The Entrepreneurial Society
The Entrepreneurial Society
The Entrepreneurial Society
Mark Sanders
Axel Marx
Mikael Stenkula Editors
The Entrepreneurial
Society
A Reform Strategy for Italy, Germany
and the UK
International Studies in Entrepreneurship
Volume 44
Series Editors
Zoltan J. Acs, George Mason University, Fairfax, VA, USA
David B. Audretsch, Indiana University, Bloomington, IN, USA
More information about this series at http://www.springer.com/series/6149
Mark Sanders Axel Marx Mikael Stenkula
• •
Editors
This Springer imprint is published by the registered company Springer-Verlag GmbH, DE part of
Springer Nature.
The registered company address is: Heidelberger Platz 3, 14197 Berlin, Germany
To Cedric, Merel, Luka and Milo. Look out
for opportunities and have the guts to act on
them.
Foreword
The Entrepreneurial Society is always in the making. At the micro level, entre-
preneurial people and organizations develop valuable new combinations, enabled
and constrained by structures at the macro level. This book provides an excellent
overview of how to improve the Entrepreneurial Society in the context of the
European Union, and more particular its member states Italy, Germany and the UK.
Improving the Entrepreneurial Society is a process of trial-and-error. One can go
through this process in the dark or be illuminated by multiple scientific disciplines.
This book, and the FIRES project at large, is a multidisciplinary endeavor that sheds
light from multiple scientific disciplines on the question and challenge of how to
build a more Entrepreneurial Society. It might look like the parable of the blind men
and the elephant, in which each blind man feels part of the animal and creates his
own version of reality from that limited experience and perspective. The FIRES
consortium has been able to connect the blind men, with teams of scholars from
law, economics, history, economic geography and innovation studies. This has
delivered insights into the process of improving the Entrepreneurial Society and a
diagnostic toolkit to uncover the key institutions of entrepreneurial societies. The
proposed improvement process provides seven steps to achieve the ultimate aim of
inclusive, innovative and sustainable growth. With this book, we will have the best
starting point available to start and guide this journey!
vii
Preface
This book marks the end of a three-year intense collaboration among some 40
excellent scientists and colleagues from nine institutes in as many countries. As not
all their names appear in the author lists of the chapters in this book, we want to
thank them here for all their patience, insights and discussions. We also extend our
gratitude to many guests and partners that got involved at some stage in our project
and Prashanth and Ruth at Springer Publishers in creating this book. Also, it would
not have been possible to make this project a success without the support of
Mischa, Martina and Mike at the LEG research support office, our project officer at
the European Commission, Danilla Conte and the Commission’s reviewers during
the project. It was a great ride for all of us.
ix
Acknowledgements
The editors thank Elisa Terragno Bogliaccini for research assistance and Erik Stam
and participants of the workshop of September 5–6, 2019, in Utrecht for useful
comments on the draft chapters. Mark Sanders thanks Montpellier Business School
for their kind hospitality while drafting the manuscript during his sabbatical in the
first half of 2019, and Mikael Stenkula gratefully acknowledges financial support
from Jan Wallanders och Tom Hedelius stiftelse and from the Marianne and Marcus
Wallenberg Foundation. Finally, financial support for open access publication of
this book was provided by the European Commission under the Horizon 2020
project Financial and Institutional Reforms for the Entrepreneurial Society (FIRES),
Grant Agreement Number 649378.
xi
Contents
xiii
xiv Contents
Selin Dilli Department of History and Art History, Utrecht University, Utrecht,
The Netherlands
James Dunstan Utrecht School of Economics, Utrecht University, Utrecht,
The Netherlands
Saul Estrin Department of Management, London School of Economics, London,
England, UK
Michael Fritsch Friedrich Schiller University of Jena, Jena, Germany
Luca Grilli Department of Management Economics and Industrial Engineering,
Politecnico di Milano, Milan, Italy
Andrea M. Herrmann Innovation Studies, Copernicus Institute of Sustainable
Development, Utrecht University, Utrecht, The Netherlands
Gresa Latifi TUM School of Management, Technical University of Munich,
Munich, Germany
Axel Marx Leuven Centre for Global Governance Studies, University of Leuven,
Leuven, Belgium
Balázs Páger Department of Management Science, University of Pécs, Pécs,
Hungary
Mark Sanders Utrecht School of Economics, Utrecht University, Utrecht,
The Netherlands
Tamás Sebestyén Regional Innovation and Entrepreneurship Research Center,
MTA-PTE Innovation and Economic Growth Research Group, University of Pécs,
Pécs, Hungary
Mikael Stenkula Research Institute of Industrial Economics, Stockholm, Sweden
xv
xvi Contributors
Abstract In this chapter, the editors introduce and motivate the approach in this
volume. Although this volume brings together contributions from different authors,
the chapters all flow directly from the work that was done in the European H2020
research project Financial and Institutional Reforms for the Entrepreneurial Society
that was conducted between 2015 and 2018. The first four chapters present and
illustrate the multidisciplinary tools that fill the diagnostic toolkit developed in the
project. Then three chapters illustrate how these tools can be usefully applied in
different institutional contexts in the European Union, namely in Italy, Germany,
and the UK.
1.1 Introduction
A good 50 years after its birth, the European Union is, arguably, in a serious midlife
crisis. The global financial crash of 2007–2008 plunged several member states in a
prolonged recession and the Syrian crisis strained already troubled relationships in the
European family. With the Brexit referendum, the rise of Alternative für Deutschland,
populist movements in Spain, Italy, and Greece and the revolt of the Gilets Jaunes
in France, it is fair to conclude that Europe is losing its appeal among a vocal and
perhaps growing share of European citizens. We believe that this decade of discontent
is rooted in feelings of injustice and of being confronted with decisions and their
consequences, rather than being involved in them. The solution in a globalizing
M. Sanders (B)
Utrecht School of Economics, Utrecht University, Utrecht, The Netherlands
e-mail: m.w.j.l.sanders@uu.nl
A. Marx
Leuven Centre for Global Governance Studies, University of Leuven, Leuven, Belgium
e-mail: axel.marx@kuleuven.be
M. Stenkula
Research Institute of Industrial Economics, Stockholm, Sweden
e-mail: mikael.stenkula@ifn.se
© The Author(s) 2020 1
M. Sanders et al. (eds.), The Entrepreneurial Society, International Studies
in Entrepreneurship 44, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-662-61007-7_1
2 M. Sanders et al.
world, however, is not a retreat to the nation-state. Europe needs to deliver on its
initial promise of providing security, well-being, and opportunity for all European
citizens. We believe that doing so is also our best chance of restoring Europe on the
path to innovative, inclusive, and sustainable growth.
Between 2015 and 2018, some 40 researchers in 9 institutions and countries
across Europe have worked on the Horizon2020 project Financial and Institutional
Reforms for the Entrepreneurial Society (FIRES; www.projectfires.eu). The chief
aim of FIRES was to translate the insights of some three decades of entrepreneurship
research into actionable institutional reform proposals. In the project, a strategy was
formulated to bring inclusive, sustainable, and innovative growth back to the Euro-
pean Union by reforming Europe’s institutions to promote a more open, contestable
Entrepreneurial Society. This book, together with its companion volume published
as The Entrepreneurial Society: A Reform Agenda for the European Union, presents
the core results of this project in a comprehensive way.
In the companion volume, FIRES-researchers Niklas Elert, Magnus Henrekson
and Mark Sanders introduced and motivated 50 proposals for reform in six key areas
of policy making (Elert et al. 2019). These six areas go well beyond the areas that
policymakers traditionally associate with entrepreneurship policy. They give us a
list of possibly useful interventions that would have to be implemented at different
levels in the European Union. In recognition of the complexity of multilayered policy
competencies in the European Union, the authors carefully analyzed the relevant
policy-making institutions and their legal and political competencies on the six areas
of policy making identified in that volume.
Inevitably, however, these proposals are general and motivated from a broad base
of evidence and scientific debate. The resulting menu of options, therefore, should
still not be interpreted as a blueprint for a reform strategy that will work in all EU
Member States and regions. It would be naive and possibly even damaging to imple-
ment all reforms in all regions across the very diverse entrepreneurial ecosystems of
the European Union. Each region and state has its specific history and institutional
trajectory, and we have therefore always stressed the need for tailoring reforms to
local needs and conditions.
In this volume, we collect, present, and illustrate the application of the tools we
have developed to do so. Before one can decide what reforms are most suitable in any
given context, one needs to distinguish the deep rooted from the more reformable
institutions in a region and identify the strengths, weaknesses, and bottlenecks in
Europe’s entrepreneurial ecosystems. Doing so requires a multidisciplinary approach
and the tools illustrated in this volume therefore build on such diverse disciplines as
history, geography, economics, and law.
1 Seven Steps Toward Inclusive, Innovative, and Sustainable Growth 3
In Part One of this volume, consisting of four chapters, we discuss how we addressed
Steps 1–3 in the FIRES project. This part of the book sets the stage and illustrates
how the FIRES-toolbox can be used to diagnose weaknesses in an entrepreneurial
ecosystem and select reforms to strengthen them. In the three chapters that make up
Part Two of this book, we apply these tools and go through the cycle from Steps 1 to
6 for three countries—Italy, Germany and the UK—representing three rather distinct
institutional clusters in the European Union. As we cannot actually implement the
proposed policies to execute Step 7, this step is outside the scope of this book, but
how this is to be done responsibly is briefly discussed in our conclusion.
In Chap. 2, Selin Dilli illustrates the importance of historical research in Step 1
for institutions shaping the allocation of labor, knowledge, and finance in Europe.
Historical research shows that the differences in these institutions are often the result
of long-term historical processes. A reform strategy can only be successful if it builds
on these historical foundations. Using the Varieties of Capitalism (VoC) framework,
4 M. Sanders et al.
the chapter provides insight into the different patterns of institutional change and its
implications for different forms of entrepreneurial activity across European countries.
The historical approach presented in Chap. 2 constitutes the first step in designing a
tailored reform strategy.
In Chap. 3, Attila Varga, László Szerb, Tamás Sebestyén and Norbert Szabó present
the Regional Entrepreneurship and Development Index (REDI) methodology for
assessing the quality of the entrepreneurial ecosystem at the regional level in step 2.
In this chapter, the authors also show how improvements in the ecosystem generate
macroeconomic impacts in a Geographic Macro Regional (GMR) model simula-
tion. The focus of the analysis here is more on the cross-sectional and geographical
dimension. The simulations communicate an important message to policy makers by
demonstrating that the impact of reforms will vary across regions and countries in
Europe, creating a tension between the level at which policies can be implemented
and where they generate positive or negative impacts.
In Chap. 4, Andrea M. Herrmann illustrates how “varieties of entrepreneurial
ecosystems” form distinct institutional constellations that facilitate different types
of entrepreneurship. More specifically, she stressed that slow-growing incrementally
innovative ventures constitute a distinct type of entrepreneurship next to radically
innovative, high-growth entrepreneurship. This reveals a second potential tension in
formulating reform proposals that build on existing strengths or rather strengthen
existing weaknesses. These findings invite policy makers to target entrepreneurial
support measures more specifically to their economy’s institutional environment and
carefully consider institutional complementarities that exist in different varieties of
entrepreneurial ecosystems.
To conclude Part One of this volume, Axel Marx presents a legal analysis of
European entrepreneurship policy in Chap. 5. In this chapter, he elaborates on how
European policy making should be affected when implementing reforms. Chang-
ing the institutional environment responsible for the quality of the entrepreneurial
ecosystem will require changes on multiple levels. The chapter shows that fostering
entrepreneurship will require a multi-level approach with a strong focus on the level
of EU Member States.
In Chap. 6, representing the first chapter of Part Two, Mark Sanders, Mikael
Stenkula, and co-authors outline a reform strategy to promote a more entrepreneurial
society in Italy, classified as a Mixed or Mediterranean Market Economy (MME).
Italy historically boasts a vibrant entrepreneurial economy of locally embedded,
often family-owned small- and medium-sized firms. But the Italian entrepreneurial
ecosystem has a bureaucratic business environment that feeds back into low lev-
els of productivity and ambition in entrepreneurship. To address the problem, Italy
could reform its educational system to promote a more experimental attitude and
reduce the bureaucratic business environment and recruitment culture that stifles
ambitious entrepreneurs. For Italy, important tensions arise between the tendency
for entrepreneurial venturing to concentrate in already well-off regions and creating
opportunities for all Italians.
1 Seven Steps Toward Inclusive, Innovative, and Sustainable Growth 5
Mark Sanders, Mikael Stenkula, and co-authors follow up in Chap. 7 with a reform
strategy to promote a more entrepreneurial society in Germany. Germany can be clas-
sified as a coordinated market economy (CME) and is historically characterized by
a strong and regionally embedded Mittelstand and an economy where high produc-
tivity growth is driven by on-the-job learning and firm-specific skill accumulation.
Germany’s entrepreneurial talent could be encouraged to take on more risk. The edu-
cation system could promote creativity, and a more equal playing field between new
and incumbent ventures in attracting finance, labor, and knowledge could be created.
For Germany, an important tension exists between supporting its traditional incre-
mentally innovative Mittelstand and channeling resources into somewhat riskier and
radically innovative ventures to also push out the global technology frontier.
In Chap. 8, Mark Sanders, Mikael Stenkula, and co-authors finally present a reform
strategy to promote an entrepreneurial society in the UK. The UK is typically classi-
fied as a liberal market economy (LME) and has a deregulated environment, flexible
labor markets, well-funded elite universities, and strong protection of intellectual
property rights. The UK should aim at strengthening the workforce’s knowledge
base and talent pool as well as the capital base. It furthermore is advisable to open
opportunities for not only starting but also for growing, perhaps less radically inno-
vative, firms in all regions in the UK. For the UK, both the geographical and the
variety of entrepreneurship tension will require careful consideration in designing
and evaluating our proposed reforms.
The country case studies in Chaps. 6–8 are substantially shortened and reworked
versions of the country reports that were submitted as reports to the European Com-
mission and published earlier on www.projectfires.eu, where the reader can also find
the policy briefs and a report on the policy round tables that were organized around
them in the spring of 2018 in Rome, Berlin, and London, respectively. For the purpose
of this book, this material has been merged and significantly revised and updated.
We conclude this volume with Chap. 9, where the editors of the book sum up
the main points concerning theory, method, and policy proposals. The editors also
elaborate on tensions that exist between the chapters.
Reference
Elert N, Henrekson M, Sanders M (2019) The entrepreneurial society: a reform strategy for the
European Union. Springer, Berlin
6 M. Sanders et al.
Open Access This chapter is licensed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0
International License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits use, sharing,
adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate
credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license and
indicate if changes were made.
The images or other third party material in this chapter are included in the chapter’s Creative
Commons license, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not
included in the chapter’s Creative Commons license and your intended use is not permitted by
statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from
the copyright holder.
Part I
Historical Roots, Ecosystem Assessment,
Firm Formation Processes
and Legal Competences
Chapter 2
A Historical Perspective on the Evolution
of Finance, Knowledge, and Labor
Market Institutions in Europe
Selin Dilli
2.1 Introduction
The author gratefully acknowledges funding from the European Union’s Horizon 2020 research
and innovation program under grant agreement No 649378. Thanks to Axel Marx, Mark Sanders,
and Mikael Stenkula for comments on earlier drafts of this chapter.
S. Dilli (B)
Department of History and Art History, Utrecht University, Utrecht, The Netherlands
e-mail: s.dilli@uu.nl
and informal sets of rules which shape individuals’ preferences and behavior (North
1990), which promote or hamper entrepreneurial activity via the reduction or increase
of uncertainty and costs (Baumol 1990). The starting point in the FIRES project is
that the institutions in finance, knowledge, and labor markets are key institutions in
shaping entrepreneurial activity. This chapter aims to provide a historical perspective
on the evolution of these institutions to be able to identify those that are more
rapidly changing versus ones that persist over time. This is important information
for policymakers aiming to build up institutions for a more entrepreneurial society.
In our earlier works, using the Varieties of Capitalism (henceforth VoC) framework
(Dilli et al. 2018; Dilli and Westerhuis 2018a; Dilli and Westerhuis 2018b; Dilli
2019), we showed that the variations in the finance, labor, and knowledge institutions
and their complementarities explain the differences both in terms of the level and
type of entrepreneurial activity across European countries today. The VoC literature
proposes a more holistic approach to institutions. Rather than focusing on single
institutions, this holistic approach to finance, labor, and knowledge institutions
identifies four institutional constellations characterizing Europe (Amable 2003; Hall
and Soskice 2001; Dilli et al. 2018). The first one is the liberal market economies
(LMEs), exemplified with the USA and UK, where institutions support market-
based solutions. On the other side of the spectrum are coordinated market economies
(CMEs), such as Germany, where institutions provide social security and stimulate
coordination among firms, governments, and other agents in the market economy
such as the labor unions. A third cluster, the Mediterranean Market Economies
(MMEs), composed of Italy, Spain, Greece, and Portugal, are characterized by a larger
state and governmental regulation. A last cluster is the Eastern Market Economies
(EMEs) that have an institutional setup to attract multinational companies.
In Dilli et al. (2018), we established that these four institutional constellations
are also relevant to explain the diversity of entrepreneurship in Europe. For instance,
in the Eastern European countries there is little protection of minority investors,
high minimum capital requirements, little facilitation of venture capital, and a
recovery rate favoring creditors over shareholders. In the UK, there are low minimum
capital requirements, institutions that facilitate the availability of venture capital,
and institutions that privilege shareholders in case of corporate failure by limiting
the chances of creditors to recover their investments. In terms of labor market
regulations, the Eastern countries and the UK have weak employment protection
contrary to the Mediterranean countries where there are strong regulations against
firing employees. The governmental transfers to research and development are much
higher in the Northwestern European countries compared to the South and Eastern
European countries. These cross-national differences in the combination with these
institutional factors explain why fewer people are willing to start a new business in the
Northwestern European countries compared to the South and East but those who do
tend to engage in high-growth innovative sectors. Herrmann (2020) provides a more
in-depth discussion of the relevance of the VoC framework for the entrepreneurship
literature and our previous findings on this topic.
To stimulate entrepreneurial activity, the European Commission (2013) has
identified more flexible labor market institutions, investment in higher education,
2 A Historical Perspective on the Evolution of Finance … 11
and better access to finance via regulatory burden reductions as strategies in the
Entrepreneurship 2020 Action Plan. Yet, such one-size-fit-all policy tools are unlikely
to be successful in Europe. With the establishment of the European Union, there was
an expectation of convergence among the Member States. However, comparative
studies on the effect of Europeanization have not found strong empirical evidence
for such convergence (See Bürzel 1999 for a review). The VoC literature argues
against convergence toward a single institutional model in Europe. According to
this school of thought, this is because the institutional arrangements of European
countries have evolved differently into complex systems of interdependent and
complementary institutions over time, which are difficult to change (Hall and Thelen
2009). Another argument against convergence is rooted in history. The literature
on path dependency suggests that the institutional legacies of the past limit the
range of current possibilities and/or options in institutional innovation (Nielson et al.
1995, p. 6). Historical conditions are thus important in determining the current-day
institutional setup as well as socioeconomic outcomes. In this chapter, the focus will
be on the latter: the influence of the past in understanding the current institutional
diversity and outcomes for entrepreneurship in the dimensions of finance, knowledge,
and labor across Europe.
Newly emerging social science literature demonstrates that the historical setting
has set in motion divergent evolutionary paths, leading to the deeply entrenched
differences in economic, institutional, social, and political outcomes today (see Nunn,
2009, for a review). For instance, Duranton et al. (2009) show that European regions
with historically weak family ties perform better in terms of economic growth, adopt
better to sectoral shifts, and have a higher educational attainment today. Alesina et al.
(2010) find that stringent labor market regulations persist over time despite being
economically inefficient due to their deep roots in the historical family structure.
Galor and Ozak (2016) find that pre-industrial agro-climatic characteristics have a
culturally embodied impact on the economic behavior of countries such as technology
adoption, education, and saving today. In the entrepreneurship literature, the deep
historical roots as an explanation for the regional and cross-country differences have
started to receive attention too. In the case of Germany, for example, Fritsch and
Wyrwich (2017) demonstrate that regions with higher levels of self-employment in
the 1920s also have higher levels of new business formation today. Nevertheless, the
evidence in this strand of literature is largely based on cross-national comparisons,
regressing one point in time in the past on a current outcome.
Historians have criticized such cross-country comparisons as it assumes limited
change over time and treats countries as being less advantaged in the institutional
and development conditions since they first appeared in history (Frankema and
Weijenburg 2012). This is a strong assumption to make, as the evidence from
historical studies on the persistence and change in historical conditions is rather
mixed. On the one hand, historical studies that focus on informal institutions (i.e.,
norms and values), such as the family systems, the co-residence patterns, and
inheritance practices, argue that these institutions experienced limited change since
the Middle Ages (Todd 1985; Reher 1998). On the other hand, there are historical
studies showing that formal institutions including democratic rule, tax regulation, and
12 S. Dilli
and then I discuss the historical trends in the underlying institutions. The last
section concludes with the relevance of the historical analysis of institutions and
its implications for the entrepreneurship literature.
2.2 Finance1
The availability of financing options is crucial in all stages and for all types of
entrepreneurial activity: in seeing an opportunity to start a firm, growing a business,
and engaging in innovation (Dilli et al. 2018). Among the various sources of
financing, banks remain the largest financial intermediaries in all European countries,
although their importance varies significantly across countries (OECD 2013; 2015).
The share of the nonbank instruments, such as factoring, crowdfunding, private
equity, and venture capital, remains relatively small in Europe in comparison to the
USA with the notable exception of the UK. For instance, between 1995 and 2010,
total European venture capital investment has been, on average, approximately only
one-third of the volume in the USA (OECD 2013). Informal financing tools are
an important source of capital for entrepreneurs too (OECD 2013). These informal
financing options via investors, such as private individuals/business angels and a
network of friends, family, and foolhardy investors, provide financing directly to
unquoted companies to which they may or may not have a family connection (Szerb
et al. 2007). Again, across Europe, differences are present in relative importance of
these informal sources to fund entrepreneurs. For instance, in Dilli and Westerhuis
(2018a), using the Global Entrepreneurship Monitor (2011), we show that today
business angels invest more in close family and relatives in the Eastern and
Mediterranean countries (with the exception of Portugal) than in the Northwestern
countries. Nevertheless, such trends provide only a snapshot of the current situation.
To a historian, they raise the question when banks started to play such a central role
for entrepreneurs in Europe and whether their role has changed over time. Another
question is whether, given the large historical differences in the family systems (Todd
1985), family can indeed be an alternative financing tool in all the European countries.
Below I discuss the historical evolution of the banking system and family systems
to address these questions.
1 This section is taken from the working paper version of Dilli and Westerhuis (2018a). The section
on banks (Section 2.2.1) mainly relies on the input by Gerarda Westerhuis in Dilli and Westerhuis
(2018a). For an extended version of the finance section please see: https://projectfires.eu/wp-content/
uploads/2018/02/D2.4-REVISED.pdf.
14 S. Dilli
The historical roots of the banking system can be traced back to the fourteenth century.
Although private banks had long provided a mix of commercial and investment
services to their customers, the term “universal bank” is usually reserved for the
large incorporated financial institutions that emerged in Europe during the second
half of the nineteenth century (Cull et al. 2006). Therefore, I will focus here on
the period from the late nineteenth century onwards as this covers the period of the
emergence of the diverse modern banking system that characterizes most European
countries today.
The size of the banks has been linked with the availability of bank credit for
entrepreneurship. Small banks have traditionally been important lenders to small
firms because small banks have a comparative advantage in relationship lending.
Accordingly, the importance of and access to bank credit fell as banks became larger
and banking got more concentrated over time (World Bank 2013). According to this
view, small banks are better than large banks at relationship lending that depends on
“soft” information. Large banks, in contrast, specialize in transaction lending to more
mature firms where less discretion is involved (Black and Strahan 2002, p. 2808).
In many European countries, large financial conglomerates have emerged over time
that are perceived as less willing to finance SMEs in general and entrepreneurship
in particular.
In many European countries, the banking landscape had been much more diverse
than it is currently. Small, locally embedded credit institutions played an important
role in introducing innovations and providing financing to firms and sectors that were
overlooked by the larger financial institutions (Wadhwani 2016, p. 192). In some
countries (e.g., the Netherlands, UK), this diversity has almost vanished, whereas
in others (e.g., Germany), it continues to play an important role in the financial
system. At the end of the nineteenth century, these differences between banking
systems across European countries started to emerge. In particular, with the Second
Industrial Revolution and the emergence of large-scale firms, the increased demand
for capital led to the emergence of large commercial banks (Westerhuis 2016). In
many countries, these big banks replaced relationship banking that was present prior
to the nineteenth century with impersonal transaction banking. In the UK, many
local banks that were typically small, private institutions, and limited by law to no
more than six partners, played a crucial role in funding local industries during the
first industrial revolution (Cull et al. 2006). During the interwar period, UK banking
became more concentrated and less competitive. Provincial banks were taken over by
large London-based banks, which preferred higher liquidity ratios. This reduced the
supply of funds for the industrial clients, in particular the smaller and younger ones. A
similar pattern is also visible in the Netherlands. While prior to the twentieth century,
regional banks played an important role in financing (new) businesses, around 1910
a process of concentration set in the Netherlands, which created five big banks that
would dominate the scene by 1925 (Jonker 1997). An alternative for their clients was
2 A Historical Perspective on the Evolution of Finance … 15
offered via market solutions such as stockbrokers and private investors (Cull et al.
2006). This pattern corresponds well with the LME’s institutional structure, which
stimulates market-oriented solutions (Hall and Soskice 2001).
In contrast, in Germany, a typical CME, and in Italy and France, classified as
MMEs, the banking system remained relatively more fragmented and the state
intervened by creating public and semipublic (i.e., cooperatives) lending institutions.
These public, semipublic, and regional banks specialized in segments of the market
reducing information asymmetries (Carnavali 2005). This type of banking structure
lowered assessment and monitoring costs due to long-term relations between
lenders and borrowers. The governmental intervention corresponds with the type
of institutional structure of the CMEs identified in the VoC literature that stimulates
coordination between different agents of the economy. The disadvantage was that
these banks were less able to diversify and spread risks (Carnavali 2005).
In Germany, for instance, cooperatives emerged in the nineteenth century in
response to the failure of existing lenders to give credit to small retailers and rural
populations. The cooperatives were owned and controlled by their members and
granted loans to members who might lack access to credit at the large financial
institutions (Wadhwani 2016). Around the First World War credit cooperatives
together with commercial banks and savings banks formed the core of the German
banking system (Deeg 1999). The cooperative model spread across Europe since the
second half of the nineteenth century. In Italy, it became a very important part of the
financial system as well (Carnevali 2005). In contrast, in the UK and USA, typical
LME economies, the credit cooperatives were established relatively late. In these
contexts, commercial banks were already providing financial services to the working
and rural people, whereas large corporates acquired capital through well-developed
capital markets.
In Germany, cooperatives and savings banks2 developed close links with local
business. Although in the literature the focus is often on the big banks from Berlin,
in Germany many small business owners, artisans, and shopkeepers banked in local
and regional banks (Carnevali 2005, p. 46). These small regional banks met fierce
opposition from the commercial banks, and it was this conflict that “shaped the
state’s response toward competition between different types of banks, ensuring the
permanence of segmentation” (Carnevali 2005, p. 196). In Germany, the state played
an important role in mediating between different types of banks. It was an active
political choice to protect the SMEs and their local economies. In contrast, savings
banks in the UK, created in the 1810s, for example, were not allowed to lend for
commercial purposes by law.
In the 1950s and 1960s, the long-term finance of small businesses in Germany
was made available via savings and cooperative banks, ensured by strong competition
and state regulation. Regulation provided incentives for the saving and cooperative
banks to grant SMEs long-term credits, where these banks operated in a limited
market and their success depended on the economic welfare of their region. In their
2 Savingbanks emerged in the late eighteenth century in order to provide possibilities for working
and poor people to save for periods of need due to illness, unemployment, or retirement.
16 S. Dilli
charters, it was stated that pursuing profits was important but only as a means to
other goals. Savings banks were mandated with the promotion of the local economy,
and cooperative banks had to serve the interests of their members (Carnevali 2005).
In Italy, the banking system was decentralized to strengthen local banks after
the Second World War. The government wanted to create local financial channels
(decentralized capitalism) to act as a counterbalance to the power of the large private
business groups. Decentralization and a segmented banking system were seen as
elements that would increase stability, whereas a concentrated banking system was
perceived as a factor that would hinder economic growth (Carnevali 2005, p. 177).
The diverse financial landscape of the 1930s with various types and sizes of financial
intermediaries was defended as a guarantee for the diffusion of credit. As a result,
regulations were reshaped in order to reduce banking competition and protect the
small- and medium-sized banks from the larger national ones (Carnevali 2005,
p. 178). The awareness of policymakers, that SMEs had disadvantages in access
to market finance, contributed to the introduction of financial subsidies as part of
national industrial policy (Spadavecchia 2005). Of the various countries discussed
here, the Italian banking system has been the most regulated and subsidized with the
aim to promote the development of small firms. From the mid-1970s, however, the
decentralized banking system was increasingly being questioned. As a result, many
territorial restrictions were abolished as well as controls over interest rates, leading
to the mergers of banks in the 1990s.
In contrast to Germany, industrialization in France occurred in a political context
of a unified nation-state, with strong central government. Although large French firms
established themselves between 1918 and 1930, SMEs remained a very important
part of the economy (Lescure 1999). Due to agreements to fix prices and quotas,
there were hardly incentives for firms to merge into bigger conglomerates in this
period (Carnevali 2005). Due to active government interference, the banking structure
remained more diverse in France than in the UK in the nineteenth century. During
the Great Depression of the 1930s, many local and regional banks had to close, and
after the Second World War, a process of concentration dominated the banking sector
in which the regional and local banks merged into national ones. Four large deposit
banks were nationalized after 1945. In 1957, 22 regional banks and 158 local banks
were left. The local banks had a strong hold over the local market. The greater role
of the state in France was also reflected in the role of public and semipublic banks
in stimulating investments after the Second World War (Carnevali 2005).
The process of liberalization and harmonization in Europe that eventually led to
the monetary union caused concentration to rise in banking across the Eurozone.
This is visible in Fig. 2.1. The (three) firm concentration ratio is the percentage of
all banking system assets accounted for by the biggest three banks in a country.
For the majority of CME countries, the combination of a few large commercial
banks and a broad base of small, local banks resulted in a C-3 ratio of well above
50% (e.g., Switzerland, Austria, Germany, Netherlands). This also applies to the
Nordic CME countries Denmark, Finland, and Sweden. An interesting case is the
UK banking system, which was rather less concentrated in 1993 with C-3 ratio of
29% increasing to 56% in 2003. Overall, in the clear majority of the 19 EU countries,
2 A Historical Perspective on the Evolution of Finance … 17
Fig. 2.1 Percentage of all banking system assets by the biggest three banks in a country. Source
World Bank (2013)
the largest banks dominated the banking industry 20 years ago and continue to do so
today.
While historical studies show that prior to the twentieth century, the regional
small-sized banks seemed to play a role in funding the small-sized businesses across
Europe, and there is still no consensus on the extent to which this diverse banking
structure in the cases of France, Italy, or Germany provided advantages in solving
finance problems for small businesses. On the one hand, Carnevali (2005) stresses
comparative advantages of these regional banks in Italy, France, and Germany
after the Second World War compared to the much more consolidated banking
system in the UK. On the other hand, the limited historical evidence shows that the
number of firms that could take advantage of the banks’ combination of investment
commercial banking services in Germany was quite small (Cull et al. 2006).
According to Cull et al. (2006), instead SMEs mostly relied on local intermediaries
and private initiatives, which ranged from notaries to family borrowing in France to
the cooperatives in Germany (Cull et al. 2006, p. 3028). In the next section, I evaluate
the role private initiatives, in particular family lending, as an alternative source of
financing for entrepreneurs and link the current differences in family lending to
historical family systems.
instance, Cull et al. (2006) show that in the case of UK and the Netherlands domestic
capital markets and governmental bonds provided an important source of exchange
and finance for businesses, whereas this option was much more limited in the
case of the Southern European countries such as Spain and Portugal. Historically,
family has also been a crucial source of finance for businesses, though its relevance
differed substantially across Europe (Cull et al. 2006). In this section, I argue that
the differences in the historical family systems have likely influenced the variation
in the family borrowing across Europe and continue to do so today.
Family members are assumed to be important providers of financial resources
(Bygrave et al. 2003). This is because financial capital from family members has
important advantages such as lower transaction costs (Au and Kwan 2009), favorable
interest and payback requirements, and availability when other sources are not
available (Steier 2003). Especially when the firm requires more time to provide
returns, family may provide a better lending possibility to the entrepreneur than
formal financing options (Arregle et al. 2015). Bygrave and Reynolds (2005) argue
that the level of social obligations individuals feel toward their family members shape
the willingness of the lender to lend money to the family member (supply side) and
the willingness of the borrower to borrow from a family member (demand side).
One can expect that in contexts where family ties are stronger (family has priority
over the individual), both the willingness to lend and borrow from a family member
would be higher, and as a result, the level of family lending would be higher.
Demographer Reher (1998), using census data, showed that strong family ties
characterize the Mediterranean countries, whereas weaker family ties (the individual
has priority over family) characterize the Northwestern European countries. This
pattern seems to correspond with the cross-national differences in the European
context in terms of lending behavior to family members by business angels today.
In the Eastern European and the Mediterranean countries, business angels seem to
invest more often in family members than in other European countries despite the
unfavorable financial institutional environment. In the Northern European countries,
on the other hand, the investment of business angels and borrowing behavior from
the family remain limited. Sweden and Belgium, depicted as having weaker family
ties, are the exceptions, which outperform the rest of the European countries in
terms of their share of business angel investment in family businesses (see Dilli
and Westerhuis 2018a for an illustration of these trends). An explanation for these
contradictory cases could be attributed to the overall supply of business angels due to
the favorable institutional context such as tax cuts for family lending (Au and Ding
2011; OECD 2015).
One of the core explanations as to why Northwestern European countries have
much weaker family ties compared to the Eastern and Southern European countries
has been linked with the historical differences in the living arrangements of family
members, having long-term effects on the norms and values regarding the importance
of the family due to the generational transfer of these norms (Reher 1998). According
to demographic historians, Hajnal’s St. Petersburg–Trieste line separates the Central
and Northwestern European territories (Scandinavia, the UK, the Low Countries,
much of Germany and Austria) from the Eastern and the Mediterranean in terms of
2 A Historical Perspective on the Evolution of Finance … 19
co-residence practices and has been present for centuries (Reher 1998; Todd 1985).
For instance, the study of Reher (1998) shows that from at least the late Middle Ages
until the second half of the nineteenth century, it was common in rural England and
in the Low Countries for young adults to leave their parental households at a young
age to work as agricultural servants in other households. On the other hand, in the
Southern European societies even though there were servants in both rural and urban
settings, it affected only a small part of the young population in rural areas (Reher
1998). These differences in the family systems have arguably been the result of the
differences in the agricultural practices, the timing of the Neolithic revolution and
geographical factors (Todd 2011).
These historical family arrangements are possibly linked with the long-term
development of different forms of (private) financing options for entrepreneurs across
European regions. The scarce historical evidence from the late Middle Ages and
Early Modern Europe shows that in this period, private lending, even that via the
family members, was already formalized in the Low Countries. Van Zanden et al.
(2012) demonstrate that in the fifteenth and sixteenth centuries, properties were used
as collateral on a large scale, and that interest rates on both small and large loans
were relatively low (about 6%). As a result, many households owned financial assets
and/or debts, and the degree of financial sophistication was relatively high.
Similarly, Gelderblom and Jonker (2004) show that deposits and bonds were
common among businessmen and entrepreneurs as a tool to borrow already in
sixteenth century Netherlands. Thus, formal institutions as well as the availability
of investors due to deep domestic markets as a result of the international trade at the
time stimulated lending both from family and non-family members in this period.
This resulted in access to credit for a larger share of the population compared to the
Southern European countries. The presence of weak family ties might have created
the necessity to regulate the lending behavior more formally in the North. On the other
hand, while financial historians show that Italian city-states were crucial financial
centers in the fifteenth and sixteenth centuries, wealth was mainly concentrated in the
hands of a small group of merchants and family businesses and lending again played
a central role. The lack of historical data, however, does not allow us to provide
insight into how family lending has changed over time across different European
countries.
Nevertheless, past and present cross-country differences in family lending
behavior and family funding can provide a feasible alternative to formal financing
options especially in the Mediterranean and the Eastern European countries given
their strong family ties. This can be done by following the Belgian example. In
Belgium, anyone who grants a loan to an entrepreneur as a friend, acquaintance, or
family member receives an annual tax discount of 2.5% of the value of the loan.
If the enterprise is unable to repay the loan, the lender gets 30% of the amount
owed back via a one-off tax credit in the context of the “win-win lending” scheme
(OECD 2015). This change in the policy seems to have helped with increasing the
availability of finance to entrepreneurs in Belgium, and its implementation might
be less costly in the Southern European countries where family members are more
willingly to invest in family members. An important implication of weak family
20 S. Dilli
2.3 Knowledge
The country case studies in Sanders et al. (2020a, b, c) discuss universities and
the patent system as the underlying institutions for knowledge creation. In this
chapter, I focus instead on outcome variables of these more fundamental institutions
of (1) educational attainment in tertiary level and the gender differences therein
and (2) research and development, which explain the different levels and types
of entrepreneurial activity across Europe (Dilli and Westerhuis 2018b; Dilli et al.
2018). These two indicators can be seen as more direct measures of the knowledge
outcomes. I focus on these two measures as they have been commonly used in the VoC
literature to capture the knowledge dimension, and there is historical and comparable
quantitative data that allows me to evaluate how these two dimensions evolved over
time across European countries.
Formal education at the university level is important for entrepreneurial
activity. For instance, both the individual entrepreneur’s education and the regional
and national educational attainment have been shown to be strong drivers of
entrepreneurs’ decision to start a business and grow their business and the economic
sector in which they engage (see Dilli and Westerhuis 2018b for a review of the
literature). At the societal level, while the educational level of consumers may shape
the demand function for an entrepreneur’s venture output, the educational level of
employees may affect the entrepreneur’s venture productivity and thereby shape his
or her supply function (Millán et al. 2014).
Next to formal education, knowledge-driven innovation is frequently considered
as the outcome of research and development (R&D) activities and the general
concern that firms may underinvest in R&D has resulted in government policies
2 A Historical Perspective on the Evolution of Finance … 21
and programs such as favorable fiscal treatment and R&D subsidies (Coad and
Rao 2010). In addition to the scientific knowledge generated by the private
sector, entrepreneurial ventures may therefore also acquire the necessary scientific
knowledge by participating in, or benefitting from, public R&D programs that lead
to new commercial opportunities (Dilli et al. 2018, p. 7).
Fig. 2.2 Educational attainment in tertiary level (age group 25–64). Notes The figure is based on
the Lee and Lee (2016) dataset. The Europe + USA average includes the 19 European countries
included in the database
22 S. Dilli
the 1960s onwards. Poland, an Eastern Market Economy, and Italy, a Mediterranean
Market Economy, have the lowest attainment in tertiary education among the
European countries. Despite the fact that these two countries also witnessed increases
in tertiary education since the 1960s, especially in Italy, this progress has been slower
compared to the other European countries. The fact that the LME economies perform
highest in the tertiary educational attainment compared to the others thus supports the
line of reasoning in the VoC framework that the LMEs have a comparative advantage
in general education, whereas CMEs focus more on vocational training.3
Dilli and Westerhuis (2018b) also looked at the role of gender differences in
educational attainment to explain the gender differences in entrepreneurial activity.
We showed that women are less likely to engage in all three stages of entrepreneurial
activity across Europe (perceived opportunities to start a business, the knowledge
intensiveness of the sector in which they start their business, and their growth
aspirations), and that education is one of the explanations for this gap. Figure 2.3
displays the ratio of women to men in tertiary education. While a score below 1
indicates women are underrepresented, 1 would indicate gender equality and a value
Fig. 2.3 Gender gap in educational attainment in tertiary level (age group 25–64). Source Lee and
Lee (2016)
3 Animportant note here is that the educational attainment at tertiary level compares only cross-
country differences in terms of quantity and does not provide information on the quality of education,
which is hard to capture historically and across space.
2 A Historical Perspective on the Evolution of Finance … 23
above 1 means women are overrepresented in education. Figure 2.3 shows a slightly
different picture than Fig. 2.2 in terms of gender differences in tertiary education.
The USA, an LME economy, is the pioneer in closing the gender gap in tertiary
education where equality between men and women is achieved as far back as in the
1940s. However, a reversal is visible between 1940s and 1980s, and in the post-1980
period, the gender gap closes again. The USA context highlights that the progress
toward gender equality is not linear (Goldin 1995). The UK, also an LME, witnesses
progress toward gender equality by the beginning of the twentieth century. From the
1960 onwards, the gap between men and women at tertiary education really starts to
close, and in 1985, equality is reached. In Poland, an EME, the gender gap in tertiary
education narrowed in the 1990s and women are even outperforming men since the
mid-1990s. A similar trend is visible in Italy. While many of the other European
countries also achieved equality in tertiary education during the 1990s, Germany
stands out as an exception where the size of the gender gap is largest and only a slow
convergence to gender equality is visible from the 1970s onwards.
When the gender differences in field of subjects at the university level are
considered, a different picture emerges. This has implications for entrepreneurial
activity. In recent years, cross-national differences in entrepreneurship have been
attributed to the differences in education, more particularly gender differences in
science, technology, engineering, and mathematics (STEM) fields (OECD 2016a). To
the extent that entrepreneurial ventures come up with radically new innovations, they
are typically based on technological inventions developed by scientifically oriented
workforces (Dilli et al. 2018). In Dilli and Westerhuis (2018b), we provided empirical
evidence on the evolution of the gender differences in STEM subjects at the tertiary
level since 1970s, which showed that the gender gap in science education is negatively
correlated with entrepreneurial activity.
In Dilli and Westerhuis (2018b), we demonstrate that there is a clear increase
in educational attainment in science subjects in all the four VoC clusters since the
1990s with LME countries having the highest level followed by MMEs, CMEs, and
EMEs, respectively. However, despite the increase in the share of the population
in science subjects, this did not translate into higher gender equality. Instead, all
VoC categories show a decrease in the share of women in science subjects since
the mid-1990s. The only exception being the 1970s when women in LMEs became
relatively more inclined toward science subjects at the tertiary level. Interestingly,
while in the period before the 1990s, the size of the gender gap is largest in CMEs,
followed by LMEs and MMEs, and EMEs, a convergence toward gender inequality
in science subjects is visible. A sharp decline is particularly visible in EMEs after
the collapse of the Soviet Union. An explanation for this increasing gap can be
partly due to the change in women’s choices to follow careers in other fields such as
health and engineering. Thus, we suggest that closing the gender gap in science
can be beneficial for knowledge intensive sectors and high-growth aspirational
entrepreneurship especially in the institutional environments that are also favorable
for women such as in the Nordic CME countries.
24 S. Dilli
The differences across the institutional constellations described in the VoC are also
visible in terms of R&D expenditures. Figure 2.4 highlights that the differences
among European countries have been present at least since the 1980s. Considering the
share of government expenditure in research and development, both Germany and the
USA have the largest public investment compared to the other European countries for
almost the entire period of 1980 and 2010, followed by France. While the Netherlands
and UK show moderate levels of investment in research and development, Italy
and Poland have the lowest. In addition, the share of governmental expenditure in
research and development remained rather constant over time. A similar trend in
terms of cross-country differences is visible when a second indicator of research and
development, researchers per capita is considered. While in the UK, the government
plays a limited role in supporting research and innovation (in line with the LME
typology), it is among the top performers in terms of the number of researchers.
This could be attributed to the academic system of the UK that does not only offer
sophisticated scientific training, but also attracts high numbers of immigrant scientists
(Dilli et al. 2018).
Over time, as the number of researchers has increased substantially across
European countries, this progress has been especially limited in the case of Italy and
Poland. Overall, the increase in the share of population following science subjects at
the tertiary level might be one of the drivers of this general increase over time. Thus,
for Poland and Italy, stimulating research and development activity via governmental
expenditure and stimulating at the tertiary level to follow science subjects might be
tools to support entrepreneurship. Another alternative could also be attracting highly
skilled migrants with a science background to increase the number of researchers.
This section illustrated that there have been rapid improvements both in
educational attainment and in number of researchers over the second half of the
twentieth century. This implies that reforms addressed toward implementation in
the field of education, and research might have impact in the short run. However,
in pursuing such reforms, it is also important to recognize the differences between
CMEs and LMEs in terms of vocational versus general training, as vocational training
in the CMEs has also been successful in supporting innovative entrepreneurial
activity (Dilli et al. 2018), although arguably, in a more incremental nature (see,
e.g., Herrmann 2020).
Labor market institutions in Europe are less flexible compared to those in the USA
(Siebert 1997). For example, the USA stands out as the least regulated country
based on indicators for dismissals of individual workers on permanent contracts.
The success of the USA in terms of entrepreneurial activity has been attributed to
less regulated labor market institutions. Among the European countries, however,
there is a large variation in the extent to which labor market regulations are stringent.
