrial Might (New York:
Summit Books, 1988), 10, 413; Chicago Tribune, Feb. 26, 1996.
40. Lebow, Unfinished Utopia, 37–40; 61–62, 74–77, 82–88, 92–93, 97–98, 103;
Janus, “Labor’s Paradise,” 455–56; Poland Today 6 (7–8) (July–Aug. 1951),
14. Photographs of the construction of Nowa Huta, including of female
plasterers, can be seen in Henryk Makarewicz and Wiktor Pental, 802 Procent
Normy; pierwsze lata Nowej Huty [802% Above the Norm: The Early Years of
Nowa Huta] (Kraków: Fundacja Imago Mundi: Vis-à-vis/etiuda, [2007]).
41. Lebow, Unfinished Utopia, 65, 71, 157–58; Paweł Jagło, “Architecture of Nowa
Huta,” in Nowa Huta 1949+, 26.
42. Leszek J. Sibila, Nowa Huta Ecomuseum: A Guidebook (Kraków: The
Historical Museum of the City of Kraków, 2007); Jagło, “Architecture of Nowa
Huta”; Lebow, Unfinished Utopia, 29–35, 41–42, 71–73; Åman, Architecture
and Ideology, 102–103, 151–53; Nowa przestrzeń; Modernizm w Nowej Hucie
(Kraków: Muzeum Historyczne Miasta Krakowa, 2012). For U.S. comparison,
see Freeman, American Empire, 12–27, 136–39.
43. Lebow, Unfinished Utopia, 3, 146–49; Åman, Architecture and Ideology, 151;
stamps:
https://www.stampworld.com/en_US/stamps/Poland/Postage%20stamps/?
year=1951 and http://colnect.com/en/stamps/list/country/4365-
Poland/theme/3059-Cranes_Machines (accessed Nov. 25, 2016); Anne
Applebaum, Iron Curtain: The Crushing of Eastern Europe, 1944–56 (New
York: Doubleday, 2012), 360, 372, 377–78, 384–85 (quotes from Ważyk in her
translation on 384); Andrzej Wajda, Man of Marble (Warsaw: Zespól Filmowy
X, 1977). See also Marci Shore, “Some Words for Grown-Up Marxists: ‘A
Poem for Adults’ and the Revolution from Within,” Polish Review 42 (2) (1997),
131–54.
44. Brunnbauer, “’The Town of the Youth,’” 96–97, 105; Janus, “Labor’s Paradise,”
454–55; Pittaway, “Hungary’s Socialist Industrial Landscape,” 75–76, 82–85.
45. Judt, Postwar, 172; Janus, “Labor’s Paradise,” 464–65; Lebow, Unfinished
Utopia, 45, 47, 50–51, 56; interview with Lebiest et al.
46. Janus, “Labor’s Paradise,” 459–64; Brunnbauer, “‘The Town of the Youth,’”
105; Lebow, Unfinished Utopia, 124–25, 138–45; Pittaway, “Hungary’s Socialist
Industrial Landscape,” 87.
47. Sztálinváros was renamed Dunaújváros in 1961. Josephson, Would Trotsky
Wear a Bluetooth?, 85–86; Applebaum, Iron Curtain, 459; Pittaway, “Hungary’s
Socialist Industrial Landscape,” 88–89.
48. Paweł Jagło, “Defense of the Cross,” in Nowa Huta 1949+, 39–40; Lebow,
Unfinished Utopia, 161–69.
49. Paweł Jagło, “Anti-Communist Opposition,” in Nowa Huta 1949+; Stenning,
“Placing (Post-) Socialism,” 105–06; Chicago Tribune, June 10, 1979.
50. Kraków environmentalists often blamed the steel mill for the severe air
pollution in the city, but prevailing winds took emissions from Nowa Huta
eastward, away from the city, not toward it. Local plants, industry west of
Kraków, coal-burning furnaces, and growing traffic were more responsible.
Maria Lempart, “Myths and facts about Nowa Huta,” in Nowa Huta 1949+, 50.
51. Judt, Postwar, 587–89; Stenning, “Placing (Post-)Socialism,” 106; Jagło, “Anti-
Communist Opposition.”
52. The official government-recognized union tacitly supported the 1988 strike,
though with its own, more modest demands. The discussion of Solidarity in
Nowa Huta is drawn primarily from Lebow, Unfinished Utopia, 169–76, and my
interview with Lebiest et al. See also Jagło, “Anti-Communist Opposition”; New
York Times, Nov. 11, 1982, Apr. 29, 1988, May 3, 1988, and May 6, 1988; and
Judt, Postwar, 605–08.
53. Interview with Lebiest et al.
54. “Poland Fights for Gdansk Shipyard,” BBC News, Aug. 21, 2007,
http://news.bbc.co.uk/2/hi/business/6956549.stm; “Gdansk Shipyard Sinking
from Freedom to Failure,” Toronto Star (accessed May 6, 2016),
https://www.thestar.com/news/world/2014/01/27/gdansk_shipyard_sinking_fro
m_freedom_to_failure.html).
55. New York Times, Nov. 27, 1989; interview with Lebiest et al.; Jagło,
“Steelworks,”19–20; Stenning, “Placing (Post-)Socialism,” 108–10, 116.
56. New York Times, Oct. 6, 2015, and Oct. 7, 2015.
57. Harold James, Krupp: A History of the Legendary German Firm (Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press, 2012), 39; Werner Abelshauser, The Dynamics of
German Industry: Germany’s Path toward the New Economy and the American
Challenge (New York: Berghahn Books, 2005), 3, 85–86, 89.
58. Though in some respects the Wolfsburg plant was modeled on River Rouge,
Volkswagen did not integrate backward to make all its parts, instead
purchasing many from a network of closely connected suppliers. Abelshauser,
Dynamics of German Industry, 91–104, 108–09; Volker R. Berghahn, The
Americanization of West German Industry 1945–1973 (Lemington Spa, NY:
Berg, 1986), 304–09.
59. Werner Abelshauser, Wolfgang Von Hippel, Jeffrey Allan Johnson, and
Raymond G. Stokes, German Industry and Global Enterprise; BASF: The
History of a Company (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2004), 487–99
(quote on 488); New York Times, Oct. 27, 2014; “BASF Headquarters”
(accessed May 16, 2016), https://www.basf.com/us/en/company/career/why-
join-basf/basf-at-a-glance/basf-headquarters.html.
60. New York Times, Oct. 6, 2015; Gillian Darley, Factory (London: Reaktion
Books, 2003), 187–89.
61. Joel Beinin, Workers and Peasants in the Modern Middle East (Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press, 2001), 99–113 (“citadels” on 109), 127, 158;
Beinin, “Egyptian Textile Workers Confront the New Economic Order,” Middle
East Research and Information Project, Mar. 25, 2007,
http://www.merip.org/mero/mero032507; Beinin, “The Militancy of Mahalla al-
Kubra,” Middle East Research and Information Project, Sept. 29, 2007,
http://www.merip.org/mero/mero092907; “The Factory,” Al Jazeera, Feb. 22,
2012,
http://www.aljazeera.com/programmes/revolutionthrougharabeyes/2012/01/201
213013135991429.html; “Mahalla textile workers’ strike enters eighth day,”
Daily News Egypt, Feb. 17, 2014,
http://www.dailynewsegypt.com/2014/02/17/mahalla-textile-workers-strike-
enters-eighth-day/; Alex MacDonald and Tom Rollins, “Egypt’s Mahalla textile
factory workers end four-day strike after deal reached,” Middle East Eye, Jan.
17, 2015, http://www.middleeasteye.net/news/egypts-mahalla-textile-factory-
workers-end-four-day-strike-after-management-agreement-260129749.
Chapter 7
“FOXCONN CITY”
1. Pun Ngai, Shen Yuan, Guo Yuhua, Lu Huilin, Jenny Chan, and Mark Selden,
“Apple, Foxconn, and Chinese Workers’ Struggles from a Global Labor
Perspective,” Inter-Asia Cultural Studies 17 (2) (2016), 166; Jason Dean, “The
Forbidden City of Terry Gou,” Wall Street Journal, Aug. 11, 2007. Ngai, Chan,
and Selden have written the most important study of Foxconn and of Apple in
China, Dying for an iPhone, from which I have greatly benefited. It is
forthcoming in English but available in Spanish and Italian editions, Morir por
un iPhone (Bueno Aires: Ediciones Continente S.R.L., 2014) and Moirire per
un iPhone (Milan: Jaca Books, 2015).
