Frank Pasquale - Two Narratives of Platform Capitalism
Frank Pasquale - Two Narratives of Platform Capitalism
Frank Pasquale - Two Narratives of Platform Capitalism
309
YALE LAW & POLICY REVIEW 35:309 2016
4. Simon Stern, Narrativein the Legal Text: Judicial Opinions and Their Narratives, in
NARRATIVE AND METAPHOR IN LAW 8 (Michael Hanne & Robert Weisberg eds.,
forthcoming 2017) (citing J. David Velleman, NarrativeExplanation, 112 PHIL. REV.
1 (2003)).
310
TWO NARRATIVES OF PLATFORM CAPITALISM
311
YALE LAW & POLICY REVIEW 35:309 2016
8. Social scientists and theorists have offered pithy definitions of both platform capi-
talism, and platforms generally. See, e.g., Paul N. Edwards, Carl Lagoze, Jean-
Christophe Plantin &Christian Sandvig, InfrastructureStudies Meet Platform Stud-
ies in the Age of Google and Facebook,1o NEW MEDIA & SOC'Y 1, 7 (2016) (comparing
infrastructure and platforms); Paul Langley & Andrew Leyshon, Platform Capital-
ism: The Intermediationand Capitalization ofDigitalEconomic Circulation,2 FIN.
&
312
TWO NARRATIVES OF PLATFORM CAPITALISM
cars in the afternoon, and write Facebook comments at night, flexibly shifting
between jobs and leisure at will.
But is platform capitalism really a route to opportunity for labor, or just
one more play for capital accumulation in an increasingly stratified economy?"o
A premier platform of digital labor matching-Amazon's Mechanical Turk
(MTurk) `--has permitted purchasers of "human intelligence tasks" to pay al-
most nothing for labor-resulting in effective compensation far lower than the
U.S. minimum wage." Scholars like Trebor Scholz13 and Miriam Cherry 4 have
discussed the sociological and legal implications of platforms that try to dis-
claim responsibility for following labor laws or other regulations. Lilly Irani has
shown just how corrosive platform capitalism has become: "With workers hid-
den in the technology, programmers can treat [workers] like bits of code and
continue to think of themselves as builders, not managers."" The lived experi-
ence of many Uber drivers and "TaskRabbits" shows the downside of disinter-
mediation. Sarah Kessler describes making $1.94 an hour labeling images for a
researcher who put the task for bid on MTurk."6 The median active TaskRabbit
in her neighborhood made $120 a week; Kessler cleared $u an hour on her best
day. 7
io. See Frank Pasquale, Closed-Circuit Economics, BALKINIZATION (Nov. 26, 2010, 11:27
AM), http://balkin.blogspot.com/20lo/11/closed-circuit-economics.html [http://
perma.cc/C386-PQY2].
11. AMAZON MECHANICAL TURK, http://www.mturk.com/mturk/welcome [http://
perma.cc/FFU8-7VAR].
12. See Frank Pasquale, Banana Republic.com, JOTWELL (Jan. 14, 2011), http://cyber
.jotwell.com/banana-republic-com/ [http://perma.cc/T59X-8YFB] (reviewing Jon-
athan Zittrain, Ubiquitous Human Computing, 366 PHIL. TRANSACTIONS ROYAL
SOC'Y 3813 (2008)).
13. See Trebor Scholz, Platform Cooperativism vs. the Sharing Economy, MEDIUM (Dec.
5, 2014), http://medium.com/@trebors/platform-cooperativism-vs-the-sharing-
economy-2ea737fib5ad [http://perma.cc/XUL9-E7AR].
14. Miriam A. Cherry, A Taxonomy of Virtual Work, 45 GA. L. REV. 951 (2011).
15. See Lilly Irani, Justice for "DataJanitors,"PUB. BOOKS (Jan. 15, 2015), http://www
.publicbooks.org/nonfiction/justice-for-data-janitors [http://perma.cc/6RVB-
6LHL].
16. Sarah Kessler, Pixeled & Dimed: On (Not) Getting By in the Gig Economy, FAST
COMPANY (Mar. 18, 2014), http://www.fastcompany.com/3027355/pixel-and-
dimed-on-not-getting-by-in-the-gig-economy [http://perma.cc/J7M8-JQXP].
17. Id.; see also Antonio Casilli, Is There a Global Digital Labor Culture?: Marginaliza-
tion of Work, Global Inequalities, and Coloniality 1 (Oct. 25, 2016) (unpublished),
http://halshs.archives-ouvertes.fr/halshs-o1387649/document [http://perma.cc/
UM62-BKSF] (discussing "the extent to which this vast click farm economy predi-
cated on value and data transfer from the Global South to the North can be con-
strued as a 'neocolonial' system").