Similar to the USA context, the UK have fairly unrestrictive individual dismissal
regulations. By contrast, regulations in France and Germany are far stricter than the
26 S. Dilli
OECD average (Scarpetta 2014: 3). These differences were also highlighted in the
VoC literature. Labor markets have been deregulated with relatively unrestrictive
individual dismissal regulations in LME economies such as UK and the USA. Since
1990, EMEs also tend to have more flexible labor market regulations compared to the
Nordic countries and the continental European countries, such as the Netherlands,
Germany, and Belgium, characterized by a moderate employment protection. In the
MMEs, notably France, Italy, and Spain, it is far more difficult to dismiss employees,
especially from public service, compared to the other contexts (Dilli 2019). Some of
these cross-national differences characterizing Europe today can be traced back in
the past of these economies.
The twentieth century witnessed an important move towards flexibility in labor
market institutions across Europe. But the extent of this change differs across
European countries. This is visible in the study of Aleksynska and Schmidt (2014),
which sheds light on the current-day differences in labor market institutions by
looking at the origin and evolution of these labor market regulations for a selected
number of European countries. Some of the rules on employment protection, such
as prohibited grounds for dismissals, have roots going back as far as the late
nineteenth century (Aleksynska and Schmidt 2014). Such labor protection laws often
emerged to address the social consequences of early industrialization. The issues of
equity and equality, dignity and decent incomes, set the scene for emerging national
frameworks of regulating work and work relationships. France was the first country to
regulate unemployment insurance, fixed-term contracts, and compensation for unfair
dismissal in 1890. Greece and Italy pioneered generous notice periods and severance
pay. Spain was the first country to explicitly regulate the use and the termination
of fixed-term contracts with respective provisions put in place in 1926. These three
Mediterranean economies also introduced regulations similar to France on the notice
period and regulations on fixed contracts during the 1920s. These economies are
known to have more stringent labor market regulations to this day. In Portugal, in
contrast to the other Mediterranean economies, many of the rules on unemployment
and employment protection were only introduced in the late 1960s and early 1970s,
whereas in the UK, the rules on employment protection legislation developed mainly
in the second half of the twentieth century (Aleksynska and Schmidt 2014).
In the second half of the century, there is more systematic evidence available on
the differences between countries in terms of the employment protection legislation
(EPL). This allows me to trace the change in labor market regulations over time
in a comparative way. The OECD has developed the EPL index—a commonly
used indicator to capture the regulation of the labor markets—based on 21 items
such as laws protecting workers with regular contracts, those affecting workers with
fixed−term (temporary) contracts or contracts with temporary work agencies, and
regulations applying specifically to collective dismissals.4 A higher score on the
4 More information on the method of OEC in constructing the EPL index and the latest version of
the index can be accessed at https://www.oecd.org/els/emp/oecdindicatorsofemploymentprotection.
htm.
2 A Historical Perspective on the Evolution of Finance … 27
Fig. 2.5 Employment protection legislation (EPL), since 1950. Source Allard (2005)
index indicates stricter labor market regulations. Allard (2005) extends this EPL
index back to 1950. Using his information, Fig. 2.5 displays the differences across a
selected number of European countries and the USA since 1950.
According to Fig. 2.5, in the 1950s, the labor market was relatively unregulated
compared to today though the cross-sectional differences between the cluster of
countries were already visible in the mid-50s. The typical LME countries, UK and
USA, had the lowest employment protection by far throughout this period. Starting
from the 1970s onwards, the regulations on employment protection started to become
stricter in many countries (e.g., Germany, France). During this period, the EPL
increased in the UK as well, though it still remained the least regulated European
country. This is because in the 1960s and 1970s, a number of legislations (i.e., the
Contracts of Employment Act 1963 and the Industrial Relations Act 1971) were
introduced to protect employees against unfair dismissals in the UK. The CMEs
Germany and the Netherlands (as well as France, which can either be classified in the
Coordinated or in the Mixed Market category) show moderate levels of employment
protection. In the early 1970s, however, Germany introduced further legislation to
increase employment protection reaching levels similar to Italy.
The late 1970s and beginning of the 1980s witnessed deregulation of the labor
market in a number of countries. A deregulation process is visible in the UK, from the
late 1970s onwards followed by the Netherlands, and Germany in the late 1980s and
early 1990s. In the early 1980s, economic deregulation was the principal labor market
policy of the Thatcher government. During the Thatcher government, a significant
28 S. Dilli
amount of legislation (i.e., Employment Acts of 1980, 1982, and 1988) was passed,
turning back the individual employee rights introduced in the 1960s and 1970s
(Capon 2004). In Germany, the major step relaxing the conditions concerning fixed-
term employment contracts was the introduction of the Employment Promotion Act
(Beschäftigungsförderungsgesetz) in 1985 (Schettkat 2002).5 It is also important to
note that in all the European countries, the number of temporary contracts noticeably
increased in the 1990s (Amable 2003). Labor market liberalization over the 1990s
effectively shows that the bulk of the adjustment was borne by temporary contracts.
The decline in employment protection for that group is especially remarkable in Italy.
While employment protection for regular contracts seems to have been fairly stable
over time, the EPL showed clear reductions for temporary workers over the same
period. Nevertheless, the extent of this deregulation process differed substantially
across the European societies and is reflected in the cross-national differences in the
labor market institutions.
In FIRES, in order to capture the wage setting institutions relevant for entrepreneurial
activity, we looked at trade union density, the level of wage bargaining (coordination),
and governmental intervention in the wage bargaining process (see Dilli 2019 for a
discussion on the relevance of these dimensions for different forms of entrepreneurial
activity and Sanders et al. 2020a, b, c in this volume for applications). For
instance, decentralized and individualized wage setting has been argued to encourage
mobility and risk-taking and would therefore support (potential) high-growth firms
(Henrekson 2014).
Figure 2.6 shows the cross-national differences in trade union density, defined
as the membership as a proportion of all wage and salary earners since 1955 in a
selected number of countries (Visser 2013).6 Figure 2.6 shows that a large variation
exists in terms of trade union density between countries.
The low unionization rate of France is remarkably low (an average of 14% for
the entire period), given the capability of trade unions to mobilize their members for
mass action (e.g., strikes), and their influence on government policy. For instance, in
France the government has withdrawn its plans for a new employment contract for
young workers in 2006, while in 2010 there were massive demonstrations between
September and October protesting against the government’s pension reform plans
(Fulton 2013). Thus, in terms of union density, France shows much lower levels
5 The law provided unconditional freedom for the conclusion of fixed-term contracts up to 18 months
which has a very low union density but very strong labor unions in terms of wage bargaining), union
density is the only indicator to my knowledge that is available historically over time and across the
contexts and to have been commonly linked with entrepreneurship outcomes (see Dilli 2019).
2 A Historical Perspective on the Evolution of Finance … 29
compared to Germany, for example. The trade unionization in the USA, a liberal
market economy, is also one of the lowest in Fig. 2.6, whereas the level of union
density in the UK is higher than in the CMEs (e.g., Germany) and the MMEs. The
CME and the MME countries are close to the average of overall European in terms
of trade union density.
Turning to trends in trade union density over time, during the early postwar
period, Western trade union movements grew in membership and achieved an
institutionalized role in industrial relations and politics, especially in the CMEs.
However, in recent decades, trade unions have seen their membership decline in
many countries as they came increasingly under pressure due to social, economic,
and political changes. The decline in unionization began in the 1960s in the USA,
spread to France after the mid-70s, and was then observed in the Netherlands
and the UK (corresponding with the Thatcher years as well) in the late 1970s.
With the wave of social protest in the late 1960s, unions targeted social groups
such as white-collar, female, and often part-time employees. Some unions were
more successful in recruiting members than others. The Italian unions, for instance,
enjoyed spectacular post-1968 growth after partially successful attempts to reunite
the politically fragmented union movements (Ebbinghaus and Visser 1999). The same
period witnessed an increase in unionism in Sweden (see also Visser 2013), but the
downward trend continued in other countries. Especially from the mid-90s onwards,
there has been a second round of decline in trade unionization observable in many
European countries. Arguably, due to the different degrees to which unions were able
30 S. Dilli
to maintain coverage in wage bargaining, these changes in trade union density did
not lead to a convergence between the European countries and the cross-sectional
differences remain rather stable over time.
Figure 2.7 reveals the large variation in terms of centralization of wage bargaining
process both between countries and over time. Hall and Soskice (2001) argue
that in CMEs, the wage bargaining would be more centralized (i.e., involving
governments, businesses and labor unions together and agreements would be made
across industries) compared to the liberal market economies. Figure 2.7 shows
support for this view. While there was industry-level bargaining in the UK historically,
since 1980, there have been no centralizing forces. A similar decentralized wage
bargaining system has been in place in the USA. The EMEs show similar patterns to
the UK with firm or local level bargaining. In the Scandinavian countries, there has
been a shift from a centralized wage arrangement to a more sectorial bargaining model
during the 1980s. In Germany, Austria, and Switzerland, industry-level bargaining
has been the dominant form. In the Netherlands, until the 1980s, there was a mix
between central level negotiations with industry bargaining in which there were
frequent government interventions. After the 1980s, the bargaining mostly took
place between employers and trade unions though during the 2009–10 recession,
the government committed to support financially to reducing temporary working
hours (Visser 2013). Among the MMEs, industry-level bargaining seems to be more
commonly practiced. While Spain first had central bargaining during the 1970s, it
moved to industrial level bargaining during the 1980s. Overall, there seems to be
a convergence toward industrial level wage bargaining in Europe since the 1980s,
except in Belgium, which counters the trend by moving to a more centralized wage
2 A Historical Perspective on the Evolution of Finance … 31
bargaining system over the same period. So, although wage bargaining institutions
change over decades, there is no tendency for convergence and the differences
between countries in terms of wage bargaining process persist.
With regard to social security, we studied the relevance of social spending together
with illness, unemployment and pension minimum replacement rates for their
relevance for entrepreneurial activity (Dilli 2019). These three show some nuanced
differences, but here it will suffice to focus on the historical evolution of social
spending with pension minimum replacement rates.
While cross-national differences in terms of social security arrangements are
clearly visible today, social security was limited prior to the twentieth century
everywhere around the world. During the eighteenth century, there were two forms
of tax based social spending, namely poor relief and public schools, which made
up at most three percent of GDP in social welfare (Lindert 2004). Still, important
differences across societies in terms of social security arrangements are already
visible in this period. While the Netherlands and the UK historically led in poverty
relief, the USA and Germany led in public schooling. With the extension of suffrage
in many countries after the First World War, public spending on welfare started to
expand in the world and the modern welfare state emerged with extensive coverage
including subsidized healthcare, education, housing, childcare, and old-age pensions
emerged (Lindert 2004). The Great Depression of 1929 and economic crisis in the
late 1970s were particularly important turning points in the European countries.
They gave rise to the role of government in providing security such as in terms of
unemployment insurance and introduction of minimum wage laws (Blanchard 2002;
Visser 2013); though, a large variation is visible in the national strategies of European
countries in terms of government’s support in providing security (e.g., Siebert 1997).
Despite the general rise in social spending and social security arrangements over
the twentieth century, progress toward social welfare regimes has not resulted in a
convergence among the European countries.
Figure 2.8 presents the trends in total social spending as the percentage of GDP.
While France, Germany, and Italy are characterized with the highest social spending
in total, the USA has the lowest followed by the Netherlands and the UK. A significant
decline in social spending is visible during the 1980s, followed by an increase during
the 1990s almost in most selected European countries. Italy has caught up with the
CMEs like Germany, with relatively large social expenditure. Poland, EME, on the
other hand shows a moderate level of social spending, which first rose rapidly but
declined in the post-Soviet period. Perhaps the most striking decline in total spending
is in the case of the Netherlands, where social security reforms in the early 1980s
have driven a sustained decline from about 23 to 17% of GDP, eventually even
undercutting levels in the USA.
32 S. Dilli
Figure 2.9 presents the trends in the minimum pension replacement rates from the
1970s onwards, referring to public pension or equivalent benefit for which a person
without working or pension contribution history is entitled. While countries like the
Netherlands and France show minimum pension replacement rates high above the
European average, the minimum replacement rate in the USA is close to the European
average. The USA and the UK, typical LMEs, have lower pension replacement rates
than France or the Netherlands, but higher than Germany or Poland. Moreover, some
change in the minimum replacement rates7 is visible in a number of countries. For
instance, from the mid-1980s onwards, minimum replacement rates have declined
in the Netherlands. On contrary, the same period has witnessed an increase in Italy
where the minimum pension replacement rate starts at the lowest level but catches
up with countries such as the USA (see also the discussion in Kuitto et al. 2012).
Overall, this section highlights that there have been various changes in the
fields of employment protection legislation, centralization of wage bargaining and
social security over the twentieth century. Labor market institutions, therefore, do
seem rather flexible. Still, despite these changes, the extent to which European
countries experienced change has been different from each other and we do not
find convergence in labor market institutions. For instance, while an increase in
employment protection legislation is visible in many European countries (such as in
Germany, Italy, France) up until the 1980s, these regulations became more flexible
7 This indicator is calculated for a fictive average production worker in manufacturing sector who
is 40 years old and has been working for the 20 years preceding the loss of income or the benefit
period.
2 A Historical Perspective on the Evolution of Finance … 33
Fig. 2.9 Minimum pension replacement rates, 1971–2011. Source Scruggs et al. (2014)
in the case of Germany and Italy after the 1980s. Overall, a convergence toward
more industry-level bargaining process is visible in Central European countries. It
is therefore important to study the history of labor market institutions and carefully
tailor reform proposals to the local and national context.
References
Millán JM, Congregado E, Román C, van Praag M, van Stel A (2014) The value of an educated
population for an individual’s entrepreneurship success. Journal of Business Venturing 29(5):612–
632
Nielson K, Jessop B, Hausner J (1995) Institutional change in post-socialism. In: Hausner J, Jessop
B, Nielsen K (eds) Strategic choice and path-dependency in post-socialism: institutional dynamics
in the transformation process. Edward Elgar, Hants, UK
North DC (1990) Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge
University Press, Cambridge
Nunn N (2009) The importance of history for economic development. Annu Rev Econ 1(1):65–92
OECD (2013) Alternative financing instruments for SMEs and entrepreneurs: the case of mezzanine
finance. OECD Publishing, Paris
OECD (2015) Financing SMEs and entrepreneurs 2015 An OECD scoreboard: an OECD
scoreboard. OECD Publishing, Paris
OECD (2016a) The missing entrepreneurs 2015 (p. 2015). OECD Publishing, Paris. http://www.
oecd-ilibrary.org/content/book/9789264226418-en
OECD (2016b) Total social spending, 1980–2012 (indicator). Accessed on 05 June 2016. https://
www.oecd.org/social/expenditure.htm
OECD (2019) Gross domestic spending on R&D (indicator). https://doi.org/10.1787/d8b068b4-en
Accessed on 01 July 2019
Reher DS (1998) Family ties in Western Europe: persistent contrasts. Popul Dev Rev 24(2):203–234
Sanders M, Stenkula M, Grilli L, Herrmann AM, Latifi G, Páger B, Szerb L, Terragno Bogliaccini E
(2020a) A Reform Strategy for Italy. In: Sanders M, Marx A, Stenkula M (eds) The entrepreneurial
society. Springer, Berlin Heidelberg
Sanders M, Stenkula M, Fritsch M, Herrmann AM, Latifi G, Páger B, Szerb L, Terragno Bogliaccini
E, Wyrwich M (2020b) A Reform Strategy for Germany. In: Sanders M, Marx A, Stenkula M
(eds) The entrepreneurial society. Springer, Berlin Heidelberg
Sanders M, Stenkula M, Dunstan J, Estrin S, Herrmann AM, Páger B, Szerb L, Terragno Bogliaccini
E (2020c) A Reform Strategy for the UK. In: Sanders M, Marx A, Stenkula M (eds) The
entrepreneurial society. Springer, Berlin Heidelberg
Scarpetta S (2014) Employment protection, IZA World of Labor, pp. 1–10. http://wol.iza.org/
articles/employment-protection.pdf
Schettkat R (2002) Regulation in the Dutch and German economies at the root of unemployment?
SCEPA working paper series. SCEPA’s main areas of research are macroeconomic policy,
inequality and poverty, and globalization. Schwartz Center for Economic Policy Analysis
(SCEPA), The New School. Accessed on 20 Dec 2015. https://ideas.repec.org/p/epa/cepawp/
2002-05.html
Scruggs L, Jahn D, Kuitto K (2014) Comparative welfare entitlements dataset 2. Version 2014−03.
University of Connecticut & University of Greiswald
Siebert H (1997) Labor market rigidities: at the root of unemployment in Europe. J Econ Perspect
11(3):37–54
Sluyterman K (ed) (2015) Varieties of capitalism and business history: the Dutch case. Routledge,
London and New York
Spadavecchia A (2005) Surviving under the shelter of government subsidies or ‘avoiding disaster’?
new evidence from Italian industrial districts, 1971–91, Working Papers 5011, Economic History
Society
Steier L (2003) Variants of agency contracts in family-financed ventures as a continuum of familial
altruistic and market rationalities. J Bus Ventur 18(5):597–618
Szerb L, Terjesen S, Rappai G (2007) Seeding new ventures—greenthumbs and fertile fields:
individual and environmental drivers of informal investment. Ventur Cap 9(4):257–284
Todd E (1985) The explanation of ideology: family structures and social system. Basil Blackwell,
Oxford
Todd E (2011) L’origine des systèmes familiaux, Tome 1: L’Eurasie. Gallimard, Paris
38 S. Dilli
Van Sluis J, Van Praag M, Vijverberg W (2008) Education and entrepreneurship selection and
performance: a review of the empirical literature. J Econ Surv 22(5):795–841
Van Zanden JL, Zuijderduijn J, De Moor T (2012) Small is beautiful: the efficiency of credit markets
in the late medieval Holland. Eur Rev Econ Hist 16:3–22
Visser J (2013) Wage bargaining institutions—from Crisis to Crisis. European economy—economic
paper. Directorate general economic and financial affairs (DG ECFIN), European Commission.
Accessed on 8 Feb 2016. https://ideas.repec.org/p/euf/ecopap/0488.html
Wadhwani RD (2016) Small-scale credit institutions. In: Cassis Y, Grossman RS, Schenk CR (eds)
The Oxford handbook of banking and financial history. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp
191–216
Westerhuis G (2016) Commercial banking: changing interactions between banks, markets, industry
and state. In: Cassis Y, Grossman RS, Schenk CR (eds) The Oxford handbook of banking and
financial history. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 110–163
World Bank (2013) Global financial development database. Accessed on 15 March 2017. http://
www.worldbank.org/en/publication/gfdr/data/global-financial-developmentdatabase
Open Access This chapter is licensed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0
International License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits use, sharing,
adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate
credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license and
indicate if changes were made.
The images or other third party material in this chapter are included in the chapter’s Creative
Commons license, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not
included in the chapter’s Creative Commons license and your intended use is not permitted by
statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from
the copyright holder.
Chapter 3
Economic Impact Assessment
of Entrepreneurship Policies
with the GMR-Europe Model
Abstract This chapter introduces the most recent version of the geographic macro
and regional (GMR) Europe model. The model estimates the economic impacts of
policies that aim at improving the quality of entrepreneurship ecosystems. As such,
GMR-Europe is the first available economic impact assessment model that estimates
the effects of entrepreneurship policies on several economic variables like productiv-
ity, GDP, employment, and wages. To measure the quality of regional entrepreneurial
ecosystems, GMR-Europe integrates the Regional Entrepreneurship and Develop-
ment Index (REDI) into its structure. In addition to introducing the GMR-Europe
This study was financed by the Financial and Institutional Reforms for an Entrepreneurial Society
(FIRES) that has received funding from the EU’s Horizon 2020 research and innovation program
under grant agreement No. 649378 and by the European Union and Hungary co-financed by the
European Social Fund through the project EFOP-3.6.2-16-2017-00017, titled “Sustainable, intelli-
gent and inclusive regional and city models”. The research has been conducted as part of the National
Excellence in Higher Education Program in Hungary (reference number of the contract: 20765-
3/2018/FEKUTSTRAT). The authors of this chapter are indebted to the following colleagues for
their invaluable assistance: Gallusz Abaligeti and Dániel Kehl, for their contribution to the empirical
calibration of the TFP model equations, Anna Csajkás and Richárd Farkas for their assistance in
data collection, data preparation and contribution to estimations and Péter Járosi, whose previous
engagement in model development and continuous assistance through this work is an inevitable
part of the present model setup. Laszlo Szerb and Attila Varga also gratefully acknowledge sup-
port from the National Scientific Research Fund of Hungary (OTKA/NKFI grant no. 120289 titled
Entrepreneurship and Competitiveness investigations in Hungary based on the Global Entrepreneur-
ship Monitor surveys 2017–2019). Thanks to Andrea Herrmann for comments on earlier drafts of
this chapter.
3.1 Introduction
1 We interpret institutions as formal and informal institutions that shape entrepreneurial attitudes of
The three sub-indices of attitudes (ATT), abilities (ABT), and aspiration (ASP)
constitute the entrepreneurship super-index, which is called REDI. All three sub-
indices contain four or five pillars, which can be interpreted as quasi-independent
building blocks of this entrepreneurship index. Each of the 14 pillars is the result of
the multiplication of an individual variable and an associated institutional variable.
In this case, institutional variables can be viewed as particular (region level) weights
of the individual variables. Table 3.1 provides a detailed picture of the sub-indices.
Unlike other EE approaches, REDI clearly defines how the different elements are
interrelated. REDI elements can have an additive (indicator level) or a multiplicative
(variable level) influence on the system performance. The novelty of this method
is that it portrays the entrepreneurial disparities among EU regions and provides
country and regional level, tailor-made public policy suggestions to improve the
level of entrepreneurship and optimize resource allocation over the different pillars
of entrepreneurship.
Entrepreneurship is defined as the interaction of entrepreneurial attitudes, abilities,
and aspirations. The penalty for bottleneck (PFB) methodology is developed for
measuring and quantifying these interactions (Rappai and Szerb 2011). A bottleneck
is defined as the worst performing element, the weakest link, or binding constraint in
the system. With respect to entrepreneurship, we define a bottleneck as a shortage, or
the lowest level of a particular entrepreneurial pillar as compared to other pillars. The
sub-indices are composed of four or five components, defined as pillars that should
be adjusted in a way that takes this notion of balance into account. After normalizing
the scores of all the pillars, the value of each pillar in a region is penalized by
linking it to the score of the pillar with the weakest performance in that region.
This simulates the notion of a bottleneck, and if the weakest pillar were improved,
the particular sub-index and ultimately the whole REDI would likewise show a
material improvement. On the contrary, improving a relatively high pillar value will
presumably enhance only the value of the pillar itself and cause a much smaller
increase of the whole REDI. Summarizing the REDI technique intuitively, it is an
index that combines information from many variables at the individual and regional
level, assumes that institutions complement individual action (multiplicative), while
for the total score the least performing elements weight more than the best ones, and
finally a well-balanced ecosystem without bottlenecks scores higher.
This notion of bottlenecks is important for policy purposes. Our model suggests
that attitudes, ability, and aspiration interact, and if they are out of balance, productive
entrepreneurship is inhibited. REDI has the capacity to demonstrate how resource
allocation can be optimized along the 14 pillars to improve the REDI score and,
ultimately, the regional entrepreneurship system performance. Moreover, the sys-
temic combination of the pillars influences the effectiveness of the ecosystem. An
improvement in the weakest pillar would produce an increase in the overall REDI
score. An EE with a homogeneous pillar configuration is viewed to be optimal (Szerb
et al. 2017). The Appendix provides a concise description of the REDI methodology.
Tables 3.2 and 3.3 below provide regional REDI values and country REDI scores
based on population-weighted average REDI scores.
3 Economic Impact Assessment of Entrepreneurship … 45
Table 3.3 shows, perhaps surprisingly, that Ireland leads, but the top ten com-
prise all the usual suspects in North-western Europe. This table, however, also hides
significant regional variation within these countries. As Table 3.2 shows, with some
interesting exceptions, the best performing entrepreneurial ecosystems in Europe are
typically found in densely populated urban centers in the North and North-western
parts of Europe. Stockholm, Helsinki, London, Paris, Amsterdam, and Berlin are all
Table 3.2 REDI values and ranks in the 125 EU regions (2012–2014)
46
Rank Region name REDI Rank Region name REDI Rank Region name REDI
1 Stockholm 78.3 43 North West (UK) 50.4 85 Illes Balears 34.3
2 Hovedstaden 76.6 44 Région wallonne 50.3 86 Region Pólnocno-Zachodni 34.2
3 London 75.5 45 Niedersachsen 50.3 87 Region Pólnocny 33.7
4 Southern and Eastern 71.3 46 Zahodna Slovenija 50.0 88 Centro (IT) 33.5
5 Île de France 70.8 47 Schleswig-Holstein 49.8 89 Nord-Ovest 33.5
6 Helsinki-Uusimaa 70.0 48 Westösterreich 49.0 90 Andalucía 33.2
7 South East (UK) 69.6 49 Länsi-Suomi 48.9 91 Lithuania 32.8
8 Hamburg 69.5 50 Sjalland 48.4 92 Cantabria 32.7
9 Sydsverige 65.8 51 Lisboa 48.1 93 Centro (PT) 32.7
10 West-Nederland 63.5 52 Südösterreich 47.6 94 Nord-Est 32.6
11 Bruxelles/Brussels 63.2 53 Ouest (FR) 46.6 95 Aragón 31.9
12 Berlin 62.4 54 Nord-Pas-de-Calais 46.4 96 Region Wschodni 31.8
13 South West (UK) 62.3 55 Småland med öarna 45.6 97 Közép-Magyarország 31.1
14 Baden-Württemberg 62.0 56 Est (FR) 45.5 98 Principado de Asturias 30.3
15 Syddanmark 61.6 57 Norra Mellansverige 45.5 99 Macroregiunea trei 29.9
16 Bayern 60.6 58 Méditerranée 45.4 100 Galicia 29.5
17 Scotland 60.5 59 Estonia 45.3 101 Región de Murcia 29.3
18 Border, Midland and Western 60.4 60 Rheinland-Pfalz 44.6 102 Canarias (ES) 29.2
19 Östra Mellansverige 59.9 61 North East (UK) 44.3 103 Attiki 28.3
20 Västsverige 59.8 62 Bratislavsky kraj 44.2 104 La Rioja 28.2
21 Hessen 58.9 63 Bassin Parisien 44.1 105 Západné Slovensko 26.7
(continued)
A. Varga et al.
Table 3.2 (continued)
Rank Region name REDI Rank Region name REDI Rank Region name REDI
22 East of England 58.7 64 Pohjois-ja Ita-Suomi 43.2 106 Isole 26.7
23 Center-Est (FR) 58.5 65 Vzhodna Slovenija 43.0 107 Stredné Slovensko 26.5
24 Midtjylland 58.2 66 Region Centralny 43.0 108 Extremadura 26.1
25 East Midlands (UK) 57.9 67 Thüringen 41.1 109 Macroregiunea unu 26.1
26 Zuid-Nederland 57.6 68 Cataluna 40.9 110 Vychodné Slovensko 26.0
27 Bremen 57.1 69 Region Poludniowy 40.5 111 Sud 25.7
28 Ostösterreich 56.9 70 Mecklenburg-Vorpommern 40.2 112 Kontinentalna Hrvatska 25.6
29 Saarland 56.7 71 Mellersta Norrland 39.9 113 Castilla-la Mancha 24.7
30 Nordjylland 56.5 72 País Vasco 38.8 114 Jadranska Hrvatska 23.5
31 Noord-Nederland 55.3 73 Czech Republic 38.8 115 Macroregiunea patru 22.3
32 Northern Ireland (UK) 55.0 74 Sachsen-Anhalt 38.2 116 Voreia Ellada 22.0
33 Nordrhein-Westfalen 54.8 75 Sud-Ouest (FR) 37.6 117 Nyugat-Dunántúl 21.7
3 Economic Impact Assessment of Entrepreneurship …
in the top ten of European regions. But the countries scoring high in Table 3.3 also
have regions in the middle range of the regional ranking.
able to track the widespread effects of the initial interventions. The key link through
which entrepreneurship is integrated into the GMR-Europe model is the REDI intro-
duced above. Entrepreneurship policies are assumed to affect the REDI in separate
regions, while the changes in REDI set in motion the GMR-Europe model simulating
the likely effects of such an exogenous improvement in the regional entrepreneurial
ecosystems.
Models frequently applied in development policy analysis are neither geographic nor
regional. They either follow the tradition of macro econometric modeling (like the
HERMIN model—ESRI 2002), the tradition of macro Computable General Equilib-
rium (CGE) modeling (like the ECOMOD model—Bayar 2007), or the most recently
developed Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) approach (QUEST
III—Ratto et al. 2009). They also bear the common attribute of national-level spa-
tial aggregation. The novel feature of the GMR approach is that it incorporates
geographic effects (e.g., agglomeration, interregional trade, migration) while both
macro and regional impacts of policies are simulated.
Geography plays a critical role in the effectiveness of development policies for
at least four major reasons. First, interventions are implemented at a certain point
in space, and their impacts might spill over to proximate locations to a consider-
able extent. Second, the initial impacts could be significantly amplified or reduced
by short-run (static) agglomeration effects. Third, cumulative long-run processes,
resulting from labor and capital migration, may further amplify or reduce the initial
impacts in the region resulting in a change of the spatial structure of the economy
(dynamic agglomeration effects). Fourth, as a consequence of the above effects, dif-
ferent spatial patterns of interventions might result in significantly different growth
and convergence/divergence patterns.
“Regions” are spatial reference points in the GMR approach. They are sub-
national spatial units ideally at that level of geographic aggregation which is appro-
priate to capture proximity relations in innovation. Besides intraregional interactions,
the model captures interregional connections such as knowledge flows expand-
ing over regional borders (scientific networking or spatially mediated spillovers),
interregional trade, and migration of production factors.
The “macro” level is also important when the impact of policies is modeled:
fiscal and monetary policy, national regulations, or various international effects
are all potentially relevant factors when calculating these impacts. As a result, the
model system simulates the effects of policy interventions both at the regional and
macroeconomic level. Depending on the question of interest, the macroeconomic
level in the GMR-Europe model can be considered as national economies, the whole
coverage of EU countries within the model, or both. With this approach, different
scenarios can be compared on the basis of their impacts on economic growth and
interregional convergence.
50 A. Varga et al.
The GMR framework is built around three interconnected model blocks: the TFP
block which is responsible for simulating changes in regional productivity levels, the
SCGE block which ensures a cross-regional equilibrium and provides estimations
for region-level economic variables like output and employment, and finally the
MACRO block which provides the dynamics of economic variables and simulates
aggregate level effects of policy interventions.
TFP is one of the most important variables in GMR-Europe. It represents the main
point through which different aspects of innovation, and innovation policy inter-
ventions in particular, interact with other parts of the model. The TFP block serves
as the point in the GMR system where different driving factors behind innovation,
especially entrepreneurial activity, are modeled. Then, in line with the traditions in
economic modeling, the impact of these factors is implemented in the MACRO and
3 Economic Impact Assessment of Entrepreneurship … 51
Fig. 3.1 Schematic structure of the TFP block. Source Authors’ own compilation
SCGE blocks through one technology variable, generally referred to as total factor
productivity, or TFP.
Figure 3.1 illustrates the setup of the TFP block in GMR-Europe. TFP is the final
variable which transfers impacts generated in the TFP block over to the other parts
of the model, namely the SCGE block and the MACRO block. However, the main
role of the TFP block is to provide a sophisticated background for determining TFP
and implement innovation-oriented policy interventions, including those targeting
entrepreneurship.
The TFP block is based on the knowledge production function approach, where
new knowledge, represented by patent applications in our model setup, is produced
using knowledge production factors, namely R&D efforts and labor (employment),
as well as already existing knowledge which is represented by national patent stock
(knowledge creation and TFP are directly modeled at the regional level). In addition
to this standard approach, we also include the role of knowledge available through
interregional networks, using the Ego Network Quality index (Sebestyén and Varga
2013) which is assumed to affect the productivity of R&D in knowledge creation
(better network positions lead to higher knowledge output for the same amount of
inputs). New knowledge, in this case patent applications at the regional level, then
feeds back into knowledge creation in a dynamic way by building up the national
patent stock.
TFP is primarily linked to the regional knowledge levels in the model, but two
additional forces are assumed to determine regional TFP. First, the level of human
capital in the region affects TFP and second, a focal element of this setup of the GMR
model, we added the entrepreneurial environment measured by REDI to the model.
52 A. Varga et al.
We assumed REDI to have a positive influence on TFP via enhancing the contribution
of human capital to TFP. This formulation is inspired by the knowledge spillover
theory of entrepreneurship (Acs et al. 2009). As entrepreneurs transfer knowledge
to economic applications, a better entrepreneurial climate in a region intensifies
new firm formation and helps to better exploit the knowledge embodied in human
capital, which eventually leads to increasing total factor productivity. This is the point
where the REDI feeds into the GMR-Europe model; productive entrepreneurship is
measured by the REDI, and policy interventions that improve the entrepreneurial
ecosystem are assumed to affect this variable which then sets in motion the TFP
block, inducing changes in regional productivity levels as well as economic activity
in the targeted region and elsewhere.
The TFP block consists of econometrically estimated equations. First, the patent
equation describes how certain variables depicted in Fig. 3.1 affect regional patenting:
log PATt,r = α + β1 log PATSCKNt−1,N + β2 log EMPt−1,r
+ β3 log RD_TOTALt−1,r
+ β4 log RD_TOTALt−1,r log ENQFPt−1,r + εt,rPAT
(3.1)
Patents on the left-hand side are measured by EPO patent applications (PAT),
national patent stock is the cumulative number of patents at the country level
(PATSCKN), research and development efforts are proxied with R&D expenditures
(RD_TOTAL), employment is captured by the total level of employment in the region
(EMP), and network quality is measured with the ENQ index (Sebestyén and Varga
2013), calculated over the network of Framework Program partnerships between
regions (ENQFP). The patent equation (Eq. 3.1) potentially contains endogeneity
through network formation, employment, and R&D as these factors may be shaped
by patenting in a region just as well as shaping it. We designed the equations with a
one period (year) lag in order to overcome this problem to a certain extent.
Second, the TFP equation describes how certain variables (as shown in Fig. 3.1)
affect regional productivity:
log TFPt,r = α + β1 log PATSCKRt−1,r + β2 log HUMCAPt−1,r
+ β3 log HUMCAPt−1,r REDIt−1,r + εt,r
TFP
(3.2)
2 It could be argued that a reasonable alternative of the TFP equation would be a specification where
REDI interacts with the regional patent stock. However, there is a very important distinction between
the two forms of knowledge (human capital and accumulated knowledge stock) in the Romerian
knowledge production function framework, and this distinction is followed in our specifications
3 Economic Impact Assessment of Entrepreneurship … 53
The quality of the entrepreneurial ecosystem is measured by the REDI.3 The TFP on
the left-hand side is estimated using a standard production function approach with
capital and labor.
After estimating the two equations of the TFP block, we have a system of equations
which is able to simulate the effects of different interventions affecting research and
development, human capital, networking, or the entrepreneurial climate on regional
TFP. One drawback of this system is that the estimated coefficients which drive these
impacts are common across all regions in the model, reflecting average tendencies
in the sample of regions. However, one may argue that due to the large differences
in the development level as well as the sociocultural and institutional context of
European regions, mechanisms through which different interventions affect regional
productivities differ largely across regions. We control for these differences in two
ways. First, in both equations, the interaction terms render the respective marginal
effects of R&D, human capital, network quality, and entrepreneurship development
level region-specific. Second, we augment this heterogeneity with a specific cali-
bration process through which region-specific parameters are calculated through an
optimization process to improve model fit. This second method is discussed briefly
below.
Given the observed data, we fit linear trends on these data points for all variables,
except regional and national patent stocks (the former is directly given by the patent
equation and the latter is calculated by summing up regional patent stocks in every
period). After trend fitting, we extrapolate the trend for out-of-sample years. These
trends constitute the baseline of the TFP block. After extrapolating trend values for
all variables in the TFP block, we perform the regressions on these data points as
well. Coefficients estimated on the historical data and coefficients estimated on the
trend data closely approximate each other.
The coefficients estimated on the trend data constitute the basis of region-specific
parameter calibrations in the next step. The aim of the calibration is to find region-
specific values for selected parameters, which improve the overall fit of the model.
After a careful selection procedure among several model versions, three coefficients
of the TFP block, namely the constant term and the coefficient of employment in
the patent equation (parameters α and β2 ) and the constant term in the TFP equation
of the equations in the TFP block (Romer 1990). The stock of patents represents accumulated
knowledge that is available in the region for potential economic applications, whereas human
capital refers to knowledge which is actually present in the region being embodied in qualified
labor. Therefore, the stock of knowledge plays a passive role in technology development, whereas
human capital is the one that contributes actively to regional productivity improvements. In our
formulation of the TFP equation, this role is enhanced by the quality of the regional entrepreneurial
ecosystem. With a higher quality of this ecosystem, the same level of human capital contributes to a
more intensive increase in TFP via more active involvement of human capital in new firm formation.
3 As described in Sect. 3.2, the REDI is a complex index that accounts for several features of the
entrepreneurial ecosystem. Due to this complexity, some of the variables that appear in the GMR
model also play a role in the REDI. However, these variables are interactive with several others, and
throughout the pillar system, the correlation of the REDI super-index with any single component
variable is small.
54 A. Varga et al.
(parameter α), are calibrated.4 As a result of this calibration process, we are presented
with region-specific parameter values for the listed three parameters of the TFP block
which improve the fit of the TFP block equations and retain the average tendencies
represented by the trend-based estimation. In this way, we obtain region-specific
mechanisms built in the TFP block with respect to the effects of right-hand side
variables on patenting activity and the productivity of the regions.
The SCGE model block draws on regional productivity changes and then simulates
the likely impacts of these changes on regional economic variables like output, prices,
wages, and employment. SCGE models add the spatial dimension to the (usually
a-spatial) CGE models. Economic units are regions, which are interconnected by
trade flows and migration. The most important feature of this block is that it takes
into account interactions across regions through the trade of goods and services as
well as the mobility of production factors. Also, transportation costs are explicitly
accounted for and positive and/or negative agglomeration effects are also part of the
model structure.
The model distinguishes between short-run and long-run equilibria. In the short
run, markets are in equilibrium within and across all regions. However, this does
not necessarily mean that the whole regional system has reached a balanced situa-
tion. In the long run, differences in utility levels across regions induce labor migra-
tion, followed by the migration of capital, leading to a long-run spatial equilibrium
where interregional utility differences are eliminated. Although possible in princi-
ple, this equilibrium is hardly reached within the applied simulation horizon, leaving
considerable gaps in utility levels in the simulated outcomes.
The macroeconomic block of the GMR approach serves two purposes. First, this is
the point, where aggregate relationships and policies, such as exchange rate toward
the rest of the world, inflation, monetary, and fiscal policy, can be handled. Second,
4 This results in an optimization procedure where the objective function is the sum of the follow-
ing five elements: (1) Mean average percentage error of the regional patent application variable
(average percentage deviation of simulated PATi,t values from the trend values). (2) Mean aver-
age percentage error of the TFP variable (average percentage deviation of simulated TFPi,t values
from the trend values). (3) Mean average percentage error of the average calibrated region-specific
constant terms in the patent equation (average percentage deviation of calibrated constant terms
from the trend-based estimated values). (4) Mean average percentage error of the average calibrated
region-specific coefficient of employment in the patent equation (average percentage deviation of
calibrated coefficients from the trend-based estimated values). (5) Mean average percentage error
of the average calibrated region-specific constant terms in the TFP equation (average percentage
deviation of calibrated constant terms from the trend-based estimated values).
5 This section reiterates a short passage that was published in Varga et al. (2018).
3 Economic Impact Assessment of Entrepreneurship … 55
it provides dynamics to the otherwise static SCGE block. In the latter, regional
productivity, labor, and capital stocks are exogenous. The TFP block provides the
dynamics of regional productivity levels, but in order to account for the possible
employment and investment effects of the simulated policies, we need to provide
dynamics for labor and capital stocks of the regions. This is performed by the MACRO
block, which provides an aggregate estimation of the likely employment and capital
stock impacts of the simulated policies, and are then broken down to the regions in
function of the regional productivity growth rates.
The macroeconomic block of GMR-Europe calculates policy impacts at the EU
and national level while the 181-region NUTS2-level TFP and SCGE blocks provide
results at the regional level. The model calculates the policy impacts on various
economic variables such as GDP, employment, investment, prices at the regional,
national, and aggregate European levels.
The macroeconomic block is a standard, large-scale Dynamic, Stochastic, Gen-
eral Equilibrium (DSGE) model. We apply the QUEST III model developed by the
European Commission for the Euro area and re-estimated it with additional coun-
tries to cover the same set of regions as those represented in the other two model
blocks. Therefore, the set of countries include the Euro-countries and some Eastern
European countries that are not part of the monetary union. The description of the
original model can be found in Ratto et al. (2009), while the re-estimated version is
described in Varga et al. (2018).
The three mutually connected model blocks are depicted in Fig. 3.2. Without inter-
ventions, the TFP growth rate is assumed to follow an exogenous and identical
steady state growth rate in every region, and the economy grows on a balanced
growth path primarily driven by the MACRO block. If any exogenous shocks are
fed into the model, it leaves this balanced growth path, and we can examine how the
policy-induced shocks affect the path of the economy compared to the steady state
path.
Given its setup, the GMR-Europe model is able to handle several types of policy
interventions, as shown on the left-hand side of Fig. 3.2. Different macroeconomic
policies, such as inflation targeting, other aspects of monetary policy, general fiscal
expansion, and different tax-related policies, are applied at the macro level, directly
affecting the MACRO block, while their effects spill over to other model parts as
well. Other policies apply at the regional level. These may include investment support
or public infrastructure development, which directly affects the (private or public)
capital stock in specific regions. Through the interconnected model setup, these
interventions then affect economic activity in other regions as well. Finally, there are
policies which directly affect the TFP block. These are interventions which have an
effect on regional productivity, like supporting education, R&D, network formation,
56 A. Varga et al.
Fig. 3.2 Regional and macroeconomic impacts of the main policy variables in the GMR-Europe
model. Numbers refer to the steps of the impact mechanism of policy interventions. Source Authors’
own compilation
4. For every year, changes in TFP are aggregated to the national level, which
increases TFP in the MACRO model as time-specific shocks (link 4).
The macroeconomic model calculates the changes in all affected variables
at the national level;
5. Changes in employment and investment calculated in the MACRO block are
distributed over the regions following the spatial pattern of TFP impacts (link 5);
6. The SCGE model runs again with the new employment and capital values to
calculate short-run and long-run equilibrium values of the affected variables
(links 3, 2a, and 2b are used again);
7. The process described in steps 5 and 6 continues until aggregate values of
regional variables calculated in the SCGE model get sufficiently close (less
than 10−10 percentage deviation) to their corresponding values calculated in the
MACRO model. This solution ensures consistent simulation results across the
different model blocks. Also, our experience shows that convergence is always
achieved and within a very limited number of iterations.
The following simulations illustrate the potential use of the GMR-Europe model in
evaluating reforms which aim to strengthen the entrepreneurial society. In principle,
it would be possible to simulate the effects of a differentiated and tailored strategy to
improve regional entrepreneurial ecosystems as, for example, presented in Chaps. 5–
7 in this volume (Sanders et al. 2020a, b, c). In this chapter, the aim is to illustrate
how our model setup works, and we therefore focus on how a common shock to the
REDI score would be transmitted in the GMR framework. Results show that there are
differences in the extent to which an equi-proportional increase in the REDI scores
affects regional productivities. Moreover, the dynamic feedback mechanisms within
the model generate diverse paths for regional output levels in response to such a
shock.
2. For every region, we then calculate the average of the baseline REDI scores over
the simulation years (2012–2031) and define 1% of these average scores as a
policy intervention (technically an exogenous shock to the model);
3. This 1% improvement is applied to the REDI in every region in a way that the
REDI is increased from its baseline value to a 5% higher value through the first
5 years of the simulation (2012–2016). Note that after five years the value of the
REDI does not change meaning that the annual improvements in REDI result in
a permanent positive effect on the quality of EE in every NUTS2 region;
4. Every region receives this 1% annual improvement in the REDI, and we trace
their effect on regional TFP and GDP levels as well as aggregate country-level
versions of these variables.
Of course, focusing on the REDI provides a bird-eye view on entrepreneurial poli-
cies. We can interpret the idea behind these simulations as follows: What is the eco-
nomic impact of a five percent improvement of the entrepreneurial climate/ecosystem
in each region over a five-year period? We use this counterfactual simulation as a first
approximation and for illustrative purposes, but emphasize that the detailed structure
of the REDI allows the model to account for more detailed approaches in this respect.
Overall, these simulations reflect the potential effects of policies which are capable
of improving the entrepreneurial ecosystem of a region by adjusting either of the
pillars behind the REDI. It is important to underline that the equality of the shocks
(in percentage terms) implies regional divergence in our simulations. The impact of a
REDI shock depends most importantly on the size of the REDI (i.e., the development
level of the regional entrepreneurial ecosystem) and on the size of human capital in
the region. Therefore, many highly entrepreneurial regions with strong human capital
gain more from the shock than their less developed counterparts. One should realize
that the same percentage increase in the REDI score cannot be the consequence of
regionally balanced policy interventions, and, indeed, the improvement of the quality
of the ecosystem in more entrepreneurial places probably requires more effort than
in less developed regions.