2. To offset the wage hikes, Foxconn also raised its prices. New York Times, May
25, 2010, June 2, 2010; Elizabeth Woyke, The Smartphone: Anatomy of an
Industry (New York: New Press, 2014), 135–36; Bloomberg Businessweek,
June 7, 2010, Sept. 13, 2010; “Foxconn’s Business Partners Respond to
Suicides,” CCTV Com English, May 20, 2010,
http://english.cntv.cn/program/china24/20100520/101588.shtml; “Foxconn
Shares Dive on Suicides,” CCTV Com English, June 29, 2010,
http://english.cntv.cn/program/bizasia/20100528/102843.shtml; “Foxconn to
Hike Prices to Offset Pay Increase,” CCTV Com English, July 22, 2010,
http://english.cntv.cn/20100722/104196.shtml; “Foxconn Hikes Salaries Again
in South China Factory After Suicides,” CCTV Com English, Oct. 1, 2010,
http://english.cntv.cn/program/20101001/101698.shtml.
3. Ngai, Chan, and Selden, Dying for an iPhone; Bloomberg Businessweek, Sept.
13, 2010; James Fallows, “Mr. China Comes to America,” The Atlantic, Dec.
2012.
4. For various statements of the number of employees at the Foxconn Shenzhen
factories in 2010, see “Foxconn Hikes Salaries Again in South China Factory
After Suicides,” CCTV Com English, Oct. 1, 2010; Bloomberg Businessweek,
June 7, 2010, Sept. 13, 2010; New York Times, May 25, 2010; Pun Ngai,
Migrant Labor in China: Post-Socialist Transformations (Cambridge: Polity
Press, 2016), 101, 119. See also Charles Duhigg and Keith Bradsher, “How the
U.S. Lost Out on iPhone Work,” New York Times, Jan. 21, 2012
(“unimaginable”).
5. Foxconn factories outside of China are generally much smaller, in some cases
modest-sized assembly plants serving local markets, built to circumvent tariffs.
Some Foxconn factories make parts or finished products for multiple clients,
including Microsoft, IBM, Intel, Cisco, GE, Amazon, HP, Dell, Motorola,
Panasonic, Sony, Toshiba, Nintendo, Samsung, LG, Nokia, Acer, and Lenovo.
Others serve just one client or even make only one product. Ngai, Migrant
Labor, 105; Rutvica Andrijasevic and Devi Sacchetto, “Made in the EU:
Foxconn in the Czech Republic,” WorkingUSA, Sept. 2014; Devi Sacchetto
and Martin Cecchi, “On the Border: Foxconn in Mexico,” openDemocracy, Jan.
16, 2015, https://www.opendemocracy.net/devi-sacchetto-mart%C3%ACn-
cecchi/on-border-foxconn-in-mexico; Ngai, Chan, and Selden, Dying for an
iPhone; New York Times, Mar. 29, 2012; David Barboza, “China’s ‘iPhone City,’
Built on Billions in Perks,” New York Times, Dec. 29, 2016.
6. Ngai, Chan, and Selden, Dying for an iPhone; New York Times, Dec. 11, 2013;
“BBC Documentary Highlights Conditions at a Chinese iPhone Factory, But Is It
All Apple’s Fault?” MacWorld, Dec. 19, 2014,
http://www.macworld.com/article/2861381/bbc-documentary-highlights-
conditions-at-a-chinese-iphone-factory-but-is-it-all-apples-fault.html.
7. Ngai, Migrant Labor, 102; Boy Lüthje, Siqi Luo, and Hao Zhang, Beyond the
Iron Rice Bowl: Regimes of Production and Industrial Relations in China
(Frankfurt: Campus Verlag, 2013), 195, 198; Hao Ren, ed., China on Strike:
Narratives of Workers’ Resistance, English edition edited by Zhongjin Li and Eli
Friedman (Chicago: Haymarket Books, 2016), 11, 201–03; Jennifer Baichwal,
Manufactured Landscapes (Foundry Films and National Film Board of Canada,
2006).
8. David Barboza, “In Roaring China, Sweaters Are West of Socks City,” New
York Times, Dec. 24, 2004; Ngai, Migrant Labor, 102.
9. New York Times, Nov. 8, 1997, Mar. 28, 2000; Nelson Lichtenstein, The Retail
Revolution: How Wal-Mart Created a Brave New World of Business (New York:
Metropolitan Books, 2009), 173; Richard P. Appelbaum, “Giant Transnational
Contractors in East Asia: Emergent Trends in Global Supply Chains,”
Competition & Change 12 (Mar. 2008), 74; “About PCG,”
http://www.pouchen.com/index.php/en/about/locations, and “Yue Yuen
Announces Audited Results for the Year 2015,”
http://www.yueyuen.com/index.php/en/news-pr/1147-2016-03-23-yue-yuen-
announces-audited-results-for-the-year-2015 (both accessed June 3, 2016);
International Trade Union Confederation, 2012 Annual Survey of Violations of
Trade Union Rights—Vietnam, June 6, 2012,
http://www.refworld.org/docid/4fd889193.html.
10. Some ten thousand Soviet technicians were posted to China to help with the
industrialization drive, while nearly three times that many Chinese went to the
Soviet Union for training. Carl Riskin, China’s Political Economy: The Quest for
Development Since 1949 (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1987), 53–63, 74;
Nicholas R. Lardy, “Economic Recovery and the 1st Five-Year Plan,” in
Roderick MacFarquhar and John K. Fairbank, eds., The Cambridge History of
China, vol. 14: The People’s Republic, part 1: The Emergence of Revolutionary
China, 1949–1965 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2008), 157–60,
177–78.
11. Riskin, China’s Political Economy, 64, 117–18, 125–27, 133, 139, 161–65;
Kenneth Lieberthal, “The Great Leap Forward and the Split in the Yenan
Leadership,” in MacFarquhar and Fairbank, eds., The Cambridge History of
China, vol. 14; Stephen Andors, China’s Industrial Revolution: Politics,
Planning, and Management, 1949 to the Present (New York: Pantheon, 1977),
68–134. By the 1990s, Anshan had become China’s largest industrial
enterprise, employing some 220,000 workers. “Anshan Iron and Steel
Corporation,” in Lawrence R. Sullivan, Historical Dictionary of the People’s
Republic of China, second edition (Plymouth, UK: Scarecrow Press, 2007), 24–
26. See, also, Cheng Tsu-yuan, Ashan Steel Factory in Communist China
(Hong Kong: The Urban Research Institute, 1955).
12. Andors, China’s Industrial Revolution, 144–47, 158–59.
13. Andors, China’s Industrial Revolution, 135–42.
14. While there was a push during the Cultural Revolution for the despecialization
of factories, there apparently was not an effort to despecialize the work of
individual workers in the production process, even as they were given
expanded roles in management and other aspects of factory function. Andors,
China’s Industrial Revolution, 160–240.
15. Ngai, Migrant Labor, 11, 15.
16. Henry Yuhuai He, Dictionary of the Political Thought of the People’s Republic
of China (London: Routledge, 2015), 287; Michael J. Enright, Edith E. Scott,
and Ka-mun Chang, Regional Powerhouse: The Greater Pearl River Delta and
the Rise of China (Singapore: John Wiley & Sons, 2005), 6, 36–38.
17. Pun Ngai, Made in China: Women Factory Workers in a Global Workplace
(Durham, NC: Duke University Press, 2005), 1, 7.
18. Gabriel Kolko, Vietnam: Anatomy of a Peace (London: Routledge, 1997); The
World Bank, “Vietnam, Overview,” Apr. 11, 2016,
http://www.worldbank.org/en/country/vietnam/overview; Nguyen Thi Tue Anh,
Luu Minh Duc, and Trinh Doc Chieu, “The Evolution of Vietnamese Industry,”
Learning to Compete Working Paper No. 19, Brookings Institution (accessed
Aug. 13, 2016), https://www.brookings.edu/wp-
content/uploads/2016/07/L2C_WP19_Nguyen-Luu-and-Trinh-1.pdf.
19. Enright, Scott, and Chang, Regional Powerhouse, 6, 12, 16, 36, 38–39, 67–68,
74, 98, 101–02, 117.
20. Enright, Scott, and Chang, Regional Powerhouse, 75, 98, 108; Andrew Ross,
Fast Boat to China: Corporate Flight and the Consequences of Free Trade—
Lessons from Shanghai (New York: Pantheon, 2006), 24–26; Bloomberg
Businessweek, Sept. 13, 2010.
21. Enright, Scott, and Chang, Regional Powerhouse, 47.
22. Ngai, Migrant Labor, 2, 20–21, 25, 32, 76–78.
23. The Guardian, July 31, 2014,
https://www.theguardian.com/world/2014/jul/31/china-reform-hukou-migrant-
workers; Ren, ed., China on Strike, 4-5; Ngai, Made in China, 36, 43–46.
