Classical Theory of Employment and Output
Classical Theory of Employment and Output
Classical Theory of Employment and Output
To build up a classical macroeconomic model, here we will consider a particular framework within which the
classical system can be studied.
This framework is composed of an aggregate production function, the labour market, the money market, and
the goods market.
1. Employment-Output Determination: Labour Market:
Let us first consider the labour market where we deal with production function in which capital stock is fixed
and labour is the variable input.
The aggregate production function is: Y = f (K , L) … (3.2)
where K denotes a constant capital stock and L denotes quantities of variable input, labour.
In the classical model, equilibrium level of output is determined by the employment of labour. The level of
output and, hence, the level of employment is established in the labour market by the demand for and supply
of labour.
Assuming a profit-maximizing economy, labour will be demanded up to the point where the revenue earned
from selling the total product produced by the marginal unit of labour is equal to the MC of labour. MC of
labour is equal to the money wage divided by the marginal product of labour, MP L, i.e.,
MC = W/MPL
The condition for profit maximization is
where W is the money wage, P is the absolute price level, and W/P is the real wage.
ADVERTISEMENTS:
We know that the MP curve for labour indicates the firm’s demand for labour. More labour is demanded at a
lower wage. Thus, demand for labour depends inversely on real wage. The aggregate demand curve for labour
is the horizontal summation of all individual firm’s demand curve for labour. Aggregate labour demand
function, shown in equation (3.7), is also inversely related to the real wage rate. That is,
DL=f (W-p) …(3.7)
Like labour demand, aggregate labour supply function also depends on the real wage rate, but in a direct
manner. Thus,
SL=g (W/P)… (3.8)
These relationships (equations 3.2, 3.7 and 3.8), together with the equilibrium condition for the labour market
DL = SL … (3.9)
determine output, employment and real wage in the classical system.
Equilibrium real wage rate and the equilibrium level of employment are determined at that point where the
negative sloping labour demand curve cuts the positive sloping labour supply curve. Once we know the equi-
librium level of employment from the aggregate production function we can derive the equilibrium level of
output.
This is shown in Fig. 3.1. In the lower panel, aggregate production function has been shown. The intersection
between DL and SL curves at point E in the upper part of the figure determines the equilibrium level of
employment (LF) at the equilibrium real wage rate (W/P)F. The equilibrium of the classical labour market is one
where everyone willing to work at the real wage (W/P)F is able to find work. Incidentally, this is the full
employment position, denoted by LE = LF. The corresponding equilibrium level of output (at the equilibrium
level of employment) is YF. This equilibrium output level is also called full employment output level.
In the classical system, full employment is achieved automatically due to wage-price flexibility. For instance, at
a real wage (W/P)1 there exists a situation of unemployment. Now, this excess supply of labour (AB) will
reduce the real wage rate until labour supply is equal to the labour demand. Ultimately, real wage rate will
decline to (W/P)F where aggregate labour demand is exactly matched by aggregate labour supply.
It may be added here that the volume of output and employment in the classical system are determined by
only supply side of the market for output. Since the classical model is a supply-determined one, it says that
equiproportionate increases (or decreases) in both money wage and the price level will not change labour
supply.
So we can say that the total demand for money in an economy is a function of money national income or
output. The supply of money and the demand for money jointly establish equilibrium in the money market.
The demand for money equation that will be presented here is the Marshallian cash balance version of the
quantity theory of money. It is;
Md = kPY … (3.10)
where Md stands for demand for money, Y the output level, P the price level and k is the fraction of Y that
people want to hold to facilitate transaction. Equation 3.10 states that people hold cash balance since there is
a gap between money receipts and expenditures.
The supply of money is fixed as it is supplied by the central bank. Thus,
Ms= M …(3.11)
For equilibrium in the money market, = kPY … (3.12)
Equation (3.12) shows a proportional relationship between money stock and the price level. The quantity
theory of money says that the quantity of money determines the price level. It is to be remembered here that
Y is also fixed due to the existence of full employment in the economy.
Fig. 3.2 represents money market equilibrium where we plot total money stock M on the horizontal axis and
the levels of PY on the vertical axis. The vector (OL), the slope of which is (1/k), shows the levels of PY that can
be supported by different quantities of money supply. As money supply increases from M 1 to M2, the price
level rises proportionately from P1to P2.
Thus, we see a link between money supply and the price level: an excess money supply means increasing
demand for commodities that pulls up the general price level. But money supply does not have any impact on
Y which is determined in the real sector and Y is fixed due to full employment. The only way for equilibrium
output to change in this classical model can be attributed to a shift in labour demand or labour supply curve.
One essential feature that follows from the classical money market is that money is neutral. This means that
changes in money stock affect only absolute prices and money wages proportionately. Real variables such as,
output, level of employment and real wage rate remain undisturbed following a change in money supply.