Although the model is capable of tracking many regional and aggregate level vari-
ables, we focus on the effect of the REDI improvement on total factor productivity
(TFP) and GDP. In both cases, we present the percentage deviation of the simulated
TFP/GDP values after the applied interventions from their baseline levels. As a result,
the diagrams reflect the percentage impact of these policies, or, to what extent would
TFP and GDP be higher/lower as a result of the policy intervention, compared to the
no intervention (business as usual) case.
In Fig. 3.3, we summarize the country-level results of the simulations. On the
left-hand side, the country-level impacts are shown for TFP, while on the right-
hand side the time averages of the GDP impacts are depicted for countries. The
3 Economic Impact Assessment of Entrepreneurship … 59
Fig. 3.3 Country-level impacts of 1% annual shocks over a five-year period to REDI on TFP and
GDP. Source Authors’ own compilation
horizontal lines show the EU-average impacts. The graphic shows that a 1% annual
improvement in the entrepreneurial climate over 5 years in every region leads to
a 2% increase in TFP and productivity on average (EU level). The GDP impact
is slightly higher, but the productivity and GDP effects go hand in hand. This is
not surprising, as in the simulations, the shock has its effect through enhancing
regional productivity. Figure 3.3 also shows that the positive development in the
entrepreneurial environment of regions positively affects the productivity levels in
all countries. However, there are differences in the magnitude of this effect. While
Ireland benefits the most from this policy, Hungary seems to be performing worst
in this respect. This corresponds with the initial ranking of regions and countries in
Tables 3.2 and 3.3.
In the dynamic analysis of policy impacts, we zoom in on the mechanisms in
the case of four countries representing the four types of capitalism: Ireland (a Lib-
eral Market Economy), Germany (a Coordinated Market Economy), Hungary (an
Eastern Market Economy), and Italy (a Mediterranean Market Economy). Although,
GDP impacts follow the TFP impacts quite closely, as seen from Fig. 3.4, there are
considerable qualitative differences in the time path of the effects. In some countries,
although the overall effect of the policy is positive, after the “lifting” power of the
policy (first 5 years) phases out, the impacts tend to decrease compared to the peak
year. This effect is due to the complex mechanisms within the GMR model where
Fig. 3.4 Dynamics of impacts of annual 1% shocks over a five-year period to REDI on TFP and
GDP in the selected countries. Source Authors’ own compilation
60 A. Varga et al.
productivity growth and the resulting economic development affect and feed back to
that of other regions through trade and factor mobility. These feedback mechanisms
may result in out-migration or capital flight which negatively affects the growth of
some regions.
In order to better understand the impact mechanism behind these results, it is
useful to distinguish all steps of the mechanism. First, the impact of the initial REDI
improvement has a one-year lag on TFP and GDP changes. Thus, interventions
between 2012 and 2016 have direct productivity and economic effects between 2013
and 2017. Second, the initial level of entrepreneurship is a defining factor in the
changes in productivity since the same increase of the REDI index in entrepreneuri-
ally developed regions means a much higher absolute change in the REDI and a
similarly higher productivity change as a consequence. Third, the direct short-run
GDP and TFP impacts are heavily dependent on the level of human capital endow-
ment in regions. Regions with higher levels of human capital are capable of taking
more productivity and economic advantage from a higher-quality entrepreneurial
ecosystem. If the levels of entrepreneurship and human capital stock are large in
a region, the short-run economic impacts are large as well. In Fig. 3.4, this means
that the slope of the curves is higher than the EU average during the 5 years of the
interventions. Fourth, some other aspects, such as investment, have to be considered
in the long run. The direct impacts of REDI last until 2017 since after 2016 there is no
further improvement in the entrepreneurial ecosystem. However, economic impacts
are still observed in years that follow. We especially experience further increase of
growth in 2018. This indirect impact is caused by the increased capital stock due to
the additional investment that is possible as a result of increased income and saving
caused by the positive effects of entrepreneurship development policy, since there is
a two-year time lag between REDI changes and the effects of investment decisions.
As a result of improvements in the entrepreneurial ecosystem, income changes in the
next period and as a result of this change in income investment will increase, result-
ing in a larger capital stock available for production two years later. Finally, human
capital accumulation also affects the results in the long run (after the interventions),
as it follows different trends in the regions.
After 2018, the path of GDP and TFP changes less rapidly. In many countries,
these paths are stabilizing to a long-run growth path. However, some countries are
able to further increase their growth rate even in the long run, while others lose
some of the initial gains of entrepreneurship policy. The long-run growth paths are
influenced by many factors, but productivity is still a key variable in this process
which is heavily influenced by the changes in human capital stock. Countries that
are characterized by a high rate of human capital accumulation can grow faster in the
long run than the average. In contrast, low human capital accumulation reduces the
growth rate in the long run, and those countries might face a slowing growth path.
These effects are further influenced by interregional migration and changes in trade
as well.
In addition, the interplay between the growth and substitution effects of TFP
improvement might play a role in regional GDP impacts. In cases when demand
for output does not increase, firms might use less inputs resulting from productivity
3 Economic Impact Assessment of Entrepreneurship … 61
improvement. As a result of that some regions might lose some of their employment
in the long run. Thus, even if a region experiences an improvement in TFP, it does
not necessarily mean that the region will grow faster than others with less impressive
TFP growth.
As shown in Fig. 3.4, Ireland is capable of benefitting most from the REDI
improvements, in terms of TFP and GDP. Ireland is characterized by the highest level
of REDI among the countries in the model, thus in absolute terms, the Irish shock will
be the largest as well. This is accompanied by a relatively high level (significantly
higher than average) of human capital. These two factors and the description of the
impact mechanism above can explain why Ireland’s TFP and GDP increase so much
under the five years of the intervention. In the long run, Ireland has one of the high-
est rates of human capital accumulation, which drives the long-run impacts after the
interventions. All these factors contribute to the predicted success of entrepreneurship
development policy in Ireland.
Germany also gains much from the improvement of the REDI scores. The initial
levels of REDI and human capital are somewhat smaller than in case of Ireland. Thus
the growth of productivity and GDP under the first 5 years is lower but still above
the other two less developed countries. In the long run, we have shown that human
capital accumulation drives economic growth. The German path clearly illustrates
that slow human capital accumulation is not enough to maintain the initial economic
impacts of the shock.
At the same time, Italy and Hungary have similar, lower-level growth paths.
Although Italy has a higher level of initial REDI, this advantage is partially com-
pensated by the higher average regional human capital stock in Hungary. As a con-
sequence, in the first five years, Italy grows only slightly faster than Hungary. In the
long run, both the Hungarian and Italian paths approach the German growth path due
to the higher level of human capital accumulation. Again, the Italian accumulation is
slightly higher than the Hungarian one, so a small gap can be found in the long-run
economic development paths of these countries.
Migration also contributes to the determination of these growth paths. While
Germany is capable of attracting new labor force in the short run due to its high growth
potential in the first five years, Hungary and Italy lose some of their labor forces.
This effect, however, is weakened significantly in the long run when the German
growth advantage disappears, and Hungary and Italy catch up. As mentioned before,
Ireland has the highest level of capital accumulation, thus economic and productivity
impacts are further increased in the long run which, as a consequence, generates more
immigration strengthening the positive effects.
At the regional level, the same impact mechanism drives the economic effects,
but in that case the differences are more pronounced since the national impacts
can be interpreted as a weighted average of the regional effects. Thus, by looking
at the regional impacts, one can have a much more detailed picture of the spatial
effects of entrepreneurship policies. Figure 3.5 shows the regional breakdown of the
simulated impacts. As can be seen, GDP impacts (on the right-hand side) follow the
productivity impacts (on the left-hand side), but there are considerable differences
between regions. In most of the cases, we see that central, more developed regions
62 A. Varga et al.
Fig. 3.5 Regional impacts of 1% annual REDI shocks over a five-year period on regional TFP and
GDP levels. Source Authors’ own compilation
(Ireland, southern Germany, northern regions, capital cities, French regions) gain
more from the improvement in REDI. The complex interaction mechanisms in the
GMR model are visible at the regional level, marked by significant differences in
regional impacts and especially in favor of central regions. Due to their economic
weight, these regions are able to attract production factors in the long run, eventually
implying improvements in less developed regions. However, we can also see that
in the long run, improving the entrepreneurial ecosystem can be successful in less
developed regions, as some Polish, Greek, and some parts of Romania are able to
catch up.
Turning our attention to the regions of the four selected countries, we can identify
strong regional differences in the effectiveness of entrepreneurship policies. First,
since Ireland consists only of one region in our model, we cannot give a more detailed
analysis of spatial economic impacts. As described previously, entrepreneurship
policy is extremely effective in Ireland both in the short and the long run.
In Germany, we see that the less developed, eastern part gains the least in eco-
nomic and productivity improvement. This is due to the fact that the majority of these
regions are characterized by low initial REDI scores and low human capital accu-
mulation. Even in the slowly growing areas, central places like Berlin are capable
of growing around the EU average thanks to the concentration of human capital and
entrepreneurial activities (REDI).
The southern, more developed part of the country is mainly characterized by
a developed entrepreneurship ecosystem (high REDI) and with some variation, and
exceptions, the majority of regions has high level and accumulation of human capital
(in some regions only one of these factors are given), which makes them very suc-
cessful in terms of economic impacts. However, some regions are not able to translate
all of the productivity changes into GDP growth since other factors play a significant
3 Economic Impact Assessment of Entrepreneurship … 63
role. For example, in Stuttgart, productivity improvements might substitute for labor
which can mitigate the growth potential to some extent.
Regions in the countries located in the East of the EU are more diverse. In general,
they all excel at some determining factors of the policy, but they do not excel in all of
them which means that they are not able to generate exceptionally high productivity
and economic growth. In some cases, judging the factors behind regional growth
changes can be straightforward since all the influencing factors contribute to growth
in the same direction. In Hungary, which has a highly concentrated spatial structure,
Budapest is characterized by the highest level of both human capital and REDI. As
a consequence, this region is the most potent in terms of the short-run impacts. In
the long run, both human capital accumulation and the substitution effect must be
considered. In the case of Budapest, accumulation is also the highest in the country
which increases the growth path of Budapest in the long run. This growth is only
slightly reduced by the substitution effect described above. Still our result suggests
that the TFP effect is slightly below the EU average, while the GDP effect is around
the EU average. Outside the capital, however, due to the lack of foundations, we see
only limited potential of entrepreneurial development policies.
Finally, Italy has a traditionally divided spatial economic structure. We find again
that the core regions can benefit the most from entrepreneurial policies. This concerns
mainly northern Italian regions (like Lombardy and the capital with some neighbor-
ing regions). If we look behind these results, we can state that northern, developed
regions benefit from both the high level of human capital and entrepreneurship, while
regions around the capital are less developed in terms of entrepreneurship, but still
concentrate a high stock of human capital. Compared to EU averages, however, these
nationally high values are not high enough to provide the basis for significant eco-
nomic growth at the EU level. Our simulations also show that southern regions that
are far from the capital have a low chance of benefitting significantly from these
policies due to their low level of development, both in terms of entrepreneurship and
human capital.
3.5 Conclusions
Policy interventions and their impacts have always been in the center of interest. Over
the decades, economists have developed various tools to estimate the ex-ante impact
as well as to evaluate the ex-post effects of policy interventions. Simple econometric
regression models are able to test the significance of a policy instrument based on the
ceteris paribus assumption. However, these uniform suggestions neglect the likely
diverse effects of policy interventions as well as the potential complex impact of a
particular policy element on other influential factors. Simultaneous regressions could
handle the complex effect of closely related factors. However, the one-size-fits-all
policy recommendations remain an open issue.
Many entrepreneurship scholars believe that improving the entrepreneurial
ecosystem contributes positively to economic growth, development, job creation, and
64 A. Varga et al.
research could easily go into more detail and simulate more specific and realistic
interventions. REDI-based policy recommendations are built on the so-called sys-
tem failure improvement that is an analogy to classical public policy aiming to correct
market failures. That is, policymakers could target policies at improving the weakest
link in the regional ecosystem, giving them endogenous REDI improvements that can
then be simulated as was shown. In Chaps. 5–7 in this volume (Sanders et al. 2020a,
b, c), we illustrate how REDI can be used to diagnose and inform a reform strategy
for Italy, Germany, and the UK, respectively. The GMR simulations in this chapter
have shown that such tailored reforms are likely to cause heterogeneous effects across
regions. A limitation of the REDI is that the interventions that can be studied under
the proposed framework remain limited to those that affect aspects of the ecosystem
represented in the REDI. We believe the processes and mechanisms in the GMR are
important to consider, and the present model setup can generate testable hypotheses.
Future research could rigorously and empirically test the assumed structures and
specifications in the REDI-extended GMR model.
2. The construction of the pillars: We calculate all pillars from the variables using
the interaction variable method, that is, by multiplying the individual variable
with the proper institutional variable. This results in pillar values for all the 125
EU regions.
n
xi,k j − n ȳ j = 0 (3.7)
i=1
It can be seen, based on previous conditions and derivatives, that the function
is decreasing and convex, meaning it can be quickly solved using the well-
known Newton–Raphson method with an initial guess of 0. After obtaining k,
the computations are straightforward. Note that if
x̄ j < ȳ j k < 1
x̄ j = ȳ j k = 1
x̄ j > ȳ j k > 1
The penalizing feature reflects the belief that the entrepreneurial performance of
each region is mainly determined by its weakest component(s), and all other pil-
lars with higher values cannot exploit their full potential because of the existence
of bottleneck in their system of entrepreneurship.
7. Sub-index calculation: The pillars are the basic building blocks of the sub-
index. There are three: entrepreneurial attitudes, entrepreneurial abilities, and
entrepreneurial aspirations. The value of a sub-index for any region is the penalty
weighted average of its average equalized pillars for that sub-index multiplied by
100. The maximum value of the sub-indices is 100 and the potential minimum is
0, both of which reflect the relative position of a region in a particular sub-index.
5
ATTi = 100 h i, j (3.9a)
j=1
9
ABTi = 100 h i, j (3.9b)
j=6
14
ASPi = 100 h i, j (3.9c)
j=10
8. REDI score calculation: The super-index, the REDI, is the simple average
of the three sub-indices. Since 100 represents the theoretically available limit,
the GEDI points can also be interpreted as a measure of the efficiency of the
entrepreneurship inputs
1
REDIi = (ATTi + ABTi + ASPi ) (3.10)
3
where REDIi is the Regional Entrepreneurship and Development Index score of
region i
i = 1, 2, …, n = the number of regions.
68 A. Varga et al.
From the policy perspective, REDI methodology has two key features. The first
is the average equalization methodology (Point 5) that is designed to equalize
the marginal effects of the additional inputs over the average of 14 pillars while
keeping all the values in the [0,1] range. This means that after transformation,
below average (0.49) pillar values increased (Opportunity Perception, Network-
ing, Technology Absorption, Human Capital and Finance) and all the other pillar
values decreased. Consequently, improving the originally below average pillar
value requires a smaller absolute increase of additional inputs as compared to
the originally higher average pillar value where a larger increase is necessary for
the same marginal improvement.
References
Acs ZJ, Audretsch DB, Braunerhjelm P, Carlsson B (2009) The knowledge spillover theory of
entrepreneurship. Small Bus Econ 32:15–30
Acs ZJ, Autio E, Szerb L (2014) National systems of entrepreneurship: measurement issues and
policy implications. Res Policy 43:476–494. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2013.08.016
Acs Z, Estrin S, Mickiewicz T, Szerb L (2017) Institutions, entrepreneurship and growth: the role
of national entrepreneurial ecosystems. Small Bus Econ (Forthcoming)
Alvedalen J, Boschma R (2017) A critical review of entrepreneurial ecosystems research: towards
a future research agenda. Eur Plan Stud 25:887–903. https://doi.org/10.1080/09654313.2017.
1299694
Anselin L, Varga A, Acs Z (1997) Local geographic spillovers between university research and high
technology innovations. J Urban Econ. 42(3):422–448
Audretsch DB, Kuratko DF, Link AN (2015) Making sense of the elusive paradigm of entrepreneur-
ship. Small Bus Econ 45(4):703–712
Autio E, Pathak S, Wennberg K (2013) Consequences of cultural practices for entrepreneurial
behaviors. J Int Bus Stud 44(4):334–362
Baum JR, Frese M, Baron RA (2014) Born to be an entrepreneur? Revisiting the personality
approach to entrepreneurship. In: The psychology of entrepreneurship. Psychology Press, pp
73–98
Baumol WJ (1996) Entrepreneurship: productive, unproductive, and destructive. J Bus Ventur
11(1):3–22
Bayar A (2007) Simulation of R&D investment scenarios and calibration of the impact on a set of
multi-country models. European Commission DG JRC Institute for Prospective Technological
Studies (IPTS)
Bradley J (2006) Evaluating the impact of european union cohesion policy in less-developed
countries and regions. Reg Stud 40:189–199
ESRI (2002) An examination of the ex-post macroeconomic impacts of CSF 1994–1999 on
Objective 1 countries and regions
Fujita M, Krugman PR, Venables AJ (1999) The spatial economy: cities, regions and international
trade. Wiley Online Library
Gartner WB (1985) A conceptual framework for describing the phenomenon of new venture
creation. Acad Manag Rev 10(4):696–706
Joint Research Centre-European Commission (2008) Handbook on constructing composite indica-
tors: methodology and user guide. OECD publishing
Krugman P (1991) Increasing returns and economic geography. J Polit Econ 99(3):483–499. https://
doi.org/10.2307/2937739
3 Economic Impact Assessment of Entrepreneurship … 69
Lafuente E, Szerb L, Acs ZJ (2016) Country level efficiency and national systems of entrepreneur-
ship: a data envelopment analysis approach. J Technol Transfer 41(6):1260–1283
Lafuente E, Acs Z, Sanders M, Szerb L (2019) The global technology frontier: productivity growth
and the relevance of Kirznerian and Schumpeterian entrepreneurship. Small Bus Econ 1–26.
Online https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-019-00140-1
Landström H, Harirchi G (2018) The social structure of entrepreneurship as a scientific field. Res
Policy 47(3):650–662
Liñán F, Fernandez-Serrano J (2014) National culture, entrepreneurship and economic development:
different patterns across the European Union. Small Bus Econ 42(4):685–701
Low MB, MacMillan IC (1988) Entrepreneurship: past research and future challenges. J Manag
14(2):139–161
Malecki EJ (2018) Entrepreneurship and entrepreneurial ecosystems. Geography Compass. Online
access, pp 1–21. https://doi.org/10.1111/gec3.12359
Naudé W (2010) Entrepreneurship, developing countries, and development economics: new
approaches and insights. Small Bus Econ 34(1):1
Nightingale P, Coad A (2014) Muppets and gazelles: political and methodological biases in
entrepreneurship research. Ind Corp Change 23:113–143. https://doi.org/10.1093/icc/dtt057
Parker SC (2018) The economics of entrepreneurship. Cambridge University Press
Prieger JE, Bampoky C, Blanco LR, Liu A (2016) Economic growth and the optimal level of
entrepreneurship. World Dev 82:95–109
Qian H, Acs ZJ, Stough RR (2013) Regional systems of entrepreneurship: the nexus of human
capital, knowledge and new firm formation. J Econ Geogr 13:559–587. https://doi.org/10.1093/
jeg/lbs009
Rappai G, Szerb L (2011) Összetett indexek készítése új módon: a szűk keresztmetszetekért történő
büntetés módszere. PTE KRTI Műhelytenulmányok 2011/1
Ratto M, Roeger W, in’t Veld J (2009) QUEST III: an estimated open-economy DSGE model of
the euro area with fiscal and monetary policy. Econ Model 26:222–233
Romer P (1990) Endogenous technological change. J Polit Econ 98:71–102
Sanders M, Stenkula M, Grilli L, Herrmann AM, Latifi G, Páger B, Szerb L, Terragno Bogliaccini E
(2020a) A Reform Strategy for Italy. In: Sanders M, Marx A, Stenkula M (eds) The entrepreneurial
society. Springer, Berlin Heidelberg
Sanders M, Stenkula M, Fritsch M, Herrmann AM, Latifi G, Páger B, Szerb L, Terragno Bogliaccini
E, Wyrwich M (2020b) A Reform Strategy for Germany. In: Sanders M, Marx A, Stenkula M
(eds) The entrepreneurial society. Springer, Berlin Heidelberg
Sanders M, Stenkula M, Dunstan J, Estrin S, Herrmann AM, Páger B, Szerb L, Terragno Bogli-
accini E (2020c) A Reform Strategy for the UK. In: Sanders M, Marx A, Stenkula M (eds) The
entrepreneurial society. Springer, Berlin Heidelberg
Schalk H, Varga A (2004) The economic effects of EU community support framework interventions.
An Ex-ante Impact Analysis with EcoRET, A Macroeconomic Model For Hungary. Center of
Applied Economic Research Münster (CAWM), University of Münster
Sebestyén T, Varga A (2013) Research productivity and the quality of interregional knowledge
networks. Ann Reg Sci 51:155–189
Shane S, Venkataraman S (2000) The promise of entrepreneurship as a field of research. Acad
Manag Rev 25(1):217–226
Spigel B (2017) The relational organization of entrepreneurial ecosystems. Entrepreneurship Theory
Pract 41(1):49–72
Stam E (2015) Entrepreneurial ecosystems and regional policy: a sympathetic critique. Eur Plan
Stud 23:1759–1769. https://doi.org/10.1080/09654313.2015.1061484
Szerb L, Vörös Zs, Komlósi É, Acs ZJ, Páger B, Ortega-Argilés R, Abaligeti G (2017) The new
regional entrepreneurship and development index: structure, data and description of methodology.
Unpublished manuscript
70 A. Varga et al.
Szerb LE, Lafuente K Horváth, Páger B (2018) The relevance of quantity and quality entrepreneur-
ship for regional performance: the moderating role of the entrepreneurial ecosystem. Reg Stud .
https://doi.org/10.1080/00343404.2018.1510481
Treyz G, Rickman D, Shao G (1992) The REMI economic-demographic forecasting and simulation
model. Int Reg Sci Rev 14:221–253
Varga A (2000) Local academic knowledge transfers and the concentration of economic activity. J
Reg Sci 40(2):289–309
Varga A (2006) The spatial dimension of innovation and growth: empirical research
methodology and policy analysis. Eur Plan Stud 14(9):1171–1186. https://doi.org/10.1080/
09654310600933298
Varga A (2007) GMR-Hungary: a complex macro-regional model for the analysis of development
policy impacts on the Hungarian economy. PTE KTK KRTI Working Papers (2007/4)
Varga A (2017a) Geographical macro and regional impact modeling. In: Jackson R, Schaeffer P
(eds) Regional research frontiers, advances in spatial science, vol 2, pp 49–58. https://doi.org/10.
1007/978-3-319-50590-9_3
Varga A (2017b) Place-based, spatially blind, or both? Challenges in estimating the impacts of
modern development policies: the case of the GMR policy impact modeling approach. Int Reg
Sci Rev 40:12–37. https://doi.org/10.1177/0160017615571587
Varga A, Baypinar M (2016) Economic impact assessment of alternative European neighborhood
policy (ENP) options with the application of the GMR-Turkey model. Ann Reg Sci 56:153–176
Varga A, Sebestyén T, Szabó N, Szerb L (2018) Economic Impact assessment of Entrepreneurship
policies with the GMR-Europe Model. FIRES Project Report D4.6, 2018.04.06
Varga A, Sebestyén T, Szabó N, Szerb L (2019) Estimating the economic impacts of knowledge
network and entrepreneurship development in smart specialization policy. Reg Stud. https://doi.
org/10.1080/00343404.2018.1527026
Vivarelli M (2013) Is entrepreneurship necessarily good? Microeconomic evidence from developed
and developing countries. Ind Corp Change 22:1453–1495. https://doi.org/10.1093/icc/dtt005
Wennekers S, Thurik R (1999) Linking entrepreneurship and economic growth. Small Bus Econ
13(1):27–56
Open Access This chapter is licensed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0
International License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits use, sharing,
adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate
credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license and
indicate if changes were made.
The images or other third party material in this chapter are included in the chapter’s Creative
Commons license, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not
included in the chapter’s Creative Commons license and your intended use is not permitted by
statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from
the copyright holder.
Chapter 4
On the Institutional Foundations
of the Varieties of Entrepreneurship
in Europe
Andrea M. Herrmann
Abstract For decades, research into the link between national institutions and
entrepreneurship has been characterized by three shortcomings: First, clear-cut con-
cepts of institutions are rare. Second, a parsimonious understanding of how a few core
institutions influence entrepreneurship is missing. Third, scholars often ignore that
incrementally innovative ventures constitute a distinct (and under-researched) type
of entrepreneurship next to the (over-researched) form of radically innovative, high-
growth or high-tech entrepreneurship. This chapter seeks to illustrate how the appli-
cation of the “Varieties-of-Capitalism” (VoC) reasoning does not only enable focused
rather than eclectic analyses of institutional influences on entrepreneurship but also
reveals the institutionally induced equifinality of the varieties of entrepreneurship
across Europe. These insights invite future entrepreneurship research to move away
from the ideology that displays radically innovative entrepreneurship as, by far,
the most desirable form of entrepreneurship. This finding also invites policymak-
ers to target entrepreneurial support measures more specifically to their economy’s
institutional environment.
This chapter summarizes some of the core findings of Work Package 5 of the FIRES research
project (https://projectfires.eu), which received funding from the European Union’s Horizon 2020
research and innovation program under grant agreement No 649378. The theoretical foundations
for this work package published earlier in Herrmann (2019) were reiterated—largely verbatim—in
Sects. 4.1 and 4.2. While Sects. 4.1 and 4.2 are therefore no original work, the remainder of the
chapter is original work to the extent that it provides a systematic overview over how this argument
is based on a set of papers that have been published or are under review, in (Dilli et al. 2018; Held
et al. 2018; Held et al. 2018a, b; Held 2019). I thank Selin Dilli for comments on earlier drafts of
this chapter.
A. M. Herrmann (B)
Innovation Studies, Copernicus Institute of Sustainable Development, Utrecht University, Utrecht,
The Netherlands
e-mail: A.M.Herrmann@uu.nl
4.1 Introduction
Over the past two decades, the Varieties-of-Capitalism (VoC) literature, going back to
the work of Hall and Soskice (2001a), has become a widely applied framework in the
political sciences, in political economy and economic sociology alike. In a nutshell,
the VoC literature illustrates that different national institutions governing labor and
financial markets as well as inter-organizational collaborations facilitate different
types of corporate innovation. While the VoC framework has been developed mostly
through studies of incumbent firms, its reasoning is also applicable to new ventures.
National institutions are likely to lead also new ventures to develop business ideas of
different innovativeness. To put it differently, given that incumbent firms were found
to compete on different types of innovations and thus, in different market segments
between countries, it is reasonable to assume that many firms have chosen these
competitive strategies from their inception as new ventures.
However, until the beginning of the H2020 project Financial and Institutional
Reforms for an Entrepreneurial Society in Europe (FIRES), the VoC framework
has hardly been applied in entrepreneurship research (for exceptions, see Ebner
2010; van der Walt 2010).1 To be clear, the entrepreneurship literature illustrates that
entrepreneurs are driven by different motives and reasons, and have diverse aspi-
rations and growth ambitions (for example, Cooper and Artz 1995; Wiklund et al.
2003). Accordingly, the literature acknowledges that different forms of entrepreneur-
ship exist, ranging from solo self-employment over small family businesses to high-
growth gazelle ventures (see also Delmar et al. 2003; Henrekson and Stenkula 2016;
Vivarelli 2013). The Global Entrepreneurship Monitor, by far the most comprehen-
sive dataset on entrepreneurship forms across the world, also shows that entrepreneur-
ship takes different forms between countries. However, systematic research into insti-
tutional reasons, as laid out by the VoC literature, for how and why entrepreneurship
between countries may differ in its innovation focus remained underdeveloped until
the start of the FIRES project.
This research gap has arguably (see Herrmann 2019) persisted because of a strong
focus on radically innovative—that is “technology-intensive” (OECD 1998), “R&D-
intensive” (Schreyer 2000), or “knowledge-intensive” (Delmar et al. 2003)—ven-
tures. This focus can be theoretically motivated by their high-growth potential and
empirically because these ventures have been shown to generate a disproportion-
ately high share of employment (see also Amat and Perramon 2010; Davidson and
Segerstrom 1998; Hölzl 2009; OECD 2002; Shane 2009). Radically innovative ven-
tures typically develop goods and services based on new technologies, leading to
strong corporate growth on the one hand and a higher risk of failure on the other.
Examples of such radically innovative ventures have emerged particularly frequently
in Silicon Valley which, in turn, has led to an idolization of this radically innovative,
1 The reason why the VoC framework has hardly been applied in business and management research
today seems straightforward: The core proponents of the VoC arguments, as well as their followers,
are political scientists (Peter Hall, Kathleen Thelen), political economists (David Soskice), and
sociologists (Wolfgang Streeck) rather than business and management scholars.
4 On the Institutional Foundations of the Varieties … 73
the most desirable entrepreneurship type. Overall, the studies below (see Sect. 4.3)
thus illustrate how a better understanding of the varieties of entrepreneurship in
Europe can lead to a more balanced understanding of the possibilities and needs—
or rather the difficulties and needless efforts—to equally foster radically innovative
entrepreneurship in Continental Europe.
To illustrate how the VoC reasoning offers a more balanced understanding of
the link between distinct national institutions and different types of entrepreneurial
innovativeness, I first review the core arguments of the VoC literature on a coun-
try’s institutional foundations in Sect. 4.2. Section 4.3 then provides an overview
of four FIRES studies that show how different institutional frameworks induce dif-
ferent types of entrepreneurial venturing across Europe. Section 4.4 illustrates the
implications that result for researchers and policymakers from these findings.
Importantly, the VoC arguments on how a distinct set of institutions support different
types of corporate innovativeness have, until the start of the FIRES project, been
empirically tested on the basis of incumbent firms (Hall and Soskice 2001a; Hancké
et al. 2007; Casper 2007; Herrmann 2008). We therefore begin with the question
of whether these arguments are equally applicable to nascent ventures. To answer
this question, we first develop a theoretical framework that could explain which
institutions are core to the development of (different types of) entrepreneurship, and
why.
Starting with the work of Stinchcombe (1965), the entrepreneurship literature
investigating how institutions influence entrepreneurship gained momentum in the
early 1990s. Its contributors arrived at the conclusion that institutions “matter”
because they structure economic payoffs which influence entrepreneurial efforts
and activities (Calcagno and Sobel 2014; Baumol 1990; Murphy et al. 1990; Sobel
2008). While the literature agrees that both formal and informal institutions incen-
tivize individual behavior (North 1990), thereby influencing the extent and character
of an economy’s entrepreneurial activity (Acs et al. 2008b; Stenholm et al. 2013;
Urbano and Alvarez 2014), it also—often implicitly—focuses on the institutional
drivers of radically innovative entrepreneurship. The formal institutions were found
to be beneficial for “productive,” “high-growth” entrepreneurship and include law
and order, contract enforcement, competition policy, trade policies, tax codes, social
insurance systems, employment protection legislation, capital market regulation, as
well as the protection of private property (Bjørnskov and Foss 2013; Hall and Jones
1999; Henrekson and Johansson 2009). Informal institutions supporting growth-
oriented entrepreneurship include individualism, social capital, trust, and power dis-
tance (Hechavarria and Reynolds 2009; Taylor and Wilson 2012). In short, the liter-
ature suggests that differences in entrepreneurship between countries or regions can,
inter alia, be explained by a broad diversity of institutions (Case and Harris 2012;
Stam 2014; World Economic Forum 2013).
4 On the Institutional Foundations of the Varieties … 75
2 For a more in-depth understanding of how different schools of thought differ from each other in
their understanding of institutions, see (Koelble 1995; Hall and Taylor 1996).
76 A. M. Herrmann
of the Northern European CMEs (in particular, that of Germany) facilitates the
development of incrementally innovative ventures.
With regard to labor skills, the VoC literature highlights how workforces in CMEs
tend to acquire company-specific rather than general skills (Hall and Soskice 2001b).
The acquisition of company-specific skills is essentially induced by regulated labor-
market institutions which prohibit the hiring-and-firing of employees at will. Unless
they fall under exempt regulations, such as start-up companies of less than 10 employ-
ees, ventures can only dismiss employees for limited reasons, after respecting specific
notice periods and involving the ventures’ work councils. Often, temporary forms of
employment can also be strongly protected with the intention to gear them toward per-
manent employment (Dencker et al. 2009). Given that these institutions tie employees
to the same firm for a long time period, employees in CMEs tend to have in-depth
firm-specific knowledge and long-standing relationships with their firms’ suppli-
ers. Such firm-specific skills enable workforces in CMEs to autonomously propose
and develop improvements which translate into incremental innovations and high-
quality products. At the same time, given their focus on just one (or a few) corporate
environments, workforces with firm-specific skills lack the imaginative capacity and
adaptiveness arising from frequent job changes. While workforces with firm-specific
skills are thus less likely to come up with radically innovative ideas, they are partic-
ularly well equipped for developing incremental innovations (Herrmann and Peine
2011).
In addition, the pension and corporate governance systems of CMEs, institu-
tionalizing the access of ventures to finance, tend to facilitate the development of
incrementally innovative ventures (Hall and Soskice 2001b; Kenyon and Vitols 2004;
Vitols 2001). Venture capital tends to be scarce in CMEs especially when the public
pension system is a pay-as-you-go scheme. In these systems, such as in Germany,
the pension provisions paid in by the current working population are directly redis-
tributed by the state to the retirees and not invested into profit-yielding projects,
let alone venture capital funds.
Once limited liability ventures reach a certain size, a supervisory board typically
needs to be established including employees as well as shareholder representatives.
Given that the supervisory board needs to agree to major strategic investment deci-
sions of the board of directors, managers have no unilateral decision-making power.
On the one hand, this makes it difficult to rapidly invest into, or divest from, new
business units, which is often necessary for radical innovations. On the other hand,
shareholders with insights into, and a say about, how their funds are to be used are
typically less interested in maximizing returns on investment in the short run. This is
particularly true whenever members of supervisory boards represent large corporate
stakeholders, such as the firm’s “house banks” or suppliers. In these cases, the board
members are often reluctant to agree that “their” venture engages in high-risk projects
(even if these promise high returns) because radically innovative businesses are also
more likely to fail. Supervisory board members thus tend to have a preference for
the firm to engage in incrementally innovative projects because the latter typically
have more stable and predictable (albeit lower) returns in the long run.
4 On the Institutional Foundations of the Varieties … 79
3 To measure the extent of highly and generally skilled workforces, these indicators report (for each
country): (i) the share of population with tertiary education, (ii) the percentage of researchers, and
(iii) the amount of R&D transfers to entrepreneurial ventures, as well as (iv) the stringency of
regular employment protection legislation, (v) the stringency of temporary employment protection,
and (vi) the social spending on start-up incentives.
4 On the Institutional Foundations of the Varieties … 81
4 These indicators capture the influence of institutional investors on nascent ventures by reporting the
extent (i) of protection of minority interests, (ii) of minimum capital requirements, (iii) of venture
capital investments, and (iv) of recovery rates in case of venture failure.
5 These indicators measure the reliability of legal procedures in case of lawsuits related to sup-
plier–producer collaborations by capturing the extent (i) of enforcing contracts, (ii) of judicial
independence, (iii) of impartial courts, (iv) of the protection of property rights, and (v) of the
integrity of the legal system.
6 More precisely, the countries covered include Austria, Belgium, Czech Republic, Denmark,
Finland, France, Germany, Hungary, Ireland, Italy, the Netherlands, Norway, Poland, Portugal,
Slovakia, Slovenia, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, the UK, and the USA.
7 In order to identify possible changes that may have taken place in the countries’ institutional
environments over time, we also split our data into two groups: the periods of 2004–2009 and
of 2009–2014, respectively. Importantly, though our separate analyses for these two time periods
revealed that no major institutional changes have taken place, the results are very similar between
the two periods. We therefore used the average of the 2004–2014 time span in the analyses and
results presented below.
82 A. M. Herrmann
Fig. 4.1 Country families with similar entrepreneurship-relevant institutions. Source Dilli et al.
(2018)
(including Italy, Spain, Portugal, and France), in turn, are characterized by con-
straining financial and labor-market institutions including education systems that
mostly teach basic skills to workforces, and, with the exception of France, less
reliable legal systems that make inter-firm collaborations difficult. Finally, EMEs
(including Poland, the Slovak Republic, the Czech Republic, Hungary, and Slovenia)
are characterized by constraining financial-market institutions, well-regulated labor
markets based on education systems that mostly teach basic skills, and unreliable
legal systems that hamper inter-firm collaborations. In short, varieties-of-capitalism
similar to the ones described in the VoC literature for established firms can be
identified for nascent ventures with regard to those national institutions governing
entrepreneurship.
We assessed the impact of these distinct varieties of entrepreneurship-related insti-
tutions on entrepreneurship in the second step (Dilli et al. 2018, pp. 309–320). Based
on the VoC reasoning about the impact of institutions on entrepreneurial innovative-
ness, we would expect to find an above-average share of radically innovative ventures
in LMEs, an elevated proportion of incrementally innovative ventures in CMEs, and
a plurality of imitative ventures in MMEs and EMEs. We assessed these hypotheses
on the basis of several regression analyses. Taking the technology intensity of indus-
tries as indicator of entrepreneurial innovativeness, these analyses tested whether
specific types of entrepreneurship (e.g., venture creation in technology-intense or,
respectively, in less technology-intense industries) are particularly frequent in LMEs,
CMEs, MMEs, and EMEs, respectively.
4 On the Institutional Foundations of the Varieties … 83
Overall, our regression analyses lend support to the idea that the institutional
constellations of LMEs, CMEs, MMEs, and EMEs support different types of
entrepreneurship (Dilli et al. 2018, pp. 309–314). While these analyses can only
establish correlations, not causalities, it is noteworthy that entrepreneurs in LMEs
outperform their counterparts in other economies in the extent to which they found
radically innovative, high-tech ventures which also grow fast. Entrepreneurs in CMEs
often develop incrementally innovative ventures. That is, they create more high- and
medium-tech ventures than entrepreneurs in EMEs and MMEs but also more low-
tech ventures than their counterparts in LMEs, whereby these ventures are overall
characterized by lower but sustainable growth. In contrast, entrepreneurs in EMEs
specialize in less innovative product imitations. Accordingly, they are outperformed
by entrepreneurs in both LMEs and CMEs in setting up high-tech ventures. However,
EME entrepreneurs are decisively better in setting up medium- and low-tech ven-
tures than their counterparts in CMEs and MMEs alike. Importantly, though, these
ventures show little growth. Finally, innovative entrepreneurship is least developed
in MMEs. Accordingly, MME entrepreneurs hardly set up any high-tech or medium-
tech ventures compared to their counterparts in all other economies. At the same
time, entrepreneurs in MMEs do outperform entrepreneurs in all other economies
in the extent to which they set up low-tech ventures, whereby these ventures hardly
show any growth.
Having established that distinct institutional constellations correlate with different
types of entrepreneurship across Europe, we asked in a third step whether, and if so
how, venture creation processes differ between countries. To this end, we collected a
unique dataset of venture creation activities. More concretely, this dataset traces—on
a monthly basis—the activities that nascent ventures undertake during their start-up
period in order (1) to build up the necessary human resources, (2) to acquire funding,
and (3) to develop product-related know-how. Based on optimal matching techniques,
we analyzed—with a specific focus on country-specific differences—how ventures
approach any of these three components of the start-up process. In short, our findings
are presented below:
(1) Beginning with human resources, two separate studies (Held 2019; Held et al.
2018) investigate how labor-market institutions influence the composition of
start-up teams in nascent ventures. The influence of the institutional setting
comes particularly to the fore in the first study, which analyzes the circum-
stances in which part-time entrepreneurs, who worked for the nascent venture
less than 30 h per week, transition to full-time entrepreneurship (Held 2019).
Interestingly, and in line with the expectations of the VoC literature, Held finds
that part-time entrepreneurs in CMEs, such as Germany, are significantly less
likely to transition to full-time entrepreneurship than those in LMEs, such as
the UK and the USA, presumably because, in case of venture failure, it is par-
ticularly difficult in CMEs to regain a responsible position as a well-paid and
well-insured employee. The study highlights that national labor-market institu-
tions do not only elicit the emergence of a dominant type of entrepreneurship
(Dilli et al. 2018) but also specific entry choices by the entrepreneur herself.
84 A. M. Herrmann
Taken together, these studies lend support to the theoretical arguments that a dis-
tinct set of national finance-, labor-, and R&D-related institutions correlates with the
development of different types of entrepreneurial innovativeness across the European
Union. While the deregulated institutional environment of Anglo-Saxon economies
implies that an above-average share of radically innovative ventures is founded in
LMEs, an elevated proportion of incrementally innovative ventures is set up in CMEs,
while a plurality of imitative ventures is founded in MMEs and EMEs.
In light of this empirical evidence supporting the VoC argument that distinct institu-
tional constellations facilitate different types of entrepreneurship, which implications
arise for entrepreneurship research and policymaking?
As we have argued elsewhere (Herrmann 2019; Dilli et al. 2018), entrepreneur-
ship research would first of all benefit from assuming a more parsimonious approach
toward investigating the link between institutions and entrepreneurship. The work of
Dilli (forthcoming) offers a useful example in this regard. One of the major insights
resulting from the VoC framework is that economic actors in different institutional
environments need to behave differently in order to achieve the same outcome. And
as a corollary, if economic actors across national institutions behave alike, this behav-
ior tends to result in different outcomes. To give an example, ventures that go public
in order to raise funds for increasing their R&D activities are likely to become rad-
ically innovative in the USA and incrementally innovative in Germany. Germany’s
corporate governance and education systems as well as the regulated labor market
imply that the resources for radical innovations are less available and, hence, more
expensive. This makes radically innovative entrepreneurship in Germany consid-
erably more difficult while facilitating incrementally innovative entrepreneurship.
Germany’s entrepreneurs thus need to behave differently from their USA and UK
counterparts if they want to achieve the same outcomes. Meanwhile, start-ups in the
UK have difficulties recruiting and retaining specifically skilled workers to grow their
businesses into export champions, as this arguably requires a disciplined and loyal
workforce that is harder to attain in LMEs. If British and German founders behave
alike, they will achieve different outcomes, while different behaviors are required to
achieve the same outcome. Research into such questions of institutionally induced
equifinality can offer a novel approach to investigating the link between institutions,
entrepreneurial behavior, and outcomes.
The entrepreneurship literature can furthermore benefit from the finding that
entrepreneurship types diffused in one institutional environment do not serve as a
role model for entrepreneurship in other institutional environments. To put it bluntly,
Silicon Valley cannot be a role model for the Continental European economies
because of their institutional differences. But neither is Baden-Württemberg, known
86 A. M. Herrmann
for its incrementally innovative firms, a suitable role model for the Midlands.
Such insights force the entrepreneurship literature to acknowledge that different
institutional constellations allow for different types of entrepreneurship to flourish.
This also has important implications for policymaking. The VoC framework high-
lights that institutional constellations which are at the same time conducive to radi-
cally innovative, high-tech entrepreneurship and incrementally innovative, medium-
tech entrepreneurship do not exist and may in fact be impossible to create. Policymak-
ers are therefore faced with a trade-off and the question about which entrepreneur-
ship type to facilitate. Of course, as laid out in the final chapters of this volume
(Sanders et al. 2020a, b, c), policymakers can design individual policy measures to
stimulate those types of entrepreneurship that are currently less supported by their
national institutional environment. But historically grown institutional complemen-
tarities imply that one has to make a choice whether to support radical, incremental,
or imitative innovation.
Policymakers should be aware of these trade-offs and carefully consider the inter-
play of institutions. While labor protection has a negative impact on the development
of radically innovative, high-tech entrepreneurship, it stimulates the development of
incrementally innovative, medium-tech entrepreneurship. Germany, for example, is
characterized by a lively start-up scene in this area (see Dilli et al. 2018; Herrmann
2019; Pahnke and Welter 2019). Finally, one should keep in mind that the regula-
tion or deregulation of labor and financial markets has broader societal implications
that may be undesirable. To give just some examples: strong wage inequalities and
increasing disparities between the rich and the poor, as well as systematic underin-
surance against the risks of disability, old-age poverty, and illness that seem to come
with LMEs’ deregulated labor markets. Similarly, high capital market volatility and
risky investments go hand in hand with deregulated financial markets. From the
above research, one can conclude that a one-size-fits-all institutional constellation
that stimulates radically and incrementally innovative and imitative entrepreneur-
ship while facilitating social cohesion does not exist and cannot be created. There
is no blueprint. The best policymakers can hope to do is experiment with small
improvements, carefully assessing their policies’ impacts as they go along.
References
Acs ZJ, Desai S, Hessels J (2008b) Entrepreneurship, economic development, and institutions.