313
YALE LAW & POLICY REVIEW 35: 309 2016
18. OURS To HACK AND To OWN: THE RISE OF PLATFORM COOPERATIVISM, A NEW
VISION FOR THE FUTURE OF WORK AND A FAIRER INTERNET (Trebor Scholz & Nathan
Schneider eds., 2016) (collecting essays critiquing platform capitalism and propos-
ing alternatives).
19. Alex Rosenblat & Luke Stark, Uber's Drivers: InformationAsymmetries and Control
in Dynamic Work, io INT'L J. COMM. 3758 (2016).
20. SeeSUSAN CRAWFORD, CAPTIVE AUDIENCE: THE TELECOM INDUSTRY AND
MONOPOLY POWER IN THE NEW GILDED AGE (2014).
21. Id.
22. Susan Crawford, Getting over Uber, BACKCHANNEL (Oct. 16, 2015), http://back
channel.com/getting-over-uber-fdf7sfaf7f6e#.kvfvxjf8 [http://perma.cc/VV7A-
KZYA]. For more work holding powerful digital companies to the standards im-
posed historically on public accommodations, see Aaron Belzer & Nancy Leong,
The New Public Accommodations, 105 GEO. L.J. (forthcoming 2017); Frank Pasqua-
le, Internet NondiscriminationPrinciples, 20o8 U. CHI. LEGAL F. 263, 267 (discussing
the "normative appeal of a common commercial ethic for dominant platforms
online").
23. Crawford, supra note 22.
24. See TOM SLEE, WHAT'S YOURS IS MINE: AGAINST THE SHARING ECONOMY (2016).
314
TWO NARRATIVES OF PLATFORM CAPITALISM
the nature of governance. 5 What happens to a city when its government's re-
sponsibilities are slowly and functionally disaggregated? Some citizens may
want to see the effective governance of paid rides via Uber, of spare rooms via
Airbnb, and so on. A full privatization6 of city governance awaits, from water2 7
to sidewalks.
For partisans of the sharing economy, the shift from territorial governance
(by elected representatives) to functional governance (by firms) will result in a
dynamic mix of corporate semi-sovereigns, all jostling to better serve the pro-
ducers and consumers" on each side of their platforms. But that narrative is
undermined by consolidation of digital platforms. A pattern familiar in online
platforms (where Google/YouTube dominates search in the United States, Bai-
du does so in China; Facebook and its subsidiaries are preeminent in social in
the United States, etc.) is replayed in the dominance of commercial apps for re-
al-space transactions like Uber and AirBnB in the United States, and Didi and
WeChat in China. 2I
The centripetal pull of producers and consumers, and of users and adver-
tisers, toward dominant platforms raises a fundamental question for progres-
sives who want to counter the standard, upbeat neoliberal narrative about the
rise of platform capitalism: should authorities facilitate competition in these
fields? Some believe that, despite all the concentration presently prevailing,
these spaces could become truly competitive over time. That Jeffersonian vision
of decentralized economic power would counsel a greater reliance on antitrust
law in the future.3 0 By contrast, others believe that trends toward monopoliza-
25. Tom Slee, Uber: (Getting Over)A3, MEDIUM (Oct. 18, 2015), http://medium.com/
@whimsley/uber-getting-over-3-e593ade95398#.ch7zu4qy6 [http://perma.cc/VLX5-
HXAA].
26. Jathan Sadowski & Karen Gregory, Is Uber's Ultimate Goal the Privatisationof City
Governance?, GUARDIAN (Sept. 15, 2015), http://www.theguardian.com/technology/
2015/sep/15/is-ubers-ultimate-goal-the-privatisation-of-city-governance [http://
perma.cc/KH4D-UMWJ].
27. See John Vidal, Water Privatization:A Worldwide Failure, GUARDIAN (Jan. 30,
2015), http://www.theguardian.com/global-development/2015/an/3o/water-
privatisation-worldwide-failure-lagos-world-bank [http://perma.cc/6RNC-
2WYZ].
28. See Leo Mirani, The Secret to the Uber Economy Is Wealth Inequality, QUARTZ (Dec.
16, 2014), http://qz.com/312537/the-secret-to-the-uber-economy-is-wealth
-inequality/ [http://perma.cc/49Q6-HA6R].
29. Didi recently purchased Uber China. See Jon Russell, Confirmed: Didi Buys Uber
China in a Bid for Profit, Will Keep Uber Brand, TECHCRUNCH (Aug. 1, 2016),
http://techcrunch.com/2o16/o8/ol/didi-chuxing-confirms-it-is-buying-ubers
-business-in-china! [http://perma.cc/ELL9-HFR5].
30. See BARRY LYNN, CORNERED: THE NEW MONOPOLY CAPITALISM AND THE
ECONOMICS OF DESTRUCTION (2010); Lina Khan & Sandeep Vaheesan, Market Pow-
er and Inequality: The Antitrust Counterrevolutionand Its Discontents, 11 HARV. L.
