Acemoglu Autor Chapter 1
Acemoglu Autor Chapter 1
Acemoglu Autor Chapter 1
5
of knowledge or skills, h, and this stock is directly part of the production
function.
(2) The Gardener view: according to this view, we should not think of human
capital as unidimensional, since there are many many dimensions or types
of skills. A simple version of this approach would emphasize mental vs.
physical abilities as different skills. Let us dub this the Gardener view af-
ter the work by the social psychologist Howard Gardener, who contributed
to the development of multiple-intelligences theory, in particular
emphasiz- ing how many geniuses/famous personalities were very
“unskilled” in some other dimensions.
(3) The Schultz/Nelson-Phelps view: human capital is viewed mostly as the
capacity to adapt. According to this approach, human capital is especially
useful in dealing with “disequilibrium” situations, or more generally, with
situations in which there is a changing environment, and workers have to
adapt to this.
(4) The Bowles-Gintis view: “human capital” is the capacity to work in or-
ganizations, obey orders, in short, adapt to life in a hierarchical/capitalist
society. According to this view, the main role of schools is to instill in
individuals the “correct” ideology and approach towards life.
(5) The Spence view: observable measures of human capital are more a
signal of ability than characteristics independently useful in the
production process.
Despite their differences, the first three views are quite similar, in that “human
capital” will be valued in the market because it increases firms’ profits. This is
straightforward in the Becker and Schultz views, but also similar in the Gardener
view. In fact, in many applications, labor economists’ view of human capital would
be a mixture of these three approaches. Even the Bowles-Gintis view has very
similar implications. Here, firms would pay higher wages to educated workers
because these workers will be more useful to the firm as they will obey orders
better and will be more reliable members of the firm’s hierarchy. The Spence
view is different from
the others, however, in that observable measures of human capital may be
rewarded because they are signals about some other characteristics of workers.
We will discuss different implications of these views below.
(1) Innate ability: workers can have different amounts of skills/human capital
because of innate differences. Research in biology/social biology has
docu- mented that there is some component of IQ which is genetic in
origin (there is a heated debate about the exact importance of this
component, and some economists have also taken part in this). The
relevance of this observation for labor economics is twofold: (i) there is
likely to be heterogeneity in human capital even when individuals have
access to the same investment opportunities and the same economic
constraints; (ii) in empirical appli- cations, we have to find a way of
dealing with this source of differences in human capital, especially when
it’s likely to be correlated with other variables of interest.
(2) Schooling: this has been the focus of much research, since it is the most
easily observable component of human capital investments. It has to be
borne in mind, however, that the R2 of earnings regressions that control
for schooling is relatively small, suggesting that schooling differences
account for a relatively small fraction of the differences in earnings.
Therefore, there is much more to human capital than schooling.
Nevertheless, the analysis of schooling is likely to be very informative if we
presume that the same forces that affect schooling investments are also
likely to affect non-schooling investments. So we can infer from the
patterns of schooling investments what may be happening to non-
schooling investments, which are more difficult to observe.
(3) School quality and non-schooling investments: a pair of identical twins
who grew up in the same environment until the age of 6, and then
completed the same years of schooling may nevertheless have different
amounts of human capital. This could be because they attended different
schools with varying qualities, but it could also be the case even if they
went to the same school. In this latter case, for one reason or another,
they may have chosen to make different investments in other components
of their human capital (one may have worked harder, or studied especially
for some subjects, or because of a variety of choices/circumstances, one
may have become more assertive, better at communicating, etc.). Many
economists believe that these “unobserved” skills are very important in
understanding the structure of wages (and the changes in the structure of
wages). The problem is that we do not have good data on these
components of human capital. Nevertheless, we will see different ways of
inferring what’s happening to these dimensions of human capital below.
(4) Training: this is the component of human capital that workers acquire
after schooling, often associated with some set of skills useful for a
particular industry, or useful with a particular set of technologies. At
some level, training is very similar to schooling in that the worker, at least
to some degree, controls how much to invest. But it is also much more
complex, since it is difficult for a worker to make training investments by
himself. The firm also needs to invest in the training of the workers, and
often ends up bearing a large fraction of the costs of these training
investments. The role of the firm is even greater once we take into account
that training has a significant “matching” component in the sense that it
is most useful for the worker to invest in a set of specific technologies that
the firm will be using in the future. So training is often a joint investment
by firms and workers, complicating the analysis.
LECTURES iN LABOR EcONOMICS
10