Small Bus Econ 31(3):219–234
Amable B (2003) The diversity of modern capitalism. Oxford University Press, Oxford
Amat O, Perramon J (2010) Gazelle companies: growth drivers and an evolution analysis. Universitat
Pompeu Fabra, Working Paper 1244
Anyadike-Danes M, Bonner K, Hart K, Mason C (2009) Measuring business growth: high-growth
firms and their contribution to employment in the UK. NESTA, London
Baumol WJ (1990) Entrepreneurship: productive, unproductive, and destructive. J Polit Econ
98(5):893–921
4 On the Institutional Foundations of the Varieties … 87
Held L (2019) Part-time entrepreneurship: the role of institutions, venture and individual charac-
teristics in entry and transition choices. Unravelling the patterns in venture creation processes.
Ph.D. thesis. Utrecht University, Utrecht, pp 25–55
Held L, Herrmann AM, van Mossel A (2018) Team formation processes in new ventures. Small
Bus Econ 51(2):441–464
Held L, Herrmann AM, Polzin F (2018a) Follow the money: the funding acquisition process
of nascent ventures. Horizon 2020 Project on “Financial and Institutional Reforms for an
Entrepreneurial Society” (FIRES),Workpackage 5, Deliverable 5.1; currently under review. Avail-
able in Held L (2019) Unravelling the patterns in venture creation processes. Ph.D. thesis. Utrecht
University, Utrecht, pp 91–122
Held L, Herrmann AM, Storz C (2018b) Whom do nascent ventures search for? Variance of link-
age formation activities during new roduct development processes. Horizon 2020 Project on
“Financial and Institutional Reforms for an Entrepreneurial Society” (FIRES), Workpackage 5,
Deliverable 5.1; currently under review. Available in Held L (2019) Unravelling the patterns in
venture creation processes. Ph.D. thesis. Utrecht University, Utrecht, pp 123–150
Henrekson M (2005) Entrepreneurship: a weak link in the welfare state? Ind Corp Change
14(3):437–467
Henrekson M, Johansson D (2009) Competencies and institutions fostering high-growth firms.
Found Trends Entrepreneurship 5(1):1–80
Henrekson M, Johansson D (2010) Gazelles as job creators: a survey and interpretation of the
evidence. Small Bus Econ 35(2):227–244
Henrekson M, Sanadaji T (2014) Small business activity does not measure entrepreneurship. PNAS
111(5):1760–1765
Henrekson M, Stenkula M (2016) Understanding entrepreneurship – definition, function, and policy.
Lund, Studentlitteratur
Herrmann AM (2008) One political economy, one competitive strategy? Comparing pharmaceutical
firms in Germany, Italy, and the UK. Oxford University Press, Oxford
Herrmann AM (2019) A plea for varieties of entrepreneurship. Small Bus Econ 52(2):331–343
Herrmann AM, Peine A (2011) When ‘national innovation system’ meet ‘varieties of capitalism’
arguments on labour qualifications: on the skill types and scientific knowledge needed for radical
and incremental product innovations. Res Policy 40(5):687–701
Hölzl W (2009) Is the R&D behaviour of fast-growing SMEs different? Evidence from CIS III data
for 16 countries. Small Bus Econ 33(1):59–75
Kenyon T, Vitols S (2004) Corporate governance in Germany and the United States: key chal-
lenges for the transatlantic business community. AICGS Policy Report. American Institute for
Contemporary German Studies, Washington
Klein B (1996) Why hold-ups: the self-enforcing range of contractual relationships. Econ Inquiry
XXXIV(July):444–463
Koch A, Späth J, Strotmann H (2013) The role of employees for post-entry firm growth. Small Bus
Econ 41(3):733–755
Koelble TA (1995) The new institutionalism in political science and sociology. Comp Polit
27(2):231–243
Lundvall B-A (1992) National systems of innovation—towards a theory of innovation and interactive
learning. Pinter Publishers, London
Mason C, Brown R (2013) Creating good public policy to support high-growth firms. Small Bus
Econ 40(2):211–225
Milgrom PR, Roberts J (1992) Economics, organization and management. Prentice Hall, Englewood
Cliffs
Molina O, Rhodes M (2007) The political economy of adjustment in mixed market economies:
a study of Spain and Italy. In: Hancké B, Rhodes M, Thatcher M (eds) Beyond varieties of
capitalism. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 223–252
Murphy KM, Shleifer A, Vishny RW (1990) The allocation of talent: implications for growth. Q J
Econ 106(2):503–530
4 On the Institutional Foundations of the Varieties … 89
Nightingale P, Coad A (2014) Muppets and gazelles: political and methodological biases in
entrepreneurship research. Ind Corp Change 23(1):113–143
Nölke A, Vliegenthart A (2009) Enlarging the varieties of capitalism: the emergence of dependent
market economies in East Central Europe. World Polit 61(4):670–702
North DC (1990) Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge
University Press, Cambridge
OECD (1998) Technology, productivity and job creation. Best policy practices. OECD Publishing,
Paris
OECD (2002) High-growth SMEs and employment. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and
Development, Paris
Ostrom E (1990) Governing the commons: the evolution of institutions for collective action.
Cambridge University Press, New York
Pahnke A, Welter F (2019) The German Mittelstand: Antithesis to the Silicon Valley entrepreneur-
ship model? Small Bus Econ 52(2):345–358
Acs Z, Parsons, W., Spencer Tracy LJ (2008a) High-impact firms: gazelles revisited. Study prepared
for the U.S. Small Business Administration, Office of Advocacy, Washington D.C.
Pfeffer J, Salancik GR (1978) The external control of organizations: a resource dependence
perspective. Harper and Row, New York, NY
Rogerson WP (1992) Contractual solutions to the hold-up problem. Rev Econ Stud (59):777–794
Schneider MR, Paunescu M (2012) Changing varieties of capitalism and revealed comparative
advantages from 1990 to 2005: a test of the Hall and Soskice claims. Socio-Econ Rev 10(4):731–
753
Schreyer P (2000) High-growth firms and employment. OECD Publishing, Paris
Shane S (2009) Why encouraging more people to become entrepreneurs is bad public policy. Small
Bus Econ 33(2):141–149
Sobel RS (2008) Testing Baumol: institutional quality and the productivity of entrepreneurship. J
Bus Ventur 23(6):641–655
Sanders M, Stenkula M, Grilli L, Herrmann A, Latifi G, Pager B, Szerb L, Terragno BE (2020a) A
reform strategy for Italy. In: Marx A, Sanders M, Stenkula M (eds) The entrepreneurial society.
Reform strategies for Italy, Germany and the UK. Springer, Berlin
Sanders M, Stenkula M, Dunstan J, Estrin S, Herrmann A, Pager B, Szerb L, Terragno BE (2020b)
A reform strategy for the UK. In: Marx A, Sanders M, Stenkula M (eds) The entrepreneurial
society. Reform strategies for Italy, Germany and the UK. Springer, Berlin
Sanders M, Stenkula M, Fritsch M, Herrmann A, Latifi G, Pager B, Szerb L, Terragno BE, Wyrwich
M (2020c) A reform strategy for Germany. In: Marx A, Sanders M, Stenkula M (eds) The
entrepreneurial society. Reform strategies for Italy, Germany and the UK. Springer, Berlin
Stam E (2014) The Dutch entrepreneurial ecosystem. SSRN Electron J
Stenholm P, Acs ZJ, Wuebker R (2013) Exploring country-level institutional arrangements on the
rate and type of entrepreneurial activity. J Bus Ventur 28(1):176–193
Stinchcombe AL (1965) Social structure and organizations. In: March JG (ed) Handbook of
organizations. Rand McNally, Chicago, pp 142–193
Streeck W, Thelen K (2005) Introduction: institutional change in advanced political economies.
In: Streeck W, Thelen K (eds) Beyond continuity: institutional change in advanced political
economies. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 1–39
Tate J (2001) National varieties of standardization. In: Hall PA, Soskice DW (eds) Varieties of
capitalism—the institutional foundations of comparative advantage. Oxford University Press,
Oxford, pp 442–473
Taylor MZ, Wilson S (2012) Does culture still matter? The effects of individualism on national
innovation rates. J Bus Ventur 27(2):234–247
Teece DJ, Pisano G (1998) The dynamic capabilities of firms. In: Dosi G, Teece DJ, Chytry J (eds)
Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 193–212
90 A. M. Herrmann
Teubner G (2001) Legal irritants: how unifying law ends up in new divergences. In: Hall PA, Soskice
DW (eds) Varieties of capitalism—the Institutional foundations of comparative advantage. Oxford
University Press, Oxford, pp 417–441
Urbano D, Alvarez C (2014) Institutional dimensions and entrepreneurial activity: an international
study. Small Bus Econ 42(4):703–716
van der Walt J (2010) Entrepreneurship and the varieties of capitalism paradigm. Working Paper
No. 10-10, Mercatus Center at George Mason University
Vitols S (2001) Varieties of corporate governance: comparing Germany and the UK. In: Hall PA, Sos-
kice DW (eds) Varieties of capitalism—the institutional foundations of comparative advantage.
Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 337–360
Vivarelli M (2013) Is entrepreneurship necessarily good? Microeconomic evidence from developed
and developing countries. Ind Corp Change 22(6):1453–1495
Wiklund J, Davidsson P, Delmar F (2003) What do they think and feel about growth? An expectancy-
value approach to small business managers’ attitudes toward growth. Entrepreneurship Theory
Pract 27(3):247–270
Williamson OE (1985) The economic institutions of capitalism: firms, markets, relational contract-
ing. Free Press, New York
Winborg J, Landström H (2001) Financial bootstrapping in small businesses: examining small
business managers’ resource acquisition behaviors. J Bus Ventur 16(3):235–254
World Economic Forum (2013) Entrepreneurial ecosystems around the globe and company growth
dynamics. World Economic Forum, Davos
Open Access This chapter is licensed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0
International License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits use, sharing,
adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate
credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license and
indicate if changes were made.
The images or other third party material in this chapter are included in the chapter’s Creative
Commons license, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not
included in the chapter’s Creative Commons license and your intended use is not permitted by
statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from
the copyright holder.
Chapter 5
Towards an Entrepreneurial Society:
What Can the European Union
Contribute?
Axel Marx
Abstract The European Union (EU) is a political system involving multiple levels
of governance. Changing the institutional environment responsible for the quality
of the entrepreneurial ecosystem will require changes on multiple levels. However,
each level is not of equal importance. For some policy areas, the EU level is the
most important level of policy-making, and for other policy areas other levels of
governance are more important. This chapter will make clear that several institutions
which might be reformed in the context of creating a more entrepreneurial society fall
under the ‘shared’ or ‘supporting’ competence category of EU policy-making. This
implies that the centre of gravity for institutional reform remains firmly on the level
of the EU Member States or on the level of sub-national regions. The chapter shows
that fostering entrepreneurship will require a multi-level approach with a strong focus
on the level of EU Member States.
5.1 Introduction
The European Union (EU) is a political system involving multiple levels of gov-
ernance. Changing the institutional environment responsible for the quality of the
entrepreneurial ecosystem will require changes on multiple levels. However, each
level is not of equal importance. For some policy areas, such as trade policy the EU
level is the most important level of policy-making since the EU has an ‘exclusive’
The author thanks Philip De Man, Ward Munters and Andrei Suse-Gavril for research assistance.
This chapter is based on joint FIRES reports. Thanks to Mark Sanders, Mikael Stenkula, László
Szerb and Attila Varga for comments on earlier drafts of this chapter.
A. Marx (B)
Leuven Centre for Global Governance Studies, University of Leuven, Leuven, Belgium
e-mail: axel.marx@kuleuven.be
competence to make policy. For other policy areas, other levels of governance might
be more important. This chapter will make clear that several institutions which might
be reformed in the context of creating a more entrepreneurial society fall under the
‘shared’ or ‘supporting’ competence category of EU policy-making. This implies
that the centre of gravity for institutional reform remains firmly on the level of the
EU Member States (EU MS) or on the level of sub-national regions (especially in
federal states).
In order to illustrate the prominence of EU MS and the more limited scope for
institutional reform on the EU level, this chapter will first discuss the importance
of the principle of subsidiarity in EU policy-making. Next, the division of compe-
tence within the EU with regard to policy areas relevant to entrepreneurship will
be discussed. The chapter will then proceed by discussing the current EU policy
towards entrepreneurship and introduces the main objectives and instruments of
EU entrepreneurship policy to show where the EU can make a contribution. The
chapter ends with a discussion and summary which clearly shows that fostering
entrepreneurship will require a multi-level approach with a strong focus on the level
of EU MS.
the area that are not addressed by the EU legislation.2 In addition, where EU action
takes the form of minimum harmonization—that is, the EU act established minimum
requirements—EU MS may enact legislation setting stricter requirements (Craig and
de Búrca 2015, p. 85). Nonetheless, the EU MS will regain their right of exercising
a shared competence, to the extent that the Union has ceased to exercise that com-
petence, for instance by repealing EU legislation covering the relevant area.3 Article
4(2) of TFEU provides that the EU shares competences with the EU MS “in the
following principal areas” (emphasis added): internal market; social policy, for the
aspects defined in the TFEU; economic, social and territorial cohesion; agriculture
and fisheries, excluding the conservation of the marine biological resources; envi-
ronment; consumer protection; transport; trans-European networks; energy; area of
freedom, security and justice; and common safety concerns in public health matters,
for the aspects defined the TFEU. Several of these policy areas are relevant in the
context of institutional reform for a more entrepreneurial society.
Finally, there are competences to coordinate, support or supplement the EU MS’
actions. Article 6 of the TFEU provides that “the Union shall have competence
to carry out action to support, coordinate or supplement actions of the Member
States” (emphasis added). The following areas are covered by such competences:
protection and improvement of human health; industry; culture; tourism; education,
vocational training, youth and sport; civil protection; and administrative cooperation.
The competences belonging to this category are the weakest among the three principal
categories of competences. EU MS retain their power to regulate these policy areas
at the national level. As clarified by Article 2(5) of the TFEU, the Union’s exercise
of its competences in these areas does not supersede the EU MS’ competences. The
same provision also stipulates that “[l]egally binding acts of the Union adopted on
the basis of the provisions of the Treaties relating to these areas shall not entail
harmonization of Member state’s laws or regulations” (emphasis added). Hence,
harmonization in these areas is quite clearly excluded. Also, this list of policy areas
contains several policy areas which are of crucial importance for institutional reform
for a more entrepreneurial society.
Table 5.1 summarizes the type of competence for some of the key policy areas for
institutional reform. The table confirms that, while most of the legal bases invoked
by the EU institutions to act towards entrepreneurial reform are shared, the key
competences of industrial policy, education, training and youth are supporting, and
the shared competence of employment is mainly of a coordinating nature.
For the shared competences listed in Table 5.1, the regulatory room remaining
for the EU MS is usually dependent on the extent to which the EU has exercised its
powers in that same field. For some policy areas such as research and technological
development, EU action will not preclude the EU MS from exercising their (parallel)
competences (see De Man et al. 2016).
Suggestions for reforming the entrepreneurial society in Europe need to take into
account the legal nature of the competences of the EU in the main policy areas for
2 Protocol No. 25, to the TEU and TFEU, on the Exercise of Shared Competences.
3 Declaration No. 18 in relation to the delimitation of competences, attached to the Treaty of Lisbon.
96 A. Marx
The starting point for the entrepreneurship policy as being implemented by the current
incarnation of the European Commission is the Small Business Act (SBA) adopted
in 2008 (European Commission 2008a). It builds on the framework and concepts
elaborated in the 2005 Community Lisbon Programme for a Modern SME Policy
5 Towards an Entrepreneurial Society: What Can the European … 97
(European Commission 2005b).4 In 2010, the Commission labelled the SBA “the
main instrument for promoting SMEs’ competitiveness and entrepreneurship within
the Single Market and beyond” (European Commission 2010b, p. 13). The act and the
continued relevance it holds for the realization of the broader entrepreneurship policy
of the EU demonstrate the pivotal importance of the SME concept as an anchoring
point for most initiatives for entrepreneurial reform. Most concrete initiatives taken
today for reforming the entrepreneurial society in Europe involve SMEs, even if
the societal actors addressed can also include students and employees. Considering
the role of the SME notion as one of the basic anchoring points for EU policy to
promote entrepreneurship, it is useful to recall the Union’s definition of what a small-
and medium-sized enterprise entails. The category of micro-, small- and medium-
sized enterprises (SMEs) includes those enterprises that employ fewer than 250
persons, with an annual turnover not exceeding e50 million and/or an annual balance
sheet total not exceeding e43 million.5 The importance of SMEs for the European
economy has long been recognized by the European Commission. It was only with
the adoption of the SBA that ‘Entrepreneurship’ became one of the main tools for
promoting the competitiveness of European SMEs and an overarching notion for a
number of diverging yet interrelated initiatives at EU and Member State level. The
Commission page for the SBA links to a definition of the term ‘entrepreneurship’,
which is conceived as “an individual’s ability to turn ideas into action. It includes
creativity, innovation, risk taking, ability to plan and manage projects in order to
achieve objectives”.6
Building on the European Charter for Small Enterprises7 and the 2006 European
Council conclusions detailing the relaunched Lisbon strategy for jobs and growth
(Presidency Conclusions 2006), the 2008 SBA compiles four priority areas and
10 principles that should guide the conception and implementation of policies for
SMEs, at both EU and Member State levels. The four priority areas were promoting
entrepreneurship, lessen the regulatory burden, provide access to finance and provide
access to markets through internationalization. The 10 principles are: (1) education
and training for entrepreneurship; (2) efficient bankruptcy procedures and second
chance for entrepreneurs; (3) institutional and regulatory framework for SME policy-
making; (4) operational environment for business creation; (5) support services for
SMEs and public procurement; (6) access to finance for SMEs; (7) supporting SMEs
to benefit from Euro-Mediterranean networks and partnerships; (8) enterprise skills
and innovation; (9) SMEs in a green economy; and (10) internationalization of SMEs.
4 The EU entrepreneurship policy is very focused on supporting SMEs. This is a narrow interpretation
htm.
7 European Charter for Small Enterprises, endorsed at the Feira European Council on 19 and 20
June 2000. The Charter recognized entrepreneurship as “a valuable and productive life skill, at all
levels of responsibility” (p. 8).
98 A. Marx
to the single market for SMEs, which was one of the four priority areas of the SBA.
In that respect, the Commission notes that “[e]ntrepreneurship must be developed by
concrete policy initiatives, including a simplification of company law (bankruptcy
procedures, private company statute, etc.), and initiatives allowing entrepreneurs to
restart after failed businesses” (European Commission 2010b, p. 13).
Six of the seven flagship initiatives that make up the Europe 2020 Strategy explic-
itly refer to SMEs, highlighting the overall importance of the strategy for the stimula-
tion of an entrepreneurial culture in Europe (COSME Regulation, Para. (1)). Indeed,
several of the Europe 2020 flagship initiatives touch upon crucial aspects of Europe’s
policy for SMEs and entrepreneurial inclusion.
Building on previous initiatives, the 2010 Integrated Industrial Policy represents
the most comprehensive attempt on behalf of the European Commission to draw
up such a policy in support of entrepreneurship in Europe (European Commission
2010c). Reiterating the fundamental importance of SMEs for the economy of the EU,
the 2010 document is clear in its statement that the promotion of the creation, growth
and internationalization of SMEs should be at the core of the Union’s integrated
industrial policy (European Commission 2010c). In pursuit of this central objective,
the industrial policy gives a detailed overview of the variety of policy areas in which
action should be undertaken by the EU and its Member States in the coming years.
Most of these areas had already been identified in the 2008 SBA and under the various
flagship initiatives of the Europe 2020 Strategy. They concern both cross-sector
and sector-specific initiatives and include, most prominently, improving framework
conditions for industry, facilitating businesses’ access to finance and reducing the
mismatch between skills currently taught and those that are required for Europe’s
industry (European Commission 2014, p. 18).
The SBA, Europe 2020 and Integrated Industrial Policy Commission documents,
taken together, are cited as the most important policy documents on which the current
Competitiveness of Enterprises and SMEs (COSME) Regulation is built (COSME
Regulation paras (1)–(4)). Adopted by the Council and the European Parliament
on the basis of Articles 173 and 195 TFEU, the COSME Regulation establishes
a Programme for the Competitiveness of enterprises and small- and medium-sized
enterprises for the current 7-year period (2014–2020). It is the immediate successor
to the Competitiveness and Innovation Programme (CIP) that ran from 2007 to 2013.
Like COSME, the CIP was primarily geared towards supporting innovative SMEs
and entrepreneurs by improving their access to markets, support services and finance,
mainly through facilitating the access to risk capital (European Commission 2005a,
b, pp. 6–7). For that purpose, the CIP established a specific Entrepreneurship and
Innovation Programme that set out EU actions to support, encourage and promote:
access to finance for the start-up and growth of SMEs and investment in innovation
activities; the creation of an environment favourable to SME cooperation, particu-
larly in the field of cross-border cooperation; all forms of innovation in enterprises
including eco-innovation; entrepreneurship and innovation culture; enterprise and
innovation-related economic and administrative reform (COSME Regulation, Arts.
2.2.a and 10.2).
100 A. Marx
Commission 2013, p. 28). Besides DG GROW, several other DGs are involved in
implementing the entrepreneurship policy (for a detailed description, see De Man
et al. 2015).
5.5 Discussion
The above discussion makes clear that in the context of the European Union fostering
institutional change towards a more entrepreneurial society involves different actors
and institutions on different levels of governance. In this context, there is a strong
emphasis on subsidiarity and most of the policy leverage to foster an entrepreneurial
society is on the level of an EU MS or even a lower level of governance (see also
chapter by Varga et al. 2020).
The Europe 2020 Strategy underscores the vital importance of subsidiarity and
ensuring comprehensive cooperation with national, regional and local authorities in
all forms and capacities in order to make progress in realizing the objective of smart,
sustainable and inclusive growth. As such, according to the Europe 2020 Strategy, EU
MS are invited to work together by increasing their exchange of policy information
of good practices (European Commission 2010a, p. 29). Further, the strategy also
stresses the role of the European Parliament, not only in its capacity as co-legislator
to implement Europe 2020, but also as a ‘driving force’ for mobilizing EU MS, both
their citizens and their national parliaments (European Commission 2010a, p. 29).
Finally, the monitoring process set up by the European Commission for overseeing the
implementation of the strategy relies heavily on country-specific progress reports,
which also detail the progress made by the sub-national (regional) units of those
countries. This emphasis on EU MS can be read in two directions. On the one
hand, it can be read in the sense that the diversity of entrepreneurial environments
between EU MS and their regions is invoked as a key consideration warranting a
strict application of the principles of subsidiarity and proportionality in developing
an entrepreneurship policy. On the other hand, it can also be read as an indicator of
the urgent need for a more closely coordinated approach to entrepreneurial reform.
Also, the 2013 COSME Regulation reiterates the need to respect the fundamental
principle of subsidiarity. The COSME Regulation emphasizes that the subsidiarity
principle will inform the subsequent actions that can and should be included in the
work programme of the Commission when implementing this regulation. The Coun-
cil and Parliament are keen to emphasize the priority consideration for executing the
COSME programme as being that “[t]he Union’s actions should be coherent, con-
sistent and complementary to the EU MS’ financial instruments for SMEs, provide
a leverage effect and avoid creating market distortion, in accordance with [relevant
regulations]. The entities entrusted with the implementation of the actions should
ensure additionality and avoid double financing through Union resources” (COSME
Regulation, Para (15)).
The key mechanism for reaching the objective of facilitating access to capital
for SMEs and entrepreneurs, the European Fund for Strategic Investment (EFSI), is
5 Towards an Entrepreneurial Society: What Can the European … 103
Member State level. This is in line with the instructions of the European Parliament
and the Council in the 2013 COSME Regulation for EU initiatives in each of the four
priority areas identified in the programme, which consistently ask the Commission
to ‘support’ actions which aim to facilitate and improve access to finance for SMEs
in their start-up, growth and transfer phases; to continue improving the competitive-
ness and access to markets of SMEs; to improve the framework conditions for the
competitiveness and sustainability of SMEs; and to promote entrepreneurship and
an entrepreneurial culture (COSME Regulation Arts. 8,9, 11 and 12).
The supporting nature of the activities of the EU is particularly apparent for those
areas covered by Action Pillars 1 and 3 of the E2020 Plan concerning education
and training, and the promotion of entrepreneurship and social inclusion of certain
demographic groups. The second pillar of the Action Plan, based largely on the
Union’s industrial policy competence, proposes more legislative actions and the
setting up of dedicated funding mechanisms. These proposals are largely confined
to actions that aim to facilitate access to finance for SMEs. However, as we have
seen, the most prominent of the measures adopted in this area so far also relied on
legal bases for shared competences in other policy areas such as economic, social
and territorial cohesion, research and technological development, and trans-European
networks. Likewise, it appears that, where cross-border competitiveness is addressed
as a factor that can improve the regulatory environment of entrepreneurs, the EU-
shared powers regarding the functioning of internal market offer more leeway, which
translates into more assertive legislative action.
5.6 Conclusion
This chapter makes clear that policies towards promoting entrepreneurship have
become more prominent on the agenda of the European Union. It was also one of
the key policy areas of the Juncker Commission. As a result, several regulatory and
financial initiatives have been taken on the level of the EU. However, as the EU
recognizes as well, promoting entrepreneurship entails reforms in many different
policy areas. This was also the starting point of the FIRES project. Making changes
in these different policy areas is difficult due to the complex nature of policy-making
competences in the EU. Some policies can only be changed on the level of the EU
(exclusive competence of the EU), while most others fall under shared competence
or the competence of the EU MS. In addition, the principle of subsidiarity requires
that policy reform should be approached on the appropriate level, including the local
and regional level.
Given the historical evolution of (national) entrepreneurial ecosystems and the
institutional frameworks that shape them, the EU MS need to be in the driver’s seat
in terms of institutional reform for a more entrepreneurial society. The European
Commission has legally committed to helping and supporting them as well as coor-
dinate their efforts, but reforms for an entrepreneurial society remain decidedly a
responsibility of EU MS. The possibilities and limitations for institutional reform on
the level of EU MS are analysed and discussed in other chapters of this volume.
122 A. Marx
References
Council of the European Union (2008a) Council conclusions on think small first—a small business
act for Europe of 1/2 Dec 2008
Council of the European Union (2008b) Council action plan for a small business act for Europe,
annexed to the council conclusions on think small first—a small business act for Europe of 1/2
Dec 2008
Craig P, de Búrca G (2015) EU law: text, cases and materials, 6th edn. Oxford University Press,
p. 85
De Man P, Munters W, Marx A (2015) EU enterpreneurial policy. Report for FIRES Project
De Man P, Munters W, Marx A (2016) EU entrepreneurial policy. Report for FIRES Project, pp. 200
Elert N, Henrekson M, Sanders M (2019) The entrepreneurial society: a reform strategy for the
European Union. Springer Verlag
European Commission (2005a) Common actions for growth and employment: the community
Lisbon program, 20 July 2005, COM (2005) 330 final
European Commission (2005b) Implementing the community Lisbon program—modern SME
policy for growth and employment, 10 Nov 2005, COM (2005) 551 final
European Commission (2008a) Think small first—a small business act for Europe, 25 June 2008,
COM (2008) 394 final
European Commission (2008b) A European economic recovery plan, 26 Nov 2008, COM (2008)
800 final
European Commission (2009a) Action program for reducing administrative burdens in the EU
sectoral reduction plans and 2009 actions, 22 Oct 2009, COM (2009) 544 final
European Commission (2009b) Report on the implementation of the SBA, s.d., COM (2009) 680
European Commission (2010a) Europe 2020—a strategy for smart, sustainable and inclusive
growth, 3 March 2010, COM (2010) 2020
European Commission (2010b) Toward a single market act—for a highly competitive social market
economy: 50 proposals for improving our work, business and exchanges with one another, 11
Nov 2010, COM (2010) 608 final/2
European Commission (2010c) An Integrated Industrial Policy for the globalisation era—putting
competitiveness and sustainability at centre stage, s.d., COM (2010) 614
European Commission (2011b) Minimizing regulatory burden for SMEs—adapting EU regulation
to the needs of micro-enterprises, 23 Nov 2011, COM (2011) 803 final
European Commission (2012b) A stronger European industry for growth and economic recovery—
industrial policy communication update, 10 Oct 2012, COM (2012) 582 final
European Commission (2013) Entrepreneurship 2020 action plan—reigniting the entrepreneurial
spirit in Europe, 9 Jan 2013, COM (2012) 795 final
European Commission (2014) For a European industrial renaissance, s.d., COM (2014) 14/2
European Commission (2015) Report on the public consultation on the new SME policy, 2015, at
http://ec.europa.eu/growth/tools-databases/newsroom/cf/itemdetail.cfm?item_id=7744
Juncker JC (2014a) Mission letter to Jyrki Katainen, Vice-President for jobs, growth, invest-
ment and competitiveness, 1 November 2014, at https://ec.europa.eu/commission/sites/cwt/files/
commissioner_mission_letters/katainen_en.pdf
Juncker JC (2014b) A new start for Europe: my agenda for jobs, growth, fairness and democratic
change—political guidelines for the next European commission, 15 July 2014, at http://www.
eesc.europa.eu/resources/docs/jean-claude-juncker—political-guidelines.pdf
Marks G, Hooghe L, Blank K (1996) European integration since the 1980s: state-centric versus
multi-level governance. J Comm Market Stud 34:343–378
Muller P, Gagliardi D, Caliandro C, Bohn NU, Klitou D (2014) Annual report on European
SMEs 2013/2014—a partial and fragile recovery, July 2014, at http://ec.europa.eu/DocsRoom/
documents/16121/attachments/1/translations/en/renditions/native
Presidency Conclusions (2006) Brussels European council of 23–24 March 2006
5 Towards an Entrepreneurial Society: What Can the European … 123
Open Access This chapter is licensed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0
International License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits use, sharing,
adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate
credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license and
indicate if changes were made.
The images or other third party material in this chapter are included in the chapter’s Creative
Commons license, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not
included in the chapter’s Creative Commons license and your intended use is not permitted by
statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from
the copyright holder.
Part II
Country Studies
Chapter 6
A Reform Strategy for Italy
All authors acknowledge financial support from the European Union’s Horizon 2020 research
and innovation program under grant agreement No 649378. László Szerb and Balázs Páger also
acknowledge support from the National Scientific Research Fund of Hungary (OTKA/NKFI grant
no. 120289, titled as Entrepreneurship and Competitiveness investigations in Hungary based
on the Global Entrepreneurship Monitor surveys 2017–2019). Mikael Stenkula also gratefully
acknowledges financial support from Jan Wallanders och Tom Hedelius stiftelse and from the
Marianne and Marcus Wallenberg Foundation.
that make up a major share of its economy. The main bottlenecks in the Italian
entrepreneurial ecosystem are low ambition levels, the lack of skills and education
flowing into entrepreneurial ventures, and a bureaucratically encumbered, non-
meritocratic, business environment that feeds back into a low familiarity with
ambitious entrepreneurship. Italy could strengthen its entrepreneurial ecosystem
in several areas, ranging from boosting human capital investments to reducing the
clientelism in the business environment and recruitment culture. This would open
up more opportunities for the young and talented, eager to engage in productive and
innovative venturing in Italy.
Italy has only been a unified state since 1861 and has been a bicameral parliamentary
democracy under the current constitution since 1948. But Italy has a long and rich
history that influenced and permeated areas well beyond its geographical boundaries.
The Italian city-states of the Renaissance saw the rise of banking and the principles
of Roman Civil Law persist in continental European legal traditions. In many ways,
the deep-rooted institutions in Italy are the deep-rooted institutions in large parts of
Europe. Foremost among these, the Catholic Church in Rome left a deep imprint.
During the Middle Ages, the Catholic Church (The Church) was promoting
corporatism to pacify the conflicts of interests between aristocracy, farmers, and
trade through the various sponsored function-based groups and institutions including
universities, guilds of artisans and craftspeople, and other professional associations.
The establishment of a system that relies on guilds involved the allocation of power
to regulate trade and prices to guilds (Wiarda 1997).
This role of the Church was also evident during industrialization. While workers
asserted their rights, the Church supported them on the one hand, but also fiercely
opposed communism on the other. Nowadays, the Catholic Church in Italy is
characterized by widespread worship throughout Italy and is still very much alive
in Italy through institutions such as schools, hospitals, nursery schools, rest homes,
shelters for the chronically ill and the handicapped, special institutions for education
and retraining, and publishing, to give just some examples (Garelli 2007). Italy
is the nation with the highest level of baptized Catholics, at 97% (55 million) of
the population (Garelli 2007). The Church has provided Italy with a long-standing
L. Szerb
e-mail: szerb.laszlo@ktk.pte.hu
6 A Reform Strategy for Italy 129
even though the legal system and the career paths for judges have essentially been
the same in both parts of the country for 150 years now (Tabellini 2010).
This gap between the two regions, in fact, requires policy makers to bear in mind
that any reform strategy proposed for the North should not blindly be suggested
for Italy’s South and vice versa. Historically, economically, and institutionally, Italy
often constitutes two distinct regions rather than one country with some regional
heterogeneity. Thus, Italy probably needs different policy interventions in its two
regions, building on the deep-rooted institutional frameworks inherited from the
past. In what follows, we, therefore, discuss how institutions for the creation and
diffusion of knowledge, the allocation of finance and labor have evolved in Italy.
In modern economies, the institutions for knowledge creation and diffusion are
largely concentrated in the academic system of education and research and the
system of intellectual property rights. These institutions, notably universities and
patent systems, both have their historical roots in Europe and in fact in renaissance
Italy.
6.1.2.1 Universities
Italian universities rank among the oldest in the world. The University of Bologna
is the oldest recognized university, established in 1088 (Università di Bologna n.d.).
Other Italian universities that have obtained the official status of university institutions
early in the Middle Ages include Padua, Naples, Rome, Perugia, Pisa, and Florence
(Simonini 1954). Universities initially emerged as institutes where theology, law, and
philosophy were taught, and their histories comprise a long struggle to keep external
influences from clerical and secular authorities out and conquering and protecting
scholarly and academic freedom. Today, Italian universities are typically very broad
institutions of academic research, which are publicly funded, while both universities
and professors enjoy high levels of autonomy and focus on academic knowledge
creation and diffusion.
There are two important technical universities in Italy which first appeared at
the end of the nineteenth century. The oldest technical university in Italy is based
in Torino and was established in 1859 under the name Scuola di Applicazione
per gli Ingegneri (Technical School for Engineers). In 1906, it transformed into
what today is known as Politecnico di Torino. Its creation coincided with the new
era of industrialization that put the focus on Electrotechnics and Building Science
(Politecnico di Torino n.d.). Today, this university strives to enhance technological
and scientific research capabilities and integrate them into a higher education
framework (Statute of Politecnico di Torino 2011).
6 A Reform Strategy for Italy 131
The other important technical university of the country, the Politechnico di Milano,
was founded only 4 years later in 1863. Its original name was Regio Instituto
Tecnico Superiore (“Royal Higher Technical Institute”) and the only majors that
were taught were Civil and Industrial Engineering. In 1987, the school expanded
to regional campuses of Como (1987) and Lecco (1989), and regional facilities in
Cremona (1991), Mantova (1994), and Piacenza (1997) (Politecnico di Milano n.d.).
Importantly, both technical universities were founded in the North at the time when
industrialization took off in Italy.1
Complementing the formal academic teaching and research institutes, Italy
recently also invested in the creation of science parks. In these parks, firms and
academic research are physically located close to one another to facilitate knowledge
spillovers and cement the links between research and commerce. According to The
Bank of Italy survey of 2012 on Science and Technology Parks, there was a boom in
the number of science parks in the 1990s. Some 25 were founded at a rate of up to
three per year over a period of about 25 years (Liberati et al. 2016).
There were important first-mover advantages in this area. For example, the
regional government of Turin, focused on policies promoting initiatives such as
incubators and science parks early on and today we see two highly regarded Science
and Technology Parks, the Environment Park, and the Bio-Industry Park (Salvador
2010) in Turin. The Politecnico di Milano was also an early mover in this domain,
and today, its incubator “Polihub” is considered excellent, and ranked as the third
best university incubator in the World Top University Business Incubator Ranking
2017/2018 by the Association UBI Global.
In recent years, Italian universities and Polytechnics have also increasingly started
to teach entrepreneurship and engage in technology transfer in order to generate
spin-offs. Yet, the literature considers entrepreneurship education in Italy still as
“immature” (Iacobucci and Micozzi 2012).
In conclusion, Italian universities and Polytechnics have a proud history and
tradition to build on, but they face challenges preparing for their emerging role
in the modern knowledge-based economy. The curriculum and didactic approaches
would probably benefit from modernization, but deeply entrenched interests and
hard-won academic freedom imply that this is hard to engineer top-down. Instead,
the Italian academic system would have to accept a more engaged role in society and
be convinced that it is also in their interest to make the transition to a system of more
modern, entrepreneurial universities that adopt evidence-based methods and focus
more on engaging academic research with societal challenges.
1 Two more universities have been awarded the label Politecnico. Politecnico di Bari is in the capital
city of the Apulia region, established in 1990 (Politecnico di Bari n.d.), and the University of
Ancona changed its name to Università Politecnica delle Marche and was recognized as a technical
university in 2003 (Politecnica delle Marche 2017). These institutions are based in the South and
Middle of the country, respectively, and were founded to become important actors in the respective
local industrial ecosystems. To date, however, they do still not play the role the older schools play
in the Northern economic system.
132 M. Sanders et al.
The banking system in Italy went through several reforms in the twentieth
century. The Bank Law of 1936 is an example that reformed the whole banking
sector by putting financial intermediaries into different categories depending on their
credit activities. The law also limited the linkages between industry and financial
institutions to alleviate possible conflicts of interest. Another reform, put in place
in 1993, aimed at increasing privatization of the banking system and expanding the
range of activities of banks. Until about 2004, there was some consolidation in the
Italian banking sector but despite this M&A activity, concentration ran counter to
the global trend. Even if there were fewer banks in 2004 (800) than in 1985 (1,100),
the market share of the five largest banks dropped over this period (Goddard et al.
2007; Coccorese 2013), implying that consolidation took place among smaller banks
whereas competition increased at the top.
European legislation, such as the 2004 New EU take-over Directive, implemented
to integrate European financial markets have stimulated further consolidation in
banking (ECB 2017). But Italy’s banking system still has many small, diverse,
relationship-based cooperative banks that support its SMEs also in times of crisis
(Castellani 2018). If the banking sector continues to consolidate, however, as in the
Netherlands or the UK, Italy risks losing its system of small, diverse and arms-length
relationship banking, and credit will be allocated more to real estate (mortgages)
and traded financial assets (Goddard et al. 2007; ECB 2017). This would harm the
entrepreneurial ecosystem and reduce the access to finance for Italian entrepreneurs.
Despite the recent improvements, many Italian banks still struggle with significant
bad debt overhang and a limited ability to finance new projects (Beccalli and
Girardone 2016). Current mandatory reserve and equity ratios are insufficient. When
banking made its biggest contributions to Italy’s development, leverage was much
lower, and banks could shoulder losses better. To justify financing experimental
venturing with bank credit, banks, therefore, should be recapitalized.
Concerning its labor market institutions, Italy is commonly grouped with other
Mediterranean countries such as Spain, Portugal, and Greece. Despite important
differences, these countries are all characterized by labor markets with high
employment protection and low social security. Union bargaining coverage is often
extended and trade unions control large parts of the labor market without being
representative of large parts of the workforce (Dilli et al. 2016; Hassel 2014). These
institutions formed largely when Italy became a unified state and industrialization
fueled the organization of labor in the early twentieth century. Italy’s welfare state
dates back to the aftermath of World War II, and both labor and social security
regulations were frequently reformed even since the 2008 global financial crisis.
6 A Reform Strategy for Italy 135
Dismissals were first regulated in Italy in 1966. Any unfair dismissal obliges
employers to either hire back workers or pay compensation based on individuals’
experience and firm size (Boeri and Jimeno 2005). For workers with less than two
and a half years of tenure, the compensation ranged between 5 and 8 months, and
for those with between two and a half and 20 years of tenure, the compensation
varied from 5 to 12 months. The above regulation applied to firms with more than
60 employees while those with less had to pay half the severance pay (Boeri and
Jimeno 2005). In 1970, the Statuto dei Lavoratori obliged firms with more than 15
employees to hire back workers and pay their foregone earnings in case of unfair
dismissals while firms with less than 15 employees were totally exempted (Leonardi
and Pica 2006).
Historically, Italy was considered one of the strictest countries in terms of
employment protection legislation (Lazear 1990; Bertola 1990; Nicoletti et al. 1999).
As these arrangements proved to represent a barrier to entrepreneurship in general
(Golpe et al. 2008) and to ambitious entrepreneurship in particular (Henrekson et al.
2010), important reforms were introduced in 2003 with the Biagi reform (Cirillo
et al. 2017) and more recently with the Monti-Fornero reforms of 2012 and the “Jobs
Act” of 2014 (Tiraboschi 2012; Carinci 2015). These reforms moved Italy’s labor
market firmly in the direction of the flexicurity camp.
The most significant modifications include the easing of dismissal regulation,
more emphasis on active labor market policies and a new supervising national
authority to enhance coordination among public and private actors (Raulli 2017).
More generally, Italy has followed the Danish flexicurity recipe and decided to move
from security of employees and jobs to security of income and work. In general, such
reforms could support a more entrepreneurial society in Italy, but a careful evaluation
of these reforms will have to show how they perform in the Italian context.
Regarding the wage setting institutions, this is based on the tripartite agreement of
July 23, 1993. Italy has an industry-wide bargaining model, applied at the national
level (Eurofound 2009). As Calmfors and Driffill (1988) have shown, such a system
of wage bargaining tends to increase wage pressure, which in turn may result in
high long-run unemployment. Specifically, for entrepreneurs, such national coverage
implies that vested interest parties can directly influence a major cost component for
any (new) employer in their sector.
More importantly, these vested interest parties will also negotiate additional job-
related rights and entitlements that have limited portability across industries, are easy
for incumbents to administer, but put a large burden on new ventures. Trade unions,
for example, negotiate the terms of pensions, sickness and maternity leave, working
hours per week, month and year, leave, and education on the job. In the Italian
corporatist tradition employers, state and workers will negotiate in relative harmony
136 M. Sanders et al.
(Regini 1997), but Italy also has a strong history of class struggle and communism
(Kertzer 1980), making unions more militant and willing to strike for their rights
than in other Continental European countries. They share this labor militancy with
the Mediterranean countries, although in recent decades, strikes are declining and
labor relations seem to become more harmonious (Gall 1999).
Alternatively, one can interpret this as trade unions becoming less powerful and
representative as organization rates decline in new industries. As unions typically
protect the position of their (long-term employed) members, their decline would level
the playing field for more entrepreneurial employers, but reforms in this area should
respect the tradition of paying “decent wages for decent jobs” not to clash with other
important aspects of the Italian institutional framework.
In the 1990s, Italy was still highly dominated by small businesses. More than 99%
of active firms employed less than 50 employees and less than 3,000 firms employed
more than 250 employees (Unioncamere 2005). Increasingly, more attention was
paid to SMEs by industrial policy, especially that concerning innovation, which was
usually thought to be of sole concern to larger firms. In addition, improvements
6 A Reform Strategy for Italy 137
The Italian response to the financial crisis of 2009 was focused on strengthening
its innovative SME sector and initially even on increasing spending to maintain
investment in innovation and R&D. In 2009, Italy was one of the first EU countries
to approve the European Commission’s 2008 Small Business Act (SBA) proposal
and adopted it domestically. The approval of this program allowed for the immediate
mandatory and continuous monitoring of SME policies and for the arrangement of
“one law a year” regarding small firms (Ministero dello Sviluppo Economico n.d.).
Some of the interventions under the SBA included:
• Law 185/2008, proposed to guarantee the integrity of credit and avoid any charges
to businesses;
• Law 29/2009-2, adopted to facilitate access to credit by introducing, the “Tremonti
Bond,” through which the banks can grant loans to businesses;
• Law 78/2009 (‘Manovra anti-crisi’), passed to promote the reinvestment of profits
in capital goods;
• Law 99/2009 (‘Legge Sviluppo’), providing a broad mandate to the government to
reorganize regulatory obligations for companies;
• “Unique Communication” launched in 2009 giving the possibility for starting a
business by sending a single communication to the Chamber of Commerce;
• Law 82/2009 establishing an 80 million euro facility for product and/or process
innovations replacing or eliminating chemical substances.
Other initiatives regarding the sustained growth of SMEs included: a fund for
competition and innovation; a fund for rescue and restructuring of businesses in
difficulty; a fund for districts and business networks; measures for the automobile
138 M. Sanders et al.
sector, domestic appliances, furniture, and apparel; the National Innovation Fund
(for patents); the Made in Italy Fund (for internationalization); and various fiscal
initiatives (Ministero dello Sviluppo Economico 2009).
More specific attention to entrepreneurship followed shortly after. The Program
Restart Italia! was launched in 2012 to reshape the Italian entrepreneurial
environment in order to promote economic growth and employment. Overall
the project envisioned outcomes such as the development of innovation and
entrepreneurship culture, social mobility, transparency, and meritocracy as well as
the attraction of foreign factors of production.