24. For an interesting portrait of life in a state-owned factory during the 1980s, see
Lijoa Zhang, “Socialism Is Great!” A Worker’s Memoir of the New China (New
York: Atlas & Co., 2008). See, also, Ching Kwan Lee, Against the Law: Labor
Protests in China’s Rustbelt and Sunbelt (Berkeley: University of California
Press, 2007), 35–36; Ross, Fast Boat to China, 57.
25. Ngai, Migrant Labor, 35, 93, 128–29; “Workers Strike at China Footwear Plant
Over Welfare Payments,” Wall Street Journal, Apr. 16, 2014,
http://www.wsj.com/articles/SB10001424052702304626304579505451938007
332; Ren, ed., China on Strike, 186.
26. Ngai, Migrant Labor, 31. For an in-depth comparison of systems of
manufacturing in China, see Lüthje, Luo, and Zhang, Beyond the Iron Rice
Bowl.
27. The wages and benefit contributions of export factories in high-cost regions
would not have been enough to support locally-living families and the services
provided to them, the cost of “social reproduction.” Enright, Scott, and Chang,
Regional Powerhouse, 192, 250; Ngai, Migrant Labor, 32–35.
28. Ngai, Migrant Labor, 83–104, 123; Hong Xue, “Local Strategies of Labor
Control: A Case Study of Three Electronics Factories in China,” International
Labor and Working-Class History 73 (Spring 2008), 92; Anita Chen, China’s
Workers Under Assault: The Exploitation of Labor in a Globalizing Economy
(Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe, 2001), 12; Ngai, Chan, and Selden, Dying for an
iPhone; Duhigg and Bradsher, “How the U.S. Lost Out on iPhone Work”; Ren,
ed., China on Strike, 7, 184.
29. For a fine, painful portrait of a migrant worker family and their trips back home,
see the documentary film Last Train Home, directed by Lixin Fan (EyeSteel
Films, 2009). Ngai, Migrant Labor, 30–32; Xue, “Local Strategies of Labor
Control,” 85, 98–99; U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, “The
Employment Situation—May 2014,”
http://www.bls.gov/news.release/archives/empsit_06062014.pdf (accessed July
16, 2016); Michael Bristow, “China’s holiday rush begins early,” BBC News,
Jan. 7, 2009, http://news.bbc.co.uk/2/hi/asia-pacific/7813267.stm; Ross, Fast
Boat to China, 16; New York Times, Jan. 26, 2017.
30. As in China, in Vietnam migrant workers form a large part of the workforce in
foreign-owned factories, especially near Ho Chi Minh City. See Anita Chan,
“Introduction,” in Chan, ed., Labour in Vietnam (Singapore: Institute of
Southeast Asian Studies, 2011), 4.
31. In addition to the Peter Charlesworth photography of workers making Reebok
shoes, see, for example, Dong Hung Group, “Shoe Manufacturers in Vietnam”
(2012), http://www.donghungfootwear.com/en/phong-su-ve-dong-hung-
group.html, which includes factory photographs and a video showing the
processes used for making sneakers. See, also, Tom Vanderbilt, The Sneaker
Book: Anatomy of an Industry and an Icon (New York: New Press, 1998), 78–
80.
32. For EUPA, see the documentary film Factory City (Discovery Channel, 2009).
Ngai, Chan, and Selden, Dying for an iPhone; Dean, “The Forbidden City of
Terry Gou”; Alfred Marshall, Principles of Economics ([1890] London:
Macmillan and Co., Ltd., 1920), 8th ed., IV.XI.7,
http://www.econlib.org/library/Marshall/marP25.html#Bk.IV,Ch.XI (accessed
Sept. 22, 2014); Alfred D. Chandler, Jr., Scale and Scope: The Dynamics of
Industrial Capitalism (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1994), 25.
33. For Appelbaum’s analysis, on which I lean heavily, see Appelbaum, “Giant
Transnational Contractors.”
34. The classic discussion of the importance of the link between manufacturing
and distribution is Alfred D. Chandler, The Visible Hand: The Managerial
Revolution in American Business (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press,
1977). See also, Nelson Lichtenstein, “The Return of Merchant Capitalism,”
International Labor and Working-Class History 81 (2012), 8–27;
http://www.clarksusa.com/us/about-clarks/heritage (accessed July 19, 2016).
35. Joshua B. Freeman, American Empire, 1945–2000: The Rise of a Global
Empire, the Democratic Revolution at Home (New York: Viking, 2012), 343–54.
36. Vanderbilt, Sneaker Book, 8–25, 76–88.
37. Boy Lüthje, “Electronics Contract Manufacturing: Global Production and the
International Division of Labor in the Age of the Internet,” Industry and
Innovation 9 (3) (Dec. 2002), 227–47.
38. There is a large literature on changes in retailing. In addition to Appelbaum,
“Giant Transnational Contractors,” particularly useful works include Charles
Fishman, The Wal-Mart Effect: How the World’s Most Powerful Company
Really Works—and How It’s Transforming the American Economy (New York:
Penguin, 2006); Lichtenstein, The Retail Revolution; and Xue Hong,
“Outsourcing in China: Walmart and Chinese Manufacturers,” in Anita Chan,
ed., Walmart in China (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 2011).
39. For a pioneering critical look at modern branding, see Naomi Klein, No Logo:
Taking Aim at the Brand Bullies (New York: Picador, 1999). Lüthje, “Electronics
Contract Manufacturing,” 230 (Nishimura quote); Marcelo Prince and Willa
Plank, “A Short History of Apple’s Manufacturing in the U.S.,” The Wall Street
Journal, Dec. 6, 2012, http://blogs.wsj.com/digits/2012/12/06/a-short-history-of-
apples-manufacturing-in-the-u-s/; Peter Burrows, “Apple’s Cook Kicks Off
‘Made in USA’ Push with Mac Pro,” Dec. 19, 2013,
http://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2013-12-18/apple-s-cook-kicks-off-
made-in-usa-push-with-mac-pro; G. Clay Whittaker, “Why Trump’s Idea to
Move Apple Product Manufacturing to the U.S. Makes No Sense,” Popular
Science, Jan. 26, 2016, http://www.popsci.com/why-trumps-idea-to-move-
apple-product-manufacturing-to-us-makes-no-sense; Klein, No Logo, 198–99.
40. Vanderbilt, Sneaker Book, 90–99; New York Times, Nov. 8, 1997; Klein, No
Logo, 197–98, 365–79; Donald L. Barlett and James B. Steele, “As Apple
Grew, American Workers Left Behind,” Nov. 16, 2011,
http://americawhatwentwrong.org/story/as-apple-grew-american-workers-left-
behind/; David Pogue, “What Cameras Inside Foxconn Found,” Feb. 23, 2012,
http://pogue.blogs.nytimes.com/2012/02/23/what-cameras-inside-foxconn-
found/.
41. Lüthje, “Electronics Contract Manufacturing,” 231, 234, 236–37; Boy Lüthje,
Stefanie Hürtgen, Peter Pawlicki, and Martina Sproll, From Silicon Valley to
Shenzhen: Global Production and Work in the IT Industry (Lanham, MD:
Rowman & Littlefield, 2013), 69–149; Appelbaum, “Giant Transnational
Contractors,” 71–72.
42. For the container revolution, see Marc Levinson, The Box: How the Shipping
Container Made the World Smaller and the World Economy Bigger (Princeton,
NJ: Princeton University Press, 2006).
43. David Barboza, “In Roaring China, Sweaters Are West of Socks City”; Oliver
Wainwright, “Santa’s Real Workshop: The Town in China That Makes the
World’s Christmas Decorations,” The Guardian, Dec. 19, 2014,
https://www.theguardian.com/artanddesign/architecture-design-
blog/2014/dec/19/santas-real-workshop-the-town-in-china-that-makes-the-
worlds-christmas-decorations.
44. Ngai et al., “Apple, Foxconn, and Chinese Workers’ Struggles,” 169; Wall
Street Journal, July 22, 2014; Adam Starariano and Peter Burrows, “Apple’s
Supply-Chain Secret? Hoard Lasers,” Bloomberg Businessweek, Nov. 3, 2011,
http://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2011-11-03/apples-supply-chain-
secret-hoard-lasers; and Adam Lashinsky, “Apple: The Genius Behind Steve,”
Fortune, Nov. 24, 2008, http://fortune.com/2008/11/24/apple-the-genius-behind-
steve/ (Cook quote).
45. In 2004, Foxconn employed five thousand engineers in Shenzhen alone.
Duhigg and Bradsher, “How the U.S. Lost Out on iPhone Work”; Ngai, Chan,
and Selden, Dying for an iPhone; Lüthje et al., From Silicon Valley to
Shenzhen, 191.