&
POL'Y REv. (forthcoming 2016); Matthew Stoller, How Democrats Killed Their Pop-
315
YALE LAW & POLICY REVIEW 35:309 2016
tion are even more powerful in the digital economy than they have been in
"brick-and-mortar" industries. 3 1 On this view, government should recognize
the likely persistence of duopolists or monopolists and regulate them like utili-
ties.32
Should policy focus on encouraging competition or regulation? The two
approaches are not mutually exclusive-many forms of regulation could assure
a fairer playing field for competition. However, the standard neoliberal narra-
tive of competition presumes that deregulation is a linchpin of truly open and
contestable markets. These clashing visions of a just social order need to be clar-
ified and sharpened in political debate and qualitative social science-not dis-
solved into technocratic cost-benefit analyses. A one-size-fits-all model of plat-
form capitalism cannot do justice to local norms, values, and cultures.33
A recurring narrative in the technology trade press is that dominant plat-
forms prevail thanks to their own merits: they are either the best coded, the best
designed, or the best marketed. But as the sage in Ecclesiastes put it, "The race is
not to the swift, nor the battle to the strong . . . Luck plays a significant role in
business. The first platform to gain critical mass can leverage that advantage in-
to massive financing, which in turn can scare away competitors. Matters are
particularly dire in two-sided markets like search or ridesharing, where con-
sumers are often in a rush and do not care to learn multiple user interfaces in
order to find the best deal among multiple providers.35
If ridesharing or other platforms really are contestable, other purveyors of
connectivity should be able to break into the market-or even redefine the
316
TWO NARRATIVES OF PLATFORM CAPITALISM
space as a public utility. That, at least, is the hope of many innovators and activ-
ists who are part of the Platform Cooperativism movement. According to its co-
convener, Trebor Scholz, "An app with the basic functionality of UberX can be
duplicated and improved upon by independent developers who are working in
tandem with cooperatives. From the very beginning, the development process
would have to be steered by workers and developers." 6 In other words, the
choice does not need to be between ossified, old-fashioned taxi and hotel ser-
vices, or gleaming new Silicon Valley monopolies. The best aspects of old and
new consumption and labor models could be combined, given the plasticity of
technology and ubiquity of connectivity.
As the technological reorganization of lodging, transit, and other vital ser-
vices accelerates, the platform cooperativists offer a hopeful message. Even if
governance disaggregates, from territorial to functional logics, we can still cre-
ate communities of concern and vectors of competition. If platform coopera-
tives can balance those two imperatives-promoting more streamlined services
while respecting fair labor practices and community norms and obligations-
they may well be able to succeed. But they are only likely to provide a real and
enduring alternative to the current, compromised giants of platform capitalism
if governments give them some initial breathing room (as infant industries),
and promote a level playing field over time.
Is that a wise policy? Among technocrats, we can only answer that question
with cost-benefit analyses and economic modeling. But behind the economic
models lie narratives about desert (dominant firms either did or did not win
their position on account of their own merits), fair competition (which is either
eroded or enabled b regulation), and the weight of stakeholder interests (cur-
rent consumers' interests trump others, or must be balanced with the interests
of future consumers, producers, and others affected by externalities from the
platform). The neoliberal narrative of platform competition lionizes currently
dominant firms, looks with suspicion on virtually all regulation of them, and
gives current consumer interests far more weight than those of other stakehold-
ers. A progressive counternarrative of platform capitalism is more skeptical of
currently dominant firms, promotes regulation as a necessary limit upon their
power, and balances the interests of current consumers with those of future
consumers (who may want the option of choosing small players who would be
driven into oblivion by the current monopolist without state intervention),
workers, and others.3 7
36. Trebor Sholz, Platform Cooperativism vs. the Sharing Economy, MEDIUM (Dec. 5,
2014), http://medium.com/@trebors/platform-cooperativism-vs-the-sharing-
economy-2ea737flb5ad#.fu8p6k8iz [http://perma.cc/FB9N-2EL3].
37. In the case of roomletting, other stakeholders include local governments (reliant
on hotel taxes), neighbors of roomletters, and tenants in need of long-term hous-
ing. In the case of ride services, traffic, pollution, insurance, and tax considerations
are on the regulatory agenda.
317
YALE LAW & POLICY REVIEW 35:309 2016
38. PHILIP MIROWSKI, NEVER LET A SERIOUS CRISIS Go TO WASTE: How NEOLIBERALISM
SURVIVED THE FINANCIAL MELTDOwN 44 (2014) (describing funding for neoliberal
economic research).
39. JOHN MAYNARD KEYNES, THE GENERAL THEORY OF EMPLOYMENT, INTEREST, AND
MONEY 241 (1936).
318
TWO NARRATIVES OF PLATFORM CAPITALISM
319
=OEZ i