Arguably, the most significant result of the implementation of the Restart Italia!
program was the newly recognized status of start-ups—as innovative enterprises
of high technological value—when it was introduced into the Italian legal system.
The resulting “Law 221/2012” (the so-called Italian Start-up Act) is an organic and
coherent policy for which public support for innovative entrepreneurship represents
a new way of thinking about industrial policymaking (Ministero dello Sviluppo
Economico 2012).
In 2014, Italy introduced the Start-up Visa (ISV) program facilitating self-
employment visas to non-EU citizens who were interested in launching an innovative
start-up in Italy. The initiative was composed of a novel procedure which was
characterized by being “fast-track”—never taking more than 30 days to be issued—
and being centralized, digitized, bilingual, and free of charge. The committee
evaluating the applications has been formed by the presidents of five key associations
of the Italian innovation ecosystem, including business angel firms, university
incubators, and others.
Several policy initiatives followed. Among the most important was the national
Plan Industria 4.0 which became effective in 2017. The plan was designed for firms
operating in the manufacturing sector and intended as “a great deed of trust from
the government to enterprise.” The program is to be applied without—or as few as
possible—constraints by bureaucratic processes or subjected to territorial or sectorial
selection and invests in all stages of the life cycle of firms, particularly focusing on
investment support in the digitalization of production, the development of employee
productivity, the training of applicable skills and the development of new products
and procedures (Ministero dello Sviluppo Economico 2017).
These programs have of course been evaluated, but it is difficult to ascertain
their true impact. It would also take us beyond the scope of this chapter to attempt
an assessment here. In short, in recent years, policy attention for SMEs and later
entrepreneurial venturing has risen considerably in Italy and the financial and Euro
crisis have strengthened the call to reform. However, in Italy there is also a political
backlash, and reformists should take care to emphasize and ensure the inclusive
character of reforms toward an entrepreneurial society, creating more and better
opportunities for challengers, not lining the pockets of incumbents in business and
politics.
6 A Reform Strategy for Italy 139
6.1.6 Conclusions
In conclusion, we can take away a few important lessons from the above. First,
Italy has a long history of supporting a vibrant entrepreneurial economy of locally
embedded, often family-owned small- and medium-sized firms that make up the
overwhelming majority of its economy. The Italian ecosystem was supported by
banks, patents, and universities early on and industrialization, especially in the North,
brought deep rooted but modern financial, labor, and knowledge institutions to Italy.
From more recent policy initiatives, we may tentatively conclude that national
policy makers in Italy have recognized the importance of supporting Italy’s
Entrepreneurial Society. Moreover, we note that recent policy initiatives seem well-
informed and well-targeted. Policy makers try to reduce the regulatory burden and
remove undue barriers to new initiatives. Policies are more general and targeted
at entrepreneurial venturing in general, and are not specifically directed toward
sectoral, geographic or size-related barriers. Building on its unique history, Italy
is well-positioned to promote more entrepreneurship in its economy in both North
and South. In our next steps, we will use quantitative and qualitative information to
identify what factors are holding Italian entrepreneurs back.
Fig. 6.1 Radar-plot REDI comparison Germany–Italy–UK and EU-average. Source Authors’ own
compilation
remains weak in the sub-index Entrepreneurial Attitudes (upper right pillars 1–5) and
in Entrepreneurial Abilities (lower pillars 6–9). Even on Entrepreneurial Aspirations,
it scores low because of the large imbalances between the pillars in the upper left
side of the radar-plot (pillars 10–14).
The underlying algorithm in the REDI puts a penalty on bottlenecks in the
ecosystem (Acs et al. 2014; Szerb et al. 2017), such that a rounder radar-plot
scores higher than a more erratic one, and policy interventions should be aimed
at alleviating bottlenecks with priority. As we have indicated, however, the national
average potentially hides a lot of regional heterogeneity. We, therefore, focus in on
Italy’s main regions next.
If we zoom in on the regional level, in Fig. 6.2 and Table 6.1, we see that all Italian
regions score between 25.7 and 33.5, with the Southern regions significantly lagging
the Center and North, as expected.2
2 The
numbers are index numbers ranging from 0 (worst) to 100 (best) across all 125 European
NUTS2/3 regions for 2012–2014.
6 A Reform Strategy for Italy 141
Fig. 6.2 REDI map of Italian regions. Source Authors’ own compilation
Without going into too much detail in this chapter,3 the intuition behind each
of the pillars is that data on individual entrepreneurial agency, obtained from the
Global Entrepreneurship Monitor adult population survey data, is combined with
relevant institutional quality indicators from a wide variety of reputed international
institutions, such as World Bank, Freedom House and OECD. The index then builds
on the assumption that institutions and individual agency are complements (Acs
et al. 2014; Acs and Szerb 2009). That is, high levels of, for example, Opportunity
Perception in a low-quality institutional environment, will contribute little. Likewise,
low Opportunity Perception in a high-quality institutional environment is also a sign
of weakness in the entrepreneurial ecosystem.
To improve the score on a given pillar, policies and reforms should seek to improve
the weakest link and then aim to increase both institutional quality and individual
agency together. Especially because of the latter, the menu of effective interventions
is not limited to improving the scores on the institutional quality indices alone. The
same logic is then also imposed on the individual pillars that make up the three
sub-indices: Entrepreneurial Attitudes, Abilities, and Aspirations.
The good news for Italy and its regions, based on these analyses, is that with
small improvements in its weakest pillars, large improvements in the ecosystem
can be expected. Moreover, from Table 6.2, we can see that, although the overall
scores are lower in the Southern regions, the weaknesses in the Southern and
Northern ecosystems seem largely concentrated in the same pillars and variables.
This implies that national policy and reform programs addressing these weaknesses,
will strengthen entrepreneurial society throughout the country and Table 6.2 gives us
a clear sense of the priorities. National level policies to promote pillars 5 “Cultural
Support,” 6 “Opportunity Start-up,” 8 “Human Capital,” and 12 “High Growth” are
likely to benefit Entrepreneurial Aspirations, Abilities, and Attitudes throughout the
territory.
3 We refer interested readers to Acs et al. (2014) and Szerb et al. (2017, 2019) for further details.
6 A Reform Strategy for Italy 143
Our reading of the data above reveals that, in all Italian regions and the country as
a whole, the main bottlenecks in the entrepreneurial ecosystem are low ambition
levels (High Growth), the lack of skills and education (Human Capital), and an
entangled business environment (Opportunity Start-up) that feeds back into a low
familiarity with ambitious entrepreneurship and a rather closed culture (Networking
and Cultural Support).
Generally, it is dangerous, to rely exclusively on data and aggregate indices, even
if they are composed of a broad set of sub-indicators and disaggregated as much
as the data might allow. It is always important to complement a data-based quick
scan with historical analysis, common sense, and more qualitative information to
contextualize and complete the diagnosis. Only after triangulating the results above
with the historical analysis, literature review, expert judgment, and more qualitative
survey results below, we can map the diagnosis onto our menu of interventions to
propose tailored reforms for Italy.
144 M. Sanders et al.
In the same survey, we also asked founders the following: “In your view, what can
policy makers do to facilitate venture creation?”. An overview of the answers to these
questions is given in Table 6.4. Almost every founder had at least one suggestion of
how venture creation could be facilitated by the government. The suggestions often
mirror the obstacles encountered during venture creation. Accordingly, measures
to alleviate bureaucracy and facilitate access to finance are listed amongst the top
priorities by the founders. The respondents suggested to facilitate venture creation by
reducing bureaucracy in almost 18% of all cases, to simplify bureaucratic procedures
through online tools in more than 4% of responses, and to eliminate the need for a
notary or to provide a notary in, together, almost 4% of cases.
Next to that, some broader suggestions were made about how to facilitate the
formalities related to venture creation, namely an easier availability or accessibility
of information about how to start a business (almost 5%) and better guidance of how
to proceed when setting-up a new venture (slightly more than 3%). Taken together,
suggestions related to facilitating administrative formalities amount to one third of all
suggestions made, which illustrates the potential of this area for policy improvements.
In order to alleviate the financial constraints on nascent ventures, the respondents
suggested to reduce taxes for small businesses (in more than 8% of all answers),
to facilitate access to financial capital (almost 14% of responses), and to establish
procedures to better detect which ventures are seeking investment (1.6% of all
responses). Finance-related policy improvements make up a quarter of all policy
suggestions, thus constituting another area of substantial concern.
While founders also followed-up on the third group of obstacles encountered by
suggesting that constant policy changes should be avoided, this suggestion was made
6 A Reform Strategy for Italy 147
in 1.6% of cases. The third major block of policy recommendations, therefore, does
not relate to more stable policies. Instead, it refers to facilitating access to human
capital. Accordingly, founders suggested in almost 7% of their answers that policy
makers should provide incentives for hiring people, in almost 5% of cases that people
should be better trained in entrepreneurial skills, and in almost 2% of cases that an
accountant should be provided to nascent ventures.
Finally, and unrelated to the hurdles they reported above, some founders also see
a role for the government in helping to market the products/services of start-ups
(1.6%) and to provide networking opportunities (1.6%).
Overall, we, thus, find general support for the weaknesses identified in the above
historical and quantitative analyses. Most importantly, Italy’s founders point to the
tedious bureaucratic processes as a major obstacle and, accordingly, for policy
improvements. At a more general level, these suggestions can be interpreted as
an invitation to move away from a non-transparent and heavy toward a leaner
way of establishing new ventures. In addition, the call for easier access to human
and financial capital reflects the insights gained from our analyses of the previous
148 M. Sanders et al.
sections. Founders are signaling a lack of information and training and call for a
more stable policy environment. We interpret this as general support for a more
fundamental reform approach that creates the institutional support for those providing
such services and knowledge.
6.3.4 Conclusions
In sum, the survey has confirmed most of the weaknesses identified in Sect. 6.2, but
also provided some interesting additional insights. For example, the need to create a
stable institutional framework that is above all transparent and clear is information
that is hard to gather from quantitative data alone. The survey was, therefore, useful
in nuancing some of the previous results.
Yet, when asked for the most important barriers encountered and possible policy
remedies, founders—rather obviously—mention those points which they met in their
personal experiences. While there certainly is valuable information in this experience,
it is important to base policy recommendations on a broader basis by combining
personal experiences with information of encompassing datasets. Taken together,
the triangulation of our historical, quantitative and qualitative information for Italy
reveals sufficient information to draw up a tentative diagnosis and turn to treatments.
In the previous sections, we have considered the history of Italy, used an advanced
diagnostic tool to scan for her most urgent problems, and asked founders how they
felt and what they believed would be good treatments. Based on all this information,
we can come to a diagnosis and map that diagnosis onto the menu of treatments
developed in Elert et al. (2019) to propose a course of action that best fits the patient.
Italy has a long and proud history. Many of the institutions that shape an
entrepreneurial society today have their roots in Italy. Italy has seen the birth of
modern banking, invented intellectual property rights protection, and boasts the oldest
surviving universities in the world. Consequently, Italy features a highly innovative
small- and medium-sized entrepreneurial sector that competes at the global level.
Innovative entrepreneurship has deep historical roots in Italy.
But time has progressed while the quality of the Italian entrepreneurial ecosystem
seems to have eroded. The Italian data show quite serious weaknesses and importantly
significant imbalances across the pillars that make up the REDI. Italy still performs
quite well on innovation and technology absorption, but this is not complemented by a
supportive culture, networks, and human capital. To face the challenges of the future,
Italy will have to build on its historical strengths but should urgently address these
bottlenecks. Fortunately, our regional analysis has shown that the same weaknesses
hold back entrepreneurship across the country, despite significant and lasting overall
6 A Reform Strategy for Italy 149
level effects between regions in the North and Center, and the South. This implies
that Italy can strengthen its entrepreneurial ecosystem in all regions by boosting
human capital investments and, more importantly, opening up opportunities for the
young and talented to engage in productive and innovative venturing across Italy.
In the recent crisis, but also before, Italy has experienced an exodus of talent. It
seems there are more opportunities abroad than at home and young Italians are
entrepreneurial enough to go after them.
Of those that stayed and started up ventures in Italy, we heard complaints
about cumbersome bureaucracy resulting in lacking growth ambitions and stunted
economic dynamics. Our survey among Italian founders also revealed that complexity
of the tax system, an inefficient judicial system, and cumbersome bureaucratic
requirements add to the uncertainties that entrepreneurs already face and put a break
on venture creation.
Taking this diagnosis to our menu of policy interventions and reform proposals
in the companion volume of this book (Elert et al. 2019), we have selected what
we believe to be fifteen suitable interventions for Italy. They are listed in Table 6.5.
In Column 1, we find the number under which they were presented in Elert et al.
(2019). Column 2 lists the policy area and 3 the proposal, where Column 4 gives our
motivation for the case of Italy tying it in with the analysis presented above.
The first proposal (1) resulted from the discussions we have had with Italian
founders in our surveys and was confirmed in a literature search. The need for
simplicity, transparency, and predictability is high in any business venture, but
certainly important in entrepreneurial ones where technical and market uncertainty
is already high. Adding legal, bureaucratic, and fiscal uncertainties and complexities
to this mix is not productive.
The set of fiscal and financial reform proposals (6, 8, 13 and 19) aim to eliminate
that uncertainty in the tax sphere, and at the same time leave more financial
resources in the hands of the people who can invest it in small amounts and in
more experimental ventures at arm’s length. When combined with investment in
a reliable ICT infrastructure that can support the emergence of platform-based
finance, this may prove a powerful push toward the decentralization of entrepreneurial
finance. Still, we chose to focus first on setting the framework conditions for such a
strategy to work. Proposal 19, instead, aims to strengthen Italy’s traditionally diverse,
decentralized, and deeply rooted system of local banking, that would also benefit from
intermediating more privately held and managed wealth.
The proposals referring to Italian labor market institutions (23, 25, 27 and 31)
all aim to mobilize labor across regions, sectors, and jobs, while at the same time
maintaining a social security level that people are by now accustomed to in Italy.
This balancing act involves making social security entitlements less conditional and
more portable, while reducing job protection and barriers to job mobility.
Reducing barriers to new business formation (32) is a direct and obvious proposal
in light of our aim to promote a more entrepreneurial society in Italy. New ventures
typically come in the form of new businesses and organizations that need to be
established also formally before they can reach their full potential. At the same time,
we propose (40) to also carefully monitor these new firms and collect and disseminate
the knowledge that is gained, even, or perhaps especially, when new businesses fail.
150 M. Sanders et al.
Finally, we propose Italy should consider urgent reforms to its educational system
(41, 42, 44 and 45) to ensure its young and talented are better prepared for a future
in a more entrepreneurial Italy. This starts in primary schools and even earlier,
with a reorientation on creativity and experimentation, whereas English proficiency
and STEM topics will prepare Italian youths for a future in a globalized and
technologically rapidly changing economy. Meanwhile, Italy’s established academic
institutions should open up to the world outside of academia, preferably from a
genuine position of scholarly curiosity and interest, rather than driven by financial
and policy incentives.
6 A Reform Strategy for Italy 155
To put our proposed reform program in its proper context, it is important to discuss
the diagnosis and proposed treatments with experts in the field. In this case that is
Italian policy makers that are active in the field every day. Moreover, given the wide
diversity of policy areas involved, it is important to not only discuss this with policy
makers that are active in “entrepreneurship policy” in the narrow sense. Our approach
emphasizes the importance of reforming institutions that determine the allocation of
financial, labor, and knowledge resources to entrepreneurial activity in the broadest
and most inclusive sense of the word. Broadening the scope was motivated by the
fact that entrepreneurship policy in the narrow sense has been around for some three
decades or more, also in Italy, and to date has achieved only limited success.
Because of its breadth, our reform agenda inevitably cuts across many policy areas,
traditionally less associated with entrepreneurship policy, including, for example,
wealth taxation, financial and labor market regulation, social security, and science
policy. As the institutions in these areas have evolved historically and policy makers
in these areas pursue different, equally relevant, public policy priorities, the challenge
is to discuss the proposed agenda in sufficient depth, but with a sufficiently diverse
group of policy makers and practitioners. Policies and institutions in these different
areas overlap and interact in ways that affect the quality and performance of the
entrepreneurial ecosystem (Stam 2015, 2018). The challenge is to not only propose
156 M. Sanders et al.
policies and reforms that will strengthen the ecosystem, but to do it in such a way
that other important policy priorities are also achieved.
In order to receive a first round of feedback on the proposals for Italy presented in
Table 6.5, a policy round table was held at the CDP Group (Cassa Depositi e Prestiti)
in Rome on March 5, 2018. This step can be seen as an attempt to allow our patient,
or perhaps more accurately, her team of medical specialists, intimately familiar with
our patient, to give feedback about our diagnosis and proposed treatments. What
proposals would this team endorse, question or maybe want to drop?
In this policy round table, the diagnosis presented above was broadly shared
among the participants. The group included representatives from the Bank of Italy,
the OECD, UNCTAD and the Italian Ministry of Economic Development (Sanders
and Grilli 2018). Participants recognized the encumbered bureaucracy and inflexible
educational system as well as the long-standing North–South divide and issues of
effective and high-quality governance. There was general consensus that universities
could function as catalysts by playing a more important role in supporting financial
education and putting entrepreneurship at the center of the stage. Another important
deficiency in the Italian entrepreneurial ecosystem is the shortage of dedicated
networking events. Italy has many, small, high-quality centers of excellence, but
they lack mass and local governments could act to improve this situation. Participants
added that it is also important to improve attitudes toward risk taking and reduce the
cultural stigma arising from failure.
Given the background and natural inclinations of the host institution, there was
perhaps a slight bias in the selection of participants and emphasis on financial
policies and institutions in Italy, even when these issues did not stand out as the main
bottleneck in Italy in our diagnosis. This fact was recognized in the group, but as many
were interested in and actively involved in financial policy making, the issue was
still on the table. Concerning financing issues and venture capital, it was mentioned
that the small VC industry may not only be a result of insufficient demand for this
type of capital. It may also stem from the VC lack of competencies and a shortage of
professional skills in this area. Crowdfunding platforms providing an alternative route
to financing scale ups and exits, may fit well with the Italian tradition of family-based
share holdings and finance and preserve an orientation on long-run value creation.
There were also weaknesses that were not mentioned in our analysis so far
but were deemed important. Public procurement and the governance of the public
administration were considered to be the most prominent problems by many
participants. Too many ministries and public bodies are responsible for too many
parts of a too complex puzzle. In addition, there is a problem with the quality of
governance in general and of innovation and entrepreneurship policy specifically
due to an aged workforce with outdated skills in the public sector—only 40% of
Italian civil servants hold a university degree and the share of central government
employees below the age of 35 is just 2.2%. High levels of job protection in civil
service make it difficult to change these numbers, but it is evidently a problem when
young and dynamic entrepreneurs have to deal with an ossified and outdated civil
service.
6 A Reform Strategy for Italy 157
6.6 Conclusions
and only form the starting point, not the final word in the policy debate. Moreover,
even if eventually adopted, our proposals all require careful implementation and
evaluation to complete the FIRES Seven Step cycle.
References
Acs ZJ, Autio E, Szerb L (2014) National systems of entrepreneurship: measurement issues and
policy implications. Res Policy 43(3):476–494. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2013.08.016
Acs ZJ, Szerb L (2009) The global entrepreneurship index (GEINDEX). Found Trends Entrep
5(5):341–435. https://doi.org/10.1561/0300000027
Allini A, Ferri L, Maffei M, Zampella A (2017) The effect of perceived corruption on entrepreneurial
intention: evidence from Italy. Int Bus Res 10(6):75–86
Barbagallo F (2001) Italy: the idea and the reality of the nation. J Mod Ital Stud 6(3):388–401
Baum CF, Munro JM, Schachter G (1990) Structural change and economic development in Southern
Italy. J Dev Stud 27(1):54–71
Beccalli E, Girardone C (2016) Banking in Italy. In: Beck T, Casu B (eds) The Palgrave handbook
of European banking. Palgrave Macmillan, London, pp 521–540
Bertola G (1990) Job security, employment and wages. Eur Econ Rev 34(4):851–879
Boeri T, Jimeno JF (2005) The effects of employment protection: learning from variable
enforcement. Eur Econ Rev 49(8):2057–2077
Bohlen C (1996) North-South divide in Italy: a problem for Europe, too. New York
Times. Retrieved from: http://www.nytimes.com/1996/11/15/world/north-south-divide-in-italy-
a-problem-for-europe-too.html
Boland V (2009) Modern dilemma for world’s oldest bank. Financial Times, June 12. Retrieved
from: https://www.ft.com/content/a034542e-5771-11de-8c47-00144feabdc0
Boldrin M, Levine DK (2008) Against intellectual monopoly. Cambridge University Press,
Cambridge
Bottazzi L, Da Rin M (2002) Venture capital in Europe and the financing of innovative companies.
Economic policy 17(34):229–270
Calmfors L, Driffill J (1988) Bargaining structure, corporatism and macroeconomic performance.
Economic policy 3(6):13–61
Carinci F (2015) Labour law and industrial relations in Italy: update to the jobs act (no. 183-2014).
IPSOA/Wolters Kluwers, Milano
Castellani D (2018) Mortgage-backed securitization and SME lending during the financial and
economic crisis: evidence from the Italian cooperative banking system. Econ Notes 47(1):187–
222
Cazzola F (1988) Della corruzione. Il Mulino, Bologna
Cirillo V, Fana M, Guarascio D (2017) Labour market reforms in Italy: evaluating the effects of the
jobs act. Econ Polit 34(2):211–232
Coccorese P (2013) Assessing the competitive conditions in the Italian banking system: some
empirical evidence. PSL Q Rev 51(205):171–191
D’Attore PP (1987) Italian reconstruction and “depressed areas”: the Marshall plan in the
Mezzogiorno. Center for European studies working paper series no. 11. Harvard University
De Roover R (1999) The rise and decline of the Medici bank: 1397–1494. Beard Books, New York
Dilli S, Elert N, Herrmann AM (2018) Varieties of entrepreneurship. Exploring the institutional
foundations of different entrepreneurship types through ‘varieties-of-capitalism’ arguments.
Special issue on “financial and institutional reforms for an entrepreneurial society.” Small Bus
Econ, 51(2):293–320
Dilli S, Henrekson M, Westerhuis G (2016) The institutional evolution of labour market institutions
in Europe and entrepreneurship. Retrieved from https://projectfires.eu/wp-content/uploads/2017/
09/D2.5-The-Institutional-Evolution-of-Labour-Market.pdf
6 A Reform Strategy for Italy 159
D’Onza G, Brotini F, Zarone V (2017) Disclosure on measures to prevent corruption risks: a study
of Italian local governments. Int J Public Adm 40(7):612–624
Duggan C (2013) A concise history of Italy. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge
ECB (2017) Report on financial structures 2017. ECB, Frankfurt
Economist (1999) Those Medici. Retrieved from http://www.economist.com/node/347333
Economist (2017) Italy’s fourth-biggest bank returns to the stock market. Retrieved from https://
www.economist.com/news/finance-and-economics/21730672-shares-bailed-out-bank-start-
trading-again-italys-fourth-biggest-bank
Elert N, Henrekson M, Sanders M (2019) The entrepreneurial society: a reform strategy for the
European Union. Springer, Berlin
Eurofound (2009) Italy: ‘wage formation’. Retrieved from https://www.eurofound.europa.
eu/observatories/eurwork/comparative-information/national-contributions/italy/italy-wage-
formation
Ferrera M (2005) Welfare states and social safety nets in Southern Europe: an introduction. In:
Ferrera M (ed) Welfare state reform in southern Europe: fighting poverty and social exclusion in
Greece, Italy, Spain and Portugal. Routledge, London, pp 1–24
Frumkin M (1945) The origin of patents. J Pat Off Soc 27(3):143–149
Gall G (1999) A review of strike activity in Western Europe at the end of the second millennium.
Empl Relat 21(4):357–377
Garelli F (2007) The public relevance of the church and Catholicism in Italy. J Mod Ital Stud
12(1):8–36
Gerschenkron A (1962) Economic backwardness in historical perspective: a book of essays. Belknap
Press of Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA
Goddard J, Molyneux P, Wilson JO, Tavakoli M (2007) European banking: an overview. J Bank
Finance 31(7):1911–1935
Goldthwaite RA (1995) Banks, palaces and entrepreneurs in renaissance Florence. Variorum,
Aldershot
Golpe AA, Millán JM, Román C (2008) Labor market institutions and entrepreneurship. In:
Congregado E (ed) Measuring entrepreneurship: building a statistical system. Springer, New
York, NY, pp 279–296
Graubard SR, Cavazza FL (1974) Il caso italiano. Garzanti, Milano
Hassel A (2014) Adjustments in the Eurozone: varieties of capitalism and the crisis in Southern
Europe. LSE Europe in question discussion paper series no. 76/2014
Held L (2019) Part-time entrepreneurship: the role of institutions, venture and individual
characteristics in entry and transition choices. In: Held L (ed) Unravelling the patterns in venture
creation processes, Ph.D. thesis. Utrecht University, Utrecht, pp 25–55
Held L, Herrmann AM, Polzin F (2018a) Follow the money: the funding acquisition process
of nascent ventures. Horizon 2020 Project on “Financial and Institutional Reforms for an
Entrepreneurial Society” (FIRES), Workpackage 5, Deliverable 5.1; currently under review. Also
available in Held L (2019) Unravelling the patterns in venture creation processes. Ph.D. thesis.
Utrecht University, Utrecht, pp 91–122
Held L, Herrmann AM, Storz C (2018b) Whom do nascent ventures search for? Variance of
linkage formation activities during new product development processes. Horizon 2020 Project on
“Financial and Institutional Reforms for an Entrepreneurial Society” (FIRES), Workpackage 5,
Deliverable 5.1; currently under review. Also available in Held L (2019) Unravelling the patterns
in venture creation processes. Ph.D. thesis. Utrecht University, Utrecht, pp 123–150
Herrmann AM (2019) A plea for varieties of entrepreneurship. Special issue on “entrepreneurship
in context.” Small Bus Econ 52(2):331–343
Herrman AM (2020) On the institutional foundations of the varieties of entrepreneurship in Europe.
In: Sanders M, Marx A, Stenkula M (eds) The entrepreneurial society. Reform strategies for Italy,
Germany and the UK. Springer, Berlin
160 M. Sanders et al.
Herrmann AM, Fischer B, Held L (2018) Internationally comparative dataset on start-up processes
and their institutional foundations in Germany, Italy, the UK and the US, 1–17. Retrieved from
https://projectfires.eu/wp-content/uploads/2018/10/d5.1-combined-complete.pdf
Henrekson M, Johansson D, Stenkula M (2010) Taxation, labor market policy and high-impact
entrepreneurship. J Ind Compet Trade 10(3–4):275–296
Henrekson M, Sanandaji T (2017) Stock option taxation: a missing piece of European innovation
policy? Retrieved from http://www.projectfires.eu/wp-content/uploads/2017/09/Complete-D5.9-
submission.pdf
Hertner P (2016) Starting from scratch? The beginnings of Banca Commerciale Italiana: 1893–
1894. In: Hofmann C, Müller M (eds) History of financial institutions: essays on the history of
European finance, 1800–1950. Routledge, New York, NY, pp 13–38
Hoggson NF (2007) Banking through the ages: from the Romans to the Medicis, from the Dutch
to the Rothschilds. Cosimo Inc., New York, NY
Iacobucci D, Micozzi A (2012) Entrepreneurship education in Italian universities: trend, situation
and opportunities. Education+Training 54(8/9):673–696
Ichino A, Maggi G (2000) Work environment and individual background: explaining regional
shirking differentials in a large Italian firm. Q J Econ 115(3):1057–1090
Kertzer DI (1980) Comrades and Christians: religion and political struggle in communist Italy.
Cambridge University Press, Cambridge
Lazear EP (1990) Job security provisions and employment. Q J Econ 105(3):699–726
Leonardi M, Pica G (2006) Effects of employment protection legislation on wages: a regression
discontinuity approach. University of Milan, Mimeo
Liberati D, Marinucci M, Tanzi GM (2016) Science and technology parks in Italy: main features
and analysis of their effects on the firms hosted. J Technol Transfer 41(4):694–729
Long PO (1991) Invention, authorship, “intellectual property,” and the origin of patents: notes
toward a conceptual history. Technol Cult 32(4):846–884
MacDonald SB, Gastmann AL (2000) A history of credit and power in the Western world.
Transaction Publishers, London
Maynard JT (1980) Understanding chemical patents. A guide for the inventor. Anal Chem
52(6):660A–660A
Ministero dello Sviluppo Economico (n.d.) Small business act. Retrieved from http://www.
sviluppoeconomico.gov.it/index.php/it/impresa/piccole-e-medie-imprese/small-business-act
Ministero dello Sviluppo Economico (2009) Small business act: le iniziative in materia di sostegno
alle pmi nell’europa A 27. Retrieved from http://www.sviluppoeconomico.gov.it/images/stories/
recuperi/Notizie/SBA27_2009.pdf
Ministero dello Sviluppo Economico (2012) Restart Italia! Report of the task force on startups set
up by the ministry of economic development
Ministero dello Sviluppo Economico (2017) Italia start-up visa hub, 4th quarter report. Summary
of the main findings, 31 Dec 2017
Moradei G (2009) Patent information in Italy. World Pat Inf 31(1):19–31
Nicoletti G, Scarpetta S, Boylaud O (1999) Summary indicators of product market regulation with
and extension to employment protection legislation. OECD working paper no. 226
Panunzi F (2012) Contro il monopolio sulla proprietà intelletuale. Lavoce. Retrieved from http://
www.lavoce.info/archives/27450/contro-il-monopolio-sulla-proprieta-intellettuale/
Politecnico di Bari (n.d.) History. Retrieved from http://www.en.poliba.it/university/history
Politecnica delle Marche (2017) Historical highlights: the origins. Retrieved from http://www.
univpm.it/Entra/Informations_about_University/Historical_Highlights
Politecnico di Milano (n.d.) Towards the present. Retrieved from https://www.polimi.it/en/
university/history/towards-the-present/
Politecnico di Torino (n.d.) History. Retrieved from https://www.polito.it/ateneo/storia/index.php?
lang=en
Raulli L (2017) Transformation of the Italian labor market under the Renzi government: explaining
the shift to flexicurity. Master Thesis, Ludwig-Maximilians-Universität, München
6 A Reform Strategy for Italy 161
Open Access This chapter is licensed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0
International License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits use, sharing,
adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate
credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license and
indicate if changes were made.
The images or other third party material in this chapter are included in the chapter’s Creative
Commons license, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not
included in the chapter’s Creative Commons license and your intended use is not permitted by
statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from
the copyright holder.
Chapter 7
A Reform Strategy for Germany
All authors acknowledge financial support from the European Union’s Horizon 2020 research
and innovation program under grant agreement No 649378. László Szerb and Balázs Páger also
acknowledge support from the National Scientific Research Fund of Hungary (OTKA/NKFI grant
no. 120289 titled as Entrepreneurship and Competitiveness investigations in Hungary based on the
Global Entrepreneurship Monitor surveys 2017–2019). Mikael Stenkula also gratefully acknowl-
edges financial support from Jan Wallanders och Tom Hedelius stiftelse and from the Marianne and
Marcus Wallenberg Foundation.
M. Wyrwich
Faculty of Economics and Business, University of Groningen, Groningen, The Netherlands
e-mail: m.wyrwich@rug.nl
1 This has implications for entrepreneurship today. Nunziata and Rocco (2018) show that Protestants
in Germany have a stronger entrepreneurial intention than Catholics under certain conditions.
7 A Reform Strategy for Germany 165
known as the Gründerkrach (Uebele and Ritschl 2009; Burhop 2011). Germany inte-
grated and industrialized rapidly until World War I. But Germany inherited a distinct
regional variation that left traces to this day (Tipton 1976; Gutberlet 2014).2
The Great War imposed an enormous burden in lives lost and resources wasted.
Due to the massive reparation payments imposed in the Versailles Treaty, Germany
had a hard time recovering (Broadberry and Harrison 2005).3 Hyperinflation left a
lasting imprint on the German psyche in 1923 and the economic situation worsened
after a few years of economic stability in the mid-1920s. The crash of 1929 and
the following Great Depression led to massive unemployment, to the breakdown of
leading banks in 1931 (James 1981; Kopper 2011), and fueled the rise of the Nazi
movement. The economic system of the Nazi regime that seized power in 1933 was
based on autarky (self-sufficiency) and the pursuit of central planning principles
(Barkai 1988). Their policy strengthened a trend toward concentration and carteliza-
tion of the economy that was already observable since the late nineteenth century
(Reckendrees 2003). In a time of slumping (export) demand, the fiscal expansion
caused by the Nazi rearmament and public infrastructure worked and resulted in
economic recovery and much needed employment, whereas autarky kept Germany
relatively isolated from further shocks from abroad.
World War II led, however, to a total destruction of the German economy in the
1940s and fueled a second hyperinflation. Upon defeat, Germany was occupied by the
Allied Powers (USA, UK, France, and Soviet Union) and lost one-third of its territory
in the East to Poland and Russia. In 1949, the country was split into two separate
states, namely the Federal Republic of Germany (FRG or West Germany), which
became a Western-style market economy, and the German Democratic Republic
(GDR or East Germany), a Soviet-style centrally planned economy. The Iron Curtain
divided Germany for more than 40 years and the two German states evolved in
distinctly different directions.
The economy of West Germany prospered in the 1950s and early 1960s, a period
referred to as economic miracle (Wirtschaftswunder). East Germany, meanwhile,
had to cope with a massive loss of economic activity as businesses relocated assets
and activities, while some 1.3 million, mostly educated and entrepreneurial, people
fled to West Germany (e.g., Hefele 1998; Falck et al. 2013) from 1950 until the
Berlin Wall was erected in 1961. The East German economy also had to cope with
massive war reparations to the Soviet Union which amounted to about 23% of the pre-
war gross national product (Lieberman 1996). The West-German economy instead
benefitted from the Marshall plan and global monetary stability under the Bretton
Woods system, security assurances under the NATO-treaty, and trade liberalization
under GATT.
2 Some German regions, for example, long retained a primogeniture inheritance system, where in
other parts inheritances were shared equally among all (male) children. This led to large estates and
landed nobility in some, and a rural, entrepreneurial class in other regions.
3 The severity of the impact of these reparations is, however, somewhat disputed in the literature
Trends in entrepreneurship also diverged strongly. In the aftermath of the oil price
shock of 1973, West Germany developed from a managed to a more entrepreneurial
society, with self-employment rising to 10–12% in 1989. In East Germany, in
contrast, there were several waves of expropriation driving down the rate of
self-employment to 1.8% at the time of reunification (Wyrwich 2012).
The biggest challenge after reunification was the integration of the economic
structures of the former East Germany into the market economy system (Hall and
Ludwig 1995; Burda and Hunt 2001). There was a massive surge in start-up activity in
the early 1990s and the self-employment rate in the former East Germany approached
the Western level around the year 2005. At the same time, almost none of the Eastern
companies that existed in 1989 were still active in the market in 2000 (Fritsch et al.
2014). Despite this massive transition and rapid convergence in self-employment,
striking economic differences between both parts of the country remain until today.
After a period of converging productivity levels in the first years after transition,
a productivity gap of 30% still persists since the late 1990s. Massive migration
and brain drain to Western Germany came to a halt only recently, and the legacy
of the socialist past continues to affect people’s inclinations, attitudes, principles,
and behavior.4 This legacy will last but perhaps not all of it is necessarily a barrier
to growth and prosperity (former East Germany has, for example, higher female
participation rates and smaller gender gaps in wages and incomes).
In conclusion, both the North-East, South-West divide between Protestants and
Catholics in the seventeenth and the East-West divide between socialists and cap-
italists in the twentieth century are important to understand the fractionalization
and regional heterogeneity of Germany today. Germany’s federal political structure
accommodates and consolidates this heterogeneity and helps explain the decentral-
ized character of its entrepreneurial ecosystem(s). These deep-rooted institutional
features are manifest in the institutions that govern the flow of knowledge, finance,
and labor to existing and new firms alike. We discuss these in the sections below.
The institutions that govern the generation and flow of knowledge to businesses
in general and to entrepreneurial ventures in particular are founded in the educa-
tional system and the institutions doing basic and applied research. The system
for registering and commercially exploiting knowledge then also deserves special
mention.
4 See for example Alesina and Fuchs-Schündeln (2007), Brosig-Koch et al. (2011), Bauernschuster
and Rainer (2012), Bauernschuster et al. (2012), Corneo and Grüner (2002), Fuchs-Schündeln and
Schündeln (2005, 2009), and Ockenfels and Weimann (1999).
7 A Reform Strategy for Germany 167
7.1.2.1 Universities
The first medieval universities emerged in Germany after the end of the Papal Schism
in 1386 with the University of Heidelberg opening in the very same year (Cantoni
and Yuchtman 2014). The political fragmentation of Germany at the time implied
that a lot of universities were set up in smaller cities which are not necessarily big
economic or administrative agglomerations today. Examples, apart from Heidelberg,
are the universities in Rostock (1419), Greifswald (1456), and Tübingen (1477), but
also the University in Marburg (1527), which was the first Protestant university in
the world, and the University of Jena (1558). There were several further universities
founded before the onset of industrialization where, like all “medieval” universities,
their curriculum consisted of Greek and Latin classics and was focused on the study
of the Bible. The art of reading, writing, rhetoric, and logic were important fields
while ability and utility played a minor role. Universities’ traditional tasks were to
collect, codify, and teach general knowledge (Carlsson et al. 2009), not to develop
any new or useful knowledge.
As a response to the rapid growth of the demand for scientific research and edu-
cation (Carlsson et al. 2009; Drucker 1998) in the nineteenth century, Germany also
saw a wave of universities founded with a technical focus and the adjustment of
curricula in already existing universities. The first higher education institutions with
a technical focus in Germany were founded in Karlsruhe and Dresden in the early
nineteenth century, while the first natural science faculty opened at the University
of Tübingen in 1863. Furthermore, there were several technical colleges, known as
Polytechnische Hochschulen that were upgraded into technical universities around
the year 1900. The main political force behind this process was the German Associa-
tion of Engineers (Verband Deutscher Ingenieure, VDI).5 All technical colleges that
became technical universities were located in the capital cities of the federal states
(König 2006; Manegold 1989). Again, the federal tradition of Germany implied that
such universities were established in smaller cities and not necessarily in places that
are the largest agglomerations today. In 1900, there were technical universities in
Berlin and Munich but also in Karlsruhe, Dresden, Hannover, Stuttgart, Aachen,
Darmstadt, and Braunschweig.
Today, there are many more technical universities in Germany. They represent a
specific type of higher education institution that has relatively strong links to (often
local) industry. Recent empirical evidence suggests that the entrepreneurial capacity
of technical universities is not necessarily higher than that of “classical” universities
(Goethner and Wyrwich 2019). But places close to, or even hosting, a technical uni-
versity that was already present in the year 1900 have a higher level of entrepreneur-
ship in high-tech industries (Audretsch and Lehmann 2005a, b; Fritsch and Wyrwich
2018). As many universities were founded in smaller places, this partly explains why
5 The main aim of the initiatives to upgrade technical colleges was to overcome the lower social
status of engineers as compared to university graduates. Moreover, upgrading technical colleges to
technical universities was regarded an important means for improving the education of engineers
(König 2006).
168 M. Sanders et al.
in Germany these smaller places (e.g., rural Baden-Württemberg) prosper today, even
though they lack the agglomeration advantages that are found to be supportive for
entrepreneurship and innovation in countries such as the USA (Glaeser 2011).
In the twentieth century, as was the case in most developed countries, there was
a massive expansion of tertiary education in Germany. Therefore, there is no region
without a significant university or university of applied science with a focus on edu-
cating people for the local labor market (e.g., Jaeger and Kopper 2014).6 Moreover,
the twentieth century saw the proliferation of scientific research institutes and the
emergence of networks like the Kaiser Wilhelm Society (1911), the Max Planck Soci-
ety (1948), and the Fraunhofer Society (1949). Their substantial (public) resources
were aimed at further developing basic research with an explicit mandate to also
disseminate this knowledge to industry (Gibbons et al. 1994; Beise and Stahl 1999).
These networks have now grown into important pillars of Germany’s knowledge
infrastructure. As for most technical universities, however, the focus in these institu-
tions has long been on serving the needs of large, industrial, incumbent firms. Initia-
tives to foster entrepreneurship at universities or research institutes did not exist until
the late 1990s when the EXIST program was initiated in a few pilot universities.
The EXIST program followed a dual strategy. One building block was support-
ing universities in developing start-up culture at their institutions, while the other
was providing direct assistance for individuals and start-up projects. In support of
those activities, universities received a grant from the German Federal Ministry of
Economics and Technology over a three-year period (e.g., Kulicke 2014). Although
there have not yet been rigorous evaluations, the pilot in Berlin was considered a
success, has gone through several revisions and extensions, and is still in operation
today (Becker et al. 2011; EXIST 2019).
In conclusion, the German university and educational system mirror its regional
decentralization, given that the federal states are responsible for education policy.
There are also joint initiatives where the lead is at the federal level. The most famous
program is the so-called excellence initiative that was initiated in 2006. Recent evi-
dence suggests that this program was successful in concentrating excellent research.
It also promoted collaborations between universities and the non-university research
sector. However, it has not caused massive changes to the overall German research
system (e.g., Möller et al. 2016). Moreover, a strong tradition of internships and
vocational education provides German firms and entrepreneurs with a well-trained
and educated workforce at the local level. In contrast to the Anglo-Saxon countries,
however, the German university system faces challenges developing into research-
oriented universities (Baker and Lenhardt 2008). Universities are mostly teaching-
oriented and made universally accessible at low costs for students. This implies,
however, that universities are tightly financed out of (state level) tax revenue and
have a hard time attracting and retaining (global research) talent. As a consequence,
differences in the quality of education and research between German universities are
is an institution of higher education that grants professional degrees and is generally more focused
on vocational education and applied research.
7 A Reform Strategy for Germany 169
much less pronounced than in other countries such as France, the UK, or the US. A
large part of top-level research takes place outside of the universities in industry and
endowed research institutes such as those of the Max Planck Society.
Germany has had regional patent systems since the eighteenth century (Harhoff
and Hoisl 2007). The first Central German patent office was established in 1877,
some six years after Germany became a state. The Imperial Patent Office (Kaiser-
liches Patentamt) provided uniform protection for discoveries in the German Empire.
Patents were based on uniform principles and were effective for the entire territory
of the German Empire. In the first 13 years of the patent law, there were between
4,000 and 5,000 patents granted per year. This number increased to 10,000 before
1906, and around 13,000 after that of which more than 10% were long-living patents
(Burhop 2010). During the separation of the country after World War II, two patent-
ing agencies coexisted, but after reunification, Germany merged them into a single
patent institution again.
There have been several changes to patent law over the last 120 years. One of
the important recent reforms was the Arbeitnehmererfindergesetz in 2001, which
was a Bayh–Dole Act-like change in the German patenting system to increase the
commercialization of scientific research. The results of this measure, however, are
rather mixed (Von Proff et al. 2012; Czarnitzki et al. 2016). Without going into
detail on the issue, this can be seen as an example where transferring legal insti-
tutions to another context leads to different, perhaps unexpected, outcomes. The
USA universities, for which the Bayh–Dole Act was written, operated under a dif-
ferent institutional setting and consequently responded very differently than those in
Germany. The Arbeitnehmererfindergesetz was perhaps less effective because of the
already strong practice of technology transfer from academia to the corporate sector
in Germany (Grimpe and Fier 2010). To achieve more commercial exploitation of
public research, reforms will have to be better tailored to the German context. The
problem with such tailored approaches, however, is that intellectual property rights
protection has developed into an international issue. That is not a reason for Germany
not to speak out. As a leading industrial nation with a lot of intellectual property at
stake, Germany’s voice in European and international negotiations governing intel-
lectual property carries significant weight and will be heeded. It is in the interest of
Germany to push for reforms that ensure a solid protection of industrial innovations
but also ensures continued access to the more generic types of knowledge (e.g., gene
sequencing) that industrial innovation builds upon.
170 M. Sanders et al.
7 Inaddition, the federal state banks secure market funding by issuing bonds. They are also inter-
nationally operating wholesale and investment banks. Therefore, they follow a business model
different from savings banks.
8 Although there is no “official” definition of the Mittelstand, one can say that it comprises firms with
between 50 and not much more than 500 employees where the owner is involved in the management
or at least in strategic decisions (Pahnke and Welter 2018). Hence, the Mittelstand is part of the
7 A Reform Strategy for Germany 171
new start-ups, however, banks are typically more hesitant to invest. Innovative start-
ups, also in Germany, have to rely on venture capital to finance capital-intensive
high-risk projects. Empirical evidence shows that the market for venture capital in
Germany is functioning relatively well (Fritsch and Schilder 2008, 2012). It remains
much smaller in size and scope than in the Anglo-Saxon world, but this is arguably
not a supply but a demand issue (Herrmann 2020).9
The German financial system, with its many small and locally well-connected
banks serving many SMEs across the country, has coevolved with the German econ-
omy. It serves the needs of the decentralized, export-oriented, and industrial economy
of organically growing medium-sized industrial firms and Mittelstand. Typically,
thanks to their cooperation on corporate governance boards, such firms have long-
standing relationships with their banks that use the relationship and trust as collateral
and security for credit.