46. Lüthje, Luo, and Zhang, Beyond the Iron Rice Bowl, 188–89; Ngai, Chan, and
Selden, Dying for an iPhone.
47. Ngai, Migrant Labor, 102–03; Xue, “Local Strategies of Labor Control,” 88–89.
48. Lüthje, Luo, and Zhang, Beyond the Iron Rice Bowl, 197;
http://www.yueyuen.com/index.php/en/about-us-6/equipments (accessed Dec.
20, 2016); Dean, “The Forbidden City of Terry Gou”; lecture by Pun Ngai,
Joseph S. Murphy Institute, City University of New York, Feb. 23, 2016.
49. Barboza, “In Roaring China, Sweaters Are West of Socks City”; Lu Zhang,
Inside China’s Automobile Factories: The Politics of Labor and Worker
Resistance (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2015), 8, 23, 60; interview
with Qian Xiaoyan (First Secretary, Embassy of the People’s Republic of China
in the U.S.A.), New York, Apr. 16, 2015; Ngai, Migrant Labor, 115–19. For
Vietnamese government policy, see Nguyen Thi Tue Anh, Luu Minh Duc, and
Trinh Doc Chieu, “The Evolution of Vietnamese Industry,” 14–24.
50. Ngai, Migrant Labor, 66, 72, 78; Ngai, Made in China, 2–3, 55–56, 65–73;
Ren, ed., China on Strike, 96.
51. Ngai, Migrant Labor, 86, 101; Emily Feng, “Skyscrapers’ Rise in China Marks
Fall of Immigrant Enclaves,” New York Times, July 19, 2016; Ross, Fast Boat
to China, 164–65; Richard Appelbaum and Nelson Lichtenstein, “A New World
of Retail Supremacy: Supply Chains and Workers’ Chains in the Age of Wal-
Mart,” International Labor and Working-Class History 70 (2006), 109.
52. Ngai, Chan, and Selden, Dying for an iPhone; Ren, ed., China on Strike, 97.
53. Ngai, Made in China, 32; Ren, ed., China on Strike, 5–9, 27.
54. Ngai, Migrant Labor, 120–23, 128–29; Ngai et al., “Apple, Foxconn, and
Chinese Workers’ Struggles,” 174; Duhigg and Bradsher, “How the U.S. Lost
Out on iPhone Work”; Wall Street Journal, Dec. 18, 2012. See also Lüthje et
al., From Silicon Valley to Shenzhen, 184–87.
55. Charles Duhigg and David Barboza, “The iEconomy; In China, the Human
Costs That Are Built Into an iPad,” New York Times, Jan. 26, 2012; Ngai, Chan,
and Selden, Dying for an iPhone; Ren, ed., China on Strike, 7, 184; Xue, “Local
Strategies of Labor Control,” 89, 92. For comparison, see William Dodd, A
Narrative of the Experience and Sufferings of William Dodd, A Factory Cripple,
Written by Himself, reprinted in James R. Simmons, Jr., ed., Factory Lives:
Four Nineteenth-Century Working-Class Autobiographies (Peterborough, ON:
Broadview Editions, 2007).
56. Chen, China’s Workers Under Assault, 10, 12, 23, 46–81; Xue, “Local
Strategies of Labor Control,” 91–92; Ngai et al., “Apple, Foxconn, and Chinese
Workers’ Struggles,” 172–74; Karl Marx, Capital: A Critique of Political
Economy, vol. 1 ([1867] New York: International Publishers, 1967), 424; Jee
Young Kim, “How Does Enterprise Ownership Matter? Labour Conditions in
Fashion and Footwear Factories in Southern Vietnam,” in Chan, ed., Labour in
Vietnam, 288; Ngai, Made in China, 80, 97.
57. “The poetry and brief life of a Foxconn worker: Xu Lizhi (1990–2014)”
(accessed Aug. 4, 2016), libcom.org, https://libcom.org/blog/xulizhi-foxconn-
suicide-poetry.
58. Serious as these problems are, large plants generally have better health and
safety equipment and records than smaller parts suppliers with fewer
resources and less subject to international scrutiny. Under pressure from Nike,
conditions in the factory in Vietnam were improved and more use was made of
less toxic water-based solvents. New York Times, Nov. 8, 1997, Apr. 28, 2000;
Chen, China’s Workers Under Assault, 82–97; Duhigg and Barboza, “The
iEconomy”; Ngai, Chan, and Selden, Dying for an iPhone; Lüthje et al., From
Silicon Valley to Shenzhen, 187.
59. Some Chinese factories consciously mix workers from different regions on
production lines, to undercut worker solidarity. Others, usually smaller, recruit
workers from particular regions or even villages, so that hometown bonds
extend into the workplace and dormitories. Ngai, Chan, and Selden, Dying for
an iPhone; Ngai, Migrant Labor, 129–30; Lüthje et al., From Silicon Valley to
Shenzhen, 190; Xue, “Local Strategies of Labor Control,” 93, 97–98.
60. Bloomberg Businessweek, Sept. 13, 2010; Duhigg and Bradsher, “How the
U.S. Lost Out on iPhone Work”; Lüthje, Luo, and Zhang, Beyond the Iron Rice
Bowl, 187; Ren, ed., China on Strike, 201–03; Ngai, Migrant Labor, 119, 130;
Fallows, “Mr. China Comes to America,” 62. See also Factory City.
61. Unlike in China, the reduction of poverty in Vietnam has not been
accompanied by a large increase in inequality. World Bank, [China] “Overview,”
http://www.worldbank.org/en/country/china/overview#3; World Bank, “China”
[Data], http://data.worldbank.org/country/china; and World Bank, [Vietnam]
“Overview,” http://www.worldbank.org/en/country/vietnam/overview, all
accessed Dec. 2, 2016. Chinese strike data derived from Chinese Labour
Bulletin “Strike Map,” http://maps.clb.org.hk/strikes/en; U.S. data from United
States Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, “Work stoppages
involving 1,000 or more workers, 1947–2015,”
http://www.bls.gov/news.release/wkstp.t01.htm (both accessed Aug. 16, 2016).
62. For overviews of strikes in China, see Ren, ed., China on Strike; Lee, Against
the Law; James Griffiths, “China on Strike,” CNN.com, Mar. 29, 2016,
http://www.cnn.com/2016/03/28/asia/china-strike-worker-protest-trade-union/;
and China Labour Bulletin’s extraordinary interactive “Strike Map.” See also
New York Daily News, Jan. 11, 2012; Ngai, Chan, and Selden, Dying for an
iPhone; Duhigg and Barboza, “The iEconomy.”
63. The Vietnamese government is generally more supportive of worker strikes
against foreign companies than the Chinese government and has less often
used repressive power against them. Benedict J. Tria Kerkvliet, “Workers’
Protests in Contemporary Vietnam” and Anita Chan, “Strikes in Vietnam and
China in Taiwanese-owned Factories: Diverging Industrial Relations Patterns,”
in Chan, ed., Labour in Vietnam; “10,000 Strike at Vietnamese Shoe Factory,
USA Today, Nov. 29, 2007, http://usatoday30.usatoday.com/news/world/2007-
11-29-vietnam-shoe-strike_N.htm; “Workers Strike at Nike Contract Factory,”
USA Today, Apr. 1, 2008,
http://usatoday30.usatoday.com/money/economy/2008-04-01-
1640969273_x.htm; “Shoe Workers Strike in the Thousands,” Thanh Nien
Daily, http://www.thanhniennews.com/society/shoe-workers-strike-in-the-
thousands-16949.html; “Vietnamese workers extract concessions in
unprecedented strike,” DW, Feb. 4, 2015, http://www.dw.com/en/vietnamese-
workers-extract-concessions-in-unprecedented-strike/a-18358432 (all
accessed Aug. 8, 2016); International Trade Union Confederation, 2012 Annual
Survey of Violations of Trade Union Rights—Vietnam; Kaxton Siu and Anita
Chan, “Strike Wave in Vietnam, 2006–2011,” Journal of Contemporary Asia,
45:1 (2015), 71–91; New York Times, May 14, 2014; Wall Street Journal, May
16, 2014, June 19, 2014.
64. Both the shrinking rural population and the gender imbalance stem in part from
China’s one-child policy. Ngai, Chan, and Selden, Dying for an iPhone; “Urban
and rural population of China from 2004 to 2014,” Statista (accessed Aug. 16,
2016), http://www.statista.com/statistics/278566/urban-and-rural-population-of-
china/; Ren, ed., China on Strike, 21–23; Ngai, Migrant Labor, 35, 114.