In conclusion, despite some important challenges in flagship banks like the
Deutsche Bank and the Commerzbank, the German financial system remains quite
decentralized and still has a significant share of small-scale relationship banking.
Thereby, it can finance incremental innovation in existing firms but is perhaps a less
favorable environment for more radical innovation by new entrants as it supplies little
capital in the form of equity to newcomers. The financial system thus consolidates
Germany’s conservatism, while underpinning its competitive strength in high-quality
incremental innovation.
The labor force in Germany is generally well trained and very productive, justifying
high wage incomes while maintaining a strong international competitive position.
Strong vocational education combined with on-the-job training promotes the accu-
mulation of firm-specific human capital in Germany’s small and medium-sized high-
tech industrial sector (Herrmann 2020). Consensus-oriented labor relations support
moderate wage growth while firm-specific human capital investments yield high
productivity growth (e.g., Soskice 1990). German export-oriented firms thus remain
competitive in global markets with high quality, high value-added products and ser-
vices. But this peace and high level of investment are based on generous social secu-
rity and stringent labor protection. It is important to realize that these institutions
have long historical roots and coevolved with the German economy into highly com-
plementary and interconnecting institutions that support its traditional competitive
strength.
SME sector. Many firms of the Mittelstand are family entities that have been passed on within the
family for several generations.
9 German entrepreneurs have been found to be reluctant to give up control rights and therefore
prefer organic growth and private ownership over a heavy reliance on external equity finance. One
could argue that this has also led to a regulatory framework that makes this type of investment less
attractive (see, e.g., Fiedler and Hellman 2001; Franzke et al. 2003).
172 M. Sanders et al.
The German system of employment protection obtained its modern form during
the period of the German miracle (Wirtschaftswunder) in the 1950s and 1960s in
the Federal Republic of Germany. This was the golden era of the so-called Nor-
malarbeitsverhältnis (standard employment relationship) which describes a depen-
dent, permanent full-time job with strict dismissal protection, a full integration into
status-protecting social insurance and collectively set wages at a relatively high level
(Eichhorst and Marx 2011).
The West German system implied high wages for insiders but also led to under-
utilization of the labor force, which is reflected, for example, by low labor force
participation of women and a male-breadwinner family model. Such a system comes
under pressure when women push into the labor market (Esping-Andersen 2002),
especially after German reunification where about 90% of all women in working age
were full-time employees in the former East Germany (Maier 1993).10 This system
gave industrial producers a strong incentive to invest in productivity growth, but
high wages and non-wage labor costs proved less suitable for developing a modern,
labor-intensive service sector (Eichhorst and Marx 2011). Moreover, demographic
changes put a heavy burden on the economy to finance the generous pension system.
Reforms were deemed necessary to increase the utilization of all labor resources.
The change in the labor market structure, however, did not come along with a
systematic flexibilization of the rigid Normalarbeitsverhältnis. Rather, a second-
tier labor market consisting of atypical and much less protected employment (e.g.,
part-time work, marginal employment) emerged. Streeck (1997) argues that this
pattern is explained by the German manufacturing system that is based on “diversified
quality production.” This model requires labor with highly specialized skills and
enables workforces—thanks to their long-standing experience within one firm—to
come up with incremental innovations and improvements that translate into high-
quality products and specialization in niche markets. Tight employment protection
incentivizes employees to invest in the necessary firm-specific skills, which would
otherwise become sunk costs in case of a job loss (Herrmann 2020).11
In the mid-1990s, the firm size threshold for dismissal protection was raised from
5 to 10 employees (Eichhorst and Marx 2011), and Bauernschuster (2013) found
a positive effect on hiring by small firms of this reform. The duality between well-
protected insiders and precariously employed outsiders in the labor market, however,
persists in larger firms and the new threshold still represents a penalty on employment
growth.
10 There is still an East-West gap in terms of female labor force participation in the year 2015.
However, recent analyses show that only about 40% of that difference can be attributed to the effect
of the socialist system (Wyrwich 2017). The rest is due to other factors.
11 This explanation is perfectly in line with basic human capital theory (Becker 1964). See Hall and
Soskice (2001) for further explanations on the relationship between employment regulation and
incremental versus radical innovation.
7 A Reform Strategy for Germany 173
The relatively high wage costs in Germany are also institutionalized in a system of
collective wage bargaining. Unions played an important role in the first decades after
World War II in West Germany and wages were collectively set (Soskice 1990).12
There was some modest flexibilization in collective bargaining (e.g., single enterprise
exceptions, the introduction of working time accounts) since the 1980s. With reuni-
fication, the West-German model was extended to the East and the system remained
relatively stable for standard employment contracts (Eichhorst and Marx 2011; Dust-
mann et al. 2014). Despite low and declining union membership, in the 2000s, still,
some 60–70% of all employees were covered by collective agreements and such
coverage still implied significant wage premia (Kohaut and Schnabel 2007; Burda
et al. 2008; Fitzenberger et al. 2013; Kluge and Weber 2018). The contrast between
marginal workers in precarious employment and the well-protected and covered
insiders has increased in recent decades (Brady and Biegert 2017). Entrepreneurs
have more or less equal access to the latter pool of labor, but face high wage and
non-wage labor costs when recruiting from the high-quality segments. A potentially
important recent development is the broadly supported introduction of a minimum
wage in 2015 of at that time EUR 8.50/h (Burda 2016).13 Its effect on the flow of
labor resources to entrepreneurship is unclear and not yet empirically investigated.
Social security also has a long tradition in Germany. The introduction of social
insurance dates back to an initiative by von Bismarck in the 1880s, which implied
the implementation of the first social security net in the world. The Compulsory
Health Insurance Act of 1883 can be regarded as the starting point of this system.
This was followed by the Accident Insurance Act (1884) and the Disability/Old-
age Pension System Act (1891). Arguably, the build-up of a social security system
enabled von Bismarck to pacify the threat of class struggle and create loyalty to
the new state (Rimlinger 1968; Pflanze 2014). The German social security system
around this time became a blueprint for Germany’s current health system and was a
role model for many insurance systems in other countries (Abrams 2007; Weichlein
2011; Bauernschuster et al. 2019).
The social insurance system underwent several reforms and extensions since the
1880s. Unemployment insurance was introduced in 1927. Finally, care insurance was
set up in 1995. The current pension system is based on a reform in 1957 and follows a
pay-as-you-go defined-benefit design. There are also state-supported private pension
schemes. These were introduced in the early 2000s to make up for the demographic
12 The wage agreements are negotiated at the sector level between labor unions and employers’
transition that implies fewer contributors in the pay-as-you-go scheme face a growing
number of retired people.
A significant reform of the unemployment insurance was associated with the
“Agenda 2010.” It was a shift from policies that were rather generous toward an
approach with stricter job search monitoring, harsher sanctioning of unemploy-
ment provisions, and a reduction in the duration of job training. Another element
of the reform was to combine the earnings-related and means-tested unemployment
assistance with the social assistance (Sozialhilfe) into a new support system called
Arbeitslosengeld II. This transfer can be regarded as a step toward a more universal
minimum income support scheme (Eichhorst and Marx 2011). The regulation also
came with new active labor market policy tools to promote start-ups by the unem-
ployed (Ich AG/“Me Inc.”). The evidence on the success of these measures to date
is mixed (Zöllner et al. 2018). While some do succeed in leaving the program and
generate an income, most of these start-ups are not very innovative and have low
growth potential.
Before reunification, the post-war “German model” can be described as a rather dis-
tinctive kind of capitalist economy that was governed by national social institutions
yielding high international competitiveness despite high wages and low dispersion
with respect to inequality of incomes and living standards (Streeck 1997). A defin-
ing feature of the German model is the existence of the Mittelstand. Audretsch
and Lehmann (2016) argue that Mittelstand firms represent a sort of “main street
entrepreneurship” of decades-old, family-owned firms with strong linkages and
social ties to their local communities, including banks. These firms attract and retain
specifically skilled employees, for example, by local apprentice programs. They also
often have close ties with local banks providing them with financial resources. These
ties are legally in the form of loans and credit, but long relations and trust enable
firms to also approach banks for financing intrapreneurial ventures and innovative
projects. Their products are successful in niche markets.
Public policy strongly promoted the German SMEs (including the Mittelstand)
in the post-war period. The state-owned Kreditanstalt für Wiederaufbau (KfW) pro-
vided finance for the development of technological capabilities of SMEs (e.g., long-
term investment loans as well as working capital loans). The KfW measures can be
regarded as small business but to a much lesser extent as entrepreneurship policies.
Policy programs directly targeted at start-ups played a rather minor role in the policy
menu in the post-war decades.
In contrast, in socialist East Germany, Mittelstand and entrepreneurship were
dubbed a bourgeois anachronism (Fritsch and Wyrwich 2016, p. 263). There were
many outright anti-entrepreneurship policies, such as the massive expropriation of all
7 A Reform Strategy for Germany 175
private industrial firms in 1972. Private business ownership was very much confined
to small craft enterprises and private shops in East Germany and self-employment fell
from 20.4% in 1955 to 1.8% in 1989 (Pickel 1992; Wyrwich 2012). Consequently,
the Mittelstand had largely disappeared in the East by 1989 (Fritsch et al. 2014).
In the 1990s, the self-employment rates were steadily increasing in West Germany,
partly reflecting the increased role of service but also the fundamental shift toward
a more entrepreneurial society. In East Germany, the level of self-employment
converged to Western levels and reached parity around the year 2005 (Welter
2007a; Fritsch et al. 2014). Interestingly, in areas that had already a high level
of entrepreneurship in the pre-socialist period, the entrepreneurial catch-up was
particularly pronounced (Wyrwich 2012; Fritsch and Wyrwich 2014).
Despite convergence in the numbers, however, East German businesses tend to be
much smaller, even 20 years after reunification. One reason is their comparatively
low levels of productivity and much lower survival rates (Fackler 2014). There are
several explanations for this weakness of East German companies, ranging from unfa-
vorable economic framework conditions to lacking managerial and entrepreneurial
skills among East German entrepreneurs (Wyrwich 2013). Furthermore, East Ger-
man businesses tend to have a strong focus on regional markets and their export
orientation is rather low (IWH 2010; Mattes et al. 2015).
In an attempt to also support start-ups in East and West, the KfW began creating
programs, such as the Eigenkapitalhilfe-Programm which consisted of subordinated
capital for (young) entrepreneurs. In 2010, the Bundesministerium für Wirtschaft
und Energie (BMWi) implemented INVEST —Zuschuss für Wagniskapital and the
Mikromezzaninfonds-Deutschland to strengthen and develop the entrepreneurial
culture of Germany. The former provides a subsidy of 20% for venture capital,
whereas the latter provides specific support for unemployed persons, women, or
migrants in creative industries (Audretsch et al. 2007). Bøggild et al. (2011) show
that these programs yielded both an increase in competitiveness and innovativeness
for subsidized start-ups as well as generated positive employment effects. Overall,
BMWi-policy initiatives include the provision of information on self-employment
(e.g., by participating in the Gründerwoche Deutschland), special measures to
strengthen interest in entrepreneurship in the education system, and the improve-
ment of the financing options available for innovative start-ups. Under the umbrella
of the Gründerland Deutschland Initiative, the BMWi also provides an online
portal to make all information available to the public and provides young ICT
176 M. Sanders et al.
entrepreneurs with means for a stay in innovative regions such as Silicon Valley
under the German Accelerator program.14
In addition to these federal initiatives, the German Länder (states) are also quite
active in developing entrepreneurship promotion programs at the regional level (Wel-
ter 2007b). In East Germany, such initiatives often relied massively on European
Structural Funds which were relatively generous in view of the low GDP per capita
of the East German Länder. It is noteworthy that there is a huge heterogeneity across
the Länder in promoting entrepreneurship. It is particularly Bavaria in West Ger-
many and Saxony in East Germany that developed multifaceted programs to promote
innovative entrepreneurship (Fritsch et al. 2010, 2015).
Finally, at the local level, some municipalities and districts focus on the develop-
ment of the entrepreneurial culture within their region. Here, the main players include
business associations, chambers of commerce, economic development departments,
and business development agencies. An example for local funding initiatives is the
GÖBI-fonds (Göttinger Fonds für örtliche Beschäftigungsinitiativen). Established
in 1997, it constitutes one of the first cases of public–private collaboration at the
regional level, where banking institutions were involved. Targeting unemployed and
young entrepreneurs, the Fonds was organized in such a way that the banks would
provide the funding, while the regional government would bear 50% of the default
risk and (thus) would subsidize the interest rate.
Although the three levels of policy regulation aim at closely integrating their
respective instruments, inconsistencies and incoherence across these levels are a real
danger. For example, most state programs do not consider part-time entrepreneur-
ship to be desirable, arguing that this type of entrepreneurship tends to contribute
little to economic and employment growth, whereas at the federal level, part-time
entrepreneurship is supported and recognized as a potential first step to full-time
self-employment and eventual business formation.
These programs have of course been evaluated, but it is difficult to ascertain their
true impact. It would also take us beyond the scope of this chapter to attempt an
assessment here. At this point, we can conclude that Germany’s policy makers at
various levels are clearly highly interested in promoting a more adventurous and
radically innovative form of entrepreneurial venturing.
7.1.6 Conclusions
Germany’s turbulent history of division and unification had a big impact on the coun-
try, its institutions and inhabitants. After World War II, the entire country experienced
an institutional reset: while informal institutions persisted, East and West Germany
set off on diverging trajectories on formal institutions.
14 There have been further measures within the framework of the Gründerland Deutschland Initiative
that are not active in 2018 anymore. For example, the Gründerwettbewerb—IKT Innovative which
consisted of a contest for young entrepreneurs in the ICT industry.
7 A Reform Strategy for Germany 177
The West developed its own unique model of capitalism, with moderate wage
growth, high productivity growth driven by on-the-job learning, and firm-specific
skill accumulation. This supported an export-oriented industry built on the his-
toric legacy of strongly regionally embedded Mittelstand, financed by a region-
ally branched bank-based financial system, also fueled by science and knowledge
developed in technical universities as well as institutes.
In the East, meanwhile, the socialist doctrine led to the destruction of the Mittel-
stand, while massive migration to the West before the building of the Wall contributed
to depriving East Germany of a significant part of its entrepreneurial talent. Impor-
tantly, the experiment with central planning failed and the East German economy
collapsed, whereas the West grew into the economic powerhouse of Europe.
Now, at 30 years after reunification and in spite of enormous efforts, the
socioeconomic gap between East and West Germany has still not been bridged
(Canova and Ravn 2000; Lindner 2017; Mertes 2018; Verheyen 2018). Against
this backdrop, it is impossible to treat Germany as a blank canvas. Hence, we
suggest policies and reforms that fit its historical heritage, consider its federal
character and multi-level governance, and build on Germany’s strengths in order
to address weaknesses within the German entrepreneurial ecosystem. To iden-
tify these weaknesses, the next section turns to the present and examines current
data.
Fig. 7.1 Radar-plot REDI comparison Germany–Italy–UK and EU-average. Source Authors’ own
compilation
than the EU average and only slightly underperforms the EU average on four pillars,
namely “Risk Acceptance,” “Human Capital,” and, perhaps surprisingly, “Product,”
and “Process Innovation.”
The underlying algorithm in the REDI puts a penalty on bottlenecks in the ecosys-
tem (Acs et al. 2014; Szerb et al. 2017), such that a rounder radar-plot scores higher
than a more erratic one. This reflects the intuition that all pillars in the index are com-
plementary and the ecosystem is only as effective as its weakest link. To increase the
REDI-score and improve the ecosystem performance, policy interventions should
therefore be aimed at alleviating bottlenecks with priority. For Germany, and based
on the data, one would conclude that improving the “Risk Acceptance,” “Human
Capital,” “Product Innovation,” and “Process Innovation” pillars is most urgent.
Fig. 7.2 REDI map of German NUTS2/3 regions. Source Authors’ own compilation
15 The
numbers are index numbers ranging from 0 (worst) to 100 (best) across all 125 European
NUTS2/3 regions for 2012–2014.
180 M. Sanders et al.
institutions, such as the World Bank, Freedom House, and OECD).16 The index then
builds on the assumption that institutions and individual agency are complements
(Acs and Szerb 2009; Acs et al. 2014). That is, for example, high levels of Opportunity
Perception in a low-quality institutional environment will contribute little. Likewise,
low Opportunity Perception in a high-quality institutional environment is also a sign
of weakness in the entrepreneurial ecosystem. To improve the score on a given pillar,
policies and reforms should seek to improve the weakest link and then aim to increase
both institutional quality and individual agency together. Especially because of the
latter, the menu of effective interventions is not limited to improving the scores
on the institutional quality indices alone. The same logic is then also imposed on
the individual pillars that make up the three subindices: Attitudes, Abilities, and
Aspirations.
For all the Länder, we have identified those three pillars that are holding back the
respective Land most. We then compared the Länder and identified the most common
weak spots in regional ecosystems. The results, presented in Table 7.2, provide some
clear-cut insights.
Across the best and the weakest entrepreneurial ecosystems in Germany, bot-
tlenecks seem to arise most frequently with regard to Business Risk, which will
reduce the score on Risk Acceptance and thereby Entrepreneurial Attitudes. On
Entrepreneurial Abilities, the overall scores are decreased by low Human Capital
16 We refer interested readers to Szerb et al. (2017) and the technical annex to Acs and Szerb (2016)
scores due to a lack of Education and Training, whereas a lack of New Product or
New Technology in Product or Process Innovation generally holds back the overall
performance on Entrepreneurial Aspirations. Despite significant heterogeneity across
the German Länder, there certainly seems to be room for national-level interventions
and reforms in these areas.
182 M. Sanders et al.
At the regional level, the Länder may well add specific interventions to strengthen
specific regional weaknesses and bottlenecks, given in particular that it does not seem
necessary to equally develop all pillars in all regions.
Our interpretation of the data above reveals that in all German Länder, and the country
as a whole, the main bottlenecks in the entrepreneurial ecosystem are a limited will-
ingness to take risk (Business Risk), an education system that can be improved (Edu-
cation and Training), and a lack of radical innovation (New Products and Technology)
that feeds back into a low familiarity with ambitious entrepreneurship.
As the simulation exercises in Varga et al. (2020) have shown, improving the scores
on REDI in Germany would have positive effects on productivity and well-being in all
regions, even if some would benefit more than others. At this point, however, it is not
quite clear exactly how one could go about engineering such an improvement in the
German entrepreneurial ecosystems. We know it is the bottlenecks that hold down
scores, and consequently, improving on those is probably the most cost-effective
way of improving the system as a whole. But a lot of research remains to be done on
how exactly policy interventions and reforms would affect the various variables and
pillars underlying REDI.
Moreover, it is not advised to draw conclusions exclusively on the basis of data
and aggregate indices, even if they are composed of a broad set of sub-indicators.
It is not yet clear from the data exactly what could be done to improve the situation
or how interventions could be made to fit local specificities. Only after triangulating
the results above with the historical analysis, literature review, expert judgment, and
qualitative survey results below, we can map propose tailored reforms for Germany.
capital, we find that entrepreneurs in Germany, who begin to set up their ventures in
part-time, are less likely to transition to full-time entrepreneurship than their counter-
parts in the UK or the USA. The reason seems related to Germany’s regulated labor
market which, in case of venture failure, makes it rather difficult for entrepreneurs
to obtain a position in dependent employment. Entrepreneurs are reluctant to give
up dependent employment and set up their ventures in part-time (Held 2019). In
addition, entrepreneurs in Germany are unwilling or unable to hire employees and
rather engage external service providers in order to access qualified labor (Held et al.
2018c).
With regard to the process of finance acquisition, Held et al. (2018a) find that
various venture characteristics influence the type of funding which nascent venture
acquire first and, respectively, most. These characteristics include the type of good
that a venture develops, its product’s novelty, size, industry, but also its institutional
environment. With regard to the latter, Germany’s entrepreneurs are particularly
likely to make up for a low stock market capitalization by seeking debt finance,
making use of the well-developed banking system instead (Held et al. 2018a).
Finally, we also find that nascent ventures in Germany are more likely to engage in
R&D collaborations with external partners, such as universities and labs, than nascent
ventures in the UK or the USA. The reason for this seems to be that nascent ventures
are reluctant to engage in joint R&D projects whenever the institutions governing
inter-firm collaborations make the outcome of lawsuits in case of IP conflicts rather
unpredictable (Held et al. 2018b).
Taken together, these studies suggest that Germany’s distinct finance, labor, and
R&D-related institutions lead entrepreneurs to focus on incrementally innovative
business ideas.
but perceived to be justified and unproblematic by the founders that actually overcame
them. Moreover, strict regulation, provided it is clear and fair, can also prevent the
entry of less viable and low-quality entrepreneurs (Stenholm et al. 2013).
When looking at the top-10 obstacles more closely, we see that founders confirm
the problem of a cumbersome bureaucracy. But only some (<5%) mention bureau-
cracy and complicated legal and regulatory requirements as a real obstacle to start a
firm. From our survey, we thus get the impression that barriers to entry in Germany
could be alleviated by reducing the administrative requirements for venture creation.
That is confirmed by the fact that Germany ranks 113 out of 190 in the World Bank
(2018a) Doing Business Index on “ease of starting a firm.”
7 A Reform Strategy for Germany 185
In the same survey, founders were also asked: “What can policy makers do to facilitate
venture creation?”. An overview of the answers to this question is listed in Table 7.4.
While an important share of the founders interviewed still thinks that policy makers
cannot facilitate venture creation, the most common suggestions point to measures
of financial support. This is remarkable in light of the fact that financial barriers
were rarely mentioned as a regulatory obstacle. Similarly, financial constraints do
not come out very strongly in the data analyses of Sect. 7.2 nor in the historical
analysis of Sect. 7.1.
Two other suggestions stand out. In slightly different wordings, the founders
suggest a simplification of procedures, which in itself need not make regulations
less tight, only more transparent and easier to follow. And, again, in different
ways, they argue that the government could promote venture creation by allow-
ing founders to benefit more from the venture they create. Although, not strongly
and perfectly, Germany’s founders clearly identified some of the same weaknesses in
the entrepreneurial ecosystem that our above data analysis revealed. Recall that the
weaknesses of the REDI analysis revealed a low score on the pillars “Risk Accep-
tance,” “Education and Training,” and “Product Innovation.” The founders’ sugges-
tions about better networking opportunities, the stimulation of a more entrepreneurial
culture, and general need for more support resonate with those weaknesses, but
the founders did not mention a lack of knowledge, absorptive capacity, or a lack
of new product and process technology. The latter might be explained by survival
bias in sampling, such that the surveyed founders may find themselves in a vibrant
entrepreneurial scene and perceive a strong ecosystem where only external con-
straints hold venturing back. Interestingly, the survey reveals founders’ frustration
with the regulatory framework and bureaucracy that the REDI-analysis is ill equipped
to reveal.
Rather unsurprisingly, the policies suggested are all action-oriented, whereby
financial instruments are typically top-of-mind, also for founders. This may explain
the high share of recommendations that suggest to supporting start-ups and new ven-
tures financially—even though capital did not seem to be a major barrier to venturing
in Germany in the REDI analysis. Those founders signaling a lack of information
and training and calling for a more stable policy environment can be interpreted in
support of a more fundamental reform approach that creates institutional support for
those providing such services and knowledge.
When calling for lower taxation and higher financial support for founders, we
should of course be very cautious. Nobody likes to pay taxes, and founders are
no exception. Still, perhaps founders’ complaints are not unjustified in this case.
Even if Germany’s founders strongly benefit from a public-funded infrastructure—
including, for example, a well-developed transportation system, public incubators,
and entrepreneurial support programs like the EXIST initiative—the level of taxation
and social security contributions out of total profits is estimated to be about 50%
(World Bank 2018a) in Germany, and on “paying taxes” Germany ranks 41 out of
186 M. Sanders et al.
190. Concerning financial support for founders, there are already quite a lot of public
programs for entrepreneurship and it is doubtful whether even more support would
be helpful.
7.3.4 Conclusions
The analysis in this section confirms some, but not all of the weaknesses identified
in the REDI analysis completed in Step 2. Moreover, it provides some revealing
additional insights, for example, the need to create a stable regulatory framework,
and the suggestion that overall taxation on new ventures is perhaps too high. Such
information is hard to gather from quantitative data or historical analyses. The more
qualitative analysis presented in this step was therefore useful to complement the
results obtained in Sects. 7.1 and 7.2. But given the limited perspective that most
founders have, the proposed interventions typically fall in the “inform, deregulate,
subsidize-more and tax-less” approach that has characterized entrepreneurship poli-
cies around the world already for decades. When asked for the most important bar-
riers and additional policy measures, it is only logical that founders would mention
those barriers and proposals that they perceived as most important in their personal
experiences and direct environment. There certainly is valuable information in that
experience. But as a guide to policy, this is not sufficient, as is an approach based on
history or aggregate data only. The true value of this information is revealed when
combined with information from other sources. Together, the insights gained from
triangulating our historical, quantitative, and qualitative information on Germany
now reveal enough information to formulate a “diagnosis” for Germany and propose
our “treatments.”
cities are themselves spread across the country, this is also the case for entrepreneur-
ship in Germany. Our quantitative data analyses suggested a large regional hetero-
geneity in entrepreneurial ecosystem performance, whereas for the country as a whole
or the regions affected, this does not necessarily constitute a problem.
The results from the surveys do not suffer from this problem and confirm that
the challenges and bottlenecks in the German ecosystem are indeed not formidable.
Founders suggested that regulation makes the founding of new ventures difficult,
especially in green tech and renewable energy sectors. This is confirmed in Ger-
many’s rankings on traditional indicators like self-employment and firm formation,
especially in high-tech sectors. These show that Germany is lagging in an inter-
national comparison. But these concerns do not seem to be overly problematic.
Importantly, founders did not complain about a lack of funding, skilled personnel,
or knowledge. The data analysis does however reveal that German entrepreneurship
is less risk seeking than in the Anglo-Saxon world. New ventures in Germany score
comparatively low in radically new products and technology as well as in risk accep-
tance. Moreover, the rates of self-employment and start-up activity in Germany have
been declining and this might be worrisome to a country that is already scoring low
on these indicators. Incremental innovation is routine in German industry, but the
pillars related to more radical innovation seem the weakest links in an otherwise well
developed and functional entrepreneurial ecosystem. This diagnosis roughly holds
for the country as a whole and the individual Länder separately.
Admittedly, though, it is not easy to change all these aspects together. German
preferences for well-designed and (over)engineered solutions, an emphasis on qual-
ity over price and a dislike for disruptive technologies that might challenge incum-
bent firms and unsettle long-grown business relations, are deeply entrenched in the
German culture. Furthermore, these even constitute the core of a carefully built and
cherished “made in Germany” brand and reputation. It is thus important not to advise
our “German patient” to become a person they are not and do not want to become.
Still, a little more adventurous spirit would not hurt and more likely improve Ger-
many’s position vis-a-vis the competition from East-Asian tiger economies that rival
its industrial and engineering dominance. Hence, making it easier to start (and end) a
venture and supporting radically innovative entrepreneurship financially could go a
long way in improving the entrepreneurial ecosystem in the country and its Länder.
Taking these general prescriptions to the menu of policy interventions and reform
proposals in the companion volume of this book (Elert et al. 2019), we have selected
fifteen suitable interventions for Germany. They are listed in Table 7.5. In Column 1,
we find the number under which they were presented in Elert et al. (2019). Column 2
lists the title and Column 3 the proposal, whereas Column 4 gives a brief motivation
for the case of Germany tying in with the analysis presented above.
The first proposal (2) refers to intellectual property. We think it is in the interest of
the German entrepreneurial society that access to knowledge remains open. Germany
is traditionally strong in developing generic knowledge into specific products and
services, and IP protection should protect the latter, not the former. But as IP is
beyond the competencies of even national authorities, our proposal here is to be
7 A Reform Strategy for Germany 189
interpreted as a suggestion to raise the issue at the appropriate governing bodies and
treaty negotiations.
The proposals in taxation and financial regulation (9, 17, 19, and 21) lie clearly
within national competencies. They serve the dual purpose of mobilizing more capital
for riskier, perhaps more radically innovative ventures and increasing the financial
rewards for such venturing and investing in it. Here, we propose a different approach
than the founders, whom in our survey called for more public funding and financial
support. Instead, we believe that mobilizing the so-called triple-F finance by family,
friends and fools, can be promoted by allowing for more wealth to accumulate and
be transferred among private individuals.
Proposals on social security and labor market regulation (23, 27, 29, and 31) all aim
to mobilize Germany’s most knowledgeable and valuable employees. Portability of
social security entitlements across jobs, sectors, and labor market statuses will reduce
the lock-in of skilled labor in gilded jobs and reduce the barriers for employers. Also,
this portability creates a level playing field for start-ups on the demand side and for
marginalized groups on the supply side of the labor market. This will make growth
in Germany more inclusive and equitable as well as more innovative.
A third group of proposals (32, 37, and 39) intends to improve the regulatory
situation for start-ups and founders both at the start and possibly the end of their
7 A Reform Strategy for Germany 193
To put our proposed reform program in context, it is important to discuss the diagnosis
and proposed treatments with experts in the field. Moreover, given the wide diversity
of policy areas involved, it is important to not only discuss this with policy makers that
are active in “entrepreneurship policy” in the narrow sense. Our approach emphasizes
the importance of reforming institutions that determine the allocation of financial,
labor, and knowledge resources to entrepreneurial activity in the broadest and most
inclusive sense of the word. Entrepreneurship policy, in the narrow sense, has been in
place for more than three decades and, to date, seems to have achieved only limited
success.
194 M. Sanders et al.
Because of its breadth, our reform agenda inevitably cuts across many policy areas
traditionally less associated with entrepreneurship policy, including wealth taxation,
financial and labor market regulation, social security, and science policy. Policies
and institutions in these different areas overlap and interact in ways that affect the
quality and performance of the entrepreneurial ecosystem (Stam 2015, 2018). As
the institutions in these areas have evolved historically and policy makers in these
areas pursue different, equally relevant public policy priorities, the challenge is to
discuss the proposed agenda in sufficient depth and with a sufficiently diverse group
of policy makers and practitioners. The challenge is to not only propose policies
and reforms that will strengthen the ecosystem, but to do it in such a way that other
important policy priorities are also achieved.
In order to receive the first round of feedback on the proposals for Germany
presented in Table 7.5, a policy round table was held at the Bundesministerium
für Wirtschaft und Energie in Berlin on April 24, 2018. This step can be seen as
an attempt to allow our patient, or perhaps more accurately, their team of medical
specialists, intimately familiar with our patient, to give feedback about our diagnosis
and proposed treatments. What proposals does this team endorse, question, or propose
to drop?
Several participants stressed that cultural aspects and attitudes are important fac-
tors affecting the entrepreneurial activity in Germany. Discussing monetary issues,
such as the size and distribution of certain items of EU’s, Germany’s, or the Bun-
desländer’s budget, will only be of limited use if one does not see how this fits into
the institutional and cultural patterns of Germany.
The participants also agreed that institutions like high employment protection
and entrepreneurship-inhibiting insolvency laws increase the risks involved with
entrepreneurial failure and the stakeholders also meant that institutional reforms that
decrease the personal risks of failure might have an effect on individuals’ risk attitude.
The relatively high-risk aversion in Germany is not innate and can be altered, even
if it might take some time.
Supporting business angels might work to reduce market failure in the seed stage.
The idea to subsidize the investors and not the firms was regarded as a fruitful strategy.
However, some participants questioned the idea that capital access was an important
bottleneck and others claimed that angel investment has no detectable effect on firm
productivity and development. Supporting the VC industry might have an effect on
the entrepreneurial culture and the risk attitude among potential entrepreneurs in
society. It was also critically discussed whether tight regulation truly is a bottleneck
for start-ups.
Some proponents argued that the size threshold of the SME definition that EU
uses should be increased to include more Mittelstand firms as well. Even if these
firms are not SMEs by the today’s definition, they operate under similar organizational
routines, managerial practices, and firm behavior. Even if this issue was not a specific
proposal, participants pointed out that this would imply that a given budget has to be
distributed among more firms or that the budget must increase substantially to avoid
that resources are diluted.
7 A Reform Strategy for Germany 195
7.6 Conclusions
to labor protection and social security. While this should not go at the cost of carefully
built-up competitive strengths, Germany could afford to become more adventurous.
The proposals individually and in combination aim to reward German entrepreneurs
more if successful and punish them less if they fail.
Of course, these proposals will need a much more detailed discussion and form
the starting point, and not the final word on the policy debate. Moreover, even if
adopted, our proposals all require careful implementation and evaluation to complete
the seven-step policy cycle presented in Chap. 1 of this volume.
References
Abrams L (2007) Bismarck and the German Empire: 1871–1918. Routledge, London
Acs ZJ, Autio E, Szerb L (2014) National systems of entrepreneurship: measurement issues and
policy implications. Res Policy 43(3):476–494. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2013.08.016
Acs ZJ, Plummer LA (2005) Penetrating the “knowledge filter” in regional economies. Ann Reg
Sci 39(3):439–456
Acs ZJ, Szerb L (2009) The global entrepreneurship index (GEINDEX). Found Trends
Entrepreneurship 5(5):341–435
Acs Z, Szerb L (2016) Extension of GEDI indicators. FIRES Report D4.1. Retrieved from https://
www.projectfires.eu/wp-content/uploads/2016/03/D4.1-Report-on-Extention-of-the-GEDI-
indicator.pdf
Alesina A, Fuchs-Schündeln N (2007) Good-bye Lenin (or not?): the effect of communism on
people’s preferences. Am Econ Rev 97(4):1507–1528
Allen F, Gale D (2000) Comparing financial systems. MIT press, Cambridge, MA
Audretsch DB, Grilo I, Thurik R (2007) Entrepreneurship policies in Germany: from small business
to entrepreneurship policy. Handbook of research on entrepreneurship policy. Edward Elgar
Publishing Inc, Cheltenham, UK, pp 47–50
Audretsch DB, Lehmann EE (2005a) Does the knowledge spillover theory of entrepreneurship hold
for regions? Res Policy 34(8):1191–1202
Audretsch DB, Lehmann EE (2005b) Do university policies make a difference? Res Policy
34(3):343–347
Audretsch DB, Lehmann EE (2016) The seven secrets of Germany: economic resilience in an era
of global turbulence. Oxford University Press, Oxford
Baker D, Lenhardt G (2008) The institutional crisis of the German research university. High Educ
Policy 21(1):49–64
Baller S, Dutta S, Lanvin B (eds) (2016) The global information technology report 2016 innovating
in the digital economy. World Economic Forum, Geneva. Retrieved from: http://reports.weforum.
org/global-information-technology-report-2016
Barkai A (1988) Das Wirtschaftssystem des Nationalsozialismus: Ideologie, Theorie, Politik. 1933–
1945. Fischer-Taschenbuch-Verlag, Frankfurt am Main
Bauernschuster S (2013) Dismissal protection and small firms’ hirings: evidence from a policy
reform. Small Bus Econ 40(2):293–307
Bauernschuster S, Driva A, Hornung E (2019) Bismarck’s health insurance and the mortality decline.
J Eur Econ Assoc (Forthcoming)
Bauernschuster S, Falck O, Gold R, Heblich S (2012) The shadows of the socialist past: Lack of
self-reliance hinders entrepreneurship. Eur J Polit Econ 28(4):485–497
Bauernschuster S, Rainer H (2012) Political regimes and the family: how sex-role attitudes continue
to differ in reunified Germany. J Popul Econ 25(1):5–27
7 A Reform Strategy for Germany 197
Ellul A, Pagano M, Panunzi F (2010) Inheritance law and investment in family firms. Am Econ Rev
100(5):2414–2450
Esping-Andersen G (2002) A new gender contract. In: Esping-Andersen G (ed) Why we need a
new welfare state. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 68–95
Exist (2019) EXIST Start-up Germany. Retrieved from: https://www.exist.de/EN/Network/EXIST-
Start-up-Germany/content.html
Fackler D (2014) Establishment survival in East and West Germany: a comparative analysis.
Schmollers Jahrb 134:183–208
Falck O, Fritsch M, Heblich S (2011) The phantom of the opera: cultural amenities, human capital,
and regional economic growth. Labour Econ 18(6):755–766
Falck O, Günther C, Heblich S, Kerr WR (2013) From Russia with love: the impact of relocated
firms on incumbent survival. J Econ Geogr 13(3):419–449
Fiedler MO, Hellmann T (2001) Against all odds: the late but rapid development of the German
venture capital industry. J Private Equity 4(4):31–45
Fitzenberger B, Kohn K, Lembcke AC (2013) Union density and varieties of coverage: the anatomy
of union wage effects in Germany. ILR Rev 66(1):169–197
Flögel F (2018) Distance and modern banks’ lending to SMEs: ethnographic insights from a
comparison of regional and large banks in Germany. J Econ Geogr 18(1):35–57
Flögel F, Gärtner S (2018) The banking systems of Germany, the United Kingdom and Spain from
a spatial perspective: The German case. Gelsenkirchen: Institute for Work and Technology (IAT)
(IAT Discussion Paper, No. 18/04)
Franzke SA, Grohs S, Laux C (2003) Initial public offerings and venture capital in Germany. CFS
Working Paper No. 2003/26
Fritsch M, Bublitz E, Sorgner A, Wyrwich M (2014) How much of a socialist legacy? The re-
emergence of entrepreneurship in the East German transformation to a market economy. Small
Bus Econ 43(2):427–446
Fritsch M, Noseleit F, Slavtchev V, Wyrwich M (2010) Innovative Gründungen und ihre Bedeutung
für den Standort Thüringen. Studie im Auftrag des Thüringer Ministeriums für Bildung, Wis-
senschaft und Kultur sowie der Stiftung für Technologie, Innovation und Forschung Thüringen
(STIFT). Friedrich-Schiller-Universität, Jena
Fritsch M, Schilder D (2008) Does venture capital Investment really require spatial proximity? An
empirical investigation. Environ Planning A 40(9):2114–2131
Fritsch M, Schilder D (2012) The regional supply of venture capital—can syndication overcome
bottlenecks? Econ Geogr 88(1):59–76
Fritsch M, Sorgner A, Wyrwich M, Zöllner M (2015) Entwicklung und Perspektiven der Förderung
innovativer Gründungen im Freistaat Thüringen. Studie im Auftrag der Stiftung für Technologie,
Innovation und Forschung Thüringen (STIFT) sowie des Thüringer Ministeriums für Wirtschaft,
Wissenschaft und digitale Gesellschaft. Friedrich-Schiller-Universität, Jena
Fritsch M, Wyrwich M (2014) The long persistence of regional levels of entrepreneurship: Germany,
1925–2005. Reg Stud 48(6):955–973
Fritsch M, Wyrwich M (2016) Entrepreneurship in the East German transition process: lessons for
the Korean Peninsula. Hist Soc Res 41(3):256–280
Fritsch M, Wyrwich M (2018) Regional knowledge, entrepreneurial culture and innovative start-ups
over time and space—an empirical investigation. Small Bus Econ 51(2):337–353
Fuchs-Schündeln N, Schündeln M (2005) Precautionary savings and self-selection: evidence from
the german reunification “experiment”. Q J Econ 120(3):1085–1120
Fuchs-Schündeln N, Schündeln M (2009) Who stays, who goes, who returns? Econ Transit
17(4):703–738
Füller C (2017) Educational expenditure: More money for schools and universities. Munich: Goethe
Institute. Retrieved from https://www.goethe.de/en/kul/wis/20925479.html on 16-04-2018
Getz D, Petersen T (2004) Identifying industry-specific barriers to inheritance in small family
businesses. Family Bus Rev 17(3):259–276
7 A Reform Strategy for Germany 199
Gibbons M, Limoges C, Nowotny H, Schwartzman S, Scott P, Trow M (1994) The new production
of knowledge: the dynamics of science and research in contemporary societies. Sage, Thousand
Oaks, CA
Glaeser E (2011) Triumph of the city: how our greatest invention makes us richer, smarter, greener,
healthier, and happier. Penguin Social Science, New York
Goethner M, Wyrwich M (2019) Cross-faculty proximity and academic entrepreneurship: the role
of business schools. J Technol Transf (Forthcoming)
Grimpe C, Fier H (2010) Informal university technology transfer: a comparison between the United
States and Germany. J Technol Transf 35(6):637–650
Guinanne T (2001) Cooperatives as information machines: German rural credit cooperatives, 1883–
1914. J Econ Hist 61(2):366–389
Gutberlet T (2014) Mechanization and the spatial distribution of industries in the German empire,
1875 to 1907. Econ Hist Rev 67(2):463–491
Hackethal A (2004) German banks and banking structure. In: Krahnen JP, Schmidt RH (eds) The
German financial system. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 71–105
Hall JB, Ludwig U (1995) German unification and the “market adoption” hypothesis. Camb J Econ
19(4):491–507
Hall PA, Soskice D (2001) Varieties of capitalism: the institutional foundations of comparative
advantage. Oxford University Press, Oxford
Hantke M, Spoerer M (2010) The imposed gift of Versailles: the fiscal effects of restricting the size
of Germany’s armed forces, 1924–9. Econ Hist Rev 63(4):849–864
Harhoff D, Hoisl K (2007) Institutionalized incentives for ingenuity—Patent value and the German
Employees’ Inventions Act. Res Policy 36(8):1143–1162
Hefele P (1998) Die Verlagerung von Industrie- und Dienstleistungsunternehmen aus der SBZ/DDR
nach Westdeutschland: unter besonderer Berücksichtigung Bayerns (1945–1961). Volume 4 of
Beiträge zur Unternehmensgeschichte. Franz Steiner Verlag, Stuttgart
Held L (2019) Part-time entrepreneurship: the role of institutions, venture and individual character-
istics in entry and transition choices. In: Held L (ed) Unravelling the patterns in venture creation
processes, Ph.D. thesis. Utrecht University, Utrecht, pp 25–55
Held L, Herrmann AM, Polzin F (2018a) Follow the money: the funding acquisition process
of nascent ventures. Horizon 2020 Project on “Financial and Institutional Reforms for an
Entrepreneurial Society” (FIRES), Workpackage 5, Deliverable 5.1; currently under review. Also
available in Held L (2019) Unravelling the patterns in venture creation processes. Ph.D. thesis.
Utrecht University, Utrecht, pp 91–122
Held L, Herrmann AM, Storz C (2018b) Whom do nascent ventures search for? Variance of link-
age formation activities during new product development processes. Horizon 2020 Project on
“Financial and Institutional Reforms for an Entrepreneurial Society” (FIRES), Workpackage 5,
Deliverable 5.1; currently under review. Also available in Held L (2019) Unravelling the patterns
in venture creation processes. Ph.D. thesis. Utrecht University, Utrecht, pp 123–150
Held L, Herrmann AM, van Mossel A (2018c) Team formation processes in new ventures. Special
Issue on “Financial and Institutional Reforms for an Entrepreneurial Society.” Small Bus Econ
51(2):441–464
Herrmann AM (2019) A plea for varieties of entrepreneurship. Special Issue on “Entrepreneurship
in Context.” Small Bus Econ 52(2):331–343
Herrman AM (2020) On the institutional foundations of the varieties of entrepreneurship in Europe.
In: Sanders M, Marx A, Stenkula M (eds) The entrepreneurial society. Reform strategies for Italy,
Germany and the UK. Springer, Berlin
Hofbauer G, Klimontowicz M, Nocoń A (2017) The changes in capital structure of selected bank-
ing markets as a result of new regulations. In: Proceedings of the 14th international scientific
conference European financial systems 2017. Masaryk University, Brno, pp. 222–229
IWH (2010) Ostdeutschlands Transformation seit 1990. Im Spiegel wirtschaftlicher und sozialer
Indikatoren, 2nd edn. Institut für Wirtschaftsforschung (IWH), Halle
200 M. Sanders et al.
Jaeger A, Kopper J (2014) Third mission potential in higher education: measuring the regional focus
of different types of HEIs. Rev Reg Res 34(2):95–108
James A (1981) State, industry and depression in Weimar Germany. Hist J 24(1):231–241
Kindleberger CP (2015) A financial history of Western Europe. Routledge, London
Kluge J, Weber M (2018) Decomposing the German East-West wage gap. Econ Transit 26(1):91–125
Kohaut S, Schnabel C (2007) Tarifliche Öffnungsklauseln: Verbreitung, Inanspruchnahme und
Bedeutung. Sozialer Fortschritt 56(2):33–40
König W (2006) Vom Staatsdiener zum Industrieangestellten: Die Ingenieure in Frankreich und
Deutschland 1750–1945. In: Kaiser W, König W (eds) Geschichte des Ingenieurs. Carl Hanser,
Munich, pp 179–231
Kopper C (2011) New perspectives on the 1931 banking crisis in Germany and Central Europe. Bus
Hist 53(2):216–229
Kulicke M (2014) 15 Years of EXIST “University-based start-up programmes”. Development
of the EXIST funding programme between 1998 and 2013. Fraunhofer-Institut für Systemund
Innovationsforschung, Karlsruhe
Liberman P (1996) Does conquest pay? The exploitation of occupied industrial societies. Princeton
University Press, Princeton, NJ
Lindner A (2017) German unification: macroeconomic consequences for the country. In: Heinemann
F, Klüh U, Watzka S (eds) Monetary policy, financial crises, and the macroeconomy. Springer,
Cham, pp 239–263
Maier F (1993) The labour market for women and employment perspectives in the aftermath of
German unification. Camb J Econ 17(3):267–280
Manegold KH (1989) Geschichte der Technischen Hochschulen. In: Boehm L, Schönbeck C (eds)
Technik und Bildung. VDI Verlag, Düsseldorf, pp 204–234
Mattes A, Arnold M, Eickelpasch A, Fritsch M, Schiersch A (2015) Kleinteiligkeit der ostdeutschen
Wirtschaft – Gibt es spezifische Wachstumshemmnisse für die Bildung größerer Unternehmen-
seinheiten? Final project report submitted to the German Ministry of the Interior. DIW econ,
Berlin
Mertes M (ed) (2018) In search of Germany. Routledge, London
Möller T, Schmidt M, Hornbostel S (2016) Assessing the effects of the German excellence initiative
with bibliometric methods. Scientometrics 109(3):2217–2239
Moshinksy B (2016) Meet the riskiest bank in the world. Business Insider Netherlands. Retrieved
from https://www.businessinsider.nl/fdic-report-on-leverage-ratio-names-deutschebank-as-
riskiest-2016-9/?international=true&r=UK on 16-04-2018
Nunziata L, Rocco L (2018) The Protestant ethic and entrepreneurship: evidence from religious
minorities in the former Holy Roman Empire. Eur J Polit Econ 51:27–43
Ockenfels A, Weimann J (1999) Types and patterns: an experimental East-West-German comparison
of cooperation and solidarity. J Pub Econ 71(2):275–287
Pahnke A, Welter F (2018) The German Mittelstand: antithesis to Silicon Valley entrepreneurship?