65. Bruce Einhorn and Tim Culpan, “Foxconn: How to Beat the High Cost of
Happy Workers,” Bloomberg Businessweek, May 5, 2011,
http://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2011-05-05/foxconn-how-to-beat-the-
high-cost-of-happy-workers; Ngai, Migrant Labor, 114–15; Xue, “Local
Strategies of Labor Control,” 96; Chen, China’s Workers Under Assault, 9.
66. Zhang, Inside China’s Automobile Factories, 57–59; Ngai, Migrant Labor, 117–
18; Ngai, Chan, and Selden, Dying for an iPhone.
67. For films dealing with Chinese factories and migrant workers, see Elena
Pollacchi, “Wang Bing’s Cinema: Shared Spaces of Labor,” WorkingUSA 17
(Mar. 2014); Xiaodan Zhang, “A Path to Modernization: A Review of
Documentaries on Migration and Migrant Labor in China,” International Labor
and Working-Class History 77 (Spring 2010).
68. For the factory as a sales tool, see Gillian Darley, Factory (London: Reaktion
Books, 2003), 157–89. In China, EUPA seems something of an exception,
allowing filmmakers and photographers to document its factory. For examples
of tightly controlled tours, see James Fallows, “Mr. China Comes to America,”
and Dawn Chmielewski, “Where AppleProducts Are Born: A Rare Glimpse
Inside Foxconn’s Factory Gates,” Apr. 6, 2015,
http://www.recode.net/2015/4/6/11561130/where-apple-products-are-born-a-
rare-glimpse-inside-foxconns-factory.
69. Bloomberg Businessweek, Sept. 13, 2010; Xing Rung, New China Architecture
(Singapore: Periplus Editions, 2006); Layla Dawson, China’s New Dawn: An
Architectural Transformation (Munich: Prestel Verlag, 2005).
70. Neil Gough, “China’s Fading Factories,” New York Times, Jan. 20, 2016; Feng,
“Skyscrapers’ Rise in China Marks Fall of Immigrant Enclaves”; Mark Magnier,
“China’s Manufacturing Strategy,” Wall Street Journal, June 8, 2016.
71. For example, compare two collections of images by the pioneer American
photographer Lewis W. Hine: Hine, Men at Work: Photographic Studies of
Modern Men and Machines ([1932] New York: Dover, 1977), and Jonathan L.
Doherty, ed., Women at Work: 153 Photographs by Lewis W. Hine (New York:
Dover, 1981). Of course, gender patterns have varied over time and place, with
more women working in heavy industry in communist countries than capitalist
ones and gender imbalances diminishing over time.
72. Countless examples can be seen by doing a Google search for images of
Chinese factories.
73. For Burtynsky, see
http://www.edwardburtynsky.com/site_contents/Photographs/China.html
(accessed Dec. 2, 2016); for Gursky, see, for example, Marie Luise Syring,
Andreas Gursky: Photographs from 1984 to the Present (New York: TeNeues,
2000).
Conclusion
1. Kenneth E. Hendrickson III, ed., The Encyclopedia of the Industrial Revolution
in World History, vol. III, 3rd ed. (Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield, 2014),
568; R. S. Fitton, The Arkwrights: Spinners of Fortune ([1989] Matlock, UK:
Derwent Valley Mills Educational Trust, 2012), 228–29; Timothy J. Minchin,
Empty Mills: The Fight Against Imports and the Decline of the U.S. Textile
Industry (Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield Publishers, 2013), 31; Tamara K.
Hareven and Randolph Lanenbach, Amoskeag: Life and Work in an American
Factory City (New York: Pantheon Books, 1978), 10–11; Gray Fitzsimons,
“Cambria Iron Company,” Historic American Engineering Record, National Park
Service, Department of the Interior, Washington, D.C., 1989; William Serrin,
Homestead: The Glory and Tragedy of an American Steel Town (New York:
Random House, 1992).
2. Lindsay-Jean Hard, “The Rouge: Yesterday, Today & Tomorrow,” Urban and
Regional Planning Economic Development Handbook, University of Michigan,
Taubman College of Architecture and Urban Planning, Dec. 4, 2005,
http://www.umich.edu/~econdev/riverrouge/; Perry Stern, “Best Selling Vehicles
in America—September Edition,” Sept. 2, 2016, http://www.msn.com/en-
us/autos/autos-passenger/best-selling-vehicles-in-america-%E2%80%94-
september-edition/ss-AAiquE5#image=21.
3. Laurence Gross, The Course of Industrial Decline: The Boott Cotton Mills of
Lowell, Mass., 1835–1955 (Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press,
1993), 44–45, 102–03, 229, 238–40.
4. Jefferson Cowie and Joseph Heathcott, “The Meanings of Deindustrialization,”
in Cowie and Heathcott, eds., Beyond the Ruins: The Meanings of
Deindustrialization (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 2003), 4. There is a
large literature on deindustrialization. In addition to this volume, see the cluster
of articles on “Crumbling Cultures: Deindustrialization, Class, and Memory,” ed.
Tim Strangleman, James Rhodes, and Sherry Linkon, in International Labor
and Working-Class History 84 (Oct. 2013).
5. Paul Wiseman, “Why Robots, Not Trade, Are Behind So Many Factory Job
Losses,” AP: The Big Story, Nov. 2, 2016,
http://bigstory.ap.org/article/265cd8fb02fb44a69cf0eaa2063e11d9/mexico-
taking-us-factory-jobs-blame-robots-instead; Mandy Zuo, “Rise of the Robots:
60,000 Workers Culled from Just One Factory as China’s Struggling
Electronics Hub Turns to Artificial Intelligence,” South China Morning Post, May
22, 2016, http://www.scmp.com/news/china/economy/article/1949918/rise-
robots-60000-workers-culled-just-one-factory-chinas. See also Wall Street
Journal, Aug. 17, 2016.
6. Rich Appelbaum and Nelson Lichtenstein, “An Accident in History,” New Labor
Forum 23 (3) (2014), 58–65; Ellen Barry, “Rural Reality Meets Bangalore
Dreams,” New York Times, Sept. 25, 2016.
7. Kevin Hamlin, Ilya Gridneff, and William Davison, “Ethiopia Becomes China’s
China in Global Search for Cheap Labor,” Bloomberg, July 22, 2014,
https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2014-07-22/ethiopia-becomes-china-
s-china-in-search-for-cheap-labor; Lily Kuo, “Ivanka Trump’s Shoe Collection
May Be Moving from ‘Made in China’ to ‘Made in Ethiopia,’” Quartz Africa, Oct.
8, 2016, http://qz.com/803626/ivanka-trumps-shoe-collection-may-be-moving-
from-made-in-china-to-made-in-ethiopia/; Chris Summers, “Inside a Trump
Chinese Shoe Factory,” Daily Mail.com, Oct. 6, 2016,
http://www.dailymail.co.uk/news/article-3824617/Trump-factory-jobs-sent-
China-never-come-back.html.
8. For variations of the factory under different social systems, see Michael
Burawoy, The Politics of Production: Factory Regimes Under Capitalism and
Socialism (London: Verso, 1985), and Dipesh Chakrabarty, Rethinking Working
Class History: Bengal, 1890–1940 (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press,
1989).
9. The documentary film After the Factory (Topografie Association, 2012),
comparing efforts in Lodz, Poland, and Detroit at postindustrial reinvention,
suggests the possibilities and limitations of such strategies.
10. 4-traders: “Hon Hai Precision Industry Co., Ltd.,” http://www.4-
traders.com/HON-HAI-PRECISION-INDUSTR-6492357/company/, and
“Pegatron Corporation,” http://www.4-traders.com/PEGATRON-
CORPORATION-6500975/company/, both accessed July 5, 2016, and “Yue
Yuen Industrial (Holdings) Ltd.,” accessed Jan. 1, 2017; “Fast Facts About
Vanguard” (accessed Jan. 3, 2017), https://about.vanguard.com/who-we-
are/fast-facts/; Calvert Social Investment Fund, “Annual Report,” Sept. 30,
2016, 4, 7.
Illustration Credits
Page numbers listed correspond to the print edition of this book. You can use your
device’s search function to locate particular terms in the text.
absentee ownership, 56
absenteeism, 129, 225
AC Spark Plug, 144
ACW (Amalgamated Clothing Workers), 178–79
Addis Ababa, Ethiopia, 318
Adidas, 292–95, 307, 309
Adler, Philip, 169–70
AFL (American Federation of Labor), 113–14, 129
African Americans, 5, 59, 104, 110, 114, 116, 157, 357n, 380n
Agnelli, Giovanni, 136
aircraft industry, 229–32, 230, 238, 328n, 381n
Akron, Ohio, 128, 161, 163–64, 235–36
Alabama, 110, 235–36
Alexander Smith carpets, 239
All Saints’ Church (Derby, England), 1
Allegheny County, Pennsylvania, 110
Allentown, Pennsylvania, 240
All-Russia Metal Workers’ Union, 177
Almy and Brown, 45–46
Alpert, Max, 212, 214
Althrop, Lord, 32
Amalgamated Association of Iron and Steel Workers, 99–103, 355n
Amalgamated Clothing Workers (ACW), 178–79
American Communist Party, 114, 145
American Federation of Labor (AFL), 113–14, 129
American Landscape (Sheeler), 152–53
American Legion, 238
American Machinist (trade journal), 144
American Notes (Dickens), 64
American Pastoral (Roth), xvi
American Steel Foundries Company, 228
American Woolen Company, 76
“Americanism and Fordism” (Gramsci), 132
Amertorp Corporation, 228–29
Amoskeag Manufacturing Company, 57–58, 76–77, 78, 79, 150, 153, 314, 345n,
349n
Amtorg, 187–90, 194, 221
Anshan Iron and Steel Company, 277–78
antitrust suits, 113, 357n
Apollinaire, Guillaume, 86–87
Apollo Iron and Steel Company, 104
Appelbaum, Richard P., 290, 300
Apple, xii, 270–71, 273, 289–90, 293–97, 308–9, 322
Appleton, Nathan, 49
Appleton Company, 53
Appliance Park (General Electric), 238, 243–44
Arab Spring, 269
ArcelorMittal, 265
architecture and design
boardinghouse model, 54, 55
building length and width, 51–52
in China, 310–11
collapse of factories, 76–77, 349n
early British textile mills, 14–17
in Eastern Europe, 251, 253–56
elevators, 16–17
fires and fire danger, 15, 17, 52, 76–77, 349n
iron, 15, 52
Kahn and modern industrial design, 133–37, 139–40
lighting, 15, 20–21, 52, 139–40
New England textile mills, 48–49
reinforced concrete, 133, 135, 139
roof monitors, 139–40
sawtooth roofs, 15, 134, 140
single-story factories, 139
steam power, 16
steel frames, 139
Arens, Egmont, 172, 369n
Arkwright, Richard, 7–9, 8, 13–15, 17, 35–36, 45, 314, 334n
armor and armaments industry, 93–95, 120, 123, 176, 223–24, 228–33, 369n
art and artists, xii
depictions of Chinese industry, 273, 288, 303, 310, 312
depictions of Cold War mass production, 233, 244, 256–57
depictions of Eiffel Tower, 86–87
depictions of Fordism and industry, 77, 102–3, 119, 136, 145, 148–61, 157, 366n
depictions of iron and steel industry, 96, 97
depictions of Soviet industry, 170, 170, 210–18
Arthur G. McKee & Company, 202
Asheboro, North Carolina, 240
assembly line, 118, 124–27, 125, 144–45, 182, 196–98
Atlanta, Georgia, 85–86, 164
Austin, James Trecothick, 84
Austin Company, 191–92, 221, 373n
automation and mechanization
cotton industry, 7, 9
downsizing and, 242–43, 317–18
Fordism, 118, 124–27, 125, 144–45, 182, 242–43, 297
textile industry, 50
automotive industry. See also names of specific automotive manufacturers
artistic depictions of, 155–58
in China, 298
conversion for military production, 229–31
in Germany, 265–67, 388n
increase in number of giant factories, 127–28, 143–44
innovative factory architecture, 133, 136–37, 140
number of workers, 143–44, 245
product standardization, 141–42
protests and strikes, 161–66
in Soviet Union, 171, 190–93, 199–200, 205
trade unions and labor organization, 129, 162–68
Autostadt (Volkswagen), 267
Avtograd, Soviet Union, 248, 385n
AvtoVaz, 248
Awful Battle at Homestead, Pa, An (illustration), 102
Cadillac, 290
Calder, John K., 188, 196
calico industry, 5, 11, 51–52, 60, 345n
California, 232–33, 235, 237, 368n
Calvert Investments, 322
Cambodia, 274, 281
Cambria Iron and Steel Works, 91, 91, 93, 314
Camden, New Jersey, 166, 236
Cameron, Ardis, 76
Canada, 76, 363n
Capital (Marx), 19, 33–34, 94
capitalism
as atavistic slogan, 227
convergence theory and, 227, 316
early British textile mills and criticism of, 33–35
emergence of industrial capitalism, 33–35
factories as essential to development of, 319
implantation of by outside merchant capital, 56
iron and steel industry “super-capitalism,” 103–5
socialism vs., 172–73, 175–76, 224–25, 278
carding, 6–7, 18, 24, 45, 341n
Carding, Drawing, and Roving (illustration), 24
Carlyle, Thomas, 31
Carnegie, Andrew, 93–94, 100–101, 105, 111–12
Carrefour, 293
Carriage, Wagon, and Automobile Workers’ Union, 129
Castro, Fidel, 256
Cayenne, French Guiana, 46
Céline, Louis-Ferdinand, 147
Cement (Gladkov), 217, 373n
cement industry, 138, 217, 249
Cendrars, Blaise, 87
Centennial Exhibition (1876), 80–82, 81, 84, 88, 107, 350n
“Centennial Inauguration March” (Wagner), 80
Central Labor Institute, 177, 371n
Chadwick, Edwin, 333n
Chagall, Marc, 86
Chamberlin, William Henry, 215
Chandler, Alfred D., Jr., 290
Chaplin, Charlie, xii, 159–61, 209, 214
Charles River, 48–49
Chartists and Chartism, 38, 41, 88
Chase, Stuart, 215
Chelmsford, Massachusetts, 54
Chelyabinsk, Soviet Union, 196, 201, 203, 212, 221, 224, 374n, 379n
Chengdu, China, 272, 302, 304, 306
Chevalier, Michael, 43–44
Chevrolet, 144, 165, 237, 290, 314
Chiang Kai-shek, 283
Chicago, Illinois, 106, 128, 167, 228–29
post-WWII strikes, 238
world’s fairs, 85, 145, 158
WWI-era labor movement, 114–17
Chicago Century of Progress Exposition (1933–34), 145, 158
Chicago Federation of Labor, 114
Chicopee Falls, Massachusetts, 55, 62, 72
child labor, 19, 42, 348n
early British textile mills, 3, 21–25
efforts to regulate, 30–33, 41, 68
New England textile mills, 45–46, 59–60, 68, 71, 74, 77, 78, 347n, 349n
outsourcing, 294
China Labour Bulletin, 306
Chinese industry. See also names of specific locations
architecture and design, 310–11
changes leading to giantism, 274
company housing and villages, 278, 285–87, 300, 304–5
compensation and wages, 271, 286, 301
Cultural Revolution, 279–80, 391n
dagongmei or dagongzai, 286
debate over economic policies and industrial practices, 278–80, 391n
decline of giant factories, 317
decollectivization of agriculture, 284
discipline, 285, 301–3
excitement of, 301
export-oriented manufacturing, 281–86, 288, 392n
Five-Year Plans, 275, 277
foreign investment and manufacturing, 282–83
gender and rural/urban imbalances, 308, 397n
government support for giantism, 298–99
Great Leap Forward, 275–79
hukou system of residency permits, 284–85
interns, 308–9
involvement of Soviet Union, 275, 390n
iron and steel industry, 277–78
leftist approach to industrial management, 277–78
legacy of giantism, 320
Maoist era, 274–80
market-oriented policies, 280–83
mass production as passing stage, 311
migrant labor, 294–301, 305, 308
number of workers, 272–73, 287
percentage of workers in manufacturing, xiii
poverty and life expectancy, 305–6
protests and strikes, 302, 306–8
recruitment, 286–87, 308, 396n
safety issues, 304
secretiveness, 272, 289, 309–10
shutting down giant factories, 316
size and scale of, 272–74, 288–90, 296–98, 300
small-scale rural industry, 276
social status, 285–86, 392n
special economic zones, 281
Spring Festival holiday week, 287–88