Small Bus Econ 52(2):345–358
Pflanze O (2014) Bismarck and the development of Germany. The period of consolidation, 1871–
1880, vol II. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ
Pickel A (1992) Radical transitions: the survival and revival of entrepreneurship. Westview Press,
Boulder
Reckendrees A (2003) From cartel regulation to monopolistic control? The founding of the German
‘steel trust’ in 1926 and its effect on market regulation. Bus Hist 45(3):22–51
Rimlinger GV (1968) Social change and social security in Germany. J Hum Resour 3(4):409–421
Rothman B (2017) After the shock: the German education system in 2017. National Center on Edu-
cation and The Economy. Retrieved from http://ncee.org/2017/09/after-the-shockt-he-german-
education-system-in-2017/ on 16-04-2018
Soskice D (1990) Wage determination: the hanging role of institutions in advanced industrialized
countries. Oxford Rev Econ Policy 6(4):36–61
7 A Reform Strategy for Germany 201
Stam E (2015) Entrepreneurial ecosystems and regional policy: a sympathetic critique. Eur Plan
Stud 23(9):1759–1769
Stam E (2018) Measuring entrepreneurial ecosystems. In: O’Connor A, Stam E, Sussan F, Audretsch
DB (eds) Entrepreneurial ecosystems. Springer, Cham, pp 173–197
Stenholm P, Acs ZJ, Wuebker R (2013) Exploring country-level institutional arrangements on the
rate and type of entrepreneurial activity. J Bus Ventur 28(1):176–193
Streeck W (1997) German capitalism: does it exist? Can it survive? New Polit Econ 2(2):237–256
Szerb L, Lafuente E, Horváth K, Páger B (2019) The relevance of quantity and quality entrepreneur-
ship for regional performance: the moderating role of the entrepreneurial ecosystem. Reg Stud
53(9):1308–1320. https://doi.org/10.1080/00343404.2018.1510481
Szerb L, Vörös Z, Komlósi É, Acs ZJ, Páger B, Rappai G (2017) The regional entrepreneurship
and development index: structure, data, methodology and policy applications. Retrieved from
http://www.projectfires.eu/wp-content/uploads/2018/07/d4.4-the-regional-entrepreneurship-
and-development-index_-structure-data-methodology-and-policy-applications.pdf
Tipton F (1976) Regional variations in the economic development of Germany during the nineteenth
century. Wesleyan University Press, Middletown, CT
Uebele M, Ritschl A (2009) Stock markets and business cycle co movement in Germany before
World War I: evidence from spectral analysis. J Macroecon 31(1):35–57
Varga A, Szerb L, Sebestyén T, Szabó N (2020) Economic impact assessment of entrepreneur-
ship policies with the GMR-Europe model. In: Sanders M, Marx A, Stenkula M (eds) The
entrepreneurial society. Reform strategies for Italy, Germany and the UK, Springer, Berlin
Verheyen D (2018) The German question. Routledge, London
Von Proff S, Buenstorf G, Hummel M (2012) University patenting in Germany before and after
2002: what role did the professors’ privilege play? Ind Innov 19(1):23–44
Weichlein S (2011) Nation state, conflict resolution and culture war, 1850–1878. In: Smith HW (ed)
The Oxford handbook of modern German history. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 281–306
Welter F (2007a) Entrepreneurship in West and East Germany. Int J Entrepreneurship Small Bus
4(2):97–109
Welter F (2007b) Book review of Deutsche Gründungsregionen, edited by Rolf Sternberg,
Berlin/Münster: Lit Verlag. Raumforschung und Raumordnung 65(2):163–164
World Bank (2018a) Doing Business 2018: reforming to create jobs. International Bank for
Reconstruction and Development and World Bank, Washington, DC
World Bank (2018b) Economy rankings. Doing Business: Measuring Business Regulations. World
Bank, Washington, DC
World Bank (2018c) Distance to frontier. Doing Business: Measuring Business Regulations. World
Bank, Washington, DC
Wyrwich M (2012) Regional entrepreneurial heritage in a socialist and a post-socialist economy.
Econ Geogr 88(4):423–445
Wyrwich M (2013) Can socioeconomic heritage produce a lost generation with regard to
entrepreneurship? J Bus Ventur 28(5):667–682
Wyrwich M (2017) Women and the labour market in East and West Germany: socialist legacy and
pre-socialist tradition. Jena Economic Research Paper 2017–015. Friedrich Schiller University,
Jena
Zöllner M, Fritsch M, Wyrwich M (2018) An evaluation of German active labour market policies:
a review of the empirical evidence. J Entrepreneurship Pub Policy 7(4): 377–410
202 M. Sanders et al.
Open Access This chapter is licensed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0
International License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits use, sharing,
adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate
credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license and
indicate if changes were made.
The images or other third party material in this chapter are included in the chapter’s Creative
Commons license, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not
included in the chapter’s Creative Commons license and your intended use is not permitted by
statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from
the copyright holder.
Chapter 8
A Reform Strategy for the UK
All authors acknowledge financial support from the European Union’s Horizon 2020 research
and innovation program under grant agreement No 649378. László Szerb and Balázs Páger also
acknowledge support from the National Scientific Research Fund of Hungary (OTKA/NKFI grant
no. 120289, titled as Entrepreneurship and Competitiveness investigations in Hungary based on the
Global Entrepreneurship Monitor surveys 2017–2019). Mikael Stenkula also gratefully acknowl-
edges financial support from Jan Wallanders och Tom Hedelius stiftelse and from the Marianne and
Marcus Wallenberg Foundation.
workforce’s knowledge base and talent pool as well as the capital base from which
UK entrepreneurs can draw. It furthermore is advisable to open opportunities for not
only starting but also growing innovative firms in all regions in the UK.
In its current form, the UK of Great Britain and Northern Ireland has existed since
the partition of Ireland as an independent country in 1922. But, of course, British
history has much deeper roots. The British Isles were raided, invaded, occupied, and
settled from the mainland frequently in the early middle ages. But since the invasion
of William the Conqueror in 1066, the British Isles have not experienced further
foreign occupation. Still, it took a long time for the country to unify. The seventeenth
century saw the English Civil War (1642–1651) and the Glorious Revolution (1688).
With the Acts of Union of 1707 England, Wales and Scotland formed the UK of
Great Britain and with the Acts of Union of 1800 the Kingdom of Ireland joined.
In the seventeenth century, the UK started to rise as a naval superpower and built
up a colonial empire that spanned the globe. The first British Empire (1583–1783)
established Britain as a global power but ended with the loss of the Thirteen Colonies
in the American Revolution. The Second Empire (1783–1815) saw the exploration of
the Pacific and the rise and fall of Napoleon. The defeat of the latter at Waterloo left
Britain without serious challengers and ushered in the Pax Britannica during which
the UK was the unrivaled global superpower until the Great War of 1914–1918. In
this imperial century, the British Empire expanded into Africa, India, and Asia. And
through its dominance in global trade, finance and diplomacy the UK effectively
ruled the world, while at home the Industrial Revolution turned Northern England
into the workshop and London into the financial capital of the world.
With the unification of Germany, the opening up of Japan and the end of the civil
war in the USA, however, new rivals to the UK’s dominance rose toward the end of
the nineteenth century. With the defeat of Germany and its allies in the Great War, the
British Empire saw its last territorial expansion, which reached its peak in 1921. The
Great War, however, had weakened the UK and boosted the confidence of colonial
elites. Independence movements in India and Ireland and later the rest of the empire
ushered in a gradual decline, while Britain’s rivals rapidly industrialized and caught
up militarily and economically.
8 A Reform Strategy for the UK 205
In World War II, the UK and its allies defeated Nazi Germany and Imperial
Japan, but its days of unrivaled global dominance were over. The UK had to repo-
sition itself in the new world order, while the age of empire left a strong economic
and geographical imprint on the country. The London area had developed into an
economic, administrative, and cultural powerhouse, far bigger than the UK alone
could have supported (Parkinson et al. 2006), whereas the Industrial Revolution had
brought prosperity to the northern regions, but also left them struggling with the loss
of the empire and its markets.
Therefore, by the 1980s, an economic policy focused on specific areas or zones was
implemented by the Thatcher government. The focus of the program was to incen-
tivize inward investment to areas experiencing severe economic problems (Potter
and Moore 2000). The Regional Development Agencies Act of 1998 then divided
England into nine regions, each with its own Regional Development Agency funded
by six different government departments, as well as EU funds (Richardson 2011).
But different regions in the UK started from very uneven starting points. Former
industrial centers such as Swansea and Middlesbrough had to divest from traditional
industries in the wake of globalization, whereas the British cities such as Cambridge,
Oxford, and Reading all lacked such industrial heritage (NESTA 2008).
In terms of entrepreneurship, the levels in the UK have historically varied sub-
stantially across regions and localities and with different effects. With London
as the administrative, financial, and political center of the Empire, a lot of the
entrepreneurial talent and resources from all over the country migrated to that area.
This pattern was further reinforced when globalization and international competition
devastated the economy in the Northern industrial districts. A long history of political
unity implies that the formal institutions have largely been built at the national level
and are uniform across the country. But the economic geography of the British Isles
and its diverse informal institutional make-up imply that entrepreneurship functions
vary in different parts of the country. Mueller et al. (2008), for example, found that,
for Great Britain as a whole, new firm formation had a positive effect on employment
growth. Yet this effect was much smaller in Scotland and Wales and even negative
for the lower quartile regions. This all suggests that we should not take the London
area to be representative of the UK and carefully consider the heterogeneity that is
hidden in aggregated data. The needs and opportunities of London are not those of
Scotland and the other way around. Therefore, a one-size-fit-all reform approach to
the UK is not advised and a regionally diversified approach is needed.
Against the backdrop of this rich history, Britain developed the institutions that
currently define its entrepreneurial ecosystems. To establish and maintain its global
Empire, the UK set up institutions that mobilized financial, human, and knowledge
resources at an unprecedented scale, whereas the loss of the empire enforced an
institutional adjustment process that arguably is still ongoing. Still, the most relevant
institutions supporting entrepreneurship in the UK have deep roots. In what fol-
lows, we focus on its institutions for knowledge creation and diffusion, its financial
institutions, and its labor markets. We then proceed to an overview of recent policy
programs and initiatives to support entrepreneurship.
206 M. Sanders et al.
8.1.2.1 Universities
The UK has a long history of higher education, beginning in the city of Oxford from
the year 1096 (University of Oxford n.d.) and followed a century later by Cambridge
in 1209 (University of Cambridge n.d.). In the fifteenth century, St Andrews, Glasgow,
and Aberdeen—the first three Scottish universities—were founded by Papal Bull, and
a century later the University of Edinburgh was established in 1583 by Royal Charter
(University of Edinburgh n.d.). These six universities are classified as the “ancient
universities” (established before 1800), with the classification sometimes stretched
to include Durham University (Bathmaker et al. 2016).
In the nineteenth century, a major expansion of higher education occurred in the
UK. St. David’s College, Lampeter (Wales), and King’s and University College of
the University of London were awarded university status by Royal Charter (British
Council n.d.), and the University of London was established as a secular alternative
to Oxford and Cambridge (University of London n.d.). The need for a more local-
ized higher education system (Barnes 1996) and a desire to increase education of
the applied sciences (Heyck 2012) resulted in the founding of the civic universi-
ties (or, “redbricks”) in Manchester, Leeds, Liverpool, Sheffield, Birmingham, and
other industrial Victorian cities. Simultaneously, the ancient universities of Oxford
and Cambridge introduced new curricula and relaxed admission requirements (Scott
2014a).
Socio-economic trends fueled by technological innovation, cheaper transporta-
tion, and the emergence of the knowledge economy put education high on the policy
agenda (Clarke 2001; Ashton and Green 1996). But while the Scottish universities
had historically lower tuition fees and living expenses, English universities before
the twentieth century remained accessible only to the wealthy as a result of the
laissez-faire principles of Victorian Britain (Anderson 2016). This paradigm radi-
cally changed following the infamous Robbins Report of 1963, which specified 178
recommendations for the higher education system focusing on greatly expanding the
number of students in tertiary education (Moser 1988). One year prior to the report,
the 1962 Education Act had already introduced state funding for full-time higher
education (domestic) students in order to equalize educational opportunity and bring
higher education to the masses (Wilson 1997).
The 1960s also saw the establishment of The Polytechnics (Henkel and Kogan
1993). Following Anthony Crosland’s 1965 speech advocating the establishment of
two parallel systems of higher education (Taylor 2003), these polytechnic institutions
8 A Reform Strategy for the UK 207
arose through the merger of colleges of technology, commerce, and art (later, includ-
ing colleges of education) and were committed to the application of knowledge. They
offered an alternative form of education to that of traditional universities by over-
coming the traditional dichotomy between theory and practice (Brosan 1972). This
created what is now referred to as the “binary divide” in UK higher education that
lasted for over a quarter of a century (Pratt 1997). The essential difference between the
two educational systems being that polytechnics continued to be controlled by local
education authorities, as opposed to the greater autonomy which the older colleges
enjoyed (Scott 2014b). In 1992, the binary divide ended, and the “new” polytechnics
became universities (Cranfield and Taylor 2008).
In 1985, universities were finally given the rights to exploit their own innovations,
which led to the spreading of science parks around universities in the UK. By 1993,
almost every university in the UK had its own science park, providing a business
environment for almost 1,200 firms and 20,000 employees (Storey and Tether 1998).
The presence of entrepreneurship “in the classroom” is a more recent phenomenon,
and as recently as the 1990s, only a handful of higher education institutes pro-
vided a serious opportunity for enterprise/entrepreneurial education (Hannon 2005).
Responding to the Lambert Review of Business-University Collaboration, the gov-
ernment announced the Science and Innovation Investment Framework in 2004,
cementing business-university collaboration within the portfolio of UK universities
(Wilson 2012).
In conclusion, British universities and higher education deliver high-quality
research and degrees and compete for the best and brightest at the global level.
Relatively high tuition fees notwithstanding, UK universities attract students, PhDs,
and staff from around the world, and these contribute to an excellent and world-class
scientific research infrastructure. The relative weaknesses in the UK educational sys-
tem, however, are the missing middle. Compared to countries like Italy or Germany
(Sanders et al. 2020a, b) or Japan and China in Asia, the quality of vocational edu-
cation is lacking due to a weak apprenticeship system and low engagement with
employers (OECD 2015). Moreover, there is hardly a culture of lifelong learning or
applied vocational education. This leads to over-education at the high general skills
levels, and a mismatch and under-education at the low vocational skills (e.g., Green
et al. 2016; Machin and Vignoles 2018). This affects the level of human capital in
the UK labor supply that is needed to grow the knowledge-intensive ventures that
emerge out of the knowledge created in its excellent research institutions.
In the British context, patents originated in the form of “letters patent” during Eliz-
abethan England. These were essentially royal privileges granting monopoly power
to the introducers of new techniques (WIPO n.d.a). However, this system came to
be abused by the monarchy whose royal favors were perceived as privileges grant-
ing selective monopolies. Consequently, judicial pressure and public outcry forced
intellectual property to be regulated under common law. The Statute of Monopolies
208 M. Sanders et al.
enacted in 1623 made all monopolies illegal except for those “… made of the sole
working or making of any manner of new manufactures within this Realm to the true
and first inventor” (Statute of Monopolies 1623). While this was by no means the
first form of patent protection for inventors, it is historically important for instilling
the principle that only “the true and first inventor” owns the rights to a monopoly
patent (Machlup and Penrose 1950).
The patent system established in 1623 remained in place for another two centuries
and evolved through the work of lawyers and judges in courts without government
regulation (IPO 2014a). This initial laissez-faire approach to patent law meant no
examination was required to acquire an English patent, only its registration. The
establishment of intellectual property rights was a fitting precursor to the Industrial
Revolution in the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries. It is important to note that the
British patent system, while present, actually provided weak and erratic protection
to inventors (MacLeod 1988).
By the mid-eighteenth century, growing criticisms with the patent system included
being too costly, as well as it being almost impossible to specify an invention in
any such way that would satisfy the courts (Robinson 1972). Consequently, the
significance of the British patent system prior to the Patent Law Amendment Act
of 1852 remains debated (MacLeod and Nuvolari 2006). Mokyr (2005) concludes
that in this period, innovation and industrialization were not held back by limited
intellectual property protection.
In essence, the reform of 1852 made two main changes to the prior patent system.
Firstly, legal fees were greatly reduced, and secondly, it implemented a single patent
for the UK (Dutton 1984). However, costs were still relatively high, but the 1883
Patents Act reduced patent filing fees by another 84% (Nicholas 2014).
Patent law in recent times can be mainly derived from the Patent Act of 1902,
which required patent examiners to construct an extensive archive of prior specifica-
tions. By 1907, all recorded patent specifications had been classified, with the first
documented patent dating back to the year 1617 (IPO 2014b).1 The 1977 Patents Act
applied more stringent novelty tests to patents, while also implementing the Euro-
pean Patent Convention of 1973 and the Patent Co-operation Treaty of 1970 (WIPO
n.d.b). The UK is still signatory to these treaties and will remain so after Brexit,
making intellectual property rights in the UK a matter of international negotiations.
The skepticism toward monopolies—such as expressed in the Act from 1623
mentioned above—may be one reason for the fact that British firms, unlike their
German counterparts, are less inclined to engage in large-scale collaborations within
the framework of over-arching industry associations (Herrmann 2020). Given that
large-scale collaboration is discouraged, British firms lack an important tool, via
industry-wide coordinated associations, to access a broad knowledge base (Tate 2001;
Teubner 2001).
1 Patent No. 1 of 1617 granted to Rathburn and Burges for “Engraving and Printing Maps, Plans
&co.”
8 A Reform Strategy for the UK 209
Banking in the UK began during the seventeenth century. The Bank of England
was founded by Royal Charter in 1694 and was primarily used to fund the war effort
against France (Bank of England n.d.). The Bank of Scotland was established one year
later in 1695 following an act made by the Parliament of Scotland providing a legal
monopoly on banking (Lloyds Banking Group n.d.). It initially fulfilled a different
role to its English counterpart, acting mainly to develop Scotland’s business and trade
with England and the Low Countries. In 1696, the Bank of Scotland became the first
European commercial bank to successfully issue a paper currency (BBC 2008). When
its legal monopoly ended in 1716, the Royal Bank of Scotland was chartered in 1727,
creating a historic rivalry between the two Scottish banks (White 1992). The Bank of
Scotland’s monopoly ended much earlier than the Bank of England’s. Scotland then
enjoyed a significant expansion in banking services and by the end of the century
had one of the most developed banking sectors in Europe (Collins 2012). The Royal
Bank of Scotland even invented the overdraft (BBC 2009).2
From 1709 onwards, the Bank of England was the only bank allowed to operate
on a joint-stock basis (Ferguson 2009). The next big leap in the history of UK
banking was the Bank Charter Act of 1844 (Bank of England n.d.), which restricted
the issuance of banknotes solely to the Bank of England. With restrictions on joint-
stock banking lifted by 1858, corporate branch deposit banking developed in the UK
(Newton and Cottrell 1998) and large commercial banks such as Lloyds (1884) and
Barclays (1896) began to emerge. On the eve of the World War I, residents’ deposits
in British banks totaled almost £1.2 billion, with a total bank-note circulation of only
£45.5 million (Ferguson 2009). UK SME finance was left predominantly to the big
four modern banks—Barclays PLC , HSBC Holdings PLC, Lloyds Banking Group
PLC, and Royal Bank of Scotland Group PLC—who still hold 78% of the SME
market and 95 percent in the case of Scotland (Han et al. 2012).
In 1945, the Industrial and Commercial Finance Corporation was created (3i
Group n.d.) via a political decision to increase funding availability for SMEs. By
then, larger banks and the London Stock exchange mainly focused on overseas com-
merce (Merlin-Jones 2010) so no “readily accessible channel, corresponding to the
new issue market for larger firms, through which the small industrialist can raise
long-term funds” existed (Radcliffe Committee on the Working of the Monetary
System cited in Merlin-Jones 2010, p. 5). In addition, the National Research Devel-
opment Corporation, founded in 1948, and the National Enterprise Board, conceived
by the Labour government in 1973, acted to provide loans to small firms to improve
R&D and boost innovation (Rothwell 1985). The inauguration of the Thatcher
government in the 1980s brought the reduction of corporate and personal taxes to
encourage greater entrepreneurship, alongside the new Business Expansion Scheme
which offered up to £40,000 in tax relief to individuals investing in non-public UK
2 Thebank allowed William Hog, a merchant, to take £1,000—the equivalent of £63,664 today—
more out of his account than he had in it.
210 M. Sanders et al.
companies (Mason and Harrison 1989). Over the 1990s and early 2000s, liberal-
ization and globalization implied that the UK financial system grew in number and
became more concentrated in terms of market participants and geographically. The
financial sector in the UK today is extremely concentrated in (the City of) London,
where all superlatives still apply. The UK boasts the biggest currency, commodities,
stock and asset markets in Europe and serves as a global financial center rivaling New
York and Tokyo. But the skyscrapers of the city are not primarily in the business of
financing SMEs and/or innovative young ventures. The UK has a significant venture
capital market and new initiatives in platform-based FinTech innovation benefit from
a sensible and benign regulatory regime, but the financial crisis of 2007 hit London
perhaps hardest of all and revealed vulnerabilities in the strong reliance on global
financial asset trading.
In conclusion, the financing of small-scale experimental ventures may not be
the biggest activity in the London City, but the sheer size of UK financial markets
still implies that entrepreneurs face little financial constraints in the UK. Moreover,
financial regulation in the UK is arguably more flexible than in the Euro-Area, as
UK financial regulators take a tougher stance on incumbent banks’ interests while
leaving more space for new, platform-based alternative intermediation services.
The labor force in the UK is typically not very loyal to the employer because that
loyalty is often not reciprocated (Herrmann 2020). At the lower end of the spectrum,
wages are low and jobs are insecure, making investment in firm-specific human
capital a risky strategy for UK workers (OECD 2019). This implies it is easy to
start a venture, but much harder to grow one into a global competitor as the latter
implies accumulating also tacit and firm-specific knowledge on product, market, and
process (e.g., Thirkell and Dau 1998). As in other countries, the existing equilibrium
in labor relations in the UK has deep historical roots that can be traced in the history
of employment protection, wage bargaining, and social security.
Labor relations in the UK (and in fact the Anglo-Saxon world) have always been
rather conflicting. Due to laws such as the Masters and Servants Acts of 1823 and
1867, disobedient workers could be punished for a criminal offense (Woods 1982;
Choi 2010). British labor law only gradually turned in favor of the workers in the
early twentieth century (e.g., the Old Age Pension Act of 1908 and the National
Insurance Act of 1911).
In 1963, the Contracts of Employment Act introduced statutory protection from
termination of employment and protection of wages (Brown et al. 2000), with sub-
sequent acts addressing race (Race Relations Act 1965) and gender (Equal Pay Act
8 A Reform Strategy for the UK 211
1970) related inequalities. High unemployment and large losses in nationalized indus-
tries wreaked havoc in the public sector budget, and the Thatcher years in the 1980s
saw a decade of legislation to break union power and liberalize labor markets. The
2002 Employment Act was implemented and essentially shifted the responsibility
of enforcement of employment rights from public tribunals to private management-
controlled procedures, giving more weight to the competitiveness of the employer
than the welfare of the individual (Hepple and Morris 2002; Hepple 2002). The
reforms in labor protection of recent decades have brought the UK back to a position
in which low wages and low employment protection create high uncertainty for and,
consequently, low loyalty of employees for their employer. The flexibility of the
labor market implies it is easy to hire employees, but the lack of investment in firm-
specific human capital and employability makes it hard to accumulate firm-specific
knowledge and retain brains. For this reason, it is easy to start a venture in the UK,
but very hard to grow that venture into a globally competitive firm of significant size.
In the UK, wage-bargaining institutions go back far in history and were formed
out of conflict between the aristocratic landowners and skilled peasants and artisans
of England. One of the earliest pieces of legislation, which came about after the
breakout of the black death, was the “Ordinance of Laborers” legislation of 1349 that
implemented a series of labor regulations and price controls to mitigate the problems
of labor shortages after the plague (Craig 2007). Building on this legislation, the
Elizabethan Statute of Artificers of 1563 prohibited conspiracies to raise wages and
the first worker’s associations formed in response to the legislation (Woodward 1980).
Unions in Britain had effectively been repressed by the aristocracy and large
employers (Curthoys 2004). By 1824, unions became partly legalized due to the
repeal of the combination laws (Shawl 1954).3 But it was not until the repeal of the
Masters and Servants Act (1867) and the Trade Union Act (1871) that there was a
positive step toward establishing more harmonious relations between the unions and
the courts (Kahn-Freund 1944).
The relationship between employers and the employed during the nineteenth cen-
tury remained one of conflict, where the interests of both parties were at odds. The
proposals set forth by the Whitley Committee led to the establishment of the coun-
try’s first Joint Industrial Council in 1918 (Clegg et al. 1985). But this was short-lived
and, following the deterioration of laborers’ power due to postwar unemployment, the
state abandoned its support for co-management and consultation (Lewchuk 1984).
The mid-1970s saw the turmoil of UK recession as a result of the oil crisis in 1973
and the decline of traditional British industries. This culminated in the “winter of
discontent” 1978–79, where 1.5 million public sector workers took part in Britain’s
largest single day of industrial action since the general strike of 1926 (Hay 2010). In
3 The combination acts of 1799 and 1800 were the embodiment of Parliament’s conversion to a
laissez-faire policy, removing protection of labor conditions up until their repeal in 1824.
212 M. Sanders et al.
1980, Thatcher’s government abolished the statutory procedure that allowed inde-
pendent trade unions to seek official recognition and British employers were no
longer legally required to bargain with the unions (Towers 1989). Thus, the 1980s
and 1990s saw a dramatic decline in trade union power and a decentralization of
collective bargaining (Wooden and Sloan 1998).
In 1999, the New Labour government under Tony Blair passed the National Mini-
mum Wage Regulations which set a minimum wage of £3.00 per hour for 18–21-year-
olds and £3.60 per hour for anyone older. The wage floor improved the conditions
for “outsiders,” such as those employed in small businesses (Morris et al. 2005), but
also increased the operating costs of smaller firms (Rusly et al. 2017).
Liberalized laissez-faire wage formation in the UK has arguably depressed wages
by lowering union bargaining power, and the UK saw significant wage diversion
between strong (insider educated white managerial jobs) and weak (outsider unedu-
cated minority female manual) jobs in the 1990s and polarization in the 2000s (Goos
et al. 2009, 2014). Labor market polarization has led to widening income inequality
and reduced incentives for medium-level human capital investment at school and on
the job.
The earliest underpinnings of a modern welfare state in the UK can be traced back
to the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries with the Act for the Relief of the Poor
in 1597 and the Poor Relief Act of 1601 (Birtles 1999). The modern welfare state
in the UK arose after the landslide victory of the Liberal government in 1906. It
introduced the concept of national health and unemployment insurance in the 1911
National Insurance Act (Feld 2011). The Beveridge Report of 1941 influenced one of
the most radical changes in British history by establishing three main principles for
postwar policy development: the introduction of family allowances, a National Health
Service, and state maintenance of full employment in order to maintain funding for
such social provisions (Whiteside 2014). The centuries’ old poor laws were replaced
by the National Assistance Act of 1948 (Spicker 2014), and in that same year, the
Attlee Labour government launched the National Health Service that is still operating
today (NHS n.d.).
By the 1980s, the Thatcher government introduced various measures to shift
social security into an enterprise incentivizing framework. The government for exam-
ple implemented an Enterprise Allowance Scheme, which gave individuals direct
transfers of between £40 and £100 per week for their first year of self-employment
(Cowling and Mitchell 1997).
In conclusion, the UK labor institutions have always been, but certainly since
the Thatcher Era, tilted in favor of employers. This creates great labor mobility and
flexibility on the one hand, but arguably low mutual loyalty, and rather militant
labor relations on the other. This results in a labor market in which it is easy to hire
and fire workers, but hard to find committed employees that will invest in firms’
specific human capital and are willing to go the extra mile and make sacrifices for
8 A Reform Strategy for the UK 213
8.1.5.1 (De)regulation
Since the 1980s, UK governments of all signatures were actively working to make
regulation better for businesses (Ashmore 1988). This started with the 1985 and
1986 White Papers “Lifting the Burden” and “Building Businesses … Not Barriers.”
In 1997, the government established the Better Regulation Task Force to advise
the government how to reduce unnecessary burdens of regulation. Government also
focused on lifting regulation for small firms specifically with the “Think Small First”
campaign.
In 2011, the government introduced the Micro-Business Moratorium—a freeze
on new regulation for start-ups and companies with fewer than 10 employees. It then
applied a “one-in, one-out” rule for UK business regulation in 2012, and following a
political logic, the rule was changed into “one-in, two-out” in 2013 and “one-in, three-
out” in 2016. Regulation of business is, however, not a matter of quantity, but rather
of quality, including transparency. More interesting initiatives in recent years develop
sensible regulation in a more interactive way. Entrepreneurs need regulatory stability
rather than ongoing changes. Frequent changes of regulation may be detrimental for
the development of the firms, a view supported by the survey of British founders
presented in Sect. 8.3.4
The deregulation doctrine is still very much alive today. In 2015, the Parliament
passed the Small Business, Enterprise and Employment Act, requiring the govern-
ment of the day to publish a “Business Impact Target”. Social security burdens for
especially small employers were reduced in 2014, when the government introduced
the Employment Allowance for all businesses and charities and since 2016 allows
start-ups and SMEs to employ four workers without paying any social security con-
tributions. The policy has not yet been evaluated on its effects and can be expected
4 This is particularly true for the renewable energy sector in UK (Leendertse 2017).
214 M. Sanders et al.
to promote the creation of new but hamper the growth of successful businesses in
the UK.
In the early 1990s, the government started supporting the development of informal
venture capital. The Business Expansion Scheme, which was implemented in 1983,
was replaced in 1993 by the Enterprise Investment Scheme. This scheme provided
both front-end and capital gains’ tax relief on investments made directly in qualifying
unquoted companies, strengthening incentives for business angels (Mason et al. 2010,
p. 47). Furthermore, the Financial Services and Markets Act (UK Government 2000)
created the opportunity for unquoted firms to raise equity and allowing investors to
obtain certification without going through an authorized institution (Mason 2009).
The government then set up the Business Finance Partnership, increasing lending
to small- and medium-sized businesses and the Enterprise Capital Funds, provid-
ing venture capital investment for early stage, innovative small- and medium-sized
businesses with high growth potential (UK Government 2015).
With these incentives in place, a vibrant angel and venture capital sector developed
(Wiltbank 2009; Mason et al. 2010), and the creation of co-investment funds to
match private investments with public funds enabled business angels to increase the
availability of finance for new ventures (Mason 2009, p. 548). In November 2011,
the Business Angel Co-Investment Fund was launched, investing with syndicates of
business angels in SMEs.
Hence, the successive governments in the UK first allowed a private business
angel and venture capital market to emerge and then also channeled public funds to
SMEs and start-ups through these channels, thereby avoiding the problem of having
to pick winners or write extensive protocols to administer subsidies and grants.
Considerable efforts were also made to get banks to lend to SMEs (UK Govern-
ment 2015). For example, in 2009, the Enterprise Finance Guarantee was initiated,
allowing banks to offer small businesses a normal, secured commercial loan. In early
2011, the Bank Appeal Process, which allowed SMEs to appeal against a bank’s
decision to decline a loan, was also launched. More than 9,000 businesses used the
process, resulting in £42 millions of further lending. But although this can be con-
sidered a success of the appeals process, it also signals that banks in the UK have
not been very keen on financing SMEs.
Nevertheless, in July 2012, with support from the government, the Bank of Eng-
land (BoE) launched Funding for Lending, allowing banks and building societies to
borrow from the BoE at cheaper than market rates for 4 years. In 2014, the Department
for Business, Innovation and Skills established the British Business Bank, manag-
ing all government programs that help smaller businesses to access finance. In the
first quarter of 2018, the Funding for Lending program was discontinued as it was
predestined to (Pike 2017). But it was also discontinued after it was shown to have
a great detrimental effect on the savings in high-street banks, as interest rates fell by
two-thirds in January 2017 (Jones 2018).
8 A Reform Strategy for the UK 215
In conclusion, tax and other policy initiatives have given formal UK financial
markets a great boost in recent decades. The UK now has the largest VC and angel
investment market in Europe, and London, arguably, remains the financial capital of
the world. But the flow of finance to SMEs and start-ups, especially in their earliest
stages of growth remains limited, especially outside London.
8.1.5.3 Innovation
prestigious awards for businesses and individuals in the UK since 1965. The Enter-
prise Act of 2002 made bankruptcy law more forgiving, recognizing that not all of
the bankruptcies are the result of misconduct and irresponsibility (Walters 2005).
The Davies Review (Davies 2002) argued that the best way to make the culture more
entrepreneurial was through the educational system. In 2004, the government estab-
lished the National Council for Graduate Entrepreneurship to promote a culture of
entrepreneurship in higher education and launched the initiative Enterprising Britain,
which since 2005 is an annual competition.
Teaching pupils to be entrepreneurial, however, is not the same as teaching them
about entrepreneurship. The government therefore shifted focus with the aim to
foster a more entrepreneurial youth. They launched Inspiring the future, where young
entrepreneurs are volunteering to go into schools to talk about running their own
business, Enterprise Village which supports teachers to set up and develop a school-
based business, and the Premier League Enterprise Academy model which enabled
football clubs to develop enterprise in young people, concentrating in deprived areas.
The government also funded the development of Student-led Enterprise Societies.
Their main activity was working together with local firms to get loans for student
support and launching start-ups. The Global Entrepreneurship Week is, further, an
annual event to help young people learn about the range of support programs available
to entrepreneurs in the UK.
Besides awards, support, and events, the UK government encouraged
entrepreneurship through Enterprise Zones, established since 2012. These Enterprise
Zones are designated areas across England that provide tax breaks and government
support. Initiatives to improve access to information and counseling are all part of a
big umbrella campaign called Great Business, under which the government launched
the Business in You Campaign with the aim to help people understand how they can
start and run their own business.
In conclusion, subsequent UK governments have always had an interest in and
developed (national) initiatives to promote an entrepreneurial mindset and culture
throughout the UK.
In discussing the current situation in the UK, it would be incomplete not to discuss the
issue of Brexit. Although the exact relationship of the UK with the European Union
after Brexit remains unclear at the time of writing this book (January 2020), the
LSE Growth Commission (2017) has published a noteworthy report on the growth
prospects of the post-Brexit UK. The Commission reports some progress on the
recommendations made in its 2013 prequel (mainly on increasing competition and
investment in long-term assets and SMEs) but, interestingly, now calls for a tax and
minimum wage system that is neutral with regard to forms of employment to promote
lifelong learning and adaptable skills in light of rapid technological changes. Coupled
with a new system of tax breaks for skills investment and better endowed technical
8 A Reform Strategy for the UK 217
education, this should make British workers more resilient in future labor markets
while supplying British entrepreneurs with the much-needed skilled labor force.
For the financial sector, the Commission suggests maintaining the links to EU
markets by developing a substitute for the financial services “passport” while also
diversifying its portfolio. The latter should be done by building new links to emerging
markets and tapping into domestic markets by widening SME access to bond markets
and boosting equity tax relief schemes for investors in SMEs. If at the same time
smart regulation would make the banking market more competitive while supporting
the emerging FinTech sector, the private financial markets can be an asset, not a
liability for the British economy. To complement the private sector, the Commission
advised the government to strengthen the British Business Bank, to establish a new
infrastructure bank, and to fill the funding gaps the private market will not fill.
Finally, the Commission challenges the UK’s industrial strategy, stating that two-
thirds of the workforce are now employed in sectors where productivity is below
average. The Commission therefore recommends the government to establish a new
framework in order to pursue six key priorities, namely:
1. Skill shortages;
2. Low productivity sectors;
3. Small firms (less obstacles in terms of taxes and regulations);
4. Universities and private sector collaboration;
5. City-growth policies (support locally);
6. Growth, environment, and well-being.
The analysis of the Commission also largely supports the proposals we present
below. Still, our focus on entrepreneurship and the entrepreneurial ecosystem has
led us to identify slightly different bottlenecks. Furthermore, a more historical and
regionally differentiated approach leads us to focus our proposals on making the UK
ecosystem more diversified and inclusive, while de-emphasizing the more traditional
UK strategies of further SME deregulation, putting a strong focus on (global) finance
and linking academic research to the private sector.
8.1.7 Conclusions
In conclusion, the UK has an eventful history that shaped its institutions in a unique
way. The British Isles were not invaded from outside since 1066, but saw centuries
of internal conflict before the country unified in the seventeenth and rose to unrivaled
global supremacy in the nineteenth century. In the twentieth century, however, this
unrivaled position was challenged and the UK, like any other nation going forward,
will have to compete in an increasingly global marketplace with innovative and
efficient competitors for the favor of consumers across the globe.
During the Thatcher years of the 1980s, the UK developed into a distinct liberal
market economy (Hall and Soskice 2001) with a deregulated business environment,
218 M. Sanders et al.
flexible labor markets, well-funded elite universities, and strong protection of intel-
lectual property rights. In such a system, however, low labor protection arguably
reduces incentives to invest and accumulate (firm-specific) human capital. Policies
based on further deregulation and stronger market competition will not be able to
address this weakness. In line with the LSE Commission on Growth (2017), we thus
argue, below, that the UK needs to start paying more attention to its collective physi-
cal, digital, and financial infrastructures—factors that entrepreneurs need to succeed
in global markets. A well-educated, loyal labor force, and excellent infrastructure are
essential for ventures to grow into sustainable and globally competitive businesses.
If, as a corollary, the UK entrepreneurial ecosystem can also become more inclu-
sive—regionally, and across income groups and wealth levels—this may turn out to
be vital for the long-run sociopolitical sustainability of the UK model.
1. Opportunity Perception
1.0
14. Risk Capital 2. Startup Skills
0.9
0.8
0.7
13. Internationalization 3. Risk Acceptance
0.6
0.5
0.4
0.3
12. High Growth 0.2 4. Networking
0.1
0.0
8. Human Capital
Fig. 8.1 Radar-plot REDI comparison Germany–Italy–UK and EU-average. Source Authors’ own
compilation
220 M. Sanders et al.
5 The
numbers are index numbers ranging from 0 (worst) to 100 (best) across all 125 European
NUTS2/3 regions for 2012–2014.
8 A Reform Strategy for the UK 221
Fig. 8.2 REDI map of UK’s regions. Source Authors’ own compilation
ecosystem that generates inclusive and innovative growth across the Kingdom may
well prove an important strategy to prevent further tensions.
Table 8.2 shows the weakest pillars in the REDI index across all UK regions. The
analysis shows that the pillars are all concentrated in the 10–14 range, with only
a few exceptions. Despite the large range between the best and worst performing
entrepreneurial ecosystems in the UK, therefore, it is possible to implement policies
and propose reforms that will strengthen all ecosystems alike. The frequent appear-
ance of pillars 7, 10, and 11 suggests a bottleneck in the transfer of knowledge from
basic and applied research to commercial activity, as in the aforementioned so-called
222 M. Sanders et al.
European Paradox. It reflects the low actual uptake of new product and process tech-
nology in new ventures in the UK. This weakness is pronounced throughout the coun-
try and even the world-class London ecosystem is (relatively) weak in that respect.
This calls for a targeted national approach, where interventions aim to strengthen
exactly that weak link.
The frequent appearance of pillar 13, underpinned with low scores on Exports and
sometimes also Connectivity, suggests UK manufacturing still has difficulty finding
foreign markets and competing in the global marketplace. The strong services’ ori-
entation of, in particular, the London ecosystem can explain why this aspect of the
entrepreneurial ecosystem remains underdeveloped. But although for London this
does not seem to be a big problem, for the more peripheral regions in the UK it may
well be. Moreover, Brexit may adversely affect the competitive position of London
as the financial and business services capital of Europe. Diversification and the devel-
opment of new, more industrially oriented competitive strengths could be a sensible
strategy to try and strengthen these pillars in the UK entrepreneurial ecosystem.
The other pillar that stands out as remarkably and consistently weak across the UK
is pillar 14 “Risk Capital.” Low scores on “Risk Capital” are typically due to very low
levels of informal investment being available and/or accessed. This is compensated
by strong formal markets for equity in early-stage venturing, but business angel
and VC markets have come under criticism for lack of regional, gender, and ethnic
inclusiveness (Bates and Bradford 1992; Mollick and Robb 2016). Well-developed
VC and private equity markets are of course good for the unicorns and gazelles that
make the headlines, but financing the SMEs and start-ups at the base requires smaller
magnitudes that promise only lower returns, making them much less interesting for
VC funds and angel investors.
In Estrin et al. (2018), the authors investigated the potential for equity crowdfund-
ing to play a complementary role in filling the funding gap. But reforms can also be
proposed to strengthen the more traditional informal investment channels. This may
be particularly important to boost access to informal investment, especially in the
periphery.
We believe the UK is doing well in developing crowdfunding as a channel to com-
plement formal financial markets. From Table 8.2, we may conclude that most UK
regions would benefit from reforms and interventions that increase the technologi-
cal sophistication and innovativeness of production and increase the flow of funds
to perhaps dull, but essential small industrial firms that turn new knowledge into
business. In manufacturing, this can give a boost to export performance and global
competitiveness, whereas in services this will stimulate the regional and national
economy.
We agree with the LSE Growth Commission (2017) that policies to level the
playing field between self-employed and employees and to increase incentives for on
the job training are helpful in this respect. The UK’s strength in labor flexibility may
well come at a cost of low loyalty and security for employees that makes investment
in firm-specific human capital, especially at the lower end of the wage distribution,
a less appealing proposition.
224 M. Sanders et al.
Our reading of the data above reveals that in all UK regions and in the country as
a whole, the entrepreneurial ecosystem is strong. But even in the best ecosystem,
there are always pillars that perform relatively weak and bottlenecks remain in a
lack of innovation (New Products and Technology), export orientation (Exports),
and informal investment. It is dangerous, however, to rely exclusively on data and
aggregate indices, even if they are composed of a broad set of sub-indicators. It is
always important to complement a data-based quick scan with common sense and
more qualitative information to contextualize and complete the diagnosis. Only after
triangulating the results above with the historical analysis, literature review, expert
judgement and more qualitative survey results below, we can map the diagnosis onto
our menu of interventions to propose tailored reforms for the UK.
As illustrated in Herrmann (2020), we studied in two ways how the British institu-
tional ecosystem influences entrepreneurial activities, namely from a static perspec-
tive (based on multiannual averages) as well as from a process-oriented perspec-
tive. Both kinds of analyses provide similar insights. Our static analyses reveal that
entrepreneurs in the UK are less likely to set up incrementally innovative ventures or
imitate existing business ideas; they rather tend to set up radically innovative ventures
(Dilli et al. 2018; Herrmann 2019).
The dynamic analyses, in turn, illustrate how the British institutional environment
influences different aspects of the venture creation process. With regard to human
capital, we find that national labor market institutions influence the work choices
of entrepreneurs (Held 2019). Whenever labor market flexibility guarantees neither
employment security nor benefits, the risk related to giving-up dependent employ-
ment in order to work full-time on venture creation is limited. Accordingly, part-time
entrepreneurs in liberal market economies, such as the UK, are significantly more
likely to transition to full-time entrepreneurship than their counterparts in coordinated
market economies, such as Germany (Held 2019).
With regard to the process of finance acquisition, we (Held et al. 2018a) find that
various venture characteristics influence the type of funding which nascent venture
acquire first and, respectively, most. These characteristics also include a venture’s
institutional environment. Ventures in countries with a higher stock market capital-
ization (such as the UK) are less likely to seek debt finance. At the same time, a
more limited availability of loans to the private sector also leads nascent ventures to
finance their endeavors through grants.