symbolism of factories, 310–13
turnover, 285
women, 286–87, 308, 311
worker input over management, 276
worker suicides and company reaction, xii, 270–72, 389n
working conditions, 301–4
working day and hours, 302
Christian Community of Working People, 261
Christian Science Monitor (newspaper), 215
Christmas decorations and accessories, 295
Chrysler Corporation, 140, 143, 145, 163, 166, 243, 290
Chrysler Tank Arsenal, 228
Chukovskaya, Lydia, 211
Church Street El (Sheeler), 151
Chutex Garment Factory, 307
Cincinnati, Ohio, 229
Cisco, 292
Citroen, André, 363n
Ciudad Juárez, Mexico, 382n
Civil War, 75, 120
Clarks shoes, 290
class. See social status and class
Classic Landscape (Sheeler), 152–53
Cleveland, Ohio, 116, 149, 163–64, 238, 242
Coburn, Alvin Langdon, 149
Cold War mass production
in Eastern Europe
decentralization and downsizing, 264–65
factory construction, 253–54, 257
model industrial cities, 249–57
Nowa Huta steelworks, 249, 251–65, 253, 255, 387n
politicized working class, 257–64
shrinkage of workforce, 264–65
urbanism, 250–51, 254
valorization of industry and workers, 249–50
in Egypt, 268–69
in Germany, 265–67
legacy of giant factories, 320
in Soviet Union
automotive industry, 246–48
convergence theory, 226–27
post-WWII reconstruction, 245–46
scientific and atomic cities, 246
tractor industry, 246
Western assistance, 247
in United States
convergence theory, 226–27
decentralization and downsizing, 227–28, 235–44, 382n
loss of interest in industrial workers, 244–45
military giantism, 228–33
post-WWII sale of plants, 238
productivity increases, 243
shrinkage of workforce, 240–41, 243–45
trade unions and labor organization, 233–42
Colt, Samuel, 123
Columbian Exposition (1893), 85
Coming of Post-Industrial Society, The (Bell), 244–45
Committee for Industrial Organization (CIO), 163–68
Commons, John L., 112
Communist Manifesto, The (Marx and Engels), 42
company housing and villages
boardinghouse model, 54, 55, 61–62, 65–66, 74–75
in China, 278, 285–87, 300, 304–5
Eastern European model industrial cities, 249–51, 253–56
iron and steel industry, 103–6
in Soviet Union, 192–93, 208–10, 246, 248, 373n, 385n
company housing and villages (continued)
textile industry, 18, 20, 53–54, 61–62, 65–66, 74–75, 334n
WWII era, 230–32
company stores, 18, 46
compensation and wages, xv
in China, 271, 286, 301
company store credit, 46
currency shortages, 18, 46
downward pressure on wages and living standards, 37
Ford Motor Company, 129–30, 132, 145–46
piecework, 6, 65, 108, 176, 178–79, 371n
post-WWII, 234
productivity vs., 65–66
raising after bad publicity, 271, 389n
reductions in, 65–66, 99–100, 163
sliding scale, 90, 100
truck, 18, 36
Waltham-Lowell system, 60
withholding, 308, 335n
women and children, 23
Condition of the Working Class in England, The (Engels), 29–30, 41, 112, 337n
Connecticut, 46, 68, 240, 347n
Cook, Tim, 296
Cooper, Hugh L., 186
cooperatives, 10, 179, 224
Corliss engines, 80, 81, 350n
Corn Laws, 31–32, 41
Cotton Factories, Union Street, Manchester (engraving), 28
cotton gin, 5
cotton industry, 4–8
age of workers, 23
architecture and construction of mills, 14–17
early American, 45–46
in Egypt, 268
England compared to New England, 43–44
environmental damage from, 27–28
fire danger, 15, 17
first giant factories, 7–10
import substitution, 5
limit of plant size, 13
living conditions, 29–30
machine wrecking, 35
Marx’s Capital and, 34
mechanization of, 7, 9
radical change in, 6–7
renting space and power to multiple employers, 10
rising demand for goods, 4–5, 46
slavery and, 5
technical demands of, 5–6
theories behind adoption of factory model, 10–13
working conditions, 23–27, 30–32
Cotton States and International Exposition (1895), 85–86
Council for Mutual Economic Assistance, 252
Couzens, James, 359n
Cowie, Jefferson, 316–17
Coxe, Tench, 82
Criss-Crossed Conveyors—Ford Plant, 1927 (Sheeler), 152
Crockett, Davy, 68–69
Cromford, England, 7–8, 13–15, 17, 23, 36, 314, 333n–34n
Crompton, Samuel, 7
croppers, 36–37
Crystal Palace Exhibition (1851), 84–85, 88, 93, 134, 291
Cuba, 161
Curtis-Wright Corporation, 229
Czechoslovakia, 249, 385n
H&M, 318
Habermas, Jürgen, xvii
Hamilton, Alexander, xii, 82
Hamilton Manufacturing Company, 53, 61, 63, 74
Hamtramck, Michigan, 143
Hard Times (Dickens), 16, 21
Hargreaves, James, 7, 35–36
Harney, G. Julian, 88
Harrison, New Jersey, 106
Hawthorne, Nathaniel, 95–96
Hayek, Friedrich von, 226–27
Heathcott, Joseph, 316–17
hemp industry, 4
Henry Ford Hospital (Kahlo), 159
Herman, Victor, 375n
Hewlett-Packard, 270, 295
Highland Park factory (Ford), 125, 127–28, 133–38, 136, 141, 143, 145, 159, 167–
68, 363n
Hillman, Sidney, 114, 178–79
Hindus, Maurice, 186–87
Hine, Lewis, 77, 78, 150–51, 153
History of the Cotton Manufacture in Great Britain (Baines), 5–6
Hitler, Adolf, 266
Ho Chi Minh City, Vietnam, 289, 307
Hobsbawm, Eric, 38
Hollingsworth, Edward, 36
Hollywood, California, 237
Holyoke, Massachusetts, 55
Home Depot, 293
Homestead, Pennsylvania, 93–94, 100–103, 102, 105, 110, 245, 314, 357n
Hon Hai Precision Industry Co., 270, 321. See also Foxconn
Honey, Frank, 197–98
Hong Kong, 282–83, 295
Hopper, Edward, 154
hours. See working day and hours
housing. See company housing and villages
Huafang Group, 273
Huajian Shoes, 318
Hudson Motor Company, 137
Hudson River, 83
Hunan, China, 300–301
Hungary, 249, 257–60, 387n
Huxley, Aldous, 147
Jackson, Andrew, 69
Jagiellonian University, 261
James, C. L. R., 380n
Japan, 283, 302, 307, 310
Jefferson, Thomas, 69
jennies, 7, 9, 20
Jobs, Steve, 271, 296
Johnstown, Pennsylvania, 91, 91, 235, 245, 314
joint stockholder corporations, 47–48, 50–52
Jones and Laughlin, 92–93
Journey to the End of the Night (Céline), 147
Joy, Henry B., 133, 137
Judt, Tony, 40
Ma Wen-jui, 278–79
Macao, 282–83
Mack Avenue plant (Ford), 133
Magnavox-Capehart, 163
magnetos, 124, 125
Magnitogorsk, Soviet Union, xiii, 171, 185, 201–5, 207, 209–10, 212, 214–17, 224,
246, 314
Magnitogorsk Metallurgical Complex. See Magnitogorsk, Soviet Union
Magnitogorsk Mining and Metallurgical Institute, 207
Mahalla el-Kubra, Egypt, 268–69
Maiak plutonium plant (Ozersk, Soviet Union), 246
Maine, 55, 81
Makarewicz, Henryk, 253, 255
Making Bessemer Steel at Pittsburgh (illustration), 97
Malaysia, 295, 307
Man of Marble (film), 257
Managerial Revolution, The (Burnham), 226
Manchester, England, 3, 8, 10
compared to Lowell, 43–44, 62
Engels and, 34, 88, 337n–38n
entertainment, 22
pollution, 16, 27, 28
population increases and poverty, 29–30
protests, 39
railroad, 40
renting space and power to multiple employers, 10
scale of mills, 21
working conditions, 26, 31
Manchester, New Hampshire, 55, 58, 62, 68, 76
Manchester Operative (newspaper), 70
Manufactured Landscapes (film), 273, 288
Mao Zedong, xii, 277–79, 284
Marcuse, Herbert, 227, 244
Marion, Indiana, 237
market proximity, 236, 241
Marquis, S. S., 131
Marshall, Alfred, 11–12, 290
Martin, Glenn L., 231–32
Martin, Samuel, 27
Marx, Karl, 5, 21, 30, 33–34, 37, 88, 123, 303, 337n–38n
Marx, Leo, 153
Maryland, 231–32. See also Sparrows Point, Maryland
Massachusetts, 46, 133, 347n. See also names of specific locations
Massachusetts Charitable Mechanic Association, 84
Masses, The (journal), 145
Maupassant, Guy de, 87
May, Ernst, 210