8 A Reform Strategy for the UK 225
Finally, we find that nascent ventures in the UK and the USA are less likely to
engage in R&D collaborations with external partners, such as universities and labo-
ratories, than nascent ventures in Germany (Held et al. 2018b). It seems that nascent
ventures are reluctant to engage in joint R&D projects whenever the institutions gov-
erning inter-firm collaborations make the outcome of lawsuits in case of IP conflicts
rather unpredictable.
Taken together, these studies lend support to the argument that the UK’s distinct
finance, labor, and R&D-related institutions influence the decisions of entrepreneurs
with regard to the business ideas they develop as well as the modus operandi they
choose to set up their ventures. This leads to the question how British entrepreneurs
experienced their institutional environment when setting up a venture: Which aspects
are constraining? And what could policy makers do to facilitate venture creation in
the UK?
In the same survey, founders were also asked: “What can policy makers do to facilitate
venture creation?”. The answers to this question are listed in Table 8.4.
Interestingly, only a small share of founders (7.2%) opined that policy makers
could not facilitate venture creation. This is a remarkable contrast to the above finding
that about every second founder did not feel constrained by regulatory obstacles. On
the contrary, British founders had numerous suggestions on how policy makers could
facilitate venture creation.
By far, the most common suggestion called for facilitating access to finance for
small businesses (almost 13% of all times mentioned). This is perhaps remarkable,
8 A Reform Strategy for the UK 227
because the UK has a well-developed financial system. The reason for this discrep-
ancy, also discussed in our REDI analysis, is related to the different types of finance
that nascent ventures use. While venture or angel capital is comparatively abundant
in the UK, only radically innovative ventures have access to such high-risk finance.
As pointed out by Herrmann (2020), even in the UK only a small minority (of less
than 10%) of all ventures founded per year are radically innovative. This would imply
that the majority of ventures, pursuing incrementally innovative or imitative business
ideas, need to turn to other financial sources. For these ventures, which also are the
largest part of respondents to our survey, bank- or government-based finance con-
stitutes the most important finance source—next to the founders’ own and informal
funding. We therefore interpret the suggestion of better access to finance as a call for
improving access to bank-based, public, and informal finance.
228 M. Sanders et al.
The second most important suggestion concerns the human resources needed for
venture creation. Almost 9% of responses highlighted that policy makers should
provide better training to people for starting businesses, while almost 5% suggested
to provide incentives for hiring people. Overall, this is in line with our above find-
ings that, in the UK, workers with (firm-) specific skills are comparatively scarce
and difficult to retain. The suggestions of UK founders indicate that the British
workforce would benefit from acquiring not only more specific skills but also more
entrepreneurial knowledge. In addition, policies that facilitate the hiring of skilled
workers may constitute a further measure to provide nascent ventures with the
necessary human capital.
While founders also asked for lower tax rates for small businesses (in almost 6.5%
of cases), they asked in various ways for better and more transparent information
about venture creation. Accordingly, they did not only suggest to reduce bureau-
cracy (in almost 7% of cases) but also to provide better information about how to
start a business (in 6%), to provide competent advice to people starting businesses
(in almost 3.5%), to centralize information for starting businesses (in 3%), and to
provide guidance (in almost 2.5%). Taken together, this indicates that founders have
experienced systematic problems in obtaining the necessary information at the right
time.
Finally, and in line with the regulatory obstacles mentioned above, the founders
interviewed suggested that venture creation would be facilitated by a more reliable
and long-term oriented regulation. Accordingly, they suggested to avoid frequent
policy changes in almost 5% of all times and to remain within the EU in almost 2.5%
of times.
8.3.4 Conclusions
While our founder survey does not confirm all the weaknesses identified in REDI
analyses based on composite indices, it adds several important nuances. It thus adds
complementary information to the results obtained in Sect. 8.2. For example, the
surveys clearly confirm the need for better opportunities for small ventures to obtain
finance. But in addition, founders also highlight the lack of (access to) an appro-
priately skilled workforce. The REDI analysis, in contrast, did not flag this as a
problem, because of its focus on tertiary education. The founders interviewed, how-
ever, agree with the LSE Growth Committee (2017) that vocational education should
be improved and incentives for employing and training workers on the job should be
strengthened.
Next to these aspects, our founder survey also highlights the importance of trans-
parent and easily accessible information about venture creation, as well as stable and
reliable regulation. Given that these aspects are not covered by the REDI data, the sur-
vey offers important complementary insights into how policy makers can still facili-
tate venture creation—even in a comparatively business-friendly environment as the
UK. Founders repeatedly highlighted the importance of clear and reliable information
8 A Reform Strategy for the UK 229
resources are highest. Quantitative data analysis then suggests large heterogeneity in
entrepreneurial ecosystem performance. While this does not come out as a problem
for the country as a whole, it creates a political divide, as the Brexit vote has clearly
uncovered, for example.
The results from our survey do not reveal this heterogeneity. While they confirm
that the challenges and bottlenecks in their ecosystem are not formidable, they still
point to a lack of funding for small ventures, as well as a lack of skilled person-
nel. This, in turn, supports the insights obtained from the previous historical and
quantitative analyses.
Our data analysis additionally reveals that entrepreneurship in the UK is less suc-
cessful in adopting and commercializing high-tech knowledge developed in academic
institutions and world-class R&D laboratories. New ventures in the UK score (com-
paratively) low in radically new products and technology absorption and its regions
lack risk capital in the form of informal investment. These pillars in the ecosystem,
together with non-transparent information about and frequently changing regulation
of entrepreneurship, seem to be the weakest links in an otherwise business-friendly
entrepreneurial ecosystem. The treatment needed should therefore help to overcome
these weaknesses.
As the UK is to leave the European Union, it may be required to diversify its
economy and regain its position in global markets also as a high-tech industrial
exporter. This will require a well-trained labor force which is also available to nascent
ventures that aim to grow into globally competitive firms. A healthy entrepreneurial
ecosystem will be an asset and interventions to strengthen technology absorption and
informal finance for more mundane and slow-growing industrial SMEs and start-ups
will be beneficial.
Taking these prescriptions to our menu of policy interventions and reform pro-
posals in Part I of this report, we can select the fifteen most suitable interventions.
They are listed in Table 8.5. In Column 1, we find the number under which they are
presented in Elert et al. (2019). Column 2 lists the policy area and 3 the full pro-
posal, where Column 4 gives a brief motivation that links the proposal to the specific
situation in the UK and the analysis presented above.
The first two proposals (2 and 4) refer to intellectual property rights and call for
the UK to experiment and negotiate for less stringent and encompassing IPR. This
may sound counterintuitive and goes against the mainstream thinking that strong IPR
promotes innovation and growth by providing incentives to generate knowledge. In
stakeholder dialogues and discussions, as well as academic research, however, that
conventional wisdom is often turned on its head. Complex legal protection of IPR
serves the interest of large incumbent corporates, who use IPR to maximize their prof-
its. This rarely involves maximizing the generation and diffusion of new knowledge
and technology through commercialization. The British experience in the industrial
revolution, when IPR enforcement was expensive and scant, is a case in point. The
reforms we propose would aim to restore IPR to its original purpose: Give credit to
the inventor, while promoting further incremental innovation and commercialization
by entrepreneurs. By opening up IPR, the UK would create opportunities for less
sophisticated entrepreneurs to compete at the global frontier.
8 A Reform Strategy for the UK 231
Proposal 13 aims to increase the levels of informal investment in the UK. Allow-
ing wealth to accumulate should not be understood as an across the board reduc-
tion in wealth or property taxes. Indeed, if our diagnosis calls for a more inclusive
entrepreneurial ecosystem, such a proposal would be strange indeed. We should
therefore add that this proposal is to be interpreted as interventions in the taxation of
wealth that will promote the accumulation of small private fortunes to be invested
in small, everyday entrepreneurial ventures, through good old personal networks,
and modern crowd-based equity and lending platforms. Proposal 18 adds the credit
information that banks typically consider proprietary. By disclosing that information
at least for the publicly guaranteed loans, also the refused ones, private investors that
can take on more risk can pick up on these opportunities to invest.
Proposals 19 and 20 also aim to have free up the banks’ balance sheets for more
risky financing of entrepreneurial and SME venturing. The role of banks in early-stage
entrepreneurial finance is typically absent, but bank credit in the form of personal
loans is an important source of finance for start-ups. Both new ventures in their
growth stage as well as established SMEs would benefit from a banking sector that
can take on more risk and banks on relationships rather than solid collateral and track
records. To allow banks to take that traditional intermediation role (again), they need
to finance their balance sheet with more equity (have more “skin in the game”) and
the savings and transaction money of ordinary people should not be at risk sitting
as a liability in the form of deposits on their balance sheets. This implies that bank
credit will become more expensive, but importantly, more risk tolerant.
Proposals 37, 38, and 40 are very much aligned with the above in strengthening
the infrastructure on which platform-based financial (and other) services operate
and creating central and publicly funded “observatories” that collect, curate, and
disclose relevant and reliable information on entrepreneurial venturing and ventures,
for entrepreneurs but also for (less sophisticated) investors.
Proposals 26, 31, 41, and 44 are directly aimed to promote the flow of talent
into entrepreneurial venturing, specifically in the form of a well-trained and creative
workforce. Proposal 26 creates a level playing field for small, risky ventures as
employers while proposal 31 intends to make Britain’s workers more resilient in the
face of faster changing jobs and labor markets. Employability in a modern economy
depends to a large extent on the ability to learn not just knowledge that was acquired
in school. Therefore, proposal 41 aims to instill creativity and experimentation in
primary and secondary education (with the required tolerance for failure), whereas
proposal 44 continues this line in higher education in support of entrepreneurial
behavior and venturing.
Proposals 48 and 50 then aim to also keep that spirit alive on the work floor, where
the former should be interpreted in the UK context as a way to incentivize small
businesses to also retain and train their employees, strengthening the accumulation
and maintenance of human capital throughout the average British career, while the
latter translates into the government giving direction to innovation, without exerting
direct control.
The intentions of these proposals, individually and in combination, are to make
British entrepreneurs and SMEs more inclined to hire workers and also train them on
8 A Reform Strategy for the UK 237
the job and maintain their skills. One may conclude that the proposals are insufficient
to create the powerful incentives to invest in on the job training that exist in CMEs,
but at least these proposals take us in the right direction and are consistent with the
historically evolved institutional framework of the UK. Reforms in education aim
to make workers more entrepreneurial while increasing their skills and flexibility,
whereas reforms in the financial system and tax code aim to allow for more private
wealth to accumulate and flow to the SMEs and start-ups that VC and angel investors
have shunned. The interventions proposed do not limit the mobility of resources
in the UK but will help to strengthen regional entrepreneurial ecosystems. Private
wealth and informal investment, as well as training on the job in small- and medium-
sized manufacturing firms, tend to strengthen local and regional ecosystems, without
risking leakage of resources to the center. London, meanwhile, can attract resources
from all around the world and still thrive as the entrepreneurial hotspot of the UK.
It is possible that, even though all regions stand to benefit from such interven-
tions, the fact that density and clustering tend to promote the quality and impact of
entrepreneurial venturing, will imply that the same policy improvements will benefit
London most. Still, that should not stop policy makers from pursuing these inter-
ventions. It is the UK citizens, not its administrative units per se, that the national
government should care about. In addition, the UK has effective automatic transfer
systems in social security and the National Health Service that will help maintain
a high quality of life throughout the country, even if the available entrepreneurial
resources end up being deployed only in parts of the territory.
As a final point, it should also be stressed that policy makers should ensure that
regulation is long-term oriented and does not change frequently, as this will deter
entrepreneurial activities and makes it hard to plan for the future. Information about
the requirements to create ventures could also be made more easily accessible for
potential entrepreneurs and, if possible, of better quality.
Of course, these proposals will need a much more detailed discussion and form the
starting point, not the final word on the policy debate. In this, we join the debate the
LSE Growth Committee’s 2017 report has sparked in UK policy circles. By focusing
on strengthening economic resilience, we believe our interventions’ success depends
a lot less on uncertain political and technological processes the UK cannot hope to
control. Based on our analysis of the situation, we propose the UK considers this set
of interventions to improve and maintain the health of its entrepreneurial ecosystem.
That will be a key asset for the UK, whatever the circumstances.
To put our proposed reform program in its proper context, it is important to discuss the
diagnosis and proposed treatments with experts in the field. In this case that is British
238 M. Sanders et al.
policy makers that are active in the field. Given the wide diversity of policy areas
involved, it is furthermore important to not only discuss this with policy makers that
are active in “entrepreneurship policy” in a narrow sense. Our approach emphasizes
the importance of reforming institutions that determine the allocation of financial,
labor, and knowledge resources to entrepreneurial activity in the broadest and most
inclusive sense of the word. Entrepreneurship policy in the narrow sense has been
around for some three decades or more and to date has achieved only limited success.
Because of its breadth, our reform agenda inevitably cuts across many policy
areas, traditionally less associated with entrepreneurship policy, including wealth
taxation, financial and labor market regulation, social security, and science policy.
As the institutions in these areas have evolved historically and policy makers in
these areas pursue different, equally relevant public policy priorities, the challenge
is to discuss the proposed agenda in sufficient depth but with a sufficiently diverse
group of policy makers and practitioners. Policies and institutions in these different
areas overlap and interact in ways that affect the quality and performance of the
entrepreneurial ecosystem (Stam 2015, 2018). The challenge is to not only propose
policies and reforms that will strengthen the ecosystem, but to do it in such a way
that other important policy priorities are also achieved.
In order to receive the first round of feedback on the proposals for the UK presented
in Table 8.5, a policy roundtable was held at the London School of Economics on
April 26, 2018. Participants included senior policy makers, consultants, and political
advisors as well as entrepreneurs and suppliers of financial capital. This step can
be seen as an attempt to allow our patient, or perhaps more accurately, her team of
medical specialists, intimately familiar with our patient, to give feedback about our
diagnosis and proposed treatments. What proposals does this team endorse, question
or maybe even want to drop?
The participants agreed that a more proactive government policy making along
the lines of the FIRES-report might be worthwhile considering carefully. However,
policies to reduce failure and accelerate scale-up were proposed as important policies
to generate more entrepreneurship, which some of the participants argued should be
the main focus of the FIRES proposals. The participants also suggested that the notion
of entrepreneurship itself and the meaning of the term was ambiguous, covering a
variety of activities from forming major new companies to providing work for the
socially excluded. It was important to link the policy proposals to the specific form
of entrepreneurship under consideration.
The participants then discussed the proposals on experimenting with or abandon-
ing IP protection laws. IP and patents are one of the few tangible components of an
entrepreneurial project upon which investors can make evaluations. It was suggested
that one could either increase renewal fees of patents or open IP systems to radical
change toward “open source.” This system would then mirror that of, for example,
the culinary industry.
Some major UK issues such as immigration, human capital, and digitalization
were pointed out as having not been sufficiently addressed in the study. The partici-
pants pointed to the importance of developing a dynamic entrepreneurial environment
with a much more inclusive venture capital investment approach.
8 A Reform Strategy for the UK 239
The participants furthermore expressed deep concern about the geographical con-
centration of entrepreneurial activity in UK, as discussed in the FIRES-report. There
is a visible centralization of the entrepreneurial resources in London which only
attracts a narrow demography and a lack of incentives for people to stay or go back
home to the countryside.
As a final point, the need for developing a benchmark that enables this study to
better evaluate the findings by comparing it to what is happening in the rest of the
world was stressed.
8.6 Conclusions
regions in the UK. All regions stand to benefit from these interventions. But by
strengthening informal investment and the skills and resilience of low wage workers,
while fostering a more entrepreneurial spirit throughout, it is likely that all regions—
even peripheral—will benefit. Of course, these proposals will need a much more
detailed discussion and only form the starting point, not the final word in the pol-
icy debate. Moreover, even if eventually adopted, our proposals all require careful
implementation and evaluation to complete the policy cycle.
References
Cranfield D, Taylor J (2008) Knowledge management and higher education: case study. Electron J
Knowl Manag 6(2):85–100
Choi WK (2010) Capitalism, unfree labor and colonial doxa: the master and servant act from Britain
to Hong Kong, 1823–1932. J Hist Sociol 23(2):284–315
Clarke T (2001) The knowledge economy. Education+Training 43(4/5):189–196
Clegg HA, Fox A, Thompson AF (1985) A history of British trade unions since 1889: 1911–1933.
Oxford University Press, Oxford
Collins M (2012) Money and banking: a history. Routledge, London
Cowling M, Mitchell P (1997) The self-employment: a study of government policy and the role of
the macroeconomy. Manchester Sch 65(4):427–442
Craig R (2007) The history of employment law in England and Northern Ireland. Business Law,
8th edn. Cengage Learning. Retrieved from: http://cws.cengage.co.uk/abbott8/students/ni_supp/
employ_law/hist_of_employ_law.pdf on 14-04-2018
Curthoys M (2004) Governments, labour, and the law in mid-Victorian Britain: the trade union
legislation of the 1870s. Oxford Historical Monographs. Clarendon Press, Oxford
Davies H (2002) A review of enterprise and the economy in education. HM Treasury, London.
Retrieved from: http://www.readyunlimited.com/wp-content/uploads/2011/09/Davies-Review-
main-doc.pdf on 7-04-2018
Degryse C (2016) Digitalisation of the economy and its impact on labour markets. ETUI Research
Paper—Working Paper 2016.02. Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2730550 or http://
dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn
Dilli S, Elert N, Herrmann AM (2018) Varieties of entrepreneurship. Exploring the institutional
foundations of different entrepreneurship types through ‘Varieties-of-Capitalism’ arguments.
Special issue on “Financial and institutional reforms for an entrepreneurial society.” Small Bus
Econ 51(2):293–320
Dutton HI (1984) The patent system and inventive activity during the industrial revolution, 1750–
1852. Manchester University Press, Dover, NH
EC (1995) Green paper on innovation. European Commission. Retrieved from: http://europa.eu/
documents/comm/green_papers/pdf/com95_688_en.pdf on 14-04-2018
Elert N, Henrekson M, Sanders M (2019) The entrepreneurial society: a reform strategy for the
European Union. Springer, Berlin
Estrin S, Gozman D, Khavul S (2018) The evolution and adoption of equity crowdfunding:
entrepreneur and investor entry into a new market. Small Bus Econ 51(2):425–439
Feld F (2011) The welfare state—Never ending reform. BBC History. Retrieved from: http://www.
bbc.co.uk/history/british/modern/field_01.shtml on 14-04-2018
Ferguson N (2009) The ascent of money: a financial history of the world. Penguin, New York
Ferrari R (2016) FinTech impact on retail banking–From a universal banking model to banking ver-
ticalization. In: Chishti S, Barberis J (eds) The FinTech book: the financial technology handbook
for investors, entrepreneurs and visionaries. Wiley, Chichester, pp 248–252
Goos M, Manning A, Salomons A (2009) Job polarization in Europe. Am Econ Rev 99(2):58–63
Goos M, Manning A, Salomons A (2014) Explaining job polarization: routine-biased technological
change and offshoring. Am Econ Rev 104(8):2509–2526
Green F, Felstead A, Gallie D, Henseke G (2016) Skills and work organisation in Britain: a quarter
century of change. J Labour Market Res 49(2):121–132
Hall PA, Soskice D (2001) Varieties of capitalism: the institutional foundations of comparative
advantage. Oxford University Press, Oxford
Han L, Benson A, Chen JJ, Zhang S (2012) The use and impacts of bank support on UK small and
medium-sized enterprises. Int Small Bus J 32(1):61–80
Hannon PD (2005) Philosophies of enterprise and entrepreneurship education and challenges for
higher education in the UK. Int J Entrepreneurship Innov 6(2):105–114
Hay C (2010) Chronicles of a death foretold: the winter of discontent and construction of the crisis
of British Keynesianism. Parliamentary Aff 63(3):446–470
242 M. Sanders et al.
Held L (2019) Part-time entrepreneurship: the role of institutions, venture and individual character-
istics in entry and transition choices. In: Held L (ed) Unravelling the patterns in venture creation
processes. Ph.D. thesis. Utrecht University, Utrecht, pp 25–55
Held L, Herrmann AM, Polzin F (2018a) Follow the money: the funding acquisition process
of nascent ventures. Horizon 2020 Project on “Financial and Institutional Reforms for an
Entrepreneurial Society” (FIRES), Workpackage 5, Deliverable 5.1; currently under review. Also
available in Held L (2019) Unravelling the patterns in venture creation processes. Ph.D. thesis.
Utrecht University, Utrecht, pp 91–122
Held L, Herrmann AM, Storz C (2018b) Whom do nascent ventures search for? Variance of link-
age formation activities during new product development processes. Horizon 2020 Project on
“Financial and Institutional Reforms for an Entrepreneurial Society” (FIRES), Workpackage 5,
Deliverable 5.1; currently under review. Also available in Held L (2019) Unravelling the patterns
in venture creation processes. Ph.D. thesis. Utrecht University, Utrecht, pp 123–150
Henkel M, Kogan M (1993) Research training and graduate education. The British macro structure.
In: Clark BR (ed) The research foundations of graduate education: Germany, Britain, France,
United States, Japan. University of California Press, Berkeley, CA, pp 71–114
Hepple B (2002) Social and labour rights in a global context: international and comparative
perspectives. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge
Hepple B, Morris GS (2002) The employment act 2002 and the crisis of individual employment
rights. Ind Law J 31(3):245–269
Herrmann AM (2019) A plea for varieties of entrepreneurship. Special Issue on “Entrepreneurship
in context.” Small Bus Econ 52(2):331–343
Herrmann AM (2020) On the institutional foundations of the varieties of entrepreneurship in Europe.
In: Sanders M, Marx A, Stenkula M (eds) The entrepreneurial society. Reform strategies for Italy,
Germany and the UK. Springer, Berlin
Heyck TW (2012) The idea of a university in Britain, 1870–1970. Hist Eur Ideas 8(2):205–219
Hijzen A, Upward R, Wright PW (2010) Job creation, job destruction and the role of small firms:
firm-level evidence for the UK. Oxford Bull Econ Stat 72(5):621–647
HM Treasury (2003) Lambert review of business-university collaboration. HM Treasury, London
HM Treasury (2006) Leitch review of skills. Prosperity for all in the global economy—World class
skills. HM Treasury, London
HM Treasury (2009) HM treasury annual innovation report. HM Treasury, London
HM Treasury (2010) HM treasury annual innovation report and accounts. HM Treasury, London
HMSO (1971) Report on committee of enquiry on small firms (Bolton Report), Cmnd 4811. HMSO,
London
HMSO (1979) Interim report on financing of small firms (Wilson Report), Cmnd 7503. HMSO,
London
Huggins R, Williams N (2009) Enterprise and public policy: a review of labour government
intervention in the United Kingdom. Environ Plan C Polit Space 27(1):19–41
Intellectual Property Office (2014a) History of patents: the 18th century. Retrieved from: http://
www.ipo.gov.uk/types/patent/p-about/p-whatis/p-history/p-history-18century.htm
Intellectual Property Office (2014b) History of patents: the 20th century. Retrieved from: http://
webarchive.nationalarchives.gov.uk/20140603131909/ on 14-04-2018
Jones H (2018) Funding for lending scheme: how does it work? Express. Retrieved
from: https://www.express.co.uk/finance/personalfinance/911166/funding-for-lending-scheme-
bank-of-england on 9-04-2018
Kahn-Freund O (1944) The illegality of a trade union. Modern Law Rev 7(40):192–205
Leendertse J (2017) Entrepreneurship in the UK’s renewable energy industry. Background paper
for FIRES WP5, mimeo
Lewchuk WA (1984) The role of the British government in the spread of scientific management
and fordism in the interwar years. J Econ Hist 44(20):355–361
Lin MJJ, Hung SW, Chen CJ (2009) Fostering the determinants of knowledge sharing in professional
virtual communities. Comput Hum Behav 25(4):929–939
8 A Reform Strategy for the UK 243
Lloyds Banking Group (n.d.) Our heritage. Timeline. 1695–1800. Retrieved from: http://www.
lloydsbankinggroup.com/Our-Group/our-heritage/timeline/1695-1800/ on 14-04-2018
LSE Growth Commission (2017) LSE growth commission report 2017. Retrieved from: http://www.
lse.ac.uk/researchAndExpertise/units/growthCommission/documents/pdf/2017LSEGCReport.
pdf on 14-04-2018
Machin S, Vignoles A (2018) What’s the good of education? The economics of education in the
UK. Princeton University Press, Princeton
Machlup F, Penrose E (1950) The patent controversy in the nineteenth century. J Econ Hist 10(1):1–
29
Mackenzie A (2015) The fintech revolution. London Bus Sch Rev 26(3):50–53
MacLeod C (1988) Inventing the industrial revolution: the English patent system, 1660–1800.
Cambridge University Press, Cambridge
MacLeod C, Nuvolari A (2006) Inventive activities, patents and early industrialization. A synthesis
of research issues. DRUID Working Paper No. 06-28
Mason C (2009) Public policy support for the informal venture capital market in Europe: a critical
review. Int Small Bus J 27(5):536–556
Mason C, Harrison R (1989) Informal venture capital. In: Storey DJ (ed) Small business: critical
perspectives on business and management. Taylor and Francis, New York
Mason C, Jones L, Wells S in collaboration with URS Corp (2010) The city’s role in providing for
the public equity financing SMEs. City of London, London
Merlin-Jones D (2010) The industrial and commercial finance corporation: lessons from the past
for the future. Civitas. Retrieved from: http://www.civitas.org.uk/.pdf on 14-04-2018
Mokyr J (2005) Long-term economic growth and the history of technology. In: Aghion P, Durlauf
S (eds) Handbook of economic growth, vol 1. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 1113–1180
Mollick E, Robb A (2016) Democratizing innovation and capital access: the role of crowdfunding.
Calif Manag Rev 58(2):72–87
Morris D, Collier T, Wood G (2005) Effects of minimum wage legislation: some evidence from
small enterprises. Int Small Bus J 23(2):191–209
Moser C (1988) The Robbins report 25 years after—and the future of the Universities. Oxford Rev
Educ 14(1):5–20. Retrieved from: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1050360 on 14-04-2018
Mueller P, van Stel A, Storey DJ (2008) The effects of new firm formation on regional development
over time: the case of Great Britain. Small Bus Econ 30(1):59–71
NAO (2014) Business perceptions survey. Retrieved from https://www.nao.org.uk/report/business-
perceptions-survey-2014/ on 16-04-2018
NESTA (2008) History matters: unlocking innovation in British cities and regions. Policy briefing
HM/26. Retrieved from: https://www.nesta.org.uk/sites/default/files/history_matters.pdf on 14-
04-2018
Newton L, Cottrell PL (1998) Joint-stock banking in the English provinces 1826–1857: to branch
or not to branch? Bus Econ Hist 27(1):115–128
NHS (n.d.) The history of the NHS in England. Retrieved from: https://www.nhs.uk/NHSEngland/
thenhs/nhshistory/Pages/NHShistory1948.aspx on 14-04-2018
Nicholas T (2014) Technology, innovation and economic growth in Britain since 1870. In: Floud R,
Humphries J, Johnson P (eds) The Cambridge economic history of modern Britain. Cambridge
University Press, Cambridge, pp 181–204
OECD (2015) OECD reviews of vocational education and training key messages and country
summaries. OECD, Paris. Retrieved from: http://www.oecd.org/education/skills-beyond-school/
OECD_VET_Key_Messages_and_Country_Summaries_2015.pdf on 14-10-2019
OECD (2019) Average wages. OECD, Paris. Retrieved from: https://data.oecd.org/earnwage/
average-wages.htm#indicator-chart on 14-10-2019
Parkinson M, Champion T, Evans R, Simmie J, et al. (2006) State of the English cities. A research
study. Office of the Deputy Prime Minister, London. Retrieved from: http://image.guardian.co.
uk/sys-files/Politics/documents/2006/03/07/StateoftheEnglishCitiespart1.pdf on 14-10-2019
244 M. Sanders et al.
Pike R (2017) How will the market adapt to the end of funding for lending? Mortgage
solutions. Retrieved from: http://www.mortgagesolutions.co.uk/better-business/2017/08/08/will-
market-adapt-end-funding-lending/ on 9-04-2018
Piketty T (2014) Capitalism in the 21st Century. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA
Potter J, Moore B (2000) UK enterprise zones and the attraction of inward investment. Urban Stud
37(8):1279–1312
Pratt J (1997) The polytechnic experiment: 1965–1992. SRHE and Open University Press,
Buckingham. Retrieved from: https://eric.ed.gov/?id=ED415724 on 14-04-2018
Richardson HW (2011) Regional development agencies in England. In: Richardson HW, Bae CHC,
Choe SC (eds) Reshaping regional policy. Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham
Robinson E (1972) James Watt and the law of patents. Technol Cult 13(2):115–139
Rothwell R (1985) Venture finance, small firms and public policy. Res Policy 14(5):253–265
Rusly FH, Talib YYA, Salleh D (2017) The impact of minimum pay implementation on small busi-
nesses operating cost and sustainability: a case of service business. In: SHS web of conferences,
vol 34. EDP Sciences, Les Ulis
Sanders M, Stenkula M, Grilli L, Herrmann A, Latifi G, Pager B, Szerb L, Terragno BE (2020a) A
reform strategy for Italy. In: Sanders M, Marx A, Stenkula M (eds) The entrepreneurial society.
Reform strategies for Italy, Germany and the UK. Springer, Berlin
Sanders M, Stenkula M, Fritsch M, Herrmann A, Latifi G, Pager B, Szerb L, Terragno BE, Wyrwich
M (2020b) A reform strategy for Germany. In: Sanders M, Marx A, Stenkula M (eds) The
entrepreneurial society. Reform strategies for Italy, Germany and the UK. Springer, Berlin
Schumpeter J (1911) The theory of economic development. Harvard University Press, Cambridge,
MA
Schwanen D, Wyonch R (2018) Canada’s innovation report card. C.D. Howe Institute e-Brief
273. Retrieved from: https://www.cdhowe.org/public-policy-research/canadas-2018-innovation-
policy-report-card on 16-04-2018
Scott P (2014a) The reform of English higher education: universities in global, national and regional
contexts. Cambridge J Reg, Econ Soc 7(2):217–231
Scott P (2014b) Robbins, the binary policy and mass higher education. High Educ Q 68(2):147–163
Shawl WF (1954) The repeal of the Combination acts 1824–1825. Graduate Student theses,
Dissertations, & Professional Papers. University of Montana
Spicker P (2014) Social policy: theory and practice. Policy Press, Bristol
Stam E (2015) Entrepreneurial ecosystems and regional policy: a sympathetic critique. Eur Plan
Stud 23(9):1759–1769
Stam E (2018) Measuring entrepreneurial ecosystems. In: O’Connor A, Stam E, Sussan F, Audretsch
DB (eds) Entrepreneurial ecosystems. Springer, Cham, pp 173–197
Storey DJ, Tether B (1998) Public policy measures to support new technology-based firms in the
European Union. Res Policy 26(9):1037–1057
Szerb L, Lafuente E, Horváth K, Páger B (2019) The relevance of quantity and quality entrepreneur-
ship for regional performance: the moderating role of the entrepreneurial ecosystem. Reg Stud
53(9):1308–1320. https://doi.org/10.1080/00343404.2018.1510481
Szerb L, Vörös Z, Komlósi É, Acs ZJ, Páger B, Rappai G (2017) The regional entrepreneur-
ship and development index: structure, data, methodology and policy applications. Fires
Report D4.4. Retrived from http://www.projectfires.eu/wp-content/uploads/2018/07/d4.4-the-
regional-entrepreneurship-and-development-index_-structure-data-methodology-and-policy-
applications.pdf
Tate J (2001) National varieties of standardization. In: Hall PA, Soskice D (eds) Varieties of
capitalism. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 442–473
Taylor J (2003) Institutional higher education: policy and outcomes since the end of the binary
divide. High Educ Q 57(3):266–293
Teubner G (2001) Legal irritants: how unifying law ends up in new divergences. In: Hall PA, Soskice
DW (eds) Varieties of capitalism—the institutional foundations of comparative advantage. Oxford
University Press, Oxford, pp 417–441
8 A Reform Strategy for the UK 245
Thirkell PC, Dau R (1998) Export performance: success determinants for New Zealand manufac-
turing exporters. Eur J Mark 32(9/10):813–829
Towers B (1989) Running the gauntlet: British trade unions under Thatcher, 1979–1988. Ind Labor
Relat Rev 42(2):163–188
UK Government (n.d.) University Enterprise Zones. Retrieved from: https://www.gov.uk/
government/publications/university-enterprise-zones/university-enterprise-zones on 7-04-2018
UK Government (2000) Financial services and markets act 2000. Retrieved from: https://www.
legislation.gov.uk/ukpga/2000/8/pdfs/ukpga_20000008_en.pdf on 8-04-2018
UK Government (2015) 2010 to 2015 government policy: business enterprise. Retrieved
from: https://www.gov.uk/government/publications/2010-to-2015-government-policy-business-
enterprise/2010-to-2015-government-policy-business-enterprise#appendix-2-encouraging-
private-sector-investment on 4-04-2018
University of Cambridge (n.d.) About the university. Early records. Retrieved from: https://www.
cam.ac.uk/about-the-university/history/early-records on 14-04-2018
University of Edinburgh (n.d.) About. Our history. Retrieved from:https://www.ed.ac.uk/about/our-
history on 14-04-2018
University of London (n.d.) History of University of London. Retrieved from: https://london.ac.uk/
about-us/history-university-london on 14-04-2018
University of Oxford (n.d.) Introduction and history. Retrieved from: https://www.ox.ac.uk/about/
organisation/history?wssl=1 on 14-04-2018
Van Bavel B (2016) The invisible hand? How market economies have emerged and declined since
AD 500. Oxford University Press, Oxford
Varga A, Szerb L, SebestyénT, Szabó N (2020) Economic impact assessment of entrepreneur-
ship policies with the GMR-Europe model. In: Sanders M, Marx A, Stenkula M (eds) The
entrepreneurial society. Reform Strategies for Italy, Germany and the UK. Springer, Berlin
Walters A (2005) Personal insolvency law after the enterprise act – An appraisal. J Corp Law Stud
5(1):65–104
White LH (1992) Competition and currency: essays on free banking and money. NYU Press, New
York
Whiteside N (2014) The Beveridge report and its implementation: a revolutionary project?
Retrieved from: https://www.researchgate.net/publication/286702415_The_Beveridge_Report_
and_Its_Implementation_a_Revolutionary_Project on 14-04-2018
Wilson T (2012) A review of business–university collaboration. HM Government, London.
Retrieved from: http://dera.ioe.ac.uk/13842/1/wilson.pdf on 14-04-2018
Wilson W (1997) Student grants, loans and tuition fees. House of Commons Library Research Paper
No 97/119
Wiltbank (2009) Siding with the angels: business angel investing—promising outcomes and
effective strategies. Research report published by NESTA & BBAA
Wooden M, Sloan J (1998) Industrial relations reform and labour market outcomes: a comparison
of Australia, New Zealand and the United Kingdom. Retrieved from: https://www.rba.gov.au/
publications/confs/1998/pdf/wooden-sloan.pdf on 14-04-2018
Woods DC (1982) The operation of the master and servants act in the black country, 1858–1875.
Midland Hist 7(1):93–115
Woodward D (1980) The Background to the statute of artificers: the genesis of labour policy,
1558–63. Econ Hist Rev New Ser 33(1):32–44
World Bank (2018) Doing business report. Retrieved from: http://www.doingbusiness.org/~/media/
WBG/DoingBusiness/Documents/Annual-Reports/English/DB2018-Full-Report.pdf on 7-04-
2018
WIPO (n.d.a) An explanatory note concerning the origins of the United Kingdom intellectual
property legal regime. Retrieved from: http://www.wipo.int/export/sites/www/wipolex/en/notes/
gb.pdf
WIPO (n.d.b) United Kingdom country profile. Retrieved from: http://www.wipo.int/wipolex/en/
details.jsp?id=1623 on 14-04-2018
246 M. Sanders et al.
Open Access This chapter is licensed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0
International License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits use, sharing,
adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate
credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license and
indicate if changes were made.
The images or other third party material in this chapter are included in the chapter’s Creative
Commons license, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not
included in the chapter’s Creative Commons license and your intended use is not permitted by
statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from
the copyright holder.
Chapter 9
What We Have Learned and How We
May Proceed
Abstract In this chapter, the editors conclude this volume and draw the most
important lessons that can be drawn from the FIRES project. The editors highlight
theoretical lessons, methodological innovations, and policy implications.
This book marks the conclusion of the project “Financial and Institutional Reforms
for the Entrepreneurial Society” (FIRES)—a European Union project launched in
2015 as part of the Horizon 2020 program to restore Europe’s ability to innovate,
grow, and create jobs over the coming decades. By 2015, the mood in Europe was
gloomy. The global financial and ensuing Euro crisis had put severe strains on Euro-
pean solidarity and weakened especially the southern Member States. The ambitious
Lisbon Agenda to make Europe the world’s most innovative continent by 2010 failed
to deliver on its promises. The Brexit vote, the Syrian refugee crisis, the backsliding
rule of law and rise of populist movements in several European Member States and
now the Corona pandemic have strengthened the need for the European Union to
reinvent itself and return Europe on the path to inclusive, sustainable, and innovative
growth. We therefore believe that since its start, the FIRES project has only gained
in importance and urgency.
In the project, we identified the entrepreneurial society as the way forward. The
entrepreneurial society is an open society in which ideas can compete on a level
playing field and challenge the status quo. First described by Schumpeter (1911),
an entrepreneurial society offers opportunity to all and organizes society to support
productive entrepreneurship that will generate innovation, jobs, and growth while
M. Sanders (B)
Utrecht School of Economics, Utrecht University, Utrecht, The Netherlands
e-mail: m.w.j.l.sanders@uu.nl
A. Marx
Leuven Centre for Global Governance Studies, University of Leuven, Leuven, Belgium
e-mail: axel.marx@kuleuven.be
M. Stenkula
Research Institute of Industrial Economics, Stockholm, Sweden
e-mail: mikael.stenkula@ifn.se
© The Author(s) 2020 247
M. Sanders et al. (eds.), The Entrepreneurial Society, International Studies
in Entrepreneurship 44, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-662-61007-7_9
248 M. Sanders et al.
solving the many social and ecological challenges that Europe faces. The Euro-
pean Union (EU) can only (re)assert its place on the global technology frontier by
channeling more of its resources and talent to the small scale, innovative, and, there-
fore, also risky ventures that develop and test solutions for tomorrow, in business
and beyond. In an entrepreneurial society, the institutions are such that produc-
tive entrepreneurial experimentation is both made possible and encouraged. In our
project, we propose seven steps to design, implement, and evaluate reforms that help
develop the entrepreneurial society across Europe.
In the companion volume to this book (Elert et al. 2019), our project identi-
fied 50 proposals for reform in six key areas of policymaking that would support
the mobilization and allocation of human, financial, and knowledge resources for
entrepreneurial activity. In this volume we explicitly recognize the diversity of insti-
tutional arrangements in the EU as well as the multi-level nature of EU policy-
making. An entrepreneurial growth and innovation strategy for the EU cannot be a
“one-size-fits-all” basket of proposals.
To identify the appropriate set of interventions in a given context, careful analysis
is required. Hence, this volume highlighted the diverse and historically deeply rooted
institutional foundations of EU Member States and introduced the tools we devel-
oped for analyzing the entrepreneurial ecosystem before turning to reforms. It has
also introduced a policy analysis of how and at which levels of governance an effec-
tive reform strategy must be formulated in the context of European policymaking.
Developing these tools required a broad, multidisciplinary approach. The project,
including this book, has included thoughts and ideas of scholars from a range of dif-
ferent fields such as history, economics, geography, management, political science
and law.
As the proof of the pudding is in the eating, we then illustrate the practical use-
fulness of our approach by analyzing Italy, Germany, and the UK in depth and
formulate a reform strategy for these countries using our seven-step approach. These
three countries were chosen to broadly represent Europe’s institutional families.1
We draw some important lessons from this exercise. The first is theoretical:
building on the work of Schumpeter (1911), Baumol (1990), and Audretsch and
Thurik (2000, 2001), our project has confirmed that institutions enable or inhibit
the allocation of resources to the challengers of the status quo that drive productive
entrepreneurial venturing. Therefore, to build an entrepreneurial economy and soci-
ety, institutional reforms are required. Our application of historical analysis, however,
has shown that, due to strong path- and interdependencies, not all institutions are so
easily reformed. Echoing the work of Williamson (2000) and new institutional eco-
nomics, we recognize that some institutions are more deeply embedded than others.
Moreover, it is the way institutions actually operate, not how they appear in law or
data, that matters. Consequently, it is the functions that institutions perform, rather
than the specific shape they take in any given context, that should be the focus of
efforts to reform.
1 Inthe Varieties of Capitalism (VoC) terminology they represent European examples of a mixed
(or Mediterranean) market system, a coordinated market and a liberal market, respectively.
9 What We Have Learned and How We May Proceed 249
To make this more concrete, we can look at the example of universities. Based
on cross-sectional and panel data evidence, many have concluded that the pres-
ence of a university promotes knowledge-intensive entrepreneurial venturing in its
direct surroundings. The university campus serves as a hotbed for entrepreneur-
ship. But university knowledge can spill over to economic activity through produc-
tive entrepreneurship in many shapes and forms. The most obvious is perhaps the
campus-based university spinoff through a USA-style tech transfer office on a land-
grant college that was indeed founded with a mission to disseminate knowledge to
business. But that is as much a manifestation of USA history as it is a measure of
knowledge spillovers. In a different, say German or Italian context, where univer-
sities have traditionally fought to minimize or exclude outside influences (e.g., the
Church and the State) in research and curriculum, the same spillover may take the
form of educated graduates joining an off-campus research institute and developing
new ideas in close collaboration with incumbent firms. Given the deep-rooted insti-
tutional context of the German university, perhaps the reform should aim to facilitate
the flow of knowledge from universities to firms via the channels that already exist,
rather than setting up a tech transfer office and copying the USA Bayh–Dole Act in
a context where the institutional framework simply does not support it.
These theoretical lessons have implications for the methods that should be applied
in analyzing the need, scope, and opportunities for institutional reform in any specific
country, region, or locality. As much as can be learned from comparing uniformly
defined indicators and their impacts across regions and countries, doing so implicitly
assumes that the same observed variables reflect the same underlying mechanisms
across regions with potentially very different institutional contexts. Methodologi-
cally, we therefore stress the need to triangulate methods. It is a good start, but
not enough to compare regions on a set of well-defined variables to identify their
weaknesses, strengths, and bottlenecks. Such analyses need to be complemented
with careful historical analysis to understand the specifics of the local, regional, and
national institutional contexts as well as survey-based and qualitative information on
how local entrepreneurial ecosystems function and how they could be improved.
These methodological innovations also have important policy implications. There
are many ways in which an ecosystem can channel resources to (or away from)
productive entrepreneurs. And there are many, potentially highly relevant, comple-
mentarities among these institutions. Proposing a one-size-fit-all reform strategy to
promote the European entrepreneurial society is then beside the point. Bavaria cannot
be(come) Silicon Valley or London, nor should it want to. Instead, the focus should
be on promoting access to resources for challengers of the status quo in all of these
specific institutional contexts.
The lack of a clear and unambiguous policy prescription also implies that policy-
makers have to make some tough choices, as there are inevitable tensions between
the various approaches. First there is the tension between universalist and particu-
larist analysis. The Varieties of Capitalism (VoC) and historical analysis approach in
Chaps. 2 and 4 clearly stress that every constellation of institutions is unique, whereas
the Regional Entrepreneurship and Development Index (REDI) and Geographic,
Macro, and Regional (GMR) modeling approaches of Chap. 3 rely on uniformly
250 M. Sanders et al.
References
Audretsch DB, Thurik AR (2000) Capitalism and democracy in the 21st century: from the managed
to the entrepreneurial economy. J Evol Econ 10(1–2):17–34
Audretsch DB, Thurik AR (2001) What’s new about the new economy? Sources of growth in the
managed and entrepreneurial economies. Ind Corp Change 10(1):267–315
Baumol W (1990) Entrepreneurship: productive, unproductive and destructive. J Polit Econ
98(5):893–921
Elert N, Henrekson M, Sanders M (2019) The entrepreneurial society: a reform strategy for the
European Union. Springer, Berlin
O’Connor A, Stam E, Sussan F, Audretsch DB (2018) Entrepreneurial ecosystems. Springer, Berlin
Schumpeter J (1911) The theory of economic development. Cambridge University Press, Cam-
bridge, MA
Stam E (2015) Entrepreneurial ecosystems and regional policy: a sympathetic critique. Eur Plan
Stud 23(9):1759–1769
Williamson OE (2000) The new institutional economics: taking stock, looking ahead. J Econ Lit
38(3):595–613
252 M. Sanders et al.
Open Access This chapter is licensed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0
International License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits use, sharing,
adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate
credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license and
indicate if changes were made.
The images or other third party material in this chapter are included in the chapter’s Creative
Commons license, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not
included in the chapter’s Creative Commons license and your intended use is not permitted by
statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from
the copyright holder.