McClintic-Marshall Products Company, 169
McClure’s Magazine, 103
McCormick, Cyrus, 106
McCormick Harvesting Machine Company, 106, 290
McKees Rocks, Pennsylvania, 110–11, 113
McKenney, Ruth, 162
meatpacking industry, 114, 121, 127, 234
mechanization. See automation and mechanization
Méliès, George, 86
Melnikova-Raich, Sonia, 194–95
Melville, Herman, xii, 72
Memphis, Tennessee, 236, 382n
Men and Steel (Vorse), 98
Mercury, 242
Merrimack Manufacturing Company, 51, 56, 65, 314, 343n, 345n
Merrimack mills. See Lowell, Massachusetts
Merrimack Mills and Boarding Houses (engraving), 55
Merrimack River, 51, 55, 57–58
Metzgar, Jack, 235
Mexico, 274, 294, 382n
Michigan. See Ford Motor Company and Fordism; names of specific locations
Middle River, Maryland, 231–32
Middlesex Company, 61
Midvale Steel Works, 107
Milan, Italy, 135
Miller, Hugh, 27
Mills, C. Wright, 227, 244
Milton (Blake), 28
mining, 16, 28, 32, 39, 41–42, 115, 194, 201, 333n
Misr Spinning and Weaving Company, 268–69
Mississippi River, 83
Missouri, 85, 229
Model A, 141–42, 144–45, 151, 191
Model T, 118, 122–27, 138, 141–42, 144–45, 147, 174, 181, 317
Modern Times (film), 159–61, 209
modernity and progress
American view of mechanical progress as integral to, 82–85
Chinese vision of, 281, 311, 313
Eastern European model industrial cities, 251
Eiffel Tower as symbol of, 86–87
factories as producers of, 319, 321
factories as symbols of, xiii–xvii, 5, 20–21, 31, 40–41
iron and steel industry as symbol of, 97–98
life cycle of factories, 315
railroads as symbols of, 40, 83–84
slavery and, 5
Soviet vision of, 171, 184, 205–6, 210, 213
steam power as symbol of, 82–84
Monchique, Portugal, 21
Monongahela River, 101
Monroe, James, 69
Montour Iron Works, 91
Moody, Paul, 47, 49
Morgan, J. P., 105, 112
Moscow, Soviet Union, 190–91, 194–95
Mubarak, Hosni, 269
Muncie, Indiana, 237
Murphy, Frank, 165
Murphy, Gerald, 154
Murray, Philip, 234
Muscle Shoals, Tennessee, 186
Museum of Modern Art, 152
My Life and Work (Ford), 174, 180
Myanmar, 274
Oastler, Richard, 26
O’Hare, Kate Richards, 145–46
Ohio. See names of specific locations
oil industry, 277–78, 290
Olds Motor Works, 123
Olmsted, Frederick Law, 104–5
Omaha, Nebraska, 85
On the Economy of Machinery and Manufacturers (Babbage), 10–11
O’Neill, Eugene, 150
organzine industry, 2–3
Orjonikidje, Sergo, 198, 200, 220
Otis Elevator, 239
Otis Steel, 149–50
Ottoman Empire, 5, 329n
outsourcing, 291–96
Overman, Frederick, 89
Owen, Robert, 24, 26
Ozersk, Soviet Union, 246
Packard Motor Company, 133, 137, 362n
painting, 86, 148, 151–59, 157, 366n
Palace of the Soviets (Moscow, Soviet Union), 230
Panama-Pacific International Exposition (1915), 144–45
panopticon, 17
paper industry, 72
“Paradise of Bachelors and the Tartarus of Maids, The” (Melville), 72
Paris, France, 85–88, 100
Parsons, Talcott, 227
Partisan Review (magazine), 161
patents and patent royalties, 3, 7, 9, 54, 190, 343n, 346n
Pawtucket, Rhode Island, 45, 66
Pawtucket Falls, 51
PBM Mariner flying boats, 232
Pearl River Delta, China, 282–83
Pegatron Corporation, 273, 296, 310, 322
Pellerin, Cora, 76
Pelton, O., 55
Pemberton Mill, 76–77, 79, 349n
Pennsylvania, 46. See also names of specific locations
Pennsylvania Railroad, 58
Pennsylvania Steel Company, 104
pensions and retirement, 113, 131, 234–35, 285, 306, 321–22
Perkins, Frances, 103
Petrograd, Russia, 180
Petrusov, Georgy, 214
Philadelphia, Pennsylvania, 80–82, 81, 84, 88, 107, 163
Philco Radio, 163
photography
depictions of Cold War mass production, 233, 244
depictions of Fordism and industry, 77, 102–3, 119, 136, 145, 148–54
depictions of Soviet industry, 211–14, 216–18
Piano, Renzo, 362n
piecework, 6, 65, 108, 176, 178–79, 371n
Pierce, George N., 361n
Pierce-Arrow, 361n
Pinkerton National Detective Agency, 100–101
Piquette Avenue plant (Ford), 133, 361n
Pittsburgh, Pennsylvania, 90–93, 95–97, 97, 103, 110, 115, 163, 234, 238, 239
Pittsburgh Survey, 96, 112–13, 357n
Plug Riots, 39
Plymouth, 154
“Poem for Adults” (Ważyk), 256–57
poetry, 86–87, 256–57, 303
Pogodi, Nikolai, 188
Poland, 250, 252, 261–64. See also Nowa Huta, Poland
Polish Military Organization, 204
politics and government
democratic voice, xv, 39–41, 101, 103, 111, 338n
in Eastern Europe, 259–62
incentives to relocate, 241
post-WWII support for union labor, 238
reaction to protests and strikes, 38–39, 78, 100–102, 110–11, 116, 165, 167,
236, 307
regulation, 5, 30–33, 41, 68, 114
Senate investigation of steel industry, 113
state support of factory system, 39–40
Waltham-Lowell system, 69
pollution. See environment and ecology
Pontiac, 191
Pou Chen Corporation, 273–74
power sources, 2, 16
charcoal, 89–91
coal, 91, 253
coke, 89–90, 353n
electric, 139
hand power, 4, 9–10
horse, 7, 45
iron shafts, 49
leather belts, 49
pace of labor and, 31
steam, 8, 10, 13, 16–17, 20, 56, 75, 80, 81, 82–84, 333n, 344n
water, 2–3, 7, 9–10, 13, 16, 51–52, 56–57, 143, 333n, 344n
Preis, Art, 234
Press Shop (Ford), 141
Pressed Steel Car Company, 110–11
production and productivity. See also automation and mechanization
adoption of factory model and scale of production, 10–11
compensation and wages vs., 65–66
concentration and centralization of production, xv, 11–12
effects on environment, xiv
effects on life expectancy, xiv
just-in-time production, 296–97
mass production, 118–19, 124
New England textile mills, 56–57
post-WWII automation and mechanization, 243
scaling up production, 296–98, 394n
scientific management, 107–9
union vs. nonunion workers, 383n
progress. See modernity and progress
Progressive Era, 112
proletariat, 30, 41
Prometheus, 96
Proprietors of Locks and Canals on the Merrimack, 51
protests and strikes
automotive industry, 155, 161–66
in China, 302, 306–8
early labor organization, 38–39
in Eastern Europe, 259–63
in Egypt, 268–69
electronics industry, 306
first substantial walkouts, 39
government and military reaction to, 38–39, 78, 100–102, 110–11, 116, 165,
167, 236, 307
immigrant participation in, 110–11, 117
iron and steel industry, 98–103, 102, 167, 358n
“labor question,” 111
Luddites, 35–39
machine wrecking, 35–39
New England textile mills, 66–67, 77–78
transformation from novel to ordinary, 42
in Vietnam, 274, 307, 397n
women’s participation in, 66–67, 77, 347n
WWI era, 115–17, 234, 358n
WWII and post-WWII, 233–35, 238, 239
“protoindustrialization,” 13
publicity. See art and artists; factory tourism
Pudong New Area of Shanghai, China, 281
Pueblo, Colorado, 96
Pulaski, Virginia, 237
Pullman, 128
Puma, 292
Pun Ngai, 281
punctuality, 20
punishment, 19, 24–25, 31, 303
Putilov metalworking complex (Petrograd, Soviet Union), 180
In Transit:
The Transport Workers Union in New York City, 1933–1966
American Empire:
The Rise of Global Power, the Democratic Revolution at Home
Copyright © 2018 by Joshua B. Freeman
Excerpt of translation of Blaise Cendrars, “Tower” © Tony Baker
For information about permission to reproduce selections from this book, write to
Permissions, W. W. Norton & Company, Inc., 500 Fifth Avenue, New York, NY
10110
For information about special discounts for bulk purchases, please contact W. W.
Norton Special Sales at specialsales@wwnorton.com or 800-233-4830
ISBN: 978-0-393-24631-5
W. W. Norton & Company, Inc., 500 Fifth Avenue, New York, N.Y. 10110
www.wwnorton.com